Water: Water Privatization and Inequality: Gini Coe For Water Resources in Chile
Water: Water Privatization and Inequality: Gini Coe For Water Resources in Chile
Water: Water Privatization and Inequality: Gini Coe For Water Resources in Chile
Article
Water Privatization and Inequality: Gini Coefficient
for Water Resources in Chile
Juan Correa-Parra 1, * , José Francisco Vergara-Perucich 1 and Carlos Aguirre-Nuñez 2
1 Centro Producción del Espacio, Universidad de Las Américas, Providencia 7500975, Chile; jvergara@udla.cl
2 Escuela de Construcción, Universidad de Las Américas, Providencia 7500975, Chile; caguirre@udla.cl
* Correspondence: juan.correa.correa@edu.udla.cl; Tel.: +56-97-373-9644
Received: 24 September 2020; Accepted: 24 November 2020; Published: 1 December 2020
Abstract: This document makes a comprehensive analysis of the inequality of the water market in
Chile, measured by the Gini coefficient method. The situation of water rights in Chile is of particular
interest because it is a wholly privatized system, where rights are traded in the market and therefore
water is presented as a commodity. This privatization of water in Chile occurred as part of the
process of neo-liberalization since the 1981 Water Code. The results of this study indicate that both
concentration and inequality in the distribution of water rights are very high, which undermines a just
social development process and facilitates the economic exploitation of the environment. It proposes
a profound revision of the application of a mercantile logic to a scarce essential resource for life such
as water and explores the importance of its role as a national good for public use.
1. Introduction
The World Health Organization and UNICEF indicated that Chile is the Latin-American country
with the highest access to safely managed drinking water services [1]. However, water rights are
privatized and diverse conflicts are related to this legal framework regarding a natural resource.
For instance, an increasing number of slums in the country have limited access to safe water [2].
The privatization scheme has triggered conflicts between water rights owners and local communities,
such as the Mapuche-Huilliche case in the south of the territory [3] and with the Atacama communities
in the north [4,5]. Furthermore, the privatized water market has fostered the creation of economic
groups related to the provision of this resource to households; nevertheless, the quality of the products
is not better than the safe water produced by independent firms and scarce regulation concerning
these entrepreneurial activities undermines access to better water for consumers [6]. The water market
in Chile has exploited the resource at such a level that, nowadays, a social movement on a national
scale has organized to contest the privatization of water and to pursue its nationalization as a public
good [7]. There is a contradiction between the global data indicating high access to safely managed
drinking water services and the conflicts occurring in the territories related to the water market in
Chile. In order to illuminate the potential origins of these conflicts, we investigated water inequalities
at global and local levels using a statistical approach. The trigger for the privatization of water started
in 1975, with the political-economic project of the dictatorship, in relation to implementing a radical
free-market economic model privatizing public services usually allocated at the state level. This process
is known as neo-liberalization.
As part of the Chilean process of neo-liberalization, in 1981 the Water Code was created, and this
scarce natural resource began to be commercialized, generating negotiable property rights in what
is known as the water market. Chile is the only country in the world with fully privatized water.
Another particularity in Chile is that the owner of the land has no right over the water that may be
present on that piece of land. Such conditions make the Chilean water market a unique study case,
now critical due to the climatic crisis. In general, the creation of a water market can be based on
the privatization of rights, institutionally controlled business cycles, pricing according to availability,
or determining its free disposal as a fundamental human right for subsistence [8]. In the face of
the climate emergency, water scarcity is a challenge and the management of the resource must be
adapted to the current planetary crisis [9,10]. It is for this reason that it is relevant to critically review
those cases in which water resource management instruments have not been adapted to the climate
crisis. This occurs in the Chilean case, which takes on greater relevance in the face of resistance from
democratic authorities to recognizing the importance of adapting regulation in the water domain
to current times. On 7 January 2020, the Senate of the Republic decided to reject the designation of
water as a national good for public use [11], despite the fact that Chile faces a severe drought [12]
and that the international literature raises the urgency of rethinking models of governance over
natural resources [13]. This article presents relevant evidence regarding the urgency of resuming
this discussion by exposing how the Chilean case can illustrate the complexity of creating a market
through the privatization of water rights for consumption purposes which leads to a high concentration
of ownership of a natural resource, generating speculative scenarios with the commercialization of
property and significant inequality in water access. The water market creates a compounded scenario
that Mehta et al. [14] define as a scarcity policy, where unequal access to water is naturalized, a decision
justified by exclusionary property regimes [15], serving as a strategy to divert attention from other
problems such as the causes of inequality or poverty [16]. Therefore, studying the water market in
Chile provides a view on different aspects of inequality, and not only in access to water.
