Prueba de Nivel - Expresión Oral
Prueba de Nivel - Expresión Oral
Prueba de Nivel - Expresión Oral
A Service of
zbw
Leibniz-Informationszentrum
Wirtschaft
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier
Working Paper
Lecture Notes on Economic Growth: Introduction to
the Literature and Neoclassical Models, Volume I
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.
www.econstor.eu
I.
'
I.
I
ECONOMIC GROWTH CENTER
YALE UNIVERSITY
VOLUME I
Xavier Sala-i-Martin
Yale University
December 1990
This paper is the revised version of the first draft, November 1988.
See Discussion Paper No. 622 for Volume II of Lecture Notes on Economic
Growth.
LECTURE NOTES ON ECONOMIC GROWTH:
VOLUME I
Abstract
· This is a survey· of· the literature on Economic ·.Growth. ·.In. the ....·
endogenous growth models using fixed savings rate analysis. We argue that
show that changes in the savings rate have different effects on long run
·growth in the .two kinds of models; we show that only endogenous growth
models are affected by shifts in the savings rate. We then explore two
without.
. .,. ·;..:..
"The consequences for human welfare involved in questions . .Like
these are simply staggering: once one starts to ·think.about them, it.is ihard
to think about anything else". Lucas (1988), p. 5.
, . .- .
~-.
multipliers may want to think of an economy described by such configuration.
Suppose also that the only asset in this (closed) economy is something we
r c'all Kt.· ·You···may want to think' of K as being physical··· CAPITAL· but .it may
also .include other inputs .that can be accumulated,,; such as knowledge". or"
skills. Now imagine .that the ..production function is .Cobb-Douglas and. that
there are two aggregate inputs. One ·of them, Kt, can be purposely
accumulated and the other·Lt, cannot be accumulated, or it grows at ar-ate
which is independent -of individual choices ~(think of 'L as 'labor but···ut·"may -··
·also include other unreproducible resources such as land or energy).
(1.1) y
constant rate, L/L=n. Let us define lower case k as the capital-labor ratio
(or capital per worker) K/L. By taking derivatives of kt with respect to
.(2) ·the discount rate be related to ::the ..parameters ·· of.Jthe model ;through·
p=f3-s, where p is the discount rate, and f3 is the share of capital in the
production function.
See also Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1990) chapter 1 for an extension
of this result.
3
Throughout these notes we will denote time derivatives by "dots"
on top of variables.
2
4
time we can rewrite (1.2) in per capita terms as
(1.2)' kt
Let us divide both sides of (1.2)' by kt and define the growth rate of
capital per worker kt/kts-yk. We will call STEADY. STATE .the state where all.
variables grow, at a,, constant· (possibly ·zero),; rate. Thus; in ·steady·"stlate ''.'fk:' ,., -
is constant. Take logarithms and derivatives of both sides and get
(1.3) 0=(/3-1)-yk+n(a+/3-l)
(1.3), 0=(/3-1)-yk
4
Notice that the difference between expressing the accumulation
equation' in levels or 'in per capita terms, is the ·term nk added to ok. We ·
can in fact think of nk as some extra depreciation since it represents the
loss of capital per person due to the fact that, when population grows, we
- have to share capital with an increasing number of people.
3
general
(1.1), yt
(1.1)'' Y = AK
t t
5
It is called exogenous because it is unaffected by any of the
parameters of the model such as the capital share or the savings rate.
6
· Notice that we are saying CR to K and no~ C(t ~ Scale. The distinction
is important: the production function Y=K L - with 0<,8<1, exhibits
constant returns to scale (if we multiply all inputs by A>l we get A times
as much output) but Decreasing Returns to Capital (since if we multiply
capital by A we get less than A times as much as output).
!+
adjusted labor. The quality of the labor force (often called Human Capital)
is accumulated as, each generation is .more knowledgeable than the one- before.
When one eombine·s "physical· -'and, 1.human - -capital• into _,·some, -broad measure -rn~f
capital, the aggregate production function will look l·ike the linear AK
,,
function postulated above. This is ·the· approach taken' by ·Lucas (1988') and
Uzawa (1956). A version of these models is presented in section 1.7.
