Selling Too Early
Selling Too Early
Selling Too Early
December 2018
In developing the efficient market hypothesis, Fama (1970) argued that prices reflect the
true fundamental values of assets because rational investors trade away any opportunities to
purchase undervalued stocks or sell stocks at inflated prices. Even if some investors do trade
irrationally, sophisticated experts would trade against them and eliminate any temporary
mispricing. Since then, a large literature has demonstrated that investors do indeed use
heuristics and are prone to systematic biases. Individual investors have been shown to be
overconfident (Barber and Odean 2001), sensation-seeking (Grinblatt and Keloharju 2009),
and to have limited attention (Barber and Odean 2008). However, the majority of evidence
documenting biased behavior of individual investors comes from data on retail investors
(Barber and Odean 2011) or day traders (Barber, Lee, Liu, and Odean 2014), who generally
hold modest portfolios.1 It remains important to better understand the extent to which the
decisions of market experts are prone to behavioral biases, and, if so, the effect of the resulting
biases on performance.
This paper examines the trade decisions of sophisticated market participants – experi-
enced institutional portfolio managers (PMs) – using a rich data set containing their daily
holdings and trades. Our data is comprised of 783 portfolios, with an average portfolio (man-
aged on behalf of a single institutional client) valued at approximately $573 million. More
than 89 million fund-security-trading dates and 4.4 million trades (2.0 and 2.4 million sells
and buys, respectively) are observed between 2000 and 2016. We evaluate performance by
constructing counterfactual portfolios, and compare PMs’ actual decisions to returns of the
counterfactual. Since PMs often need to raise capital by selling existing positions in order to
buy, evaluating a selling decision relative to a counterfactual which is unrelated to existing
holdings (e.g., a benchmark index) is not an appropriate comparison.2 Instead, we evaluate
selling decisions relative to a conservative counterfactual that assumes no skill: randomly
selling an alternative position that was not traded on the same date.
We document a striking pattern: while the investors display clear skill in buying, their
selling decisions underperform substantially. Positions added to the portfolio outperform
1
There are several notable exceptions: Frazzini (2006) and Jin and Scherbina (2010) present evidence for
the disposition effect using data from SEC mutual fund filings. Coval and Shumway (2005) and Liu, Tsai,
Wang, and Zhu (2010) present evidence for history-dependent risk-taking from market makers on the Chicago
Board of Trade and the Taiwan Futures Exchange, respectively. Work has also documented behavioral biases
amongst experts in corporate finance settings (see Malmendier (2018) for review).
2
An asset sold may outperform a benchmark index, but the sale may still be optimal depending on what is
bought with that capital and what other assets could have been sold (e.g. an alternative may have gone up
even more). In turn, a counterfactual for selling in a long-only portfolio must consider current holdings.
We present evidence consistent with the discrepancy in performance between buy and sell
decisions being driven by an asymmetric allocation of cognitive resources, particularly atten-
tion. When selling decisions coincide with exogenous releases of salient and portfolio-relevant
information – company earnings announcements – sales also outperform the counterfactual.
Buying and selling decisions are fairly similar in their underlying fundamentals: both re-
quire incorporating information to forecast the future performance of an asset. Forecasting
returns with greater accuracy should improve the performance of purchases and sales. Skill
in both decisions requires the investor to look for relevant information and integrate it into
the forecast. Paying relatively little attention to selling would hinder the first step. But if
the investor attends to the relevant information, then skill in buying should translate to skill
in selling. Specifically, if decision-relevant information is salient and readily available, such
as in the case of earnings announcements, differences in performance between buys and sells
should be mitigated.
Indeed, it does not appear that the investors lack fundamental skills for selling: selling
decisions appear to capitalize on information during earnings announcements and outperform
the counterfactual by between 90 and 120 basis points annually. This performance is in stark
contrast to sales on non-announcement days, which consistently trail the random selling
strategy by up to 200 basis points annually. On the other hand, the performance of purchases
around announcement days does not meaningfully differ from those on non-announcement
days. This is consistent with attention being generally allocated to buying decisions; in this
case, the relevant information shock does not add much to the attention already devoted to
making purchases.
Moreover, we find an empirical link between the underperformance in selling and PMs’
use of salient information in choosing what to sell. Various measures of prior returns are
3
As a benchmark, 100 basis points is double the typical annual management fee charged to investors in
actively-managed mutual funds.
4
Section 6 demonstrates that our results are robust to risk adjustment by replacing raw counterfactual returns
with those of beta-neutral strategies that take out exposure to risk factors in the Fama-French/Carhart 4
factor model. We also show that the results hold for PMs who trade in developed and developing markets.
The tendency to sell positions with extreme returns is robust to numerous alternative
specifications. Using annual, quarterly, weekly, or since-initial purchase cumulative returns
yields the same U-shaped selling pattern. The pattern emerges regardless of how the assets
are grouped; PMs are more likely to sell assets with extreme returns when considering 6 bins
of past returns (1st and 6th bins are most likely to be sold), or 20 bins of past returns (1st
and 20th bins are most likely to be sold). Moreover, assets with extreme returns are more
likely to be sold even when conditioning on other, less salient, attributes such as position
size. We find the same U-shaped selling strategy regardless of the assets’ weights in the
portfolio or how long they have been held. Similar to a test proposed in Hartzmark (2014),
the pattern persists even after the inclusion of stock-date fixed effects which absorb a number
of time-varying stock-specific unobservables. Moreover, the vast majority of portfolios in our
sample are tax-exempt, meaning that tax considerations are unlikely to explain the selling of
extreme performers.
Importantly, this strategy is costly to the PMs and is predictive of much of the under-
performance in selling. The tendency to sell extreme positions forecasts substantially lower
returns than the counterfactual of a random selling strategy both between and within man-
ager. Comparing managers based on their proclivity to sell positions with extreme returns,
PMs who have a more pronounced U-shaped selling pattern have substantially worse sell-
ing outcomes than those with a less pronounced pattern; PMs with the most pronounced
U-shaped pattern (top quartile) forgo between 110 and 200 basis points annually relative
to a random selling strategy. Changes in the proclivity to sell extremes within manager
are associated with similar magnitudes of differences in expected performance. In Section 6
we demonstrate that the results documenting the selling strategy and its affect on perfor-
mance are robust to risk adjustments. For PMs most prone to sell extreme positions relative
Consistent with salience theory as formalized by Bordalo et al. (2013), these reasons are
not without merit and carry a ‘kernel of truth.’ However, as noted above, the systematic
selling of assets with extreme returns is costly even relative to a no-skill random selling
strategy. While a formal explanation why the use of heuristics is associated with particularly
poor performance is beyond the scope of this paper, one possibility is that high conviction
ideas – stocks for which managers had the strongest beliefs were likely to increase in value
– are also salient and thus more likely to be considered for potential selling choices. For
instance, it may be particularly easy to justify selling a stock which was strongly expected to
and, in line with ex-ante expectations, subsequently did appreciate relative to the benchmark.
5
The following quotes from PMs in our sample are illustrative of this attitude: “When I sell, I’m done with
it. In fact, after I sell, I go through and delete the name of the position from the entire research universe.”
“Selling is simply a cash raising exercise for the next buying idea.” “Buying is an investment decision, selling
is something else.”
Lastly, the robustness of the U-shaped selling pattern to alternative specifications, the
costs associated with this behavior, and the decrease in selling performance when attentional
resources are likely to be stretched all suggest that pecuniary motives such as agency concerns
are unlikely to be driving the selling of positions with extreme returns. Rather, these results
are quite consistent with limited attention and the accompanying use of costly heuristics as
the driver of poor selling performance.
The unique aspect of our analysis is examining buying strategies separately from selling
strategies. The findings shed light on the nature of expertise in financial markets. While a
large fraction of fund managers use a distinct heuristic when selling that hurt performance,
we find no evidence of such heuristic use in their buying decisions. This is surprising given
that the two decisions are similar operationally – the outcomes of both are a function of
future asset returns of the asset. They also have equivalent consequences for trading profits:
the ‘quality’ of a buy decision is evaluated relative to alternatives in the choice set (not
purchasing, purchasing other assets), as is a sell decision (not selling, selling other assets).
Yet we do not observe traces of heuristic use in buy decisions, which unlike sell decisions,
outperform counterfactuals such as the benchmark.
