DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH AND Inherit
DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH AND Inherit
DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH AND Inherit
INHERITANCE TAX
IUDEM
Documento de Trabajo 2001-1
Año 2001
ABSTRACT
The full text of this paper may be downloaded (in PDF format) from
the IUDEM´s World-Wide Web site at http://www. ucm.es/info/iudem.
RESUMEN
Este trabajo pone de relieve la inconsistencia que existe entre dos obje-
tivos básicos del impuesto-por una parte, existen limitaciones en la herencia
cuando el heredero dispone de un patrimonio excesivamente elevado y, por
otra, hay un incentivo a que la propiedad permanezca en la familia. Si el
último es el objetivo principal, debería claramente olvidarse el primero. Si
el objetivo principal es la redistribución de riqueza, no debería favorecerse a
los parientes más cercanos o a las empresas familiares.
JEL: H2, D1
There is a third reason for setting aside capital: the desire to transfer it
to one’s descendants after death. Alfred Marshall, for example, considered
that the greatest motivation for a person to work and save was precisely this
desire to leave assets to his children and that, if this possibility did not exist,
people would buy a lifelong income with their capital and would work and
save less1. This argument means that the members of one generation act in
an altruistic way with respect to the members of the following generation
because in their own utility functions they are using the utility function of
their descendants as their argument. In this case, the process of maximising
the utility function will not be limited by the life of the testator but the latter
will obtain maximum satisfaction from using his assets both for his own
consumption and for leaving an inheritance for his descendants.
2
cial need.3 Today, however, things have changed and the returns from in-
heritance tax are very small, both in absolute terms and in terms of the per-
centage of total tax revenue.
The current situation for the OECD countries is given in Table 2. This
shows that, except for Japan and Greece, none of the member States of the
OECD receives even one per cent of its tax revenue from this tax.
––––––––––––––
3
In addition to the English example mentioned above, in the United States a federal tax
was created in 1864 on inheritances as an exceptional measure to finance the Civil War. This
was done again in 1898 for the war against Spain and in 1916 when the US entered the Euro-
pean War. France, Germany and Italy also raised inheritance taxation sharply during the post-
war years.
3
TABLE Nº 2. Percentage of revenue from inheritance and gift taxes
over total tax revenue in OECD countries (1992)
Australia 0.00
Austria 0.18
Belgium 0.74
Canada 0.00
Denmark 0.56
Finland 0.46
France 0.93
Germany 0.25
Greece 1.04
Iceland 0.22
Ireland 0.30
Italy 0.14
Japan 2.01
Luxembourg 0.32
Netherlands 0.53
New Zealand 0.29
Norway 0.19
Portugal 0.25
Spain 0.42
Sweden 0.17
Switzerland 0.85
Turkey 0.11
UK 0.58
US 0.91
Non-weighted average
EEC 0.50
OECD (Europe) 0.42
OECD (Total) 0.48
4
Communities are acknowledged as having legislative authority, there are
certain limits and the structure of the rate set up by each region must be
scaled in a similar way to the State tax and must be the same as the latter in
the amount of the first tranche of the tax base and the minimum marginal
rate.
Obviously, the fact that a tax does not bring in a large revenue is no
reason why it should not be established. What is more relevant is its differ-
ential tax incidence measured as the costs for the society of collection by
the State of a certain amount of resources through inheritance tax in
comparison with the costs of collecting the same amount of money through
other taxes, such as income or sales tax. The theoretical analysis of the
income and substitution effects of this tax is well known and does not need
to be repeated here. It is also a fact that there is no consensus amongst the
specialists over how to quantify the effects of these taxes on the rate of
saving. However, there are important empirical studies which establish a
close link between the accumulation of capital and the possibility of this
capital being inherited by descendants. Basically, it is not necessary to ac-
cept the well-known figures drawn up Kotlikoff and Summers4 - whereby as
much as two-thirds of capital accumulation is due to inheritances – to real-
ise that this tax may have a high cost in terms of efficiency. Moreover, there
is no agreement on the idea that revenue from this tax has a low social cost,
because the tax is levied on resources which have been received at no cost
at all, not earned as a result of personal effort. And since the cost of collec-
tion in comparison with the actual fiscal revenue is rather high, clearly other
reasons must be found to explain why this tax still exists in most countries.
5
tion and on buying up power. Reduction of inequality of wealth is usually
presented as an important objective because the data show that wealth is
distributed in all countries in a less equal way than income.6 And it is
thought that this distribution might distort competition based on the talent
and hard work of the individual.
