Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 243

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

FOR
BUSINESS AND STRATEGIC
DECISIONS

Delta Publishing Company


Copyright  2008 by

DELTA PUBLISHING COMPANY

P.O. Box 5332, Los Alamitos, CA 90721-5332

All rights reserved. No part of this course may be


reproduced in any form or by any means, without
permission in writing from the publisher.

ii
PREFACE

This course provides a clear and concise introduction to managerial economics.


The course managerial economics is offered in a variety of titles including business
economics, economic analysis for business decisions, economics for management decisions, etc. at
both the undergraduate and graduate levels.

It focuses on the fundamentals and essentials needed to understand how business decisions
are made and tackled using economics and other quantitative tools. It illustrates decisions with
many solved problems to test and help students reinforce their understanding of the subject.
Further, many business professionals can benefit from this course. The reader is assumed to have
done some introductory-level work in economics. A minimal amount of background in college-level
math and statistics is also expected.

This course extensively and intensively shows the application of economic theory and
concepts to real-life business decisions. It consists of questions and problems along with their
answers and suggested solutions.

iii
Table of Contents

Chapter 1 The Fundamentals of Managerial Economics

Chapter 2 Optimization Techniques

Chapter 3 Market Forces: Demand and Supply

Chapter 4 Quantitative Demand Analysis

Chapter 5 Economic and Business Forecasting

Chapter 6 Theory of Production

Chapter 7 Multiple Product Planning and Linear Programming

Chapter 8 Cost: Theory and Analysis

Chapter 9 Markets and the Behavior of the Firm

Chapter 10 Pricing Policies and Strategies

Chapter 11 Long -Term Investment Decisions (Capital Budgeting)

Chapter 12 Risk in Project Analysis

Chapter 13 A Manager's Guide to Government in the Market Place

Appendix

Glossary

iv
CHAPTER 1
THE FUNDAMENTALS OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Explain and list the functions associated with managerial economics.


2. Identify the sources and give examples of accounting profits.
3. Describe the role of economic profits.
4. Compute and define the concept of time value of money.
5. Analyze and detail the process of deriving the present value.
6. Detail and explain the value of a firm.
7. Explain the concept of profit maximization.
8. Articulate and elaborate how wealth (shareholder) value is maximized.
9. Explain and give examples of marginal analysis.
10. Diagnose and implement strategies to optimize profits.

Managerial economics (or business economics) is economics applied in decision making. It is


a branch of economics that applies economic theory and decision science methodology to
solve business and managerial problems. Its objective is to bridge the gap between abstract
economic theory and managerial practice. It is the systematic study of how resources should
be allocated in such a way to most efficiently achieve a managerial goal.

We often find that economic theory and tools are not sufficient to tackle all kinds of
managerial problems. We borrow a variety of techniques and tools taken from finance,
operations
research, and other business disciplines. In this sense, economic theory and tools on one hand
and business disciplines on the other are blended into the subject.

ECONOMIC THEORY AND DECISION SCIENCES AND


TOOLS TOOLS

.Demand theory .Optimization


.Theory of the firm .Statistical methods
.Production theory .Forecasting and estimation
.Market structure .Finance and investment
.Macroeconomics .Other decision science tools

MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS

Use of economic theory and


tools and decision sciences
methodology to solve business
problems and for optimal
resource allocation 5
THE MANAGEMENT DECISION MAKING PROCESS

The basic steps that are taken in any decision process include:

Step 1 Recognize and define the problem. When management concludes that a
problem exists, it should prepare a specific definition or exact statement of the problem. For
example, how many of what products should the company produce?

Step 2 Select a goal. Is it profit maximizing or cost minimizing?

Step 3 Identify any constraints. Management's choice is always limited to some


extent by resources available, law, regulatory action, moral values, or management
preferences. Any constraints which might exist need to be identified.

Step 4 Identify alternatives or define decision variables a firm is trying to solve for.