When a water market was proposed, it is crucial to understand that this is one of the particularities
of Chilean reality, wherein in 1981 water rights were privatized and the values and mechanisms
necessary in order to exchange water for money established a market that sets its prices by the law
of supply and demand. For Boelens [17], in the study of water rights it is critical to identify the
affordability of the resource for users, determining how the owner of the water rights exercises his
power by controlling a scarce resource elemental for the development of life. Boelens proposes that
power relations will define the distribution of water resources, but the discussion also concerns the
restructuring of power relations across society. In the specialized international literature, there is
consensus that the water market should not operate like that for any other type of tradable good and
requires democratic and institutionalized regulations. In some cases, the development of a water
market can improve the efficiency in the distribution of water resources [18], but in the case of weak
regulatory institutions, it can generate speculative frameworks that end up reducing the population’s
access to water [18–20]. The conflictive relationship between water owners and communities has been
presented in literature from qualitative approaches, [21,22] so this article contributes by offering a
nation-wide perspective on how uneven the water market is from a quantitative approach.
Hence, this article seeks to contribute to the discussion of the effects of generating a water market
in a situation of water scarcity, that is to say, a scarcity policy; from the review of its distribution and
sustainability, it takes the case of water rights in Chile. Specifically, it studies the inequality of water
distribution in Chile as measured by the Gini index. To frame the problem, the article presents a
general framework for the origin and scope of water management in Chile, from the first regulations
to the creation of a market through privatization in 1981. The data for the study and the methods used
are then discussed. The source of information analyzed is based on secondary data obtained from
the General Water Directorate of the Ministry of Public Works. These data are georeferenced and the
inequality of the allocation of this resource for consumption is studied, i.e., for waters that are extracted
without reincorporation into supply channels. The method used is a geo-localized Gini index to review
the distribution of the resource spatially. The results argue that privatization optimizes the distribution
of the water resource. The proposal is to open discussion based on the specialized international
literature in order to rethink how to manage water resources in Chile from the institutional and public
policy point of view, considering the important drought that the country faces and in view of the
Water 2020, 12, 3369 3 of 13
climate emergency. Although Chile presents good indicators of human access to drinking water in
urban areas, this study considers total water rights, as the treatment and management of drinking
water for human consumption does not reach more than 12%. In this sense, the concentration of rights
and their use in extractive areas presents a clear risk for these positive indicators in the future.
• Transfer of water management from the State as a public good to the market as a commodity.
• The enshrining of original water rights to generate ownership.
• The work of inspection and conflict resolution among private parties is organized, giving this role
top government.
• Strategic planning for water resource management is generated with a focus on its productive
role, without sufficient emphasis on the sustainability of its use.
With these transformations, the territory as a whole entered a process of privatization for
commercial purposes. For Carl Bauer, the separation of water rights from land rights would be another
Water 2020, 12, 3369 4 of 13
problematic factor since water tributaries crossing a land will not have a direct commercial relationship
with the landowner. This will account for the overlap of property rights on the same land. The use
of water will not have much territorial weight, but will be valuable as an economic resource, so its
primary role for the development of life is subjugated to its commercial efficiency. Making water a
commodity via the 1981 Water Code also marks the emergence of a water market that in those years
followed the recommendations of the Inter-American Development Bank and the World Bank [21].
The main objective argued by the promoters of these reforms was the need to manage water scarcity.
These water policies proposed that access and coverage would be achieved in a better way if the
until then public management of the water resource passed to private hands, in search of increasing
efficiency and improving management, favoring competitiveness in the sector, eliminating barriers for
international companies, reducing regulations, and assuring a 10.3% profitability [16–18]. This was the
fundamental argument of neoliberalism [26].
To be precise, the perspective of increasing efficiency and improving management of the resource
is defined by Panayotakis [27] as “the order of the day”, where governments and elites use the idea of
scarcity to legitimize the capitalist system and its logic, just like the privatization or financialization
of public goods, reserving an exclusive access to these assets to producers only. This privatization
generates severe effects on environmental equilibrium and also on social groups in rural and urban
areas. Mehta [28] considers these effects as a those of a new type of policy regime, where the practice
of resource control ends up by making vulnerable the most deprived communities.
For Bauer [25], the freedom to buy and sell water rights has led to the revaluation of water resources
in certain areas. Still, the adverse effects are related to the normative rigidity of the constitutional and
legal framework of the Water Codes. This makes it difficult for regulations to be adapted to the diverse
uses of water and the nature of water flows, which eventually leads to the aforementioned potential
conflicts over water between companies and communities, or the reduction of efficient management of
the resource due to inadequate exploitation, despite scarce conditions. Using this short-term logic,
water privatization with a focus on productive activities does not consider the common good but
instead aspires to economic return on such activities, thus neglecting the ecological role of water
resources, since productive processes have other objectives related to income and commercial efficiency.
