Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Female Household Headship

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 71

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/30520834

Female Household Headship and the Feminisation of Poverty: Facts, Fictions


and Forward Strategies

Article · January 2003


Source: OAI

CITATIONS READS

110 866

1 author:

Sylvia Chant
The London School of Economics and Political Science
185 PUBLICATIONS   4,037 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

London School of Economics research View project

Radical Policies in Gender and Development View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Sylvia Chant on 01 October 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


LSE Research Online
Working paper

Sylvia H. Chant

Female household headship and the feminisation of


poverty : facts, fictions and forward strategies

Originally produced for the Gender Institute, London School of


Economics and Political Science © 2003 Sylvia Chant.

You may cite this version as:


Chant, Sylvia H. (2003). Female household headship and the
feminisation of poverty : facts, fictions and forward strategies [online].
London: LSE Research Online.
Available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/archive/00000574
Available online: January 2006

LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of
the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the
individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print
one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for
non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or
use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute
the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website.

http://eprints.lse.ac.uk
Contact LSE Research Online at: Library.Researchonline@lse.ac.uk
Female Household Headship and the
Feminisation of Poverty: Facts, Fictions
and Forward Strategies

Sylvia Chant
Issue 9, May 2003

New Working Paper Series

1
London School of Economics, Gender Institute ISSN No:1470-8515
New Working Paper Series

Editor:Gail Wilson (g.wilson@lse.ac.uk)


Issue 9, May 2003

This new working paper series is designed to bring new ideas and new findings in the field of
gender studies into the public arena. The author/s welcome comments.

Sylvia Chant is Professor of Development Geography at LSE. She has carried out research in
Mexico, Costa Rica, the Philippines, and has published widely on gender and development.
Specific themes include migration, poverty, employment, household livelihood strategies, lone
parenthood, and men and masculinities. Professor Chant’s recent books include Women-
headed Households: Diversity and Dynamics in the Developing World (Macmillan, 1997),
Three Generations, Two Genders, One World: Women and Men in a Changing Century
(with Cathy McIlwaine) (Zed, 1998), Mainstreaming Men into Gender and Development:
Debates, Reflections and Experiences (with Matthew Gutmann) (Oxfam, 2000), and Gender
in Latin America (in association with Nikki Craske) (Latin America Bureau/Rutgers University
Press, 2003). Professor Chant has recently embarked on new collaborative research with Dr
Gareth A. Jones (Department of Geography and Environment, LSE) on youth, gender and
livelihoods in sub-Saharan Africa (Ghana and The Gambia), and between 2003 and 2006, will
be exploring gendered and generational aspects of poverty in Africa, Asia and Latin America
under the auspices of a Leverhulme Trust Major Research Fellowship. (s.chant@lse.ac.uk)

The Gender Institute was established by the London School of Economics in 1993 to address
the major intellectual challenges posed by contemporary changes in gender relations. The
Director is Professor Anne Phillips.

The research work of the Institute is informed by the belief that all social processes are
‘gendered’, and that understanding gender relations is therefore a crucial component in any
social science research. Some of the projects undertaken at the Institute focus directly on the
position of girls and women, the contemporary character of gender relations, and the
formation of sexual identities. Others employ a gendered perspective to address issues not
normally considered as gender concerns. The focus of the research projects ranges across
local, national and international contexts, and the relationship between gender and ethnicity
has become an increasingly prominent concern.

Research work falls broadly into the following categories:


• Gender and the media, especially representation of women and men; popular radio;
gender and technology; masculinities.

• Gender, sexuality and space; feminist theories of knowledge; historiography and the
recent feminist past.

• Feminist political theory; normative political theory; democracy, political representation,


especially representation of gender, ethnicity and race; multiculturalism.
Applications from those wishing to study for a PhD degree are welcome within the research
initiatives outlined above. In addition, the Institute runs five Masters programme in Gender,1)
Gender Relations (2) Gender and Development, (3) Gender and Social Policy, (4) Gender and
the Media and (5) Gender (Research). From October 2004 Gender & Development will
discontinue but we will be offering a new degree from then entitled Gender, Development &
Globalisation.

For further information on the LSE:Gender Institute and its research and teaching programmes
contact Hazel Johnstone on tel 0207 955 7602, fax 0207 955 6408, email
h.johnstone@lse.ac.uk http://www.lse.ac.uk/depts/gender/
postal address: Houghton Street London WC2A 2AE

2
FEMALE HOUSEHOLD HEADSHIP AND
THE FEMINISATION OF POVERTY:
FACTS, FICTIONS AND
FORWARD STRATEGIES

Sylvia Chant

3
ABSTRACT
This paper interrogates the common assumption that a large part
of the so-called ‘feminisation of poverty’ in recent decades is due
to the progressive ‘feminisation of household headship’. Its
specific aims are three-fold. The first is to summarise how and
why women-headed households have come to be widely equated
with the ‘poorest of the poor’ in development discourse. The
second is to trace the evolution of challenges to this stereotype
from a growing and increasingly diverse body of macro- and micro-
level research. The third is to explore some of the implications and
outcomes of competing constructions of female household
headship, especially in relation to policy. At one end of the
spectrum, what kinds of attitudes and actions flow out of the
mantra that female-headed households are the ‘poorest of the
poor’? At the other extreme, what happens when the links
between the ‘feminisation of poverty’ and the ‘feminisation of
household headship’ are disrupted? In particular, I am concerned
to reflect on the potential consequences of acknowledging that the
epithet ‘women-headed households are the poorest of the poor’
may be more ‘fable’ than ‘fact’.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
Thanks are due to Sarah Bradshaw, Monica Budowksi, Andrea
Cornwall, Hazel Johnstone, Brian Linneker, María del Carmen
Feijoó, Cathy McIlwaine, Maxine Molyneux, Silvia Posocco and
Ramya Subrahmanian for their helpful advice and comments.

4
FEMALE HOUSEHOLD HEADSHIP AND THE
FEMINISATION OF POVERTY: FACTS, FICTIONS AND
FORWARD STRATEGIES 1

INTRODUCTION
The idea that women bear a disproportionate and growing burden
of poverty at a global scale, often encapsulated in the concept of a
‘feminisation of poverty’, has become a virtual orthodoxy in recent
decades. The dearth of reliable and/or consistent data on poverty,
let alone its gender dimensions, should undoubtedly preclude
inferences of any quantitative precision (Marcoux, 1997;
Moghadam, 1997:3). Yet this has not dissuaded a large segment
of the development community, including international agencies,
from asserting that 60-70% of the world’s poor are female, and that
tendencies to greater poverty among women are deepening (see
for example, UNDP, 1995:4; UN, 1996:6; UNIFEM, 1995:4 cited in
Marcoux, 1997; also ADB, 2000:16).

The factors responsible for the ‘feminisation of poverty’ have been


linked variously with gender disparities in rights, entitlements and
capabilities, the gender-differentiated impacts of neo-liberal
restructuring, the informalisation and feminisation of labour, and
the erosion of kin-based support networks through migration,
conflict and so on. One of the primary tenets, however, has been
the mounting incidence of female household headship (see
BRIDGE, 2001; Budowski et al, 2002; Chant, 1997a, 2001;
Marcoux, 1997; Moghadam, 1997).2 Indeed, Davids and van Driel
(2001:162) go as far as to say that: ‘...the feminisation of poverty
focuses on female-headed households as an expression of that
same feminisation of poverty’. In turn, because lone mothers are

1
often the biggest sub-group of female heads3, whose poverty is
attested not only to affect them, but their children too (see below),
it is no surprise that in some circles the ‘culture of single
motherhood’ has been designated the ‘New Poverty Paradigm’
(see Thomas, 1994, cited in Budowski et al, 2002:31).

Contemporary reflection of this thinking can be seen in a recent


internet circular distributed by the Coordination for Productive
Development for Women of FONAES, a subsidiary decentralised
body of the Mexican Ministry of the Economy. Referring to a
census-based graph of marriage and divorce statistics for 1990
and 2000, the opening statement of the communication reads:

‘At the present time, we are experiencing a phenomenon


known as the “feminisation of poverty”, which has been
accentuated, amongst other things, by the increase in
separation and divorce. Added to the tradition of leaving
responsibilities for children to the mother, this situation has
given rise to an increasing incidence of lone parent
families headed by women whose vulnerability, for all their
members, is elevated’ (my translation) (see also Appendix,
Box 1).4

The links so frequently drawn between the feminisation of poverty


and household headship derive first, from the idea that women-
headed households constitute a disproportionate number of the
poor, and second, that they experience greater extremes of poverty
than male-headed units (see BRIDGE, 2001:1; Buvinic and
Gupta,1993; González de la Rocha, 1994b:6-7; Moghadam,1997;
Paolisso and Gammage,1996:23-5). An additional element,
summed up in the concept of an ‘intergenerational transmission of
disadvantage’ is that the privation of female household heads is

2
passed on to their children (see Chant, 1997b,1999). As asserted
by Mehra et al (2000:7), poverty is prone to be inter-generationally
perpetuated because female heads cannot ‘properly support their
families or ensure their well-being’ (see also ILO, 1996).

In broader work on poverty, and especially in policy circles, the


poverty of female-headed households has effectively become a
proxy for women’s poverty, if not poverty in general (see Jackson,
1996, 1998; Kabeer, 1996, 2003:81; also May, 2001:50). In fact,
the twinning of the ‘feminisation of poverty’ with the ‘feminisation of
household headship’ has become so routinised in policy discourse
that interrogating whether or not any intrinsic interrelationship
actually exists seems to have become secondary to doing
something about the ‘problem’. If women-headed households are
the ‘poorest of the poor’, then attention needs to be directed to
alleviating their condition. In its most immediate form this may
involve palliative interventions such as the provision of assistance
to affected parties with child-feeding, day care, access to credit,
skills-training, or shelter (see for example, Bibars, 2001:81 et seq;
Chant, 1997a; Grosh, 1994: Lewis, 1993; Safa, 1995:84). At its
logical extreme, however, more strategic, preventive, measures
may entail strengthening the ‘traditional’ (male-headed) family
within society as a means of arresting the process by which
women’s vulnerability to poverty (and that of their children), is
aggravated by ‘deviant’ or ‘unfortunate’ domestic circumstances.
Indeed, despite numerous calls on the part of feminist activists,
academics and others to acknowledge historical and contemporary
diversity in household structures, female-headed households,
especially lone mother units, are typically regarded as symptomatic

3
of ‘family breakdown’ (Chant, 2002). Even if ‘alternative’ family
patterns are tolerated, the heterosexual male-headed household,
preferably based on formal marriage, persists as a normative ideal
in most parts of the world (see Chant, 1999; Stacey,1997; Ypeij
and Steenbeek, 2001). Grounded largely in the notion that dual
(‘natural’/biological) parenthood not only offers the best prospects
of social, moral and psychological well-being for children, but
material security, this is of particular relevance when considering
contemporary attempts to re-draw the boundaries between the
market, state and citizens in the interests of paring down public
welfare provision (see Moore, 1994; also Molyneux, 2002).

Yet despite repeated emphasis on the links between female


headship and poverty, a growing body of literature based on
macro-level data, as well as micro-social research, has challenged
the construction that women-headed households are the ‘poorest
of the poor’. This, however, throws up new dilemmas, especially
given increased targeting within poverty alleviation and reduction
programmes, and the plausible need to maintain high visibility of
gender in the face of shrinking resources for development and/or
social assistance.

In an attempt to explore some of the tensions emanating from


growing equivocation over the links between female household
headship and poverty, the first section of this paper sets out the
principal reasons why women-headed households have
traditionally been regarded (and portrayed) as the ‘poorest of the
poor’. In section two, the discussion synthesises arguments and
evidence which have qualified and/or opposed this orthodoxy. The

4
third and final section focuses on social and policy implications.
After considering the dangers attached to blanket stereotyping of
women heads as the ‘poorest of the poor’, attention turns to
potential outcomes of surrendering a conventional wisdom which
has undoubtedly helped to harness resources for women. As part
of this analysis I evaluate the role of targeted interventions for
female-headed households in relation to other initiatives which
might more effectively address women’s poverty and better
accommodate diversity and dynamism in household arrangements.

HOW WOMEN-HEADED HOUSEHOLDS BECAME THE


‘POOREST OF THE POOR’: KEY RATIONALES

In the last 10-15 years, pronouncements about women-headed


households being the ‘poorest of the poor’ have proliferated in
writings on gender not only in developing regions, but at a global
scale (see for example Acosta-Belén and Bose, 1995:25; Bullock,
1994:17-18; Buvinic,1995:3; Buvinic and Gupta,1993;
Kennedy,1994; Tinker, 1990:5; UN, 2000; UNDAW,1991; also
Appendix, Box 1).

While such statements have often been been made without direct
reference to empirical data, the assumption that women-headed
households face an above-average risk of poverty (mainly
construed in terms of income, although other factors such as
health and nutritional status factors may enter the equation), is by
no means groundless. Indeed, there are several persuasive
reasons why we might expect a group disadvantaged by their
gender to be further disadvantaged by allegedly ‘incomplete’, or

5
‘under-resourced’, household arrangements (see Appendix, Box
2). This is especially so given the assumption that female
household headship is prone to arise in situations of economic
stress, privation and insecurity, whether through labour migration,
conjugal instability, and/or the inability of impoverished kin groups
to assume responsibility for abandoned women and children (see
Benería, 1991; Chant, 1997b; Chen and Drèze, 1992:22; Fonseca,
1991:138).

Extrapolating women’s disadvantage to women headed


households
Although rejecting the notion that female household headship
should automatically be classified as the ‘poorest of the poor’,
Moghadam’s (1997) extensive review of the ‘feminisation of
poverty’ identifies three main reasons which, prima facie, are likely
to make women poorer than men. These are first, women’s
disadvantage in respect of poverty-inducing entitlements and
capabilities; second, their heavier work burdens and lower
earnings, and third, constraints on socio-economic mobility due to
cultural, legal and labour market barriers (see also Kabeer, 2003).

In respect of the ways in which these factors may engender


particular disadvantage for women in female-headed households,
those pertaining to labour supply, employment and earnings have
claimed most attention, especially where headship and lone
motherhood coincide.

6
Labour supply, employment and earnings
Lone mother units are often assumed to be worse off than two-
parent households because, in lacking a ‘breadwinning’ partner
they are not only deprived of an adult male’s earnings, but have
relatively more dependents to support (see Fuwa, 2000:1535;
IFAD, 1999; ILO, 1996; McLanahan and Kelly, nd:6; Safa and
Antrobus, 1992:54; UNDAW,1991:38). On top of this, women’s
purported single-handed management of income-generation,
housework and childcare further compromises economic efficiency
and well-being. On one hand, female heads are conjectured to
have less time and energy to perform the full range of non-market
work so vital to income conservation in poor neighbourhoods, such
as shopping around for the cheapest foodstuffs, or self-
provisioning rather than purchasing market goods and services.
On the other hand, women’s ‘reproduction tax’ (Palmer, 1992) cuts
heavily into economic productivity, with lone mothers often
confined to part-time, flexible, and/or home-based occupations.
This is compounded by women’s disadvantage in respect of
education and training, their lower average earnings, gender
discrimination in the workplace, and the fact that social and labour
policies rarely provide more than minimal support for parenting
(see Dia, 2001; Elson, 1999; Finne, 2001; Kabeer, 2003; also
Christopher et al, 2001; England and Folbre, 2002; Folbre, 1994;
Rogers, 1995).

The difficulties of reconciling income-generation with childcare are,


of course, widely noted as applying to most mothers, and
constitute a major reason why a disproportionate share of women’s
employment in the South is in the informal sector (see Arriagada,

7
1998:91; Baden with Milward, 1997; Fuwa, 2000:1535; Kabeer,
2003: Chapter 3; Leach, 1999; Tinker, 1997, forthcoming; UN,
2000:122, Chart 5.13; also Rai, 2002:111-12). When considering
that poor female heads are much more commonly engaged in
informal activity than their male counterparts, and in the lower tiers
as well (see Bolles, 1986; Chant, 1991a; Brown, 2000; Merrick
and Schmink, 1983; Sethuraman, 1998), it is no surprise that
women-headed units are thought to be at an above-average risk of
poverty, especially in cases where households have only one
‘breadwinning’ adult. Indeed, not only are levels of remuneration
in general lower in the informal sector, but gender differentials are
wider. In Colombia, women’s average earnings are 86% of men’s
in the formal sector as against 74% in the informal sector (Tokman,
1989:1971). In Honduras, the respective levels are 83% and 53%
(López de Mazier, 1997: 263). For Central America as a whole,
the gender earnings gap in informal employment averages 25%
compared with 10% in formal occupations (Funkhouser,
1996:1746).