Related Literature. Our results suggest that PMs systematically fail in porting their
expertise in buying to selling decisions. Prior work has documented the fractionation of
The selling pattern we document is most related to the rank effect described in Hartzmark
(2014). There, retail investors appear to exhibit a similar pattern in selling and buying behav-
ior – unloading and purchasing assets with more extreme returns. While it is not clear from
the data whether these trading strategies are particularly maladaptive, this set of investors
have been found to underperform the market in general and display a host of heuristics and
bias such as the disposition effect (Odean 1998), overconfidence (Odean 1999), and narrow
bracketing (Frydman, Hartzmark, and Solomon 2017).6 Our results also relate to the anal-
ysis of Di Mascio, Lines, and Naik (2017), who used the Inalytics dataset of institutional
investors to test theoretical models of optimal strategic trading with private information.
Most of their analyses aggregate information across managers to examine the speed at which
managers trade and, in turn, the rate at which private information is incorporated into prices.
The authors argue that the results support models of optimal trading strategies: stocks with
above average buying and selling volume tend to outperform the benchmark. Given the dif-
ferent focus of their paper (aggregate metrics rather than individual decision-making), they
do not explore individual-level determinants of trading behavior nor use existing holdings to
6
Though Hartzmark (2014) focuses on the behavior of retail investors, he also present evidence that mutual
funds are prone to such behavior as well. However, due to the limitations of the data, which comes from
quarterly holdings reports, he notes that the behavior can be driven by strategic concerns in response to
investor preferences.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 presents results on
performance of buying and selling decisions, while Sections 4 and 5 present results on the use
of heuristics in trading strategies and how those strategies affect performance, respectively.
Section 6 demonstrates the robustness of the results to risk-adjustment and other factors.
Section 7 discusses our results and concludes.
2 Data
This section discusses the data sources which are assembled for our analysis, presents de-
scriptive statistics, and discusses a number of portfolio and position-specific variables which
we use throughout the analysis.
Our primary source of data for this analysis is compiled by Inalytics Ltd. These data include
information on the portfolio holdings and trading activities of institutional investors. Inalytics
acquires this information as part of one of its major lines of business, which is to offer
7
One exception to this is a literature which emphasizes slow/inefficient incorporation of certain types of
aggregate signals into asset prices; see, e.g., Chang, Hartzmark, Solomon, and Soltes (2016); Giglio and Shue
(2014); Hartzmark and Shue (2017); Hong, Torous, and Valkanov (2007).
For purposes of this study, Inalytics assembled an extract of data of long-only equity
portfolios spanning from January 2000 through March of 2016. In our data, the names of
funds and managers are anonymized – only a numerical identifier for each fund is provided.
These portfolios are internationally diversified, including data from a large number of global
equity markets. Data are only collected during periods for which Inalytics’ monitoring service
is performed. This leaves us with an unbalanced panel.
For each portfolio, we have a complete history of holdings and trades at the daily level
throughout the sample period. Inalytics collects portfolio data on a monthly basis and extends
them to a daily basis by adjusting quantities using daily trades data. As a result, we observe
the complete equity holdings of the portfolio at the end of each trading day (quantities, prices,
and securities held), as well as a daily record of buy and sell trades (quantities bought/sold
and prices) and daily portfolio returns, though we do not observe cash balances. Further,
each portfolio is associated with a specific benchmark (usually a broad market index) against
which its performance is evaluated – a feature we exploit heavily throughout our analysis.
To complement these data, which characterize portfolios and trades at specific points in
time, we merge in external information on past and future returns (including periods before
and/or after we have portfolio data). When possible, we use external price and return series
from CRSP; otherwise, we use price data from Datastream. When neither of these sources
are available, Inalytics provided us with the remaining price series which are sourced (in order
of priority) from MSCI Inc. and the portfolio managers themselves.
8
We will use the terms fund and portfolio interchangeably throughout our discussion.
This table reports summary statistics of the analysis dataset for 783 portfolios at various levels of aggregation.
The position level summary statistics include various holding lengths, portfolio weights, future return measures
and the number of trades (indicator for buy and sell trades). Future returns are reported in percentage points
over specified horizons. The fund-level and position-level summary statistics are reported at monthly and daily
frequencies, respectively. See Table 2 and text for additional details on variable construction.
Differences from other datasets This sample offers some unique opportunities for the
study of expert decision-making relative to other datasets in the literature. First, in contrast
to the Large Discount Brokerage dataset of Barber and Odean (2000), which features portfolio
holdings and trades of individual retail investors and has been used in numerous studies11 ,
our data include complete portfolio and trade-level detail for a population of professional
investors managing large pools of assets. Illustrative of this distinction, while Barber and
Odean (2000) report that the value of the average portfolio is $26,000 and that the top
quintile of investors by wealth had account sizes of roughly $150,000, the average portfolio
in our sample is almost four thousand times larger. Second, unlike other datasets which
characterize institutional portfolios, such as mutual fund portfolio holdings reports and 13-F
filings, we are able to observe changes in portfolio holdings at a daily level.12 This facilitates
the testing of hypotheses on individual decision-making that is infeasible with quarterly data.
Additionally, most other datasets with institutional trading information often lack timely
information on portfolio holdings.
With these data in hand, we construct a wide array of measures at the portfolio-time and
portfolio-stock-time (position) level. Formulas for many of these variables are presented in
9
Trades are sometimes imputed at month-end because Inalytics receives portfolio snapshots in adjacent months
which do not fully match with the portfolio which would be expected from aggregating the trade data, which
necessitates a reconciliation process. We exclude funds that have a large fraction of trades occurring at the
end of each month.
10
We compile data on exchange rates from three sources: Datastream, Compustat Global, and Inalytics’
internal database, with Datastream being our primary source. In the vast majority of cases, at least two of
these sources have identical exchange rates.
11
See Barber and Odean (2011) for a survey of studies using this and other similar datasets.
12
See Frazzini (2006) for example of such a dataset.
10
This table describes how we construct several characteristics for use in our analysis. The first column
reports the variables, the second column reports the frequency that we compute the variables and
the type of sorting methods (across-fund or within-fund) used in the analysis. The third column
reports the formula or the description of the sorting variable construction.
Table 2. We begin by discussing some characteristics of fund portfolios in our sample; these
are summarized in Panel A of Table 1 on a monthly basis. All portfolios are large, and
there is considerable heterogeneity in portfolio size. In addition, funds differ noticeably in
terms of their trading activity levels. Average monthly turnover is about 4% of assets under
management, but some funds are considerably more active in their trading behavior than
others (the standard deviation is 5.7%).
While holding fairly diversified portfolios (average number of stocks is about 78 with a
standard deviation of 68), funds in our sample remain active, with positions that deviate
substantially from their benchmarks. The average tracking error – the standard deviation of
the difference between the daily portfolio return and the benchmark – is about 0.35% per
day, or about 5.7% on an annualized basis. On average, a manager will initiate a sell trade for
about 10% and a buy trade for about 15% of the stocks in his/her portfolio each month. We
also characterize fund portfolios in terms of factor exposures by computing rolling Carhart
4-factor regressions (using the prior 1 year of daily data with the Fama-French international
factors), adjusted for asynchronous trading.13 The average market beta is about 1, and
13
Following Dimson (1979), we adjust for asynchronicity by including 1 lag and 1 forward returns of each
11
Panel A also reports the average benchmark-adjusted return that uses each portfolio-
specific return series. The average fund in our sample beats its respective benchmark by
about 0.22% per month, or 2.6% per year. This, in conjunction with the fact that funds’
average betas are close to 1 and have little average exposure to the 3 other priced risk factors,
suggests that these managers are highly skilled, earning returns above and beyond exposure
to known risk factors.
Next, we turn to our position-level data. Our simplest position-level variable is an indi-
cator variable which equals 1 if the manager buys or sells a given stock on a given date. Of
the 89 million position-date combinations in our sample where a stock was in the portfolio
at either the start or end of the day, about 2.4 million of them involved an active purchase
decision on that same day and 2 million of them involved active sell decisions, or about 2.6%
and 2.2% of the time, respectively.