In 2005, a change to the Water Code was introduced. Although the water market was not
disestablished, a monetary tax was generated on the non-exploitation of water resources by those who
held the corresponding water rights, seeking to avoid speculation. According to Peña and Jaeger [29],
the objective of preventing speculation and monopolistic frameworks was to generate a better balance
between the productive role of water and social needs, in addition to adding sustainability criteria
to water resource management. However, it was Peña himself, the author of the reform, who later
recognized that it was made in an adverse political climate, in which the Constitution facilitates the
hindering of progressive reforms, favorable to the conservative political forces that in Chile tend
to prioritize the market over the social function of water [24]. In other words, the reforms were
limited, without managing to resolve the conflicts related to the sustainability of the water market,
preserving the negative characteristics that tend to concentrate resources and access unequally.
Inequality in the distribution of water is a complex scenario. The Water Code establishes a
situation in which the owner of the land has no rights over the water flowing on that land. As the
community leader Rodrigo Mundaca indicates, in Chile there are no planning regulations associated
with the productive capacities of agricultural soil. Therefore, with the person holding water rights on
the one hand and agricultural production on the other, communities’ access to water may be affected
by the consumption industry [1]. Studying the water market in Chile is a means to observe how a
non-comprehensive planning apparatus may undermine community access to natural resources.
Figure 1.
Figure Location of
1. Location of water
water capture
capture points
points registered
registered as
as rights
rights at
at the
the General
General Water
Water Directorate
Directorate of
of the
the
Ministry of Public Works. Source: drawn up by the authors based on data from the Dirección
Ministry of Public Works. Source: drawn up by the authors based on data from the Dirección General General
de Aguas
de Aguas (DGA).
(DGA).
To analyze this data, a study of unequal access to water rights was carried out using the Gini
To analyze this data, a study of unequal access to water rights was carried out using the Gini
coefficient. The Gini coefficient is a method for measuring levels of inequality in the distribution of a
coefficient. The Gini coefficient is a method for measuring levels of inequality in the distribution of a
specific factor in a given population. It is usually used to measure income inequality, as suggested
by its creator, Conrado Gini. The result of the calculation ranges from 0 (total equality) to 1
Water 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 6 of 13
specific factor in a given population. It is usually used to measure income inequality, as suggested by
its creator,
Water 2020, 12,Conrado
3369 Gini. The result of the calculation ranges from 0 (total equality) to 1 (complete
6 of 13
inequality). Its interpretation is simple, which is crucial in a study that seeks to review the problem
of water rights in Chile so that its discussion is taken up by different disciplines, from human rights
(complete inequality). Its interpretation is simple, which is crucial in a study that seeks to review the
approaches to marketing. In particular, we have classified rights to consumptive water according to
problem of water rights in Chile so that its discussion is taken up by different disciplines, from human
the volume of water assigned for each user registered with the General Water Directorate, in order
rights approaches to marketing. In particular, we have classified rights to consumptive water according
to achieve clarity on the levels of inequality in the allocation of water resources.
to the volume of water assigned for each user registered with the General Water Directorate, in order
Then, based on the distribution patterns of water rights, we will be able to review which actors
to achieve clarity on the levels of inequality in the allocation of water resources.
consume the most greatest amount of liters per second and how these results are interpreted in the
Then, based on the distribution patterns of water rights, we will be able to review which actors
light of the water crisis the country is experiencing.
consume the most greatest amount of liters per second and how these results are interpreted in the
To obtain the Gini coefficient, the following calculation was made:
light of the water crisis the country is experiencing.
To obtain the Gini coefficient, the following calculation was made:
𝐺𝑖𝑛𝑖 = 1 − (𝑋 − 𝑋 )(𝑌 − 𝑌 ) (1)
n−1
X
Gini = 1 − (Xk+1 − Xk )(Yk+1 − Yk ) (1)
where X corresponds to the cumulative proportion
k =1 of the variable stakeholders owning water rights
included
where in this study,towhile
X corresponds Y corresponds
the cumulative to the cumulative
proportion proportion
of the variable of water
stakeholders volume
owning measured
water rights
in L/s.
included in this study, while Y corresponds to the cumulative proportion of water volume measured in
L/s.
