An Analysis of David Graeber's 'Debt' The First 5,000 Years by Sulaiman Hakemy - Compressed
An Analysis of David Graeber's 'Debt' The First 5,000 Years by Sulaiman Hakemy - Compressed
An Analysis of David Graeber's 'Debt' The First 5,000 Years by Sulaiman Hakemy - Compressed
David Graeber’s
Debt
The First 5,000 Years
Sulaiman Hakemy
Copyright © 2017 by Macat International Ltd
24:13 Coda Centre, 189 Munster Road, London SW6 6AW.
Macat International has asserted its right under the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988 to be
identified as the copyright holder of this work.
The print publication is protected by copyright. Prior to any prohibited reproduction, storage in a
retrieval system, distribution or transmission in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical,
recording or otherwise, permission should be obtained from the publisher or where applicable a license
permitting restricted copying in the United Kingdom should be obtained from the Copyright Licensing
Agency Ltd, Barnard’s Inn, 86 Fetter Lane, London EC4A 1EN, UK.
The ePublication is protected by copyright and must not be copied, reproduced, transferred, distributed,
leased, licensed or publicly performed or used in any way except as specifically permitted in writing by
the publishers, as allowed under the terms and conditions under which it was purchased, or as strictly
permitted by applicable copyright law. Any unauthorised distribution or use of this text may be a direct
infringement of the authors and the publishers’ rights and those responsible may be liable in law
accordingly.
www.macat.com
info@macat.com
Notice
The information in this book is designed to orientate readers of the work under analysis, to elucidate
and contextualise its key ideas and themes, and to aid in the development of critical thinking skills. It is
not meant to be used, nor should it be used, as a substitute for original thinking or in place of original
writing or research. References and notes are provided for informational purposes and their presence
does not constitute endorsement of the information or opinions therein. This book is presented solely
for educational purposes. It is sold on the understanding that the publisher is not engaged to provide
any scholarly advice. The publisher has made every effort to ensure that this book is accurate and up-
to-date, but makes no warranties or representations with regard to the completeness or reliability of the
information it contains. The information and the opinions provided herein are not guaranteed or
warranted to produce particular results and may not be suitable for students of every ability. The
publisher shall not be liable for any loss, damage or disruption arising from any errors or omissions, or
from the use of this book, including, but not limited to, special, incidental, consequential or other
damages caused, or alleged to have been caused, directly or indirectly, by the information contained
within.
CONTENTS
WAYS IN TO THE TEXT
Who Is David Graeber?
What Does Debt: The First 5,000 Years Say?
Why Does Debt: The First 5,000 Years Matter?
SECTION 1: INFLUENCES
Module 1: The Author and the Historical Context
Module 2: Academic Context
Module 3: The Problem
Module 4: The Author’s Contribution
SECTION 2: IDEAS
Module 5: Main Ideas
Module 6: Secondary Ideas
Module 7: Achievement
Module 8: Place in the Author’s Work
SECTION 3: IMPACT
Module 9: The First Responses
Module 10: The Evolving Debate
Module 11: Impact and Influence Today
Module 12: Where Next?
Glossary of Terms
People Mentioned in the Text
Works Cited
THE MACAT LIBRARY
The Macat Library is a series of unique academic explorations of seminal
works in the humanities and social sciences – books and papers that have had
a significant and widely recognised impact on their disciplines. It has been
created to serve as much more than just a summary of what lies between the
covers of a great book. It illuminates and explores the influences on, ideas of,
and impact of that book. Our goal is to offer a learning resource that
encourages critical thinking and fosters a better, deeper understanding of
important ideas.
Each publication is divided into three Sections: Influences, Ideas, and
Impact. Each Section has four Modules. These explore every important facet
of the work, and the responses to it.
This Section-Module structure makes a Macat Library book easy to use,
but it has another important feature. Because each Macat book is written to
the same format, it is possible (and encouraged!) to cross-reference multiple
Macat books along the same lines of inquiry or research. This allows the
reader to open up interesting interdisciplinary pathways.
To further aid your reading, lists of glossary terms and people mentioned
are included at the end of this book (these are indicated by an asterisk [*]
throughout) – as well as a list of works cited.
Macat has worked with the University of Cambridge to identify the elements
of critical thinking and understand the ways in which six different skills
combine to enable effective thinking.
Three allow us to fully understand a problem; three more give us the tools to
solve it. Together, these six skills make up the PACIER model of critical
thinking. They are:
ANALYSIS – understanding how an argument is built
EVALUATION – exploring the strengths and weaknesses of an argument
INTERPRETATION – understanding issues of meaning
CREATIVE THINKING – coming up with new ideas and fresh
connections
PROBLEM-SOLVING – producing strong solutions
REASONING – creating strong arguments
To find out more, visit WWW.MACAT.COM.
CRITICAL THINKING AND DEBT: THE FIRST
5,000 YEARS
Primary critical thinking skill: PROBLEM-SOLVING
Secondary critical thinking skill: REASONING
Debt is one of the great subjects of our day, and understanding the way that it
not only fuels economic growth, but can also be used as a means of
generating profit and exerting control, is central to grasping the way in which
our society really works.
David Graeber’s contribution to this debate is to apply his anthropologists’
training to the understanding of a phenomenon often considered purely from
an economic point of view. In this respect, the book can be considered a fine
example of the critical thinking skill of problem-solving. Graeber’s main aim
is to undermine the dominant narrative, which sees debt as the natural – and
broadly healthy – outcome of the development of a modern economic system.
He marshals evidence that supports alternative possibilities, and suggests that
the phenomenon of debt emerged not as a result of the introduction of money,
but at precisely the same time.
This in turn allows Graeber to argue against the prevailing notion that
economy and state are fundamentally separate entities. Rather, he says, “the
two were born together and have always been intertwined” – with debt being
a means of enforcing elite and state power. For Graeber, this evaluation of the
evidence points to a strong potential solution: there should be more readiness
to write off debt, and more public involvement in the debate over debt and its
moral implications.
ABOUT THE AUTHOR OF THE ORIGINAL WORK
Born in 1961, US anthropologist and activist David Graeber was weaned on
leftist politics, and declared himself an anarchist at age 16. He became an
anthropology professor, and his early cultural research in Madagascar
exposed him to poverty that he saw as caused by pressures to repay excessive
government debt. Through a combination of activism and scholarship he has
devoted much of his career to developing an intellectual basis for
undermining capitalism. In his 2011 book Debt: The First 5,000 Years,
Graeber uses the insights of an anthropologist to argue that debt plays a toxic
role in human relations.
ABOUT MACAT
GREAT WORKS FOR CRITICAL THINKING
Macat is focused on making the ideas of the world’s great thinkers
accessible and comprehensible to everybody, everywhere, in ways that
promote the development of enhanced critical thinking skills.
It works with leading academics from the world’s top universities to
produce new analyses that focus on the ideas and the impact of the most
influential works ever written across a wide variety of academic disciplines.
Each of the works that sit at the heart of its growing library is an enduring
example of great thinking. But by setting them in context – and looking at the
influences that shaped their authors, as well as the responses they provoked –
Macat encourages readers to look at these classics and game-changers with
fresh eyes. Readers learn to think, engage and challenge their ideas, rather
than simply accepting them.
‘Macat offers an amazing first-of-its-kind tool for interdisciplinary learning
and research. Its focus on works that transformed their disciplines and its
rigorous approach, drawing on the world’s leading experts and educational
institutions, opens up a world-class education to anyone.’
Andreas Schleicher Director for Education and Skills, Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development
NOTES
1. David Runciman, “The Democracy Project: A History, a Crisis, a
Movement by David Graeber – Review,” Guardian, March 28, 2013,
http://www.theguardian.com/books/2013/mar/28/democracy-project-
david-graeber-review.
2. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2011), 18.