Barro (1990) and its extensions ' outlined in Barro "and
Sala-i-Martiri (1990) - assume that' the two 'inputs of production are private
physical capital and publicly provided inputs such as roads, infrastructure
or law enforcement. Output exhibits constant returns to both inputs. In
section 1.5 we will show that this setup ends U? being similar to
postulating an AK production function where K must again be interpreted as a
broad measure of capital.
Notice that (as can be seen from equation (1.3)', the steady state
growth rate -yk derived from these models is positive without assuming
exogenous productivity growth. As we will see in the next subsection, the
parameters"''of the modeJ. (in-particular the savings rate) will determine this
growth. rate/ Because the growth' rate is determined within the model, (in
other words, it depends on the other parameters of the model) these are
often,cal-led "ENDOGENOUS' GROWTH MODELS".
Finally, equation (1.3) allows for one more possibility. If the
population growth rate is zero (n=O), we can have nonreproducible inputs
(a>O) together with ENDOGENOUS GROWTH (-yk>O) if there are CONSTANT RETURNS
TO THE INPUTS THAT CAN BE ACCUMUI.ATED (fi=l). But notice that this implies
OVERALL INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE (a+fi>l). This possibility gives rise to
the so called "INCREASING RETURNS ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODELS 117 •
Of course, if we plainly postulate an Increasing Returns to Scale
(IRS) production function we run into trouble since we cannot find a set of
7
As can be seen from equation ( 1. 3) , when the population growth
rate is positive, the inc,reasing returns -to scale models· (a+fi>l) run· into
trouble since there is no -yk that satisfies the key equality. What happens
in this. circumstances'· is that' the ·growth rate is never constant but, rather,
it increases over time.
5
t
prices to support a general competitive equilibrium. There are at least two
ways to get around this problem.
(a) The first one (due to Alfred:Marshall) is to introduce IRS.at
the aggregate level but CRS at ' the firm level. This can be formulated
through production externalities or spillovers: each fir:m' s decisionc.:affects
all other firms output, but none of the firms takes this into account.
Hence, all the . firms face a, "concave''. problem -which has a competitive
solution. .The ··economy as. a whole, :however; ·.faces an IRS production.function
.which, .·;under ..some .conditions . that we will mention in·. a second, generates
endogenous growth. The Cobb Douglas version of this production function is
(1.1.)" yt
(1.1)'''' y = AKP+~Ll-P
t t t
6
approach is interesting for a variety of reasons, one of the main ones being
that under imperfect competition the rewards to all inputs of production
does not .·exhaust, total.o.utput,:>,.~rHe.nce; .. there.. are rEHlts ...that ,can be, ass:i,gned_
to activities not. di·rectly productive but ;that . may, contribute .to- the
expansion of the··- frontiers of -knowledge• such as R&D. No~ surprisingly,
therefore, this approach has been extensively- used by economists --that ,th-i,nk"
that R&D is an important source of economic growth. .In sec.tion 8 we explore
8
a model of R&D =and. ,growth ·taken from Barro-'and ,Sala-i-Martin (1990 ;a) ·where
firms invest in R&D in search.of new-varieties of capital goods. In that
model, there are NO decreasing returns to the introduction of new varieties
so the incentive to perform R&D never diminishes, which keeps the economy
9
growing
Of course one could have models with both imperfect competition
and externalities. In fact •there - is an important line of research that
combines R&D (with imperfect competition) with externalities. It emphasizes
R&D as some activity exercised by firms in search for new varieties of
products· or higher quality products; · As a side product, R&D . increases the
general stock of .'knowledge. which -has. two effects. First, it decreases the
cost of further research (so the incentive to perform R&D remains positive
and Knowledge grows at a constant rate forever). And second it .increases
the productivity of --other inputs (such as -labor) in ·-·the production of a
manufacturing good. Therefore, given that the stock of knowledge grows at
constant rate, so does the manufacturing good. Models of this type include
Aghion and Howitt (1989), Grossman (1989) and Grossman and Helpman (1989 d
and e).
Before showing the mechanics of all these models, let us introduce
8
This model, in turn, -is •an extension of Romer (1987) and Grossman
and Helpman (1989, a).
9
There is a third way to model increasing returns in a model of
perfectly competitive firms and that is to introduce imperfect financial
markets. This approach has been taken by Greenwald, Salinger and Stiglitz
(1990).