Step 5 Select the alternative consistent with the firm’s objectives or determine the
optimal solution (i.e., profit-maximizing or cost-minimizing solution).

PROFITS

A profit is frequently described as a firm’s bottom line. What then does the bottom
line, ethically and legally produced, do for companies? First, it is a clear message that the
company is delivering products or services that people need or want--especially at prices they
are willing to pay. Also, a good bottom line means that the company has its costs in line. It
also means “efficiency.” Why do companies need to produce a good bottom line?

THE ROLE OF PROFITS

A good bottom line allows companies to


1. Reward investors for risking their capital.
2. Research and develop new and better products or services.
3. Add jobs and employees, reward employees, and provide opportunities for
employee growth and development.
4. Take pride in efficient performance.

ACCOUNTING VS. ECONOMIC PROFITS

We must differentiate between accounting profits and economic profits. Accounting


profits, also called business profits, are the difference between the total revenue and the cost
of producing goods or services. Accounting profits are what shows up on the bottom line of
the firm’s income statement.
Economic profits, on the other hand, are the difference between the total revenue and
the total opportunity costs. The opportunity cost of using a resource results in economic costs
that include both the explicit cost of the resource and the implicit cost of forsaking the next-

6
best alternative use of the resource. For this reason, the opportunity cost is generally higher
than accounting or bookkeeping costs. For example, the opportunity cost of attending summer
school is the cost of tuition and textbooks plus the amount of money you would earn had you
decided to work during the summer session.

PROFIT MAXIMIZATION AND MARGINAL ANALYSIS


The goal of a firm is to maximize its profit. This is the traditional theory of the firm,
which is distinguished from the behavioral theory of the firm. Marginal analysis suggests
that business decisions should be made and actions taken only when marginal revenues (MR)
exceed marginal costs (MC). (MR is the additional revenue resulting from the sale of an
additional unit of output and MC is the cost of the inputs used to make an additional unit of
output).

If MR = MC, a given decision should maximize the firm's profits.

EXAMPLE 1

Let TR(Q) denote the total revenue a firm generates from producing Q units of output
and let TC(Q) represent the total costs to the firm of producing Q units of output. The profit
(π ) then is:
π(Q) = TR(Q) - TC(Q).
The manager facing a situation like that summarized in columns of 1 through 3 in Table 1
wishes to determine the output quantity that will maximize its profits.

TABLE 1
MARGINAL ANALYSIS

Q TR(Q) TC(Q) π(Q) MR MC


(1) (2) (3) (4) = (2) - (3)
0 0 0 0 - -
1 90 10 80 90 10 MR>MC
2 170 30 140 80 20
3 240 60 180 70 30
4 300 100 200 60 40
5 350 150 200 50 50 MR=MC
6 390 210 180 40 60
7 420 280 140 30 70
8 440 360 80 20 80
9 450 450 0 10 90
10 450 550 -100 0 100 MR<MC

The profits are given in column 4. Note from Table 1 that:

(a) So long as MR exceeds MC, an increase in Q adds more to total revenues than it does
to total costs.

7
(b) The profits in column 4 are maximized when profits equal $200, which occurs when 5
units of Q are chosen by the manager.
(c) At the profit maximizing level of Q (5 units), MR = MC (both are equal to $50 in this
example). Note that the profit is maximized at 4 units. This situation occurs since we
are dealing with discrete output units. In a continuous case which we assume
throughout the book, the profit is maximized always when MR = MC.

Unfortunately, the profit-maximization goal, as operationally defined, suffers from


some technical flaws: (1) In its problems, it provides no explicit way of considering the risk
associated with alternative decisions, (2) it provides no basis for comparing varying flows of
revenues and costs over time, and (3) instead of seeking to “maximize” some objective such
as profits, the firm is said to satisfice, or seek acceptable levels of performance, which is
another model of the firm known as the behavioral theory of the firm. Furthermore, profit
maximization is a short-term goal, which is simply the maximization of profits within a given
period of time.