We compute three other primary measures at the position level. First, we construct
several different measures of the holding length associated with a given position. Specifically,
we consider the length of time (in calendar days) elapsed since the position was first added
to the portfolio. In many case, this measure will be censored because a stock may have been
in the portfolio since it was first added to our sample. The average holding length is 485
calendar days (or about 15 months), though this measure is downward-biased. As such, we
also examine holding length measures which consider the time elapsed since a stock was most
recently bought (or traded). The average position was last purchased about 112 calendar
days (a bit less than 4 months) ago and was last traded about 10 weeks ago. In much of the
analysis that follows, we will exclude stocks which were very recently bought to avoid having
our results being driven by predictable buying (and lack of selling) behavior as managers
split trades over several days while building up positions over time. Second, we compute the
portfolio weight as a fraction of market value associated with each position on each date.
The average stock has a weight of about 1.2% with a standard deviation of 1.6%.
12
Having described the basic properties of our dataset and variable construction procedures,
we now begin to analyze PMs’ decision-making. We begin by discussing our methodology
for computing counterfactual portfolio returns and, accordingly, value-added measures. We
then present the first of our empirical results, which calculates the average value-added (or
lost) associated with managers’ active buying and selling decisions.15
This section outlines how we construct counterfactual strategies in order to evaluate trade
performance, which is greatly facilitated by the availability of daily holdings information.
Given that the portfolio managers in our sample tend to hold limited cash positions and
are not generally permitted to use leverage, the primary mechanism for raising money to
purchase new assets is selling existing ones. Since the portfolios already include stocks that
are carefully selected to outperform their respective benchmarks, the choice of which asset to
sell may be far from innocuous. Precisely if managers have useful private information that
makes them skilled at picking stocks, biased selling strategies have the potential to canni-
balize existing, still viable investment ideas and to reduce the potential value for executing
new ones. It is therefore important to construct the appropriate benchmark to serve as the
counterfactual for evaluating buying and selling decisions. Note that this issue is less impor-
tant when considering unskilled investors; there, we would expect them neither to gain nor
lose money (on a risk-adjusted basis) by relying on a simple rule of thumb for selling existing
positions.
The ability to observe daily transactions allows us to compare observed buy and sell
decisions to counterfactual strategies constructed using portfolio holdings data. Our measures
correspond to the relative payoffs from two hypothetical experiments: one for evaluating
buying decisions and one for evaluating selling decisions. For evaluating buys, suppose that
we learned that a manager was planning to invest $1 to purchase a stock tomorrow and to
15
We will return to this analysis in more depth in Section 5 below, which will link other position and fund-
characteristics with predictable differences in trading performance.
13
Since the information being used by us was also available to the manager, we would
expect the decisions of a skilled PM to outperform our suggested strategies; this is due to the
fact that, on the margin, our strategies are always feasible.16 Note that the expected payoff
from the counterfactual strategy (integrating out uncertainty about which stock is randomly
selected) simply corresponds to the equal-weighted mean of realized returns across stocks held
in the portfolio, which we denote by Rhold . The manager’s selection adds value relative to the
random counterfactual if Rbuy − Rhold > 0 in the first example and if Rhold − Rsell > 0 in the
second example. Following this logic, we compute Rbuy −Rhold and Rhold −Rsell over horizons
ranging from 1 week to 2 years for all buy and sell trades, respectively, to characterize the
value-added associated from each.
14
Note that one disadvantage of this value-added measure is that our use of long horizon
returns introduces an overlapping structure in the error term of each fund’s value-added time
series. To address this concern, we compute heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation robust
standard errors using a panel version of the Hansen-Hodrick (1980) correction using a lag of
the horizon minus 1.19 This allows for individual fund time series to be serially correlated
but assumes that these value-added measures are cross-sectionally independent across funds
and across non-overlapping periods of time within funds.
Figure 1, Panel A shows average counterfactual returns for buying decisions. As will turn out
to be the case across the vast majority of our specifications, we find very strong evidence that
buy trades add value relative to our random buy counterfactual, Rbuy − Rhold . The average
stock bought outperforms stocks held by 60 basis points over one year and 87 basis points
over two years.
Figure 1, Panel B presents the average value-added, Rhold − Rsell , for sell trades. Recall
that our measure is already signed so that positive values indicate that a trade helps port-
folio performance relative to the counterfactual and negative values point to a trade hurting
performance. In stark contrast to Panel A, these estimates suggest that managers’ actual sell
trades underperform a simple random selling strategy. Magnitudes are quite substantial: the
value lost from an average sell trade is on the order of 100 basis points at a 1 year horizon
relative to a simple counterfactual which randomly sells other stocks held on the same day.
As we will discuss and further justify below, the interpretation that we find most plausible
is that the results in Panel B are due to managers’ allocation of cognitive resources rather than
a fundamental difference between buying and selling decisions. The latter explanation seems
18
In our baseline analysis, we weight observations inversely to the number of trading days in a calendar year
that the fund buys a stock. For easier comparison across buys and sells, we use the same weights across
buys and sell trades. Unweighted results are reported in the Appendix. They are qualitatively similar in
terms of direction and statistical significance as the weighted results.
19
We compute these standard errors using the ivreg2 package in Stata.
15
This figure presents average returns relative to random buy/sell counterfactuals for buy and sell trades. For buy
trades, we compute average returns of stocks bought minus returns of stocks held on each day. For sell trades,
we compute average returns of stock held minus returns of stocks sold. We then compute the average of these
performance measures across all portfolios and dates, weighted inversely to funds’ trading activity. Each bar
represents average counterfactual returns in percentage over specified horizons on the x axis. The range on the top
of each bar is the confidence interval of the average returns of a portfolio at each horizon. The standard errors are
computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard errors with number of lags equal to the horizon -1.
16
This figure presents average returns relative to random buy/sell counterfactuals for overall buy and sell trades that
take place on firm’s earning announcement days (red bars) vs trades that are executed on all other days (blue bars).
Earning announcement dates are taken from the I/B/E/S database. For buy trades, we compute average returns
of stocks bought minus returns of stocks held on each day. For sell trades, we compute average returns of stocks
held minus returns of stocks sold. We then compute the average of these performance measures across all portfolios
and dates, weighted inversely to funds’ trading activity. Each bar represents average counterfactual returns in
percentage over specified horizons on the x axis. The range on the top of each bar is the confidence interval of the
average returns of a portfolio at each horizon. The standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard
errors with number of lags equal to the horizon -1.
Panel A: Buy Trades
17
Figure 2 depicts the outcomes of buy and sell decisions on announcement and non-
announcement days. Figure 2, Panel A looks at the value-added of buy trades executed on
earnings announcement days compared to other days. In both cases, averages are positive,
and, consistent with attentional resources already being devoted towards purchase decisions,
magnitudes are similar on both types of days. Panel B demonstrates the stark contrast in the
performance of selling decisions on announcement versus non-announcement days. On non-
announcement days, results are similar to Panel B of Figure 1: observed sells substantially
underperform a random sell strategy.20 However, stocks sold on announcement days are as-
sociated with substantial value-added, especially at longer horizons. When decision-relevant
information is salient and readily available, we observe little asymmetry between buy and
sell trades. This provides initial evidence that poor selling performance is likely due to a lack
of attentional resources devoted to the task rather than a fundamental inability to sell. All
results in this section are summarized in Table 8 below.
Why might the performance of buying and selling decisions diverge to the extent documented
in the preceding section? Here, we provide evidence on one potential mechanism: limited
attention to selling decisions, which leads managers to rely in part on simple heuristics. We
begin by motivating our proposed empirical measures of heuristic use and then proceed to
provide evidence for the use of a salience heuristic based on past returns.
20
Magnitudes differ somewhat because the sample composition is limited to stocks that can be linked with
I/B/E/S for this exercise.
18
Prior work has argued that selling and buying decisions are driven by different psychological
processes (Barber and Odean 2013; Grosshans et al. 2018). We conjecture that the discrep-
ancy in buying and selling performance is due to unequal allocation of limited attention. Our
discussions with PMs indicate that they typically focus more on what to add to the portfolio
rather than what to unload; as discussed further in Section 7, PMs appear to largely view
selling as a cash raising exercise to fund purchases. The results from Section 3.2 provide
initial support for this hypothesis. The underlying fundamentals between buying and selling
decisions are fairly similar: in both cases, the investor attempts to make the best trade given
her forecasts of expected returns. More accurate forecasts should improve the outcomes of
decisions in both cases. And in both cases, this requires skill in gathering relevant infor-
mation and incorporating it into the forecast. Our findings suggest that a lack of attention
precludes the first step in the case of selling decisions. When the relevant information is
salient and readily available – such as in the case of earnings announcements – sales no
longer underperform a no-skill strategy, and in fact do almost as well as buys.
