The "Exorbitant Privilege" - A Theoretical Exposition
The "Exorbitant Privilege" - A Theoretical Exposition
The "Exorbitant Privilege" - A Theoretical Exposition
Wenli Cheng
Department of Economics, Monash University
Dingsheng Zhang
China Economics and Management Academy
Central University of Finance and Economics
Abstract: This paper develops a general equilibrium model to study how the
“exorbitant advantage” works, whether it is sustainable, and what may be the
consequences if it is removed. Its main findings are: (1) the center country that issues
the reserve currency enjoys the “exorbitant advantage” in the sense that her current
account deficit can be financed by the periphery country’s reserve holdings. The
“exorbitant privilege” is predicated on the overvaluation of the reserve currency
caused by a higher rate of money growth in the center country; (2) the “exorbitant
advantage” is not likely to be sustainable in the long run; (3) if the “exorbitant
advantage” is removed, the value of the reserve currency will depreciate, the terms of
trade will change against the periphery country and sector composition will change in
favour of the tradable sector in the center country and in favour of the non-tradable
sector in periphery country. These changes will be more pronounced if the center
country repays her debt by printing money instead of raising taxes.
1
1. Introduction
The term “exorbitant privilege” was coined in 1965 by the then French Minister
Valery Giscard d’Estaing to describe the US’s unique ability to finance large external
deficits (Gourinchas and Rey, 2005). The French economist Jacques Rueff (1971)
is to say, the United States, for example - it pays the creditor country dollars,
which end up with the latter's central bank. But the dollars are of no use in Bonn
or in Tokyo or in Paris. The very same day, they are reloaned to the New York
money market, so that they return to the place or origin. Thus the debtor country
does not lose what the creditor country has gained. So the key-currency country
never feels the effect of a deficit in its balance of payments. And the main
Rueff (1971) argues that the American balance-of-payment deficits (over the 1950s)
he analyses was not brought about by the United States; rather it was “the outcome of
“By accepting this substitution, the banks of issue put themselves in a position
of being able to lend immediately to the United States, wholly or in part, the
deficits. …
2
To the extent that the new system was applied, it in fact released the United
States from the obligation of settling its foreign debts. Thus the United States
was in a position to lend, to give, and even to buy outside its own frontiers
More generally, Rueff (1971) contends that the gold-exchange standard “allowed the
without taking, to lend without borrowing and to acquire without paying.” (p.23)
Fifty years on, the Bretton Woods System that Rueff criticizes has long broken
down, but the US appears to continue to enjoy the “exorbitant privilege” as evidenced
by its apparent ease in acquiring foreign debts to finance its persistent current account
and fiscal deficits. This “exorbitant privilege”, as Rueff might argue, is attributable to
the “international prestige” that the US dollar possesses. Besides being the main
vehicle currency in foreign exchange markets, the main invoice currency for
international trade, the US dollar is the most important reserve currency and the US
Treasury securities are widely held by central banks around the world as official
exchange reserves. Given the US dollar’s dominant position and the fact that the US
dollar is no longer tied to gold, the current international monetary order is referred to
as the “dollar standard” (McKinnon, 2001). A notable feature of the dollar standard in
recent decades is that some fast growing Asian countries (including those that have
officially adopted floating exchange rate systems) choose to fix the value of their
local currencies against the US dollar (Calvo and Reinhart, 2002). The outcome of
these unilateral choices of exchange rate policies resembles the arrangement under the
Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, thus Dooley, Folkerts-Landau, &
3
Garber (2004) characterise it as the “Revived Bretton Woods system”, with the US
How does the “exorbitant privilege” work under the “Revived Bretton Woods
system”? Is the system sustainable? What might happen to the real economies of the
world should the centre country lose its “exorbitant privilege”? These are the
simple two-country, three-good trade model with money. The setup of our model is
similar to that in Lucas (1982) and Stockman & Dellas (1989), but our model makes
Bretton Woods system”: (1) the currency of the centre country (the “dollar”) is the
medium of exchange used in international trade and is the reserve currency of the
periphery country; (2) the periphery country’s currency is pegged to the dollar, with
the peg maintained by the periphery country’s intervention in the foreign exchange
market; (3) the periphery country’s foreign exchange reserves are invested in country
2’s government bonds with no well-defined date of net repayment; and (4) the funds
raised from the government bond issue are given to the citizens of the center country
as transfer payments.