7
a graphical device that will further clarify the basic difference between
exogenous and endogenous growth models. It will also help,us understand why
,the ,,, savings , (or, investment),, rate-·,does not ''"af,£ec t',~long,,"run growthw-in "the '''''·1
8
we are in the steady state and, suddenly, the savings rate s, increases.
Figure 1 suggests that the curve sAk~ (l-{3) will shift to the right and
.: nothing will:,.happen to the (o+n) .line. We can see .that."the following things
are true:
(a) the growth rate·. will immediately increase.
(b) the growth• rate will be falling over time until, eventually, it
goes back to zero.
(c) the steady state capital. labor ratio is higher.
9
there is no convergence in the absolute sense. Yet there is CONDITIONAL
convergence in the sense that each country converges to its own steady state
at· dimini'Shing growth rates. : :c Empirically,· this means that if w~ hold
··constant the steady state, poor -;·countries will . . grow faster ;than rich, one.s ..
<[f we don't, however, we will not. see poor ec.onomies growing faster unless
they are very similar (in the sense that they converge to similar steady
states).
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1990) find that this feature of the
neoclassical model can be found in.the data. They find that the States of
the U.S. display absolute convergence while countries in the world do not.
Holding constant the steady state, however, there is convergence across
countries also. This makes sense if we think that the states of the U.S.
are similar .in the sense. of having. the same tastes and technology so they
converge to the same steady state. This is certainly not true for the large
cross section of countries, so they display conditional convergence only.
For related studies on convergence see Baumol (1986), Delong (1988), Dowrick
and NGuyen (1989), Manki~, Romer andWeil (1990), and Sala-i-Martin (1990).
Let us now expand the· neoclassical production function by
introducing exogenous productivity growth. Recall that the production
function now looks like
(1.1)' yt = A(t)k~
10
increases both the short run and the steady state growth rates. Hence,
contrary to the neoclassical predictions, policies directed to increases in
the savings (and. investment).·• -rates ·will have ·long ru,n ..growth effects.
Further, notice that· if economies differ in the•initial capital stock ONLY,
it is not true anymore·' that poor ·ones will· grow faster·· than rich. ones.
Finally,· this model predicts .that a, temporary· recession will have-permanent
effects. That is, if the capit'al stock temporarily falls for some exo.genous
reason (an earthquake, a•natural tragedy or . a . war that destroys part.of the.
capital stock), the economy will not grow temporarily faster so as to go
back to the prior path of capital accumulation. The endogenous model
described here predicts that after such a temporary reduction in the capital
stock, the growth rate will still be the same so the loss will tend to be
10
permanent
Figure 4 depicts the case where fi>l (IRS in the inputs that can be
accumulated11 ). The curve sAk-(l-fi) is upward sloping (and if fi>2 its slope
is increasing!). Notice that this implies growth rates that increase over
time. We will refer to this case again in section 6 (Romer (1986)).
Long before the neoclassical theory came to life in the mid 50's,
the most popular model of economic growth was the so called the Harrod-Damar
mode·l (developed by >Harrod (1939). and Damar (1946)). We can use the
graphical tool developed in the last subsection to learn about this older
10
There are unbelievable amounts .of papers on the existence of a
unit root in macroeconomic aggregates such ·as GNP. There seems . to some
evidence that, for the United States, GNP is non stationary, which is what
this simple model would predict. See Blanchard and Fischer (1989) Ch. 1 for
discussion of these issues.
11
In this case the assumption of GRS o:+fi=l must be dropped since a
negative labor share has little economic sense. Think of this case as one
where ·a=O {so •all. inputs· can be accumulated) and fi>l (so there are both IRS
and IR to capital.
11
growth model.
Harrod and Domar tried to put together two of the key features of the
·<, ·Keynesian···economics . -·the··_><:multiplier. and the .accelerator-. in a model~ .that_.·· ·,_v
explained 1ong•i run economic gr.owth. We have been. using the multiplier
assumption (savings is >a ·fixed proportion of income) .alL along. so let .us
describe the differential feature of the Harrod-Domar model: the
accelerator. The increase in capital required to produce a given increase
in output is .assumed to be a constant number. In .particular,· . it .. is
independent of the capital labor ratio. That is
12
In fact, Domar's paper is called "Capital Expansion, Rate of
Growth, and Employment".