If limited attention is responsible for the discrepancy in performance between buying and
selling decisions, then selling strategies will be more prone to heuristics that typify a lack of
attentional resources, such as those that overweigh salient features of the choice environment.
Relative to other forms of information relevant to the decision problem, such as forecasted
returns, data on past returns is ubiquitously available to PMs in our setting. This information
is prominently featured on trading terminals, which typically break down past returns by year,
quarter, month, day and since last purchase. Most news programs and popular webpages
that cover financial markets include a segment which covers the stocks which experienced the
largest moves on a given (both positive and negative).21 The availability of this information,
as well as the large range of values past returns take relative to the portfolio average (as
captured by their standard deviation, 51% over the average holding period in our sample),
makes it highly likely that past returns are a particularly salient attribute of a given asset.
Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2012) and Bordalo et al. (2013) develop a theoretical
framework where individuals attach disproportionately high weights to salient attributes of
a good or lottery. An attribute’s salience is a function of the availability of the relevant
information, either from the environment or from memory (Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer
2017), and the extent to which the values of this attribute deviate from the attribute’s average
value in the choice set. If investors are prone to overweigh salient attributes of assets, then
21
See Kumar, Ruenzi, and Ungeheur (2018) for discussion of media focus on past returns.
19
In our setting, applying a salience heuristic to generate reasons for unloading assets is
predicted to result in a greater propensity to sell stocks with extreme prior returns. If prior
returns are overweighed in selling decisions, then this heuristic may be costly relative to a
more uniform selling strategy, a possibility we investigate in section 5 below. Moreover, the
underperformance of sales should be particularly pronounced during episodes when atten-
tional resources are stretched or otherwise occupied, such as during periods of stress or when
the investor is selling to raise cash (as opposed to selling based on forecasted performance
metrics of the asset).
We construct the following empirical measure of heuristic use. For each portfolio-date, we
identify a set of stocks (a subset of holdings in the prior day’s portfolio) potentially under
consideration to be bought or sold, rank existing holdings according to an empirical proxy
for salience (past benchmark-adjusted returns), then ask whether managers are more likely
to trade the holdings based on past returns.
Given the size of our dataset, we adopt a fairly flexible, non-parametric approach to
measuring managers’ tendency to buy and sell positions based on past returns. Specifically,
for the set of prior holdings which are included in the analysis, we compute a measure
of returns, usually relative to the benchmark over the same horizon. We also emphasize
within-manager rankings, rather than absolute levels of these measures, since the definition of
“extreme returns” may depend on the types of assets in a given PM’s investment opportunity
set. Then, on each trading date, we sort stocks into Nbin bins using these relative rankings.
We always choose an even number of bins and always set the breakpoint between bins Nbin /2
and Nbin /2 + 1 equal to zero. This ensures that all stocks in bins Nbin /2 have declined
20
Our preferred measure of prior returns is computed as follows. For positions which were
opened more than 1 year prior to the date of interest, we use the benchmark-adjusted return
of the stock from 365 calendar days prior through the trading day before the date of interest.
For positions with shorter holding periods, we change the starting point for computing the
benchmark adjusted return to the opening date. We use this as our preferred measure
because it is unclear whether large returns relative to benchmarks more than 1 year in the
past are likely to be salient attributes for the PMs. From a more pragmatic perspective,
this construction is less sensitive to the censoring issues for holding length discussed above.
However, as we show in Section 4.3, results are robust to alternative definitions of past
returns.22
We make one substantive restriction on the sample of stocks which are under consideration
for this analysis. In predicting the probability that a manager will add to/reduce an existing
position, we exclude stocks that were bought in the very recent past. Specifically, we sort
positions into 5 bins based on the holding length since the last buy trade, and exclude the
bottom bin (shortest time elapsed since last purchase) from our calculations. We elect to do
this to avoid a fairly mechanical relationship between our prior return measure, which has
a variance which shrinks with the holding period, and the probability of buying/selling that
can be generated if managers build up positions by splitting buy trades over short windows of
time in order to minimize price impacts.23 Such trades likely originate from a single purchase
decision being executed over time, and so we construct our measures to treat them as such.
Further, to ensure meaningful distinctions between bins, we exclude fund-dates which include
fewer than 40 stocks in the portfolio throughout the analysis in this section, though results
do not meaningfully change without such a restriction.
22
We find nearly identical results if we restrict attention to stocks with opening dates that are observed during
our sample.
23
This phenomenon mechanically tends to increase the likelihood that positions with non-extreme returns are
bought and decrease the likelihood that they are sold, since a manager is unlikely to sell an asset immediately
after or while actively building a position in it. Related to this concern, in addition to imposing this selection
criterion, our regression analyses below always control for the holding period since the position was opened
and the holding period since last buy, as well as squared terms of each.
21
This table reports the buying and selling probabilities (in percentage points) at the stock-level for
six bins of past benchmark-adjusted returns capped at one year. We create bins based on past
cumulative returns of a position capped at one year. The three bins on the left are positions with
negative benchmark adjusted returns and the three bins on the right are positions with positive
benchmark-adjusted returns. The selling (buying) probability is computed by the number of stocks
sold (bought) in a particular bin divided by the total number of stocks in that bin. We exclude
recently bought stocks by sorting based on the holding length from last buy on each day within a
portfolio and dropping the bottom quintile of holding length since last buy. For buying probability,
we only consider stocks that a portfolio manager has already held as of the prior day when computing
the probability in order to avoid mechanical zero returns for newly bought stocks. The first row
reports buying probabilities and the second row represents selling probabilities.
Table 3 summarizes our primary result on PMs’ heuristic use. Each row reports the fraction
of existing positions that are bought or sold within each of the six bins formed on prior
position returns, so that positions with the least extreme returns according to our measure
appear in the center of the table and the most extreme ones appear at the edges.24 The
fraction of assets bought in each bin is the first row, and the fraction of assets sold in each
bin is depicted in the second row.
We begin with the buying probabilities. Consistent with the discussion above, the prob-
ability of purchasing a stock already held is quite flat across the bins of prior returns. Figure
3, which we discuss further below, depicts this result graphically using a variety of different
prior return measures with 20 bins formed on each measure, where bins are sorted from left
to right according to prior returns. These results hold across prior return measures and no
pronounced patterns appear as we move towards extreme bins in all cases.
24
These fractions, which can be interpreted as probabilities, are computed by first calculating the proportion
of stocks sold within each bin at the fund-date level, then averaging across all fund-dates in the sample.
22
This set of figures reports buying and selling probabilities for stocks in the portfolio sorted into 20 bins of various
past return measures. Panel A sorts on cumulative past benchmark-adjusted returns since the purchase date or
one year/quarter, whichever is shortest. Panel B sorts on past benchmark-adjusted returns of a position over
one year and one quarter. Panel C sorts on past raw returns of a position over one week and one day. The ten
bins on the left are positions with negative returns and the ten bins on the right are positions with negative
returns. The selling (buying) probability is computed as the number of stocks sold (bought) in a particular bin
divided by the total number of stocks in that bin. We exclude recently bought stocks by sorting based on the
holding length from last buy on each day within a portfolio and dropping the bottom quintile of holding length
since last buy. For the buying probability, we only consider stocks that a portfolio manager has already held
before when computing the probability in order to avoid mechanical zero returns for newly bought stocks. Blue
bars represent buying probabilities and the red bars represent selling probabilities.
23
This set of figures reports probabilities, in percentage points, of buying/selling by 6 bins of past benchmark-
adjusted returns double sorted with bins of holding characteristics including position sizes and holding lengths.
The left panel plots probabilities of buying and the right panel plots probabilities of selling. The x axis represents
different position sizes in Panel A and holding length in Panel B. 6 bins of past position returns are plotted
within each section on the horizontal axis. The selling (buying) probability is computed by the number of stocks
sold (bought) in a particular bin divided by the total number of stocks in that bin. For Panel A, we exclude
recently bought stocks by sorting based on the holding length from last buy on each day within a portfolio
and dropping the bottom quintile of holding length since last buy. For Panel B, we do not exclude the bottom
quintile of holding length since last buy when computing buying probabilities.
