Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Global Money Notes #8: From Exorbitant Privilege To Existential Trilemma

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18
At a glance
Powered by AI
The document discusses how Basel III regulations and money fund reforms have reduced liquidity in the global dollar funding market, weakening the US's exorbitant privilege. This has created an existential trilemma for the Fed between controlling monetary policy, exchange rates, and constraints on bank balance sheets.

The Fed can no longer have constraints on bank balance sheets, a stable exchange rate between onshore dollars and Eurodollars, and a domestically oriented monetary policy at the same time. One of these things will have to give as the Fed tries to normalize rates.

Basel III liquidity requirements and the clamping of prime money funds as a major global dollar funding artery have made the Eurodollar market structurally more expensive and less liquid and dominant than it used to be.

18 November 2016

Global
Fixed Income Research
Global Strategy

Global Money Notes #8


Research Analysts
Zoltan Pozsar
212 538 3779
zoltan.pozsar@credit-suisse.com From Exorbitant Privilege to Existential Trilemma
We have yet to see what President Trump means for the Fed’s independence
and monetary policy going forward, but for now our expectation remains that
the FOMC will remain willing and free to normalize short-term interest rates.
With that assumption in mind, this issue of Global Money Notes explains why
an FOMC determined to normalize interest rates has no choice but to become
a Dealer of Last Resort in the FX swap market and provide quantitative
Eurodollar easing (“QEE”) for the rest of the world through its dollar swap lines.
The U.S.’s exorbitant privilege – its ability to borrow in its own currency
anywhere in the world thanks to a vast and deep Eurodollar market – is waning.
The first throw of sand at the gears of the global Eurodollar market was the
adoption of Basel III which imposed liquidity requirements on a system born
out of banks’ desire to avoid reserve requirements in the first place (see here).
The second was money fund reform.
Prime funds’ loss of over $1 trillion in assets under management amounts to
the clamping of a major global funding “artery” whose role was to bridge the
Eurodollar market’s marginal dollar needs. These needs are now bridged
through a smaller and increasingly tight “vein” that’s the balance sheet of
American banks under Basel III. The result is a Eurodollar market that’s
structurally more expensive and less liquid and dominant than it used to be.
Basel III and money fund reform are turning the exorbitant privilege into an
existential trilemma that’s usually a problem for EM central banks with pegs to
the dollar, rather than the Fed at the center of the dollar-based financial order.
According to the Fed’s newfound trilemma, it is impossible to have constraints
on bank balance sheets (restraining capital mobility in global money markets),
a par exchange rate between onshore dollars and Eurodollars, and a
domestically oriented monetary policy mandate. Something will have to give.
It’s either the cross-currency basis, the foreign exchange value of the dollar or
the hiking cycle. It’s either the Fed’s regulatory and monetary objectives, or
control over the Fed’s balance sheet size. It’s either quantities or prices…
Cross-currency bases will have to go more negative before the Fed steps in,
and -150 bps on the three-month dollar-yen basis is not an unlikely target.
In a way, QEE is the missing piece in a mosaic where the ECB and the BoJ
continue on with QE at an aggressive pace, and investors in their jurisdictions
are filling their duration gaps with higher-yielding U.S. dollar assets on a
hedged basis. But the private provision of FX swaps to hedge these flows can’t
possibly keep pace with the public creation of euros and yen on massive scale.
Elephant-size €QE and QQE can only be countered by elephant size QEE:
the Fed needs to lend banks a hand and provide dollar hedges more cheaply.
It’s either Lender of Last Resort or Dealer of Last Resort.
Take your pick…

DISCLOSURE APPENDIX AT THE BACK OF THIS REPORT CONTAINS IMPORTANT DISCLOSURES, LEGAL ENTITY
DISCLOSURE AND ANALYST CERTIFICATIONS.
18 November 2016

Part 1 – Clamping an Artery


Going into the October 14 prime money fund reform deadline, institutional-class prime
funds prepared for the worst and hoped for the best – they provisioned for about 70% of
assets under management (AuM) leaving and expected that only 50% will leave. But
outflows turned out to be far worse than expected – just under 90% of AuM – and so
expectations that any margin of safety built into pre-cautionary liquidity buffers will quickly
flow back to the CD and CP markets and compress rates post-deadline didn’t materialize.
Judging from price action and high-frequency data on foreign banks’ CD and CP issuance
since May, the bulk of unsecured funding lost to prime money fund reform was replaced
mostly through the FX swap market, and to a lesser extent through the term debt market.
With that shift, large American banks and asset managers (corporate bond funds)
replaced prime money market funds as the marginal lenders of dollars to foreign banks,
and by extension, the outer rim of the U.S. money market (the offshore FX swap market)
and capital markets replaced the inner core (the onshore CD and CP market in New York).
Figure 1 shows the price impact of this shift in the FX swap market, and Figure 2 shows
where we believe foreign banks’ marginal funding curve currently trades: in our view,
the orange curves are a more accurate reflection of foreign banks’ marginal funding curve
for dollars longer than 30-days than the blue U.S. dollar Libor curve. We plotted the
orange lines by taking the average of three-month FX-swap implied costs of dollar funding
for key currencies and the yields of major foreign banks’ one- and two-year fixed rate debt.
Going forward, we expect these markets to be a deeper source of marginal (“just-in-time”)
funding than the term CD and CP market. While at $1 trillion the term CD and CP market
remains large, its nature has changed. Pre-reform, prime funds represented a $1 trillion pool
of “omnipresent” liquidity that was sliced and diced according to foreign banks’ needs:
investors in prime funds rolled their o/n balances everyday which foreign banks could tap in
custom terms and size any day – the way a marginal funding market is supposed to trade.
But this omnipresent pool of liquidity is now gone.
What’s left is investors with a periodic as opposed to constant presence in the market.
With that shift the term CD and CP market became more similar to the real estate market
(where trades happen if a buyer wants exactly what a seller has at exactly the same time)
than a marginal funding market where pools of liquidity are ready for any trade at any time.
The key question from here is how much money will come back to prime money funds.
If the answer is a lot, then rates could come down as prime funds pour money back into
the term CD and CP market. The recent climb in rates will go down in history as cyclical.
If the answer is not much, then funding rates will stay elevated indefinitely. We’ve reached
the “new normal” and the recent climb in rates will go down in history as structural.
Which one will it be?
It looks like the latter, for four reasons: regulatory constraints on generating yield,
preference for safety over yield, economies of scale, and the “gravitational” pull of Basel III.
First, the SEC’s new liquidity rules will limit prime funds’ ability to generate yield to lure
money back from government funds. The new rules effectively turn half the portfolio of
prime funds into a government fund, which will limit yield spreads over government funds
to about a half of their historical average.1 Whatever spread prime funds will have over
government funds, it won’t be enough to compensate investors for the risk of liquidity gates.

1 The SEC’s new rules require prime money funds to hold at least 30% of their AuM in liquid assets such as U.S. Treasuries. But
since reaching the 30% minimum would require the imposition of liquidity gates and fees, prime money funds are implementing
the new rules with a considerable margin of safety, running their liquidity buffers at close to 50% of their AuM on average.