WEALTH MAXIMIZATION

A more operational goal of the firm is wealth maximization (or stockholders’ value
maximization). It is a long-term goal. Wealth maximization is generally preferred because it
considers (1) wealth for the long term, (2) risk or uncertainty, (3) the timing of returns, and (4)
the stockholders' return.

The wealth-maximization criterion requires that a firm evaluate the expected profits or
cash flows associated with a decision, by explicitly accounting for the timing of these flows as
well as the risk associated with them. Timing considerations require that future cash flows be
adjusted or discounted by some rate of interest that reflect the “cost” of the funds being used
to finance the project. The risk associated with cash flows can be treated in a number of ways,
including a way of specifying the probability distribution of the cash flows. The time value of
money concept and risk factors will be discussed in detail in Chapters 11 and 12.

The behavioral theory of the firm suggests that the firm has multiple goals such as
growth, size, and long-term survival. The growth is frequently measured in terms of
increased sales, market share, assets, and/or number of employees. A company’s long term
survival is assured only when business decision making is oriented toward the avoidance or
minimization of risk rather than the maximization of profits.

RECOGNIZING THE TIME VALUE OF MONEY

A dollar now is worth more than a dollar to be received later. This statement sums up an
important principle: money has a time value. The opportunity cost of receiving one dollar in the
future is the forgone interest that could be earned on one dollar received today. This opportunity
cost reflects the time value of money.

8
Time value of money is an important consideration in making business decisions. The
present value (or discounted cash flow) analysis is used widely to account for the timing of cash
inflows and outflows.

What Is Present Value - How Much Money Is Worth Now?


Present value is the value today of future cash flows. The computation of present values
(discounting) is the opposite of determining the compounded future value. The interest rate i is
referred to as the discount rate.
Therefore,

FVn
PV = ---------
n
(1 + i)

EXAMPLE 2

$10,000 you expect to receive 6 years from now at a 15 percent discount rate would be
worth $4,320 today.

1
PV = $10,000 = $10,000(0.432) = $4,320
6
(1 + 0.15)

This means that $4,320 invested today at 15 percent for 6 years grows to $10,000.

The basic idea of the present value of a future amount can be extended to a series of
future cash flows, as shown below.

n
FV1 FV2 FVn FVt
PV =
(1 + i) 1
+
(1 + i) 2
.... +
(1 + i) n
= ∑ (1 + i)
t =1
t

EXAMPLE 3

You are thinking of starting a new product line that initially costs $32,000. Your annual
projected cash inflows are:
1 $10,000
2 $20,000
3 $5,000

9
If you must earn a minimum of 10 percent on your investment, should you undertake this new
product line?

The present value of this series of mixed streams of cash inflows is calculated as follows:
t
Year Cash inflows 1/(1+0.10) Present Value
1 $10,000 0.909 $9,090
2 $20,000 0.826 16,520
3 $5,000 0.751 3,755
$29,365

Since the present value of your projected cash inflows is less than the initial investment, you
should not undertake this project.

Note:
Present value calculations can be done using:
(a) Financial calculators
(b) Present value tables (Tables 3 and 4 in the Appendix)
(c) Present value function keys in spreadsheet software such as Excel or Lotus 1-2-3.

Depending on the method you use, rounding errors in answers are unavoidable. Details on
present value analysis are covered in Chapter 11.

DEFINING THE VALUE OF THE FIRM

The process of determining the value of the firm involves finding the present value of
the firm’s expected future profits (or cash flows), discounted back to the present at an
appropriate interest rate. Thus, the basic valuation model can be defined mathematically as

n
Ct
V=∑
t =1 (1 + r)
t

follows:

where V = present value of the firm


Ct = expected future cash flows or profits in period t = 1, ..., n
r = required rate of return
EXAMPLE 4

XYZ company has the following year-end expected profits in each of the next three
years:
$30,000, $90,000, and $120,000. Then it shuts down. Assuming a 10 percent interest
rate, determine the value of the firm.