12
production function (1.1) by
Notice that this technology is similar to the Ak model ·but only for
small capital labor ratios. For large ·ones, 'however, the production function
is flat so the Marginal Product of Capital is equal to zero. We can now
a.pply the basic .savings equal investment equality (1.5.) to this technology.
to get.
CASE 1: sA<6+n
When the savings rate and/or the marginal productivity of capital
are very small compared to the aggregate depreciation rate (which includes
population growth), there is no possible steady state. This is pictured in
Figure 6. Notice that the economy converges to a point where the logarithm
of the capital labor ratio is minus infinity· (so the capital labor ratio
13
converges to zero) . In this case not only there will be unemployment
(because AK<BL) but it will grow over time. Harrod and Domar thought that
~.·t • this was 'a "good de·scr:i:ption of ..;the observed large .and1 growing unemployment _,
rates of the 30's.
CASE 2: sA=o+n
When, by chance, the exogenously given savings rate and marginal
product of capital are such that sA=o+n, the economy will reach a steady
state where all the per capita variables grow at a zero rate. In Figure- 7
we show· that,, in this case, the initial. capital labor . ratio .will .b,e .,the
steady state one.
CASE 3: sA>o+n
The third case, depicted in Figure 8, is one where the marginal
product of capital or/and the savings rate are very large relative to the
depreciation rate. We see incFigure 8 that, for small capital labor ratios,
this case looks very ·much like the Rebelo model. But as the capital labor
ratio grows, the labor requirement gets binding (that is we hit kt =B/A at
" ·•s01ne. 'finite point .ini,vtime). :-;. After this. point,.,~the- marginal product. of.,.
capital is zer·o and .the ·per. capita« growth process stops. The steady state
capital labor ratio, k* will. be one where there will be. unemployed
machinery.
Two out of the three configurations of parameters yield long run
equilibria were there are idle •resources and the only that does not, would
be achieved-•only by chance: remember ,that all the relevant parameters -A, s,
o and n- were given by mother nature. The question is why in the world
would mother nature be so kind as to give us exactly that configuration of
parameters?. In other words, the chance of them being such that the
equality above is satisfied are quite small.
At the time, the Neoclassical approach was seen as a way of
solving this knife edge property of the Harrod-Domar model. That is, the
neoclassical production function achieves the equality between sA and o+n by
13
allowing for A (the marginal product of capital) to be variable in k . We
13
And we know that there will be a level of capital k such that the
14
should just mention that there are other non neoclassical ways of achieving
this equality. One of them, proposed by, the old Cambridge School in England
'was to argue that '.the savings ,,rate was .endogenous. . ·They- thought that.
workers had a different marginal propensity to save from capitalists.
Hence, so they argued, ; ;in the process. of., economic growth there will be
changes in the distribution of income that will lead to changes in the
aggregate savings rate in such a way that the equality between sA and S+n
14
will be guaranteed We will not talk about the Cambridge school of thought
anymore.
Finally, with this graphical approach we can see that the growth
paths are not limited·to the cases seen up to now. ·We could find functions
that behave in some other ways, ..we may discover new growth models and new
transitional dynamics . towards steady states.·. ·Consider Figure 9: The steady
· ~- -state:. is: sim:ilar .. ·.~~to,. ~the ...,one::· . de.s.crib~d ;~.,by ·.-the Rebelo ·. mo.del b.ut "···the·,
transitional dynamics •are different. · One production function that exhibits.
such dynamics is the following:
15
literature by Jones and Manuelli (1990). Notice that this function is half
fi ' 15
way between Solow (BK ) and Rebelo (AK) . It has all the nice properties
·required by the Kuhn Tucker theorem so we can apply straightforward ·
optimization techniques to find solutions.
In per capita terms the Solow production function is concave and,
as k tends to infinite, the marginal product of capital approaches zero.
The Rebelo production function in per capita terms is linear with. slope
equal to A for all values- of k. The Sobelow production function is also
concave for all ·capital-labor ratios . . As k goes to infinity, however, the
slope of the production function does not go to zero but to A. For large
levels of k, therefore, it gets arbitrarily close to the Rebelo production
function. Hence, the only difference between the Solow and the Sobe low
functions is the latter does not satisfy the Inada condition.