3. Results
3. Results
For a general description of the sample, out of a total of 131,124 permits granted and registered
in theFor
original database,
a general 128,015
description (97.62%
of the sample,ofout
theoftotal) areofidentified.
a total In this
131,124 permits database,
granted and 54.1% of the
registered in
licenses were for groundwater and 45.9% for surface water. Of the total number of permits,
the original database, 128,015 (97.62% of the total) are identified. In this database, 54.1% of the licenses those
corresponding
were to consumptive
for groundwater and 45.9%water are studied,
for surface whose
water. Of flownumber
the total estimateof is 4,293,280
permits, L/s.corresponding
those As indicated
in Figure
to 2, mostwater
consumptive of the are
non-consumptive
studied, whoselicenses are located
flow estimate near the mountain
is 4,293,280 range in in
L/s. As indicated theFigure
central-
2,
southern zone of the country (regions of Valparaíso, Metropolitana, O’Higgins, Maule, Ñuble,
most of the non-consumptive licenses are located near the mountain range in the central-southern zone Biobio,
Araucanía,
of the countryLos(regions
Ríos and of Los Lagos), Metropolitana,
Valparaíso, while consumptive licenses
O’Higgins, are distributed
Maule, throughout
Ñuble, Biobio, the
Araucanía,
national
Los Ríos territory.
and Los Lagos), while consumptive licenses are distributed throughout the national territory.
Figure 2. National
Figure 2. Nationalmap
mapwith thethe
with permits according
permits to consumptive
according or non-consumptive
to consumptive rights. Source:
or non-consumptive rights.
Compiled by the authors
Source: Compiled based onbased
by the authors information from thefrom
on information DGA.the DGA.
Figure 2 show the distribution of the consumptive and non-consumptive rights throughout the
Chilean territory. In addition to the concentration of extraction spots in the central zone of the country
Water 2020, 12, 3369 7 of 13
(where about 75% of the population is concentrated), more than the 90% of the non-consumptive
rights are localized in this area, particularly in the mountainous area (over 1000 MSL). In these areas,
the water rights are linked principally to hydroelectric companies which generate electricity to supply
urban areas and for economic activities nearby.
When quantifying the value of the water market for surface consumption rights, it is estimated
that it corresponds to a market of USD 45,868,679. One of the problems found in the study is that
the General Water Directorate holds 57.4% of permits, without information on the owners or the
destination relating to these water rights. For this reason, we present the concentration of water rights,
incorporating those protagonists for whom we do not have data (Table 1) and a table of consumptive
rights considering only those for which uses for the water are identified (Table 2).
Table 1. Consumptive water rights by use, including “No data” cases. Source: Author’s elaboration
based on DGA data.
Table 2. Consumptive water rights by use, excluding “No data” cases. Source: Author’s elaboration
based on DGA data.
One of the main observations is that irrigation as a consumptive activity and at the same time a
productive activity, registers 71% of the volume of water transferred, with clear identification of use.
The use of water for irrigation in Chile is equivalent to the annual consumption of 243 million homes,
similar to the number of households in India or 10 times that of the United Kingdom (Figure 3).
Water 2020, 12, 3369 8 of 13
Water 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 8 of 13
Figure 33 presents
Figure presentsaaclear
clearpattern
patternofofthe
thedistribution
distributionofofactivities
activitiesusing
using water
waterforfor
production,
production, such as
such
mining
as activity,
mining which
activity, in relation
which to water
in relation rightsrights
to water tenuretenure
is predominant in both in
is predominant location and volume,
both location and
despite the scarcity of water resources in the Atacama Desert, where most
volume, despite the scarcity of water resources in the Atacama Desert, where most mining mining activities areactivities
situated
(northern
are situated area of the territory).
(northern area of the Onterritory).
the other Onhand,theinother
the central
hand, in valley of Chilevalley
the central both irrigation
of Chile bothand
hydroelectric activities capture most of the water rights. This relationship is related
irrigation and hydroelectric activities capture most of the water rights. This relationship is related to to the greater extent
of cities,
the greaterindustrial
extent ofactivities, and agriculture.
cities, industrial activities,Products with high
and agriculture. demand
Products withforhigh
water are produced
demand for waterin
thisproduced
are valley, especially fruit and
in this valley, wines. fruit and wines.