Given the common disadvantages of informal employment not only


in respect of earnings, but also in terms of fringe benefits, social
security coverage and pensions, the short- and long-term
implications for female heads of household are potentially serious.
It is also important to remember that women's conventionally
limited access to ‘physical capital assets’ (Rakodi, 1999) or ‘non-
labour resources’ (Kabeer, 2003:198), such as infrastructure, land
and property ownership, may exacerbate financial difficulty. For
example, since informal sector businesses are often based in or
from the home, female heads who have no option but to rent or

8
share accommodation may find their choice and scale of
entrepreneurial activities constrained by landlords (see
Chant,1996: Chapter 3).

Comparative disadvantage in labour supply and opportunities is


thought to be futher compounded in women-headed households
given their higher conjectured proportion of female vis-à-vis male
members (Marcoux, 1997; also Appendix, Box 2). Whether or not
this is actually the case, evidence from Vietnam, Bangladesh and
South Africa suggests that women’s lower average earnings
translate into a virtually ‘unequivocal’ risk of poverty in households
which have only female members (Kabeer, 2003:141). This said,
the question of how the ‘femaleness’ of the household is
constituted, for example, in terms of age and economic activity of
members, may well mediate gender-poverty linkages (see
Kusakabe, 2002:8 on Cambodia).

Limited support from external parties


Another important set of factors in the construction of women-
headed households as ‘poorest of the poor’ is that in most parts of
the South there is little or no compensation for earnings shortfalls
through ‘transfer payments’ from external parties such as the
State, or ‘absent fathers’. While some countries, as discussed in
greater detail later, have launched targeted initiatives to alleviate
the poverty of female-headed households, where these do exist,
they have rarely made an appreciable difference to household
incomes or assets (see Chant, 1997b, 2001).5 The same applies
in cases where female heads, along with other ‘vulnerable’ groups
such as the elderly, disabled or orphaned, receive benefits from

9
residual social programmes designed to cater to those excluded
from mainstream contributory aid and welfare schemes (see
Bibars, 2001:83 et seq on Egypt).

As Bibars (2001:86) further notes in relation to non-contributory


poverty alleviation programmes in Egypt, ‘The state has not
provided women with an institutional alternative to the male
provider’.6 This is significant more generally since in most
countries in the South there is scant enforcement of legal
stipulations pertaining to absent fathers. While in many places
legislation governing maintenance payments has now extended to
cover children from consensual unions as well as formal marriage,
in most instances, especially among the poor, levels of ‘paternal
responsibility’ are notoriously low and men are seldom penalised
for non-compliance (see Budowksi and Rosero-Bixby, 2003;
Chant, 1997a, 2001; Marenco et al, 1998:9). Recognising that
men’s incapacity to pay because they are un- or underemployed or
have limited earnings may be an important factor among low-
income groups, unwillingness to pay is often an additional element
(see Chant, 1997b, 2001). In Costa Rica, for example, men tend
to regard ‘family’ as applying only to the women and children with
whom they are currently residing or involved, and distance
themselves from the offspring of previous relationships (ibid; see
also Menjívar Ochoa, 2002:46)

Another reason offered to account for poverty among female-


headed households is that their social networks (and hence access
to social capital) may be smaller (see Appendix, Box 2). This is
sometimes attributed to the fact that female heads lack ties with

10
ex-partners’ relatives, or because they ‘keep themselves to
themselves’ in the face of hostility or mistrust on the part of their
own family networks or others in their communities (see Chant,
1997a; Lewis, 1993; Willis, 1994). Indeed lone mothers may
deliberately distance themselves from kin as a means of deflecting
the ‘shame’ or ‘dishonour’ attached to out-of-wedlock birth and/or
marriage failure, not to mention, in some instances, stigmatised
types of employment such as sex work (see Chant and McIlwaine,
1995:302; also Bibars, 2001:60-61). Added to this, some female
heads are unable to spare the time to actively cultivate social links
and/or may eschew seeking help from others because deficits in
material and other resources prevent ready reciprocation of
favours (Chant, 1997a:206; González de la Rocha, 1994a:211; see
also Chen and Drèze, 1992:23).7,8

As discussed in more detail later, we cannot necessarily assume


that women heads lack transfers from external parties (especially
non-resident children). Nor can we readily accept that women’s
general disadvantage as individuals translates directly to greater
disadvantage for female-headed households, or, indeed, that living
with men automatically mitigates women’s risks of poverty. None
the less, there are probably three main factors over and above
those already discussed which help to explain the frequently
unproblematised construction of women-headed households as
the ‘poorest of the poor’.

Historical dynamics
A first, and fairly plausible, reason owes to historical legacy insofar
as the term ‘feminisation of poverty’ originated in the United States

11
in the late 1970s, and was linked during this period to the fast-
rising numbers of households headed by low-income women and
their children, especially among the Afro-American community (see
Moghadam, 1997:6; also McLanahan and Kelly, nd for discussion
and references). While extrapolation of terminology and concepts
across space and time has been roundly criticised, especially by
feminists from the South, it would certainly not be the first occasion
that such a construction has ‘gone global’ (see for example,
Cornwall and Lindisfarne, 1994:12 et seq on ‘machismo’; Chant,
2002; Moore, 1994 on ‘family breakdown’). Once grafted into the
literature on development, repeated statements linking the
feminisation of poverty with the feminisation of household
headship, not least by international agencies, have undoubtedly
added cumulative legitimation (see Jackson, 1998; also Appendix,
Box 2).

Continued reliance on quantitative indicators of poverty


A second important factor in constructing women headed
households as ‘poorest of the poor’ derives from the continued
precedence of quantitative measures in poverty assessments, be
these in relation to incomes, expenditure or consumption.
Generally speaking, poverty analyses also continue to be
grounded in the ‘physical aspects of deprivation, rather than the
more intangible ones’ (Kabeer, 1994:161; see also Appendix, Box
2). Despite growing lip-service to the importance of ‘social
deprivation’ (rather than ‘physiological deprivation’), approaches to
poverty evaluation, which, via more holistic, participatory methods
take into account the ‘voices of the poor’ and nominally consider
(gendered) subjectivities, power relations and so on, the

12
development ‘mainstream’ seems to find it easier to fall back on
traditional (quantitative) formulae, especially for big, internationally
comparative estimates of poverty levels and trends (see, as an
example, World Bank, 2000, and for critiques, Razavi, 1999;
Whitehead and Lockwood, 1999). When considering that
aggregate household (rather than per capita) incomes, usually
based on earnings, are often taken as the benchmark for
measuring income poverty (see Kabeer, 2003:79-81), it is hardly
surprising that female-headed households show up as a
particularly vulnerable constituency, not least because of their
smaller average size (see Chant, 1997b; also Appendix, Box 2).

Political agendas
Third, and related to this, the fact that female-headed households
are a ‘visible and readily identifiable group in income poverty
statistics’ (Kabeer,1996:14), provides rich justification for a range
of political and economic agendas. In one respect, this serves
neo-liberal enthusiasm for the efficiency-driven targeting of poverty
reduction measures to ‘exceptionally’ disaffected parties, not
forgetting that considerations of efficiency (as opposed to equity),
seem to have powered the incorporation of gender into poverty
alleviation, welfare and savings and credit programmes more
generally (see Jackson, 1996:490; Kabeer, 1997:2; Molyneux,
2001:184; Pankhurst, 2002; Razavi, 1999:419; also World Bank,
1994, 2002). Yet in another vein, highlighting the disadvantage of
female-headed households has also served GAD interests insofar
as it has provided an apparently robust tactical peg on which to
hang justification for allocating resources to women (see Baden
and Goetz, 1998:23; Chant, 2001; Jackson, 1998).

13
However, despite the instrumental value of such a strategy, there
are numerous, less auspicious, corollaries. One is that resources
may be won for some women only at the expense of sidestepping
the needs of the majority (who are in male-headed households).
Another downside is that in targeting women without co-resident
partners, women are addressed in isolation, which, in line with one
of the main criticisms of WID approaches, fails to confront the
thorny (but arguably crucial) terrain of intra-household gender
relations (see Jackson, 1997:152). Another contentious outcome
of ‘poorest of the poor’ stereotyping, is that it can bolster neo-
conservative agendas for strengthening the ‘traditional’ family.
During an era in which advocacy for children’s rights is at an all
time high, emphasising the ‘inter-generational transmission of
disadvantage’ ascribed to female headship can all too easily be hi-
jacked by anti-feminist interests. This said, the idea that
something is better than nothing is undoubtedly a major reason
why many stakeholders, including those within the GAD arena,
have been reluctant to abandon a construction that provides a
plausibly hard case for intervention.

CHALLENGES TO THE CONSTRUCTION OF WOMEN-HEADED


HOUSEHOLDS AS THE ‘POOREST OF THE POOR’.

Despite the pervasive emphasis on female household headship in


exacerbating women’s poverty, and the idea that the mounting
‘feminisation of poverty’ can be attributed partially, if not
substantially, to rising female household headship, challenges to
the blanket stereotyping of women as ‘poorest of the poor’ have
gathered increasing momentum. These challenges have emerged
from a number of quarters, as itemised below.

14
Lack of ‘fit’ with quantitative data
Somewhat surprisingly perhaps, especially in light of the categorical
pronouncements issued by international agencies, one set of
qualifications about the poverty of female-headed households has
come from analyses of macro-level quantitative statistics. For
example, comparative inter-regional and/or international data
compiled by the World Bank and other mainstream sources such as
the Economic Commission for Latin America, the International
Fund for Agricultural Development, and the International Food
Policy Research Institute, fail to demonstrate with any consistency
that female household headship predicts an above average
probability of poverty (see CEPAL, 2001:20; IFAD, 1999;
Kennedy,1994:35-6; Moghadam, 1997:8; Quisumbing et al, 1995).
This is echoed in the findings of a number of sub-regional and
national studies (see Menjívar and Trejos, 1992 on Central America;
Fuwa, 2000 on Panama; Gafar, 1998 on Guyana; GOG, 2000 on
The Gambia; Kusakabe, 2002 on Cambodia; Wartenburg, 1999 on
Colombia). Moreover, there would not appear to be any consistent
relationship between levels of poverty at national or regional scales
and proportions of female heads, nor between trends in poverty and
in the incidence of female headship over time (see Chant, 2001;
Chant with Craske, 2003: Chapter 3; Varley, 1996: Table 2). In
Latin America, for example, upward trends in female household
headship in urban areas (where the incidence of women-headed
households is generally higher) occurred in every single country for
which data exist for 1990 and 1999 (see CEPAL, 2001: Cuadro V3),
whereas the regional proportion of urban households in poverty
declined from 35% to 29.8% between 1990 and 1999, and indigent
households from 17.7% to 13.9% (ibid.: Cuadro 1.2). Regardless

15
of the fact that in some parts of the region female heads have borne
a greater burden of poverty over time (as, for example, in Costa
Rica), Arriagada (1998:91) asserts for the continent as a whole that:
‘...the majority of households with a female head are not poor and
are those which have increased most in recent decades’.9

That female headship is not necessarily a poverty-specific


phenomenon is also evident from detailed micro-level data
generated by in-depth household research in a number of
developing and emerging market economies. A comparative
analysis of the effects of structural adjustment in low-income
neighbourhoods of Guayaquil, Manila, Budapest and Lusaka, for
example, indicated that in all but the last city, there was no
relationship between the sex of household heads and income
(Moser,1996:50). Similarly, research across a broader cross-
section of the population in a range of countries shows that that
women-headed households are just as likely to be present among
middle- and/or upper-income groups as among the poor (see
Appleton, 1996 on Uganda; Geldstein, 1994,1997 on Argentina;
González de la Rocha, 1999:31; Willis, 2000:33 on Mexico;
Hackenberg et al, 1981:20 on the Philippines; Kumari, 1989:31 on
India; Lewis, 1993:23 on Bangladesh; Wartenburg, 1999:78 on
Colombia; Weekes-Vagliani,1992:42 on the Côte d'Ivoire). Indeed,
given that many younger lone mothers tend not to be able to afford
their own accommodation and so live under the roof of kin or friends
as ‘embedded female-headed sub-families’ (see Chant and
McIlwaine, 1995 on the Philippines; Marenco et al, 1998 on Costa
Rica; Wartenburg,1999 on Colombia), it is entirely possible that

16
pockets of poverty are equally, if not more, likely to be found in
households headed by men

In turn, it is by no means clear that female household headship is


responsible for an ‘inter-generational transmission of
disadvantage’, with research in a variety of contexts indicating that
children in female-headed households may actually be better off
than their counterparts in male-headed units in terms of educational
attainment, nutrition and health (Blumberg, 1995; Chant, 1997a;
Engle, 1995; Hoddinott and Haddad, 1991; Moore and Vaughan,
1994; Oppong, 1997). Moreover, despite the common assumption
that female heads of household send young children out to work,
levels of child labour do not seem to be noticeably higher in female-
headed units (see Chant,1997a:230 et seq).

These findings clearly need to be balanced against research which


indicates that women-headed households are likely to be poorer in
income terms than male-headed units (see, for example, Bibars, 2001:
68; van Driel, 1994:216; González de la Rocha, 1994b:6-7; Paolisso and
Gammage, 1996:18-21; Todes and Walker, 1993:48). Indeed, one of the
most ambitious comparative reviews to date, based on over 60 studies
from Latin America, Africa and Asia, concluded that in two-thirds of cases
women-headed households were poorer than male-headed households
(see Buvinic and Gupta, 1993,1997).10 None the less, given conflicting
findings, and the tenuous evidence for any systematic relationship
between female household headship and poverty, it is clearly wise to
refrain from over-emphasising the ‘plight of female-headed households’
(Scott, 1994:86; see also Chant, 1997b; Elson, 2002:95; Fonseca,
1991:138; González de la Rocha and Grinspun, 2001:61-2; Kabeer,

17
2003:81-3; Quisumbing et al, 1995; Razavi, 1999:410). In turn, given
widespread economic inequalities between men and women, a more
important issue is arguably to establish how substantial numbers of
female heads manage to avoid a greater incidence and depth of poverty
than their male counterparts (see Appendix, Box 3).

Heterogeneity of female-headed households


Aside from the fact that survival capacity, bargaining power and 'fall-
back' position (Sen, 1990) of female heads vary greatly in different
social, cultural, demographic and economic contexts, female-
headed households are a highly heterogenous group.
Differentiation occurs inter alia, through such factors as routes into
the status (whether by ‘choice’ or involuntarily, and/or through non-
marriage, separation, divorce, widowhood and so on), by rural or
urban residence, by ‘race’, by composition, by stage in the life
course (including age and relative dependency of offspring), and by
access to resources from beyond the household unit (from absent
fathers, kinship networks, state assistance and the like) (see
Baylies, 1996; Chant, 1997a; Feijoó, 1999; Safa, 2002; Varley,
2002; Whitehead and Lockwood, 1999; also Note 2). These
differences can be eminently important in explaining how female
headship does not automatically entail consignment to the category
of ‘poorest of the poor’.

Age seems to play a major role in mediating disadvantage,


recognising that its particular influence on women at different stages
of the life course varies from one context to another. In Egypt, for
example, Bibars (2001:67) points out that many female heads are
poor because they are ‘old and illiterate and unable to work’,

18
whereas in Chile, the average age of ‘non-poor’ female heads is
higher (at 56.9 years) than for those classified as ‘poor’ (51.9 years),
and/or ‘destitute’ (46 years) (Thomas,1995:82, Table 3.3). Indeed,
in Latin America more generally, the mean age of low-income female
household heads is often 5 years more than their male counterparts
(see Chant, 1997a:Chapters 5&6), and they tend to be better-off than
their younger counterparts, especially where they continue to co-
reside with family members. One reason is that they may have fewer
dependent children (González de la Rocha,1994b:8). National
Household Survey data from Costa Rica, for example, indicate that
the risk of poverty is 55% greater in households with children under
12 years old, than in those without (Marenco et al, 1998:11). In turn,
older female heads often have children of working age (whether co-
resident or who have left home) who are able to help out financially.
This is critical when considering that female heads often receive
larger and more frequent remittances than male heads from non-
resident offspring, not only in Latin America, but in other parts of the
South too (see Appleton, 1996 on Uganda; Brydon and Legge,1996:
49 & 69 and Lloyd and Gage-Brandon, 1993:121 & 123 on Ghana;
Chant,1997a: 210-1 on Mexico; Chant and McIlwaine, 1995 on the
Philippines; Kusakabe, 2002:6 on Cambodia). As summarised by
Safa (2002:13) in the context of the Dominican Republic, ‘female-
headed households can function quite adequately as long as the
consanguineous ties that provide crucial financial, domestic, and
emotional support are maintained’. In fact, in some parts of the
world, such as the Netherlands Antilles, it has been argued that
‘...family networks provide women with more security than an
individual male partner’ (Ypeij and Steenbeek, 2001:73).

