Desai, Mihir (2009) The Decentering of The Global Firm
Desai, Mihir (2009) The Decentering of The Global Firm
Desai, Mihir (2009) The Decentering of The Global Firm
1. INTRODUCTION
LMOST 20 years ago, Robert Reich questioned how firms are linked to
A nation states by posing a provocative question, ‘Who is Us?’. Reich argued
that a nation’s interests could be advanced by firms from various nations and,
indeed, that a firm’s national identity no longer guaranteed that it would
advance the economic interests of a particular country. For example, a foreign
firm with substantial investments in the United States may well be better for
America than an American firm with most of its operations abroad.
Reich’s question provoked considerable debate but the ability to ascribe
firms to nations was not contentious (Reich, 1990, 1991).1 By such logic, firms
such as Caterpillar are American companies by virtue of their history while
Honda, for example, is a Japanese company. Indeed, this presumption underlies
various policies and the oft-cited notion of ‘national competitiveness’ that links
firms to countries. Until recently, this presumption seemed reasonable. Even as
multinational firms dramatically increased the scale of their global operations,
relocating various activities around the world in response to value creation
opportunities, they largely retained their national identities and their headquar-
ter activities remained concentrated in their home countries. While production
or distribution might move abroad, the loci of critical managerial decision-
making and the associated headquarters functions were thought to remain
bundled and fixed.
Now, it appears that the center cannot hold. The archetypal multinational
firm with a particular national identity and a corporate headquarters fixed in
one country is becoming obsolete as firms continue to maximise the opportuni-
ties created by global markets. National identities can mutate with remarkable
ease and firms are unbundling critical headquarters functions and reallocating
This paper was prepared as a keynote speech for the CESifo Venice Summer Institute. I thank vari-
ous seminar participants for helpful comments, Kathleen Luchs for excellent research assistance,
and the Division of Research of Harvard Business School for generous financial support.
1
For a response to Reich see Tyson (1991).
investors. The publishing firm Reed Elsevier has preserved its separate British
and Dutch identities. Reed Elsevier PLC is incorporated in the United Kingdom
and listed on the London Stock Exchange while Reed Elsevier NV is headquar-
tered in the Netherlands and listed in Amsterdam. Each company also has its own
listing on the New York Stock Exchange. Although they have separate legal and
national identities, cross-ownership makes the firm an economic entity. The dual-
listed company, historically associated with mergers from the beginning of the
twentieth century (such as Royal Dutch Shell and Unilever), is enjoying a renais-
sance as firms no longer feel compelled to have one home. The structure of dual
listed firms is described in more detail in Appendix B.
Such dramatic transactions and mergers are just one sign of how global firms
are redefining their homes. Another sign is the unbundling of headquarters
activities within global firms. Many firms with global activities have created
regional headquarters. The natural next step has been to relocate traditional
headquarters activities to the regional headquarters best suited for the purpose.
For example, an American multinational firm headquartered in Chicago might
find itself with a European regional headquarters in Brussels and an Asian
regional headquarters in Singapore. Shortly thereafter, the global treasury and
financing function might usefully migrate to Brussels and the global informa-
tion technology function might usefully migrate to Singapore. In short, firms
are becoming decentered. With these changes, the idea of firms as national
actors rooted in their home countries is becoming outdated.
Why are these changes taking place and what are their consequences? In this
paper, I place the increasing mobility of corporate identities within the broader
setting of transformations to the ‘shape’ of global firms over the last half cen-
tury. I argue that these varied transactions are of a piece and are responses to
secular changes. Responding to these changes requires a reconceptualisation of
what a corporate home is. I outline a potential reconceptualisation, describing
how managers will make conscious choices about how to unbundle activities
that have traditionally been centered in a home country headquarters. Policy-
makers in countries around the world have to understand how to create attrac-
tive homes for firms, and researchers have to devise ways to incorporate these
changes in their empirical and theoretical work.