24
Panel A of Figure 3 considers our baseline measure and an analogous one that caps
relative returns at the shorter horizon of 90 calendar days instead of 1 year. In this second
specification, the difference between central and extreme bins is even more pronounced than
when using the baseline measure. Panels B and C look at benchmark-adjusted returns over
fixed horizons of 1 year, 90 days, and returns over 1 week and 1 day, respectively. Across all
horizons, there is a strong increase in selling probabilities as one moves from intermediate to
more extreme bins. This is in stark contrast to buying probabilities which remain relatively
flat both for intermediate and extreme returns. Our finding that extremes in terms of both
very long and very short horizon returns also points very strongly to attention as a likely
mechanism as opposed to agency-based stories (e.g. concerns about reporting realized losses).
Figure 4 considers the extent to which our observed pattern can be explained by two
potential omitted variables which may be correlated with our prior return measures: position
size and holding length. We use the same prior return sorting procedure as Table 3 for
the remaining analyses in this section, though results are similar with different numbers
of bins. As a step towards addressing these concerns, we conduct simple double-sorting
analyses. We assign each stock into one of 6 bins based on prior returns and the other sorting
variable, respectively. Since the breakpoints used for the second characteristic are the same
regardless of the bin associated with the first characteristic, there will be unequal numbers
of observations in each bin. We then compute the buying (left panel) or selling (right panel)
probabilities within each group.
First, even if initial positions all begin at the same size, portfolio drift will imply that
stocks that experience extreme relative returns will tend to have very large or very small
portfolio weights in the absence of trading. Therefore, simple rebalancing motives (e.g.,
to reduce portfolio exposures to idiosyncratic risk) could motivate managers to sell positions
25
Second, as discussed above, positions which have only been held for a short period of
time will tend to have less dispersion in returns and also be more likely to be bought and less
likely to be sold. Panel B double sorts on 6 bins based on time elapsed since last buy (the
variable we filter on) and prior returns. For this analysis only, we do not discard any stocks
from the analysis based on this holding period measure. One can observe the mechanical
patterns discussed in Section 4.2 when looking at the buying probabilities of assets in the bin
with the shortest holding length; buying probabilities are flat in prior returns for all other
holding periods. In contrast, the U-shaped pattern of selling probabilities persists across all
holding lengths.
Finally, Tables 4 and 5 report estimates from a series of linear probability models for the
likelihood of selling or buying, which allow us to control for a number of time-varying fund
characteristics (either via controls, fund fixed effects, or fund-date fixed effects), calendar time
effects, as well as other position characteristics. All specifications include linear and quadratic
controls for holding length since the position was opened, holding length since last buy, and
position-level portfolio weight (as a fraction of total portfolio assets under management). The
key regressors of interest are dummies for each of the prior return categories, which have the
same interpretation as differences across rows in Table 3, where the omitted category is bin
3 (slight loser positions). Again, results are similar with different prior return measures and
different numbers of bins.
We begin with Table 4, which characterizes selling probabilities. Coefficients are quite
similar across columns 1-4, which include different types of fixed effects. Across all of these
specifications, the difference in the predicted probability of selling a stock in bin 1 is at
least 0.44% higher than the probability of selling a stock in either bin 3 or 4. The final
column includes stock-date fixed effects, so the main coefficients of interest are identified off
of variation in the relative return categories across portfolio managers who hold the same
stock on the same date. Even when coefficients are only identified using this narrow source
of variation, we find that positions in the most extreme returns are substantially more likely
to be sold.
Turning to Table 5, the relationship between buying probabilities and prior return mea-
25
Note, however, that similar logic would potentially imply that we would see more buying of positions that
have became small due to portfolio drift, which we do not observe.
26
This table presents position-level estimates of a linear probability model (in percentage points) for
the likelihood of selling a given stock. The key explanatory variables of interest are indicators
corresponding to six bins of past benchmark-adjusted returns capped at one year, where the Slight
Loser bin is the omitted category. We control for fund characteristics including log(yesterday’s assets
under management), prior-month turnover, the volatility of a fund benchmark-adjusted returns
over the past year, and prior month loadings on Fama-French Cahart regressions (calculated using
the Dimson (1979) procedure using 1 year of prior daily returns). We control for position-level
characteristics including linear and quadratic terms in holding lengths (overall and since last buy)
and position sizes(% AUM) at the beginning of the day. Columns consider various fixed effects
including Fund, Date, Fund x Date and Stock x Date for different comparisons. We exclude recently
bought stocks by dropping the bottom quintile of holding length since last buy from the analysis.
The coefficients and t-statistics are reported for the variables included for each model. The standard
errors for each model are clustered at fund level. * denotes statistical significance at 5% level , **
denotes statistical significance at 1% level and *** denotes statistical significance at 0.1% level.
sures is much more muted. Most of the coefficients are insignificant despite being estimated
on a sample of over 50 million observations. Even the significant coefficients are substan-
tially smaller in magnitude than the coefficients associated with selling probabilities. In the
saturated specification presented in column 5, none of the coefficients in the Loser categories
are statistically distinguishable. Taking stock, the regression specifications, in conjunction
with the nonparametric evidence in Figure 4, suggest that the considered sources of omitted
variable bias are unlikely to explain our results.26 Together, these results are consistent with
26
Increases in selling probabilities for very extreme bins are even larger in additional unreported results with
more bins (or dummies for being in the bottom 5%, 5-10%, 90-95%, or top 95%) and other measures of prior
return rankings. We elected not to report these estimates since magnitudes are quite similar to Figure 3.
27
This table presents position-level estimates of a linear probability model (in percentage points) for
the likelihood of buying a given stock. The key explanatory variables of interest are indicators
corresponding to six bins of past benchmark-adjusted returns capped at one year, where the Slight
Loser bin is the omitted category. We control for fund characteristics including log(yesterday’s assets
under management), prior-month turnover, the volatility of a fund benchmark-adjusted returns
over the past year, and prior month loadings on Fama-French Cahart regressions (calculated using
the Dimson (1979) procedure using 1 year of prior daily returns). We control for position-level
characteristics including linear and quadratic terms in holding lengths (overall and since last buy)
and position sizes(% AUM) at the beginning of the day. Columns consider various fixed effects
including Fund, Date, Fund x Date and Stock x Date for different comparisons. We exclude recently
bought stocks by dropping the bottom quintile of holding length since last buy from the analysis.
The coefficients and t-statistics are reported for the variables included for each model. The standard
errors for each model are clustered at fund level. * denotes statistical significance at 5% level , **
denotes statistical significance at 1% level and *** denotes statistical significance at 0.1% level.
a salience heuristic being used for selling decisions but not buying decisions.
Above, we provide evidence suggesting that PMs asymmetrically allocate attentional re-
sources between buying and selling trading strategies. In this section, we exploit the panel
nature of our dataset in order to illustrate a more direct link between the performance of sell-
ing strategies and fund characteristics that are likely associated with differential allocation of
attention. To do so, as in Section 3, we compare the returns of the actual stocks traded with
These pronounced increases in probabilities of selling extremes are not matched for buys.
28
Before proceeding, we note that this analysis is only able to identify correlations in the
data, so it it is not feasible via these designs to rule out other all other types of time-varying
fund-characteristics which simultaneously drive performance and observable properties of
trading behavior. However, we will be able to use within-manager time series variation in
these characteristics to compare the relative performance of selling strategies for the same
individual at different points in time. Such an approach allows us to at least difference some
types of time-invariant, between-manager sources of heterogeneity from the analysis.
We begin by considering the potential implications for performance (or lack thereof) of
the heuristic strategies documented in Section 4. To capture heuristic intensity, we calculate
the fraction of stocks sold that are located in the extreme bins (worst loser and best winner)
for each fund-week.27 We then rank fund-weeks into 4 categories according to this measure to
calculate relative performance of the associated selling decisions. Our primary rationale for
a weekly frequency is that it provides a nice balance between reducing potential noise in the
sorting variable (by averaging over multiple trades), while still operating at a high enough
frequency so as to capture within-manager variation in attention allocation.
