Washington Consensus Chapter
Washington Consensus Chapter
Washington Consensus Chapter
John Williamson
Ever since I suggested that there was a useful measure of consensus at the end of
the 1980s about the policies that Latin American countries needed to adopt in order
to end the debt crisis and start building a brighter future, a vast number of consensi
have been proclaimed. Apart from my own Washington Consensus, there is the
augmented Washington Consensus (with parts of which I differ profoundly), the
Barcelona Agenda (which was almost called a Consensus), the Beijing Consensus,
the Beijing-Seoul-Tokyo Consensus (the BeST Consensus), the Buenos Aires
Consensus, the Copenhagen Consensus (though this dealt with different issues and
was not aimed at replacing the Washington Consensus), the London Consensus, the
post-Washington Consensus, the Santiago Consensus, the Seoul Consensus, and the
Singapore Consensus. Doubtless other cities have had consensi named after them.
Let me state at the outset that I do not believe that listing desirable policies
solves all of the profound problems of economic development. I agree with Dani
Rodrik (2007) in believing that there are also issues of priority and implementation
that agreement on the objectives does not address. I nevertheless do believe that a
clear view of the proximate objectives is valuable. I also believe that there are major
differences between alternative statements of what commands a consensus.
Accordingly I take the view that I have a topic worth discussing.
1
The Beijing Consensus
Hence in this paper we shall contrast the policies pursued by China with
those called for by the Washington Consensus.
1. Fiscal discipline. Governments should aim to restrict budget deficits to a level that
can be financed in a non-inflationary manner. (I should have added that if interpreted
as a medium-run objective this can be a corollary to, rather than competitive with,
fiscal policy being conducted in a counter-cyclical manner.) NO VIEW WAS TAKEN, OR
IS IMPLIED, ABOUT THE RIGHT COMBINATION OF EXPENDITURE RESTRAINT AND TAX
POLICY TO ACHIEVE FISCAL DISCIPLINE.
3. In re-designing tax policy, governments should aim to raise revenue by a broad tax
base combined with moderate marginal tax rates.
5. The exchange rate should be unified and set at a level that is competitive. (I define a
competitive rate as one that is not overvalued, i.e. is either correctly valued or
undervalued.)
2 He tells us that the Beijing Consensus consists of three theorems, but these are not
sufficiently well-defined to identify the Beijing Consensus.
2
speed with which tariffs should ideally be reduced and the expediency of allowing the
process to be interrupted by adverse economic developments.
8. State enterprises should be privatized. (The statement is somewhat bald, but was
intended to imply that every Latin American country had state enterprises that would
be better off privatized rather than that there is never a justification for state
enterprise.)
Encouraging Innovation
This has again been explicitly favored by many adherents of the BC, while the WC is
silent on the topic. One could make a case similar to that offered above for not
including this topic in the WC, but in this case there is an argument for regarding the
omission more seriously. A popular recent development has been the tendency to
assert the existence of a middle-income trap (see, for example, World Bank and
Development Research Center of Chinas State Council 2012), and one antidote
suggested is to change the mix of industries in which a country specializes to more
technology-intensive, or innovation-intensive, ones. I am concerned that the notion
of a middle-income trap has never been properly demonstrated and that it may
well be an illusion (Williamson 2012b). But I did not claim to prove the converse,
3
and the possibility should be taken seriously. The Beijing Consensus, unlike the WC,
mentions a possible antidote.
Macroeconomic Stability
This was a major theme in the WC (items 1-3, though monetary policy was not
mentioned, betraying the historic origins of the WC). Beijing has maintained
something close to price stability ever since 1949, even during the Great Leap
Forward and associated famine, when there was a massive increase in food prices.
When necessary, notably during the world recession starting in 2008, it has
employed Keynesian policies of demand stimulation in order to keep the economy
near full capacity operation. In giving a high priority to maintaining macroeconomic
balance, China has proved typically Asian. This part of the WC has received has
never been problematic in Asia.
Other countries have now followed the Asian and WC lead: rapid inflation
has been essentially eliminated from Africa and Latin America. Item 1 of the WC is
not controversial. There have of course been innumerable fights (not least in
Washington) about the mix of expenditure cuts and tax rises used to achieve fiscal
discipline, but the goal is no longer seriously contested. As I emphasized in the
preceding presentation of the WC, the mix that should be used was not a part of my
version of the WC, although the populist version of the WC called for this to be
achieved by expenditure reduction.