3. Graeber, Debt, 18.
4. Graeber, Debt, 18.
5. Graeber, Debt, 19.
6. Graeber, Debt, 18.
7. Graeber, Debt, 130.
8. Graeber, Debt, 381.
9. Graeber, Debt, 383.
SECTION 1
INFLUENCES
MODULE 1
THE AUTHOR AND THE HISTORICAL
CONTEXT
KEY POINTS
These two crises together have exposed the weakest points of a consumer
economy based on credit* (borrowing) and debt, national economies built on
financing debt of other nations, and a global economy based on balancing the
effects of imports and exports between countries. The common thread
through all of these layers of economic woe is debt—which makes Graeber’s
work extremely relevant for students of the social sciences and members of
the public alike.
The author is the first to write a popular book that considers economic
questions from an anthropological perspective. By introducing this approach
in a book written for a non-academic audience, Graeber has popularized the
idea of taking interdisciplinary* approaches (approaches that draw on the
aims and methods of different academic fields) to economic issues. On a
more fundamental level, however, Graeber’s book seeks to challenge the
popular understanding of economics,* and to undermine the central
principles of the social and economic system of capitalism* itself (a system
in which trade and production are held in private hands and exercised for
private profit). Graeber’s views have been taken up by anti-capitalist
intellectuals and activists alike, and provide sophisticated and understandable
arguments for rethinking the capitalist system.
Author’s Life
David Graeber was born in New York in 1961. The son of working-class
intellectuals active in labor union* circles (organizations of workers founded
to guarantee things such as fair pay and decent working conditions), he was
exposed to leftist politics* at an early age. Graeber’s mother was a garment
worker. His father was affiliated with the Young Communist League* as a
student and later participated in the Spanish Revolution* and Spanish Civil
War* of the 1930s, in which supporters of the extreme right-wing regime of
the military leader Francisco Franco* fought a coalition of Spanish and
international volunteers who wanted to preserve the previous, democratic,
regime.
Graeber began to declare himself an anarchist at the age of 16.1 He
graduated from the State University of New York at Purchase in 1984, then
studied anthropology as a graduate student at the University of Chicago.
While there he won a prestigious Fulbright Fellowship* to conduct
ethnographic* research into the culture of the people of Madagascar, an
island nation east of Africa. Graeber received his doctorate in anthropology in
1997.
Graeber’s involvement in political activism began in 1999, when he joined
protests against the World Trade Organization (WTO)* meeting in Seattle.
The WTO promotes and regulates global trade, and is a symbol of the
growing connections among nations around the world. Graeber established
himself as a vocal figure in the global justice movement,* an international
network of activist groups opposed to capitalism and globalization.* In 2011,
he became an intellectual leader within Occupy Wall Street (OWS),* an
activist group that grew out of a local protest in a park in New York City.
Among other things, OWS protested against debt-relief policies that they
believe unfairly favored wealthy creditors.* Graeber is sometimes credited
for coming up with the group’s now famous protest slogan “We are the
99%.”2
Today, Graeber is a professor of anthropology at the London School of
Economics* and continues to participate in social activism.
Author’s Background
David Graeber was a teenager in the 1970s, a period bookended by major
disruptions in the global economic order. In 1971, the United States began a
process that led to the end of the gold standard,* under which the US dollar
and other currencies had been linked to a fixed amount of gold. In 1979, an
energy crisis* caused by interruptions in the supply of petroleum from the
Middle East and faltering economies in the West saw fuel prices rise sharply,
creating economic hardship throughout the economy.
While Graeber was a university student, the world saw a debt crisis in the
1980s* triggered by unregulated lending from global banks to governments
in developing countries* that borrowed (and sometimes wasted) more money
than they could repay. In response, global trade and development
organizations—the International Monetary Fund (IMF)* and the World
Bank*—forced changes that created hardships for citizens of developing
countries reliant on suddenly unaffordable public welfare programs and local
jobs. In exchange for high-interest loans that saved them from default, these
developing countries had to focus more of their budgets on loan repayment,
and open their economies to international trade. According to the
anthropologist Keith Hart,* “Graeber’s internationalism was shaped by this
wholesale looting” of developing countries.3
Graeber’s doctoral fieldwork in Madagascar also played a considerable
role in informing his politics. His views on economic inequality arose from
his research on the slave trade, colonialism,* and postcolonial power
struggles between Madagascar and wealthier nations. All of these aspects of
Graeber’s background fuel his political activism and inform the tone of Debt
and his other academic work.
NOTES
1. Stuart Jeffries, “David Graeber Interview: ‘So Many People Spend Their
Working Lives Doing Jobs They Think Are Unnecessary,’” Guardian,
March 21, 2015,
http://www.theguardian.com/books/2015/mar/21/books-interview-
david-graeber-the-utopia-of-rules.
2. David Runciman, “The Democracy Project: A History, a Crisis, a
Movement by David Graeber – Review,” Guardian, March 28, 2013,
http://www.theguardian.com/books/2013/mar/28/democracy-project-
david-graeber-review.
3. Keith Hart, “In Rousseau’s footsteps: David Graeber and the
Anthropology of Unequal Society,” The Memory Bank, July 4, 2012,
http://thememorybank.co.uk/2012/07/04/in-rousseaus-footsteps-david-
graeberand-the-anthropology-of-unequal-society-2/.
MODULE 2
ACADEMIC CONTEXT
KEY POINTS
Academic Influences
By disputing what he called the “Myth of Barter,”* David Graeber draws on
the work of anthropologists before him. Marcel Mauss,* a nineteenth-century
French sociologist considered to be a pioneer in anthropology, proposed in
his book The Gift that barter was not a natural or necessary method of
exchange in human society.11 In “Barter and Economic Disintegration,” the
renowned British anthropologist Caroline Humphrey* wrote: “No example of
a barter economy, pure and simple, has ever been described, let alone the
emergence from it of money; all available [studies of the world’s peoples]
suggests that there never has been such a thing.”12
The British anthropologist Keith Hart* has also contributed much to the
field’s scholarship on money. In his 1986 essay “Heads or Tails? Two Sides
of the Coin,” Hart argues that money has always been both a commodity*
(something that can be traded), and a token of debt. Graeber has stated that
Hart’s essay was one of the inspirations for Debt.13
Debt also draws on unorthodox theorists like the influential German
political philosopher Karl Marx,* who in his classic book Capital (1867–
94)14 warned that capitalism uses debt to oppress people, and the Hungarian
American economic historian Karl Polanyi,* who in his book The Great
Transformation (1944) suggested that markets are artificial concepts that
were entirely created by the power of the state.15 As a result, Debt draws on a
wide variety of academic traditions.
NOTES
1. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2011), 18.
2. Graeber, Debt, 21.
3. T. C. Barker, “The Beginnings of the Economic History Society,” The
Economic History Review 30, no. 1 (February, 1977): 4.
4. Shahzavar Karimzadi, Money and Its Origins (Abingdon: Routledge,
2013), 213.
5. A. Mitchell Innes, “What Is Money?,” The Banking Journal 30 (1913):
377– 408.
6. Graeber, Debt, 28
7. Graeber, Debt, 48.
8. Georg Friedrich Knapp, The State Theory of Money (London:
Macmillan & Company, 1924), 1.
9. A. Mitchell Innes, “The Credit Theory of Money,” The Banking Journal
31 (1914): 151–68.
10. John Maynard Keynes, A Treatise on Money (New York: Harcourt,
Brace, & Co, 1930), 4.
11. Marcel Mauss, The Gift (London: Cohen & West, 1954).
12. Caroline Humphrey, “Barter and Economic Disintegration,” Man 20, no.
1 (March, 1985): 48.
13. Keith Hart, “Heads or Tails? Two Sides of the Coin,” Man 21, no. 4
(December, 1986): 637–56.
14. Karl Marx, Das Kapital (Chicago: Charles H. Kerr & Co, 1906).
15. Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation (Boston: Beacon Press, 1944).
MODULE 3
THE PROBLEM
KEY POINTS
Core Question
In Debt: The First 5,000 Years, David Graeber is attempting to answer
several questions, some of which are academic and some of which are moral.