Table 6 presents sample averages of counterfactual returns where funds are sorted into
four bins based on heuristic intensity. Different panels correspond to three alternative ranking
schemes and different columns correspond with different holding period lengths. Panel A
corresponds to a between-manager measure of heuristics intensity. In each week, we sort
each portfolio into one of four categories based on its level of heuristic intensity. In Panel
B, we use a within-manager measure, comparing trades that a manager makes during weeks
in which heuristic intensity is relatively high or relatively low. Panel C repeats this analysis
using a monthly measure of heuristics instead. The left panel plots average performance of
buy trades, while the right panel plots average performance of sell trades.
To the extent that increased reliance on heuristics is suboptimal, we would expect trades
27
For instance, the mean of this heuristics intensity measure is 0.4 on a monthly basis, which would imply
(through a simple application of Bayes’ rule) that the likelihood of a stock being sold in the extreme bin is
4/3 the likelihood of a stock being sold in one of the central bins. In Appendix Table ??, we use a variety
of fund sorts to show that, perhaps surprisingly, our measure of heuristics intensity is nearly uncorrelated
with a variety of observable fund characteristics.
29
This table presents the average returns relative to random buy/sell counterfactuals for buy and sell portfolios sorted
by heuristics intensity. For buy trades, we compute average returns of stocks bought minus returns of stocks held
on each day. For sell trades, we compute average returns of stock held minus returns of stocks sold. The heuristics
intensity is computed by measuring the fraction of sells in the lowest and highest of 6 bins of cumulative returns
capped at 1-year at weekly or monthly horizons. We rank the heuristics intensity both in the cross section of funds
and within-fund time series and sort funds into four bins from Lowest, Low-Med, Med-High to Highest heuristics
use. Columns represent buy or sell performance measures at the following horizons: 1 month, 3 months, and 1
year. We report point estimates of average counterfactual returns for each portfolio at different horizon as well
as their standard errors in parenthesis (below the point estimate), where we weigh observations inversely to the
number of trades per year of a fund. Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard errors with
number of lags equal to the horizon -1.
Buy Sell
Heuristics Intensity Bin Horizon Horizon
28 days 90 days 1 year 28 days 90 days 1 year
30
This table presents the average returns relative to random buy/sell counterfactuals for buy and sell portfolios sorted
by cumulative benchmark-adjusted fund returns since the beginning of a quarter, and weekly trading activities
(Gross Sell and Net Buy). For buy trades, we compute average returns of stocks bought minus returns of stocks
held on each day. For sell trades, we compute average returns of stock held minus returns of stocks sold. The
weekly gross sell is computed by counting the number of unique positions sold within a week. Weekly net buy
is computed by the unique number of positions bought per week minus the unique number of positions sold per
week. For the fund cumulative returns since the beginning of a quarter, we rank it across funds for each date in the
sample. For trading activities, we rank these measures within portfolios across all weeks in the sample. We divide
these measures into four bins from Lowest, Low-Med, Med-High and Highest, based on their rankings. Columns
represent buy or sell performance measures at the following horizons: 1 month, 3 months, and 1 year. We report
point estimates of average counterfactual returns for each portfolio at different horizon as well as their standard
errors in parenthesis (below the point estimate), where we weigh observations inversely to funds’ trading activity.
Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard errors with a lag equal to the number of horizon -1.
Buy Sell
Fund Characteristics Bin Horizon Horizon
28 days 90 days 1 year 28 days 90 days 1 year
31
The literature on heuristics and biases documents that people are more likely to rely
on heuristics during situations when cognitive resources are in higher demand, such as in
times of stress or when attention is otherwise occupied (see Kahneman (2003) for review).
Table 7 considers three alternative empirical proxies intended to capture periods emblematic
of such episodes. As in Panels B and C of Table 6, the three measures are computed on
a weekly basis and sort fund-weeks into 4 categories to capture either between or within-
manager variation.The first aims to capture performance when the PM is likely to be stressed.
Institutional investors are known to be evaluated or take stock of their own performance based
on calendar time, e.g. on a quarterly or yearly basis. Based on the conjecture that the PMs
are more likely to be stressed when their overall portfolio is underperforming, we construct
a measure that captures portfolio performance relative to the beginning of the preceding
quarter. Table 7, Panel A demonstrates that selling quality is worst (relative to a random-
sell counterfactual) when the PM’s overall portfolio is underperforming the most – consistent
with the notion that stress exacerbates suboptimal decision-making. We do not observe a
similar relationship between portfolio performance and quality of buying decisions.
Next, we consider two measures aimed to proxy for sales that are more driven by cash
raising considerations rather than forecasts of relevant performance metrics. We posit that
sales of solitary assets are more likely to be driven by the latter motives than sales of asset
bundles, and that observing larger bundles being sold (relative to being bought) is emblematic
of the manager being in “cash-raising mode.” Intuitively, executing purchases likely involves
reducing the size of a number of positions in order to free up capital to prepare to invest in a
small number of new positions. Therefore, a low number of buys relative to sells would likely
be consistent with periods of time where the manager is engaging in “cash-raising” activities.
In Table 7, Panel B considers the number of distinct names being sold in a given week relative
to the total number of names in the portfolio. We find that sell trades underperform most
during weeks when a larger number of distinct names are being sold. In Panel C, we compute
the difference between the number stocks bought and the number of stocks sold, where both
measures are expressed as fractions of the number of stocks in the portfolio. We find that the
32
Together, the results of this section paint a stark picture: greater heuristic use amongst
expert investors is associated with substantial underperformance in their selling decisions.
Moreover, periods when attentional resources are likely to be stretched or otherwise occupied,
such as when the investor is stressed or focused on purchase decisions, are associated with
the worst underperformance in investors’ selling decisions.
In this section, we consider two main tests to verify the robustness of our main results
related to buying/selling performance relative to counterfactuals. First, we consider a more
explicit adjustment for systematic risk and confirm that our main results are not driven by
differential exposures to known, priced risk factors between stocks traded versus those held
(which are constituents of the random sell counterfactual portfolios). Second, to address
potential issues about measurement errors (e.g., stale prices) and/or liquidity, we re-run our
main counterfactual analyses excluding stocks which are traded in developing and emerging
markets.28 Again, our key results are unchanged for this subsample.
The performance measures described above estimate the value-added that a given trade
would create/lose relative to a randomly-selected, feasible alternative, where value-added can
be interpreted as the expected change in benchmark-adjusted returns over a given horizon
per dollar traded. We demonstrate that stocks bought tend to increase more than randomly
selected alternatives, and stocks sold also tend to increase more than these alternatives.
Whereas the former helps performance, the latter acts as a drag on performance. A natural
concern, therefore, is that stocks traded tend to have above average exposures to systematic
risk, meaning that our estimates could be driven by risk compensation rather than skill.
If this were the case, we would tend to overstate positive performance of buy trades and
understate performance of sells, which is directionally consistent with our results above.
33
This table presents the average value added measures (post-trade returns relative to a random sell counterfactual)
for buy and sell trades under two measures of returns 1) returns and 2) factor-neutral returns, for the whole
sample and the subsample of stocks from developed markets (see text for further details). We first present the
overall average counterfactual returns, and then report the average counterfactual returns for trades on earnings
announcement days (A-day) and non-earnings announcement days (N-day), where we weigh observations inversely
to a fund’s trading activity. Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard errors with number of
lags equal to the horizon -1.
34
FN
Ri,t ≡ Ri,t − Λ0i,q(t)−1 Ft ,
where Ri,t is stock i’s excess return on date t and Ft is a (4 × 1) vector of factor realizations.
Λi,q(t)−1 is a (4 × 1) vector of factor loadings which are estimated 1 year of daily data using
F N thus captures return of a self-
data up to the end of the previous calendar quarter. Ri,t
financing portfolio which, if factor loadings are estimated correctly and are stable, has zero
exposure to the priced risk factors on each date. Thus, if the asset pricing model holds, all
Ri,t should earn zero excess return in expectation and, accordingly, randomly sold portfolios
should have the same factor-neutral returns period-by-period as actual stocks sold. Next,
we compute value-added as before, by compounding factor neutral returns and compare
cumulative factor-neutral returns of stocks traded with the average of cumulative factor-
neutral returns of stocks held.