FIGURE 1
The Changing Shape of the Global Firm
1960s–1980s 1990s–2000s 2000s
Self Replication to Specialisation Ownership based
Avoid Tariffs and High and Fragmentation outsourcing decisions
Transport Costs through Offshoring
Final Goods
& Services
(G&S) MNC HQ MNC HQ
US MNC HQ
customers Intellectual Intellectual
Property Property
Ca
pi Ca Unrelated
tal pi Austrian
tal Austrian
Sub Company
Capital
Intermediate Intermediate
G&S G&S
Austrian Brazilian Canadian Brazilian Brazilian
Sub Sub Sub Sub Sub
Initial forays abroad, particularly in the 1950s and 1960s, took the form of
self-replication, or so-called horizontal foreign direct investment. In this stage,
multinational firms sought to overcome high tariffs and transport costs by
recreating themselves around the world to serve customers around the world.
Such a strategy was an appropriate response to these high costs and also allowed
investors in these firms to gain an exposure to various economies by investing
in multinational firms. The headquarters remained in the firm’s home country as
most of the firm’s activities were still there and critical decisions about which
markets to invest in and how to invest were all made in the headquarters.
This self-replication came at a sizeable cost. Specifically, the duplication of
capital investment in this model was only reasonable in a world of high trans-
port costs and high tariffs. With the rapid decline of these costs, multinational
firms reshaped themselves, becoming more vertically specialised. In the 1990s,
offshoring of activities became much more prominent as global production
chains began to be fragmented around the world. Capital efficiency was greatly
improved through this so-called vertical foreign direct investment. While the
home market no longer solely supported headquarters activities, headquarters
remained critical for many of the higher value-added functions of the firm,
such as research and development and product design.
The fragmentation of the global production chain through offshoring led to a
key question that preoccupies firms today: if my activities are spread around
the world in this way, do I need to own all of them? With outsourcing, firms
contract with outside firms for some activities and only the most central activi-
ties remain within the ownership chain. In the 1990s, the shift to offshoring
occurred when activities were specialised in the countries best suited to them.
Today, outsourcing represents a similar specialisation of activities across firms
so that not every firm undertakes all activities.
FIGURE 2
Decentering the Global Firm
MNC HQ
Home(s) for
A Financial Home A Legal Home Managerial Talent
of private equity firms have been willing to splinter homes for managerial tal-
ent because of the preferences of highly valued talent who refuse to move.
A third force driving these changes is that countries increasingly compete to
become the legal or financial homes for corporations. Low-tax countries, such
as Bermuda and Ireland, have become compelling legal homes for firms from
many countries. National stock exchanges actively compete for listings of
foreign firms and many firms today are listed on a stock exchange outside their
home country or on more than one stock exchange. Also, various countries,
such as Dubai and Singapore, compete actively to be regional or global homes
for managerial talent. Each of these developments is likely to continue and
these are the very forces that have facilitated the unbundling of headquarters
activities that traditionally had been co-located. Finally, and perhaps most
importantly, the emergence of global shareholder and lender bases reinforces
these trends. These investors often facilitate and demand these kinds of changes
as they seek to champion value creation in new ways.
If firms can choose the most appropriate homes for their managerial talent,
the most beneficial financial home, and the best legal home, what determines
the best home for each of these functions?
reside in countries with limited regulatory barriers and access to deep and
broad financial markets, such as the United Kingdom, Belgium or the United
States. Chief information officers can reside close to large pools of highly-
skilled labour in countries with flexible immigration policies, such as Singapore
or India. Heads of design might usefully locate near creative hubs in expensive
metropolises, such as New York or Milan, and chief operating officers might
locate in low-cost countries where production is concentrated, such as China,
or in convenient hubs near their supply chains, such as Dubai or Singapore.
The choice of home or homes for a firm’s managerial talent will have a sig-
nificant impact on a company’s culture, and changing this home can change
the company’s culture. For example, when private equity players took control
of Celanese, its German-based managers were replaced with American-based
managers. The sponsors of the transaction felt that American managers were
both more familiar with private equity and more sympathetic with the objec-
tives of the firm’s new owners, including significant restructuring of the com-
pany. Lend Lease, a leading Australian property developer, provides another
instructive example of the consequences of splintering the home for managerial
talent. Lend Lease divided its most senior talent between Sydney and London
for several years in the early 2000s with the CEO moving to London away
from his managerial team. The move was inspired by, and apparently fulfilled,
the desire to expose the organisation to global deal flow in a way that could
not be facilitated otherwise.