Based on our model, we come to three main conclusions. First, the centre
country that issues the reserve currency has the “exorbitant privilege” in the following
sense: once the center country’s current account deficits translates into increases in
reserves of the periphery country, the increased reserve is reinvested in the center
country, thus the center country’s deficits are more or less automatically funded.
However, having access to automatic funding does not mean that the center country
will necessarily run a current account deficit. The presence of a current account deficit
4
is an indication that the currency of the centre country is overvalued. The
overvaluation may be caused by a higher rate of money growth in the centre country
or by a desire on the part of the periphery country to devalue its currency for
is also broadly consistent with the casual observation that the increase in global
imbalances during the years prior to the global financial crisis of 2008 coincided with
both an easy monetary policy environment in the US and a fast rate of official reserve
accumulation in Asia.
not change, the center country does not utilise its “exorbitant privilege” although it
continues to benefit from the existing reserves invested by the periphery country. If
the policies of the center country or the periphery country or both make the dollar
overvalued, trade imbalance will occur. The imbalance cannot be sustained in the long
Third, if the “exorbitant privilege” were to be removed in the sense that the
demand for the dollar as a reserve currency falls significantly and the periphery
country withdraws (a part of) its reserves invested in the center country, the dollar
5
would fall in value, the terms of trade would change against the periphery country and
the sector composition would change in favour of the tradable sector in country 2 and
the non-tradable sector country 1. The dollar depreciation and country 1’ terms of
trade deterioration would be more drastic, but the changes in sectoral composition
would be less pronounced if the centre country chose to repay its debt by “printing
Our paper connects with three related strands of literature. The first literature
concerns the “exorbitant privilege”. Gourinchas and Rey (2005) find that the US
enjoys an “exorbitant privilege” in the sense that US’s return on its external assets
was notably higher than foreigners’ return on US liabilities for over half a century
since the early 1950s. Gourinchas, Rey and Govillot (2010) further argue that the
worsening of US foreign asset position during the recent global financial crisis when
exorbitant privilege is somewhat different from ours since they emphasise the excess
return of US external assets whereas we focus on the center country’s ability to obtain
automatic funding for its external deficits. However our analysis points to an
explanation for the excess return of US external assets, namely that, government
policies under the dollar standard can create a powerful force that draws large
amounts of official reserves from periphery countries to the US. Since safety is the
main concern for the owners of official reserves, the reserves are typically invested in
6
Secondly, our paper relates to the literature concerning the direction of
international capital flows. The flow of official reserves from the poor periphery to
the rich center country in our model constitutes a significant part of the “global saving
glut” which Bernanke (2005, 2007) suggests may be a contributing factor to the
global financial crisis. The direction of capital flow in our paper is also consistent
with the empirical findings documented by Lucas (1990) and Alfaro et al. (2008).
Thirdly, our paper contributes to the ongoing debate on the causes and
argued that the imbalances may be an equilibrium outcome resulting from the fact that
different regions of the world differ in their capacity to generate financial assets from
real investments (Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas, 2008). It is further suggested that
the pattern of global capital flow associated with the imbalances may be “optimal”
sector (Dooley and Garber, 2007). On the pessimistic side, there are concerns that the
global imbalances cannot be sustained and that its eventual correction may trigger a
dollar crisis and impose substantial adjustment costs on the world economy. For
instance, Blanchard, Giavazzi, & Sa (2005) argue that the increases in US demand for
foreign goods and in foreign demand for US assets are behind the US current account
deficits. They predict that the current account deficit must be reversed in the future
Rogoff (2005) present a model of an adjustment process through which global balance
versus foreign goods. They also predict a large depreciation of the US dollar. The
conclusions of our paper are closer to the pessimistic view of the debate. However,
7
our focus is on the role of the US dollar as the reserve currency and the ramifications
of government policies in both the center country and the periphery for the global
imbalances.