Table 8 reports estimated return measures from the analysis in Figures 1-2 for our base-
line specification as well as three alternatives. Our first alternative is the factor-neutral
performance measure described immediately above. Our second two alternatives recompute
baseline and factor-neutral performance measures for the subsample of developed countries
only. Therefore, any stocks from outside of these developed markets are excluded from both
the Rbuy , Rsell , and Rhold portfolios. In all cases, magnitudes are fairly similar between the
baseline model and the three alternatives. At long horizons, factor-neutral and overall mea-
sures are within 10-20 bp of one another. Consistent with much trading activity not being
concentrated among stocks with above-average systematic risk exposure, we find fairly sim-
ilar estimates of value-added for factor-neutral portfolios as the baseline estimates. Results
also are quite similar in the developed only sample as in the full sample.
Table 9 also demonstrates the robustness of our results relating funds’ use of heuristics
and performance. Once again, magnitudes vary somewhat, but our main result that the
highest level of heuristic use is associated with the worst performance is quite similar across
all of the specifications. If anything, magnitudes are somewhat larger for the alternative
specifications relative to the baseline.
29
The four factors are the market excess return, the Fama-French (1993) size and value factors, as well as
the Carhart momentum factor. As above, we compute loadings using data for the global factors from Ken
French’s website.
35
This table presents the average counterfactual returns for buy and sell trades under two return measures (raw,
factor-neutral) for the whole sample and the subsample of developed market, sorted into four bins based on our
measure of heuristics intensity. Heuristics intensity is computed by measuring the fraction of sell trades in the
lowest and highest of 6 bins of cumulative returns capped at 1-year, sorted weekly across funds. See text for further
details on variable definitions. Panel A and B report mean counterfactual returns of each measure for buy and sell
trades respectively, weighted by a fund’s trading activity, as well as their standard errors in parenthesis (below the
point estimate). Each cell represents the average counterfactual returns in percentage over specified horizons and
levels of heuristics intensity. Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard errors with number of
lags equal to the horizon -1.
36
We use a unique data set to show that financial market experts – institutional investors
managing portfolios averaging $573 million – display costly, systematic biases. A striking
finding emerges: while investors display skill in buying, their selling decisions underperform
substantially – even relative to random sell strategies. A salience heuristic explains the
underperformance: investors are prone to sell assets with extreme returns. This strategy is
a mistake, resulting in substantial losses relative to randomly selling assets to raise the same
amount of money.
Why would the performance of buying and selling decisions diverge to the extent docu-
mented in the proceeding sections? Barber and Odean (2013) argue that buying and selling
are driven by two distinct psychological processes: purchase decisions are forward looking
while sales are backward looking. Grosshans et al. (2018) find some supporting evidence
for this conjecture, demonstrating that choices of what to buy are more belief-driven than
choices of what to sell. While we do not have direct evidence for why PMs take different
approaches to the two decisions, interviews with the investors offer anecdotal evidence that
they view buying and selling as distinct processes and do not allocate resources (cognitive or
otherwise) equally between the two. A skilled manager of a long-only (short-sale constrained)
portfolio can add value in two ways: 1) by identifying and increasing positions in underval-
ued assets and 2) by identifying assets within his/her portfolio which offer less attractive
upside potential, reducing these positions in favor of more attractive alternatives. PMs seem
to view the first as central: identifying new investment opportunities is seen as perhaps the
most critical aspect of a PM’s role. Moreover, the decision to add an asset to the portfolio or
substantially increase the size of an existing position often follows lengthy periods of research
and deliberation. In contrast, there is substantially less emphasis on decisions of what to sell.
PMs mostly discussed selling decisions in the context of raising money for the next purchase;
they viewed selling as necessary in order to buy. Quoting two PMs: “Selling is simply a cash
raising exercise for the next buying idea” and “Buying is an investment decision, selling is
something else.” Additionally, many readily admit that sell decisions are made in a rush,
particularly when attempting to time the next purchase.
As shown in Section 3, the performance of buy decisions is vastly superior to the perfor-
mance of sell decisions. Moreover, the PMs do not lack the fundamental skills to sell well,
they are just not paying attention. When relevant information is salient and readily available
– on earnings announcement days – the investors are able to effectively incorporate it into
their selling decisions which end up outperforming the counterfactual. We find that the ma-
37
Perhaps more surprising than the fact that sell trades appear to add less value than buy
trades is our empirical finding that sell trades also substantially underperform a random
selling strategy, which requires no skill. While formal modeling of this question is beyond
the scope of this paper, we suggest one potential explanation here. All else constant, PMs’
highest conviction ideas – those for which managers’ ex-ante estimates of expected risk-
adjusted returns are the largest – may also be more easily accessible in PMs’ minds. Moreover,
high conviction ideas which recently experienced large price movements may be particularly
salient relative to ideas about which the manager was less confident prior to observing these
signals. If so, he or she may be especially likely to select these stocks when using the salience
heuristic documented above. If this were indeed the case, periods with large fractions of
extreme positions sold might actually be expected to underperform more neutral strategies
such as our random sell counterfactual, consistent with our empirical results. We leave the
further exploration of such interactions for future research.
The question remains of why professional PMs have not learned that their selling de-
cisions are underperforming simple no-skill strategies. While we can only speculate here,
the environment in which fund managers make decisions offers several clues. As Hogarth
(2001) notes, the development of expertise requires frequent and consistent feedback. While
it is feasible to generate this type of feedback for both buy and sell decisions, in practice
the environment in which fund managers make decisions is overwhelmingly focused on one
domain over the other. The vast majority of the investors’ research resources are devoted
to finding the next winner to add to the portfolio. Purchased assets are tracked, providing
salient and frequent feedback on the outcomes of buying decisions. This process appears
successful in producing expertise – purchased assets consistently outperform the benchmark.
In comparison, paltry resources are devoted to decisions of what to sell. From our interviews
with the PMs, the relevant feedback is largely lacking: assets sold are rarely, if ever, tracked
to quantify returns relative to potential alternatives such as our random sell counterfactual.
38
References
Barber, B. and T. Odean (2000): “Trading is hazardous to your wealth: The common
stock investment performance of individual investors,” The journal of Finance, 55, 773–806.
Barber, B. M., Y.-T. Lee, Y.-J. Liu, and T. Odean (2014): “The cross-section of
speculator skill: Evidence from day trading,” Journal of Financial Markets, 18, 1 – 24.
Barber, B. M. and T. Odean (2001): “Boys Will be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence, and
Common Stock Investment,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 261–292.
——— (2008): “All That Glitters: The Effect of Attention and News on the Buying Behavior
of Individual and Institutional Investors,” The Review of Financial Studies, 21, 785–818.
Bordalo, P., N. Gennaioli, and A. Shleifer (2012): “Salience Theory of Choice Under
Risk,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 1243–1285.
——— (2013): “Salience and Consumer Choice,” Journal of Political Economy, 121, 803–843.
——— (2017): “Memory, attention, and choice,” Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Chen, D. L., T. J. Moskowitz, and K. Shue (2016): “Decision making under the
gambler?s fallacy: Evidence from asylum judges, loan officers, and baseball umpires,”
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131, 1181–1242.
39
Di Mascio, R., A. Lines, and N. Y. Naik (2017): “Alpha decay,” Working paper.
Dimson, E. (1979): “Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 197–226.
Fama, E. F. (1970): “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,”
The Journal of Finance, 25, 383–417.
Frazzini, A. (2006): “The Disposition Effect and Underreaction to News,” The Journal of
Finance, 61, 2017–2046.
Frydman, C. and A. Rangel (2014): “Debiasing the disposition effect by reducing the
saliency of information about a stock’s purchase price,” Journal of economic behavior &
organization, 107, 541–552.
Frydman, C. and B. Wang (2018): “The Impact of Salience on Investor Behavior: Evi-
dence from a Natural Experiment,” Journal of Finance, forthcoming.
Giglio, S. and K. Shue (2014): “No news is news: do markets underreact to nothing?”
The Review of Financial Studies, 27, 3389–3440.
Green, E., J. M. Rao, and D. M. Rothschild (2017): “A Sharp Test of the Portability
of Expertise,” mimeo.
Hartzmark, S. M. (2014): “The worst, the best, ignoring all the rest: The rank effect and
trading behavior,” The Review of Financial Studies, 28, 1024–1059.