We observe in fig~re 9 that sf(k)/k now is not going to zero
asymptotically but to A. As Kurtz (1968) noted, if A is sufficiently large
(in this case this means if sA>o+n), then the steady state growth rate is
positive, even though-, there' is a transition, period" where growth rates -are
decreasing monotonically. , It .is worth noticing that -if the economy has
been· going on for a while, the decreasing returns part of the production
function will· be almost ··'-irrelevant so we might as well ·deal with the
(simpler) -linear technology described above.
15
That we.call it the Sobelow production function.
16
-- .:•..:.. ..
,.·
initial capital lies to the left of k * will fall into this trap. Countries
2
that start to the right of this trap will tend to a constant growth steady
state a la Rebelo.
In the next two •sections we .will present the optimizing versioTl.s
of the Neoclassical models we have been, talking about in this introduction.
In sections 4 through 7 we present the "new" growth models of the 80's. It
is useful to think about them in terms of·being optimal saving versions of
the /3=1 model we just presented in this section.
(2.0) U(O)
0
16
Ramsey was considering the optimal choice from a government's
point of view. He thought that introducing a discount rate was ethically
indefensible because that meant that the government was giving a larger
weight to current than to future generations.
17
Since ct is consumption per capita, u(ct) is the instantaneous per capita
felicity. Hence, the instantaneous felicity for the whole family is equal to
.the individual times the number of people in the family.
We assume that there is only one good (cookies). We will assume
17
that households OWN the firms (or that there is only household production )
so they can consume this good or they can nail it to the floor. The reason
why anyone would .·do such a horrendous thing· is that cookies nailed to. :the
floor can be used to , produce. more cookies in the . future ... For lack . of a
better name, all cookies nailed to the floor will be called "capital" and
will be represented by Kt. We assume that there is nobody else in the
universe, so all the cookies produced will have be consumed or nailed. Hence
the increase in existing capital (called investment) must be equal to
saving. If we let kt be per capita capital (Kt/Lt), the following resource
constraint must be satisfied:
17
As we will show in the next section, the results will be the same
we would get if we assume that households own capital and labor and sell
their services to competitive firms in exchange for wages and rents.
18
The last two conditions (the Inada conditions) are often swept
under the rug. They are of crucial importance because, as Kurtz (1968)
showed, the mathematical difference between an endogenous and exogenous
growth model is the condition lim f' (k)=O. This point has been emphasized
k->oo
also by Jones and Manuelli (1990).
18
assumed to grow at the (exogenously given) rate n so we can rewrite the
program as:
0
-t - -
1-a
s.t. k f(k) - c -nk - ok
k(O) >0 given
(2.2) p>n.
(2.3) H()
-(p-n)t -a
(2 .. 4) H 0 ~ e c - v = 0
c
(2.5) Hk -v ~ v = -v(f'(k)-n-o)
(2.6) TVC lim (ktvt) = 0
t~OO
Equation (2.4) says that at the margin, the value we will give to
19
consume one more unit will be equal to the value we will give to invest one
more unit (that is, we, will ,,be" indifferent between consuming and investing
the unique good) . Take logs of (2.4) to get -(p-n)t-alog(ct)=log(v). Now
take the derivative with respect to time to get:
so
-1 .
(2.7)' c/c a (-p+n-v/v)
-1
(2.8) 1=c/c =a (f'(k)-p-o)
-1 -(1-P)
(2.8)' 1 =a (pk -p-o)
t
20
If we define steady state as the state where all the variables grow at a
constant {and possibly zero) rate,- equations (2.8) together with the capital
accumulation equation (2. 0)' say that there is steady state k *
a unique
. h ensures t h at capita
wh ic . 1 and consumption
. .
per capita d o not grow19 Hence
this model says that, in the steady state, all variables in per capita terms
do not grow at all. Alternatively, all "level" variables grow at the same
rate as population, which is assumed to be exogenous.
(2.9) kt = w + r k - c
t t t t
19
We can show that the only sustainable growth rate is zero:
take the constraint k=k,B-c-nk-ok and divide it by k. Define k/k=1k which in
steady state will be a constant (by definition of steady state!!). Realize
that k(,8-l)=ba+p)/,B. Rearrange to get c/k=ba+p)/,B-1k-n-o=constant. Take
logs and derivatives to conclude that c/c=k/k=1k=1. Now consider again the
equality k(,8-l)=(1a+p)/,B. The RHS is a constant. Take logs and derivatives
of both sides to conclude that (,8-l)1k=O. This is another way to show what
we saw in section 1: if there are DR to k (,B<l), then the steady state
growth must be zero. The only way to achieve nonzero growth rates is to have
CR to k (,8=1).