However, there are also arguments against this idea that marriage is a
determining factor in the concentration of wealth. Firstly, the family is not
only a consumer unit but also a production unit. This means that the choice
of partner will take into account the comparative advantage of each member
of the couple and the complementarity of their respective types of human
capital. The choice of partner may therefore be based more on differences
than similarities. According to the principle of hypergamy, a husband with a
high level of human capital or wealth is likely to look for a wife who will
basically be responsible for care of the home and who, therefore, will be of
a lower social rank than his own.
If we accept the possibility that the benefits of marriage are not shared
out on an equal basis but that, provided the position of each of the spouses
will be better than before marriage, it might be that each spouse will at-
tempt to maximise not the total utility of the couple but personal individual
––––––––––––––
6
Note that calculations of the distribution of wealth are often seriously flawed by meth-
odological errors because they do not usually consider as wealth the updated value of the flows
of returns from retirement pensions, especially in the case of public pension schemes.
7
G.S. BECKER (1993). Chapter 4.
6
utility by marrying a person who has less desirable characteristics. This
would allow him or her to maintain a dominant position in the marriage,
with his or her individual utility being higher than that which would result
from higher combined utility shared out in a more equal way. From our
point of view, the effect of such a strategy would be a reduction in the ac-
cumulation of family wealth over a number of generations.
Other factors also affect the accumulation of wealth. Some of these are
related to inheritance but they are distributed in a more random way than
the estate amongst the members of a specific generation. These are factors
such as intelligence or diligence which are not inherited from parents in the
same proportion as wealth so may increase or decrease inequality in the
distribution of wealth. Fertility is another important factor which may sub-
stantially reduce the accumulation of wealth because the more children a
couple has, the smaller the concentration of wealth in the following genera-
tion will be. The influence of this variable, however, is affected by the in-
heritance law which is in force in the country and at the time.
The structure of tax rates, which gives beneficial treatment to the closest
family members, creates incentives for the inheritance to remain within the
7
family. This principle has always been present in inheritance taxation which
often exempts the direct heirs and the spouse from any payment at all.
The privileged treatment which fiscal law gives the closest family
members is really only another aspect of the favourable attitude shown
towards the family in almost all inheritance legislation which is undoubt-
edly based on consideration of the family as something more than just a
group of related persons that establish agreements involving the provision
of services in line with the general principle of freedom of contract. It can
even be affirmed that some of the characteristic institutions of family law in
some countries are based on the existence of a certain type of community of
assets within the family which not only affects the two or three generations
that usually live together but reaches into the past and towards the future to
include previous and subsequent generations. According to this traditional
vision of the family, the person who at a specific time owns property - most
of which has probably been received in the form of inheritance - does not
own it in the full sense of the term but rather just holds and administers the
family property and must eventually pass it on to the following generation.
The case of entailed estates governed by the right of primogeniture in which
the majority of the family property - especially real estate - is inherited by
the eldest child to prevent it from being split up is probably the most sig-
nificant example. But it is not the only case. More important is at the pre-
sent time the legitimate share system –namely the obligation to set aside
part of the state for the heirs by necessity of the deceased person with the
testator being entitled to freely dispose of another part of it- that is the rule
in the civil law of the majority of the European countries
The great social changes that have taken place in western society in re-
cent decades have resulted in the disappearance of many of the characteris-
tic institutions of the traditional family. But law in some countries still gov-
erns inheritance as if the family community were more important than it
really is. The legitimate share can be understood as an attempt to equalise
the position of the children who had previously been treated in a discrimina-
tory fashion by favouring the first-born. But the idea behind such systems is
still the existence of a family community within which the property must
necessarily be transmitted. However, traditional families also imposed du-
ties and patterns of behaviour. One of these and perhaps the most important
was the acceptance by the family members of a hierarchical structure
headed by the old patriarch who administered the property. Today this hier-
archical structure has disappeared because it is incompatible with a modern
economy and modern society. And in most cases the different generations
8
do not even live under the same roof. The elderly have lost their authority
within the family but, surprisingly, they have not lost their obligation to
leave most of the property to their children over whom they no longer have
any authority.
Fiscal laws have reinforced this favourable treatment for close family
members. The data given below refer to Spain but are fairly indicative of
the general situation. In Spain, most inheritances have remained within the
family as a result of testators’ wills, the law and the structure of tax rates.
Table 3 shows 5-yearly averages for the destination of inheritances amongst
heirs apparent (mostly children) or other heirs for both the tax base and the
revenue got by the State.
Source: Drawn up by the authors based on data from the Spanish Insti-
tute for Fiscal Research.
