11 IGF Insights Tax Competition Mining
11 IGF Insights Tax Competition Mining
11 IGF Insights Tax Competition Mining
IGF Secretariat hosted by: IGF Secretariat funded by: Project funded by:
Introduction
This paper highlights key findings from an analysis of the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database, a
collection of files comparing the fiscal regimes of 104 mining projects across 21 countries. The
database is the first large-scale, systematic attempt to compile tax incentives used by developing
country governments to attract mining investment. It is also the first public effort to bring together
incentives granted in mining contracts. This is made possible through greater contract transparency—
in particular, the availability of resource contracts compiled by the Natural Resource Governance
Institute (NRGI), Colombia Centre for Sustainable Investment (CCSI), the World Bank and Open Oil.
The findings below are by no means exhaustive. It is hoped that further analysis of the database by
policy-makers, researchers, international organizations and civil society, will yield additional lessons
for the design and use of mining tax incentives. To ensure that the contents remain relevant, and
in light of the Extractive Industry Transparency Initiative (EITI) requirement to publish all resource
contracts by 2021, IGF is committed to periodically updating the database, and welcomes support
from researchers and partner organizations in this task.
The database is part of a series of materials on mining tax incentives. Readers should refer to the
IGF-OECD practice note Tax Incentives in Mining: Mining Risks to Revenue, as well as the open-
source IGF financial model for estimating the cost of tax incentives.
1
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
2 Tunisia
Mali 12 1 Mongolia
1 Niger
3 Afghanistan
Senegal 5
3 Cameroon
7 Philippines
Guinea 8
6 DR Congo
Colombia 5
Sierra Leone 8
1 Burundi
Ecuador 1
Liberia 16
Peru 5 2 Malawi
Burkina Faso 7
Zambia 6 1 Madagascar
4 Mozambique
2
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
3
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
an even lower tax rate in its contract. While it could be argued that the incentive in the law
is cancelled out by the more generous incentive in the contract, both are counted in the
database. This is because the incentive in the law would still apply to any other investor
entering the market as well as to existing investors with less generous contracts. Table 2
provides a stylized example of how incentives were assessed in such cases. On the other
hand, if the incentive in the contract is less generous than the incentive in the law, the
“incentive” in the contract as not counted as an incentive.
Tax code 30% tax rate 30% tax rate 30% tax rate 30% tax rate
Mining code 30% tax rate 25% tax rate 30% tax rate 25% tax rate
Contract According to law According to law 25% tax rate 10% tax rate
4
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
7 Key Findings
1 It is more common for countries to grant incentives in the
primary law than in contracts.
Across the three regions, the average number of incentives granted through law is higher than the
number of incentives granted by contract. Without considering the type of incentives, it is positive
that a greater proportion are granted in the law, which is public, and subject to legislative review,
rather than by contract, which are often discretionary, secret and vulnerable to corruption.
→ See page 18 of the IGF-OECD practice note for a checklist for good governance and tax incentives.
However, there are significant regional differences. In particular, African countries grant more
contract-based incentives than their peers in Asia and Latin America. It should be considered that
the database coverage of Asia and Latin America is less than Africa, which may impact regional
comparisons. Notwithstanding, the finding is still valid given that the results are weighted for
number of contracts and number of countries. The average number of incentives in law per region is
determined by the combined number of incentives in law divided by the number of countries in that
region. Incentives per contract per region are the number of contract-based incentives divided by the
number of contracts analyzed. Thus, the comparison is valid, although the results may look different
if more Asian and Latin American countries were included in the database (the limitation was the
availability of contracts).
9.00
8.00 7.7
7.0
7.00
Number of incentives
6.00
5.0
5.00
3.9
4.00
3.00
2.00
1.2
1.00 0.7
0.00
Africa Asia Latin America
5
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
Reading the chart: The “number of incentives in law” is the sum of incentives by
type for the primary law; this may include incentives in the general tax code, the
mining code, and, in some cases, investment codes. It is not necessary to provide an
average here as the chart is per country.