All of them lead to the core question: “What, in terms of economic life, is a
fair way to live?” After the global financial crisis 2008,* this was a major
concern for many economists and policy makers.
As Graeber recalls: “After 2008, for example, there was this moment that
lasted maybe a month or so, where suddenly you could talk about anything.
Everything was in doubt. Even The Economist* ran headlines effectively
asking: ‘Capitalism: was it a good idea?’ Obviously, they concluded yes;
they’re The Economist. But, nonetheless, it seemed like everything was up
for grabs. You could think big thoughts again and wonder why it was all
here. Why do we have an economy? And that lasted about four weeks, until
everyone said, ‘Shut up and stop thinking about this. It will come back if we
just close our eyes and ears and keep carrying on as if nothing is
happening.’”1
“This book is a history of debt, then, but it also uses that history as a
way to ask fundamental questions about what human beings and
human society are or could be like––what do we actually owe each
other, and what it even means to ask that question”.
David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years
The Participants
Another question related to Graeber’s focus––the question of how to
reconcile our ideas of debt under capitalism with harsh realities for debtors––
was part of a raging debate at the time of Debt’s publication. One camp,
consisting primarily of Western politicians and economic institutions founded
to provide loans and financial assistance for developing countries* (the
International Monetary Fund* and the World Bank*), and backed by the
American economists Carmen Reinhart* and Kenneth Rogoff,*2 maintained
that high levels of debt were bad for economic growth. They also argued that
rescuing debtors by forgiving debt would encourage more irresponsible
behavior (a principle described as “moral hazard”), so the debts should be
paid back. The opposing camp, consisting of most mainstream economists in
the academic world and including prominent Keynesians* like the Nobel
Prize-winning economists Paul Krugman* and Amartya Sen,* supported
some concessions for debt relief. They also argued that forcing developing
countries to reduce government spending until debts are repaid would be a
bigger barrier to economic growth. According to Keynesian thought, a
country’s economic output, in the short run, is influenced by the economy’s
level of total demand.
At the same time, activist movements driven by anger over economic
inequality were rallying on the fringes of the academic and policy debates.
These movements, including the global justice movement* (a network of
international social activist movements that oppose corporate globalization*)
and, later, the Occupy movement (a global protest movement against
economic and social inequality that began in 2011), were joined by radical
economists like the French scholar Thomas Piketty* in extending the pro-
debt relief position to its most extreme. They argued that capitalism itself was
unjust, as it reinforced inequality and took away the rights of debtors.3
Graeber’s work reflects this belief.
NOTES
1. Hannah Chadeayne Appel, “Finance Is Just Another Word for Other
People’s Debts: An Interview with David Graeber,” Radical History
Review, no. 118 (2014): 168.
2. Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, “Growth in a Time of
Debt,” American Economic Review 100, no. 2 (May, 2010): 573–8.
3. Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 2014).
4. Amartya Sen, “The Economic Consequences of Austerity,” New
Statesman, June 4, 2015.
MODULE 4
THE AUTHOR’S CONTRIBUTION
KEY POINTS
Author’s Aims
David Graeber has several aims in Debt: The First 5,000 Years. At a basic
level, he wants to clear up the “profound moral confusion”1 about what debt
actually is by building a definition of debt that is free from “the logic of the
marketplace.”2
He wants to advance the discipline of anthropology by injecting its
insights into a discussion usually associated with economic theory and
economic history. As such, the book practices a kind of intellectual sabotage
that systematically undermines the work of the eighteenth-century economist
Adam Smith* and his descendants, and strengthens the position of Graeber’s
own intellectual forebears in the field of economic anthropology along the
way.
At the broadest level, however, Graeber is trying to promote anti-
capitalism* by means of relevant and serious scholarship without falling back
on the outmoded ideas of Karl Marx* or the fringes of leftist extremism.
Graeber does not make any sweeping policy proposals, other than offering
the idea of extensive debt relief.3 But he clearly intends to inspire others to
create solutions once they have set aside their commitment to capitalism.
“One of the puzzling things about all the theories on the origins of
money that we’ve been looking at so far is that they almost completely
ignore the evidence of anthropology.”
David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years
Approach
In Debt, Graeber does not build arguments on top of preexisting economic
theory or political philosophy. He seeks only to disprove existing arguments.
Graeber believes capitalism evolved because of a series of events in world
history, and is not based on any objective economic truths. Based on this
approach, he reveals lessons about debt, morality, and markets by examining
economic history in detail.
Graeber bases his work on evidence, and is thorough in referencing his
sources. But the sheer size of the time period covered (3500 b.c.e. to the
present) forces him to trot briskly through historical and anthropological
evidence, providing his own opinions and theories where they are relevant.
As a result, the book’s chapters are not neatly tied to a central point. Graeber
quickly lays out some of his arguments at the beginning and provides the
evidence to support them as he goes along, making other key arguments at
the end.
While this would be a problem in an academic paper, the approach works
well in a book written for a popular audience. Graeber values storytelling
over technicalities, so that the reader finishes with a clear set of ideas and
opinions and plenty of examples to support them. But it is difficult to stitch
all the ideas together into a consistent theory.
Contribution in Context
One of Debt’s unique contributions is that it combines the various traditions
in economic anthropology in an effort to disprove the traditional
understanding of economics. Graeber pulls together an enormous range of
ethnographic* (cultural) studies, physical evidence from earlier societies, and
anthropological theory to conclude that money did not originate from barter*
(trade without money) and did not arise as a unit of exchange.
He also supports the school of thought pioneered by the British
anthropologist Keith Hart,* who said money has always been both a
commodity* (something valuable in its own right) and a tool for credit,* and
debt accounting. Graeber builds on Hart’s views by arguing that over history,
civilization has swung back and forth between credit and commodity forms
of money. When Graeber told Hart of this claim in person, Hart
acknowledged that he had never realized that before.
Graeber also discusses why money really came about, if not for exchange.
He then draws moral conclusions from this discussion, arguing that
economies have manipulated the concepts of credit and debt by using money
to enforce power relationships. While Graeber does not describe a new anti-
capitalist anthropological theory, he assembles many of the pieces needed to
do so.
NOTES
1. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2011), 8.
2. Graeber, Debt, 90.
3. Graeber, Debt, 390.
SECTION 2
IDEAS
MODULE 5
MAIN IDEAS
KEY POINTS
David Graeber writes about two key themes in Debt: the origin of
money and markets,* and the origins of the concept of “debt” itself.
According to Graeber, money and markets are tools artificially
created to convert the social obligations on which human
relationships are built into measureable “debts” people in a position
of power can use to take advantage of others.
Debt is written for a popular audience, so while making its
arguments it provides easily understandable discussions on morality
and political philosophy.
Key Themes
David Graeber wants to understand whether our current economic system,
centered on the idea of debt, is truly fair; the title Debt: The First 5,000 Years
makes it plain that debt will be the central focus of the work. His attempts to
answer the question “What is debt?” are a tool for the teaching of many
lessons about the economy.
Debt addresses three themes that work together to build a clear idea of
what debt really is:
“Not only is it money that makes debt possible: money and debt appear
on the scene at exactly the same time.”
David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years
Finally, Graeber argues that debt is artificial by tracing how the nature of
money has changed throughout history. He presents a vast discussion of the
history of Eurasia split into four stages:
NOTES
1. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2001), 43.
2. Graeber, Debt, 28.
3. Graeber, Debt, 56.
4. Graeber, Debt, 18.
5. Graeber, Debt, 18.
6. Graeber, Debt, 113.
7. Graeber, Debt, 213.
8. David Graeber, “Can We Still Write Big Question Sorts of Books?”
Savage Minds, July 31, 2011, http://savageminds.org/2011/07/31/can-
we-still-write-big-question-sorts-of-books/.
9. Graeber, “Big Question Sorts of Books.”
MODULE 6
SECONDARY IDEAS
KEY POINTS
Graeber argues that money has always been a fluid concept, used as
both a symbol or representation of credit* and as a tradable
commodity* (a physical object, such as gold).