especially
This result makes it necessary
This result makes it necessary to to review
review whether
whether this this water
water consumption
consumption makes makes aa similar
similar
contribution to the treasury through production taxes, when only
contribution to the treasury through production taxes, when only 2.75% of annual 2.75% of annual sales are concentrated,
sales are
representing only
concentrated, 6.27% of companies
representing only 6.27%inofChile and contributing
companies in Chile and through income tax
contributing from agricultural
through income tax
activities only 0.46% of the fiscal budget (0.11% of GDP). It is also essential
from agricultural activities only 0.46% of the fiscal budget (0.11% of GDP). It is also essential to review thetovolume
review
of privatized
the volume of water distributed
privatized in the regions,
water distributed in thewhere Maule
regions, where (14.69%), O’Higgins
Maule (14.69%), (14.04%)(14.04%)
O’Higgins and the
Metropolitan
and Region Region
the Metropolitan (13.52%)(13.52%)
are whereare awhere
significant part ofpart
a significant the of
total
thenational consumption
total national consumption flow
is concentrated (Table 3). This initial descriptive review allows us to recognize
flow is concentrated (Table 3). This initial descriptive review allows us to recognize the general profile the general profile
of consumptive
of consumptive water water rights
rights in
in Chile
Chile (Figure
(Figure 4)4) and
and the
the importance
importance of of studying levels of
studying levels of inequality
inequality
and concentration.
and concentration.
Table 3. Spatial distribution of permits in the territory by political-administrative region. Source:
Table 3. Spatial distribution of permits in the territory by political-administrative region. Source:
Compiled by the authors based on DGA data.
Compiled by the authors based on DGA data.
Region Region Recount Recount Add
Add UpUpOf the Total
Of the Total
Arica y Parinacota
Arica y Parinacota2281 2281 20,996
20,996 0.49% 0.49%
Tarapacá Tarapacá 1708 1708 37,273
37,273 0.87% 0.87%
Antofagasta
Antofagasta 1022 1022 25,840
25,840 0.60% 0.60%
Atacama Atacama 1592 1592 41,040
41,040 0.96% 0.96%
Coquimbo 11,891 149,198 3.48%
Coquimbo 11,891 149,198 3.48%
Valparaíso 13,958 410,540 9.56%
Valparaíso 13,958 410,540 9.56%
Metropolitana 9575 580,271 13.52%
O’Higgins 8744 602,980 14.04%
Maule 9022 630,651 14.69%
Water 2020, 12, 3369 9 of 13
Table 3. Cont.
Figure
Figure 4.4. Water
Water rights
rights according
according to
to total
total liters/second
liters/second per
percommune.
commune. Source:
Source: Own
Own elaboration
elaboration from
from
DGA data. Figure 4 shows the distribution and volumes of water rights per commune, which illustrates
DGA data. Figure 4 shows the distribution and volumes of water rights per commune, which
the territorial inequalities throughout the country. This map underline the high levels of water
illustrates the territorial inequalities throughout the country. This map underline the high levels of
consumed in the northern areas of the national territory and the high levels of inequality between
water consumed in the northern areas of the national territory and the high levels of inequality
neighboring communes in the central valley of Chile, where industrial activity, hydroelectric generation,
between neighboring communes in the central valley of Chile, where industrial activity, hydroelectric
agro-industrial crops and extended cities act as stresses on natural resources. This situation adds up
generation, agro-industrial crops and extended cities act as stresses on natural resources. This
to a critical scenario for the most vulnerable communities, especially small agricultural and livestock
situation adds up to a critical scenario for the most vulnerable communities, especially small
producers whose access to water is uneven in relation to the big companies owning water rights [12,13].
agricultural and livestock producers whose access to water is uneven in relation to the big companies
owning water rights [12,13].
The Gini coefficient for all permits at the national level is 0.9999585 and, in the specific case
of surface consumption rights, this reaches a value of 0.9537 (Table 4). At first glance, the level of
The Gini coefficient for all permits at the national level is 0.9999585 and, in the specific case of
inequality is abysmal, and concentration is very high. In this study, 1% of registered actors own 79.02%
surface consumption rights, this reaches a value of 0.9537 (Table 4). At first glance, the level of
of the total volume of water available in the system, which in turn makes up only 4.3% of the existing
inequality is abysmal, and concentration is very high. In this study, 1% of registered actors own
water property rights. In other words, we see very high inequality and very high concentration of
79.02% of the total volume of water available in the system, which in turn makes up only 4.3% of the
water resources.
existing water property rights. In other words, we see very high inequality and very high
concentration of water resources.
Water 2020, 12, 3369 10 of 13
Table 4. Study of the Gini Coefficient at the national level for the total and specific superficial consumer
rights. Source: Prepared by the authors.
