Towards A New Enlightenment? A Transcendent Decade: Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, and Future
Towards A New Enlightenment? A Transcendent Decade: Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, and Future
Towards A New Enlightenment? A Transcendent Decade: Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, and Future
A Transcendent Decade
Behavioral Economics:
Past, Present, and Future
Michelle Baddeley
Michelle Baddeley is Director and Research Professor at the Institute for Choice,
University of South Australia, and an Honorary Professor at the Institute for
Global Prosperity, University College London. Previously, she was Professor
of Economics and Finance at the Bartlett Faculty of the Built Environment,
University College London, and before that was Fellow and Director of Studies
(Economics) at Gonville & Caius College / Faculty of Economics, University
of Cambridge. She has a Bachelor of Economics (First Class Honors) and
BA (Psychology) from the University of Queensland, and a Masters/PhD
(Economics) from the University of Cambridge. She specializes in behavioral
Michelle Baddeley economics, applied macroeconomics, labor economics, and development
University of South Australia
economics. She also has a keen interest in public policy and has collaborated
with many public policy makers and government departments throughout
her career. Her most recent books include Behavioural Economics – A Very
Short Introduction (Oxford University Press, 2017), Behavioural Economics
and Finance (Routledge, 2013/2018), and Copycats and Contrarians: Why We
Follow Others... and When We Don’t (Yale University Press, 2018).
The Past
Behavioral economics may seem to many observers to be a new thing, for better or worse.
Most of the excitement about behavioral economics has bubbled-up in the past ten or so years.
The first milestone was the award of the 2002 Nobel Prize jointly to economic psychologist
Daniel Kahneman, alongside Vernon L. Smith—an experimental economist whose insights
and tools inspired behavioral economists even though experimental economics is not be-
havioral economics. The second was the award of the 2017 Nobel to behavioral economist
Richard Thaler, who has written colorfully about his contributions in his book Misbehaving
(Thaler, 2106). Thaler is most famous for his work on behavioral finance and behavioral public
policy—commonly known as “nudging,” named after his best-selling book with legal scholar
Cass Sunstein—the book this year celebrating its tenth anniversary (Thaler and Sunstein,
2008). These thinkers have had enormous influence on modern policy—not least through
advising the policy-making teams of the then US President Barak Obama and the then UK
Prime Minister David Cameron. The establishment of a “nudge” unit in Cameron’s Cabinet
Office spawned the growth of similar units around the world—from Australia to Lebanon to
Mexico, to name just a few.
The Present
We have said a lot about where behavioral economics comes from without saying too much
about what behavioral economists actually do. In understanding this more deeply, we can
look at a range of themes which behavioral economists explore to illustrate the power and
relevance of their insights. Behavioral economics is now an enormous literature and doing
justice to it all in one chapter is impossible, but a few key themes dominate and we will focus
here on those insights from behavioral economics that are most powerful and enduring in
illuminating real-world decision-making problems. These include behavioral analyses of
incentives/motivations; social influences; heuristics, bias, and risk; time and planning; and
impacts of personality and emotions on decision-making (see Baddeley, 2017 and 2018b, for
detailed surveys of these and other behavioral economics literatures).
Social Influences
Linking to these insights around social preferences, behavioral economists have explored
some other ways in which social influences affect our decisions and choices. Broadly speaking,
these social influences can be divided into informational influences and normative influences
(Baddeley, 2018a). Informational influences are about how we learn from others. In situations
where we do not know much or are facing a complex and uncertain series of potential out-
comes, it makes sense for us to look at what others are doing, inferring that they may know
better than we do about the best course of action. Economists have analyzed this phenome-
non in terms of updating our estimates of probabilities—and a classic example outlined by
Abhijit Banerjee is restaurant choice (Banerjee, 1992). We are new to a city—perhaps visiting
as tourists—and we see two restaurants, both of which look similar but we have no way of
knowing which is better. We see that one is crowded and the other is empty and—perhaps
counter-intuitively—we do not pick the empty restaurant, which might be more comfortable
and quieter. Instead, we pick the crowded restaurant. Why? Because we infer that all those
people who have chosen the crowded restaurant ahead of the empty restaurant know what
they are doing, and we follow their lead—using their actions (the restaurant they choose) as a
piece of social information. We respond to these informational influences in a rational way—
perhaps not the extreme form of rationality that forms the cornerstone of a lot of economics,
but nonetheless sensible—the outcome of a logical reasoning process.