He adds a moral dimension to his arguments by saying there is a
pattern of violence associated with debt, and that the capitalist*
system is designed to help the wealthy and powerful take advantage
of others.
Graeber connects the rise and fall of currency and the rise and fall
of slavery throughout human history as an extreme example of the
dangers of money and debt.
Other Ideas
An important secondary idea in David Graeber’s Debt: The First 5,000 Years
is the relationship between debt, markets,* and violence. Graeber explores
this through his concept of the “human economy.”
One of the main ideas of Debt is that our current economic system is not
legitimate because it is built on the idea that debt is simply an impersonal
exchange that is not yet complete. Graeber argues that exchange-related debt
is part of a broader system of more personal obligations. By artificially
reducing debt to an amount of money and insisting on repayment, the
economic system alienates people from each other.
In Debt, Graeber also argues that the modern economic system centered
on debt is actually harmful. This means the book is not just an alternative to
mainstream economic history,* but also thoroughly anti-capitalist. This is in
line with Graeber’s own politics,* and provides academic justification for his
participation in activist movements.
“The crucial factor … is money’s capacity to turn morality into a
matter of impersonal arithmetic––and by doing so, to justify things that
would otherwise seem outrageous or obscene.”
David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years
Debt asks the question “What is debt?” Graeber answers in the last
paragraph of his book: “A debt is just the perversion of a promise. It is a
promise corrupted by both math and violence.”6
Overlooked
Graeber’s discussion of the primordial debt* theory is both his least
developed and most overlooked. As the cultural anthropologist Bill Maurer
has written, “Everyone is captivated by [Graeber’s] critique of the myth of
primitive barter.* Yet it is a puzzle that a core element of his argument––the
myth of primordial debt––has been largely overlooked.”7
The “Myth of Barter”* is the idea that money arose spontaneously as a
solution to the inconveniences of barter; it is possible to approach the truth of
this proposition by testing evidence. But “primordial debt” is a philosophical
idea, resistant to similar analysis; the primary sources we must turn to are
ancient scriptures. Referring to sacred texts of the Indian Hindu tradition
written in about 800 b.c.e., Graeber writes that “two famous passages in the
Brahmanas* insist that we are born as a debt not just to the gods, to be repaid
in sacrifice … but also to the Sages … which we must repay through study;
to our ancestors, who we must repay by having children; and finally, ‘to
men’––apparently meaning humanity as a whole, to be repaid by offering
hospitality to strangers.”8 Primordial debt theorists say these ideas “are not
peculiar to a certain intellectual tradition [but are] essential to the very nature
and history of human thought.”9
As Graeber says, by thinking about how to repay an “infinite debt” we are
saddled with at birth, “the Brahmanas are offering a quite sophisticated
reflection on a moral question that no one has really ever been able to answer
any better before or since.”10 While Graeber says he rejects the primordial
debt myth, his own alternative philosophy can be read as supporting it: “If
one were looking for the ethos for an individualistic society such as our own,
one way to do it might well be to say: we all owe an infinite debt to
humanity, society, nature, or the cosmos … but no one could possibly tell us
how we are to pay it … Human freedom would then be our ability to decide
for ourselves how we want to do so.”11
NOTES
1. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2001), 130.
2. Graeber, Debt, 158.
3. Graeber, Debt, 130.
4. Graeber, Debt, 208.
5. Graeber, Debt, 208.
6. Graeber, Debt, 391.
7. Bill Maurer, “David Graeber’s Wunderkammer, Debt: The First 5,000
Years,” Anthropological Forum 23, no. 1 (2013): 79.
8. Graeber, Debt, 57.
9. Graeber, Debt, 57.
10. Graeber, Debt, 67.
11. Graeber, Debt, 68.
MODULE 7
ACHIEVEMENT
KEY POINTS
Achievement in Context
The structural weaknesses of Debt have not kept it from becoming a
prominent work of nonfiction. The “big book of ideas” produced by an
established academic for a broad audience was (and remains) popular. As a
genre, Debt follows in the footsteps of Guns, Germs, and Steel, an equally
vast work by the scientist and author Jared Diamond.* Guns, Germs, and
Steel pushed geography* as an academic discipline into the debates of
economic historians* in much the same way that Graeber intends for
anthropology. Nearly 20 years after its publication in 1997, Diamond’s book
continues to have considerable influence as a contribution to the theory of
“path dependency”*—the idea that states develop along a certain path
because of predetermined factors like geography.
Debt was an international bestseller in the year after its publication
(2011).2 So far, no one has challenged the factuality of the historical and
anthropological evidence Graber presents, even while debating the
conclusions he draws from that evidence. This suggests that Debt could
become a respected academic work just as it has captured the public
imagination, although more gradually and after long processes of peer
review.
Limitations
Graeber intends to incorporate global history and anthropology into Debt and
apply them to the universal human experience. To the extent that he is
successful, his reflections on economic life are not limited by geography or
the present historical period. Graeber’s background as an anthropologist
helps him reach out to a broad audience, because he is in the business of
understanding the similarities and differences between people from different
backgrounds. Debt’s individual claims are meant to remain sound and logical
even as they thread their way through different cultures.
At the same time, the work’s greatest limitation is in its title—a
declaration that it is only looking backward. While the book combines
various insights into a value judgment on capitalism as a whole, that is not
enough to lead to any policy prescriptions, beyond the single suggestion of
providing more debt relief. It might be argued that this hinders Debt from
making a wholly constructive contribution to the debate.
NOTES
1. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2011), 212.
2. Keith Hart, “In Rousseau’s Footsteps: David Graeber and the
Anthropology of Unequal Society,” The Memory Bank, July 4, 2012,
http://thememorybank.co.uk/2012/07/04/in-rousseaus-footsteps-david-
graeberand-the-anthropology-of-unequal-society-2/.
MODULE 8
PLACE IN THE AUTHOR’S WORK
KEY POINTS
Positioning
Debt: The First 5,000 Years builds heavily on David Graeber’s previous
scholarship and the development of his political ideas throughout his
scholarly career. It also represents a change in Graeber’s scholarly direction,
in which he turns away from the pure anthropology and ethnography* (field
study of a people’s culture or society) that characterized his work in most of
the 2000s to revisit the economic anthropology of his first book, Toward an
Anthropological Theory of Value (2001).
In many ways Debt is a logical extension of Toward an Anthropological
Theory of Value. Debt uses one of Toward’s core arguments—the inability of
the capitalist market* to accurately value human actions—as an intellectual
backdrop. To underwrite his analysis of debt, Graeber musters a great deal of
evidence from his previous works in anthropology and his own research.
Significance
Graeber was already considered one of the greatest anthropologists of his
generation well before the publication of Debt. His extensive ethnographic
work on Madagascar, which ranged from his time as a graduate student to his
publication of Lost People, was highly regarded within his field.3 After the
publication of Graeber’s books Toward an Anthropological Theory of Value
and Fragments of an Anarchist Anthropology, the British anthropologist
Maurice Bloch* wrote: “[Graeber’s] writings on anthropological theory are
outstanding. I consider him the best anthropological theorist of his generation
from anywhere in the world.”4
Graeber’s significant body of anthropological writing on power relations,
hierarchies, and activism, bookended by Toward an Anthropological Theory
of Value and Debt: the First 5,000 Years, positions Graeber as a pioneering
intellectual in what the anthropologist Keith Hart* calls “anthropology of
unequal society.”5 Of all his work, Debt has received the most critical
acclaim, winning the Bateson Book Prize from the Society for Cultural
Anthropology and the Bread and Roses Award from the Alliance of Radical
Booksellers.
NOTES
1. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville
House, 2011), 4.
2. David Graeber, Toward an Anthropological Theory of Value: The False
Coin of Our Own Dreams (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2001).
3. Thomas Meaney, “Anarchist Anthropology,” The New York Times,
December 8, 2011,
http://www.nytimes.com/2011/12/11/books/review/anarchist-
anthropology.html.
4. Maurice Bloch, “Letter from Maurice Bloch, London School of
Economics” (2005).