Consider a world with two countries, country 1 (the periphery country) with a
Individuals in both countries derive utility from consuming three goods X, Y and Z
trade is mediated by each country’s domestic currency, the “yuan” in country 1 and
the “dollar” in country 2; and international trade is meditated by the dollar. As a result,
their budget constraint has a domestic currency component and a foreign exchange
exchange rate is fixed at e and country 1’s central bank maintains this rate by buying
We assume that all of country 1’s foreign exchange reserves are in dollars and
exogenously determined interest rate i). Bond repayments are financed by new bond
issues. The funds raised by issuing bonds are distributed to country 2’s consumers in
transfer payments.
8
subject to the budget constraint:
pxt FX Gt
x2t + p yt y2t + pz2 t z2t =w2t + .
e N2
In the above decision problems, subscript t denotes time t and subscript i (i=1, 2)
denotes country i; xit , yit , zit are quantities of goods X, Y and Z consumed;
pxt , p yt , pzi t are money prices of goods X, Y and Z denominated in the currency of the
country of production; wit is the wage rate; FX It is the foreign exchange (dollars)
purchased in the foreign exchange market to pay for imports (good Y); e is the fixed
exchange rate; FX Gt is the amount of dollars purchased by country 1’s central bank in
reserves and the reserves are invested in country 2’s government bond, FX Gt / N 2 is
the per person transfer payment from the country 2’s government funded by its bond
issue.
On the supply side, producers in country 1 produce goods X and Z using the
following technologies:
where L1xt and L1zt are labor devoted to producing goods X and Z in country 1.
9
Under the assumption of perfect competition, the following conditions hold:
Equation (4) is a standard zero-profit condition. Equation (5) stipulates that the
difference between country 1’s total value of production and its total value of
consumption is the value of trade surplus, which is equal to the amount of the foreign
has a trade surplus, country 1’s central bank buys FX Gt dollars (with FX Gt e yuan),
invests the same amount in country 2’s government bonds, enabling country 2 to
Y2t = a2 y L2 yt , Z 2t = a2 z L2 zt . (6)
π yt = p yt Z 2t − w2t L2 yt =0 , π z t = pz t Z 2t − w2t L2 zt = 0 .
2 2
(7)
N1 y1t + N 2 y2t =
Y2t =
a2 y L2 yt . (10)
L1xt + L1zt =
N1 , L2 yt + L2 zt =
N2 . (11)
10
(5) The foreign exchange market:
pxt
N1 FX It + FX Gt = N 2 x2t . (12)
e
The left-hand side of equation (12) is the sum of private demand for dollars (to pay
for imports) and central bank’s purchase of dollars; the right hand side is country 1’s
Strictly speaking, there are no separate markets for money – money, as the medium of
government intervention in the foreign exchange market, but the government can still
choose a rate of money growth π 1 (although this will affect the amount of foreign
exchange intervention required to maintain a given exchange rate). The time path of
(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) + FX Gt e ,
m1t = (13)
where π 1t is a measure of money growth rate (on the basis of last period’s money
assuming no sterilisation.
After a foreign exchange market intervention, country 1’s reserve holdings are:
R=
t FX Gt + (1 + i ) Rt −1 , (14)
where Rt −1 is the reserve holdings in the previous period, and i is the (exogenous)
The total money supply is equal to the total wage income in each country:
Solving the consumers’ decision problems (1) and (2), and applying zero
profit conditions and market clearing conditions, we obtain the solutions for all
endogenous variables in the model, which are presented in Table 1. 1 Based on the
model outlined above and the solutions presented in Table 1, we now attempt to
answer the questions set out in the introduction section, namely, how the “exorbitant
privilege” works, whether it is sustainable, and what would likely happen to the
3. Analysis
ability to obtain automatic funding for its trade deficit because the dollar is the
periphery country’s reserve currency and the reserves are invested in the center
only utilised when country 2 runs a trade deficit which is funded by country 1’s
which implies,
α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
FX Gt ≥ 0 ⇔ e ≥ . (17)
α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
1
These solutions describe a temporary “state of rest” in the sense that consumers behave optimally and
markets clear; they are not real equilibrium solutions as external trade is not balanced. There is a
market tendency to regain balance as explained in section 3.