21
where wt is the return to labor (wage) and rkt is the return to
capital (we are abstracting again from depreciation and population growth).
In the other side, competitive firms will price factors at marginal costs
so:
f' (kt)-&k
f(kt)-ktf' (kt)
state. This transition is·shown in Figure 11. The vertical line is the c=O
locus·. The upward sloping line is the k=O locus representing the· resource
constraint (2.0)'. Notice that the economy can converge to the steady state
from below or from above. The interesting case is the one where we converge
from· below so we '.actually grow. Along this• path k/k>O. Per capita capital
grows, but it does so at a decreasing rate (which ends up being zero in
steady state). As the capital labor ratio increases, the marginal product
of capital falls and, therefore so does the interest rate.
It is worth noticing that, in Figure 11, there is a level of
capital called kgold (for Golden Rule). This is the capital level that
maximizes steady state consumption. Froni the budget constraint we see that
22
capital. In other words, in order to achieve higher consumption in the
future the economy would need to dissave (which of course means higher
consumption today). Therefore, if the economy were to find itself in one of
such capital levels, everybody could increase consumption at all points in
time. The points above kgold are called the DYNAMIC INEFFICIENT REGION
because some generations could be made better off without making any
generation worse off. Notice that for capital levels below the Golden
Rule, if the economy ·wants to increase the steady state consumption, , it
needs to· accumulate· or save: higher consumption tomorrow would have to be
traded for lower consumption today. This region is called DYNAMIC EFFICIENT
REGION.
We can integrate (2.5) forward between 0 and t and get
e-I(f'(ks)-o-n)ds
(2.5)' lit =110
_ r(f' (ks)-o-n)ds
(2.6)' lim 11
0e ~ kt 0
t->oo
20
23
I
I
I
(d) Ruling out explosive paths.
I
It just remains to be shown that, given the saddle-path stability I
property of the model, the economy will find itself on the stable arm. To
show this we must rule out all other possible paths. Suppose that we start
with the capital stock k in Figure 11. Let c the consumption level that
0 0
corresponds to the ,, saddle path. Let 1us· imagine; first that the <initial
consumption level is c >c .
0 0
If this is the case, the economy will follow
the path depicted in Figure 11: at first both c and k will be growing. At
some point the economy will hit the k=O schedule and, after that,
consumption will keep growing yet capital will be falling. Hence, the
economy will hit the zero capital axes in.finite time. At this point, there
will be a jump in c (because with zero capital there is zero output and
therefore zero, 'consumption) which will violate the first order condition
(2.8). In order to show that the economy will hit the k=O axes in finite
time just realize that kt can be rewritten as
(2.11) k ds
s.
Recall that k * is such that f' (k* )=p+6 and that the bounded
utility condition (2. 2) implies that p>n. Therefore
f' (k )=p+6>n+6=f' (k · ) .. Since the production function is concave (f' '<0)
gold*
it follows that k <kgold"
24
(2.12) dk/dt [f'(k). - (n+cn]k: - c <O
notice that since kt<k* , we know that f'>n+o. We also know that k<O and c>O
so overall, (2.12) is negative which implies that k is falling at increasing
rates. '.Hence, if:we--are ·in. this region:•in·.finite- time: (ie·.if we .hit;:the-... k=<Oc,...
schedule in finite time), then kt will-hit zero in finite time.· Therefore,
it ONLY remains to be shown that we will hit the k=O schedule in finite
time). We can show that this is the case because around the k=O schedule,
noti:ce::.·,.::that''' the ;first.·· terms.is' positive.· and, around the k=O schedule it.·.
is larger than the one required by the stable arm we will first hit the k=O
schedule in .finite-time and then hit the k=O axes in finite time. This will
imply a finite time jump in consumption which will violate the first order
condition (2.8). Hence, it is not optimal to start above the stable arm.
Let us imagine next that we start below the stable arm. The
dynamics in Figure 11 tell us that we will converge to k ** Notice that
this path will violate the transversality conditions since k **>kgold' That
is
- (f'(k** )-o-n)ds
lim k
t->oo
** e I >0
25
Hence, initial consumption levels below the stable arm are not optimal
either. We are left, therefore, with the stable arm as the UNIQUE optimal
path of this model.