Global Money Notes #8 2


18 November 2016

Figure 1: Funding at the “Outer Rim”


FX swap-implied costs of three-month U.S. dollar funding, %
1.80 1.80

Prime fund outflows start...


1.60 1.60

1.40 1.40

1.20 1.20

1.00 1.00

0.80 0.80

0.60 0.60

0.40 0.40
Jan-16 Apr-16 Jul-16 Oct-16
Implied funding cost JPY Iimplied funding cost GBP Implied funding cost EUR Implied funding cost CAD Implied funding cost CHF
Pre-reform average (Q1) Pre-reform average (Q1) Pre-reform average (Q1) Pre-reform average (Q1) Pre-reform average (Q1)

Source: Credit Suisse, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service

Figure 2: Which is the True Marginal Bank Funding Curve?


%, as of October 28, 2016 unless otherwise noted
2.00 2.00

1.75 1.75

1.50 1.50

1.25 1.25

1.00 1.00

0.75 0.75

0.50 0.50

0.25 0.25

0.00 0.00
o/n 1-week 1-month 3-month 6-month 1-year 2-year
U.S. dollar Libor 3-month FX swap rate (average) 2-year term bank debt (fixed rate) 2-year one month ago 3-month one month ago

Source: Credit Suisse, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service

Global Money Notes #8 3


18 November 2016

Second, reforms will also limit treasurers’ demand for yield and hence prime money funds.
When regulatory reforms are turning prime funds from a liquidity vehicle to a credit vehicle,
effectively cutting the system’s menu of options for safe, par on demand vehicles from
three (demand deposits, government funds and prime funds) to two (demand deposits and
government funds), the natural response of investors is to gravitate toward safety (that is
government funds), not yield (that is, prime funds). This, combined with prime funds’
constraints to generate yield going forward, will severely limit flows back into prime funds.
Third, if there is neither yield pickup, nor reach for yield, the future of what is left of
institutional-class prime funds looks rather bleak. Institutional prime funds lost $800 billion
in AuM since 2015, leaving only $100 billion in assets to look after (see Figure 3). Whether
such a small asset-base can support overheads that were scaled to manage trillions, not
billions is yet to be seen. Economies of scale matter and are make or break.
Fourth, the future of retail prime funds also looks bleak due to the gravitational pull of Basel
III. Retail prime funds lost $250 billion in AuM since 2015, with only $250 billion left. Retail
deposits are "gold" for large American banks as they require no HQLA and count as NSFR
at face value. In an era when banks like Goldman Sachs are paying over 100 bps for
checking accounts, funds will continue to migrate out of prime funds paying only 25 bps.
If we are right that prime funds will shrink further from here, the steepening of the Libor
curve, the widening of Libor-OIS spreads and the increase in offshore dollar funding costs
we have witnessed to date are all structural, not cyclical. At best we are looking at funding
markets to stabilize at current levels, and at worst we are looking for the curve to steepen,
spreads to widen and cross-currency bases to sink much deeper into negative territory as
prime money market funds fail to attract cash back and continue to bleed assets over time.
The end-state of the system is one where foreign banks raise their marginal dollars mostly
in the FX swap market (from American banks) or the capital market (from asset managers).
The end-state is dominated by American banks because post-reform, they are the only
ones left with access to cheap retail dollars onshore to lend offshore via FX swaps – all
foreign banks that used to lend via FX swaps raised dollars wholesale from prime funds
(for a review of the impact of money fund reform on the FX swap market see Appendix 1).
As large American banks grow to dominate the FX swap market, they will inevitably
become the marginal price setters in the system. Going forward, the key questions from a
pricing perspective will be how American banks’ growing FX swap books will push up
against their balance sheet constraints: (1) how much balance sheet they will have to
onboard these trades from an SLR perspective; (2) what will these trades do to their LCR;
(3) what will the looming requirement to currency-match HQLA portfolios mean for their
appetite to do these trades; and (4) will the Volcker Rule let them run speculative books?
None of these constraints mean anything good for the marginal cost of Eurodollar funding
going forward, which means that what’s referred to as a “global dollar shortage” is bound
to get worse in the future. But in light of the points raised above, none of this is about a
shortage of dollars per se, but rather a shortage of balance sheet to intermediate dollars
(please, let’s forget the whole “shortage versus scarcity” debate and call a spade a spade).
Effectively, what we have here is a case where money fund reform amounts to the
clamping of a major global funding “artery” and a redirection of flows through a smaller and
increasingly tight "vein" that is the balance sheet of American global banks under Basel III.
For a sense of scale, consider that over $1 trillion has left prime funds. Now consider the
image of American banks absorbing these flows through hamstrung balance sheets…
…what you see is an elephant inside a snake (see Figure 4), and a global dollar funding
market structurally more expensive and less liquid and dominant than it used to be.

Global Money Notes #8 4


18 November 2016

Figure 3: Tectonic Shifts


$ billions
800 800

600 600

400 400

200 200

0 0

-200 -200

-400 -400

-600 -600

-800 -800
14 15 16

Outflows from institutional prime funds Inflows into institutional government funds

Source: Credit Suisse, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service

Part 2 – QEE and the Fed as Dealer of Last Resort


What does all this mean for the Fed?
Quite a lot, which makes the fact that no Fed official devoted a speech to the topic of
prime money fund reform and its local and global repercussions puzzling to say the least.
First, the local repercussions.
Prime money fund reform just made the ARRC’s quest for an alternative reference rate
more difficult and will increase the allure of a repo rate as an alternative (see here).
Outflows from prime funds to date have reduced the volume of o/n Eurodollar trades from
$250 billion to $90 billion today (see Figure 5).2 By the time the dust of reform will settle,
the OBFR will have lost most of its volume advantage over the fed funds rate, in our view.
Next, the global repercussions.
The message that emerged from the previous section is that the era of cheap marginal
flows into the Eurodollar market are over. Tapping the CD and CP markets via prime funds
is a thing of the past and the future likely belongs to American global banks that are set to
become the dominant price-setters of the marginal dollars the rest of the world needs. The
key to figuring out where cross currency bases will settle is to figure out the interaction
between American banks’ growing FX swap books and their balance sheet constraints.
The more dollars American banks will intermediate through the FX swap market, the less
balance sheet they will have left over for everything else, and the higher the price of the
marginal FX trade will have to be. Standard logics of arbitrage do not hold under Basel III:
with balance sheets no longer unlimited, the more you arb the higher the marginal price.3

2 This is because institutional-class prime money funds were the single biggest lenders of o/n Eurodollars in the Caribbean-based
segment of the Eurodollar market as measured by the Federal Reserve’s new overnight bank funding rate (OBFR).
3 Banks arbitrage differences between onshore and offshore funding rates by borrowing onshore in the CD and CP market from
prime money funds and lending the proceeds in the FX swap market. Such arbitrage trades inflate banks’ balance sheets.