12
Since the fixed exchange rate ( e ) coincides with the free market exchange rate when
higher than the free market rate, or in other words, when the dollar is overvalued.
Suppose e is equal to the free market rate at time t-1, an overvaluation of the dollar
may occur at time t if country 1 devalues its currency ( e becomes larger), and/or if
the rate of money growth in country 2 is higher than that in country 1 ( π 2 > π 1 ).
Once the exorbitant privilege is utilised at time t (i.e., FX Gt > 0 ), the money
equal, the increase in country 1’s money supply lowers the market value of country
1’s currency relative to the dollar, thereby driving the fixed exchange rate towards the
free market rate in the next period. Therefore, in the absence of continued devaluation
is likely that the policies in the periphery country or the centre country or both have
While government policies in the center country and/or in the periphery can
lead to persistent external imbalances, it does not mean that “exorbitant privilege” is
sustainable. A necessary condition for the “exorbitant privilege” is that the periphery
country is willing to use the dollar as its reserve currency. An important reason why
currency based on past experiences. If, as shown above, the utilisation of the
supports the dollar as a reserve currency, therefore the system cannot be sustainable in
The use of the “exorbitant privilege” also has other consequences that lower
the sustainability of the system. From the periphery country’s perspective, the
which over time tend to go above its desired level. As the increase in reserves is lent
back to the central country on an indefinite basis, it leads to the peculiar direction of
long-term capital flow from the relatively poor periphery country to the relatively rich
centre country, and since the capital flow is the outcome of a net flow of goods in the
opposite direction, it has the effect of transferring real resources from the periphery to
the centre.
While the centre country benefits from the real resource transfer in the short
run, there are long run costs. First of all, the flip side of the increase in reserves by the
periphery country is the centre country’s accumulation of debt. Although the debt is
denominated in dollars and has no well-defined time frame for net repayment,
sovereign debt problems can escalate and result in financial crises as the history of the
last eight centuries amply testifies (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009). Secondly, the use of
L1xt α1 + α 2
= (18)
L1zt α3
which implies that if the “exorbitant privilege” is at work, then country 2 has a lower
words, the use of the “exorbitant privilege” results in a change in the sectoral
composition in the centre country in favour of the non-tradable sector at the expense
of the tradeable sector. This is politically undesirable as it raises concerns about the
“hollowing out” of the manufacturing sector in the centre country. The sectoral
comparative advantage, and entails future adjustment costs to the extent that the bias
If, as argued above, the “exorbitant privilege” cannot be sustained in the long run, the
logical next question is what would happen if it were removed. By the removal of the
“exorbitant privilege”, we mean that the standing of the dollar as a reserve currency is
in question and the periphery country not only stops accumulating dollar reserves, but
also gradually reduces its dollar reserves over time. As the dollar reserves are held in
the form of the centre country’s government bonds, a reduction of reserves amounts to
demanding the centre country’s government to repay its debt. The centre country’s
government may raise taxes to repay the debt (case 1), or it may simply print money
to meet its debt obligations since its debt is denominated in dollars (case 2). In the
following we present two simple models to illustrate what would likely happen to the
economies of the centre and the periphery countries in these two cases.
15
For simplicity of illustration, our models assume: (1) the government of the
periphery country an equal amount of principal in each period; and (2) the debt
payments.
The model for case 1 is similar to that presented in section 2 except for 3 differences.
which changes the foreign exchange component of the budget constraint. The decision
∆Rt
foreign exchange: p yt=
y1t FX It + ,
N1
Second, an individual consumer in country 2 now has to pay a tax to fund the
pxt ∆R
x2t + p yt y2t + pz2 t z2t =w2t − t ,
e N2
where ∆Rt / N 2 is the per capita tax imposed for the purpose of debt repayment.