An Open Economy
Points 5, 6, and 7 of the WC deal with this topic, calling for a competitive exchange
rate, trade liberalization, and opening toward inward FDI. (My version of the WC,
unlike the popular version, specifically did NOT call for countries to engage in
general capital account opening.) Beijing liberalized inflows of FDI very early in the
reform era and beginning in the mid-1990s reduced protection substantially as a
condition for joining the WTO, so there is no contradiction on points 6 and 7.
Exchange rate policy is less clear. By a competitive exchange rate I understand one
that is not overvalued, so that technically Beijing (which has in practice used an
undervalued exchange rate as the main tool for achieving its occasionally large and
certainly consistent current account surpluses) satisfied this one too. Moreover, if
one measures the openness of the economy in the traditional way, by the ratio of
exports to GDP, then the Chinese economy is the most open large economy in the
world.
4
I nonetheless feel some qualms about declaring China guiltless in terms of its
external relations. This is primarily because it remains opposed to any attempt to
impose an international discipline on exchange rates3, and certainly has not
abandoned the practice of running an undervalued exchange rate and the resulting
current account surplus.
I do not think the central issue on which Beijing and Washington differ is well
caught by the WC (primarily because this was written for Latin America at a time
when there was on prospect of the region developing current account surpluses).
The fundamental issue is whether surplus countries have a duty as a member of the
international community to take action to curb their surpluses. Even though I
believe the demands coming from Washington have confused this message by
expressing it as a demand for floating, the basic demand seems to me entirely
reasonable, and I would like to see it codified as an IMF duty to avoid large
surpluses. The fact that Beijing resists the notion of placing a limit on the surpluses
that countries should pursue is a dis-service to far more than the United States: it
also makes life far more difficult for most other developing countries, as well as to
the cause of building a robust international system, and to the Immediate prospects
of restoring prosperity in the advanced world.
Market Liberalization
5
The demand for market liberalization is expressed in #4, 6, 8, 9, and perhaps 10 of
the WC. This is surely the most basic difference between Beijing and the WC: the fact
that even stripped of the absurdities of demands for a minimal state and a belief in
the ubiquity of perfect competition (characteristics of the popular version of the WC
but emphatically not my version), the WC is basically pro-market while Beijing
allows a far larger role for the state. Indeed, since macro-stabilization and opening
up to international trade (globalization) are nowadays uncontroversial in most of
the developing world, one infers that it was this aspect of the WC which provoked
the strong reactions to it.
On the general topic of market liberalization, I would offer two reactions. The
first is that Beijing has in fact undertaken a fair measure of market liberalization,
and that it is this that prompted the impressive growth of the Chinese economy,
rather than the continuing existence of SOEs. By the end of the 1990s China had
already liberalized most commodity (though not factor) prices. In 1978 three-
quarters of manufactures in China were produced by SOEs, while this figure had
fallen to under one-quarter by 2010. (And this decline is not an artifact of changing
definitions: SOEs include those that have listed on national or foreign stock
exchanges but still have major government participation.) Desire to proclaim a BC is
more a characteristic of Western than of Chinese economists.
The second is that there are different forms of market economy, and it is far
from obvious that the only way, let alone the right way, to define a market economy
is by the absence of the state. This is shown most clearly by the fact that many
countries have developed an anti-monopoly (anti-trust) policy. If the maintenance
of vigorous competition is dependent upon state action, and one regards a market
economy as characterized by competition, than a market economy depends on state
action. Of course, it is state action of a particular kind, and does not suggest that all
state actions (such as nationalization or the institution of an industrial policy) are to
be welcomed. The point is that one cannot judge a market-oriented policy by the
test that was often used in the aftermath of the crisis, the minimization of the role of
the state.
6
The second element of market liberalization included in the WC is trade
liberalization. Opponents of liberalization have often pointed out that most
presently developed countries went though a phase of protecting their infant
industries when they were developing, and therefore accuse those who argue that
presently developing countries should liberalize trade of hypocrisy. There are
several answers to this critique. First, past levels of protection were modest
compared to the barriers that many hopefully developing countries erected in the
postwar period. Second, it may be that protection was a bow to sectional interests
that impeded overall development in the now-developed countries, rather than the
boon to development that is portrayed. It is certainly not true that every presently
developed country embraced protection at some stage: Hong Kong provides the
most vivid counter-example. Third, while it is difficult to refute the argument that
some protection of infant industries may help to establish new industries, it is easy
to point to examples of industries that have failed to grow up and continued to need
protection for many years.