19
Leading on from this, the common pattern for female headed units
to contain extended kin members can bolster security and well-
being, whether because this adds wage earners to the household
unit, or because it facilitates engagement in wage-earning among
other household members. In low-income neighbourhoods in
urban Mexico more than one-half of female-headed households are
extended, compared with just over one-quarter of male-headed
units (Chant 1997a). In Nicaragua, surveys conducted in four rural
and urban settlements indicate that 54% of female-headed units are
extended, as against 21% of their male-headed counterparts
(Bradshaw, 2002:16). In Colombia too, data from National
Household and Quality of Life Surveys reveal that the incidence of
extension is higher in female-headed than male-headed households
(46% versus 30%) (Wartenburg, 1999:88).

There is often important interaction between stage in the life course


and composition insofar as older heads are more likely to extend
their membership through the marriage of sons and daughters.
This means too, that female-headed households may contain male
adults, underlining Fonseca’s (1991) point that ‘female-headed’
household does not equate with ‘male-absent’ household (see also
Appendix, Box 3).11 Notwithstanding that in some cases, especially
where there are few opportunities for productive work, household
extension might not bring (or be perceived to bring) economic
benefits, and ‘may actually serve to increase rather than decrease
vulnerability’ (Bradshaw, 2002:21), in other instances, it can also
reflect a proactive measure to protect and/or improve well-being.

20
Although it is impossible to generalise about different features of
female-headed households and the links with poverty across
different contexts, at the bottom line, findings suggest that it is
obviously inappropriate to collapse the well-being of household
members to the relative economic status of individual heads. In
short, the diversity of female-headed households in respect of
socio-economic status, age, composition, dependency of offspring,
access to resources from beyond the household and so on,
precludes their categorical labelling (see Chant, 1997a,b; Feijoó,
1999; Kusakabe, 2002; Oliver, 2002; Varley, 2002; Whitehead and
Lockwood, 1999). In turn, other aspects of the livelihood
strategies of female-headed households indicate that potential
shortfalls in the income and assets are compensated in other
ways.

Variations in household employment and earning strategies


Even if female heads of household may be disadvantaged by gender
inequalities in earnings, we cannot assume that they are the sole
breadwinners in households (Varley,1996; see also Appendix, Box
3). Indeed, in many parts of the South, especially those which have
experienced major debt crises and/or undergone neo-liberal
restructuring, multiple earning has been key to strategies adopted by
low-income households to keep afloat. 12 Accordingly, mounting
contributions from other household members have diminished the
share of total income apportioned by heads (González de la Rocha,
2002:64). Furthermore, much research, especially on Latin
America, suggests that relative to household size, female-headed
households may have more earners (and earnings) than their male-
headed counterparts who, for various reasons (for example, pride,

21
honour, sexual jealousy) fail to mobilise their full potential labour
supply. Several studies of Mexico, for example, indicate that some
men adhere to a long-standing (if increasingly unviable) practice not
only of forbidding their wives to work, but daughters as well,
especially in jobs outside the home (see Benería and
Roldan,1987:146; Chant,1997b; Fernández-Kelly,1983; Proctor,
2003:303; Townsend et al, 1999:38; Willis,1993:71). When this
leaves households reliant on a single wage, there are greater risks of
destitution. Moreover, although female-headed households may
clearly need more workers (in other words, women's wages may
require supplementation by the earnings of others), maximising the
use of female labour supply can add to the effects of household
extension and/or multiple earning strategies in reducing dependency
ratios and enhancing per capita incomes (see Chant, 1991a:204,
Table 7.1; Selby et al, 1990:95; Varley,1996:Table 5 on Mexico; also
Chant, 1997a:210; Kennedy, 1994; Oliver, 2002:47; Paolisso and
Gammage, 1996:21; Quisumbing et al, 1995; Shanthi, 1994:23 on
other contexts). As summed-up by Wartenburg (1999:95) in
relation to Colombia, the manner in which female-headed
households organise themselves can optimise the positive elements
of such arrangements and thereby contribute to neutralising the
negative effects of gender bias. Aside from the fact that the diverse
livelihood strategies entered into by female-headed households can
raise earning capacity and reduce vulnerability, earnings seem to
have a greater chance of being translated into disposable income for
household use, mainly because women heads are able to sidestep
the vagaries of resource contributions from male ‘breadwinners’.

22
Intra-household resource distribution and household bargaining models
A critically important input to feminisation of poverty debates has
been the argument that earning differentials between households
may be tempered by intra-household distributional factors, which are
often highly gendered (Folbre, 1991:110).

Empirical evidence from a range of contexts reveals that more


money, in relative terms, may be available for common expenditure
within households headed by women, with positive effects for
members’ nutritional intake, health care and education (see
Blumberg, 1995:215 et seq; Chant, 1997a:227-8; Engle, 1995;
Kabeer, 1996:13, 2003:165 et seq). This situation is in part
explained by gender disparities in the use and allocation of earnings.
Whereas women frequently devote all they earn to household needs,
this is less so among men. In poor communities in Honduras, for
example, around one-third of the income of male heads may be
withheld from collective household funds (Bradshaw, 1996b), and in
some instances in Nicaragua and Mexico, up to 50% (Bradshaw,
2002:29; González de la Rocha, 1994b:10). Some money may be
retained by men for routine daily expenses such as transport to work.
However, varying amounts are also devoted to discretionary personal
expenditure. When this involves ‘non-merit’ items such as alcohol
and tobacco, the costs to other household members may be long- as
well as short-term, when considering time off work, medicines, health
visits, managing debt and so on (see Appleton,1991; Benería and
Roldan,1987:114; Chant,1997a; Dwyer and Bruce [eds], 1988;
Hoddinott and Haddad,1991; Kabeer,1994:104; Young, 1992:14).
This is clearly serious, particularly where incomes are low and
livelihoods precarious (Tasies Castro,1996). While not denying that

23
expenditure on extra-domestic pursuits may act to bolster masculine
identities, not to mention provide solace in situations where men
have limited access to employment13, the personally symbolic and
psychological value of such actions can hardly justify the extreme
costs of 'secondary poverty' imposed upon women and children
(Chant, 1997b, 2001; see also Muthwa, 1993).

Such findings have lent major weight to feminist critiques of


orthodox ‘household economics’ models which have discredited
the idea that households are unitary entities operating on altruistic
principles and instead emphasise how they are more likely to be
characterised by competing claims, rights, power, interests and
resources. Popularised most widely in the shape of Amartya
Sen’s ‘cooperative conflict’ model (Sen, 1987b, 1990), this
perspective requires us to look inside households rather than
leaving them as unproblematised, undeconstructed ‘black boxes’
or conceptualising them as entities governed by ‘natural’
proclivities to benevolence, consensus and joint welfare
maximisation (see also Baden with Milward,1997;
Bradshaw,1996a; Cagatay, 1998; Hart, 1997; Kabeer,1994:
Chapter 5; Lewis,1993; Molyneux, 2001: Chapter 4; also Appendix,
Box 3). As summed-up by González de la Rocha and Grinspun
(2001:59-60):

‘Analysing vulnerability requires opening up the household


so as to assess how resources are generated and used,
how they are converted into assets, and how the returns
from these assets are distributed among household
members’.

24
Following on from the observation that 'The presence of two parents
in the same residence gives no guarantee of either financial or
emotional support' (Baylies, 1996:77; also van Driel, 1994:208 et
seq), it should also be noted that in cases where women partners are
earning, men may keep more of their wage for themselves such that
women’s incomes end up substituting rather than complementing
those of partners (see Bradshaw, 2002:29 on Nicaragua).
Moreover, in some instances male household heads not only retain
substantial amounts of their own earnings for personal use, but take
'top-up' money from working wives as well. In Thailand, for example,
Blanc-Szanton (1990:93) observes that it is culturally acceptable for
husbands to gamble and go drinking with friends after work and to
demand money from their spouses (see also Chant and
McIlwaine,1995:283 on the Philippines). These findings underline
Folbre's (1991:108) argument that male heads may command a
larger share of resources (due to their privileged bargaining position)
than they actually bring to the household (see also Baylies, 1996:77).
Accordingly, instead of resulting in destitution, men's demise or
departure may well enhance the economic security and well-being of
other household members. In Mexico, Costa Rica and the
Philippines, for example, low-income women often stress that they
actually feel more secure financially without men, even when their
own earnings are low and/or prone to fluctuation. They also claim to
feel better able to cope with hardship when they are not at the mercy
of male dictat and are freer to make their own decisions (see Chant,
1997a,b). Critically, therefore, even if women are poorer in income
terms as heads of their own household, they may feel they are better
off and, importantly, less vulnerable (see Appendix, Box 3). Where
women have the power to determine how they themselves generate

25
and use resources, this also allows them to resist other aspects of
male control and authority, thereby echoing the idea that ‘..single
parenthood can represent not only a different but a preferable kind of
poverty for lone mothers’ (Graham,1987:59; also UNDAW, 1991:41).
The notion that ‘A lower income may even be preferred over a
position of dependence and domination’ (Davids and van Driel,
2001:164), is echoed by González de la Rocha’s (1994a) research in
Guadalajara, Mexico, where although lone-parent units usually have
lower incomes (both total and per capita) than other households, the
women who head them ‘are not under the same violent oppression
and are not as powerless as female heads with partners’ (ibid.:210).

Poverty as a multidimensional and subjective concept


That command over resources may be deemed more important than
level of resources in influencing subjective definitions of poverty is
integral to ‘social deprivation’ thinking about poverty which calls for
more holistic, multidimensional conceptualisations which extend
beyond a narrow focus on incomes and consumption and do not
‘stop at the front door’ of domestic units (Bradshaw, 2002:12). On
one hand, literature within this genre has emphasised the importance
of ‘assets’, which are not only financial or physical in nature (labour,
savings, tools, shelter, for instance), but include ‘human capital’ such
as education and skills, and 'social capital' such as kin and friendship
networks and community organisations (for discussions see
Chambers,1995; Linneker, 2003; Moser,1996,1998; Moser and
McIlwaine,1997; McIlwaine, 2002; Rakodi, 1999; Rakodi with Lloyd-
Jones [eds], 2002; Willis, 2000; Wratten,1995; also World Bank,
2000). On the other hand, through the greater use of participatory
methodologies in poverty evaluations, concepts of vulnerability, well-

26
being, self-esteem, respect, agency, and power are brought into the
frame (see Baden with Milward,1997; Baulch,1996; Cagatay, 1998;
Chambers, 1983,1988, 1989,1995; Kabeer, 2003:96 et seq; Moser
et al,1996a,b; Sen, 1981,1986, 1987a; Wratten,1995). This is
critically important for women, as summed up by Razavi (1999:417):

‘From a gender perspective, broader concepts of poverty


are more useful than a focus purely on household income
levels because they allow a better grasp of the multi-
dimensional aspects of gender disadvantage, such as lack
of power to control important decisions that affect one’s
life...’.

Leading on from this, multidimensional conceptualisations of


poverty provide important inroads into explaining why some low-
income women make ‘trade-offs’ between different forms of
privation that, at face value, may seem prejudicial to their well-
being. One such case is where female heads refuse offers of
financial support from absent fathers in order to evade on-going
contact and/or sexual relations (Chant, 1997b). Another instance
is where women forfeit assets such as their houses and
neighbourhood networks in order to leave abusive relationships
(ibid.). It is also significant that while financial pressures may
force some women to search for other partners following conjugal
breakdown, others choose to remain alone rather than return to ex-
partners or to form new relationships (see Chant 1997a: Chapter 7;
also Bradshaw,1996a; Ypeij and Steenbeek, 2001). As noted by
Fonseca (1991) in relation to research in Porto Alegre, Brazil,
women who live without partners often do so not through lack of
opportunity, but by choice (ibid.:156). In many cases these are
older (post-menopausal) women, who, ‘having gained a moment of

27
respite in the battlefield of the sexes’, prefer to rely upon sons than
spouses (ibid.:157; see also Appendix, Box 3).

Recognising that not all female heads have access to financial


help from sons or other male kin, and that a ‘high price’ may have
to be paid for independence (Jackson, 1996; Molyneux, 2001:
Chapter 4), benefits in other dimensions of their lives may be
adjudged to outweigh the costs. Clearly ‘trade-offs’ are made
between one form of privation and another, and the options
available to poor women are usually ‘bleak’, not to mention ‘painful’
(see Kabeer, 1997,1999; also van Driel, 1994). None the less,
men’s incomes, though potentially beneficial, can carry too many
conditions to make them worthwhile. While the perceived benefits
of being without a male partner often centre on non-economic
aspects of well-being (Bradshaw, 2002:31), women’s deliberated
rejection of men’s support and/or co-residence can diminish
personal and family vulnerability in various ways, including
materially (Chant, 2001).

Although the findings discussed above suggest that sweeping


stereotypes about the poverty of women-headed households are
misplaced, I am not by any means advocating a counter-
stereotypical proposition. Female headship is far from being a
‘panacea for poverty’ (see Feijoó, 1999:162), and it is clear that
some women’s individual endowments and household
characteristics make them more vulnerable than others. Lone-
parent households (especially those with young children), rarely
‘compete on an equal playing field’ with their two-parent
counterparts (Hewitt and Leach,1993:v), whether in terms of labour

28
resources, access to jobs or other productive assets. This puts
some female heads in the position of having to become ‘time-poor’
and/or self exploit in the interests of overcoming income deficiency
and to enable them to cope with multiple responsibilities for
economic provisioning and reproductive work (see also Fuwa,
2000:1517; Panda, 1997). This, in turn, can greatly constrain
their possibilities for rest and leisure, with major implications for
personal well-being, health, investments in income-generating
activities, and time available to spend with children. As such
recognising that poverty is multi-causal and multi-faceted, and that,
in some ways and in some cases, female household headship can
be positive and empowering, is no justification for lack of
assistance from state agencies and other institutional providers
(Bibars, 2001:67; Chant, 2001). How female heads might be
helped best, however, needs serious consideration. This is
explored further below in the context of the implications of
adhering, on one hand, to the stereotype that they are the ‘poorest
of the poor’, and on the other, working from a more circumspect,
nuanced set of premises.

IMPLICATIONS OF COMPETING CONSTRUCTIONS OF


FEMALE HOUSEHOLD HEADSHIP AND THE LINKS WITH
POVERTY

Female headed households as ‘poorest of the poor’:


consequences and cautions

There is little doubt that the feminisation of poverty thesis has been
powerful in pushing gender to the centre stage of international fora on
poverty and social development, with women’s economic
empowerment -- through welfare and productivity investments -- now

29
widely seen as crucial not only in achieving gender equality but
eliminating poverty (see DFID, 2000; Razavi, 1999:418; UNDAW,
2000; UNDP, 2001; World Bank, 2000). Indeed, seeking to alleviate
poverty through women seems to have become one of the most
favoured routes to ensuring all-round developmental benefits, as
articulated in an indicative statement by Finne (2001:9):

‘Economic progression and improvements in the quality of life


for all people is more rapidly achieved where women’s status
is higher. This is not simply a focus on a single individual, but
because of women’s communal role positive effects will be
seen in the family, home, environment, children, elderly and
whole communities and nations’ (see also World Bank, 1994,
2002).

While notions of ‘returns’ or ‘pay-offs’ from investing in women can


at least serve to secure resources for women, whether in the form
of literacy and education programmes, micro-credit schemes, or
skills training and extension services for female heads of
household (see Chant, 1999; Grosh, 1994; Mayoux, 2002;
Pankhurst, 2002; Yates, 1997), such naked instrumentalism leaves
much to be desired. Moreover, whether the linking of poverty and
female household headship is an appropriate part of the equation
is another question. As argued by Moore (1994:61):

'The straightforward assumption that poverty is always


associated with female-headed households is dangerous,
because it leaves the causes and nature of poverty
unexamined and because it rests on the prior implication that
children will be consistently worse-off in such households
because they represent incomplete families'.

Over and above the fact that there is little substantive macro- or
micro-level evidence to suggest that women-headed households

30
are the ‘poorest of the poor’, a number of undesirable (if
unintended) consequences result from these links and their
homogenising tendencies (see Appendix, Box 4). One of the most
important is that it suggests that poverty is confined to female
heads alone, which thereby overlooks the situation of the bulk of
women in general (Feijoó, 1999:156; Jackson, 1996, 1997:152;
Kabeer, 1996; May, 2001:50). As noted by Davids and van Driel
(2001:162):

‘What is implied is that female-headed households are


poorer than male-headed households. The question that is
not asked, however, is whether women are better-off in
male-headed households. By making male-headed
households the norm, important contradictions vanish within
these households, and so too does the possibly unbalanced
economical (sic) and social position of women compared to
men’.

Lack of attention to intra-household inequalities in resource


allocation, as we have seen, can also draw a veil over the
‘secondary poverty’ often experienced by women in male-headed
units (see Bradshaw, 1996; Chant, 1997a; Fukuda-Parr, 1999;
González de la Rocha and Grinspun, 2001; Moghadam, 1997;
Varley, 1996).