The present value of this series of profits is calculated as follows:


n
Year Cash inflows 1/(1+0.10) Present Value

10
1 $30,000 0.909 $27,270
2 90,000 0.826 74,340
3 120,000 0.751 90,120
$191,730

QUESTIONS
1. Define managerial economics.
2. What is the role of a firm? What is the goal of a firm?
3. Differentiate accounting profits and economic profits.
4. What is the value of a firm?
5. Explain marginal analysis.
6. Define opportunity costs.

PROBLEMS
1. You are trying to decide whether to open a new hamburger shop. You presently
make $45,000 per year as a free-lance consultant and will have to give up this job if
you open the shop. If you elect to open the restaurant, it will cost you annually
$245,000 per year in rent and other operating expenses.
(a). What are your accounting costs? (b). What are your opportunity costs?

2. The following table shows year-end expected profits for each firm over the next
three years. Interest rates are expected to be stable at 8 percent over the next three
years. Determine the value of each firm.

Profits in Profits in Profits in


Firm Year 1 Year 2 Year 3

X $60,000 $70,000 $80,000


Y $40,000 $80,000 $100,000

(a) Discuss the differences in the profits associated with each firm.
(b) Which firm has more value?

3. Complete the following table, and answer the accompanying questions:

Q TR(Q) TC(Q) π(Q) MR MC

0 0 0 - -
1 200 10
2 380 30
3 540 60
4 680 100
5 800 150
6 900 210
7 970 280
8 1,040 360

11
9 1,080 450
10 1,100 550

(a) What level of Q maximizes profits?


(b) What is the relation between marginal revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC)
at the level of Q?

ANSWERS
1. Managerial economics is the systematic study of how resources should be allocated in
such a way to most efficiently achieve a managerial goal.
2. The role of a firm is to allocate limited resources in an optimal manner and to meet the
goals of its owners. The goal of a firm is to maximize profits.
3. Accounting profits, also called business profits, are the difference between the total revenue
and the cost of producing goods or services. Accounting profits are what shows up on the
bottom line of the firm’s income statements. Economic profits, on the other hand, are the
difference between the total revenue and the total opportunity costs.
4. The value of a firm is the present worth of the firm’s expected future profits, discounted
back to the present at an appropriate interest rate.
5. Marginal analysis suggests that business decisions should be made and actions taken only
when marginal revenues exceed marginal costs. If this condition exists, a given decision
should maximize the firm's profits.
6. Opportunity costs are net benefits forgone by rejecting the next-best use of a resource and
the implicit costs of producing the items.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
(a) Accounting costs are $245,000 per year in rent and other operating expenses.
(b) Opportunity costs are $290,000 per year. ($45,000 + $245,000).

2.
(a) Firm X has the higher first year profits, but the lowest second and third year profits, while
Firm Y earns less in the first year than X, but more in years two and three.
(b) The present value of this series of profits is calculated as follows:

For Firm X
n
Year Cash inflows 1/(1+0.08) Present Value
1 $60,000 0.926 $55,560
2 70,000 0.857 59,990
3 80,000 0.794 63,520
$ 179,070

For Firm Y
n
Year Cash inflows 1/(1+0.08) Present Value
1 $40,000 0.926 $ 37,040
2 80,000 0.857 68,560
3 100,000 0.794 79,400

12
$ 185,000

Firm Y has the higher present value.

3.

Q TR(Q) TC(Q) π(Q) MR MC


(1) (2) (3) (2) – (3)

0 0 0 0 - -
1 200 10 190 200 10
2 380 30 350 180 20
3 540 60 480 160 30
4 680 100 580 140 40
5 800 150 650 120 50
6 900 210 690 100 60
7 970 280 690 70 70
8 1,030 360 680 60 80
9 1,080 450 630 50 90
10 1,100 550 550 20 100

(a) Q = 7 maximizes profits.