16
Third, the periphery country no longer intervenes in the foreign exchange
market. As a result, the clearance condition for the foreign exchange market becomes:
pxt
N1 FX It = N 2 x2t , (23)
et
m1=
t (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) (24)
Now consider case 2 where country 2’s government simply discharges its debt
obligations with “printed” dollars. The model for case 2 differs from that for case 1 in
two aspects. First, consumers in country 2 are no longer required to pay tax to fund
the debt repayments, thus the decision problem for the representative consumer in
country 2 is:
pxt
x2t + p yt y2t + pz2 t z2t =
w2t
e
Secondly, the dollar “printing” changes country 2’s money supply, which becomes:
We solve for the equilibrium for each of the models outlined above and
present the solutions in Table 2. Based on the results in Table 2, we investigate how
the economies would respond to the removal of the “exorbitant privilege”, focusing
on the exchange rate, the terms of trade, and sectoral composition in each country.
Intuitively, the removal of the “exorbitant privilege” means that the demand
for the dollar would fall, therefore the value of the dollar would fall as well. The value
17
of the dollar would fall by more if country 2 also increases its supply of dollar to
discharge its debts. As shown in Table 2, the exchange rates under the two cases are:
α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
Case 1: (et )1 = , (27)
α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt
α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
Case 2: (et ) 2 = . (28)
α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
From equation (17), we know that for the “exorbitant privilege” to work, the dollar
α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
e> . (29)
α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
Inequality (30) implies that if the “exorbitant privilege” were removed, the dollar
would depreciate in value; and that the dollar would depreciate more in the case 2
(where country 2 resorts to money printing to meet its debt obligations) than in case 1
Now consider the terms of trade. From Table 1, we have the prices for tradable
(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
( p yt )ep = , (32)
a2 y N 2
From Table 2, we have the prices for tradable goods in the two models with the
18
(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
Case 1: ( pxt )1 = , ( p yt )1 = , (33)
a1x N1 a2 y N 2
pxt p
( )1 > ( xt ) 2 . (36)
p yt p yt
Equations (35) and (36) suggest that the removal of the “exorbitant privilege” would
leads to a fall in country 1’s terms of trade; and the fall would be more pronounced in
case 2 than in case 1. The fall in country 1’ terms of trade is driven by a change in
relative demand for goods X and Y due to income changes in country 1 and country 2.
The relative price change is larger in case 2 because the increase in money supply in
the ratio of labor employed in the tradable sector relative to that in the non-tradable
have each country’s sector composition in the model of the “exorbitant privilege”:
L1xt α + α2
Country 1: ( )ep = 1 , (37)
L1zt α3
19
From Table 2, we have each country’s sector composition with the removal of the
α 2 m2t
(α1 + α 2 )
L1xt α 2 m2t + α 3 ∆Rt
Case 1: ( )1 = (39)
L1zt α 2 m2t
(1 − α1 − α 2 )
α 2 m2t + α 3∆Rt
∆Rt
(α1 + α 2 + α 3
)
L2 yt m2t
( )1 = (40)
L2 zt ∆R
(1 − α1 − α 2 − α 3 t )
m2t
α 2 ∆Rt
(1 − α 3 − α 3 )
L1xt α1m2t + α 3 ∆Rt
Case 2: ( )2 = (41)
L1zt α 2 ∆Rt
(α 3 + α 3 )
α1m2t + α 3∆Rt
L2 yt 1 − α3
( )2 = (42)
L2 zt α3
L1xt L L
( )ep > ( 1xt ) 2 > ( 1xt )1 (43)
L1zt L1zt L1zt
L2 yt L2 yt L2 yt α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
( )ep < ( )2 < ( )1 if e > (44)
L2 zt L2 zt L2 zt α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
Inequalities (43) and (44) suggest that with the removal of the “exorbitant privilege”,
labour resources would move away from the tradable sector (producing good X) in
country 1 and move towards the tradable sector (producing good Y) in country 2. The
changes in sectoral composition are driven by changes in relative demand for good X
and good Y. The extent of change in sector composition would be smaller in case 2
than in case 1 because in case 2, debt repayment financed by dollar “printing” drives
20
up of the price of good Y, therefore the relative demand increase for good Y is
smaller.