-(1-a)ln(k )
(1/a)(ae t -(p+o))
(2.15)
e
-(1-a)ln(kt) - e (ln(ct)-ln(k t )) -
( n+o~)
-(1-a)ln(k* )
e (p+o)/a
(2.16)
e
*
(ln(c )-ln(k*)) e-(1-a)ln(k* ) _ (n+o) h >0
where c* and k* are the steady state values of ct and kt respectively and
h=(p+o(l-a)-an)/a. We can now Taylor-expand the system (2.15) around (2.16)
21
See King and Rebelo (1990) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1990) for
a discussion of convergence when the economy is far away from the steady
state.
26
and get
-µ[ln(kt)-ln(k* )]
(2.17)
-h[ln(ct)-ln(c * )] + (p-n)[ln(kt)-ln(k* )]
.
ln(c )]
(2.18)
[
ln(k:)
notice'''that the·. determinant of the matrix is detA=-hµ<O which implies
that the system is saddle path stable. The eigenvalues of the system are
2 )(1/2)
-A = (l/2)(p-n - ( (p-n) +4µh ) <0
1
.(2.19)
2 (1/2)
A2 = (l/2)(p-n + (<p-n) +4µh) ) >0
.~le-Alt
'I' + .~'1'2e A2t
where and .,µ are two arbitrary constants. To determine them, we notice
.,µ
1 2
that since A is positive, the capital stock will violate the transversality
2
condition unless .,P =0. The initial conditions help us determine the other
2
constant since at time 0 the solution implies
27
Hence the final solution for the log of the capital stock has the form
*
where a=ln(y )(1-e
->. t .
1 )/t and ~=(1-e
->. t
1 )/t. This equation says that if a
set of economies have the same deep parameters (discount rate, coefficient
of intertemporal elasticity of substitution, capital share, depreciation and
population growth rates,· etc} sd they converge to the same steady state, the
cross section regres·sion of growth on the·· log of initial income should
display a negative coefficient. In other words, poor countries should tend
to grow faster. The· .reason for- that is that countries with low .initial
capital would have high .initial. marginal product of capital. That would
lead them to save, invest and therefore grow a lot.
If countries converge to different steady states, however, there should
be no relation between growth and initial income, unless we hold constant
the determinants of the steady state. Sala-i-Martin (1990) and Barro and
22
Sala-i-Martin (1990) use a slightly more complicated version of (2.22) to
show that the states of the U.S. (which we may think are described by
similar production and utility parameters) converge to each other exactly
the way equation (2.22) predicts. They also show that, once they hold
constant the determinants of the steady state, large sample of countries
ALSO converge to each other the way equation (2 .. 22) predicts.
22
It is a slightly more complicated version because they include
exogenous productivity growth.
28
(3) EXOGENOUS PRODUCTIVITY AND GROWTH
according to At= A egt (ie, A/A=g) and were F() is still homogeneous of
0
degree one. The second definition of technological unbias is due to Harrod.
He ·says that a technical innovation is neutral (Harrod Neutral) if the
relative shares (KFk/LFL) remainunchanged for a given capital OUTPUT ratio.
Robinson·· (1938) ;and .. Uzawa. (19.61) . showed that this implied a production
29
function of the form
Y(K,AL) BY(K,L)
30
embodiment in economic growth. Proponents of what at the time was called
"New Investment Theory" (embodied technological progress) said that
,. investment in new .machines had the usual effect. of increasing the capital
stock and the additional effect of modernizing the average capital stock.
Proponents of the "unimportance of the embodiment question" argued that this
new effect was a level effect but that it did not affect the steady state
rate of growth. In a couple of important papers Solow (1969) and Phelps
(1962) showed the following:
(1) The neoclassical model with· embodied technological progress and
perfect competition (so the marginal product of labor is equal for all
workers no matter what the vintage of the machine they are using is) can be
rewritten in a way that is equivalent to the neoclassical model with
disembodied progress (Solow (1969)).
(2),The Steady State growth is independent of the fraction of progress
that is embodied (it depends on the total rate of technical progress but not
on its composition) (Phelps (1962)).