10.00
8.00
6.00
4.00
2.00
0.00
Ecuador
Madagascar
Niger
Afghanistan
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Colombia
DRC
Guinea
Liberia
Malawi
Mali
Mongolia
Mozambique
Peru
Philippines
Senegal
Sierra Leone
Tunisia
Zambia
Average number of incentives in contract Number of incentives in law
Tax stabilization and corporate income tax incentives are the most common form of incentives
across both primary law and mining contracts. They are also two of the most high-risk incentives
according to the IGF-OECD practice note. Partial or complete income tax holidays may cause the
investor to increase their income during the tax-free period by speeding up the rate of production
and shifting the profits offshore. Combining incentives with excessive use of broad and long-
term fiscal stability provisions will magnify the adverse impact of tax incentives, including the
unintended consequences, by potentially cutting off government’s ability to correct mistakes and
unexpectedly large revenue losses.
Incentives relating to withholding tax raise particular tax base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS)
issues. Withholding tax requires the taxpayer to withhold some income tax on outbound payments.
For example, a taxpayer in Country A borrows USD 1,000 from a lender in Country B; the lender
requires 10 per cent interest on the loan, which is USD 100. The withholding tax rate in Country A is 5
6
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
per cent, meaning the borrower must withhold USD 5 income tax on the USD 100 interest it pays to
the lender. However, if countries reduce or exempt withholding tax on interest expense, management
fees or royalties, there is an added incentive for investors to increase these payments in order to strip
profits out of the mine, transferring them to a foreign affiliate, usually based in a low-tax country.
Only Colombia, Mongolia and the Philippines offer an investment allowance or tax credit in the
law. This is surprising given that cost-based incentives are generally better targeted to mining
investments. An investment allowance, or tax credit, allows taxpayers to recoup their investment, as
well as defer taxes to later stages in a project’s life and hence not eat into cash flows in the early
years when capital is most needed. They are also easier to monitor, as the benefit is based on the
amount of investment. However, there are some importance differences: Mongolia gives a 10 per cent
tax credit, whereas Colombia offers an allowance for investments made in the environment, including
the rehabilitation of mine sites. A tax credit will reduce the tax payable, whereas the investment
allowance will reduce the taxable income. The effect is different; the tax credit being significantly
more generous than the investment allowance.
16
14
12
10
0
Loss carry
Royalty
Tax stability
Other
Accelerated
depreciation
CIT
Deduction
on CAPEX
Property tax
or licence fee
Tariffs and
excise taxes
Tax credits
and allowances
VAT
WHT
forward
rates
agreement
7
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
Loss carry
Royalty
Tax stability
Other
Accelerated
depreciation
CIT
Deduction
on CAPEX
Property tax
or licence fee
Tariffs and
excise taxes
Tax credits
and allowances
VAT
WHT
forward
rates
agreement
4 Royalty-based incentives feature heavily in contracts but
not in the primary law.
Very few countries grant royalty-based incentives in the primary law. Thus, it is particularly striking
that many more offer such incentives in contracts. Royalty-based incentives may take the form of
reduced or deferred royalties, or variable rate royalties where the benchmark is a flat rate. The extent
of royalty-based incentives is concerning for two reasons. First, royalties are intended as payment for
the right to extract a publicly owned resource. If government reduces or waives royalties, it foregoes a
regular and relatively predictable source of revenue. Secondly, a royalty holiday provides an incentive
to shift revenues into the tax-free period, like the response to an income tax holiday. While there may
be circumstances in which it is necessary to waive or exempt royalty payments, when cash flows are
negative, for example, there should be clear and objective criteria and procedures.
8
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
16
14
Number of incentives
12
10
2
Loss carry
Royalty
Tax stability
Other
Accelerated
depreciation
CIT
Deduction
on CAPEX
Property tax
or licence fee
Tariffs and
excise taxes
Tax credits
and
allowances
VAT
WHT
forward
rates
agreement
Number of countries with incentive in law Number of countries with incentive in at least one contract
Nearly all countries include a tax stability clause either in the primary law or mining contracts. A
predictable investment environment is important to ensure the bankability of projects. However,
where the period extends well past the financing stages, for example, 30–34 years on average in
Guinea, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Madagascar and Mali, stabilization clauses become more akin to
rent-seeking tools than necessary financial assurances. Where governments choose to offer fiscal
stabilization, they should ensure that the time period and scope are limited, and that there are
opportunities for review.