Global Money Notes #8 5


18 November 2016

Either way we look at it, cross-currency bases are bound to get more negative, with no
private mechanism in place to check three-month points from sinking as low as -150 bps.
The limit to this will be the extent to which the rest of the world will be able to cope with
higher dollar funding costs and how these will feed back to the Fed’s reaction function.
There are at least three feedback channels.
First, an ongoing increase in the FX swap-implied cost of dollar funding and increasingly
negative cross-currency bases mean tighter financial conditions for the rest of the world. In
turn, tighter financial conditions point to slower, not faster global growth as foreign banks
pass on higher costs to their customers or worse: de-lever their books. These dynamics
are disinflationary on the margin and don’t help interest rate normalization back in the U.S.
Second, increasingly negative cross-currency bases mean rising hedging costs for foreign
investors on their U.S. dollar assets, which force them out the duration curve and down the
credit spectrum. In turn, this tends to ease financial conditions, raise financial stability risks,
and also blunt the traditional channels of monetary policy transmission back in the U.S.
Chairman Greenspan’s conundrum is back and spreading to mortgage and credit curves.
Third, everything described above goes hand-in-hand with a further strengthening of the
dollar (see Figure 6) – this is because increasing hedging costs are prompting foreign
investors to reduce their hedge ratios or take on naked exposures, both of which tend to
drive the appreciation of the dollar. If the Fed leaves the intermediation of all of the rest of
the world’s marginal dollar needs to American banks' constrained balance sheets, offshore
financial conditions may tighten and the dollar may strengthen to the point where they are
no longer consistent with the path the Fed envisioned for the funds rate (see Shin, 2016):
rounds of RMB devaluation would follow which also won’t help interest rate normalization.

Figure 5: It’s Back to the Drawing Board for the ARRC…


$ billions
300 300

250 250

227

200 200 200

150 150

131

112 113
100 100

70

50 50 50
44 46

0 0
15 16

o/n FF volume (reported) o/n FF volume (ex month ends) o/n ED volume (reported) o/n ED volume (ex month ends)

Source: Credit Suisse, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service

Global Money Notes #8 6


18 November 2016

Figure 6: The Cross-Currency Basis and the U.S. Dollar


January 2nd, 2007 = 100 (LHS), basis points (RHS)

Source: BIS

It seems like balance sheet constraints are in conflict with monetary policy objectives…
Balance sheet constraints are driving prices in a way where financial conditions abroad
are tighter than financial conditions in the U.S. Where borrowing a Eurodollar is more
expensive than borrowing an onshore dollar. The feedback of this on the U.S. dollar and
financial stability risks are making interest rate hikes less possible and also less effective.
What to do?
In this environment, the only bank that could counter the tendency of cross-currency bases
to sink deeper and deeper into negative territory is none other than the New York Fed.
It could do so by scrapping its philosophy that it should primarily serve the system as a
Lender of Last Resort – providing a liquidity backstop when no one wants to lend – and
become a Dealer of Last Resort – providing a backstop to prices when dealers hit their
balance sheet constraints and have no room left to make markets at reasonable spreads.
The tool to use is the Fed's dollar swap lines but the aim would no longer be to backstop
funding markets, but to police the range within which various cross currency bases trade.
Just as the reasons why various cross currency bases spiked during 2008 and 2011
(credit and sovereign risks) were different from the reasons why they have been widening
since 2014 (Basel III and money fund reform), the mindset with which the dollar swap lines
should be deployed today should also be different – not to provide a liquidity backstop
because prime funds won’t lend to banks, but to provide a balance sheet backstop
because private market makers are pushing up against their balance sheet constraints,
and are giving quotes that are strengthening the dollar and forcing the Fed to stay on hold.
Of course, if the Fed were to switch from treating the swap lines as a funding backstop to
a pricing backstop, its attitude toward being tapped would have to be relaxed. In English,
this means that long held notions of stigma would have to be expunged from the market’s
conscience and everyone would have to adopt a mindset where if banks’ quotes are more
expensive than the quotes of the Fed, everyone would default to trading with the Fed with
no further thought, period – much like the ECB’s repo facilities are routinely tapped.
Will this really happen?
It’s not unlikely. We know from the July FOMC minutes that the Fed is actively looking into
"approaches to reducing perceived stigma associated with borrowing at the discount
window" and is conscious that "the dollar is the principal reserve currency and that
monetary transmission in the U.S. occurs through globally connected funding markets".

Global Money Notes #8 7


18 November 2016

The Fed’s ongoing review of its Long-Run Monetary Policy Implementation Framework
(to be published in January) may conclude the Fed should become a Dealer of Last Resort
and be willing to make markets once spreads hit certain levels (the “outside” spread). Not
doing so would have unwanted feedbacks on the dollar, the RMB’s peg to the dollar, and
the Fed’s ability to raise rates. Were the Fed to turn into a Dealer of Last Resort, it would
give up control over its balance sheet and so should charge more for the dollar swap lines.
Recognize that the theme we’ve been emphasizing about the U.S. money market (see here)
– that the sovereign has effectively crowded out private banks in money markets onshore4
– is also inevitable in money markets offshore. The Eurodollar market is a private system
and the historically tight relationship between onshore and offshore funding curves implied
a “par exchange rate” between onshore dollars and Eurodollars – OIS, Libor and FX swap
curves were all on top of each other. The widening spreads between Libor and OIS, and
Libor and FX swap-implied dollar funding rates (that is, the cross-currency basis) reflect a
structural breakdown of the par exchange rate between onshore dollars and Eurodollars –
just as the crisis of 2008 marked a similar breakdown. But 2008 was a panic. It was
temporary. Today is structural. It feels more persistent than temporary. It is driven by
balance sheet constraints due to Basel III which limit American banks’ ability to serve as
private dealers of dollars from onshore to offshore. It also means that a dollar abroad is
more expensive than a dollar at home, which will continue to push the spot value of the
dollar higher and higher unless the Fed decides to give up control over its balance sheet
and ease the shortage of offshore dollars by becoming a public dealer of Eurodollars.
Regulatory reforms turned the exorbitant privilege into an existential trilemma typically
associated with emerging market economies with fixed exchange rates to the U.S. dollar.
According to the impossible trinity of yore it is only possible to have two of three goals:
free capital mobility, a fixed FX rate and monetary policy oriented toward domestic goals.
The Fed now faces the impossible trinity in a new form: it’s impossible to have constraints
on bank balance sheets (restraining free capital mobility in global money markets), a par
exchange rate between onshore and offshore dollars across the term structure, and a
monetary policy oriented toward domestic goals. Either way, something will have to give:
(1) Reforms – the domain of Governor Tarullo – are limiting balance sheet quantities
and driving a wedge between the price of onshore and offshore dollars as evident
in more negative cross-currency bases. This contributes to the dollar’s strength.
(2) Monetary policy independence – the domain of Chair Yellen – is under threat, as
a stronger dollar increases the chance of further RMB devaluation by the PBoC.
The deflationary risks inherent in RMB devaluation limit the Fed’s ability to hike.
(3) Quantitative Eurodollar easing (“QEE”) for the rest of the world is the solution,
which is President Dudley’s domain. If the increasing cost of Eurodollars is what’s
driving the appreciation of the dollar, and the appreciation of the dollar is what
stands in the way of the Fed’s hiking cycle, it appears that the right thing to do is
to break the impasse and give the rest of the world what it needs through the
swap lines so as to relieve the pressure on the dollar so that the FOMC can hike.
It’s either quantities or prices…
Monetary policy divergence is not a new phenomenon – we’ve seen it in the past. But in
the past, unconstrained balance sheets ensured that cross currency bases were minimal
(or in other words, deviations from covered interest parity weren’t large or persistent).

