Chapter 7 - Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior
Chapter 7 - Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior
Chapter 7 - Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior
Describing Risk
• To measure risk we must know:
1. All of the possible outcomes
2. The probability or likelihood that a given outcome will occur
• Interpreting Probability
– Objective probability
Observed frequency of past events
– Subjective probability
Perception that an outcome will occur
Influenced by different information or different abilities to process the
same information – based on judgment or experience
• 2 measures to help describe and compare risky choices
1. Expected value
2. Variability
• Expected Value
– Probability-weighted average of the payoffs or values associated with all
possible outcomes
measures the central tendency; the payoff or value expected on average
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 1
– In general, for n possible outcomes:
E(X) = Pr1X1 + Pr2X2 + … + PrnXn
where X1, X2, … Xn = payoffs of possible outcomes
Pr1, Pr2, … Prn = probabilities of each outcome
• Variability
– Extent to which possible outcomes of an uncertain event differ
– How much variation exists in the possible choices
– Example: Suppose you are choosing between two part-time sales jobs that
have the same expected income ($1,500)
Outcome 1 Outcome 2
Pr Income Pr Income
Job 1: Commission 0.5 $2,000 0.5 $1,000
Job 2: Fixed salary 0.99 $1,510 0.01 $510
E(X1) = 0.5($2,000) + 0.5($1,000) = $1,500
E(X2) = 0.99($1,510) + 0.01($510) = $1,500
Same expected values, but different variability
Greater variability from expected values signals greater risk
Variability comes from deviations in payoffs
– Difference between expected payoff and actual payoff
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 2
– The standard deviation is written:
Pr1 ( X 1 E ( X )) 2 Pr2 ( X 2 E ( X )) 2
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 3
• People differ in their preference toward risk
– People can be risk averse, risk neutral, or risk loving
• Risk Averse
– A person who prefers a certain given income to a risky income with the
same expected value
– Diminishing marginal utility of income
– Most common attitude towards risk
Ex: Market for insurance
– Example:
A person can have a $20,000 job with 100% probability and receive a
utility level of 16
The person could have a job with a 0.5 chance of earning $30,000 and a
0.5 chance of earning $10,000
Expected Income of risky job
E(I) = (0.5)($30,000) + (0.5)($10,000) = $20,000
Expected Utility of risky job
E(U) = (0.5)(10) + (0.5)(18) = 14
Both jobs have the same expected income but different expected utilities
– Risk averse individual would choose the certain job for its greater
utility
Risk averse person’s losses (decreased utility) are more important than
risky gains
– Risk averse utility function
E
Utility 18 Level of utility increases as
D
16 income increases – marginal
C utility is diminishing
14 F
A A risk-averse person prefers a
certain income of $20,000 to
10 an uncertain expected income
of $20,000
0 10 16 20 30 Income ($1,000)
• Risk Neutral
– A person is indifferent between a certain income and an uncertain income
with the same expected value
– Constant marginal utility of income
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 4
– Expected utility for risky option is the same as for certain outcome
E(I) = (0.5)($10,000) + (0.5)($30,000) = $20,000
E(U) = (0.5)(6) + (0.5)(18) = 12
– This is the same as the certain income of $20,000 with utility of 12
Utility 18
Level of utility increases as
income increases –
marginal utility is constant
12
A risk-neutral person is
indifferent between certain
events and uncertain events
6 with the same expected
income
0 10 20 30 Income ($1,000)
• Risk Loving
– A person prefers an uncertain income to a certain income with the same
expected value
Examples: Gambling, some criminal activity
– Increasing marginal utility of income
– Expected value for risky option
E(I) = (0.5)($10,000) + (0.5)($30,000) = $20,000
E(U) = (0.5)(3) + (0.5)(18) = 10.5
– Certain income is $20,000 with utility of 8
– Risky alternative is preferred
Utility 18
Level of utility increases as
income increases –
marginal utility is increasing
0
10 20 30 Income ($1,000)
• Risk Premium
– The maximum amount of money that a risk-averse person would pay to
avoid taking a risk
– Depends on the risky alternatives the person faces
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 5
– Example:
A person has a 0.5 probability of earning $30,000 and a 0.5 probability of
earning $10,000
The expected income is $20,000 with expected utility of 14
Utility
G
20
18 The risk premium is $4,000
C E because a certain income of
14
F $16,000 gives the person
A the same expected utility as
10 the uncertain income with
expected value of $20,000
0 10 16 20 30 40 Income ($1,000)
Point F shows the risky scenario – the utility of 14 can also be obtained
with certain income of $16,000
This person would be willing to pay up to $4,000 (20 – 16) to avoid the
risk of uncertain income
– Can be shown graphically by drawing a straight line (CF) between the
two points
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 6
• Risk Aversion & Indifference Curves
– Indifference curves that relate expected income to variability of income
(standard deviation) can be used to represent a person’s risk aversion
(Risk/Return Tradeoffs)
– Since risk is undesirable, greater risk requires greater expected income to
make the person equally well off
– Indifference curves are therefore upward sloping
U3
Expected U2
Income U1 Highly Risk Averse:
An increase in standard
deviation requires a large
increase in income to
maintain satisfaction
Expected
Income Slightly Risk Averse:
A large increase in
U3
standard deviation
U2 requires only a small
increase in income to
U1 maintain satisfaction
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 7
Reducing Risk
• 3 ways to reduce risks: diversification, insurance, and obtaining more
information
• Diversification – allocating resources to a variety of activities whose outcomes
are not closely related (positively or negatively correlated)
– Investing in a portfolio of 10 or 20 different stocks
– Buying shares in mutual funds
Organization that pools funds of individual investors to buy a large
number of different stock or other financial assets
• Insurance – paying a premium (= the expected loss from the risky situation) to
avoid risk
– A risk-averse individual counts losses (in terms of changes in utility) more
than gains
– The law of large numbers – although single events may be random and
largely unpredictable, the average outcome of many similar events can be
predicted
– Actuarial fairness – the insurance premium is equal to the expected payout
– Example: Burglary insurance: 100 people are similarly situated and face a
10-percent probability of a $10,000 loss
Premium from the 100 individuals: $100,000
Expected payout to the 100 individuals as a whole: $100,000
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 8
Value of complete information:
Expected value with complete information $8,500
Less: Expected value with uncertainty (buy 100 suits) 6,750
Value of complete information $1,750
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 9
Expected return on the portfolio, Rp, increases as the standard deviation
of that return p increases
(Rm – Rf ) /m is the price of risk – extra risk that an investor must incur
to enjoy a higher expected return
– No risk – invest all the funds in T-bills (b = 0) and earn an expected
return Rf
– Incur a risk level of m – invest all the funds in stocks (b = 1) and earn
an expected return Rm
– Incur a risk level between 0 and m – invest some funds in each type of
asset and earn an expected return somewhere between Rf and Rm
Expected
return, Rp U3 U2 U1
Rm
R*
Rf
0 * m Standard deviation
of return, p
– Risk and indifference curves – describes combinations of risk and return that
leave the investor equally satisfied
Upward-sloping because risk is undesirable
With a greater amount or risk, it takes a greater expected return to make
the investor equally well-off
– The choices of different investors
Investor A is highly risk averse – he invests mostly in risk-free asset
Investor B is less risk averse – he invests mostly in stocks
Investor C has very low degree of risk aversion – he invests more than
100% of his wealth in stocks (buy stocks on margin)
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 10
Expected UA UB UC
return, Rp
RC
Rm
RB
RA
Rf
0 A B m C Standard deviation
of return, p
Source: Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2018), Microeconomics, 9th Ed., Pearson Prentice Hall. 11