Preparing For Multi Party Negotiations
Preparing For Multi Party Negotiations
Preparing For Multi Party Negotiations
By Pablo M. Linzoain
There is a substantial difference between negotiation involving two parties and those, which
involve more than two parties. Sebenius (1996) states that the most powerful advances in
negotiation theory have been mainly inspired by the two-party case. On the other hand, multi-
party negotiation is often seen as a question of coalition-formation (Rubin and Brown, 1975,
Zartman, 1988). The coalitional possibilities make the analysis of a complex negotiation more
difficult and interesting. Part of the game for each party is to build a relationship with the group
and to form alliances with some of the members within it. In these relationships they should be
able to improve their communication, trust, exchange of information and understanding each
which three or more persons, with their interests, decide how to resolve their conflicting
preferences among issues. However, the knowledge, theory and practice of two-party negotiation
A classic example of two-party negotiation is the standard strategic model Prisoner’s Dilemma
Game, which has been called the negotiator’s dilemma by Lax and Sebenius (1986). Both
Pablo M. Linzoain 1
negotiators face a choice between contending (“claiming value”) and problem solving (“creating
N EGOTIATOR 2
CREATE CLAIM
GOOD GR EA T
CREATE
GOOD TER R IB LE
N EGOTIATOR 1
M ED IOC R E
TER R IB LE
CLAIM
GR EA T M ED IOC R E
Source: The negotiator’s dilemma, David Lax and James Sebenius (1986:39) “The Manager as Negotiator” The
Free Press, USA
The negotiator’s dilemma characterises the whole of a negotiation. The line between
“creating” and “claiming” need not be clear-cut. Each negotiator has specific interest and s/he can
reveal information early, late, throughout, or not at all; s/he can mislead by omission or
commission, or be straight.
The tension the negotiator’s dilemma reflects between cooperative impulses to create
value and competitive impulses to claim it is the same regardless of the scale of the negotiation.
The essence of an effective negotiator is being able to manage this tension, creating while
claiming value (Lax and Sebenius, 1986). However, the dynamics of group negotiation are far
Pablo M. Linzoain 2
more complex than those of the two-party negotiator’s dilemma. As has been seen, with two
parties there are four possible outcomes, two sets of interests and one interaction. With three
parties, the network grows; there are three sets of individual interests, three possible interactions
between any two players and one interaction of all three. In a five-party situation, there are five
sets of individual interests, ten possible two-player interactions, multiple potential three- and
four-person subgroups, and one five-person group. This web of interests and relationships
becomes increasingly complex as the number of parties grows (Bazerman and Neale, 1992).
When the negotiation is between more than two persons, it makes coordination and
cooperation much more important. It is relatively easy for two parties to find the motivation to
work together: with more than two, it is much more difficult. In the Harborco1 case (in which the
author of this assignment played the role of the Governor’s Negotiator), some parties were
motivated to work together, to build productive relationships. Some parties, however, showed
little enthusiasm for coordinating their actions with others’, which resulted in disarray. It was no
surprise to discover that the group needed time and resources to be able to work in coordination
and cooperation with one another and to find solutions that maximize the interests of the parties.
In the complex negotiation of the Harborco case, it was difficult at the beginning to
understand the interests and preferences of each party. Only when the group started to listen to
one another and to divide into sub-groups did the situation become clearer. In almost every case,
in a multi-party negotiation it will take longer to differentiate interests and preferences of group
1
D.Madigan and T.Weeks wrote this case study under the supervision of Professor Lawrence Susskind (M.I.T.),
Assistant Professor, David Lax and the Negotiation Roundtable.
Pablo M. Linzoain 3
It is more complicated to build trust with two, three or six people than it is with just one.
For example, in the Harborco case, as each party expressed its preferences and it became apparent
that parts of the interests were incompatible, the parties grew more and more suspicious of one
another. Negotiators did not know if the other party was pushing hard or it was a real conflict of
interest. Communication about what each party wants and making the effort to understand the
others’ needs are more difficult when the parties face the problem of lack of trust. To overcome
an exercise in coalition-building. Negotiators should try to form coalitions in order to pool their
resources and have greater influence on outcomes. This is perhaps the biggest difference between
Thus, it can be seen that it is more difficult to create value and new alternatives in a
information and exchange of ideas, trust, definition of interests and needs, and indeed the
common goal between parties is more complicated to see than in a two-party situation.
Raiffa stated “Significant conceptual complexities arise when even a single new party is added to
In preparing for the formal process of multi-party negotiation, the negotiator should think
hard about his/her real interest in the initiative. In a negotiation with a group of people, it is
wasting other people’s time to arrive without a clear understanding of one’s own interest.
Pablo M. Linzoain 4
The negotiator should then assess the other parties involved and their possible interests.