Normative social influences are less obviously rational and are about how we respond
to pressures from the groups around us. In explaining these social pressures, behavioral
economics draws on key insights from social psychologists, such as Stanley Milgram and
Solomon Asch, and their colleagues. Stanley Milgram created controversy with his electric
shock experiments. Experimental participants were instructed by an experimenter to inflict
what they thought were severe electric shocks on other people hidden from view. The partic-
ipants in Milgram’s experiments could still hear the people who were supposedly receiving
the shocks. In fact, these people were just actors but the experimental participants did not
know this and a significant number of the participants (not all) were prepared to inflict what
they were told were life-threatening levels of shock: the actors pretended to experience severe
pain, screaming and at worst in some cases going worryingly quiet after the shocks. Milgram
explained the fact that his participants were prepared to act in these apparently ruthless ways
as evidence that we are susceptible to obedience to authority. We are inclined to do what we
are told, especially when we confront physically and psychologically challenging scenarios.
Milgram’s evidence was used in part to explain some of the atrocities associated with the
Holocaust—in an attempt to answer the puzzle of why so many otherwise ordinary civilians
not only observe but also actively engage in atrocities.
Another influential set of social psychology experiments that have informed behavioral
economists include Solomon Asch’s experiments (Asch, 1955). He devised a line experiment
More generally, many of us use others’ choices and actions to guide our own choices and
actions—such as in the restaurant example above. When we copy other people we are using
a rule of thumb—a simple decision-making tool that helps us to navigate complex situations,
especially situations characterized by information overload and choice overload. In today’s
world, the ubiquity of online information and reviews is another way in which we use in-
formation about others’ choices and actions as a guide. For example, when we are buying a
new computer or booking a hotel, we will find out what others have done and what others
think before deciding for ourselves. In these situations, when thinking through lots of infor-
mation and many choices is a cognitive challenge, it makes sense to follow others and adopt
what behavioral economists would call a herding “heuristic.” Following the herd is a quick
way to decide what to do. This brings us to the large and influential literature on heuristics
and bias, developing out of Daniel Kahneman’s and his colleague Amos Tversky’s extensive
experimental work in this field.
What are heuristics? Heuristics are the quick decision-making rules we use to simplify our
everyday decision-making and they often work well, but sometimes they create biases in
our decision-making. In other words, in some situations when we use heuristics they lead us
into systematic mistakes. The psychologist Gerd Gigerenzer makes the important observation,
however, that heuristics are often good guides to decision-making because they are fast and
frugal. They often work well, especially if people are given simple techniques to enable them
to use heuristics more effectively (Gigerenzer, 2014).
If you Google behavioral bias today, you will get a long and unstructured list, and, in devising a
taxonomy of heuristics and their associated biases, a good place to start is Daniel Kahneman and
Amos Tversky’s taxonomy of heuristics—as outlined in their 1974 Science paper (Tverksy
and Kahneman, 1974) and summarized for a lay audience in Kahneman (2011). Kahneman and
Tversky identified three categories of heuristic, based on evidence from an extensive range
of experiments they had conducted, including the availability, representativeness, and an-
choring and adjustment heuristics.
The availability heuristic is about using information that we can readily access—either
recent events, first moments, or emotionally vivid or engaging events. Our memories of these
types of highly salient information distort our perceptions of risk. A classic example is the
impact that vivid and sensationalist news stories have on our choices, linking to a specific
type of availability heuristic—the affect heuristic. For example, vivid accounts of terrible
plane and train crashes stick in our memory leading us to avoid planes and trains when,
objectively, we are far more likely to be run over by a car when crossing the road, something
we do every day without thinking too hard about it. We misjudge the risk—thinking plane
and train crashes are more likely than pedestrian accidents—and this is because information
about plane crashes is far more available, readily accessible, and memorable for us.