4 Look no further than the demise of prime funds and rise of government-only funds, the increased volume of bills issued by the
U.S. Treasury, the increased volume of floaters issued by by the FHLBs and the increased size of the Fed’s foreign repo pool
and o/n RRP facility as counterparts to less short-term funding raised by banks and primary dealers’ diminished repo books.

Global Money Notes #8 8


18 November 2016

Under the old regime, the focus was on prices and tight spreads – or in the present
context a “par exchange rate” between onshore and offshore dollar funding curves.
Quantities (balance sheet) were endless, and the volume of matched money market books
that accumulated through global banks’ money dealing activities – borrowing in onshore
segments of the money market in order to lend offshore – were massive indeed. No longer.
Basel III restricting quantities and money fund reform clamping a main funding artery is
turning the Fed’s world on its head. Quantity constraints will have to be relaxed if the Fed
wants to have monetary independence and parity between onshore and offshore dollars.
Barring the scrapping of Basel III or the blanket exemption of reserves from the SLR,
quantitative Eurodollar easing (“QEE”) for the world – the fixed-price, full-allotment
broadcast of Eurodollars globally through the dollar swap lines – is the solution we need.
In a way, QEE is the missing piece in a mosaic where the ECB and BoJ continue with QE
and investors in their jurisdictions are looking to fill their duration gaps with higher-yielding
dollar assets on a hedged basis. But the private provision of FX swaps to hedge these
flows cannot possibly keep pace with the public creation of euros and yen on mass scale.

Conclusions
Elephant-size €QEs and QQEs can only be countered by elephant-size QEEs by the Fed:
the Fed needs to lend banks a hand and provide Eurodollars more cheaply to the world…
It’s either regulatory and monetary objectives or the Fed’s balance sheet size.
It’s either the cross-currency basis, the dollar or the next hike.
It’s either Lender of Last Resort or Dealer of Last Resort.
Take your pick…

Global Money Notes #8 9


18 November 2016

Appendix 1 – Pricing at the Outer Rim


Figure A-1 lists the four steps involved in foreign banks’ and investors’ use of FX swaps.
It also demonstrates the example of a firm borrowing euros to arbitrage funding costs.
All three cases are examples of market participants borrowing dollars via FX swaps.
Figure A-2 aims to explain how two of these borrowers (banks and real money accounts)
link up with the suppliers of dollars via FX swaps, using the dollar-yen basis as an example.
On the demand side we have real money accounts such as insurance companies and
pension funds with a need to hedge dollar investments (motivated by search for yield), and
banks with a need to fund dollar loans (search for lending opportunities outside of Japan).
On the supply side, we have prime money funds that lend dollars onshore (in New York to
the New York branches of Japanese banks which then “forward” those dollars to Tokyo)
and institutional cash pools that lend dollars offshore (from New York or anywhere in the
world to Tokyo). Institutional cash pools include FX reserve managers like the RBA (see
page 44 of their latest annual report for a sense of their size in the FX swap market),
multilateral accounts like the IMF or the World Bank, asset managers and hedge funds.
Structurally, these four groups of players line up such that Japanese real money accounts
only have access to the FX swap market for dollars, but not the cheaper CD and CP
market where money funds lend. Japanese banks have access to both sources, but they
historically opted for the latter as CD and CP funding is typically cheaper than FX swaps.
On the lending side, regulations allowed prime funds to lend only in CD and CP markets
but not the FX swap market, and institutional cash pools were free to lend wherever. Free
to be, they historically opted for FX swaps as swaps paid better than CD and CP. Not
doing so would have been like not picking up €500 bills from the pavement day after day.
Those who could borrow dollars only through FX swaps (real money accounts) and those
who chose to lend dollars only through FX swaps (institutional cash pools) “met” through
the matched books of market makers – global banks active in the FX swap market.
No market is ever balanced, however, and market makers’ job is to smooth temporary
imbalances in order flows through their speculative books. Demand for dollars in Tokyo
has been persistently stronger than the supply of dollars from cash pools, and global
banks bridged this structural dollar shortage by tapping markets onshore to lend offshore.
It is here – in the speculative books – where the price of the marginal FX swap trade is set.
Figure A-3 builds on Figure A-2 by adding the typical tenors that each participant trades in.
Japanese real money accounts borrow at the three-month point of the FX swap market (to
hedge quarterly coupon flows), and banks borrow in the three-month CD and CP market
from prime funds to minimize their HQLA funding costs while staying LCR compliant.
Institutional cash pools typically lend at the richest point of the FX forward curve, which,
given the hedging needs of real money accounts and banks, is the tree-month point.
Correspondingly, market makers’ books are dominated by matching three-month swaps.
Imbalances in order flows also involve mostly three-month FX swaps. Global banks fund
these speculative long positions with funding that is structurally cheaper to raise. For non-
American global banks these come from prime funds at tenors shorter than 30-days.
But for American global banks these funds are essentially for “free” – they have endless
amounts of retail deposits at their disposal, and if they need to raise funds elsewhere, the
FHLBs are there to offer one-week or one-month money at 55 and 60 bps, respectively.
Given these structural funding relationships, Figure A-4 demonstrates what the demise of
prime money funds means for the balance of pricing power in the system going forward.
First, it means that Japanese banks (and banks from other jurisdictions as well) will lose
access to cheap onshore dollars via CD and CP and will replace them with FX swaps.

Global Money Notes #8 10


18 November 2016

Second, just as Japanese banks will be shifting toward FX swaps for funding, the size of
non-American speculative books in the market will be shrinking. This is because the cheap
source of CD and CP funding from prime funds to non-American global banks that are
active arbitrageurs of the difference between offshore and onshore rates will be gone.
Enter the American bank, which, as noted above, has a funding advantage over everyone
else and hence is uniquely positioned to dominate the FX swap market going forward.
As large American banks grow to dominate the FX swap market, they will inevitably
become the marginal price setters in in the system. The key questions from a pricing
perspective will be how an increased volume of speculative FX swaps positions will
interact with American banks’ regulatory constraints – how much balance sheet will they
have to onboard these trades from an SLR perspective; what will these trades do to their
LCR; what will the looming requirement to currency-match HQLA portfolios mean for their
overall appetite to do these trades; will the Volcker Rule let them run speculative books?
Figure out these questions and you will find the ‘keys to the kingdom’. And remember this:
under Basel III, the more dollars American banks intermediate via FX swaps, the less
balance sheet they will have left over for everything else, and the higher the price of the
marginal FX trade will have to be. Standard logics of arbitrage do not hold under Basel III:
with balance sheets no longer unlimited, the more you arb the higher the marginal price.5
Either way we look at it, cross-currency bases are bound to get more negative, with no
private mechanism in place to check three-month points from sinking as low as -150 bps.
The limit to this will be the extent to which the rest of the world will be able to cope with
higher dollar funding costs and how these costs will feed back to the Fed’s reaction function
In this environment, the only bank that can counter the tendency of cross-currency bases
to sink deeper and deeper into negative territory is none other than FRBNY (see above).
Other than money fund reform in the U.S., there are at least three risks on the horizon
which point to a further increase in American banks’ dominance in the FX swap market.
First, money fund reform in the EU. Investors should know that about half of money funds
in the EU are U.S. dollar-denominated. If the EU reforms follow the spirit of U.S. reforms,
we can expect a further steepening of the U.S. dollar Libor curve, a further migration of
funding from Eurodollar CD and CP markets to FX swaps, a further reduction in funding for
non-American global banks for arbitrage, and more on the plate of American global banks.
If institutional-class prime outflows were the first wave to push the Libor curve steeper and
cross-currency bases more negative, and retail-class prime fund outflows are the second,
then EU money fund reform will be the third. We should forget about Libor normalization…
Second, shortages of JGB bills are making it increasingly difficult for hedge funds and
asset managers to find assets to invest yen collateral when lending dollars via FX swaps.
This will naturally impede the volume of FX swaps intermediated through matched books,
and will pressure large American banks to increase their speculative books further. This
will exacerbate balance sheet pressures and push cross-currency bases more negative
(note that unlike hedge funds and asset managers, large American banks can deposit yen
at the BoJ via their Tokyo branches and so aren’t limited by the shortage of JGB bills).
Third, the reform of the U.S. corporate tax code and the potential re-patriation of hundreds
of billions of cash currently parked abroad. These offshore cash balances form an integral
part of the funding base of Eurodollar loan books across the globe. Were these cash
balances to flow back into the U.S., then even more of the funding of Eurodollar assets
would have to come from large American banks through FX swaps. The impact of this on
cross-currency bases would make money fund reform look like baby stuff (see Figure A-5).