The reallocation of a firm’s managerial talent to a new home, or to different
homes, is neither costless nor easy. In particular, internal communication net-
works and interpersonal relationships become more important. Senior manage-
ment teams that are not well-integrated will not be able to handle such
reallocations as trust, and pre-existing relationships will be particularly critical
in these settings. Growing a culture is also much more challenging in such a
decentered set-up and such reallocations are best suited for more mature com-
panies. These costs, while readily identifiable and daunting, must be compared
with the potentially large benefits created by managerial specialisation and the
ability to access differentiated resources easily.
b. A Financial Home
A firm also has to have a financial home, a place where its shares are listed
and traded and its finance function is located. This financial home can now be
distinct from the original birthplace of a firm, from where most of its managers
are located and from its legal home. Genpact decided to list in New York
where it is neither legally domiciled nor are there significant managers. A
firm’s financial home is the aspect of headquarters that has been most
neglected. What happens in a financial home and why is it so important?
First, a firm’s financial home determines what legal rules govern its relation-
ship with its investors, and this relationship, in turn, impacts a firm’s financing
costs. The rights of investors and creditors vary significantly across countries.
Firms whose legal home is situated in a country with weak investor protection
have been shown to have higher financing costs because investors consider
such firms riskier. Today, a firm can effectively recontract around poor rules
that govern its relationship with investors by establishing its financial home in
another location. Firms can accomplish this by cross-listing their shares on a
stock exchange in a country with strong investor protection. Cross-border list-
ings are now common, with many firms using depositary receipts to list their
shares on one or more foreign stock exchanges (see Appendix C for more
detailed information on cross-border listings). Cross-border listings effectively
allow firms to bond themselves to stronger disclosure rules and investor rights
than provided for in their local markets There is considerable empirical evi-
dence that firms from weakly regulated markets that cross-list their shares in
well-regulated markets have a cheaper cost of financing because investors
consider such firms less risky. In other words, a firm can lower its financing
costs by choosing the right financial home without changing its legal home.
These motivations underlie many cross-border listings and the efforts of some
corporations to list primarily in the United States which has strong investor
protection.
Second, a financial home will dictate the incentive compensation arrange-
ments used to reward talent. While managerial talent can be located opportunis-
tically around the world, hiring for some functions (and certainly for CEOs) is
happening in global labour markets. Attracting and retaining talent today typic-
ally requires high-powered contracts that will not be fully valued if the under-
lying securities are in financial markets that are underdeveloped or narrow.
Nestlé ran into this problem when it was the sole owner of the US-based oph-
thalmology company, Alcon. Alcon had to compete with US firms for mana-
gerial talent but stock options in Alcon’s Swiss parent were not highly valued
by Alcon’s American managers. Alcon therefore based its incentive compen-
sation on a phantom stock programme. Managers, however, frequently ques-
tioned the pricing of Alcon’s phantom stock, an issue that was only resolved
when Nestlé sold part of Alcon and the company was listed on the New York
Stock Exchange. Global firms have to choose a financial home that facilitates
their ability to compete for managerial talent.
Third, firms require a financial home for capital raising and capital alloca-
tion. Typically, countries where, for regulatory reasons or tax reasons, costs of
funding are lower and capital can be reallocated around a firm most easily are
desirable. The James Hardie decision to change its financial home to the
Netherlands was dictated by the financing options available there and the News
Corporation move to the United States was similarly motivated.