The distribution of water rights in all regions of Chile shows very high inequality (Table 5),
fluctuating between 0.8309 (Atacama Region) and 0.9721 (O’Higgins and Ñuble Regions). The most
unequal areas correspond to the central sector of the country, where there are greater population and
agricultural developments, reflected in regions such as O’Higgins, Maule and Metropolitan, which,
although they have fewer water rights, delivered 4726 rights, equivalent to 10.6% of the national
total; each right has in proportion more liters/second than the rest of the nation, equal to 42.9% of the
national total. In other words, the highest consumption of liters/second occurs in the central valley, in
areas with a high preponderance of agricultural activities that demand irrigation, such as vineyards,
avocados, berries and fruits in general.
Table 5. Summary of Gini Coefficient results by national regions. Source: Prepared by the authors.
4. Discussion
When speculation occurs, decisions are made about specific actions without enough evidence
about what is believed to generate optimal results for everyone in the future. A speculative process
results from the search for rewards with a strong element of chance. Indeed, speculation has no
scientific basis since it is driven by belief rather than evidence. Using this definition as a starting point,
we can state that in Chile there is a process of water speculation, given that its consumption would
indicate that more water is consumed than is naturally regenerated. A water ownership scheme has
Water 2020, 12, 3369 11 of 13
modeled a scenario of scarcity. As Mehta et al. indicate [14], this capitalist fueled scarcity produces a
situation in which natural resources have become the focus of global discussion, allowing governments
to legitimize the privatized management of resource rights. In the case of Chile, this benefit becomes
monetary capital which can be accumulated in rights and used for speculative enterprises which
lead to drastic inequality of access to water for people. Restrictions of direct access to user groups
benefits a minority with economic and productive interests, principally linked to the social and
economic inequalities rooted in Chilean society [31]. Therefore, in our interpretation, water markets
reduce accessibility to natural resources because the price of water rights hinders universal access
in low-income communities, an everyday reality in rural areas. Given the way in which the water
market in Chile is conducted, the use of water rights as financial assets which increase price over
time is problematic for social development, and the social benefits of this mode of managing natural
resources are difficult to find. Hence, speculation in water rights is one of the results of having a water
market for distributing water.
To illustrate this problem with an analogy, it is as if water is being consumed that the glaciers will
not run out, while in reality the water supplies of the planet are reaching an abundance threshold,
producing scarcity. The mere fact that runoff is much lower than productive consumption generates a
deep concern, where sustainability of water resources are compromised in the future. Do we know if
the runoff of glaciers is enough for domiciliary consumption and more sustainable forms of production?
Some authors [31,32] assert that the naturalization of the scarcity of natural resources, as an acceptable
phenomenon not created by society, justifies exclusionary property practices, as with the public right
to access nature.
Without regulatory mechanisms appropriate to the Chilean reality [33–35], the water market
and its speculative characteristics are dangerous for subsistence in Chile. This complexity, that
especially affects rural communities [36], needs to be remedied through public policy and the structural
transformation of property management in Chile.
On the one hand, the World Bank proposes that water markets should be formalized and more
transparent, which leads to significant price dispersion, unclear operating costs and considerable
information asymmetries among market participants. The latter could lead to the development
of inequitable economic activities concerning exchange processes. Recently, the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) has proposed that Chile increase its tax collection by
increasing (or creating) taxes on the exploitation of natural resources (such as water) to finance new
social and infrastructure projects needed to advance development.
The water market is more important in areas where the resource is scarcer [37–39]. However, this
is contradicted by much of the literature that presents a critical view of water resource distribution.
To understand the idea of the water market, then, we can conclude that water privatization is far from
being a socially just way of distributing resources in a society that, in addition, presents high levels of
inequality and segregation [40–42].
The climate emergency represents another critical point in the discussion. This crisis will increase
the intensity and frequency of extreme events which will cause mass migration waves and food and
water insecurity, increasing the occurrence of violent climate conflicts [27,32]. Chile is no exception,
considering the social and political conflicts in the Latin-American region, where people from different
countries migrate to Chile in search of better opportunities, working in primary economic activities like
mining, forestry or agriculture, three activities entirely linked to water rights and community conflicts.
Finally, this work represents the first approximation of an inequality metric and spatial perspective
on the concentration of water rights in the continental territory of Chile. With a nation-wide perspective,
the article links not only with localization but also indicates the type of rights assigned, the number of
liters granted and the ways of using of the resource, all strongly related to the productivity of mining,
forestry and agriculture, which are the primary resources of the Chilean economy. We have shared the
data freely to contribute to further analysis and studies related to water rights.