(b) MR = MC = $70 at Q = 7 units.

13
CHAPTER 2
OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Define a derivative.
2. Explain the uses of a partial derivative.
3. Calculate and define the slope.
4. Distinguish the characteristics of a second derivative.
5. Identify and compute the extreme point.
6. Formulate the process involved in optimization.
7. Facilitate and implement the process to achieve profit maximization.
8. Explain cost minimization.
9. Define and give examples of constrained optimization.
10. Demonstrate and give examples of the Lagrangean function
11. Discuss and demonstrate the uses of the Lagrangean multiplier.

In the field of economics it is often important to talk about relationships between different
economic quantities. For example, you will hear that there is a relationship between the price
of a good (or service) and the quantity that people will purchase of it. Throughout this course,
you will see numerous relationships such as the production function, cost function, and profit
function.

There are two basic types of analysis: mathematical and graphical.

THE CONCEPT OF A FUNCTIONAL RELATIONSHIP

The expression y = f(x) (Read "y is a function of x") means that the value of y
depends on the value of x. There is a relationship between these variables. For example, the
quantity of a commodity that people will purchase depends upon the price for which the
commodity can be purchased. This expression tells us nothing, however, about the nature of
the relationship. It can mean that as x increases, y increases or it can mean that it will
decrease. y = f(x) means merely that there is a relationship so that for every value of x, there
is a value of y.

If, however, we say, for example:


y = 4x + 5

we have stated a specific hypothesis or idea - we have given content to that relationship. As
the value of x increases by 1, the value of y increases by 4. We can in fact know the value of
y for every value of x.

USING GRAPHS

14
Consider the following functional relationship: y= 2x + 2 where x stands for the
amount of fertilizer used and y for the amount of the resulting crop. We can make a table or
schedule of this relationship showing the value of y for a few values of x. Table 1 is as
follows:

TABLE 1
FUNCTIONAL RELATIONSHIP

IF X = THEN Y =
0 2
1 4
2 6
3 8
4 10

FIGURE 1
GRAPH OF A FUNCTION

Each point of the above grid (not just the ones emphasized) represents a value of x
and a value of y. For example, the point labeled A represents x = 3, y = 8. To graph this
equation, we simply plot two points consistent with the equation on the graph and draw a line
through these two points. Each point on the line shows the given value of x (tons of fertilizer)
and the corresponding value of y. In mathematics, it is usual to use y as the dependent variable
and x as the independent variables and to graph the relationship with x on the horizontal axis

15
and y on the vertical axis. Not all functions can be represented by a straight line on a graph
(Those that can are called linear).

NOTE:
Sometimes economists represent the dependent variable on the horizontal axis and the
independent variable on the vertical axis. An example of this is in supply and demand
analysis for which price (the independent variable) and quantity (the dependent variable) are
graphed respectively on the vertical and horizontal axis (See Figure 2).

FIGURE 2
DEMAND AND SUPPLY FUNCTIONS

DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS
Differential calculus can be used to determine the rate of change in a function
relative to a change in the independent variable. In fact the designation differential
refers to differences that occur in the value of a function as a result of changes in
the independent variable: ∆y/∆x where the change in y, ∆y indicates the change in
the dependent variable associated with ∆x, the change in the value of x.

The main tool provided by differential calculus for the determination of such
differences is the derivative. The derivative dy/dx = y’ = f ’(x) of a function y = f(x)
at x 0 is defined as
dy ∆y f(x0 + ∆ x) - f(x0 )
--- = lim --- = lim -------------------.
dx ∆x->0 ∆ x ∆x->0 ∆x

16
This means that the derivative dy/dx = y’ = f ’(x) of a function y = f(x) at x 0 is the
limit of the difference quotient ∆y/ ∆ x as the change in x approaches zero.