40
Jin, L. and A. Scherbina (2010): “Inheriting losers,” The Review of Financial Studies,
24, 786–820.
Kumar, A., S. Ruenzi, and M. Ungeheur (2018): “Daily Winners and Lowers,” Working
paper.
Liu, Y. J., C. L. Tsai, M. C. Wang, and N. Zhu (2010): “Prior Consequences and Subse-
quent Risk Taking: New Field Evidence from the Taiwan Futures Exchange,” Management
Science, 56, 606–620.
Malmendier, U., G. Tate, and J. Yan (2011): “Overconfidence and Early-Life Experi-
ences: The Effect of Managerial Traits on Corporate Financial Policies,” The Journal of
Finance, 66, 1687–1733.
Massey, C. and R. H. Thaler (2013): “The Loser’s Curse: Decision Making and Market
Efficiency in the National Football League Draft,” Management Science, 59, 1479–1495.
Odean, T. (1998): “Are investors reluctant to realize their losses?” The Journal of finance,
53, 1775–1798.
——— (1999): “Do investors trade too much?” American Economic Review, 89, 1279–1298.
Pope, D. G. and M. E. Schweitzer (2011): “Is Tiger Woods Loss Averse? Persistent Bias
in the Face of Experience, Competition, and High Stakes,” American Economic Review,
101, 129–57.
Romer, D. (2006): “Do Firms Maximize? Evidence from Professional Football,” Journal of
Political Economy, 114, 340–365.
Shafir, E., I. Simonson, and A. Tversky (1993): “Reason-based choice,” Cognition, 49,
11–36.
41
This appendix provides additional detail about how we construct and clean our dataset, then
presents some supplemental tables/figures referenced in the main text. The primary source
of our analysis is Inalytics’ holding data and changes in holdings. After we clean the holdings
data, we convert all the prices into USD using exchange rates mainly from Datastream. To
ensure accuracy in exchange rates, we compare the exchange rate in Datastream with two
other sources of exchange rates from Compustat and Inalytics. In the event of a discrepancy,
we pick the two out of three that are the same, and this procedure takes care of discrepancy
in all cases. We then augment the holding data by merging in external prices series and
forward and backward returns from CRSP (US stocks), Datastream (International stocks)
and Inalytics’ provided price series in this order. The external price series allow us to compute
the market value of each holding precisely. There are instances where the market value of
a stock (likely due to a measurement error in price/quantity) seems implausibly high, so we
employ an iterative weight cleaning algorithm to eliminate these positions from the analysis.
We provide additional details about these steps below.
We begin by outlining the key steps of our data cleaning procedure:
1. Cleaning identifiers: Inalytics has four main types of identifiers for stocks: SEDOL,
ISIN CUSIP, and LOCAL. For the first three types of identifiers, they are distinguish-
able by the number of digits. SEDOL has 6-7 digits, CUSIP has 8-9 digits, and ISIN
has 12 digits. In a few instances one type of identifier is mislabeled by the clients, so
we correct them according to the number of digits.
2. Merging in liquidated stocks with holdings data: There are instances when a
fund completely closes a position, so a stock disappears from the holding data. Since
our main trade measure is computed from the change in stock?s holding, a position-
closing trade will not be observed in the holdings. To do so, we first measure the
minimum date of a fund and maximum date. Then, we compute tag the instance when
the stocks disappear on some date between the minimum and maximum dates of each
fund. We then append those stocks back to the holding data in order to measure trading
activities, from the changes in holdings accurately.
3. Dropping portfolios without daily trades: Some of the portfolios in the dataset
do not receive daily time-stamped trade data. In these cases, only monthly holdings are
reported and trades are imputed at the end of the month. To filter out these portfolios,
we count the fraction of trades after the 27th of the month for each fund. If a fraction
of trades after the 27th for a fund is over 50% or missing (in case of no trades observed),
we drop the portfolio from the analysis sample. In addition, Inalytics independently
provided a list of these portfolios from their internal records, essentially all of which
were filtered out by this criterion. We also remove these manually flagged portfolios.
Next, we discuss some potential issues related to measurement errors in the price data.
We use external price series from CRSP and Datastream, and we additionally have data
provided by Inalytics. Inalytics relies on multiple data vendors such as MSCI or Thompson,
as well as clients themselves, for price series in the holding data. Since these prices are
42
43
This table presents the average returns relative to random buy/sell counterfactuals for buy and sell port-
folios sorted by heuristics intensity. For buy trades, we compute average returns of stocks bought minus
returns of stocks held on each day. For sell trades, we compute average returns of stock held minus returns
of stocks sold. The heuristics intensity is computed by measuring the fraction of sells in the lowest and
highest of 6 bins of cumulative returns capped at 1-year at weekly or monthly horizons. We rank the heuris-
tics intensity both in the cross section of funds and within-fund time series and sort funds into four bins
from Lowest, Low-Med, Med-High to Highest heuristics use. Columns represent buy or sell performance
measures at the following horizons: 1 month, 3 months, 1 year, and 2 years. We report point estimates of
unweighted average counterfactual returns for each portfolio at different horizon as well as their standard
errors in parenthesis (below the point estimate). Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick
standard errors with number of lags equal to the horizon -1.
Buy Sell
Heuristics Intensity Bin Horizon Horizon
28 days 90 days 1 year 2 year 28 days 90 days 1 year 2 year
44
This table presents the average returns relative to random buy/sell counterfactuals for buy and sell port-
folios sorted by cumulative benchmark-adjusted fund returns since the beginning of a quarter, and weekly
trading activities (Gross Sell and Net Buy). For buy trades, we compute average returns of stocks bought
minus returns of stocks held on each day. For sell trades, we compute average returns of stock held minus
returns of stocks sold. The weekly gross sell is computed by counting the number of unique positions sold
within a week. Weekly net buy is computed by the unique number of positions bought per week minus
the unique number of positions sold per week. For the fund cumulative returns since the beginning of a
quarter, we rank it across funds for each date in the sample. For trading activities, we rank these measures
within portfolios across all weeks in the sample. We divide these measures into four bins from Lowest,
Low-Med, Med-High and Highest, based on their rankings. Columns represent buy or sell performance
measures at the following horizons: 1 month, 3 months, 1 year, and 2 years. We report point estimates of
the average counterfactual returns for each portfolio at different horizon as well as their standard errors
in parenthesis (below the point estimate). Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard
errors with a lag equal to the number of horizon -1.
Buy Sell
Fund Characteristics Bin Horizon Horizon
28 days 90 days 1 year 2 year 28 days 90 days 1 year 2 year
This table reports the average measure of heuristic intensity at the fund-level, where funds are sorted
into four bins according to various fund characteristics. We measure heuristics intensity by the fraction of
positions sold in extreme bins of past position returns. We report this for a variety of fund characteristics,
sorted in ascending order. For each bin of fund characteristics denoted by b, we measure heuristics intensity
by fraction of position sold by computing :
46
This table presents the average value added measures (post-trade returns relative to a random sell counter-
factual) for buy and sell trades under two measures of returns 1) returns and 2) factor-neutral returns, for
the whole sample and the subsample of stocks from developed markets (see text for further details). Panel
A, B presents the average counterfactual returns on buy and sell trades respectively, along with their stan-
dard errors in parenthesis (below the point estimate). We first present the overall average counterfactual
returns, and then report the average counterfactual returns for trades on earnings announcement days (A-
day) and non-earnings announcement days (N-day). Standard errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick
standard errors with number of lags equal to the horizon -1
47
This table presents the average counterfactual returns for buy and sell trades under two return measures
(raw, factor-neutral) for the whole sample and the subsample of developed market, sorted into four bins
based on our measure of heuristics intensity. Heuristics intensity is computed by measuring the fraction of
sell trades in the lowest and highest of 6 bins of cumulative returns capped at 1-year, sorted weekly across
funds. See text for further details on variable definitions. Panel A and B report mean counterfactual
returns of each measure for buy and sell trades respectively, weighted by a fund’s trading activity, as
well as their standard errors in parenthesis (below the point estimate). Each cell represents the average
counterfactual returns in percentage over specified horizons and levels of heuristics intensity. Standard
errors are computed using Hansen-Hodrick standard errors with number of lags equal to the horizon -1
48