It is important to identify potential coalition members and estimate which parties are going to
have conflicts of interest. As the negotiation progresses, it is essential to begin to make coalitions
with parties whose agreement will have the strongest influence over the other parties.
Since a chaotic negotiation achieves very little, it is important to be calm and to allow
others adequate time to speak. A negotiator needs to be able to send signals or code that s/he is
prepared to move, and also to read signals that the other person is prepared to move. It is essential
to be a good listener because listening enables the negotiator to obtain information and to identify
what makes people move from one stage to the next. It has already been said that, in negotiation,
information is power, so it is important not to miss any kind of signals that people send.
The negotiator should reach agreement through packaging the separate issues on the
table. Rubin and Brown (1975) tell us, “the social-psychological literature lends experimental
support to the proposition that juggling multiple issues together can lead to settlements that are
jointly preferred to those obtained by bargaining on an issue by issue basis.” However, adding
issues together for negotiation purposes while ignoring their interdependence has its dangers.
Bringing other parties to the table can increase support for the party who invited them.
For example, in the Malta case, Dom Mintoff strengthened his position by involving the Soviets
and the Libyans in the naval base negotiation with Great Britain. Malta thus forced Britain into
Working with opponents separately can be useful to find support and to recognize needs.
The negotiator representing Harborco Port took the initiative to talk with the different parties
separately. This was a good way to build a coalition of support; dealing one to one allowed
Pablo M. Linzoain 5
Harborco’s negotiator to understand better what was needed to secure the other parties’
agreement.
Sometimes parties choose to emphasize the differences between themselves and the
others. A more productive approach is to highlight the similarities and to work on the easier
issues first, returning later to the bigger issues involving most conflict.
The methods employed in coalition-building, what Lax and Sebenius (1986) call
“strategic sequencing”, are crucial. The negotiator must consider “which parties are approached,
IN CONCLUSION
Real-world negotiations are complex. It is unusual that a group should be wholly “claiming
value” or wholly “creating value”. Normally, as has been said above, there is in every negotiation
tension between creating and claiming value. According to Bazerman and Neale (1992), to
negotiate successfully and deal with this tension, members must reveal their preferences, attempt
The principal difference between two-party and multi-party negotiation is probably the
need to build coalitions. The dynamics of group negotiation are far more complex than those
between two parties; establishing communication, building up trust, identifying interests and
goals become automatically more difficult when more than two parties are involved.
Therefore, to prepare for a multi-party negotiation the negotiator must assess his/her own
interests and those of the others, in order to calculate with which of the members around the table
Pablo M. Linzoain 6
Two other tactics for the negotiator to bear in mind for a multi-party negotiation are
introducing additional parties to the proceedings and the packaging of the issues on the table.
international.
For the past ten years he has been working on the planning and execution of strategies
and tactics for getting into new markets for important companies in various countries of Europe,
South and North America, capitalizing on his expertise in diverse industries such as fast moving
consumer goods (FMCG), manufacture, vehicle parts, commodities trading, insurance, film and
He now lives in USA, in the cities of Pittsburgh and Washington where he works as
Managing Director of Consulting Global Business, Vice Marketing President for Fennell
His academic background includes course of studies in USA, Europe and Argentina. He
graduated from the Negotiation Programme of Law School, Harvard University, Boston, USA;
and from the Business School of the Manchester Metropolitan University, Manchester, England.
He obtained his double degree for the Master in Management Science of International Business
and specialization in International Marketing, and for the MBA of the Institute of Management
Sciences from the Manchester Metropolitan University and the catholic University of Córdoba,
Córdoba, Argentina. He also obtained the certificate “Programme of Management Update” from
Pablo M. Linzoain 7
University of California, Berkeley, USA. He graduated from the Business Faculty of the Catholic
Business Administration.
international negotiations.
References
Bazerman, Max H. and Neale, Margaret A. 1992. "Negotiating Rationally", USA: The Free
Press.
Bazerman, Mannix and Thompson 1988. “Groups as mixed-motive negotiations”, In, Lawler and
Markovshy, eds., Advances in group process: theory and research, vol. 5 (Greenwich: JAI press)
Lax and Sebenius 1986. “The Manager as Negotiator”, USA The Free Press.
Raiffa, Howard 1982. "The Art and Science of Negotiation", Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Rubin, Jeffrey Z. and Brown, Bert R. 1975. "The Social Psychology of Bargaining and
Negotiation", London: Academic Press, Inc.
Sebenius 1996. “Sequencing to Build Coalitions: With Whom Should I Talk First?” Wise
Choices: Games, and Negotiation. Edited by Richard J. Zeckerhauser et al. USA, Harvard
Business School Press. Chapter 18.
Zartman, I.W. 1988. “Common Elements in the Analysis of the Negotiation Process”, USA
Cambridge Negotiation Journal, January-1988.
Pablo M. Linzoain 8