Fourth, a financial home dictates who your owners are. Even though share-
holder bases are becoming increasingly global, where a firm lists its shares does
have a significant impact on who owns its shares. Nestlé’s listing in Switzerland
ensures that it has a Swiss-dominated shareholder base. Nestlé may have reason
to be content with its Swiss ownership. Swiss shareholders seldom challenge
management or question performance, so Nestlé is largely protected from take-
over attempts. When Nestlé sold off part of Alcon, though, it chose to have
mainly American shareholders for Alcon and so listed it in New York. Why? It
was in Nestlé’s interest to get the highest valuation for Alcon so it was willing to
accept the closer scrutiny and higher performance expectations of US sharehold-
ers. Shareholders in different countries may have distinct expectations from man-
agers over possibly varying horizons. When a firm chooses to list in New York, it
will open itself up to the demands and monitoring of US institutional investors.
Similarly, European shareholders may require discussions of corporate social
responsibility that would otherwise not be germane. Financial homes help dictate
a firm’s shareholders and, accordingly, corporate priorities.
Finally, the choice of a financial home will dictate firm value. While it is
tempting to think that no valuation discrepancies can arise between comparable
firms in today’s globally integrated markets, this does not appear to be the
case. Equity research analysts and institutional investors are deeper in some
markets than others and this can vary by industry. The Celanese, Warner-Chil-
cott and News Corporation examples demonstrate that relocating a financial
home can give rise to considerable value creation.
Picking a financial home can be thought of as two distinct decisions. First, a
firm has to decide where to list its shares and have its stock traded. This deci-
sion will have an impact on the firm’s financing costs, its valuation, its owner-
ship, its contractual relationships with its investors and its success in competing
for managerial talent with stock-based incentives. Second, a firm has to decide
where its finance function will be located and which countries offer the firm
the most seamless ability to reallocate funds across the world. This decision
affects the firm’s capital-raising and capital allocation functions. The two deci-
sions on a financial home need not be twinned. For example, it is conceivable
that an NYSE-listed stock will have a CFO administering a finance team in
Singapore. Just as firms may have several homes for their managerial talent,
they may have more than one financial home.
c. A Legal Home
Ultimately, a corporation is a legal person, a citizen of the country where it
is incorporated. A legal home creates obligations and opportunities. First, cor-
porate residency determines the firm’s tax obligations at the corporate and
investor level. There are wide variations in tax rates and in the definition of
taxable income across countries. For example, a country can choose to tax the
income earned within its borders or the income earned by its citizens regardless
of where it is earned. Similarly, a country can choose varying ways to tax divi-
dend income and can afford relief to dividend taxes depending on an investor’s
residence. Today, firms can choose a legal home that can minimise its tax obli-
gations at the corporate and individual level. Stanley Works, for example, tried
to move to Bermuda in order to circumvent the worldwide corporate tax regime
of the US, and the BHP-Billiton structure was designed in part to preserve indi-
vidual tax benefits for residents of different countries. A firm can change its
legal home through a specially-designed transaction or a merger.2
Legal homes can also determine the rights for a firm’s investors and work-
ers, wherever they are located. Countries vary tremendously in the degree to
which they protect creditors during bankruptcy proceedings. Unsurprisingly,
weaker investor protections have been found to give rise to higher costs of
finance, lower valuations and higher control premia on stocks with voting
rights. By reincorporating opportunistically, managers can choose to go to
locales where investor rights are stronger (and gain valuation benefits) or
weaker (and gain more autonomy). Similarly, worker participation in firm gov-
ernance (as in the German co-determination system) and worker rights can vary
according to a firm’s legal home. These arrangements, in turn, will likely influ-
ence firm value. The ability to change their legal home means that firms are no
longer stuck with the creditor rights or worker rules with which they were
born.
Figure 3 summarises this reconceptualisation of the determinants of how
firms are dividing up traditionally bundled homes. Firm value will be maxi-
mised when each function is located in the most advantageous location.
What types of firms are most likely to maximise firm value through the de-
coupling and optimal location of the traditional headquarters functions? Firms
in global industries – ones with global customer bases and global competitors –
are likely to have the skills and knowledge required to identify the best homes
for each of their headquarters functions. Multinationals with significant intan-
gible assets, such as pharmaceutical and technology firms, have experience in
decentralised processes, and such experience could be applied to the unbundling
of headquarters activities. Mature businesses with strong cultures have the
strong networks required to maintain the ties among differently-located head-
quarters functions. Start-up firms may also be well positioned to locate their
different headquarters functions opportunistically because they are less likely
to be bound to a particular location by their heritage. More generally, the de-
coupling, and optimal allocation, of homes for managerial talent, a legal home
and a financial home requires significant managerial effort and an increased
2
For an explanation of such transactions see Appendix A and Desai and Hines (2002).