Another major outcome of emphasis on female-headed


households as the ‘poorest of the poor’ is that it conveys an
impression that poverty owes more to their household
characteristics (including the marital and/or civil status of their
heads), than to the macro social and economic contexts in which
they are situated. In the UK, for example, the centrality of lone
motherhood in debates about the country’s growing ‘underclass’

31
are levelled by Phoenix (1996:174) as having contributed to ‘a
construction of lone mothers as “feckless”, wilfully responsible for
the poverty that has been well-documented to be a feature of lone
parenting’, or as Laws (1996:68-9) puts it: ‘It is argued that lone
parenthood itself is the problem, not the conditions in which it
occurs’ (see also Roseneil and Mann,1996:205). These lines of
argument, which are noted in other contexts such as the USA (see
Lewis, 1989; Stacey, 1997; Waldfogel, 1996), not only scapegoat
women but divert attention from wider structures of gender and
socio-economic inequality (Moore,1996: 74). They also imply that
motherhood is only viable and/or acceptable in the context of
marriage or under the aegis of male household headship (see
Chant, 1997b; Collins,1991:159; Hewitt and Leach,1993).

Related to this, persistent portrayals of the economic disadvantage


of female-headed units which implicitly or otherwise attribute this to
their household circumstances, not only misrepresent and devalue
the enormous efforts made by female heads to overcome the
problems they face on account of their gender, but also obliterate
the meanings of female headship for women. As asserted by
Davids and van Driel (2001:166):

‘Female-headed households appear as an objective


category of households in which the subject position of the
female head vanishes completely as does the socio-cultural
and psychological meaning that their status has for them
personally’.

Other outcomes include fuel for pathological discourses of female-


headed households as deviant and/or ‘inferior’ to a male-headed
‘norm’. This, in turn, can perpetuate the idea that male-headed

32
households are the sole embodiment of ‘intact’ and essentially
unproblematic family arrangements (Feijoó, 1999:156). Moreover,
uncompromisingly negative images of female heads can condemn
them to greater privation, for example, by limiting their social
networks which, in many parts of the world, act as sources of job
information, as arenas for the exchange of labour and finance, and
as contexts for securing the prospective marriages of offspring
(see for example, Bruce and Lloyd, 1992; Davids and van Driel,
2001:64; Lewis,1993:34-5; Monk,1993:10; Winchester,1990:82).
A further, and extremely invidious, implication is that gender
inequality becomes reduced to a function of poverty, when gender
and poverty are clearly distinct, albeit overlapping, forms of
disadvantage (Jackson, 1996, 1998; Jackson and Palmer-Jones,
1999; Kabeer, 2003; also Appendix, Box 4).

Last but not least, the aforementioned tendency for the static and
universalising assumptions of the feminisation of poverty thesis to
produce policy interventions which either target women in isolation
or focus mainly on those who head their own households can
neglect vital relational aspects of gender which are likely to play a
large part in accounting for gender bias within and beyond the
home (see Buvinic and Gupta, 1997; Jackson, 1997; May, 2001;
Moore, 1996). Some of these issues are discussed below in
relation to the pros and cons of targeted programmes for female-
headed households.

33
Consequences and cautions of de-linking female household
headship from poverty

While there are many persuasive reasons to revisit (if not de-link)
female household headship from poverty, a major danger is that
this can undermine the case for policy attention. In other words,
denying that households headed by women are the ‘poorest of the
poor’ potentially deprives them of resources that could enable
them to overcome some of the inequities that face women in
general, and lone mothers in particular. Is this wise in a situation
of diminishing public funds for social expenditure and increasing
market-driven economic pressure on households, especially given
that many female-headed households have struggled under the
auspices of a ‘survival model’ requiring high degrees of self-
exploitation, that now looks to be exhausting its possibilities? (see
González de la Rocha, 2001; also Appendix, Box 5).

The answer here is probably no, but how they should be assisted
merits more dedicated consideration. One response to date has
been to target female-headed households in poverty-related
programmes, as has occurred in various forms in Singapore,
Cambodia, Iran, Bangladesh, India, Honduras, Puerto Rico, Chile,
Colombia and Costa Rica.14,15 Although such programmes remain
relatively rare, they have grown in number in the last two decades.
This is not only because of the momentum built up by ‘poorest of the
poor’ stereotyping, but because neo-liberal drives towards cost-
savings and ‘efficiency’ have led to reduced public expenditure on
universal social programmes in favour of re-directing smaller
amounts of resources to specific groups (see Budowski and
Guzmán, 1998; Chant, 2002).

34
Pros and cons of targeted programmes for female-headed
households living in poverty

Recognising the empirical limitations of few ‘test cases’, a useful


review of the potential benefits and drawbacks of dedicated initiatives
for female heads of household by Mayra Buvinic and Geeta Rao
Gupta (1997), identifies three major arguments in favour of targeting.
The first is that in situations where data on poverty is unreliable,
isolating households headed by women is likely to capture a
significant share of the population ‘in need’, especially where there
are substantial gaps in male and female earnings and where
subsidised childcare facilities are limited. Second, targeting
assistance to lone mothers may be an effective means of improving
child welfare given widespread empirical evidence that children fare
better where women have resources at their own disposal. A third
potential benefit is greater equitability of development resource
allocation among men and women (Buvinic and Gupta, 1997).

Arguments against targeting highlighted by Buvinic and Gupta (1997)


include the fact that female-headed households may become male-
headed over time through remarriage or cohabitation, thereby
resulting in a leakage of benefits to male-headed households.
Another potential slippage of benefits is to non-poor households
given that not all female-headed households have low incomes, and
some may receive support, albeit periodically, from men. Further
problems arise from difficulties inherent in screening processes
whereby some female-headed households may not be classified as
such due to cultural norms of naming men as heads of household,
even if they are largely or permanently absent, or make little

35
contribution to family life and welfare. Tactics for determining which
types of female heads are most in need of help may also be
problematic. In Honduras, for example, a food coupon programme
targeted at primary school children from female-headed households
attempted to ascertain the financial status of mothers through
questioning children and neighbours in the community. Aside from
the invasive nature of this approach, little could be done to guard
against a degree of arbitrary and inappropriate decision-taking
(Grosh, 1994).

On top of this, many women may not want to be identified as lone


mothers given the stigma attached to the status. They may also
feel that taking public money will increase antagonism against
them.16 Here Buvinic and Gupta (1997:271) draw attention to the
fact that targeting can alienate male-headed households and thus
have high political costs. This is especially likely to be the case
when female heads are targeted with interventions that are not
perceived as ‘female-specific’ such as housing subsidies, food
coupons and so on. Less conflict, alternatively, is likely to occur
when female-heads receive benefits that are perceived as female-
specific such as skills training for 'female' jobs, or child and
maternal health interventions (ibid.).

Other problems of targeting include the construction of female-


headed households as a vulnerable and residualised group. As
Bibars (2001:83 et seq) notes of Egypt, while the beneficiaries of
mainstream contributory aid and welfare schemes (who are
primarily men) are perceived as having ‘rights’, the recipients of
non-contributory programmes (who are predominantly female) are

36
perceived in the disparaging light of ‘charity cases’. In fact, noting
the build-up of a ‘distrustful, punitive and contemptuous attitude
towards female-headed households and the poor in general’ in
recent years, the trend is now away from charity and welfare to
credit to promote productivity. This is reminiscent of the ‘workfare’-
type programmes which have increasingly been implemented in
advanced economies such as the UK and USA since the 1980s
(see Chant, 1997a:Chapter 2; Stacey, 1997).

Another argument against targeting, particularly common among


government bodies, is that it may produce so-called ‘perverse
incentives’ and encourage more households to opt for female
headship. Fear of this has been so pronounced in Costa Rica that
when the Social Welfare Ministry established its first programme for
female household heads in 1997, specific declaration was made in
the supporting documentation that there was no intention to
promote increases in lone motherhood (Chant 1999). Moreover,
subsequent programmes of a related nature, such as ‘Amor Joven’
for adolescent mothers, have been oriented as much to preventing
rises in lone parenthood as assisting the client group (Chant, 2001).
In the context of Egypt, Bibars (2001:67) comments that free and
unconditional assistance is thought not only to increase the
numbers of female-headed households, but to encourage them ‘to
relax and not work’.

Last but not least, we have to acknowledge the limited impacts that
targeted schemes for female household heads are observed to
have had when the resources allocated are small and/or where
broader structures of gender inequality remain intact. In Chile, for

37
example, which piloted a Programme for Female Heads of
Household in 1992-3, that was later extended nationally, efforts to
increase women’s access to employment through vocational
labour training, access to childcare and so on, were tempered by
the government’s failure to address the social and cultural
structures underlying gender segregation in the labour market and
the perpetuation of poverty among women (Arriagada, 1998:97;
Badia 1999; see also Budowski, 2000, 2002; Marenco et al, 1998
on Costa Rica; Rico de Alonso and López Tellez, 1998:197 on
Colombia; Pankurst, 2002 on savings and credit schemes for
women more generally). Indeed, it is instructive that in Cuba,
where although Castro’s government has resisted providing
special welfare benefits to female heads, policies favouring greater
gender equality in general, high levels of female labour force
participation and the availability of support services such as
daycare, have all made it easier for women to raise children alone
(see Safa, 1995).

Alternative strategies to address the ‘feminisation of poverty’


While in some respects a targeted approach recognises barriers to
well-being in female-headed households and should not on this
count be abandoned, efforts to address the putative ‘feminisation
of poverty’ more generally could arguably be more effective if they
were to take on board the fact that women in male-headed
households also suffer poverty, albeit in different ways, and for
different reasons. As Bradshaw (2002:12) has summarised,
women’s poverty is not only multidimensional but is also
‘multisectoral’, namely ‘women’s poverty is experienced in different
ways, at different times and in different “spaces”’. Recognising

38
that any single category of household is marked by its own
heterogeneities, one of the main differences between women in
female- and male-headed units is that the former tend to face
problems of a limited asset base (labour, incomes, property and so
on), while the latter’s main difficulty may be restricted access to
and control over household assets (Bradshaw, 2002:12; see also
Linneker, 2003:4). Accordingly, gender inequality clearly needs to
be addressed within as well as beyond the boundaries of
household units (Chant, 2001; also Kabeer, 2003:167).

Interventions to reduce women’s poverty to date, whether as


heads of household or otherwise, have taken a number of forms.
These include investing in women’s capabilities, through
education, health, vocational training and so on, and/or enhancing
their access to assets such as employment, credit, infrastructure
and housing. While such interventions potentially go some way to
narrowing gender gaps in well-being, and have arguably moved
into a new gear given increasing experimentation with ‘gender
budgets’ at national and local levels (see Borges Sugiyama, 2002;
BRIDGE,2003; Budlender, 2000; Budlender and Hewitt [eds],
2002; Kabeer, 2003:220-5)17, it is worth noting that with the
possible exception of domestic violence, initiatives relating to the
‘private’ sphere of home and family are often left out of the frame
(see Chant with Craske, 2003: Chapter 7). This relative neglect of
‘family matters’ is somewhat surprising given the common
argument advanced by international institutions that it is families
who actually benefit from reductions in women’s poverty! In
addition unless factors such as ‘secondary poverty’ within
households are recognised by policymakers then efforts to reduce

39
poverty or enhance well-being through stimulating income-
generating activities among women, increasing their access to
credit, and so on, may well come to nothing (Bradshaw, 2002: 31;
Kabeer, 1999).

With this in mind, it is important not only to regard women as


individuals (even if increasing their personal autonomy and
empowerment is an ultimate goal), but to go back to what, in one
sense, might be construed as a less fashionable premise, namely
that women are also embedded in family and community structures
that play a large role in determining their behaviour and
possibilities. Leading out of this, three ‘family-oriented’ strategies
that might be useful in complementing existing approaches to
alleviating poverty among women include public support for
parenting, equalisation of responsibilities and power among
parents, and bolstering the socio-economic status and rights of
female heads of household.

Public support for parenting


One of the problems with normative assumptions about the dominance
of the ‘male-headed family’ is that, coupled with dominance of men in
public institutions, family and other sectoral policies for the most part
reflect male bias (see Bibars, 2001: 159; CEPAL, 2001:13). With regard
to parenting, for example, it is implicitly expected that the daily care of
infants and children should fall to women, and that the burden of this
care should be borne privately. The fact is, however, that macro-
economic change has required more and more women to take on
responsibilities for income-generating activity, such that the only way
these multiple obligations can be performed is at considerable personal

40
cost. This applies as much to female partners in male-headed
households as it does to women who are household heads in their own
right, with one major implication being that they are not free to enter the
labour market on the same terms as men (see Palmer, 1992). This
contributes either to lower incomes for women and their families, or to a
weaker bargaining position within households. Eliminating further
increases in the ‘feminisation of poverty’ would accordingly be better
assured if there were to be greater recognition of women’s
disproportionate responsibility for raising children through public-
sponsored provision of childcare and family benefits (see Chant, 2002).18
Pressure on employers to contribute to such initiatives might also be
desirable, with the added value that this could be tactically negotiated on
instrumentalist grounds. As Diane Elson (1999: 612), has argued,
employers tend to conceive of the unpaid caring of their employees as
‘costs’rather than as ‘benefits’, when the latter can accrue from the fact
that workers bring skills to the workplace that derive from their roles as
parents and as household managers. In short: ‘... the reproductive
economy produces benefits for the productive economy which are
externalities, not reflected in market prices or wages’ (see also Folbre,
1994).

To push such agendas, it is clearly vital to get more women consulted and
on board in policmaking processes, recognising that broad-based
participation is not easy and may even lead to fragmentation among
women. Yet as argued by Finne (2001:7):

‘If women comprise 70% of impoverished people, how can


they be left ignored in decisions that further contribute and
create this extreme situation? A beginning in alleviation (sic)

41
rests on the power of women, representation and decision-
making’.

Equalising gender divisions of power and responsibility in the


domestic realm

In addition to public support for parenting, there are also strong


grounds for mobilising resources closer to home, and more
specifically to promote greater involvement on the part of men in
childcare, contact with children, and financial responsibility.

In respect of income poverty, for example, this is often


unnecessarily exacerbated in female-headed households through
lack of child maintenance payments from absent fathers, which, as
noted earlier, are often demanded by law, but seldom upheld in
practice. Were states to monitor and enforce men’s economic
obligations to children, this could go a substantial way to reducing
the financial pressures faced by female-headed households.

One recent initiative of this type has occurred in Costa Rica in the
form of a radical new ‘Law for Responsible Paternity’ (Ley de
Paternidad Responsable), passed in 2001. Momentum for the law
came, inter alia, from a steady increase in the non-registration of
fathers’ names on children’s birth certificates, such that by 1999
nearly one in three new-born children in the country had a ‘padre
desconocido’ (‘unknown father’). The law requires men who do
not voluntarily register themselves as fathers on their children’s
birth certificates to undergo a compulsory DNA test at the Social
Security Institute. If the result is positive, they not only have to
pay alimony and child support, but are liable to contribute to the
costs of the pregnancy and birth, and to cover their children’s food

42
expenses for the first twelve months of life (INAMU, 2001; Menjívar
Ochoa, 2002).19,20

As for women and children in male-headed households, efforts to


ensure men’s compliance with economic obligations are likely to
be more complex given palpable reluctance along policymakers to
engage in ‘intra-household interference’ (Jackson 1997:152).
Given the difficulties (and possible undesirability) of public
surveillance and/or policing of every aspect of inter-personal
relations, one of the most tactical strategies here might be to
mount public information campaigns, as has been done with some
success in relation to domestic violence in Nicaragua (see
Solórzano et al, 2000), and/or to encourage men (with or without
their spouses) to attend workshops in which they are informed of
evolving agendas of children’s rights, and how these can (and
should) be safeguarded by parents. Such interventions may be
even more successful where attempts are made to promote male
participation in a portfolio of ‘family’ activities that extends beyond
the generation of income for their ‘dependents’, to emotional
support and practical care (Chant, 2001, 2002; UNICEF, 1997).
As highlighted by England and Folbre (2002:28): ‘Less gender
specialisation in the form of parental involvement could lead to
improved outcomes for children, not only by improving mothers’
economic position, but also by improving emotional connections
between fathers and children’.21

Although the most appropriate form that gender-sensitive


approaches to intra-household relations and responsibilities might
take requires considerably more thought, the need to engage with

43
men in domestic and family arenas is vital given that where social
programmes oriented to women do not recognise the importance
of men, then hostilities between women and men may increase,
and potentially result in more harm than good. In Costa Rica, for
example, Budowski (2003:231-2) reports some women who had
received ‘human training’ in the ‘Comprehensive Training
Programme for Women Heads of Household in Poverty’, and who,
as a result of this denounced domestic violence or began claiming
child support payments, became violent towards the fathers of their
children because of their accentuated sense of injustice. In turn,
other women complained to the organisers of the training
workshops that there was no point in learning about their rights as
women when men were barred from attending and when matters in
the home continued as normal (Chant, 2001).22 Another important
consideration is that directing resources to lone mothers can
alienate men still further from assuming responsibilities for their
children’s upkeep (Chant, 2002).