5. Keith Hart, “In Rousseau’s Footsteps: David Graeber and the
Anthropology of Unequal Society,” The Memory Bank, July 4, 2012,
http://thememorybank.co.uk/2012/07/04/in-rousseaus-footsteps-david-
graeberand-the-anthropology-of-unequal-society-2/.
SECTION 3
IMPACT
MODULE 9
THE FIRST RESPONSES
KEY POINTS
The principal criticisms made of Debt are that David Graeber has
not adequately understood the internal debates among economists,
that he attaches too much importance to the origins of economic
ideas as a measure of their value, and that his recommendation for
debt relief is impractical.
The fact that Graeber and his detractors come from different
disciplines (anthropology* and economics,* respectively) makes it
difficult for the two to engage in a substantive debate.
Graeber’s ideas have been well received by economists outside the
mainstream.
Criticism
Debt: The First 5,000 Years was a controversial book at the time of its
publication; while David Graeber’s ideas have been ignored by most
economists, a few have expressed opposition or support. Among those who
chose to critically engage with Debt, Noah Smith* and Mike Beggs* offer the
most detailed criticisms.
Smith, an assistant professor of finance at Stony Brook University and a
popular economics writer, says that many monetary economists already
recognize that credit* preceded barter.* He suggests that Graeber accuses
economists of misleading the public without understanding the diversity of
views within economics. Smith also argues that Graeber’s proposal for debt
cancellation in response to overwhelming debt levels would make lenders
very unwilling to lend in the future, and would reward those bold enough to
take out large loans rather than those in need.1
Responses
Graeber has been accused by many of his detractors of being unwilling to
accept any criticism. Because they are not anthropologists,* Graeber’s critics
have been unable to dispute the anthropological evidence he cites to dismiss
the Myth of Barter;* because he is not an economist, Graeber lacks the
technical knowledge to engage with the claims of economists such as Mike
Beggs who accuse him of overlooking constructive solutions to debt crises
from the field of economics. The result is that both Graeber and his critics are
left to argue over minor points rather than the merits of the book as a whole
or its broader implications.
Graeber’s main response to arguments like those of Noah Smith that debt
relief makes lenders unwilling to lend is that this has been disproven. As
Graeber points out, history has had many instances of debt relief, and the
practice of lending continues. Furthermore, “big players” (that is, the wealthy
or giant corporations) forgive and restructure* one another’s debts frequently.
NOTES
1. Noah Smith, “David Graeber: Debt Is Bad, or Something?,”
Noahpinion, February 13, 2013,
http://noahpinionblog.blogspot.co.uk/2013/02/david-graeber-debt-is-
bad-or-something.html.
2. Mike Beggs, “On Debt: A Reply to Josh Mason,” Jacobin, September
20, 2012, https://www.jacobinmag.com/2012/09/on-debt-a-reply-to-
josh-mason/.
3. Mike Beggs, “Debt: The First 500 Pages,” Jacobin, August, 2012, 7–8.
4. J. W. Mason, “In Defense of David Graeber’s Debt,” Jacobin,
September 18, 2012, https://www.jacobinmag.com/2012/09/in-defense-
of-david-graebers-debt/.
5. Beggs, “Debt.”
6. Mason, “In Defense of David Graeber’s Debt.”
MODULE 10
THE EVOLVING DEBATE
KEY POINTS
Schools of Thought
Scholars who have played an important role in popularizing the debate on
global inequality and capitalism include the economists Thomas Piketty* of
France, Joseph Stieglitz* of the United States, and Dani Rodrik* of Turkey.
By far the most successful recent book in bridging the divide between
academia and the public over inequality is Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the
Twenty-First Century. This book does not call for dismantling the capitalist
system, but, rather, for a serious reform of its mechanics so that global tax
systems might redistribute enough wealth to undo inequality produced by
capitalism.3 Nonetheless, Capital shares some of Debt’s core features,
arguing against the idea that capitalism operates on principles of equality. As
Knox Peden has written in the Sydney Review of Books: “Though Piketty and
Graeber are temperamentally antipodal [opposites], the thematic resonance
connecting their works is clear enough.”4
In 2015, Piketty appeared to acknowledge Graeber’s analysis when he
called for an international conference on debt and the implementation of a
new strategy for dealing with the European debt crisis:* “Essentially, it
consists of three components: inflation,* a special tax on private wealth, and
debt relief.”5
In Current Scholarship
Brought together by a mutual frustration with inequality, Graeber and Piketty
have engaged with each other directly on how to move forward the current
scholarship criticizing capitalism and inequality. The two scholars approach
the debate from completely different practical viewpoints.
In Capital, Piketty supports Graeber’s idea that capitalism is a system that,
in its purest form, cannot help but create injustice: “Capitalism does not
contain an inherent tendency to civilize itself. Left to its own devices, it can
be expected to create rates of return on investment so much higher than
overall rates of economic growth that the only possible result will be to
transfer more and more wealth into the hands of a hereditary elite of
investors, to the comparative impoverishment of everybody else.”6
In line with his own intellectual background and previous work, Graeber
favors a revolutionary response to this problem. “Since the 1970s,” he writes,
“as any significant political threat has receded, things have gone back to their
normal state: that is, to savage inequalities.” Graeber’s criticism of Piketty is
that he “has nothing against capitalism itself … He just wishes to provide a
check on capitalism’s tendency to create a useless class of parasitical
rentiers* [people who live off the profits from investments].” Graeber
concludes that total debt relief and an “unplugging” of the capitalist system is
in order.7
Piketty’s response has been that Graeber’s solution—to put the burden on
creditors—is unjust. “The fact is, as I say, that the last creditors are not
necessarily the ones who should be made to pay,” Piketty has argued. Rather,
a progressive tax* should be imposed on wealth, which, according to Piketty,
“seems … a more civilized way to arrive at the same result.”8
NOTES
1. Hannah Chadeayne Appel, “Finance Is Just Another Word for Other
People’s Debts: An Interview with David Graeber,” Radical History
Review no. 118 (2014): 168.
2. Appel, “Other People’s Debts,” 168.
3. Thomas Piketty and Arthur Goldhammer, Capital in the Twenty-First
Century (Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University
Press, 2014).
4. Knox Peden, “The Abstractions of History,” The Sydney Review of
Books, July 22, 2014, http://www.sydneyreviewofbooks.com/capital-
twenty-first-century-thomas-piketty/.
5. Gavin Schalliol, “Thomas Piketty: ‘Germany Has Never Repaid Its
Debts. It Has No Right to Lecture Greece,’” The Wire, July 8, 2015,
http://thewire.in/2015/07/08/thomas-piketty-germany-has-never-repaid-
its-debts-it-has-no-right-to-lecture-greece-5851/.
6. David Graeber, “Savage Capitalism Is Back––And It Will Not Tame
Itself,” Guardian, May 30, 2014,
http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2014/may/30/savage-
capitalism-back-radical-challenge.
7. Graeber, “Savage Capitalism.”
8. David Graeber and Thomas Piketty, “Soak the Rich: An Exchange on
Capital, Debt, and the Future,” The Baffler, July 31, 2014,
http://thebaffler.com/odds-and-ends/soak-the-rich.
MODULE 11
IMPACT AND INFLUENCE TODAY
KEY POINTS
Position
Debt has become a “must-read” in international activist circles. Public
intellectuals like Antonio Negri,* the Italian Marxist* sociologist and
political philosopher, have cited Debt in their activist writings and calls for
action. In their 2012 joint essay Declaration, Negri and American political
philosopher Michael Hardt* state, “In contrast to the myth of equal exchange,
then, the debtor–creditor relationship has the virtue of unmasking the vast
inequalities at the foundation of capitalist society.” One of their listed sources
of evidence for this statement is David Graeber’s Debt: The First 5,000
Years.
Even outside of the community of hardcore anti-capitalist activists,
however, Debt receives glowing praise. The book allows the reader to step
outside the boundaries of traditional economic thought, and instead ask
questions about the system as a whole. While questioning the capitalist
system is an activity as old as capitalism itself, Debt makes the exercise more
accessible to today’s audience. In a time of global economic turmoil caused
by personal and national debt, Graeber’s book offers both sympathy and
defiance.