FIGURE 3
Reconceptualising the Corporate Home
MNC HQ
Home(s) for
A Financial Home A Legal Home
Managerial Talent
Maximising
firm value
3
Tax policy in an international setting is discussed in Desai and Hines (2003, 2004).
specialise in this way, larger countries are more likely to succeed by reducing
the reasons for their native corporations to seek multiple homes.
6. CONCLUSIONS
The notion of a firm with a unique national identity is quickly fading. A Ber-
muda-incorporated, Paris-headquartered firm, listed on the NYSE with US-style
investor protections and disclosure rules, a chief information officer in Banga-
lore, a chief finance officer in Brussels and a chief operating officer in Beijing
may not sound nearly so fanciful in the near future. The conclusion that ‘the
center cannot hold’, however, does not necessarily mean that ‘things fall apart’.
The same forces that have dictated the changing shape of the multinational firm
over the last several decades will propel these changes as well, even if much
hand-wringing is likely to occur. An appropriate response to these develop-
ments should acknowledge the difficulties inherent in policies predicated on
characterising firms as exclusively linked to specific countries.
APPENDIX A
FIGURE A1
Pre-inversion Post-inversion
US
Parent Bermuda Co.
Operations
Foreign US Foreign
Subsidiary Operations Operations Operations
Transaction Summary
US parent own all worldwide
1
operations
nities to reinvest their foreign-based income abroad. US firms can avoid the
complexities and relative disadvantages of the US worldwide tax system by
restructuring themselves as foreign corporations, and an increasing number of
firms did so during the 1990s.
Congress responded to the cry against firm expatriations and the call for tax
changes with the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004. The Act made it more
difficult for US firms to restructure themselves as foreign firms; expatriate firms
would still be considered US firms for tax purposes if they relocated to a
country where they had no substantial operations and their shareholders
remained essentially the same. The principle of taxing the worldwide income
of US firms remained intact, but the law simplified the system of foreign tax
credits and the rules on allocation of expenses among US and foreign opera-
tions. It also lowered the tax on repatriated foreign earnings to 5.25 per cent
for one year. Firms took advantage of this concession by repatriating over
US$300 billion of foreign profits, a six-fold increase over the previous year.
APPENDIX B
4
Firms are often described as ‘dual listed’ when their shares are listed on more than one stock
exchange and ‘dual listings’ may refer to firms listed on two exchanges in the same country, or to
firms listed in two different countries. ‘Dual listings’ also sometimes refer to firms that list different
classes of shares. There are numerous firms with multiple (or dual) listings, but only a few firms
have the dual listed company structure described above.
any shareholder. In a DLC, each parent pays dividends to its own shareholders,
and this may be beneficial when two countries have different tax treatments of
dividend payments.
Firms and tax experts continue to explore the potential of DLC structure but
there is still uncertainty about the regulatory and tax implications for such firms
and there are only a handful of DLCs. Some firms have abandoned the struc-
ture: ABB ceased being a DLC in 1998, and Royal Dutch ⁄ Shell moved to a
unified structure and single stock listing in 2001 following criticisms of its cor-
porate governance. Other firms continue as DLCs but have moved to simplify
an unwieldy structure stemming from having two parents. Unilever now has a
single chief executive for the first time in its history, and Reed Elsevier has
instituted a unitary management structure and identical boards for each of its
parents.
APPENDIX C
Cross-border Listings
Over 3,200 companies around the world are listed on stock exchanges out-
side their home country. The NYSE lists over 400 foreign companies (from 47
countries) and NASDAQ lists around 350 non-US firms. In Europe, the London
Stock Exchange Main Board lists over 350 non-UK firms and about the same
number of foreign firms are listed on its AIM market for smaller companies.