5 Banks arbitrage differences between onshore and offshore funding rates by borrowing onshore in the CD and CP market from
prime money funds and lending the proceeds in the FX swap market. Such arbitrage trades inflate banks’ balance sheets.

Global Money Notes #8 11


18 November 2016

Figure A-1: FX Swap Uses

Japanese Bank Real Money Corporations


(dollar funding) (dollar hedges) (bargain hunting)
[1] Fund in ¥. ¥ ¥ ¥ ¥ € € Fund in €. [1]
Time: t (spot) (cash) (deposit) (cash) (alpha) (cash) (bond) Time: t (spot)

Japanese Bank Real Money Corporations


(dollar funding) (dollar hedges) (bargain hunting)

¥ ¥ ¥ ¥ € €
(cash) (deposit) (cash) (alpha) (cash) (bond)
[2] Exchange ¥ for $ spot (buy $). $ $ $ Exchange € for $ spot (buy $). [2]
[2] (currency risk) (cash) (cash) (cash) (currency risk) [2]
Time: t (spot) Time: t (spot)

Japanese Bank Real Money Corporations


(dollar funding) (dollar hedges) (bargain hunting)
¥ ¥ ¥ ¥ € €
(cash) (deposit) (cash) (alpha) (cash) (bond)
[3] Spend $ on U.S. dollar assets. $ $ $ Spend $ on dividends paid or w hatever [3]
[3] (currency, duration and credit risk) (loan) (bond) (spend) (currency risk) [3]
Time: t (spot) Time: t (spot)

Japanese Bank Real Money Corporations


(dollar funding) (dollar hedges) (bargain hunting)

¥ ¥ ¥ ¥ € €
(cash) (deposit) (cash) (alpha) (cash) (bond)
spot

spot
$ $ $
(loan) (bond) (spend)
[4] Hedge by selling $ from quarterly interest flow s ¥ $ ¥ $ € $ Hedge by selling $ from cash inflow s from sales [4]
FW

FW

[4] forw ard for ¥ at today's forw ard FX rate. (buy FW) (sell FW) (buy FW) (sell FW) (buy FW) (sell FW) forw ard for € at today's forw ard FX rate. [4]
[4] (duration and credit risk, no more FX risk)
Time: t + 90 days (FW) Time: t + 90 days (FW)

[5] Net Cash Flow s: Japanese Bank Real Money Corporations


(dollar funding) (dollar hedges) (bargain hunting)

$ ¥ $ ¥ $ €
spot

spot

Time: t (spot) Time: t (spot)


(loan) (deposit) (bond) (alpha) (revenues) (bond)

¥ $ ¥ $ € $
FW

FW

Time: t + 90 days (FW) Time: t + 90 days (FW)


(buy FW) (sell FW) (buy FW) (sell FW) (buy FW) (sell FW)

↓ ↓ ↓
Use ¥ to pay back original ¥ deposit if it is not rolled over. Use ¥ to pay a return in ¥ to Japanese pensioners. Use € to service debt denominated in €.

Source: Credit Suisse

Global Money Notes #8 12


18 November 2016

Figure A-2: FX Swap Links


Real Money Cash Pools

FXS FXS
←cash pool to real money ←
(indirectly via FX swap market makers)

Market Makers

matched book → FXS FXS

speculative book → FXS CD

Banks Prime Funds

CD CD

← prime fund to bank ←


(directly)

Source: Credit Suisse

Figure A-3: FX Swap Terms


Real Money Cash Pools

FXS FXS
(3-mo.) ←cash pool to real money ← (3-mo.)
(indirectly via FX swap market makers)

Market Makers

matched book →
FXS FXS
(3-mo.) (3-mo.)
FXS CD
speculative book →
(3-mo.) (1-mo.)

Banks Prime Funds

CD
CD
(3-mo.)
← prime fund to bank ←
(directly)

Source: Credit Suisse

Global Money Notes #8 13


18 November 2016

Figure A-4: FX Swaps without Prime Money Funds


Real Money Cash Pools

FXS FXS
(3-mo.) ←cash pool to real money ← (3-mo.)
(indirectly via FX swap market makers)

Market Makers

matched book →
FXS FXS
(3-mo.) (3-mo.)
FXS Deposits
spec. book →
(3-mo.) (retail)

Banks

FXS Basel III/Volcker constraints.


(3-mo.)