Water 2020, 12, 3369 12 of 13
Author Contributions: Conceptualization, J.F.V.-P.; methodology, J.C.-P.; validation, J.C.-P., C.A.-N. and J.F.V.-P.;
formal analysis, J.C.-P., C.A.-N. and J.F.V.-P.; investigation, J.C.-P.; resources, J.C.-P.; data curation, J.C.-P. and
J.F.V.-P.; writing—original draft preparation, J.F.V.-P.; writing—review and editing, J.C.-P., C.A.-N. and J.F.V.-P.;
visualization, J.C.-P.; funding acquisition, J.F.V.-P. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of
the manuscript.
Funding: This research was funded by ANID, grant number FONDECYT 11180569 and Universidad de
Las Américas.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
References
1. UNICEF and WHO. Joint Monitoring Programme for Water Supply, Sanitation and Hygiene JMP WASH.
2017. Available online: https://washdata.org/data/household#!/table?geo0=region&geo1=sdg&geo2=Latin%
20America%20and%20the%20Caribbean (accessed on 17 November 2020).
2. Ojeda, L.; Mansilla, Q.P.; Rodríguez, J.C.; Pino, V.A. The access to water in informal settlements. The case of
Valparaíso, Chile. Bitácora Urbano Territ. 2020, 30, 151–165. [CrossRef]
3. Rojas, M.A.L.; Garcia, P.A. Estrategias cosmopolticas para la defensa del agua en territorio Mapuche-Huilliche.
Agua Territ. 2019, 14, 45–56. [CrossRef]
4. Bolados, G.P.; Babidge, S. Rituality and extractivism. The cleaning of channels and the disputes for the water
in the salt flat of Atacama, north of Chile. Estud. Atacamenos 2017, 54, 201–216.
5. Prieto, M. Irrigation that the Market Does Not Want to See: History of the Water Dispossession in the
Communities of Lasana and Chiu-Chiu (Atacama Desert, Chile). J. Lat. Am. Geogr. 2017, 16, 69–91. [CrossRef]
6. Molinos-Senante, M.; Farías, R. Evaluation of the influence of economic groups on the efficiency and quality of
service of water companies: An empirical approach for Chile. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2018, 25, 23251–23260.
[CrossRef] [PubMed]
7. Torres-Salinas, R.; García-Carmona, A.; Rojas-Hernández, J. Privatizando el agua, produciendo sujetos
hídricos: Análisis de las políticas de escala en la movilización socio-hídrica contra Pascua Lama e HidroAysén
en Chile. Agua Territ. 2017, 10, 149–166. [CrossRef]
8. Bakker, K. The Business of Water: Market Environmentalism in the Water Sector. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour.
2014, 39, 469–494. [CrossRef]
9. Gosling, S.N.; Arnell, N.W. A global assessment of the impact of climate change on water scarcity. Clim. Chang.
2016, 134, 371–385. [CrossRef]
10. Hanjra, M.A.; Qureshi, M.E. Global water crisis and future food security in an era of climate change.
Food Policy 2010, 35, 365–377. [CrossRef]
11. Senado de la República de Chile. Rechaza Reforma Constitucional Sobre Dominio y Uso de Aguas,
Valparaíso, Chile. 2020. Available online: https://www.senado.cl/appsenado/index.php?mo=tramitacion&
ac=getDiscusion&nrobol=612409_P&idsesion=8454 (accessed on 10 October 2020).
12. Vergara-Perucich, F.; Jara, B.; Lufin, M.; Roco, L.; Arias-Loyola, M. El Mercado del Agua: Una Mirada Económica
al Caso de Chile. El Agua en Antofagasta; Centro de Investigación Tecnológica del Agua en el Desierto
CEITSAZA: Antofagasta, Chile, 2017; pp. 27–45.
13. Aldunce, P.; Borquez, R.; Adler, C.; Blanco, G.; Garreaud, R.D. Unpacking Resilience for Adaptation:
Incorporating Practitioners’ Experiences through a Transdisciplinary Approach to the Case of Drought in
Chile. Sustainability 2016, 8, 905. [CrossRef]
14. Mehta, L.; Huff, A.; Allouche, J. The new politics and geographies of scarcity. Geoforum 2019, 101, 222–230.
[CrossRef]
15. Champeyrache, C. Artificial scarcity, power, and the Italian Mafia. J. Econ. Issues 2014, 48, 625–640. [CrossRef]
16. Mehta, L. The Limits to Scarcity: Contesting the Politics of Allocation; Earthscan: London, UK, 2010.
17. Boelens, R. Water rights, indigenous management and national legislation. The indigenous struggle for
water and cultural policies of participation. Boletín Arch. Histórico Agua 2003, 8, 5–19.