Some firms list their shares directly on a foreign exchange, meeting the same
regulatory requirements as domestic firms listed on the exchange, but shares in
most cross-listed firms are traded in the form of depositary receipts, or DRs. In
2007, the trading value of DRs on stock exchanges around the world was
US$3.3 trillion, representing a record level of cross-border investing. US stock
exchanges accounted for 88 per cent of the traded value of DRs in 2007 (Bank
of New York Mellon, 2007).
Depositary receipts make it possible for investors to invest in foreign firms in
the same way they invest in domestic firms. Most foreign firms listed in the US
trade in the form of American Depositary Receipts, or ADRs. Shares of the for-
eign firm are held by a depositary bank which issues depositary receipts that are
traded on a US exchange just like domestic stocks. (The underlying mechanics of
an ADR are illustrated in Figure C1.) ADRs are listed on a US exchange, so
American investors do not have to deal with a foreign broker or a stock exchange
which may be unfamiliar to them. ADRs are denominated in US dollars, so inves-
tors do not incur any foreign exchange costs in buying or selling shares or when
they receive dividends. Foreign firms trading through ADRs that are listed on a
US exchange have to meet US accounting and governance standards, so investors
FIGURE C1
The Mechanics of an ADR
1
NY Broker
NYSE Local
AMEX
DTC NASDAQ Stock
Exchange
OTC
1 The foreign firm signs an exclusive deposit agreement with the depositary pursuant to which the firm
will provide shares to back the initial ADR issuance and the depositary will maintain the ADR facility.
2 The local firm issues shares directly into the custodian as underlying securities for the ADRs.
do not have to worry about foreign reporting conventions or be uneasy about the
shareholder protections available to them as foreign investors. ADRs thus over-
come many of the barriers to foreign investments and facilitate international
diversification by investors. Other types of depositary receipts meet the needs of
investors around the world. European investors, for example, can use euros to
invest in non-euro area firms through European Depositary Receipts (EDRs).
Cross-listing allows a firm to access more investors and can increase the
liquidity of its shares. A listing on the NYSE or other major exchange makes a
foreign firm more visible to investors and may broaden its shareholder base.
A US listing also provides investors with strong shareholder protections
because US regulatory and disclosure standards are more stringent than in
many other countries, making the shares less risky. Increased liquidity, a larger
shareholder base, and lower risk may increase firm value. Academic studies of
firms that cross-listed in the US suggest that such firms do have higher returns
and lower their cost of capital.
There are risks to cross-listings, both to firms and to local stock exchanges.
Firms that issue ADRs may not attract sufficient investor interest in the US,
and trading volume may ‘flow back’ to the home market, meaning the firm
gains little from its cross-listing. Cross-listed firms may draw trade away from
local exchanges. This is an issue in emerging economies when trade in cross-
listed domestic firms migrates to larger, more international centers, under-
mining trading volume on the local exchange and making it more difficult to
sustain an active market for local firms.
REFERENCES
Bank of New York Mellon (2007), The Depositary Receipts Market: The Year in Review
(New York: ADRBNYMellon).
Desai, M. A. and J. R. Hines Jr. (2002), ‘Expectations and Expatriations: Tracing the Causes and
Consequences of Corporate Inversions’, National Tax Journal, 55, 3, 409–41.
Desai, M. A. and J. R. Hines Jr. (2003), ‘Evaluating International Tax Reform’, National Tax
Journal, 56, 3, 487–502.
Desai, M. A. and J. R. Hines Jr. (2004), ‘Old Rules and New Realities: Corporate Tax Policy in
a Global Setting’, National Tax Journal, 57, 4, 937–60.
Reich, R. B. (1990), ‘Who is Us?’, Harvard Business Review, January/February, pp. 3–13.
Reich, R. B. (1991), ‘Who is Them?’, Harvard Business Review, March–April, pp. 14–23.
Tyson, L. (1991), ‘They Are Not Us: Why American Ownership Still Matters’, The American
Prospect, 4, 37–49.