The representativeness heuristic is about judgments by analogy—we judge the likelihood of
different outcomes according to their similarity to things we know about already. In some
of their experiments, Kahneman and Tversky asked their participants to read a person’s
profile and judge the likelihood that this profile described a lawyer versus an engineer. They
discovered that many of their participants judged the likelihood that a person described was
a lawyer or an engineer according to how similar the profile was to their preconceptions and
stereotypes about the characteristic traits of lawyers versus engineers.
Anchoring and adjustment is about how we make our decisions relative to a reference point.
For example, when participants in Kahneman and Tversky’s experiments were asked to guess
the number of African nations in the United Nations, their guesses could be manipulated by
asking them first to spin a wheel to give them a number. Those who spun a lower number on
the wheel also guessed a smaller number of African countries in the UN.
Another seminal contribution from Kahneman and Tversky emerges from their analyses
of heuristics and bias: their own unique behavioral theory of risk—what they call “prospect
theory” (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). They devised prospect theory on the basis of a se-
A whole other swathe of behavioral economics literature taps into some important insights
about our ability to plan our choices and decisions over time. Standard economics predicts that
we form stable preferences about time, as we do for risk. This means that it does not matter
what time horizon we are considering. If we are impatient, we are impatient, no matter what
the context. Behavioral economists overturn this understanding of how we plan and make
decisions over time, building on the substantial evidence from psychological experiments
that we are disproportionately impatient in the short term—we suffer from what behavioral
economists call present bias. We overweight benefits and costs that come sooner relative to
those that come later. For example, if we are choosing between spending on our credit card
today or tomorrow and comparing this choice with spending on our credit card in a year or
a year and a day, then standard economics predicts that our choices should be time consist-
ent: if we prefer to spend today then we should prefer to spend in a year; and if we prefer
to spend in a year and a day, then we should also prefer to spend tomorrow. But behavioral
experiments show that we are disproportionately impatient in the short term relatively to
the longer term: we prefer to spend today over tomorrow, but when planning for the future
we prefer to spend in a year and a day than in a year. We overweight immediate rewards.
Behavioral economists such as David Laibson have captured this within alternative theories
of discounting to that incorporated in standard economics—specifically in the form of hy-
perbolic discounting (Laibson, 1997). This is more than an academic curiosity because it has
significant implications in our everyday lives—in explaining everything from procrastination
to addiction. Present bias can explain why we delay actions that are costly or unpleasant.
It can also explain a range of bad habits, or lack of good habits. A telling experiment was
one conducted by economists Stefano DellaVigna and Ulrike Malmendier in their study of
gym-going habits. Looking at a dataset from a real-world gym, they found that some people
signed-up for annual contracts and then attended the gym only a handful of times—even
though they had been offered pay-as-you-go membership as an alternative (DellaVigna and
Malmendier, 2006). Over the course of a year and sometimes longer, these very occasional
gym-goers were effectively paying enormous sums per visit when they would not have had
All these insights from behavioral economics are now changing mainstream economics, and
also having a strong impact on policy-making via nudging, as highlighted in the introduction.
So, are there new horizons for behavioral economics, or do we know all we need to know? For
nudging, more evidence is needed to capture how robust and scalable nudging policies really
are—and there has been progress in this direction. Another key area that has been largely
neglected until recently is behavioral macroeconomics. British economist John Maynard
Keynes pioneered the analysis of psychological influences, particularly social conventions, in
financial markets and the implications for macroeconomies more generally—see for example
RELATED ARTICLES
MORE ABOUT #ECONOMY #FINANCE
• Frontier Research in Economics
Frontiers of Knowledge, Joan Esteban