Source: Credit Suisse

Figure A-5: Another Trillion, Another Percentage Point…


Three-month FX-swap implied cost of dollar funding for yen-based borrowers, %

Source: Bank of Japan

Global Money Notes #8 14


18 November 2016

References:
Pozsar, Zoltan, “The Rise and Fall of the Shadow Banking System,”
Moody’s Economy.com (July, 2008)
Wilmot, Jonathan, Sweeney, James, Klein, Matthias and Lantz, Carl, “Long Shadows,”
Credit Suisse (May, 2009)
Pozsar, Zoltan, Adrian, Tobias, Ashcraft Adam and Boesky, Hayley, “Shadow Banking,”
FRBNY (July, 2010)
Pozsar, Zoltan
“Institutional Cash Pools and the Triffin Dilemma of the US Banking System,”
IMF (August, 2011)
Sweeney, James and Wilmot, Jonathan, “When Collateral Is King,”
Credit Suisse (March, 2012)
Mehrling, Perry, Pozsar, Zoltan, Sweeney, James and Neilson, Dan
“Bagehot Was a Shadow Banker,”
INET (November, 2013)
Sweeney, James, “Liquidity Required: Reshaping the Financial System,”
Credit Suisse (November, 2013)
Pozsar, Zoltan, “Shadow Banking: The Money View,”
US Treasury (July, 2014)
Pozsar, Zoltan, “How the Financial System Works,”
US Treasury (July, 2014)
Pozsar, Zoltan, “A Macro View of Shadow Banking,”
INET Working Paper (January, 2015)
Di Iasio, Giovanni, and Pozsar, Zoltan,
“A Model of Shadow Banking: Crises, Central Banks and Regulation,”
Banca d’Italia (May, 2015)
Pozsar, Zoltan and Sweeney, James,
“Global Money Notes #1: The Money Market Under Government Control,”
Credit Suisse (May, 2015)
Pozsar, Zoltan and Sweeney, James, “Global Money Notes #2: A Turbulent Exit,”
Credit Suisse (August, 2015)
Pozsar, Zoltan and Sweeney, James, “Global Money Notes #3: Flying Blind,”
Credit Suisse (December, 2015)
Pozsar, Zoltan, “Global Money Notes #4: A Tool of Their Own – The Foreign RRP Facility,”
Credit Suisse (February, 2016)
Pozsar, Zoltan, “Global Money Notes #5: What Excess Reserves,”
Credit Suisse (April, 2016)
Pozsar, Zoltan, “Global Money Notes #6: QE, Basel III and the Fed’s New Target Rate,”
Credit Suisse (June, 2016)
Pozsar, Zoltan “Global Money Notes #7: Japanese Banks, LIBOR and the FX Swap Lines,”
Credit Suisse (August, 2016)

Global Money Notes #8 15


GLOBAL FIXED INCOME AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH
James Sweeney, Managing Director Dr. Neal Soss, Managing Director
Head of Fixed Income and Economic Research Vice Chairman, Fixed Income Research
+1 212 538 4648 1 212 325 3335
james.sweeney@credit-suisse.com neal.soss@credit-suisse.com

US / GLOBAL ECONOMICS AND STRATEGY


James Sweeney
Chief Economist Xiao Cui Axel Lang Zoltan Pozsar Jeremy Schwartz
+1 212 538 4648 +1 212 538 2511 +1 212 538 4530 +1 212 538 3779 +1 212 538 6419
james.sweeney@credit-suisse.com xiao.cui@credit-suisse.com axel.lang@credit-suisse.com zoltan.pozsar@credit-suisse.com jeremy.schwartz@credit-suisse.com

Sarah Smith Wenzhe Zhao


+1 212 325-1022 +1 212 325 1798
sarah.smith@credit-suisse.com wenzhe.zhao@credit-suisse.com
Praveen Korapaty
Head of Interest Rate Strategy Jonathan Cohn William Marshall
212 325 3427 212 325 4923 212 325 5584
praveen.korapaty@credit-suisse.com jonathan.cohn@credit-suisse.com william.marshall@credit-suisse.com
Jamie Nicholson-Leener
Head of Latin America Credit Luis Serrano
+1 212 538 6769 +1 212 325 3147
jamie.nicholson@credit-suisse.com luis.serrano@credit-suisse.com

EUROPEAN ECONOMICS AND STRATEGY


Neville Hill
Head of European Economics & Strategy Anais Boussie Peter Foley Sonali Punhani Veronika Roharova Giovanni Zanni
+44 20 7888 1334 +44 20 7883 9639 +44 20 7883 4349 +44 20 7883 4297 +44 20 7888 2403 +44 20 7888 6827
neville.hill@credit-suisse.com anais.boussie@credit-suisse.com peter.foley@credit-suisse.com sonali.punhani@credit-suisse.com veronika.roharova@credit-suisse.com giovanni.zanni@credit-suisse.com
David Sneddon
Head of Technical Analysis Christopher Hine James Lim
44 20 7888 7173 212 538 5727 65 6212 3612
david.sneddon@credit-suisse.com christopher.hine@credit-suisse.com lifeng.lim@credit-suisse.com
William Porter
Head of European Credit Chiraag Somaia
+44 20 7888 1207 +44 20 7888 2776
william.porter@credit-suisse.com chiraag.somaia@credit-suisse.com

GLOBAL FX / EM ECONOMICS AND STRATEGY


Shahab Jalinoos
Head of Global FX Strategy Honglin Jiang Trang Thuy Le Alvise Marino Bhaveer Shah
212 325 5412 44 20 7888 1501 +852 2101 7426 212 325 5911 44 20 7883 1449
shahab.jalinoos@credit-suisse.com honglin.jiang@credit-suisse.com trangthuy.le@credit-suisse.com alvise.marino@credit-suisse.com bhaveer.shah@credit-suisse.com
Kasper Bartholdy
Head of Global EM Strategy Ashish Agrawal Daniel Chodos Nimrod Mevorach Martin Yu
+44 20 7883 4907 +65 6212 3405 +1 212 325 7708 +44 20 7888 1257 +65 6212 3448
kasper.bartholdy@credit-suisse.com ashish.agrawal@credit-suisse.com daniel.chodos@credit-suisse.com nimrod.mevorach@credit-suisse.com martin.yu@credit-suisse.com
Berna Bayazitoglu
Head of EEMEA Economics Alexey Pogorelov Carlos Teixeira
+44 20 7883 3431 +44 20 7883 0396 +27 11 012 8054
berna.bayazitoglu@credit-suisse.com alexey.pogorelov@credit-suisse.com carlos.teixeira@credit-suisse.com
Alonso Cervera
Head of Latin America Economics Juan Lorenzo Maldonado Casey Reckman Alberto Rojas
+52 55 5283 3845 +1 212 325 4245 +1 212 325 5570 +52 55 5283 8975
alonso.cervera@credit-suisse.com juanlorenzo.maldonado@credit-suisse.com casey.reckman@credit-suisse.com alberto.rojas@credit-suisse.com
Nilson Teixeira
Head of Brazil Economics Paulo Coutinho Iana Ferrao Leonardo Fonseca Lucas Vilela
+55 11 3701 6288 +55 11 3701-6353 +55 11 3701 6345 +55 11 3701 6348 +55 11 3701-6352
nilson.teixeira@credit-suisse.com paulo.coutinho@credit-suisse.com iana.ferrao@credit-suisse.com leonardo.fonseca@credit-suisse.com lucas.vilela @credit-suisse.com

ASIA PACIFIC DIVISION


Ray Farris, Managing Director
Head of Fixed Income Research and Economics, Asia Pacific Division
+65 6212 3412
ray.farris@credit-suisse.com
EMERGING ASIA ECONOMICS
Dr. Santitarn Sathirathai Vincent Chan
Head of Emerging Asia Economics Head of China Macro Deepali Bhargava Weishen Deng Christiaan Tuntono Michael Wan
+65 6212 5675 +852 2101 6568 +65 6212 5699 +852 2101 7162 +852 2101 7409 +65 6212 3418
santitarn.sathirathai@credit-suisse.com vincent.chan@credit-suisse.com deepali.bhargava@credit-suisse.com weishen.deng@credit-suisse.com christiaan.tuntono@credit-suisse.com michael.wan@credit-suisse.com