4. Concluding remarks
In this paper, we have presented a set of three simple models to study how the
“exorbitant advantage” works, whether it is sustainable, and what would be the likely
consequences if it were removed. We have shown that the presence of the “exorbitant
policies in the periphery and/or the center country. We have argued that the
“exorbitant privilege” is unsustainable in the long run, and that its removal would
likely lead to a dollar depreciation, a change in the terms of trade against the
periphery, and a change in sector composition in favour of the tradable sector in the
Our model has some simplifying assumptions which we hope to relax in future
research. Although relaxing these assumptions does not qualitatively change the main
phenomena we want to study so that we can gain a deeper understanding of them. For
simplifies the model as the consumers’ decisions become time independent. With the
inclusion of private lending and borrowing in the model, the extent of the “exorbitant
privilege” may be greater because the capital flowing into the center country can be
used to finance both the center country’s current account deficit and its external asset
acquisition, enabling the center country to become the world’s “venture capitalist”
21
Another simplifying assumption in this paper is that there is no private
demand for money therefore money does not enter the consumers’ utility function.
Under the dollar standard, there is a demand for dollars in the periphery but virtually
no demand for the periphery countries’ currencies in the center country. If this
asymmetry in money demand is included in the model, a higher monetary growth rate
in the center country (which results in the utilisation of the “exorbitant privilege”) can
lead to a greater resource transfer from the periphery to the center country. This is
because higher money growth leads to higher prices which increase the transaction
demand for dollars in the periphery, and this increase in demand for dollar holdings
of dollars in the foreign exchange market. With the introduction of a partial (but not
complete) sterilisation, it will slow down but not stop the process through which the
fixed exchange rate approaches the free market level, consequently the exorbitant
privilege can persist for longer but not forever in the absence of continued policy
interventions.
References
Aizenman, J. (2010). On the causes of global imbalances and their persistence: myths,
facts and conjectures. In S. J. E. a. B. H. Stijn Claessens (Ed.), Rebalancing
the global economy: a primer for policymaking: CEPR London.
Alfaro, L., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., and Volosovych, V. (2008). Why doesn't capital flow
from rich to poor countries? An empirical investigation. The Review of
Economics and Statistics 90(2).
Bernanke, B. S. (2005). The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit
speech delivered for the Sandridge Lecture at the Virginia Association of
Economists, Richmond, March 10,
www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/200503102/default.htm.
22
Bernanke, B. S. (2007). Global Imbalances: Recent Developments and Prospects.
Speech delivered at the Bundesbank Lecture, Berlin, Germany, September 11.
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20070911a.htm.
Blanchard, O., Giavazzi, F., and Sa, F. (2005). International Investors, the U.S.
Current Account, and the Dollar. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity(1),
1-49.
Caballero, R. J., Farhi, E., and Gourinchas, P.-O. (2008). An Equilibrium Model of
'Global Imbalances' and Low Interest Rates. American Economic Review,
98(1), 358-393.
Calvo, G. A., and Reinhart, C. M. (2002). Fear of Floating. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 117(2), 379-408.
Cheng, W. and Zhang, D. (forthcoming). International Transmission of Monetary
Shocks and the Non-neutrality of International Money, Review of
International Economics.
Dooley, M., Folkerts-Landau, and Garber, P. (2004). The Revived Bretton Woods
System. International Journal of Finance and Economics, 9(4), 307-313.
Dooley, M., and Garber, P. (2007). Is It 1958 or 1968? Three Notes on the Longevity
of the Revived Bretton Woods System. In R. H. Clarida (Ed.), G-7 Current
Account Imbalances: Sustainability and Adjustment (pp. 103-132). Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Gourinchas, P.-O., and Rey, H. (2005). From World Banker to World Venture
Capitalist: US External Adjustment and the Exobitant Privilege. NBER
working paper 11563.
Gourinchas, P.-O., Rey, H., and Govillot, N. (2010). Exorbitant privilege and
exorbitant duty. IMES Discussion Paper Series 10-E-20, Bank of Japan.