“Graeber … has emerged as perhaps the most influential radical
political thinker of the moment.”
Kelefa Sanneh, The New Yorker
Interaction
The first translation of Debt was published in Germany, which, as the
primary creditor of the European debt crisis,* is often thought to occupy the
moral high ground. While Graeber thinks of debt as a social invention that is
often used to take advantage of others, German thinkers tend to view debt as
a moral absolute. In Debt, Graeber notes that the German word for “debt,”
schuld, is also the word for “guilt.” “But at the same time they realize that
[debt is] about to destroy the European Union,* which is the last thing they
want.” Debt was a best seller for 11 weeks in Germany, indicating that
Graeber’s ideas may be gaining acceptance there. German voters, it might
appear, are increasingly willing to at least discuss compromising with debtor
nations.
If Debt can be said to argue against a specific group of people, it is the
central bankers and policymakers who are responsible for resolving today’s
economic crises. The book’s success in Germany, where a leading
conservative politician praised it on the cover of the major daily Frankfurter
Allgemeine Zeitung,1 shows that policymakers might be following the
citizens they serve in acknowledging the book’s arguments.
NOTES
1. “Melville House Press Release: Debt: The First 5,000 Years,”
November 27, 2012, http://cdn.mhpbooks.com/2012/12/Debt-PR.pdf.
2. Hannah Chadeayne Appel, “Finance Is Just Another Word for Other
People’s Debts: An Interview with David Graeber,” Radical History
Review, no. 118 (2014): 171.
3. Appel, “Other People’s Debts,” 171.
4. Appel, “Other People’s Debts,” 171.
5. Appel, “Other People’s Debts,” 173.
MODULE 12
WHERE NEXT?
KEY POINTS
Potential
In terms of style and structure, Debt: The First 5,000 Years resembles both a
history book and a declaration of belief. Debt also challenges the assumptions
we have made over the last several hundred years about civilization, history,
and society. While it provides an alternate view of history, Debt offers almost
nothing to replace the policy assumptions that it challenges. Instead, the book
serves as a giant signpost pointing the public and the intellectual community
in a direction that may be anarchist* or reformist, but is essentially unknown.
The book will likely be remembered as a classic in anthropology for its
ability to unite the reflections and observations of anthropologists on
economic life and collectively aim them toward a common mission.
However, pure economists have proven so unwilling to break free from rigid
ideas like the Myth of the Barter* that Debt will probably remain out of the
mainstream, on secondary reading lists as an object of curiosity.
Summary
David Graeber’s Debt is a vast work, more than 500 pages, on the origins and
meaning of debt and money in human society. Published in the wake of the
2008 global financial crisis,* the book’s sharp criticism of many of the
foundational principles of capitalism has found an audience. Debt’s central
lesson is that the traditional understanding of economics and economic
history has hidden the real story of capitalism, which is that money and debt
allow the powerful to take advantage of the weak. War and slavery, Graeber
argues, were instrumental in creating and shaping the institutions that form
our modern market economy.
Debt uses anthropological and historical evidence to argue that money did
not arise from a natural human tendency toward bartering,* despite the claims
of Adam Smith and the economists that followed him. In fact, rather than
base their lives on cutting deals with or profiting off of one another, Graeber
argues that pre-market and non-market societies operated in the “human
economy.” People worked together to meet their needs based on complex
networks of social obligations shaped by their personal relationships, and any
barter-like behavior was for strangers who lacked mutual trust.
As rulers and states grew more powerful, however, social obligations
gradually converted into measurable, impersonal debts, which disrupted
human relationships. Graeber describes money as the tool used to calculate
debts and justify punishments for those who owed them. With five millennia
of history as evidence, Graeber argues that the commercial economy does not
reflect human nature, and that it creates complex ways for the wealthy to take
advantage of the poor. His book declares that capitalism itself is far from the
fair and equitable system many imagine, and that capitalism can be undone.
NOTES
1. David Graeber, “Why Is the World Ignoring the Revolutionary Kurds in
Syria?” Guardian, October 8, 2014,
http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2014/oct/08/why-world-
ignoring-revolutionary-kurds-syria-isis.
GLOSSARY OF TERMS
Anarchism a political philosophy advocating the destruction of governments
in favor of stateless societies.
Barter the practice of trading goods or services directly for other goods or
services, without exchanging money. Barter is possible only when each party
has something that the other wants.
Chartalism the economic school of thought that teaches that money arose
from states’ efforts to direct market activity rather than spontaneously to
enable barter.
Debt crisis of the 1980s a debt crisis triggered by unregulated lending from
global banks to governments in developing countries that borrowed (and
sometimes wasted) more money than they could repay. In response, global
trade and development organizations (the International Monetary Fund and
the World Bank) forced changes that created hardships for those people in
developing countries who benefitted from public welfare programs and local
jobs.
Economic history a discipline of the social sciences that studies the history
and development of economies.
Global financial crisis of 2008 the most serious financial crisis since the
Great Depression of the 1930s. The crisis was caused by the collapse of the
American housing bubble and resulted in mass defaults on debts, affecting
financial institutions and markets worldwide.
Market an economic system in which parties buy and sell goods and
services.
Mesopotamia the name for the area of the Middle East, much of it in Iraq,
lying between the Tigris and Euphrates rivers. The region is generally
considered to be the home of the earliest human civilizations.
Myth of Barter the idea that money arose spontaneously as a solution to the
inconveniences of barter. Economists have believed this for centuries, but
many anthropologists argue that it is not correct.
1979 energy crisis an economic event that occurred in the United States in
which there was a panic about shortage of the supply of oil as a result of
political upheaval in Iran, leading to sharply increased prices.
Progressive tax taxation where the tax rate increases as income increases.
Spanish Civil War a civil war fought in Spain between 1936 and 1939
between loyalists to the Second Spanish Republic and supporters of General
Francisco Franco.
Syrian Civil War an ongoing civil war in Syria between the national
government and various rebel movements.
Jared Diamond (b. 1937) is an American scientist and geographer. His ideas
on the path dependency of nations brought influence from the fields of
anthropology and geography to economic history.
Thomas Piketty (b. 1971) is a French economist. He is best known for his
work highlighting the propensity of unrestricted capitalism to result in
economic and social inequality.
Amartya Sen (b. 1933) is a Bangladeshi economist. He is best known for his
work on poverty relief and development economics, and has strongly
opposed austerity measures in response to debt crises.
ANTHROPOLOGY
Arjun Appadurai’s Modernity at Large: Cultural Dimensions of
Globalisation
Philippe Ariès’s Centuries of Childhood
Franz Boas’s Race, Language and Culture
Kim Chan & Renée Mauborgne’s Blue Ocean Strategy
Jared Diamond’s Guns, Germs & Steel: the Fate of Human Societies
Jared Diamond’s Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Survive
E. E. Evans-Pritchard’s Witchcraft, Oracles and Magic Among the Azande
James Ferguson’s The Anti-Politics Machine
Clifford Geertz’s The Interpretation of Cultures
David Graeber’s Debt: the First 5000 Years
Karen Ho’s Liquidated: An Ethnography of Wall Street
Geert Hofstede’s Culture’s Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors,
Institutes and Organizations across Nations
Claude Lévi-Strauss’s Structural Anthropology
Jay Macleod’s Ain’t No Makin’ It: Aspirations and Attainment in a Low-
Income Neighborhood
Saba Mahmood’s The Politics of Piety: The Islamic Revival and the Feminist
Subject Marcel Mauss’s The Gift
BUSINESS
Jean Lave & Etienne Wenger’s Situated Learning
Theodore Levitt’s Marketing Myopia
Burton G. Malkiel’s A Random Walk Down Wall Street
Douglas McGregor’s The Human Side of Enterprise
Michael Porter’s Competitive Strategy: Creating and Sustaining Superior
Performance
John Kotter’s Leading Change
C. K. Prahalad & Gary Hamel’s The Core Competence of the Corporation
CRIMINOLOGY
Michelle Alexander’s The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of
Colorblindness
Michael R. Gottfredson & Travis Hirschi’s A General Theory of Crime
Richard Herrnstein & Charles A. Murray’s The Bell Curve: Intelligence and
Class Structure in American Life
Elizabeth Loftus’s Eyewitness Testimony
Jay Macleod’s Ain’t No Makin’ It: Aspirations and Attainment in a Low-
Income Neighborhood
Philip Zimbardo’s The Lucifer Effect
ECONOMICS
Janet Abu-Lughod’s Before European Hegemony
Ha-Joon Chang’s Kicking Away the Ladder
David Brion Davis’s The Problem of Slavery in the Age of Revolution
Milton Friedman’s The Role of Monetary Policy
Milton Friedman’s Capitalism and Freedom
David Graeber’s Debt: the First 5000 Years
Friedrich Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom
Karen Ho’s Liquidated: An Ethnography of Wall Street
John Maynard Keynes’s The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money
Charles P. Kindleberger’s Manias, Panics and Crashes
Robert Lucas’s Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?