JAPAN ECONOMICS
Hiromichi Shirakawa
Head of Japan Economics Takashi Shiono
+81 3 4550 7117 +81 3 4550 7189
hiromichi.shirakawa@credit-suisse.com takashi.shiono@credit-suisse.com
Disclosure Appendix
Analyst Certification
I, Zoltan Pozsar, certify that (1) the views expressed in this report accurately reflect my personal views about all of the subject companies and
securities and (2) no part of my compensation was, is or will be directly or indirectly related to the specific recommendations or views expressed in
this report.
Important Disclosures
Credit Suisse's policy is only to publish investment research that is impartial, independent, clear, fair and not misleading. For more detail, please
refer to Credit Suisse's Policies for Managing Conflicts of Interest in connection with Investment Research: http://www.csfb.com/research-and-
analytics/disclaimer/managing_conflicts_disclaimer.html .
Credit Suisse's policy is to publish research reports as it deems appropriate, based on developments with the subject issuer, the sector or the market
that may have a material impact on the research views or opinions stated herein.
The analyst(s) involved in the preparation of this research report received compensation that is based upon various factors, including Credit Suisse's
total revenues, a portion of which are generated by Credit Suisse's Investment Banking and Fixed Income Divisions.
Credit Suisse may trade as principal in the securities or derivatives of the issuers that are the subject of this report.
At any point in time, Credit Suisse is likely to have significant holdings in the securities mentioned in this report.
As at the date of this report, Credit Suisse acts as a market maker or liquidity provider in the debt securities of the subject issuer(s) mentioned in this
report.
For important disclosure information on securities recommended in this report, please visit the website at https://rave.credit-
suisse.com/disclosures/view/fixedincome or call +1-212-538-7625.
For the history of trade ideas suggested by the Fixed Income Research department over the previous 12 months, please view the document at
https://plus.credit-suisse.com/r/aaCzfz . Credit Suisse clients with access to the Locus website may refer to http://www.credit-suisse.com/locus . For
the history of trade ideas suggested by Emerging Markets Strategy Research, please see the latest Emerging Markets Fixed Income Views report on
Credit Suisse PLUS .
For the history of recommendations provided by Technical Analysis, please visit the website at https://plus.credit-
suisse.com/ECP_S/app/container.html#loc=/MENU_FI_ECON_TECHNICAL_ANALYSIS .
Credit Suisse does not provide any tax advice. Any statement herein regarding any US federal tax is not intended or written to be used, and cannot
be used, by any taxpayer for the purposes of avoiding any penalties.
For a history of recommendations for the financial instrument(s) featured in this report, disseminated within the past 12 months, please refer to
https://rave.credit-suisse.com/disclosures/view/reportfi?i=260130&v=-70lfnz8bw789bc7s5ap8hw441 .
This research report is authored by:
Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC .................................................................................................................................................... Zoltan Pozsar
This report is produced by subsidiaries and affiliates of Credit Suisse operating under its Global Markets Division. For more information on our structure, please use the following link: https://www.credit-suisse.com/who-we-are
This report may contain material that is not directed to, or intended for distribution to or use by, any person or entity who is a citizen or resident of or located in any locality, state, country or other jurisdiction where such
distribution, publication, availability or use would be contrary to law or regulation or which would subject Credit Suisse or its affiliates ("CS") to any registration or licensing requirement within such jurisdiction. All material
presented in this report, unless specifically indicated otherwise, is under copyright to CS. None of the material, nor its content, nor any copy of it, may be altered in any way, transmitted to, copied or distributed to any other
party, without the prior express written permission of CS. All trademarks, service marks and logos used in this report are trademarks or service marks or registered trademarks or service marks of CS or its affiliates.The
information, tools and material presented in this report are provided to you for information purposes only and are not to be used or considered as an offer or the solicitation of an offer to sell or to buy or subscribe for securities
or other financial instruments. CS may not have taken any steps to ensure that the securities referred to in this report are suitable for any particular investor. CS will not treat recipients of this report as its customers by virtue of
their receiving this report. The investments and services contained or referred to in this report may not be suitable for you and it is recommended that you consult an independent investment advisor if you are in doubt about
such investments or investment services. Nothing in this report constitutes investment, legal, accounting or tax advice, or a representation that any investment or strategy is suitable or appropriate to your individual
circumstances, or otherwise constitutes a personal recommendation to you. CS does not advise on the tax consequences of investments and you are advised to contact an independent tax adviser. Please note in particular
that the bases and levels of taxation may change. Information and opinions presented in this report have been obtained or derived from sources believed by CS to be reliable, but CS makes no representation as to their
accuracy or completeness. CS accepts no liability for loss arising from the use of the material presented in this report, except that this exclusion of liability does not apply to the extent that such liability arises under specific
statutes or regulations applicable to CS. This report is not to be relied upon in substitution for the exercise of independent judgment. CS may have issued, and may in the future issue, other communications that are
inconsistent with, and reach different conclusions from, the information presented in this report. Those communications reflect the different assumptions, views and analytical methods of the analysts who prepared them and
CS is under no obligation to ensure that such other communications are brought to the attention of any recipient of this report. Some investments referred to in this report will be offered solely by a single entity and in the case
of some investments solely by CS, or an associate of CS or CS may be the only market maker in such investments. Past performance should not be taken as an indication or guarantee of future performance, and no
representation or warranty, express or implied, is made regarding future performance. Information, opinions and estimates contained in this report reflect a judgment at its original date of publication by CS and are subject to
change without notice. The price, value of and income from any of the securities or financial instruments mentioned in this report can fall as well as rise. The value of securities and financial instruments is subject to exchange
rate fluctuation that may have a positive or adverse effect on the price or income of such securities or financial instruments. Investors in securities such as ADR's, the values of which are influenced by currency volatility,
effectively assume this risk. Structured securities are complex instruments, typically involve a high degree of risk and are intended for sale only to sophisticated investors who are capable of understanding and assuming the
risks involved. The market value of any structured security may be affected by changes in economic, financial and political factors (including, but not limited to, spot and forward interest and exchange rates), time to maturity,
market conditions and volatility, and the credit quality of any issuer or reference issuer. Any investor interested in purchasing a structured product should conduct their own investigation and analysis of the product and consult
with their own professional advisers as to the risks involved in making such a purchase. Some investments discussed in this report may have a high level of volatility. High volatility investments may experience sudden and
large falls in their value causing losses when that investment is realised. Those losses may equal your original investment. Indeed, in the case of some investments the potential losses may exceed the amount of initial
investment and, in such circumstances, you may be required to pay more money to support those losses. Income yields from investments may fluctuate and, in consequence, initial capital paid to make the investment may
be used as part of that income yield. Some investments may not be readily realisable and it may be difficult to sell or realise those investments, similarly it may prove difficult for you to obtain reliable information about the
value, or risks, to which such an investment is exposed. This report may provide the addresses of, or contain hyperlinks to, websites. Except to the extent to which the report refers to website material of CS, CS has not