At the bottom line, where there is no attention to men and to


gender relations then it is unlikely that efforts to help women lift
themselves out of poverty will get very far. This plugs into
increasing recognition of the need and desirability of bringing men
on board as practitioners and beneficiaries in GAD policy and
planning (Chant and Gutmann, 2000; Cornwall, 2000; Cornwall
and White, 2000).

44
Equalising the status of female- and male-headed households
Recalling too, that poverty is not just about incomes, but about
power, self-esteem and social legitimacy, legislation and
campaigns to promote a socially-inclusive stance to a broad
spectrum of family arrangements could make major inroads in
respect of equalising the status and opportunities of female- and
male-headed households. There is potentially much to be gained
by bringing female-headed households more squarely into the
formal remit of ‘family options’ and treating them as a part of
(rather than apart from), normative and/or legally endorsed
arrangements for the rearing of children. As noted by van Driel
(1994:220) in relation to Botswana, female headship has to be
recognised legally and socially, since: ‘As long as women have a
secondary legal status, both in customary and common law, and in
Tswana society at large, women who are female heads of
household will be seen as the exception to the rule whereas in
practice the rule seems to be the exception’.

Knowing that female headship has the full support of the state and
society could also mean that women within male-headed
households have more options. In turn, these options may lead to
more bargaining power among women, and greater compliance
with obligations to the children they raise on the part of men

CONCLUDING COMMENTS
It is possibly paradoxical that despite nearly three decades of
rhetoric and intervention to reduce gender inequality, and some
evidence of diminishing gender gaps in education, economic
activity and so on, women should not only be an estimated two-

45
thirds of the world’s poor, but a purportedly rising percentage.
However, while to talk of the ‘feminisation of poverty’ as an on-
going and/or inevitable process, and as intrinsically linked with the
feminisation of household headship, is arguably over-drawn, this
should not detract from the fact that the ‘social relations of gender
predict greater vulnerability among women’ (Moghadam, 1997:41;
see also Bibars, 2001; Kabeer, 1996:20; Millar, 1996:113;
Quisumbing et al, 1995). Moreover, as summed-up by Williams
and Lee-Smith (2000:1):

‘The feminisation of poverty is more than a slogan: it is a


marching call that impels us to question our assumptions
about poverty itself by examining how it is caused,
manifested and reduced, and to do this from a gender
perspective’.

While consensus on different tenets of the feminisation of poverty


thesis remains elusive, not least on account of contradictory
evidence arising from studies grounded in different approaches, at
different scales, and in different places (see Buvinic and Gupta,
1997), debates have been productive insofar as they have drawn
attention to the problems of generalising about women’s poverty,
and of engaging in superficial dualistic comparisons between
male- and female-headed households within, as well as across,
cultures. Even if it continues to be impossible to pin down the
fine detail of exactly how many women are poor, which women
are poor, and how they become and/or remain poor, unpacking
the ‘feminisation of poverty’, and problematising some of its
conventional wisdoms (not least that women-headed households
are the worst afflicted), broadens prospects for change insofar as
it demands tackling gender inequalities in a number of arenas.

46
This not only signifies interventions which strive to redress gender
inequalities in different ‘spaces’, such as the labour market, legal
institutions, the home and so on, but which confront different
types, aspects and processes of poverty and inequality, extending
beyond the material, physiological and ‘objective’, to the political,
social, psychological and subjective. Ultimately, the prospects
are that arresting the feminisation of poverty can only be achieved
through a feminisation of power, and this applies to most poor
women, whatever their household circumstances.

47
NOTES
1. This paper was prepared for International Workshop: ‘Feminist Fables and
Gender Myths: Repositioning Gender in Development Policy and Practice’,
Institute of Development Studies, Sussex, 2-4 July 2003, and is published in this
series with the kind permission of the conference organisers.

2. In most national and international data sources 'female household headship' refers
to situations where an adult woman (usually with children) resides without a male
partner (or, in some cases, another adult male such as a father or brother) (Chant,
1997a: 5 et seq; also Wartenburg, 1999:77). Accepting the caveats of standardised
definition when headship is not a politically neutral concept, and where female
headship is prone to be under-reported through male bias (see Buvinic and Gupta,
1997:260; Feijoó, 1999:162; Folbre, 1991; Harris, 1981), 20-25% of households
worldwide are estimated to be headed by women (Moghadam, 1997).

3. Female-headed households are often equated with ‘lone mother households’


consisting solely of mothers and children. Yet although in many contexts lone
mothers constitute the majority of female heads, in a substantial number of cases
their households may be extended in composition. On top of this, female-headed
households also comprise other sub-groups such as grandmother-headed, women-
only, and lone female households (see Chant, 1991b,1997a: Chapter 1; also
Folbre,1991). Moreover, despite the fact that it is commonly assumed that the bulk
of 'lone mothers' are 'unmarried', the majority are often separated, divorced and/or
widowed (Chant,1997a: Chapter 6; see also Marenco et al, 1998:8).

4. This item was circulated on the pmujeres@avantel.net mailing list on 25 February


2003. FONAES stands for the Fondo Nacional de Apoyo a Empresas Sociales
(National Fund for Support to Social Enterprises) which aims to assist the
organisational efforts of indigenous populations in Mexico, together with urban and
rural groups in the popular sector, to create production, income and employment
opportunities. FONAES’ strategy for women (Coordinación de Desarrollo Productivo
de la Mujer), includes directing a proportion of its budget to women-only initiatives. In
this context, emphasising the ‘feminisation of poverty’ through the increase in female-
headed households could well be regarded as a bid to justify resources.

5. For many countries in the North too, low levels of state financial support are held to
account for the poverty of lone mother households (see for example, Edwards and
Duncan,1996; Hardey and Glover,1991:94; Hobson,1994:180; Mädge and Neusüss,
1994:1420; Millar,1992:15).

6. An interesting contrast is presented by Ypeij and Steenbeek (2001:73) in relation


to Surinamese and Antillean lone mothers in the Netherlands, where the welfare
benefit system protects women from financial dependence on men. One Antillean
mother, who had been offered support by the father of one of her children as a
means by which they might resume sexual relations, had been able to turn down his
money (and its associated ‘price’) because of public assistance. In fact, the only
reason that the respondent would countenance sexual relations with her ex-partner
was on her own terms, and as a means to get him more involved in the actual raising
of their child.

7. In the context of research on informal mutual insurance networks in Southern


Ghana, Goldstein et al (2001:7) note that these do not always work because people
fail to ask others for assistance. This tends to apply more to women than men, the

48
main reason being that: ‘... not asking largely reflects internalising rejection, or not
wanting to incur the transaction costs associated with asking’.

8. Another factor, pointed up in relation to black women in the Netherlands, is that


resisting favours from kin can be a means of reducing interference in their lives (Ypeij
and Steenbeek, 2001:78).

9. It is also worth pointing out that the overall average incidence of female headship
remains higher in the richer nations of the world than in the South (see Varley,1996:
Table 2).

10. Thirty-two of the studies had been conducted in Latin America, 20 in Africa and
14 in Asia, between the years 1979 and 1989 (see Buvinic and Gupta,1993,1997).
The indicators of poverty used included, inter alia, total and/or per capita household
income and consumption, mean income per adult equivalence, expenditure, access
to services and ownership of land or assets.

11. This said, Wartenburg’s study of Colombia found that whereas in male headed
households there were 101 men for every 100 women, there were only 54 men for
every 100 women in female-headed households (Wartenburg, 1999:89). By the
same token, in Costa Rica it appears that the significance of co-resident male adults
in determining levels of poverty in female-headed households is less than that of the
existence of young women aged 12-18 years who can help out in the home or take
on other household obligations (see Marenco et al, 1998:10).

12. Context is highly important here however. For example, a study of four rural and
urban communities in Nicaragua in the aftermath of Hurricane Mitch indicated that as
many as 16% of households reported no-one working at the time of interview, and
those households with only one earner (42%) were the single biggest category
(Bradshaw, 2002:18).

13. This point is particularly resonant at the present time, with recent enquiry into
men and masculinities in various parts of the South revealing growing pockets of
economic and labour market vulnerability among low-income males (Arias, 2000;
Chant, 2000, 2002; Fuller, 2000; Gutmann, 1996; Kaztman, 1992; Silberschmidt,
1999; Varley and Blasco, 2000).

14. In the Costa Rican case, a programme that was originally directed to lone
mothers, notably the ‘Comprehensive Training Programme for Female Household
Heads in Conditions of Poverty’ (Programa de Formación Integral para Mujeres Jefas
de Hogar en Condiciones de Pobreza), introduced during the regime of President
José María Figueres (1994-98), was revised and re-launched by the Social Christian
Unity regime of President Miguel Angel Rodríguez (1998-2002) under the title
‘Creciendo Juntas’ (‘Growing Together’). The original programme had involved the
provision of a modest stipend (‘asignación familiar temporal’) for up to six months
during which time women were expected to take courses in personal development
(including the building of self-esteem) and in employment-related training (Chant,
1997a:151; Marenco et al, 1998:52). This basic format was retained, but the
Creciendo Juntas programme was extended to all women in poverty (see IMAS,
2001). Although the new programme only reached 17% of female-headed
households classified as poor between 1999 and 2001, an estimated half of the
15,290 beneficiaries covered during this period were female heads of household
(personal communication, María Leiton, IMAS).

49
15. In the case of Nicaragua, female-headed households received priority in post-
Hurricane Mitch reconstruction programmes (see Bradshaw, 2001; Linneker,
2003:12), and in Singapore, the Small Families Improvement Scheme, which is
designed to assist low-income families gain access to education and housing, has
prioritised households headed by women (UNDPI, 2000).

16. This does not appear to be the case in Nicaragua where female heads expressed
a preference to receive help from institutional providers rather than kin or neighbours
(Linneker, 2003). Many women in Costa Rica also seem to have welcomed the
support granted through targeted state initiatives (see Budowksi, 2003).

17. Kabeer (2003:220) points out that Gender-responsive Budget Analysis (GBA)
can potentially promote greater transparency and accountability in policy processes,
as well as help to ‘match policy intent with resource allocation’.

18. One model used in Costa Rica has been that of ‘Community Homes’ (Hogares
Comunitarios). Administered by the Social Welfare Institute (IMAS/Instituto Mixto de
Ayuda Social), and concentrated primarily in low-income settlements, women running
'community homes' are given training in childcare and paid a small state subvention
for looking after other people's children in the neighbourhood. Individuals using this
service pay what they can as a token gesture and lone mothers are technically given
priority for places (see Sancho Montero, 1995).

19. Although this initiative is likely to go some way to improving the economic
conditions of lone mother households in future and may well encourage men to
prevent births, whether it will be sufficient to substantially change long-standing
patterns of paternal neglect remains another issue (Chant, 2001).

20. On the basis of research in the USA, McLanahan (nd:23) points out that:
‘Fathers who are required to pay child support are likely to demand more time with
their children and a greater say in how they are raised, Such demands should lead
to more social capital between the father and child. Similarly, greater father
involvement is likely to lead to less residential mobility, retarding the loss of social
capital in the community’. Potential benefits to children notwithstanding, there may
well be costs for mothers in terms of their freedom to raise the child as they see fit, or
to change residence (ibid.).

21. Engaging men in such ventures might not be as difficult as anticipated given that
some partners in male-headed units willingly comply with these responsibilities
already (see Chant, 2000; Gutmann, 1996,1999), and because in women-headed
households men often perform these roles in their capacities as grandfathers, uncles,
brothers and sons (see Fonseca, 1991).

22. Partly as a response to this, plans are currently underway at IMAS to develop a
project called ‘Apoyémonos’ (‘Let’s Support Each Other’). The main goal will be to
provide personal and collective empowerment and capacity-building in gender
consciousness, rights, self-esteem and so on (encapsulated terminologically as
‘fortalecimiento personal y colectivo’), to groups of men who are partners of women
undergoing equivalent training in the Creciendo Juntas programme (see Note 14),
and/or in the programme ‘Construyendo Oportunidades’ (Building Opportunities) which
caters to pregnant adolescents and teenage mothers (personal communication from
Erika Jiménez Hidalgo and Alison Salazar Lobo, IMAS, San José, May 2003).

50
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Acosta-Belén, Edna and Bose, Christine (1995) 'Colonialism, Structural Subordination and Empowerment:
Women in the Development Process in Latin America and the Caribbean', in Christine Bose and Edna
Acosta-Belén (eds) Women in the Latin American Development Process (Philadelphia: Temple University
Press) 15-36.
Appleton, Simon (1991) 'Gender Dimensions of Structural Adjustment: The Role of Economic Theory and
Quantitative Analysis', IDS Bulletin, 22:1, 17-22.
Appleton, Simon (1996) ‘Women-headed Households and Household Welfare: An Empirical Deconstruction
for Uganda’, World Development, 24:12, 1811-27.
Arriagada, Irma (1998) ‘Latin American Families: Convergences and Divergences in Models and Policies’,
CEPAL Review, 65, 85-102.
Asian Development Bank (ADB) (2000) Women in Pakistan: Country Briefing Paper (Manila: ADB Programs
Department [West] and Office of Environment and Social Development).
Baden, Sally with Milward, Kirsty (1997) Gender, Inequality and Poverty: Trends, Linkages, Analysis and
Policy Implications (Sussex: Institute of Development Studies, Bridge Report No.30).
Baden, Sally and Goetz, Anne Marie (1998) ‘Who Needs [Sex] When You Can Have [Gender]’, in Cecile
Jackson and Ruth Pearson (eds) Feminist Visions of Development: Gender Analysis and Policy (London:
Routledge) 19-38.
Badia, Monica (1999) The Chilean ‘Social Integration; Approach to Poverty Alleviation: The Case of the
Programme for Female Heads of Households (Hertford: University of Hertfordshire Business School,
Employment Studies Paper No.25).
Baulch, Bob (1996) 'Editorial. The New Poverty Agenda: A Disputed Consensus', IDS Bulletin, 27:1, 1-10.
Baylies, Carolyn (1996) 'Diversity in Patterns of Parenting and Household Formation', in Elizabeth Bortolaia
Silva (ed.) Good Enough Mothering? Feminist Perspectives on Lone Motherhood (London: Routledge) 76-
96.
Benería, Lourdes (1991) ‘Structural Adjustment, the Labour Market and the Household: The Case of Mexico’,
in Guy Standing and Victor Tokman (eds) Towards Social Adjustment: Labour Market Issues in Structural
Adjustment (Geneva: International Labour Organisation) 161-83.
Benería, Lourdes and Roldan, Martha (1987) The Crossroads of Class and Gender: Industrial Homework,
Subcontracting and Household Dynamics in Mexico City (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Bibars, Iman (2001) Victims and Heroines: Women, Welfare and the Egyptian State (London: Zed).
Blanc-Szanton, Cristina (1990) 'Gender and Inter-generational Resource Allocation among Thai and Sino-
Thai Households', in Leela Dube and Rajni Palriwala (eds) Structures and Strategies: Women, Work and
Family (New Delhi: Sage) 79-102.
Blumberg, Rae Lesser (1995) 'Introduction: Engendering Wealth and Well-Being in an Era of
Economic Transformation, in Rae Lesser Blumberg, Cathy Rakowski, Irene Tinker and
Michael Monteón (eds) Engendering Wealth and Well-Being: Empowerment for Global
Change (Boulder: Westview) 1-14.
Borges Sugiyama, Natasja (2002) Gendered Budget Work in the Americas: Selected Country Experiences
(Austin: University of Texas at Austin).
Bortolaia Silva, Elizabeth (1996) 'Introduction', in Elizabeth Bortolaia Silva (ed.) Good Enough Mothering?
Feminist Perspectives on Lone Motherhood (London: Routledge) 1-9.
Bradshaw, Sarah (1995a) 'Women's Access to Employment and the Formation of Women-headed
Households in Rural and Urban Honduras', Bulletin of Latin American Research, 14:2, 143-58.
Bradshaw, Sarah (1995b) 'Female-headed Households in Honduras: Perspectives on Rural-Urban
Differences', Third World Planning Review (Special issue on 'Gender and Development') 17:2, 117-31.
Bradshaw, Sarah (1996a) 'Female-headed Households in Honduras: A Study of their Formation and Survival
in Low-income Communities'. Unpublished PhD thesis (Department of Geography, London School of
Economics).
Bradshaw, Sarah (1996b) 'Inequality within Households: The Case of Honduras'. Paper presented at the
symposium 'Vulnerable Groups in Latin American Cities', Annual Conference of the Society of Latin
American Studies, University of Leeds, 29-31 March.
Bradshaw, Sarah (2001) Dangerous Liaisons: Women, Men and Hurricane Mitch (Managua: Puntos de
Encuentro).
Bradshaw, Sarah (2002) Gendered Poverties and Power Relations: Looking Inside Communities and
Households (Managua:ICD, Embajada de Holanda, Puntos de Encuentro).