Huang, X.D., and Suchada, T. (2003). Sources of Exchange Rate Fluctuations: The
Cases of Mexico and Thailand in the Aftermaths of their Recent Currency
Crises. Annals of Economics and Finance 4, 375-400.
Lucas, R. E. (1982). Interest rates and currency prices in a two-country world. Journal
of Monetary Economics, 10(3), 335-359.
Lucas, R. E. (1990). Why doesn't capital flow from rich to poor countries? American
Economic Review 80, 92-106.
McKinnon, R. I. (2001). The International Dollar Standard and the Sustainability of
the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
2001(1), 227-239.
Obstfeld, M., and Rogoff, K. S. (2005). Global Current Account Imbalances and
Exchange Rate Adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity(1), 67-
123.
Reinhart, C. M., and Rogoff, K. S. (2009). This time is different : eight centuries of
financial folly. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rueff, J. (1971). The Monetary Sin of the West. New York: MacMillan.
Stockman, A., and Dellas, H. (1989). International Portfolio Nondiversification and
Exchange Rate Variability. Journal of International Economics, 26, 271-289.
23
Table 1. Solutions for the model of “Exorbitant Privilege”
Equilibrium solutions
Purchase of “dollars” α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) e − α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
by country 1’s central FX Gt =
bank (1 − α1 + α 2 )e
(1 − α1 )(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) + α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) e
w1t =
(1 − α1 + α 2 ) N1
Wages
(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
w2t =
N2
α1 (1 − α1 − α 2 )(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) + α1 (1 + α1 + α 2 )(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) e
pxt = ,
(1 − α1 + α 2 )(α1 + α 2 )a1x N1
24
Table 2. Equilibrium Solutions for the models of debt repayment
Case 1 Case 2
α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) α 2 (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
Exchange rate et = et =
α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
w1t = w1t =
N1 N1
Wages
(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
w2t = w2t =
N2 N2
(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
pxt = pxt =
a1x N1 a1x N1
(1 + π 1 )m1(t −1) (1 + π 1 )m1(t −1)
pz1t = pz1t =
a1z N1 a1z N1
Prices
(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ∆Rt
p yt = =p yt +
a2 y N 2 a2 y N 2 a2 y (1 − α 3 ) N 2
(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
p z2 t = p z2 t =
a2 z N 2 a2 z N 2
α 2 ∆Rt
=x1t a1xα1 (1 + ) α 2 ∆Rt
α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt =x1t a1xα1{1 + }
α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
N 2 α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + (α 2 + α 3 )∆Rt
y1t = a2 y
( ) N α1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt
N1 (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) y1t= (1 − α 3 )a2 y 2 [ ]
N1 (1 − α 3 )(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt
α 2 ∆Rt
=z1t α 3a1z {1 + } α 2 ∆Rt
α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt = z1t α 3a1z {1 + }
Consumption α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
N [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] − ∆Rt
x2t = α1α 2 a1x 1 N [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] − ∆Rt
N 2 α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt x2t = α1α 2 a1x 1
N 2 α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
∆Rt
= y2t α 2 a2 y {1 − } (1 + π 2 )m2(t −1)
[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] y2t α 2 (1 − α 3 )a2 y [
= ]
(1 − α 3 )(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt
∆Rt
= z2t α 3a2 z {1 − } z2t = α 3 a2 z
[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ]
α 2 [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ]
α1 + α 2 α 2 ∆Rt
L1xt α 2 [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt 1 − α3 − α3
= L1xt α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
L1zt α 2 [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] =
Labor ratio:
1 − α1 − α 2 L1zt α 2 ∆Rt
tradable α 2 [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ] + α 3∆Rt α3 + α3
vs. non- α1[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) + ∆Rt ] + α 3∆Rt
tradable ∆Rt
α1 + α 2 + α 3
L2 yt [(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ]
= L2 yt 1 − α3
L2 zt ∆Rt =
1 − α1 − α 2 − α 3 L2 zt α3
[(1 + π 2 )m2(t −1) ]
25