reviewed any such site and takes no responsibility for the content contained therein. Such address or hyperlink (including addresses or hyperlinks to CS's own website material) is provided solely for your convenience and
information and the content of any such website does not in any way form part of this document. Accessing such website or following such link through this report or CS's website shall be at your own risk.
This report is issued and distributed in European Union (except Switzerland): by Credit Suisse Securities (Europe) Limited, One Cabot Square, London E14 4QJ, England, which is authorised by the Prudential Regulation
Authority and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation Authority. Germany: Credit Suisse Securities (Europe) Limited Niederlassung Frankfurt am Main regulated by the Bundesanstalt fuer
Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht ("BaFin"). United States and Canada: Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC; Switzerland: Credit Suisse AG; Brazil: Banco de Investimentos Credit Suisse (Brasil) S.A or its affiliates; Mexico:
Banco Credit Suisse (México), S.A. (transactions related to the securities mentioned in this report will only be effected in compliance with applicable regulation); Japan: by Credit Suisse Securities (Japan) Limited, Financial
Instruments Firm, Director-General of Kanto Local Finance Bureau ( Kinsho) No. 66, a member of Japan Securities Dealers Association, The Financial Futures Association of Japan, Japan Investment Advisers Association,
Type II Financial Instruments Firms Association; Hong Kong: Credit Suisse (Hong Kong) Limited; Australia: Credit Suisse Equities (Australia) Limited; Thailand: Credit Suisse Securities (Thailand) Limited, regulated by the
Office of the Securities and Exchange Commission, Thailand, having registered address at 990 Abdulrahim Place, 27th Floor, Unit 2701, Rama IV Road, Silom, Bangrak, Bangkok10500, Thailand, Tel. +66 2614 6000;
Malaysia: Credit Suisse Securities (Malaysia) Sdn Bhd, Credit Suisse AG, Singapore Branch; India: Credit Suisse Securities (India) Private Limited (CIN no.U67120MH1996PTC104392) regulated by the Securities and
Exchange Board of India as Research Analyst (registration no. INH 000001030) and as Stock Broker (registration no. INB230970637; INF230970637; INB010970631; INF010970631), having registered address at 9th Floor,
Ceejay House, Dr.A.B. Road, Worli, Mumbai - 18, India, T- +91-22 6777 3777; South Korea: Credit Suisse Securities (Europe) Limited, Seoul Branch; Taiwan: Credit Suisse AG Taipei Securities Branch; Indonesia: PT
Credit Suisse Securities Indonesia; Philippines: Credit Suisse Securities (Philippines ) Inc., and elsewhere in the world by the relevant authorised affiliate of the above.
Additional Regional Disclaimers
Hong Kong: Credit Suisse (Hong Kong) Limited ("CSHK") is licensed and regulated by the Securities and Futures Commission of Hong Kong under the laws of Hong Kong, which differ from Australian laws. CSHKL does
not hold an Australian financial services licence (AFSL) and is exempt from the requirement to hold an AFSL under the Corporations Act 2001 (the Act) under Class Order 03/1103 published by the ASIC in respect of financial
services provided to Australian wholesale clients (within the meaning of section 761G of the Act). Research on Taiwanese securities produced by Credit Suisse AG, Taipei Securities Branch has been prepared by a
registered Senior Business Person.
Malaysia: Research provided to residents of Malaysia is authorised by the Head of Research for Credit Suisse Securities (Malaysia) Sdn Bhd, to whom they should direct any queries on +603 2723 2020.
Singapore: This report has been prepared and issued for distribution in Singapore to institutional investors, accredited investors and expert investors (each as defined under the Financial Advisers Regulations) only, and is
also distributed by Credit Suisse AG, Singapore branch to overseas investors (as defined under the Financial Advisers Regulations). By virtue of your status as an institutional investor, accredited investor, expert investor or
overseas investor, Credit Suisse AG, Singapore branch is exempted from complying with certain compliance requirements under the Financial Advisers Act, Chapter 110 of Singapore (the "FAA"), the Financial Advisers
Regulations and the relevant Notices and Guidelines issued thereunder, in respect of any financial advisory service which Credit Suisse AG, Singapore branch may provide to you.
UAE: This information is being distributed by Credit Suisse AG (DIFC Branch), duly licensed and regulated by the Dubai Financial Services Authority (“DFSA”). Related financial services or products are only made available
to Professional Clients or Market Counterparties, as defined by the DFSA, and are not intended for any other persons. Credit Suisse AG (DIFC Branch) is located on Level 9 East, The Gate Building, DIFC, Dubai, United
Arab Emirates.
EU: This report has been produced by subsidiaries and affiliates of Credit Suisse operating under its Global Markets Division
This research may not conform to Canadian disclosure requirements.
In jurisdictions where CS is not already registered or licensed to trade in securities, transactions will only be effected in accordance with applicable securities legislation, which will vary from jurisdiction to jurisdiction and may
require that the trade be made in accordance with applicable exemptions from registration or licensing requirements. Non-US customers wishing to effect a transaction should contact a CS entity in their local jurisdiction
unless governing law permits otherwise. US customers wishing to effect a transaction should do so only by contacting a representative at Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC in the US.
Please note that this research was originally prepared and issued by CS for distribution to their market professional and institutional investor customers. Recipients who are not market professional or institutional investor
customers of CS should seek the advice of their independent financial advisor prior to taking any investment decision based on this report or for any necessary explanation of its contents. This research may relate to
investments or services of a person outside of the UK or to other matters which are not authorised by the Prudential Regulation Authority and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation
Authority or in respect of which the protections of the Prudential Regulation Authority and Financial Conduct Authority for private customers and/or the UK compensation scheme may not be available, and further details as to
where this may be the case are available upon request in respect of this report.
CS may provide various services to US municipal entities or obligated persons ("municipalities"), including suggesting individual transactions or trades and entering into such transactions. Any services CS provides to
municipalities are not viewed as "advice" within the meaning of Section 975 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. CS is providing any such services and related information solely on an arm's
length basis and not as an advisor or fiduciary to the municipality. In connection with the provision of the any such services, there is no agreement, direct or indirect, between any municipality (including the
officials,management, employees or agents thereof) and CS for CS to provide advice to the municipality. Municipalities should consult with their financial, accounting and legal advisors regarding any such services provided
by CS. In addition, CS is not acting for direct or indirect compensation to solicit the municipality on behalf of an unaffiliated broker, dealer, municipal securities dealer, municipal advisor, or investment adviser for the purpose of
obtaining or retaining an engagement by the municipality for or in connection with Municipal Financial Products, the issuance of municipal securities, or of an investment adviser to provide investment advisory services to or on
behalf of the municipality. If this report is being distributed by a financial institution other than Credit Suisse AG, or its affiliates, that financial institution is solely responsible for distribution. Clients of that institution should contact
that institution to effect a transaction in the securities mentioned in this report or require further information. This report does not constitute investment advice by Credit Suisse to the clients of the distributing financial institution,
and neither Credit Suisse AG, its affiliates, and their respective officers, directors and employees accept any liability whatsoever for any direct or consequential loss arising from their use of this report or its content. Principal is
not guaranteed. Commission is the commission rate or the amount agreed with a customer when setting up an account or at any time after that.
Copyright © 2016 CREDIT SUISSE AG and/or its affiliates. All rights reserved.
Investment principal on bonds can be eroded depending on sale price or market price. In addition, there are bonds on which investment principal can
be eroded due to changes in redemption amounts. Care is required when investing in such instruments.
When you purchase non-listed Japanese fixed income securities (Japanese government bonds, Japanese municipal bonds, Japanese government guaranteed bonds, Japanese corporate bonds) from CS as a seller, you
will be requested to pay the purchase price only.

You might also like