51
BRIDGE (2001) Briefing Paper on the ‘Feminisation of Poverty’ (prepared for the Swedish International
Developent Cooperation Agency). BRIDGE Report No.59 (Sussex: Institute of Development Studies).
BRIDGE (2003) ‘Gender and Budgets’, Bridge Bulletin: Gender and Development in Brief, Issue 12.
Brown, Suzanne Francis (2000) ‘Women No Cry: Female-Headed Households in the Caribbean’, in Judith
Mirsky and Marty Radlett (eds), No Paradise Yet: The World’s Women Face a New Century (London:
Panos/ Zed) 101-18
Bruce, Judith and Lloyd, Cynthia (1992) Finding the Ties That Bind: Beyond Headship and the Household
(New York/Washington DC: Population Council/International Center for Research on Women).
Brydon, Lynne and Legge, Karen (1996) Adjusting Society: The IMF, the World Bank and Ghana (London:
I.B.Tauris).
Budlender, Debbie (2000) A Global Assessment of Gender Responsive Budget Initiatives (Washington DC:
World Bank) (www.worldbank.org/wbi/ publicfinance/ documents/ gender/budlender.pdf).
Budlender, Debbie and Hewitt, Guy (eds) (2002) Gender Budgets Make More Cents: Country Studies and
Good Practice (London: Commonwealth Secretariat).
Budowksi, Monica (2002) ‘Lone Motherhood in Costa Rica: A Threat for Society or a Chance for Change?’,
in Christian Giordano and Andrea Boscoboinik (eds) Constructing Risk, Threat, Catastrophe (Fribourg:
University Press Fribourg Switzerland) 121-43.
Budowski, Monica (2003) ‘“Yo Valgo”. The Importance of Dignity for Daily Practice: Lone Mothers
in Costa Rica’ (Fribourg: University of Fribourg Switzerland, Habilitation manuscript).
Budowski, Monica and Guzmán, Laura (1998) ‘Strategic Gender Interests in Social Policy: Empowerment
Training for Female Heads of Household in Costa Rica’. Paper presented at the International Sociological
Association XIV World Congress of Sociology, Montreal, 26 July - 1 August.
Budowski, Monica and Rosero Bixby, Luis (2003) ‘Fatherless Costa Rica? Child
Acknowledgement and Support Among Lone Mothers’, Journal of Comparative Family
Studies, 34:2, 229-54.
Budowski, Monica; Tillman, Robin and Bergman, Manfred Max (2002) ‘Poverty, Stratification, and Gender in
Switzerland’, Swiss Journal of Sociology, 28:2, 297-317.
Bullock, Susan (1994) Women and Work (London: Zed).
Buvinic, Mayra (1990) 'The Vulnerability of Women-headed Households: Policy Questions and Options for
Latin America and the Caribbean'. Paper presented at the Economic Commission for Latin America and
the Caribbean Meeting on 'Vulnerable Women', Vienna, 26-30 November.
Buvinic, Mayra (1995) Investing in Women (Washington DC: International Center for Research on Women,
Policy Series).
Buvinic, Mayra and Gupta, Geeta Rao (1993) 'Responding to Insecurity in the 1990s: Targeting Woman-
headed Households and Woman-maintained Families in Developing Countries'. Paper presented at the
International Workshop 'Insecurity in the 1990s: Gender and Social Policy in an International Perspective',
London School of Economics and European Association of Development Institutes, London, 5-6 April.
Buvinic, Mayra and Gupta, Geeta Rao (1997) ‘Female-headed Households and Female-Maintained Families:
Are They Worth Targeting to Reduce Poverty in Developing Countries?’, Economic Development and
Cultural Change, 45:2, 259-80.
Cagatay, Nilüfer (1998) Gender and Poverty (New York: United Nations Development Programme, Social
Development and Poverty Elimination Division, Working Paper 5).
Chambers, Robert (1983) Rural Development: Putting the Last First (Harlow: Longman).
Chambers, Robert (1988) Poverty in India: Concepts, Research and Reality (Brighton: University of Sussex,
IDS Discussion Paper No.241).
Chambers, Robert (1989) 'Vulnerability: How the Poor Cope', IDS Bulletin, 20:2,1-9.
Chambers, Robert (1995) 'Poverty and Livelihoods: Whose Reality Counts?', Environment and Urbanisation,
7:1, 173-204.
Chant, Sylvia (1991a) Women and Survival in Mexican Cities: Perspectives on Gender, Labour Markets and
Low-income Households (Manchester: Manchester University Press).
Chant, Sylvia (1991b) 'Gender, Households and Seasonal Migration in Guanacaste, Costa Rica', European
Review of Latin American and Caribbean Studies, 50, 51-85.
Chant, Sylvia (1996) Gender,Urban Development and Housing (New York: United Nations Development
Programme, Publications Series for Habitat II, Volume 2).
Chant, Sylvia (1997a) Women-headed Households: Diversity and Dynamics in the Developing World
(Houndmills, Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Chant, Sylvia (1997b) ‘Women-headed Households: Poorest of the Poor? Perspectives from Mexico, Costa
Rica and the Philippines’, IDS Bulletin, 28:3, 26-48.

52
Chant, Sylvia (1999) ‘Women-headed Households: Global Orthodoxies and Grassroots Realities’, in Haleh
Afshar and Stephanie Barrientos (eds) Women, Globalisation and Fragmentation in the Developing World
(Houndmills, Basingstoke: Macmillan) 91-130.
Chant, Sylvia (2000) ‘Men in Crisis? Reflections on Masculinities, Work and Family in North-West Costa
Rica’, European Journal of Development Research, 12:2, 199-218.
Chant, Sylvia (2001) ‘Female Household Headship, Privation and Power: Challenging the “Feminisation of
Poverty” Thesis’. Working paper No.01-09b (Princeton: Center for Migration and Development: University
of Princeton).
Chant, Sylvia (2002) ‘Whose Crisis? Public and Popular Reactions to Family Change in Costa Rica’, in
Christopher Abel and Colin Lewis (eds) Exclusion and Engagement: Social Policy in Latin America
(London: Institute of Latin American Studies) 349-77.
Chant, Sylvia with Craske, Nikki (2003) Gender in Latin America (London/New Brunswick: Latin America
Bureau/Rutgers University Press).
Chant, Sylvia and Gutmann, Matthew (2000) Mainstreaming Men into Gender and Development: Debates,
Reflections and Experiences (Oxford: Oxfam).
Chant, Sylvia and McIlwaine, Cathy (1995) Women of a Lesser Cost: Female Labour, Foreign Exchange and
Philippine Development (London: Pluto).
Chen, Marty and Drèze, Jean (1992) ‘Widows and Health in Rural North India’. Paper presented at workshop
on ‘Health and Development in India’, National Council of Applied Economic Research and the Harvard
Center for Population and Development Studies, India International Center, New Delhi, 2-4 January.
Christopher, Karen; England, Paula; McLanahan, Sara; Ross, Katherin and Smeeding, Tim (2001) ‘Gender
Inequaliity in Affluent Nations: The Role of Single Motherhood and the State’, in Koen Vleminckx and Tim
Smeeding (eds) Child Well-Being in Modern Nations (Bristol: The Policy Press).
Collins, Stephen (1991) 'The Transition from Lone-Parent Family to Step-Family', in Michael Hardey and
Graham Crow (eds) Lone-Parenthood: Coping with Constraints and Making Opportunities (Hemel
Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf) 156-75.
Comisión Económica para América Latina (CEPAL) (2001)Panorama Social de América Latina 2000-2001
(Santiago: CEPAL).
Cornwall, Andrea (2000) ‘Missing Men? Reflections on Men, Masculinities and Gender in GAD’, IDS Bulletin,
31:2, 18-27.
Cornwall, Andrea and Lindisfarne, Nancy (1994) ‘Dislocating Masculinity: Gender, Power
and Anthropology’, in Andrea Cornwall and Nancy Lindisfarne (eds) Dislocating
Masculinity: Comparative Ethnographies (London: Routledge) 1-47.
Cornwall, Andrea and White, Sarah (2000) ‘Men, Masculinities and Development:
Politics, Policies and Practice’, IDS Bulletin, 31:2, 1-6.
Davids, Tine and Driel, Francien van (2001) ‘Globalisation and Gender: Beyond Dichotomies’, in Frans J.
Schuurman (ed.) Globalisation and Development Studies Challenges for the 21st Century (London: Sage)
153-75.
Department for International Development (DFID) (2000) Poverty Elimination and the Empowerment of
Women (London:DFID).
Dia, Ibrahima Amadou (2001) ‘“Feminisation” of Poverty, Informal Sector and Masculinity in a Global Area:
The Experience of Senegalese Women’. Paper prepared for Research Committee 19 on Poverty, Social
Welfare and Social Policy, University of Oviedo, Spain, 6-9 September.
Driel, Francien van (1994) Poor and Powerful: Female-headed Households and Unmarried Motherhood in
Botswana (Saarbrücken: Verlag für Entwicklungspolitik Breitenbach GmbH, Nijmegen Studies 16).
Dwyer, Daisy and Bruce, Judith (eds) (1988) A Home Divided: Women and Income in the Third World
(Stanford: Stanford University Press).
Edwards, Rosalind and Duncan, Simon (1996) 'Lone Mothers and Economic Activity', in Fiona Williams (ed.)
Social Policy: A Reader (Cambridge: Polity Press).
Elson, Diane (1995) ‘Gender Awareness in Modelling Structural Adjustment’, World Development, 32:11,
1851-68.
Elson, Diane (1999) ‘Labour Markets as Gendered Institutions: Equality, Efficiency
and Empowerment Issues’, World Development, 27:3, 611-27.
Elson, Diane (2002) ‘Gender Justice, Human Rights and Neo-liberal Economic Policies’, in Maxine
Molyneux and Shahra Razavi (eds) Gender Justice, Development and Rights (Oxford: Oxford University
Press) 78-114.

53
England, Paula and Folbre, Nancy (2002) ‘Involving Dads: Parental Bargaining and Family Well- Being’, in
Catherine Tamis-LeMonda and Natasha Cabrera (eds) Handbook of Father Involvement:
Multidisciplinary Perspectives (Mahwah, New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates).
Engle, Patrice L. (1995) ‘Father’s Money, Mother’s Money, and Parental Commitment:
Guatemala and Nicaragua’ in Rae Lesser Blumberg, Cathy Rakowski, Irene Tinker and
Michael Monteón (eds) Engendering Wealth and Well-Being: Empowerment for Global
Change (Boulder: Westview) 155-79.
Escobar Latapí, Agustín (1998) ‘Los Hombres y Sus Historias: Reestructuración y
Masculinidad en México’, La Ventana (Universidad de Guadalajara) 122-73.
Fauné, María Angélica (1997) ‘Costa Rica: Las Inequidades de Género en el Marco de la
Apertura Comercial y la Reestructuración Productiva: Análsis a Nivel Macro, Meso, Micro’
in Diane Elson, María Angélica Fauné, Jasmine Gideon, Maribel Gutiérrez, Armida López de
Mazier and Eduardo Sacayón (eds) Crecer con la Mujer: Oportunidades para el
Desarrollo Económico Centroamericano (San José: Embajada Real de los Países Bajos) 51-
126.
Feijoó, María del Carmen (1999) ‘De Pobres Mujeres a Mujeres Pobres’ in Mercedes
González de la Rocha (ed.) Divergencias del Modelo Tradicional: Hogares de Jefatura
Femenina en América Latina (México DF: Centro de Investigaciones y Estudios Superiores
en Antropología Social) 155-62.
Fernández-Kelly, María Patricia (1983) 'Mexican Border Industrialisation, Female Labour Force Participation
and Migration', in June Nash and María Patricia Fernández-Kelly (eds) Women, Men and the International
Division of Labour (Albany: State University of New York Press) 205-23.
Finne, Giselle (2001) ‘Feminisation of Poverty’ (Geneva: World Alliance of YMCAs, Global Programmes and
Issues) (http://www.ywca.int/programs).
Floro, Maria Sagrario (1995) ‘Women’s Well-Being, Poverty and Work Intensity’, Feminist
Economics, 1:3, 1-25.
Folbre, Nancy (1991) 'Women on their Own: Global Patterns of Female Headship', in Rita S. Gallin and Ann
Ferguson (eds) The Women and International Development Annual Vol.2 (Boulder: Westview) 69-126.
Folbre, Nancy (1994) Who Pays for the Kids? Gender and the Structures of Constraint (London: Routledge).
Fonseca, Claudia (1991) 'Spouses, Siblings and Sex-linked Bonding: A Look at Kinship Organisation in a
Brazilian Slum', in Elizabeth Jelin (ed.) Family, Household and Gender Relations in Latin America (London:
Kegan Paul International/Paris:UNESCO) 133-60.
Ford, Reuben (1996) Childcare in the Balance: How Lone Parents Make Decisions About Work (London:
Policy Studies Institute).
Fukuda-Parr, Sakiko (1999) ‘What Does Feminisation of Poverty Mean? It Isn’t Just
Lack of Income’, Feminist Economics, 5:2, 99-103.
Fuller, Norma (2000) ‘Work and Masculinity Among Peruvian Urban Men’, European Journal
of Development Research, 12:2, 93-114.
Funkhouser, Edward (1996) ‘The Urban Informal Sector in Central America: Household
Survey Evidence’, World Development, 12:11, 1737-51.
Fuwa, Nobuhiko (2000) ‘The Poverty and Heterogeneity Among Female-headed Households
Revisited: The Case of Panama’, World Development, 28:8, 1515-42.
Gafar, John (1998) ‘Growth, Inequality and Poverty in Selected Caribbean and Latin American
Countries, with Emphasis on Guyana’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 30:3, 591-617.
Geldstein, Rosa (1994) ‘Working Class Mothers as Economic Providers and Heads of Families
in Buenos Aires’, Reproductive Health Matters, 4, 55-64.
Geldstein, Rosa (1997) Mujeres Jefas de Hogar: Familia, Pobreza y Género (Buenos Aires:
UNICEF-Argentina).
Goldstein, Markus (2003) ‘Intra-household Efficiency and Individual Insurance in Ghana’.
Paper in preparation, DESTIN, London School of Economics.
Goldstein, Markus; de Janvry, Alain and Sadoulet, Elisabeth (2001) ‘Is a Friend in Need a
Friend Indeed? Inclusion and Exclusion in Mutural Insurance Networks in Southern Ghana’.
Paper prepared for ‘Insurance Against Poverty’ programme, World Institute for
Development Economics Research (WIDER), United Nations University, Helsinki.
Gomáriz, Enrique (1997) Introducción a los Estudios Sobre la Masculinidad (San José: Centro
Nacional para el Desarrollo de la Mujer y Familia).
González de la Rocha, Mercedes (1988) 'De Por Qué las Mujeres Aguantan Golpes y Cuernos: Un Análsis
de Hogares sin Varón en Guadalajara', in Luisa Gabayet et al (eds) Mujeres y Sociedad: Salario, Hogar y