Burton G. Malkiel’s A Random Walk Down Wall Street
Thomas Robert Malthus’s An Essay on the Principle of Population
Karl Marx’s Capital
Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century
Amartya Sen’s Development as Freedom
Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations
Nassim Nicholas Taleb’s The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly
Improbable
Amos Tversky’s & Daniel Kahneman’s Judgment under Uncertainty:
Heuristics and Biases
Mahbub Ul Haq’s Reflections on Human Development
Max Weber’s The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism
GEOGRAPHY
The Brundtland Report’s Our Common Future
Rachel Carson’s Silent Spring
Charles Darwin’s On the Origin of Species
James Ferguson’s The Anti-Politics Machine
Jane Jacobs’s The Death and Life of Great American Cities
James Lovelock’s Gaia: A New Look at Life on Earth
Amartya Sen’s Development as Freedom
Mathis Wackernagel & William Rees’s Our Ecological Footprint
HISTORY
Janet Abu-Lughod’s Before European Hegemony
Benedict Anderson’s Imagined Communities
Bernard Bailyn’s The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution
Hanna Batatu’s The Old Social Classes And The Revolutionary Movements
Of Iraq
Christopher Browning’s Ordinary Men: Reserve Police Batallion 101 and the
Final Solution in Poland
Edmund Burke’s Reflections on the Revolution in France
William Cronon’s Nature’s Metropolis: Chicago And The Great West
Alfred W. Crosby’s The Columbian Exchange
Hamid Dabashi’s Iran: A People Interrupted
David Brion Davis’s The Problem of Slavery in the Age of Revolution
Nathalie Zemon Davis’s The Return of Martin Guerre
Jared Diamond’s Guns, Germs & Steel: the Fate of Human Societies
Frank Dikotter’s Mao’s Great Famine
John W Dower’s War Without Mercy: Race And Power In The Pacific War
W. E. B. Du Bois’s The Souls of Black Folk
Richard J. Evans’s In Defence of History
Lucien Febvre’s The Problem of Unbelief in the 16th Century
Sheila Fitzpatrick’s Everyday Stalinism
Eric Foner’s Reconstruction: America’s Unfinished Revolution, 1863-1877
Michel Foucault’s Discipline and Punish
Michel Foucault’s History of Sexuality
Francis Fukuyama’s The End of History and the Last Man
John Lewis Gaddis’s We Now Know: Rethinking Cold War History
Ernest Gellner’s Nations and Nationalism
Eugene Genovese’s Roll, Jordan, Roll: The World the Slaves Made
Carlo Ginzburg’s The Night Battles
Daniel Goldhagen’s Hitler’s Willing Executioners
Jack Goldstone’s Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World
Antonio Gramsci’s The Prison Notebooks
Alexander Hamilton, John Jay & James Madison’s The Federalist Papers
Christopher Hill’s The World Turned Upside Down
Carole Hillenbrand’s The Crusades: Islamic Perspectives
Thomas Hobbes’s Leviathan
Eric Hobsbawm’s The Age Of Revolution
John A. Hobson’s Imperialism: A Study
Albert Hourani’s History of the Arab Peoples
Samuel P. Huntington’s The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of
World Order
C. L. R. James’s The Black Jacobins
Tony Judt’s Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945
Ernst Kantorowicz’s The King’s Two Bodies: A Study in Medieval Political
Theology
Paul Kennedy’s The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers
Ian Kershaw’s The “Hitler Myth”: Image and Reality in the Third Reich
John Maynard Keynes’s The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money
Charles P. Kindleberger’s Manias, Panics and Crashes
Martin Luther King Jr’s Why We Can’t Wait
Henry Kissinger’s World Order: Reflections on the Character of Nations and
the Course of History
Thomas Kuhn’s The Structure of Scientific Revolutions
Georges Lefebvre’s The Coming of the French Revolution
John Locke’s Two Treatises of Government
Niccolò Machiavelli’s The Prince
Thomas Robert Malthus’s An Essay on the Principle of Population
Mahmood Mamdani’s Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa And The
Legacy Of Late Colonialism
Karl Marx’s Capital
Stanley Milgram’s Obedience to Authority
John Stuart Mill’s On Liberty
Thomas Paine’s Common Sense
Thomas Paine’s Rights of Man
Geoffrey Parker’s Global Crisis: War, Climate Change and Catastrophe in
the Seventeenth Century
Jonathan Riley-Smith’s The First Crusade and the Idea of Crusading
Jean-Jacques Rousseau’s The Social Contract
Joan Wallach Scott’s Gender and the Politics of History
Theda Skocpol’s States and Social Revolutions
Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations
Timothy Snyder’s Bloodlands: Europe Between Hitler and Stalin
Sun Tzu’s The Art of War
Keith Thomas’s Religion and the Decline of Magic
Thucydides’s The History of the Peloponnesian War
Frederick Jackson Turner’s The Significance of the Frontier in American
History
Odd Arne Westad’s The Global Cold War: Third World Interventions And
The Making Of Our Times
LITERATURE
Chinua Achebe’s An Image of Africa: Racism in Conrad’s Heart of Darkness
Roland Barthes’s Mythologies
Homi K. Bhabha’s The Location of Culture
Judith Butler’s Gender Trouble
Simone De Beauvoir’s The Second Sex
Ferdinand De Saussure’s Course in General Linguistics
T. S. Eliot’s The Sacred Wood: Essays on Poetry and Criticism
Zora Neale Huston’s Characteristics of Negro Expression
Toni Morrison’s Playing in the Dark: Whiteness in the American Literary
Imagination
Edward Said’s Orientalism
Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak’s Can the Subaltern Speak?
Mary Wollstonecraft’s A Vindication of the Rights of Women
Virginia Woolf’s A Room of One’s Own
PHILOSOPHY
Elizabeth Anscombe’s Modern Moral Philosophy
Hannah Arendt’s The Human Condition
Aristotle’s Metaphysics
Aristotle’s Nicomachean Ethics
Edmund Gettier’s Is Justified True Belief Knowledge?
Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel’s Phenomenology of Spirit
David Hume’s Dialogues Concerning Natural Religion
David Hume’s The Enquiry for Human Understanding
Immanuel Kant’s Religion within the Boundaries of Mere Reason
Immanuel Kant’s Critique of Pure Reason
Søren Kierkegaard’s The Sickness Unto Death
Søren Kierkegaard’s Fear and Trembling
C. S. Lewis’s The Abolition of Man
Alasdair MacIntyre’s After Virtue
Marcus Aurelius’s Meditations
Friedrich Nietzsche’s On the Genealogy of Morality
Friedrich Nietzsche’s Beyond Good and Evil
Plato’s Republic
Plato’s Symposium
Jean-Jacques Rousseau’s The Social Contract
Gilbert Ryle’s The Concept of Mind
Baruch Spinoza’s Ethics
Sun Tzu’s The Art of War
Ludwig Wittgenstein’s Philosophical Investigations
POLITICS
Benedict Anderson’s Imagined Communities
Aristotle’s Politics
Bernard Bailyn’s The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution
Edmund Burke’s Reflections on the Revolution in France
John C. Calhoun’s A Disquisition on Government
Ha-Joon Chang’s Kicking Away the Ladder
Hamid Dabashi’s Iran: A People Interrupted
Hamid Dabashi’s Theology of Discontent: The Ideological Foundation of the
Islamic Revolution in Iran
Robert Dahl’s Democracy and its Critics
Robert Dahl’s Who Governs?