One should also note that the WC is to be judged as a whole rather than by its
independent parts. It is absurd to blame Argentinas trade liberalization for its
economic collapse and ignore Argentinas failure to maintain a competitive
exchange rate; trade liberalization only makes sense if there are thriving export
industries into which the resources displaced from import-competing industries can
flow.
It is, however, wrong to regard this as the only factor at stake in choosing the
size of the state sector. Most analyses, including comparisons of the performance of
various sectors in China, favor privately-owned over state-owned companies. For
example, the study by the World Bank and the Development Research Center of
Chinas State Council (2012, p.211) calculated the return on equity in state and
private companies over the years 1998-2009 and showed that the return was
always greater in private enterprises, approaching being double by 2009. Similarly,
the National Bureau of Statistics has found the return on equity was always greater
in the private sector, and was most recently over 14% (versus under 6% for the
state sector). Despite this, privatization probably heads the list of the unpopular
elements of the WC. One reason for this is without much doubt the manner in which
privatization has often been undertaken: corruptly, so as to channel rents to cronies.
7
Clearly privatization needs to be handled transparently and in a manner that can be
expected to have no first order effects on income distribution, and this should have
been added to the WC to have any hope of producing a statement of consensus
views.
The final element of the WC that has often been taken to be pro-market was
the furthering of property rights, with the emphasis on extending these to the
informal sector reflecting specifically (though not exclusively) Latin America. Secure
property rights are usually reckoned to be of fundamental importance to growth in
a market economy, since no one has an incentive to take care of the future unless
they expect to be the major beneficiary. Dani Rodrik has often remarked on the
paradox of Chinas fast growth rate in view of its dubious property rights.
I never claimed that the WC contained all the elements needed for fast
growth. If one asks what the East Asian countries that enjoyed fast growth had in
common, the answer is a demographic transition; competitive exchange rates; good
education; high savings; and macroeconomic stability. If one excepts Hong Kong,
one can add an active state role, typically taking the form of an industrial policy.
Demographic factors are exogenous. A competitive exchange rate was applauded
(explicitly) in the WC. Education made it only parenthetically, in #2, but there would
seem no contradiction. High savings were not mentioned at all, because this was not
perceived as an obstacle to Latin American countries escaping from the debt crisis
in 1989, but it is difficult to envisage a coherent objection. Macro stability was
certainly emphasized by the WC. In any event, the element on which opponents of
the WC have seized (notwithstanding the embarrassment of Hong Kong, which was
simply declared a city-state and therefore irrelevant) is industrial policy.
8
Authoritarianism
Not only do they refuse to countenance democracy at home, but they always
oppose efforts to use the international organizations to spread any sort of
democratic (or, for that matter, human rights) notions. This is done in the name of
national sovereignty, which means that it is often popular with the public of the
affected state as well as (naturally) with their rulers.
Concluding Remarks
There are two reasons why following the WC might not induce rapid growth, quite
apart from the possibility embraced by the critics that the policies are basically
wrong. The first is that it was not constructed for that purpose, and therefore it
omits certain policies that are essential. The second is that it was designed to be an
expression of consensus views, and if some essential policies were espoused only by
a minority then they would not appear. In practice I would judge the first factor to
9
be the overwhelmingly important one. The examination of the individual policies
recommended by the WC did not reveal any to be inappropriate, let alone harmful.4
4 I reached a similar conclusion when I was invited by the World Bank to consider
the appropriateness of the Washington Consensus as a formula for development
(see Williamson 2005).
10
References
Acemoglu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail The Origins of
Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (New York: Crown Business, 2012).
Doucouliagos, Hristos, and Mehmet Ali Ulubaolu. 2008. Democracy and Economic
Growth: A Meta-Analysis. American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 52, No. 1,
January 2008, Pp. 6183.
Halper, Stefan. 2010. The Beijing Consensus: How Chinas Authoritarian Model Will
Dominate the Twenty-first Century. (New York: Basic Books.)
Ramo, Joshua Cooper. 2004. The Beijing Consensus. (London: The Foreign Policy
Centre.)
Rodrik, Dani. 2007. One Economics, Many Recipes. (Princeton: Princeton University
Press.)
Williamson, John. 1990. Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened?
(Washington: Institute for International Economics.)
____. 2012a. Is the Beijing Consensus Now Dominant? Asia Policy, 13, January, 1-16.
World Bank and the Development Research Center of Chinas State Council. 2012.
China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative High-Income Society.
(Washington: World Bank.)
11
12