54
Acción Social en el Occidente de México (Guadalajara: El Colegio de Jalisco/CIESAS del Occidente) 205-
27.
González de la Rocha, Mercedes (1994a) The Resources of Poverty: Women and Survival in a Mexican City
(Oxford: Blackwell)
González de la Rocha, Mercedes (1994b) 'Household Headship and Occupational Position in Mexico', in
Eileen Kennedy and Mercedes González de la Rocha, Poverty and Well-Being in the Household: Case
Studies of the Developing World (San Diego: Center for Iberian and Latin American Studies, University of
California San Diego) 1-24.
González de la Rocha, Mercedes (1999) ‘A Manera de Introducción: Cambio Social, Transformación de la
Familia y Divergencias del Modelo Tradicional’, in Mercedes González de la Rocha (ed.) Divergencias del
Modelo Tradicional: Hogares de Jefatura Femenina en América Latina (México DF: Centro de
Investigaciones y Estudios Superiores en Antropología Social/Plaza y Valdés Editores) 19-36.
González de la Rocha, Mercedes (2001) ‘’From the Resources of Poverty to the Poverty of Resources: The
Erosion of a Survival Model’, Latin American Perspectives, 28:4, 72-100.
González de la Rocha, Mercedes (2002) ‘The Urban Family and Poverty in Latin America’, in Jennifer Abassi
and Sheryl L. Lutjens (eds) Rereading Women in Latin America and the Caribbean: The Political
Economy of Gender (Lanham, Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield) 61-77.
González de la Rocha, Mercedes and Grinspun, Alejandro (2001) ‘Private Adjustments: Households, Crisis
and Work’, in Alejandro Grinspun (ed.) Choices for the Poor: Lessons from National Poverty Strategies
(New York:UNDP) 55-87.
Government of the Gambia (GOG) (2000) 1998 National Household Poverty Survey Report (Banjul:
Department of State for Finance and Economic Affairs).
Graham, Hilary (1987) 'Being Poor: Perceptions and Coping Strategies of Lone Mothers', in Julia Brannen
and Gail Wilson (eds) Give and Take in Families: Studies in Resource Distribution (London: Allen and
Unwin) 56-74.
Grosh, Margaret (1994) Administering Targeted Social Programs in Latin America: From Platitudes to
Practice (Washington DC: World Bank).
Gutmann, Matthew (1996) The Meanings of Macho: Being a Man in Mexico City (Berkeley:
University of California Press).
Gutmann, Matthew (1999) ‘A Manera de Conclusión: Solteras y Hombres. Cambio e Historia’
in González de la Rocha, Mercedes (ed.) Divergencias del Modelo Tradicional: Hogares de
Jefatura Femenina en América Latina (México DF: Centro de Investigaciones y Estudios
Superiores en Antropología Social) 163-72.
Hackenberg, Robert; Murphy, Arthur and Selby, Henry (1981) 'The Household in the Secondary Cities of the
Third World'. Paper prepared in advance for the Wenner-Gren Foundation Symposium 'Households:
Changing Form and Function', New York, 8-15 October.
Hardey, Michael and Glover, Judith (1991) 'Income, Employment, Daycare and Lone Parenthood', in Michael
Hardey and Graham Crow (eds) Lone Parenthood: Coping with Constraints and Making Opportunities
(Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf) 88-109.
Harris, Olivia (1981) ‘Households as Natural Units’ in Kate Young, Carol Wolkowitz and Roslyn McCullogh
(eds) Of Marriage and the Market (London:CSE Books) 48-67.
Hart, Gillian (1997) ‘From “Rotten Wives” to “Good Mothers”: Household Models and the Limits of
Economism’, IDS Bulletin, 28:3, 14-25.
Hewitt, Patricia and Leach, Penelope (1993) Social Justice, Children and Families (London: Institute for
Public Policy Research).
Hobson, Barbara (1994) 'Solo Mothers, Social Policy Regimes and the Logics of Gender', in Diane Sainsbury
(ed.) Gendering Welfare States (London: Sage) 170-88.
Hoddinott, John and Haddad, Lawrence (1991) Household Expenditures, Child Anthropomorphic Status and
the Intra-Household Division of Income: Evidence from the Côte d'Ivoire (Oxford: University of Oxford, Unit
for the Study of African Economics).
International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) (1999) The Issue of Poverty Among Female-headed
Households in Africa (Rome: IFAD) (http://www.ifad.org/gender/learning/challenges/women/60.htm).
Instituto Mixto de Ayuda Social (IMAS) (2001) Area Atención Integral para el Desarrollo de
las Mujeres. Programas: Creciendo Juntas, Construyendo Oportunidades (San José:
IMAS).
Instituto Nacional de la Mujeres (INAMU) (2001) Responsible Paternity Law (San José:INAMU).
International Labour Organisation (ILO) (1996) ‘All Women are Working Women: The Feminisation of
Poverty’ (Geneva: ILO) (http://www.ilo-mirror.cornell.edu).

55
Jackson, Cecile (1996) ‘Rescuing Gender from the Poverty Trap’, World Development, 24:3,
489-504.
Jackson, Cecile (1997) ‘Post Poverty, Gender and Development’, IDS Bulletin, 28:3, 145-55.
Jackson, Cecile (1998) ‘Rescuing Gender From the Poverty Trap’, in Cecile Jackson and Ruth Pearson (eds)
Feminist Visions of Development: Gender Analysis and Policy (London: Routledge) 39-64.
Jackson, Cecile and Palmer-Jones, Richard (1999) ‘Rethinking Gendered Poverty and Work’, Development
and Change, 30:3, 557-83.
Kabeer, Naila (1994) Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought (London: Verso).
Kabeer, Naila (1996) 'Agency, Well-being and Inequality: Reflections on the Gender Dimensions of Poverty',
IDS Bulletin, 27:1, 11-21.
Kabeer, Naila (1997) ‘Editorial. Tactics and Trade-offs: Revisiting the Links Between Gender and Poverty’,
IDS Bulletin, 28:3, 1-25.
Kabeer, Naila (1999) ‘Resources, Agency, Achievements: Reflections on the Measurement of
Women’s Empowerment’, Development and Change, 30:3, 435-64.
Kabeer, Naila (2003) Gender Mainstreaming in Poverty Eradication and the Millennium Development
Goals: A Handbook for Policy-makers and Other Stakeholders (London: Commonwealth Secretariat)
Kaztman, Rubén (1992) ‘Por Qué Los Hombres son Tan Irresponsables?’, Revista de la CEPAL, 46, 1-9.
Kennedy, Eileen (1994) 'Development Policy, Gender of Head of Household, and Nutrition', in Eileen
Kennedy and Mercedes González de la Rocha, Poverty and Well-Being in the Household: Case Studies of
the Developing World (San Diego: Center for Iberian and Latin American Studies, University of California
San Diego) 25-42.
Kusakabe, Kyoko (2002) ‘Vulnerability of Female-headed Households in Cambodia’. Paper presented at
workshop ‘Family, Gender and Health’, Centre for Family and Women’s Studies, Hanoi, 11-13 December.
Kumari, Ranjana (1989) Women-headed Households in Rural India (New Delhi: Radiant Publishers).
Lancaster, Roger (1992) Life is Hard: Machismo, Danger and the Intimacy of Power in Nicaragua (Berkeley:
University of California Press).
Lara, Silvia with Barry, Tom and Simonson, Peter (1995) Inside Costa Rica (Albuquerque: Resource Center
Press).
Laws, Sophie (1996) 'The Single Mothers Debate: A Children's Rights Perspective', in Janet Holland and Lisa
Adkins (eds) Sex, Sensibility and the Gendered Body (Houndmills, Basingstoke: Macmillan) 60-77.
Leach, Fiona (1999) ‘Women in the Informal Sector: The Contribution of Education and Training’, in Oxfam
Development for Women (Oxford: Oxfam) 46-62.
Lewis, David (1993) 'Going It Alone: Female-Headed Households, Rights and Resources in Rural
Bangladesh', European Journal of Development Research, 5:2, 23-42.
Lewis, Jane (1989) 'Lone Parent Families: Politics and Economics', Journal of Social Policy, 18:4, 595-600.
Lind, Amy (1997) ‘Gender, Development and Urban Social Change: Women’s Community Action in Global
Cities’, World Development, 25:8, 1187-203.
Linneker, Brian (2003) ‘Gender Comparisons of Capital Influences on the Well-Being of Women and
Households Experiencing Poverty in Nicaragua’, Working Draft Report, Coordinadora Civil - Nicaragua
(CCER) Managua.
Lloyd, Cynthia and Gage-Brandon, Anastasia (1993) 'Women's Role in Maintaining Households: Family
Welfare and Sexual Inequality in Ghana', Population Studies, 47, 115-31.
López de Mazier, Armida (1997) ‘La Mujer, Principal Sostén del Modelo Económico de
Honduras: Un Análisis de Género de la Economía Hondureña’ in Diane Elson, María
Angélica Fauné, Jasmine Gideon, Maribel Gutiérrez, Armida López de Mazier and Eduardo
Sacayón Crecer con la Mujer: Oportunidades para el Desarrollo Ecónomico
Centroamericano (San José: Embajada Real de los Países Bajos) 215-52.
Mädge, E. and Neusüss, C. (1994) 'Lone Mothers on Welfare in West Berlin: Disadvantaged Citizens or
Women Avoiding Patriarchy?', Environment and Planning, A, 26, 1419-33.
Marcoux, Alain (1997) The Feminisation of Poverty: Facts, Hypotheses and the Art of Advocacy. (Rome:
Food and Agriculture Organisation, Population Programme Service, Women and Population Division).
Marenco, Leda; Trejos, Ana María; Trejos, Juan Diego and Vargas, Marienela (1998) Del Silencio a la
Palabra: Un Modelo de Trabajo con las Mujeres Jefas del Hogar (San José: Segunda Vicepresidencia).
May, Julian (2001) ‘A Elusive Consensus: Definitions, Measurement and the Analysis of Poverty’, in Alejandro
Grinspun (ed.) Choices for the Poor: Lessons from National Poverty Strategies (New York:UNDP) 23-54.
Mayoux, Linda (2002) ‘Women’s Empowerment or the Feminisation of Debt? Towards a New Agenda in
African Microfinance’. Paper given at One World Action Conference, London, 21-22 March
(http://www.oneworldaction.org/Background.htm).

56
McIlwaine, Cathy (1997) 'Vulnerable or Poor? A Study of Ethnic and Gender Disadvantage among Afro-
Caribbeans in Limón, Costa Rica’, European Journal of Development Research, 9:2, 35-61.
McIlwaine, Cathy (2002) ‘Perspectives on Poverty, Vulnerability and Exclusion’, in Cathy
McIlwaine and Katie Willis (eds) Challenges and Change in Middle America: Perspectives
on Mexico, Central America and the Caribbean (Harlow: Pearson Education).
McLanahan, Sara (nd) ‘Father Absence and the Welfare of Children’ (MacArthur Research
Network on the Family and the Economy, working paper)
(http://www.olin.wustl.edu/macarthur).
McLanahan, Sara and Kelly, Erin (nd) ‘The Feminisation of Poverty: Past and Future’
(MacArthur Research Network on the Family and the Economy, working paper
(http://www.olin.wustl.edu/macarthur).
Mehra, Rekha; Esim, Simel and Simms, Margaret (2000) Fulfilling the Beijing Commitment:
Reducing Poverty, Enhancing Women’s Economic Options (Washington DC: International
Center for Research on Women).
Menjívar, Rafael and Trejos, Juan Diego (1992) La Pobreza en América Central, 2nd ed. (San José:
FLACSO).
Menjívar Ochoa, Mauricio (2002) Actitudes Masculinas Hacia la Paternidad: Entre las
Contradicciones del Mandato y el Involucramiento (San José: Instituto Nacional de las
Mujeres, Colección Teórica No.2).
Merrick,Thomas and Schmink, Marianne (1983) 'Households Headed by Women and Urban Poverty in
Brazil', in Mayra Buvinic, Margaret Lycette and Wiliam McGreevey (eds) Women and Poverty in the Third
World (Baltimore: John Hopkins Universiy Press) 244-71.
Millar, Jane (1992) 'Lone Mothers and Poverty', in Caroline Glendinning and Jane Millar (eds) Women and
Poverty in Britain in the 1990s (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf) 149-61.
Millar, Jane (1996) 'Mothers, Workers, Wives: Comparing Policy Approaches to Supporting Lone Mothers', in
Elizabeth Bortolaia Silva (ed.) Good Enough Mothering? Feminist Perspectives on Lone Motherhood
(London: Routledge) 97-113.
Moghadam, Valentine (1997) The Feminisation of Poverty: Notes on a Concept and Trend. (Normal: Illinois
State University, Women’s Studies Occasional Paper No.2).
Molyneux, Maxine (2001) Women’s Movements in International Perspective: Latin America and Beyond
(Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave).
Molyneux, Maxine (2002) ‘Gender and the Silences of Social Capital: Lessons from
Latin America’, Development and Change, 33, 167-88.
Monk, Sue (1993) From the Margins to the Mainstream: An Employment Strategy for Lone Parents (London:
National Council for One-Parent Families).
Moore, Henrietta (1994) Is There a Crisis in the Family? (Geneva: World Summit for Social Development,
Occasional Paper No.3).
Moore, Henrietta (1996) 'Mothering and Social Responsibilities in a Cross-cultural Perspective', in Elizabeth
Bortolaia Silva (ed.) Good Enough Mothering? Feminist Perspectives on Lone Motherhood (London:
Routledge) 58-75.
Moore, Henrietta and Vaughan, Megan (1994) Cutting Down Trees: Gender, Nutrition and Agricultural
Change in the Northern Province of Zambia, 1890-1990 (Portsmouth, New Jersey: Heinemann).
Moser, Caroline (1996) Confronting Crisis: A Comparative Study of Household Responses to Poverty in Four
Poor Urban Communities (Washington DC: Environmentally Sustainable Development Studies and
Monographs Series No.8).
Moser, Caroline (1998) ‘The Asset Vulnerability Framework: Reassessing Urban Poverty Reduction
Strategies’, World Development, 26:1, 1-19.
Moser, Caroline; Gatehouse, Michael and Garcia, Helen (1996a) Urban Poverty Research Sourcebook.
Module I: Sub-city Level Household Survey (Washington DC: UNDP/UNCHS/World Bank - Urban
Management Program, Working Paper Series 5).
Moser, Caroline; Gatehouse, Michael and Garcia, Helen (1996b) Urban Poverty Research Sourcebook.
Module II: Indicators of Urban Poverty (Washington DC: UNDP/UNCHS/World Bank - Urban Management
Program, Working Paper Series 5).
Moser, Caroline and McIlwaine, Cathy (1997) Household Responses to Poverty and Vulnerability, Volume 3:
Confronting Crisis in Commonwealth, Metro Manila, Philippines (Washington DC: World Bank, Urban
Management Programme).
Muthwa, Sibongile (1993) 'Household Survival, Urban Poverty and Female Household Headship in Soweto:
Some Key Issues for Further Policy Research'. Paper given in seminar series 'The Societies of Southern

57
Africa in the 19th and 20th Centuries: Women, Colonialism and Commonwealth', Institute of
Commonwealth Studies, University of London, 19 November.
Oliver, Chloe (2002) ‘Female-headed Households: Diverse and Disadvantaged? An Investigation into
Households Headed by Women in Low-income Neighbourhoods of Montevideo, Uruguay’. Unpublished
BA dissertation, Department of Geography, University College London.
Oppong, Christine (1997) ‘African Family Systems and Socio-economic Crisis’, in Aderanti Adepoju (ed)
Family, Population and Develpment in Africa (London: Zed) 158-82.
Panda, Pradeep Kumar (1997) ‘Female Headship, Poverty and Child Welfare: A Study of Rural Orissa’,
Economic and Political Weekly, 25 October, 73-82.
Palmer, Ingrid (1992) ‘Gender, Equity and Economic Efficiency in Adjustment Programmes’, in Haleh Afshar
and Carolyne Dennis (eds.) Women and Adjustment Policies in the Third World (Houndmills: Macmillan)
69-83.
Pankhurst, Helen (2002) ‘Passing the Buck? Money Literacy and Alternatives to Savings and Credit
Schemes’, Gender and Development, 10:3, 10-21.
Paolisso, Michael and Gammage, Sarah (1996) Women's Responses to Environmental Degradation: Case
Studies From Latin America (Washington DC: International Center for Research on Women).
Phoenix, Ann (1996) 'Social Constructions of Lone Motherhood: A Case of Competing Discourses', in
Elizabeth Bortolaia Silva (ed.) Good Enough Mothering? Feminist Perspectives on Lone Motherhood
(London: Routledge) 175-90.
Proctor, Sharon (2003) ‘Gender, Livelihoods and Labour in Rural Mexican Households: The Impact of Neo-
liberal Reform upon the Farm and Non-Farm Economy’, Unpublished PhD dissertation, Department of
Agricultural and Food Economics, University of Reading.
Quisumbing, Agnes; Haddad, Lawrence and Peña, Christine (1995) Gender and Poverty: New Evidence from
Ten Developing Countries (Washington DC: International Food Policy Research Institute, Food
Consumption and Nutrition Division, Discussion Paper No.9).
Rai, Shirin (2002) Gender and the Political Economy of Development (Cambridge: Polity).
Rakodi, Carole (1999) ‘A Capital Assets Framework for Analysing Household Livelihood Strategies:
Implications for Policy’, Development Policy Review, 17, 315-42.
Rakodi, Carole with Lloyd-Jones, Tony (2002) (eds) Urban Livelihoods: A People-Centred Approach to
Reducing Poverty (London: Earthscan).
Razavi, Shahra (1999) ‘Gendered Poverty and Well-Being: Introduction’, Development and Change, 30:3,
409-33.
Rico de Alonso, Ana and López Téllez, Nadia (1998) ‘Informalidad, Jefatura Femenina y Supervivencia’,
Revista Javeriana (September) 193-7.
Rogers, Beatrice (1995) ‘Alternative Definitions of Female Headship in the Dominican Republic’, World
Development, 23:12, 2033-9.
Roseneil, Sasha and Mann, Kirk (1996) 'Unpalatable Choices and Inadequate Families: Lone Mothers and
the Underclass Debate', in Elizabeth Bortolaia Silva (ed.) Good Enough Mothering? Feminist Perspectives
on Lone Motherhood (London: Routledge) 191-210.
Safa, Helen (1990) 'Women and Industrialisation in the Caribbean', in Sharon Stichter and Jane Parpart (eds)
Women, Employment and the Family in the International Division of Labour (Basingstoke: Macmillan) 72-
97.
Safa, Helen (1995) The Myth of the Male Breadwinner: Women and Industrialisation in the Caribbean
(Boulder: Westview).
Safa, Helen (2002) ‘Questioning Globalisation: Gender and Export Processing in the Dominican Republic’,
Journal of Developing Societies, 18:2-3, 11-31.
Safa, Helen and Antrobus, Peggy (1992) 'Women and the Economic Crisis in the Caribbean', in Lourdes
Beneria and Shelley Feldman (eds) Unequal Burden: Economic Crises, Persistent Poverty and Women's
Work (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press) 49-82.
Sancho Montero, Silvia María (1995) El Programa Hogares Comunitarios en Costa Rica,
Sus Primeros Pasos: Primera Parte (San José: Institute Mixto de Ayuda Social,
Dirección Hogares Comunitarios).
Scott, Alison MacEwen (1994) Divisions and Solidarities: Gender, Class and Employment in Latin America
(London: Routledge)
Selby, Henry; Murphy, Arthur and Lorenzen, Stephen (1990) The Mexican Urban Household: Organising for
Self-Defence (Austin: University of Texas Press).
Sen, Amartya K. (1981) Poverty and Famines (Oxford: Clarendon Press).