David Brion Davis’s The Problem of Slavery in the Age of Revolution
Alexis De Tocqueville’s Democracy in America
James Ferguson’s The Anti-Politics Machine
Frank Dikotter’s Mao’s Great Famine
Sheila Fitzpatrick’s Everyday Stalinism
Eric Foner’s Reconstruction: America’s Unfinished Revolution, 1863-1877
Milton Friedman’s Capitalism and Freedom
Francis Fukuyama’s The End of History and the Last Man
John Lewis Gaddis’s We Now Know: Rethinking Cold War History
Ernest Gellner’s Nations and Nationalism
David Graeber’s Debt: the First 5000 Years
Antonio Gramsci’s The Prison Notebooks
Alexander Hamilton, John Jay & James Madison’s The Federalist Papers
Friedrich Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom
Christopher Hill’s The World Turned Upside Down
Thomas Hobbes’s Leviathan
John A. Hobson’s Imperialism: A Study
Samuel P. Huntington’s The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of
World Order
Tony Judt’s Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945
David C. Kang’s China Rising: Peace, Power and Order in East Asia
Paul Kennedy’s The Rise and Fall of Great Powers
Robert Keohane’s After Hegemony
Martin Luther King Jr.’s Why We Can’t Wait
Henry Kissinger’s World Order: Reflections on the Character of Nations and
the Course of History
John Locke’s Two Treatises of Government
Niccolò Machiavelli’s The Prince
Thomas Robert Malthus’s An Essay on the Principle of Population
Mahmood Mamdani’s Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa And The
Legacy Of Late Colonialism
Karl Marx’s Capital
John Stuart Mill’s On Liberty
John Stuart Mill’s Utilitarianism
Hans Morgenthau’s Politics Among Nations
Thomas Paine’s Common Sense
Thomas Paine’s Rights of Man
Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century
Robert D. Putman’s Bowling Alone
John Rawls’s Theory of Justice
Jean-Jacques Rousseau’s The Social Contract
Theda Skocpol’s States and Social Revolutions
Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations
Sun Tzu’s The Art of War
Henry David Thoreau’s Civil Disobedience
Thucydides’s The History of the Peloponnesian War
Kenneth Waltz’s Theory of International Politics
Max Weber’s Politics as a Vocation
Odd Arne Westad’s The Global Cold War: Third World Interventions And
The Making Of Our Times
POSTCOLONIAL STUDIES
Roland Barthes’s Mythologies
Frantz Fanon’s Black Skin, White Masks
Homi K. Bhabha’s The Location of Culture
Gustavo Gutiérrez’s A Theology of Liberation
Edward Said’s Orientalism
Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak’s Can the Subaltern Speak?
PSYCHOLOGY
Gordon Allport’s The Nature of Prejudice
Alan Baddeley & Graham Hitch’s Aggression: A Social Learning Analysis
Albert Bandura’s Aggression: A Social Learning Analysis
Leon Festinger’s A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance
Sigmund Freud’s The Interpretation of Dreams
Betty Friedan’s The Feminine Mystique
Michael R. Gottfredson & Travis Hirschi’s A General Theory of Crime
Eric Hoffer’s The True Believer: Thoughts on the Nature of Mass Movements
William James’s Principles of Psychology
Elizabeth Loftus’s Eyewitness Testimony
A. H. Maslow’s A Theory of Human Motivation
Stanley Milgram’s Obedience to Authority
Steven Pinker’s The Better Angels of Our Nature
Oliver Sacks’s The Man Who Mistook His Wife For a Hat
Richard Thaler & Cass Sunstein’s Nudge: Improving Decisions About
Health, Wealth and Happiness
Amos Tversky’s Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases
Philip Zimbardo’s The Lucifer Effect
SCIENCE
Rachel Carson’s Silent Spring
William Cronon’s Nature’s Metropolis: Chicago And The Great West
Alfred W. Crosby’s The Columbian Exchange
Charles Darwin’s On the Origin of Species
Richard Dawkin’s The Selfish Gene
Thomas Kuhn’s The Structure of Scientific Revolutions
Geoffrey Parker’s Global Crisis: War, Climate Change and Catastrophe in
the Seventeenth Century
Mathis Wackernagel & William Rees’s Our Ecological Footprint
SOCIOLOGY
Michelle Alexander’s The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of
Colorblindness
Gordon Allport’s The Nature of Prejudice
Albert Bandura’s Aggression: A Social Learning Analysis
Hanna Batatu’s The Old Social Classes And The Revolutionary Movements
Of Iraq
Ha-Joon Chang’s Kicking Away the Ladder
W. E. B. Du Bois’s The Souls of Black Folk
Émile Durkheim’s On Suicide
Frantz Fanon’s Black Skin, White Masks
Frantz Fanon’s The Wretched of the Earth
Eric Foner’s Reconstruction: America’s Unfinished Revolution, 1863-1877
Eugene Genovese’s Roll, Jordan, Roll: The World the Slaves Made
Jack Goldstone’s Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World
Antonio Gramsci’s The Prison Notebooks
Richard Herrnstein & Charles A Murray’s The Bell Curve: Intelligence and
Class Structure in American Life
Eric Hoffer’s The True Believer: Thoughts on the Nature of Mass Movements
Jane Jacobs’s The Death and Life of Great American Cities
Robert Lucas’s Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?
Jay Macleod’s Ain’t No Makin’ It: Aspirations and Attainment in a Low
Income Neighborhood
Elaine May’s Homeward Bound: American Families in the Cold War Era
Douglas McGregor’s The Human Side of Enterprise
C. Wright Mills’s The Sociological Imagination
Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century
Robert D. Putman’s Bowling Alone
David Riesman’s The Lonely Crowd: A Study of the Changing American
Character
Edward Said’s Orientalism
Joan Wallach Scott’s Gender and the Politics of History
Theda Skocpol’s States and Social Revolutions
Max Weber’s The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism
THEOLOGY
Augustine’s Confessions
Benedict’s Rule of St Benedict
Gustavo Gutiérrez’s A Theology of Liberation
Carole Hillenbrand’s The Crusades: Islamic Perspectives
David Hume’s Dialogues Concerning Natural Religion
Immanuel Kant’s Religion within the Boundaries of Mere Reason
Ernst Kantorowicz’s The King’s Two Bodies: A Study in Medieval Political
Theology
Søren Kierkegaard’s The Sickness Unto Death
C. S. Lewis’s The Abolition of Man
Saba Mahmood’s The Politics of Piety: The Islamic Revival and the Feminist
Subject Baruch Spinoza’s Ethics
Keith Thomas’s Religion and the Decline of Magic
COMING SOON
Chris Argyris’s The Individual and the Organisation
Seyla Benhabib’s The Rights of Others
Walter Benjamin’s The Work Of Art in the Age of Mechanical Reproduction
John Berger’s Ways of Seeing
Pierre Bourdieu’s Outline of a Theory of Practice
Mary Douglas’s Purity and Danger
Roland Dworkin’s Taking Rights Seriously
James G. March’s Exploration and Exploitation in Organisational Learning
Ikujiro Nonaka’s A Dynamic Theory of Organizational Knowledge Creation
Griselda Pollock’s Vision and Difference
Amartya Sen’s Inequality Re-Examined
Susan Sontag’s On Photography
Yasser Tabbaa’s The Transformation of Islamic Art
Ludwig von Mises’s Theory of Money and Credit