18. Pahl-Wostl, C. A conceptual framework for analysing adaptive capacity and multi-level learning processes
in resource governance regimes. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2009, 19, 354–365. [CrossRef]
19. Kirsch, B.R.; Maxwell, R.M. The Use of a Water Market to Minimize Drought-Induced Losses in the Bay Area
of California. J. Am. Water Work. Assoc. 2015, 107, E274–E281. [CrossRef]
Water 2020, 12, 3369 13 of 13
20. Larraín, S. El Agua en Chile: Entre los Derechos Humanos y las Reglas del Mercado. Polis. Rev. Latinoam.
2006, 14, 1–21.
21. World Bank. CHILE. Diagnóstico de la Gestión de los Recursos Hídricos; Departamento de Medio Ambiente y
Desarrollo Sostenible Región para América Latina y el Caribe: Santiago, Chile, 2011.
22. Bauer, C. Water Conflicts and Entrenched Governance Problems in Chile’s Market Model. Water Altern.
2015, 8, 147–172.
23. Donoso, G. Water (Rights) Markets: Experiences and Proposals in South America; United Nations Publications:
New York, NY, USA, 2014.
24. Bauer, C.J. Contra la Corriente: Privatización, Mercados de Agua y el Estado en Chile; Lom Ediciones: Santiago,
Chile, 2002.
25. Peña, H. Meaning and Scope of Water Code Reform in Chile; Circular N. 22; Network for Cooperation in
Integrated Water Resource Management for Sustainable Development in Latin America and the Caribbean:
Santiago, Chile, 2005.
26. Larraín, S. Glaciares chilenos: Reservas estratégicas de agua dulce. Rev. Ambiente Desarrollo 2007, 23, 28–35.
27. Panayotakis, C. Remaking Scarcity: From Capitalist Inefficiency to Economic Democracy; Pluto Press: London,
UK, 2011.
28. Mehta, L. The Politics and Poetics of Water: The Naturalisation of Scarcity in Western India; Orient Blackswan:
Telangana, India, 2005.
29. Jaeger, P.; Peña, H. Del Orden Neoliberal al Régimen de lo Público, en Materia de Aguas; XV Jornadas de Derecho
de Aguas; Universidad Católica de Chile: Santiago, Chile, 2013.
30. DGA. Derechos de Aprovechamiento de Aguas Registrados en DGA; Dirección General de Aguas: Santiago,
Chile, 2020.
31. García, P.B.; Olguín, F.H.; Mahn, C.C.; Cuevas, A.S. La eco-geo-política del agua: Una propuesta desde
los territorios en las luchas por la recuperacin del agua en la provincia de Petorca (Zona central de Chile).
Rev. Rupturas 2017, 8, 159–191. [CrossRef]
32. Mehta, L. Water and human development. World dev. 2014, 9, 59–69. [CrossRef]
33. Panez-Pinto, A.; Faúndez-Vergara, R.; Mansilla-Quiñones, C. Politization of the hydrological crisis in Chile:
An analysis of the conflict over water in the Petorca Province. Agua Territ. 2017, 10, 131–148. [CrossRef]
34. De Carvalho, S.; Ana, C.; Magalhães, R.D.P.; Iacomini, V. Privatização dos recursos hídricos no Chile e sua
prevalência sobre o direito fundamental à água. Braz. J. Anim. Environ. Res. 2019, 2, 846–849.
35. Maturana, H. Defensa del Servicio del Agua: Una Postura Sindical. In El Derecho al Agua en el Sur de las
Américas; Alianza Chilena por un Comercio Justo, Ético y Responsable (ACJR): Santiago, Chile, 2002.
36. Bravo, P. Agua: Dónde Está y de Quién es; Programa Chile Sustentable: Santiago, Chile, 2003.
37. Pinto, A.P.; Quiñones, P.M.; Moreira-Muñoz, A. Agua, tierra y fractura sociometabólica del agronegocio.
Actividad frutícola en Petorca, Chile. Bitácora Urbano-Territorial 2018, 28, 153–160. [CrossRef]
38. Schleyer, R.G. Chilean Water Policy: The Role of Water Rights, Institutions and Markets.
Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 1996, 12, 33–48. [CrossRef]
39. Ríos, M.A.; Quiroz, J.A. The market of water rights in Chile: Major issues. Cuad. Econ. 1995, 1, 317–345.
40. Harvey, D. A Brief History of Neoliberalism; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2005.
41. Gómez-Lobo, A.; Paredes, R. Reflexiones Sobre el Proyecto de Modificación del Código de Aguas; Universidad de
Chile: Santiago, Chile, 2000.
42. Donoso, G.; De Chile, P.U.C. Water markets: Case study of Chiles 1981 Water Code. Cienc. Investig. Agrar.
2006, 33, 131–146. [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional
affiliations.
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).