58
Sen, Amartya K. (1985) Commodities and Capabilities (Helsinki: United Nations University, World Institute for
Development Economics Research).
Sen, Amartya K. (1987a) Hunger and Entitlements (Amsterdam: North Holland Press).
Sen, Amartya K. (1987b) Gender and Cooperative Conflicts (Helsinki: World Institute for Development
Economics Research, Working Paper No.18).
Sen, Amartya K. (1990) 'Gender and Cooperative Conflicts', in Irene Tinker (ed.)Persistent Inequalities:
Women and World Development (New York: Oxford University Press) 123-49.
Sen, Gita (1999) ‘Engendering Poverty Alleviation: Challenges and Opportunities’, Development and Change,
30:3, 685-92.
Sethuraman, S.V. (1998) Gender, Informality and Poverty: A Global Review. Gender Bias in Female Informal
Employment and Incomes in Developing Countries (Geneva/Cambridge, Mass/Washington DC: Women in
Informal Employment Globalising and Organising (WIEGO)/World Bank).
Shanthi, K. (1994) 'Growing Incidence of Female Household Headship: Causes and Cure', Social Action
(New Delhi) 44, 17-33.
Silberschmidt, Margrethe (1999) ‘Women Forget that Men are the Masters’: Gender Antagonism and
Socio-economic Change in Kisii District, Kenya (Uppsala:
Nordiska Afrikainstitute).
Solórzano, Irela; Abaunza, Humberto and Bradshaw, Sarah (2000) ‘Evaluación de la Campaña “Violencia
Contra las Mujeres: Un Desastre que los Hombres Sí Podemos Evitar”’. Mimeo. (Managua: Puntos de
Encuentro).
Stacey, Judith (1997) ‘The Neo-Family-Values Campaign’, in Roger Lancaster and Michaela di Leonardo
(eds) The Gender/Sexuality Reader (New York: Routledge) 432-70.
Sweetman, Caroline (2002) ‘Editorial’, Gender and Development, 10:3, 2-9.
Tasies Castro, Esperanza (1996) 'Mujer, Pobreza y Conflicto Social', Ciencias Sociales (FLACSO, San José)
71, 39-32.
Thomas, Susan (1994) ‘From the Culture of Poverty to the Culture of Single Motherhood: The New Poverty
Paradigm’, Women and Politics, 14:2, 65-97.
Thomas, J.J. (1995) Surviving in the City: The Urban Informal Sector in Latin America (London: Pluto).
Tinker, Irene (1990) 'A Context for the Field and for the Book', in Irene Tinker (ed.) Persistent Inequalities:
Women and World Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press) 3-13.
Tinker, Irene (1997) Street Foods: Urban Food and Employment in Developing Countries (New York: Oxford
University Press).
Tinker, Irene (forthcoming) ‘The Many Paths to Power: Women in Contemporary Asia’, in Christine Huefeldt,
Jennifer Troutner and Peter Smith (eds), Building New Societies: Women in Asia and Latin America
(Lanham, Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield).
Todes, Alison and Walker, Norah (1993) ‘Women and Housing Policy in South Africa: A Discussion of Durban
Case Studies’, in Hemalata Dandekar (ed.) Women, Shelter and Development: First and Third World
Perspectives (George Wahr: Ann Arbor, Michigan) 41-53.
Tokman, Victor (1989) ‘Policies for a Heterogeneous Informal Sector in Latin America’, World Development,
17:7, 1067-76.
Townsend, Janet; Zapata, Emma; Rowlands, Jo; Alberti, Pilar and Mercado, Marta (1999) Women and
Power: Fighting Patriarchies and Poverty (London: Zed).
Trejos, Juan Diego and Montiel, Nancy (1999) El Capital de los Pobres en Costa Rica: Acceso, Utilización y
Rendimiento (Washington DC: IADB).
United Nations (1996) Food Security for All, Food Security for Rural Women (Geneva: International Steering
Committee on the Economic Advancement of Rural Women).
United Nations (UN) (2000) The World’s Women 2000: Trends and Statistics (New York: United Nations).
United Nations Children’s Fund (UNICEF) (1997) Role of Men in the Lives of Children: A Study of How
Improving Knowledge About Men in Families Helps Strengthen Programming for Children and Women
(New York: UNICEF).
United Nations Department of Public Information (UNDPI) (2000) ‘Women 2000: The Feminisation of Poverty
- Fact sheet No.1’ (http://www.un.org/womenwatch/daw/followup).
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (1995) Human Development Report 1995 (Oxford: Oxford
University Press).
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (2001) Human Development Report 2001 (Oxford: Oxford
University Press).

59
United Nations Division for the Advancement of Women (UNDAW) (1991) 'Women and Households in a
Changing World', in Eleanora Barbieri Masini and Susan Stratigos (eds) Women, Households and Change
(Tokyo: United Nations University Press) 30-52.
United Nations Division for the Advancement of Women (UNDAW) (2000) Women2000: Gender Equality,
Development and Peace for the 21st Century (New York: UNDAW).
United Nations Fund for Women (UNIFEM) (1995) The Human Cost of Women’s Poverty:
Perspectives from Latin America and the Caribbean (Mexico City: UNIFEM).
Varley, Ann (1996) 'Women-headed Households: Some More Equal Than Others?', World Development,
24:3, 505-20.
Varley, Ann (2002) ‘Gender, Families and Households’, in Vandana Desai and Robert Potter
(eds) The Companion to Development Studies (London: Edward Arnold) 329-34.
Varley, Ann and Blasco, Maribel (2000) ‘Exiled to the Home: Masculinity and Ageing in Urban
Mexico’, European Journal of Development Research, 12:2, 115-38.
Waldfogel, Jane (1996) What Do we Expect Lone Mothers to Do? Competing Agendas for Welfare Reform in
the United States (London: London School of Economics, Suntory Toyota International Centre for
Economics and Related Disciplines, Welfare State Programme, Discussion Paper No.124).
Wartenburg, Lucy (1999) ‘Vulnerabilidad y Jefatura en los Hogares Urbanos Colombianos’ in Mercedes
González de la Rocha (ed.) Divergencias del Modelo Tradicional: Hogares de Jefatura Femenina en
América Latina (México DF: Centro de Investigaciones y Estudios Superiores en Antropología
Social/Plaza y Valdés Editores) 77-96.
Weekes-Vagliani, Winifred (1992) 'Structural Adjustment and Gender in the Côte d'Ivoire', in Haleh Afshar
and Carolyne Dennis (eds) Women and Adjustment Policies in the Third World (Basingstoke: Macmillan)
117-49.
Westwood, Sallie ‘“Feckless Fathers”: Masculinities and the British State’, in Ma’rt’n Mac An Ghaill (ed.)
Understanding Masculinities: Social Relations and Cultural Arenas (Buckingham: Open University Press)
21-34.
Whitehead, Ann and Lockwood, Matthew (1999) ‘Gendering Poverty: A Review of Six World Bank African
Poverty Assessments’, Development and Change, 30:3, 525-55.
Williams, Chris and Lee-Smith, Diana (2000) ‘Feminisation of Poverty: Re-thinking Poverty Reduction from a
Gender Perspective’, Habitat Debate, 6:4, 1-5 (http://www.unhabitat.org/HD).
Willis, Katie (1993) 'Women's Work and Social Network Use in Oaxaca City, Mexico', Bulletin of Latin
American Research, 12:1, 65-82.
Willis, Katie (1994) Women’s Work and Social Network Use in Oaxaca City, Mexico. Unpublished DPhil
dissertation, Nuffield College, Oxford.
Willis, Katie (2000) ‘No es Fácil, Pero es Posible: The Maintenance of Middle-Class Women-headed
Households in Mexico’, European Review of Latin American and Caribbean Studies, 69, 29-45.
Winchester, Hilary (1990) 'Women and Children Last: The Poverty and Marginalisation of One-parent
Families', Transactions, Institute of British Geographers,NS, 15:1, 70-86.
World Bank (1994) Enhancing Women’s Participation in Economic Development (Washington DC: World
Bank).
World Bank (2000) World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty (New York: Oxford University
Press).
World Bank (2002) Integrating Gender into the World Bank’s Work (Washington DC: World Bank).
Wratten, Ellen (1995) 'Conceptualising Urban Poverty', Environment and Urbanisation, 7:1, 11-36.
Yates, Rachel (1997) ‘Literacy, Gender and Vulnerability: Donor Discourses and Local Realities’, IDS Bulletin,
28:3, 112-21.
Young, Kate (1992) 'Household Resource Management', in Lise Østergaard (ed.) Gender and Development:
A Practical Guide (London: Routledge) 135-64.
Ypeij, Annelou and Steenbeck, Gerdien (2001) ‘Poor Single Mothers and Cultural Meanings of Social
Support’, Focaal - European Journal of Anthropology, 38, 71-82.

60
APPENDIX

Boxes 1-5
__________________________________________________________________________

BOX 1: STATEMENTS ABOUT FEMALE-HEADED HOUSEHOLDS AND POVERTY

‘...the global economic downturn has pressed most heavily on women-headed


households, which are everywhere in the world, the poorest of the poor’.

Tinker (1990: 5)

‘Women-headed households are over-represented among the poor in rural and urban,
developing and industrial societies’.

Bullock (1994:17-18)

‘One continuing concern of both the developing and advanced capitalist economies is
the increasing amount of women’s poverty worldwide, associated with the rise of
female-headed households’.

Acosta-Belén and Bose (1995:25)

‘...the number of female-headed households among the poor and the poorer sections
of society is increasing and…they, as a group -- whether heterogeneous or not -- are
more vulnerable and face more discrimination because they are poor and also
because they are man-less women on their own’.

Bibars (2001:67).

‘ Households headed by females with dependent children experience the worst


afflictions of poverty … Female-headed households are the poorest’

Finne (2001:8)
________________________________________________________________

61
________________________________________________________________

BOX 2: FACTORS INFLUENCING THE CONSTRUCTION OF FEMALE-


HEADED HOUSEHOLDS AS THE ‘POOREST OF THE POOR’

* Historical association of ‘feminisation of poverty’ concept with poor lone mothers and
their children

* Repeated ‘statements of fact’ in academic and policy literature

* Endorsement of greater incidence and degrees of poverty among female-headed


households by mainstream development institutions

* Priority attached to quantitative/’physiological deprivation’ indicators of poverty

* Reliance on aggregated household (rather than per capita) figures for income,
consumption and expenditure

* ‘Visibility’ of female-headed households in conventional poverty statistics

* Instrumental value of ‘poorest of the poor’ orthodoxy in securing resources for women
in development/social programmes

* Extrapolation of women’s labour market disadvantage as individuals (e.g. in


occupational status, earnings etc) to female-headed households

* Perceived impacts of gender inequalities in respect of land, property and other


material assets on female-headed households

* Over-emphasis (or exclusive emphasis) on economic status of household head as


signifier of well-being for all household members

* Equation of female-headed households with ‘lone mother and children’ households

* Assumption that female heads are primary or sole ‘breadwinners’

* Assumption that women-headed households have greater proportions of female


members than male-headed units

* Limited state/institutional transfers to female-headed households

* Limited financial support to children in female-headed households from absent fathers

* Conjectured limitations in access to and/or use of social capital of female-headed


households in respect of networks of kin, neighbours, friends

* Dominance of normative assumptions about the advantages of the ‘natural’ and/or


‘traditional’ (patriarchal/male-headed) family unit for material well-being

* Social pathology discourses of lone mother households as ‘incomplete families’,


‘problematic families’ and/or as symptomatic of ‘family breakdown’

* Concern for children’s rights and well-being

62
________________________________________________________________

BOX 3: FACTORS CHALLENGING THE CONSTRUCTION OF FEMALE-


HEADED HOUSEHOLDS AS ‘POOREST OF THE POOR’

* Lack of systematic ‘fit’ with quantitative data pertaining to incomes, consumption,


indicators of well-being among children and so on

* Heterogeneity of female-headed households (in respect of routes into


status, composition, stage in the life course etc)

* Recognition that female-headed households are not necessarily ‘male


absent’ households

* Strategies adopted by female-headed households to compensate for gender


bias and/or household vulnerability (e.g. household extension, increases in
occupational density, optimal utilisation of labour supply [especially that of women])

* Recognition that households are permeable units with flows from beyond household
boundaries affecting internal well-being

* Above-average receipt of financial support from working children within


and beyond the home

* Rejection of unitary household models in favour of models emphasising


household as a sites of bargaining, ‘cooperative-conflict’, and intra-household
inequalities along lines of gender when considering resource generation and
distribution.

* Idea that household well-being cannot be automatically equated with economic status
of heads

* Multi-dimensional/’social deprivation’ conceptualisations of poverty which extend


beyond incomes and consumption, emphasising, inter alia, assets, subjective
experiences of privation, ‘vulnerability’ and poverty-generating processes

* Poverty relations as power relations, namely that command and control over
resources may be equally, if not more, important as level of resources in determining
individuals’ experiences of poverty

* Acknowledgement that female heads of household may make ‘trade-offs’ between


different dimensions of poverty (e.g. ‘income poor’ but ‘power-rich’).

* Recognition that some women may actively choose female household


headship on grounds of improved material and/or other aspects of well-being, and/or
resist becoming part of new male-headed arrangements following conjugal breakdown
or widowhood

63
_______________________________________________________________________
BOX 4: IMPLICATIONS OF CONSTRUCTING FEMALE-HEADED
HOUSEHOLDS AS THE ‘POOREST OF THE POOR’

* Can potentially secure resources for women in development/social programmes

* Homogenises negative economic circumstances of female-headed households

* Ignores non-economic aspects of disadvantage in women’s lives, such as unequal


gender roles and relations, domestic violence etc.

* Ignores subjective meanings of household headship for women such as power,


autonomy, self-esteem.

* Neglects and/or deflects attention from situation of women in male-headed


households

* Suggests that women in male-headed households do not experience poverty

* Places undue emphasis on household circumstances in exacerbating the poverty of


women, rather than wider gender inequalities

* Devalues the efforts made by female-headed households to overcome gender bias


and/or household vulnerability

* Contributes to negative image of female-headed households

* Pathologisation of female headship can contribute to narrowing their livelihood


possibilities

* Gives rise to programmes which focus on women only rather than on


women and men, and/or gender relations (WID vs GAD)

* Ignores lone father households

* Serves neo-liberal agendas for efficiency and the substitution of universal


social programmes with targeted programmes

* Leads to targeted programmes for female heads of household which, to date,


do not seem to have appreciable benefits in respect of raising women’s status,
social legitimacy and well-being, and/or diminishing inequalities in gender or
between household structures

* Objectification of female heads as a group in need (rather than as a group with


rights)

* Serves conservative agendas for strengthening marriage and the ‘traditional


family’,

* Gender inequality becomes conflated with poverty


_____________________________________________________________

64
________________________________________________________________

BOX 5: IMPLICATIONS OF DISRUPTING THE STEREOTYPE THAT


FEMALE-HEADED HOUSEHOLDS ARE THE ‘POOREST OF THE
POOR’

* Potentially sacrifices public/development resources for women, especially in context of


shrinking assistance on the part of national governments, international agencies etc

* Can feed into discourses about women-headed households, especially lone parent
units, being an ‘undeserving poor’.

* Emphasis on relative economic well-being of female-headed households glosses over


other (non-material) aspects of female household headship which can prejudice the
well-being of women and children (e.g. strains on time, energy and physical and
mental health to compensate for structural economic disadvantage and household
discrimination)

* Recognition of diversity among female-headed households makes targeting more


difficult

* Requires new ways of thinking about how to reach disaffected women that go beyond
targeting female heads. For example, recognition that poverty affects women within
male-headed households calls for policy attention to men, fatherhood and gender
relations

* Complexity and scope of developing diverse new programmes to address women’s


poverty carries cost and resource implications, especially given lack of expertise in
areas such as GAD for men

* Requires re-visiting, deconstructing and re-formulating the concept of


the ‘feminisation of poverty’

_____________________________________________________________________

65

View publication stats

You might also like