Comparative Statics: Introduction: M C C - C S 1
Comparative Statics: Introduction: M C C - C S 1
Comparative Statics: Introduction: M C C - C S 1
In many economic problems, the solution, or equilibrium, depends on one or more parameters, and
we want to know how the solution changes when a parameter changes
• In the ISLM model we find a solution for output y and the interest rate r , which depends on
government spending G and the money supply M :
y = y(G, M ), r = r(G, M )
∂y ∂r
Then and tell us how y and r change with G
∂G ∂G
For each value of x you could try to solve the equation, to obtain a corresponding value of y
When possible (if there’s a unique y for each x) the equation defines y as an implicit function of x
• F (x, y) = 3x2 − 2y
• F (x, y) = y + ln(y + 1) − x
• F (x, y) = x2 + y 2 − 4
. . . differentiate the whole equation wrt x, allowing for the fact that y is a function of x
dy 1 dy dy y+2 dy y+1
• y + ln(y + 1) = x ⇒ + =1 ⇒ =1 ⇒ =
dx y + 1 dx dx y+1 dx y+2
Note that if x and y satisfy F (x, y) = 0, and there is an infinitesimal change in x and y so that the
equation is still satisfied, then the total differential dF = 0 is
dy F1(x, y)
dF = F1dx + F2dy = 0 ⇒ =−
dx F2(x, y)
∂u ∂u dy ∂u . ∂u
u(x, y) = c ⇒ dx + dy = 0 ⇒ =−
∂x ∂y dx ∂x ∂y
If u(x, y) is homothetic then u(x, y) = g(f (x, y)) where f is h.o.d. r and g is monotonic
Writing ux and uy for the partial derivatives, note that ux = g 0(f )fx and uy = g 0(f )fy (so the
indifference curves are the same for any g )
Suppose x ∈ Rm, and (x∗, y ∗) is a solution to F (x, y) = 0. Suppose that F is C 1 in an open ball
around (x∗, y ∗), with ∂F ∗ ∗ 1
∂y (x , y ) 6= 0. Then there is a C function y = y(x) defined on an open
ball around x∗ such that
1. y(x∗) = y ∗
2. F (x, y(x)) = 0
∂y ∂F . ∂F
3. (x, y) = −
∂xi ∂xi ∂y
Implication: If F (x, y) = 0 has a solution y ∗ for a particular x∗, then it is legitimate to think of y as
a function of x around that point, and you can determine how y changes from y ∗ when x changes
a little from x∗ by implicitly differentiating
Suppose (x∗, y∗) is a solution to F(x, y) = 0 and that each Fi is C 1 around this point, then a
generalisation of the Implicit Function Theorem above allows you to determine how yk changes
from yk∗ when xj changes a little from x∗j . Implicitly differentiating the ith equation wrt xj
and provided the Jacobian matrix is non-singular you can solve or use Cramer’s rule
More generally, you can allow for all the xj s to change by taking the total differential:
X ∂F
∂F1 ∂F1 ∂F1 1
dxj
...
∂y1 ∂y2 ∂yn dy1 Xj ∂xj
∂F2
∂F2 ∂F2 ∂F2
... dy2 dxj
⇒ ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂yn = − j ∂xj
... ... ... .. ...
.
X
∂Fn ∂Fn ∂Fn dyn ∂F n
∂y1 ∂y2 ... ∂yn ∂x dxj
j j
−1
∂P ∂S ∂QS ∂S ∂P
= D2 − D1 >0 ⇒ e.g. = >0
∂r ∂P ∂r ∂P ∂r
−1
∂P 0 ∂S ∂QD ∂P
= S − D1 >0 ⇒ e.g. = D1 <0
∂t ∂P ∂t ∂t