(3) The convergence or speed of adjustment to the steady state growth
rate is faster the larger the fraction of embodied progress (Phelps (1962)).
23
The importance of embodiment in modeling business cycles can be
seen from the fact that an embodied shock affects the marginal product of
capital but does NOT affect the marginal product of labor or current output
supply. This is a key difference with respect to a disembodied shock,
especially as far as ·the implications for the procyclicality of real wages
and real interest rates is concerned.
31
(Y-C) in a later period generates a larger increase in capital than a unit
of saving in earlier time. This is like saying that later vintages of
capital are more productive.
I\ A
(3.4) y f(k)
equal gross domestic investment so Y=K+C-oK. Divide both sides by L and get
I\ • /\ I\ I\ A • A
32
(3.5). Notice that the utility function is defined in consumption per capita
(per physical body) while the budget constraint is ·defined in terms of
" "
(3.11) v/v -(p-n) + g -ac/c - ag f' (k) + n + g +o
" "
by setting c/c=O we will get the steady state condition:
33
variables in efficiency units do not grow, variables in per capita terms
grow at the constant rate g.
Note that if p > n+g(l-a) > n, the second term goes to zero. Since c
will end up growing at rate g, the first term also goes to zero if the above
condition holds. Notice, finally, .that this condition implies that the TVC
is satisfied and that we will end up at a point to the left of the golden
rule (dynamically efficient region).
Finally, let's analyze the saving rate.
(3.27) s/y=(k/y)+(nk/y)=(k/k)(k/y)+n(k/y)=(-y+n)(k/y)=
(-y+n)/(k-(l-,8)eg(l-,8)t)=(-y+n)/[(p+a1)/,B]=(g+n),B/(p+ga).
A patient society (low p) will save more and end up with a higher
output LEVEL along the balanced ,path than an impatient one. She will not,
however, grow at a faster rate. we have seen that the growth rate depends
on g and n only. This is an important implication of the neoclassical model
of economic growth.
34
Figure 1 : The Neoclassical Model
B-1 B<1
' \ sAk , o+n
Growth Rate
'\
l.;.)
V1
,/
I ! .. m. . .
sAk B- 1
' \
ko k* kt
' \
:.·
' \
w
°'
cS+n ~~~~+---'-~r--~~__,__~~~~~~~~~~
B-1
s~kP B-1
S~kR
~p kOR ~ k* kt
R
cu
"O
0
E
~
4=0
cu
_a
cu ,-
a: II cu
cu en
..c co
a:
I-
.. ..c
C')
~
Q)
1...
0
1...
:J
O> CJ
·-
LL
c
+
\.Q
... c
<(
en +
\.Q
37
. .,,. ~· :: ; .:.. ,.
Figure 4: Increasing Returns and Increasing Growth Rates
k kt
0
t
(])
.c
1-
LO
(]) ~
Lo <(
::J
O> II
·-
LL
_ _ _ _ __ j __ _ _ _---'I Q,'
39
Figure 6: The Harrod-Damar Model
Case 1: sA<(6+n)
sf(k)/k, 6+n
.p-.
0
6+n~~~~--r-+~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
sA
~sf(k)/k
ko 8/A kt
Q)
"O
.o
:?
"-
co
oc
E
0I +
t.()
e
"O ..........,
II
"- <(
~ .en.
Q) C\I ···················· ~
co
..c Q)
J- en
. . (.)
co
I"-
Q)
"-
::J
Cl
·-
LL
c
+
t-0
--
~
2
-
..........,
'+-
en
<(
en
II
c
+
t-0
41
.,, - · - ,.-. v
... - .
~ . ,.·. .
Q)
"'O
0
~
co
'--
E ............
0 c
0I +
"'O .._....
\.<)
0
'-- /\
co
'--
<(
en
I
Q) CW')
..cQ)
I- en
co
co (.)
Q)
'--
::J
Cl
·-
LL
c
+
\.<)
--
""
~
............ <( c
.._....
~
'+-
en +
\-0
en
42
Figure 10: Stable Poverty Trap
sf(k)/k, o+n
<
\
.;::...
w
k* k*
1 2 kt
Figure 11 : The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Phase Diagram
c
t
6=0
.
k=o
"
''·
+:-
+:-
c'0 .
l .............../ ........... ,
co
c"
0
·~~k*-;---~k~~===~~ ko gold k** kt