9
This historical series shows that the largest volume of estates transmit-
ted that was subject to this tax was amongst heirs by necessity in a ratio of 4
to 1 to those transmitted to other heirs. However, because of the different
rates based on the degree of relationship with the deceased person, the
amounts collected are almost equal for the two types of heir. The amount
transmitted to heirs by necessity is between 78 and 81 per cent of the total
inheritance before 1945; and since 1945 there has been an even greater
accumulation in favour of the closest family relations.
It is normal for the testator to obtain greater utility if the estate is left to
the closest family members and anyway civil and fiscal regulations give
greater incentives for this type of behaviour. The person would have to
make an additional effort to save if he or she planned to pass the inheritance
outside the close family circle and this would result in a reduction of the
amounts transmitted to people outside the family. These incentives have a
double effect on efficiency and distribution. With regard to efficiency, privi-
leges for the closest family members have a negative effect in that they limit
property rights by restricting the capacity of a specific person to negotiate
with third parties to receive care in exchange for a future inheritance. But
they may also have a positive effect by restricting inefficient rent-seeking
behaviour by possible heirs.8 The effects on distribution are clear in that
such regulations tend to concentrate wealth among the deceased’s direct
descendants.
10
pay a 5 per cent supplement if their estate before the inheritance was in
excess of 385,000 Euros; 10 per cent if it was in excess of 1,900,000 Euros,
and 20 per cent if it was in excess of 3,873,000 Euros. This is commonly
known as “the prodigal son clause”. It has been much criticised because it
discriminates amongst heirs and penalises saving. It means that if there are
two direct heirs who have started out in life with equal opportunities, the
heir who has saved is penalised in favour of the heir who has consumed his
rent. This is clearly inefficient but, if the main aim is to achieve greater
distribution of wealth, we have to accept that it is reasonable to penalise the
heirs having a larger initial estate.
Let us take the example of Spain once again, this being a country in
which family firms receive very favourable treatment, although this is a
result that certain pro-family firm lobbies might reject. In the case of a firm
being passed on through inheritance, for the purpose of inheritance tax the
value of the firm is reduced by 95 per cent, provided that the heirs are
spouses, descendants or adopted descendants and provided that the heirs
undertake to maintain the firm or their shares for ten years. These advan-
tages go together with especially favourable treatment in wealth tax
whereby the goods and rights of the persons who are necessary for carrying
out the social or professional activity are exempted from taxation, provided
that the activity is carried out habitually, personally and directly by the
person in question and is his or her main source of income. This is an im-
portant exemption considering that, although wealth tax has fairly low rates,
it is a progressive tax.
11
and large firms and eliminating many of the problems of discrimination in
favour of large estates. There are also special regulations that are applied
only to companies having specific characteristics or being in specific sectors
such as farms when inheritance law is sometimes adapted to allow one of
the heirs to receive the whole of the business even if this goes against the
system of the legitimate share. Or more simply, payment of inheritance tax
may be deferred so that payment can be made out of returns from the busi-
ness over time rather than from the sale of the firm’s assets.
The idea behind these tax benefits is, as stated above, to help family
businesses to survive. It has been shown in estimates carried out in a num-
ber of countries that the death of the entrepreneur places the business at risk.
In France, for example, it is calculated that 10 per cent of business shut-
downs are the result of inheritance problems and, over the next decade, the
death of 60,000 family entrepreneurs will lead to the loss of one million
jobs. In Spain it has been estimated that only one third of family firms sur-
vives into the second generation, and the figure is 15 per cent in the third
generation.10
12
the firm and anyway involve discriminatory treatment of the heirs, possibly
favouring people who already have a large estate.
5. CONCLUSIONS
Several factors are taken into account in this argument. Firstly, the idea
that it is good for a fiscal system to achieve more equal distribution of
wealth is a value judgement which is accepted by many but rejected by
many others. Even if we accept this as a desirable objective, it is not clear
that inheritance tax is the best possible method of achieving it. Although
there are no reliable figures, there is a widespread feeling that the degree of
tax evasion in this connection is directly related to the size of the inheri-
tance in question. There are two reasons for this. Firstly, incentives for tax
evasion increase the greater the estate to be inherited and, secondly, the
possibility of concealing assets from the tax office are greater for larger
estates. For most people, the home is the main asset and real estate is the
part of the assets which is easiest for the State to tax. But if the estate is
made up of financial assets in an international scenario of free movement of
capital, fiscal pressure is more limited.11
13
main aim is redistribution of wealth, then the closest family members or
family firms should not be favoured.
REFERENCES
SMITH, A. (1776) An inquiry into nature and causes of the Wealth of Na-
tions.
14
IUDEM
DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO PUBLICADOS
15
DT 2OO1-1 DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH AND INHERITANCE
TAX, Carmen González de Aguilar y Francisco Cabrillo
16