→ See page 43 of the IGF-OECD practice note for recommendations on drafting fiscal
stabilization clauses.
Reading the chart: The “average years of stability” are calculated using the number
of years offered for each contract. If the contract does not specify a number of years,
the number of years specified in legislation is entered. If the offered tax stability is for
the entire duration of the project or indefinite, 30 is entered as a benchmark.
9
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
Afghanistan
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Colombia
DRC
Ecuador
Guinea
Liberia
Madagascar
Malawi
Mali
Mongolia
Mozambique
Niger
Peru
Philippines
Senegal
Sierra Leone
Tunisia
Zambia
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
More than half of the countries surveyed offer a corporate income tax holiday either in the law, or in
one or more mining contracts. Statutory tax holidays are provided for in Ecuador, Madagascar, Niger
and the Philippines.
Tax holidays are problematic for two reasons: First, income tax holidays are a relatively inefficient and
ineffective incentive for mining. They are ineffective because mining is location-specific, making it
difficult for investors to move where they are offered better fiscal terms. They are inefficient because
profitable projects benefit more from tax holidays than marginal ones whose viability may actually
depend on favourable fiscal terms. The second problem is the risk of abuse. Investors are incentivized
to increase their income during the tax-free period by speeding up production and shifting the profits
offshore, leaving less income to tax after the holiday has ended. In some cases, the tax holidays are
more than the average life of the mine, in which case government may never collect income tax.
→ See pages 20 to 24 of IGF-OECD practice note for a detailed discussion of tax holidays.
10
Reading the table: Tax holiday is defined as a corporate income tax exemption
during the operating phase and is counted as “yes” if either legislation or at least
one contract is granted such for at least one year. Tax holiday length is the simple
average of the projects with a tax holiday, regardless of whether this comes from law
or contract. In one case in the Democratic Republic of Congo, the tax holiday is not
time-limited: for this a period of 30 years is used to calculate the average. In Guinea,
one contract has a tax holiday "Until full repayment of initial investments." For this
case we do not assign a number of years.
Malawi 30.0 No
The use of mining tax incentives peaked during the late 1990s, with an average of 4.7 incentives per
contract. This coincides with many African countries seeking to attract private investment to develop
their mineral resources. Some of the Zambian contracts signed during that period offered 0.6 per cent
11
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
royalty rates, for example. The experience was mixed during most of the 2000s. However, there was a
sharp decline in incentives from 2010 to 2013, which coincides with high commodity prices. This was
followed by a steep increase from 2014 onwards, mirroring the commodity price crash, in which case
countries would have been under pressure to offer generous fiscal terms to attract investment. With
the exception of these events, countries’ motivations for granting incentives seem relatively random,
and are more likely determined by particular policy choices, or private sector investors, than global
economic conditions.
Incentives
Figure 9. Incentives in contracts in contracts over time
over time
14 8.0
6.0
Number of contracts
10
5.0
8
4.0
6
3.0
4
2.0
2 1.0
0 0.0
1977
1987
1997
2007
2017
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Contracts without incentives Contracts with incentives Average number of incentives per contract
12
Seven Insights from the IGF Mining Tax Incentives Database
The International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD) is an independent think tank
championing sustainable solutions to 21st–century problems. Our mission is to promote
human development and environmental sustainability. We do this through research,
analysis and knowledge products that support sound policy-making. Our big-picture view
allows us to address the root causes of some of the greatest challenges facing our planet
today: ecological destruction, social exclusion, unfair laws and economic rules, a changing
climate. IISD’s staff of over 120 people, plus over 50 associates and 100 consultants, come
from across the globe and from many disciplines. Our work affects lives in nearly 100
countries. Part scientist, part strategist—IISD delivers the knowledge to act.
IISD is registered as a charitable organization in Canada and has 501(c)(3) status in the
United States. IISD receives core operating support from the Province of Manitoba and
project funding from numerous governments inside and outside Canada, United Nations
agencies, foundations, the private sector and individuals.
Our Tax Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) in Mining Program provides sector-specific
guidance and tools on BEPS challenges, as well as capacity building support to developing
country governments, with the goal of helping countries capture a fair share of the
fiscal benefits from their natural resources. Funding for this program comes from the UK
Department for International Development.
13