NOTE:
Simply put, the derivative is the instantaneous rate of change of a function at
a point (x = x0 ), whereas the difference quotient is the average rate of change over
some interval (x0 , x0 + ∆x). Only in a straight line case, they are identical.
Graphically, the derivative is the slope of the line tangent to the curve at some point
x0.

This section provides the derivatives of various functions. The rules for
differentiation (the process of obtaining the derivative) provided by differential
calculus are as follows:

RULES FOR DIFFERENTIATION


Rule 1 (Constant Rule): y= f(x) = c, a constant.
The derivative: dy/dx = y’= f ’(x) = 0. This rule holds that whenever the
function is a constant, the derivative is zero. That is, the rate of change in a constant
relative to a change in the independent variable (or any variable, for that matter) is
zero.
Example: If y = 13, then dy/dx = 0

Rule 2 (Power Function Rule): y = f(x) = cx n .


The derivative: dy/dx=cnxn-1 .
Examples: If y = x3 , then dy/dx = 3x2 .
If y = x, then dy/dx = 1x0 = 1.

Rule 3 (Sum-Difference Rule): y = f(x) + g(x).


The derivative: dy/dx = f(x) + g’(x), where f ’(x) = df(x)/dx and g’(x) = dg(x)/
dx. This rule holds that the derivative of the sum of two different functions of the
same independent variable is the sum of the two derivatives of the different
functions.
Examples: If y = x4 + 2x, dy/dx = 4x3 + 2.
If 4x - 5x2 , then dy/dx = 4 - 10x.

Rule 4 (Product Rule): y = f(x)g(x).


The derivative: dy/dx = f ’(x)g(x) + g’(x)f(x).
This rule says that the derivative of the product of two different functions of the
same independent variable is the sum of the first function times the derivative of the
second function, plus the second function times the derivative of the first.
Example: If y = x2 (2x - 3), then dy/dx = x2 (2 - 0) + (2x - 3)(2x) = 2x2 + 4x2 - 6x
= 6x2 - 6x = 6x(x - 1)

Rule 5 (Quotient Rule): y = f(x)/g(x).


The derivative: dy/dx = f”(x)g(x) - g’(x)f(x).
[g(x)] 2

17
Example: If y = 5x/(2x + 1), then

dy/dx = 5(2x + 1) - 2(5x) = 5/(2x + 1)


(2x + 1)2

Rule 6 (Chain Rule or Function-of-Function Rule): y =g(z), where z = f(x).


dy dz
The derivative: dy/dx = ---- ---- = g’(z) f ’(x).
dz dx

This rule holds that a change in x will produce a change in z, which will, in turn,
produce a change in y. Thus, dy/dx, or the rate of change of y with respect to x, is
given by the rate of change of z with respect to x, dz/dx. multiplied by the rate of
change of y with respect to z, dy/dz.
Example: If y = 10z - 2z 2 - 3, where z = 2x2 - 1, then
dy/dx = (10 - 4z)(4x) = [10 - 4(2x2 - 1)](4x)
= (10 - 8x2 + 4)(4x) = 40x - 32x2 + 16x = 56x - 32x2 .

Rule 7 (Inverse Function Rule): x = f --1 (y), where f --1 refers to the inverse
function, not 1/f(y).
1
The derivative: dx/dy = -----
dy/dx

Example: If y = 5x + 3, then x = 1/5 y - 3/5, and dx/dy = 1/5.


The following example shows how the derivative can be used to find the rate
of change.

EXAMPLE 1
Peruvian Cleaning Supply Company is the exclusive distributor of an
important cleaning fluid used by furriers throughout the southeastern U.S.. This
cleaning fluid is used to prepare fur garments for protective storage in refrigerated
vaults during the humid summer season. Peruvian delivers the cleaner in tank
trucks, and each customer must take at least 100 gallons. The price is $12 per
gallon. A discount of $0.05 per gallon is granted to each customer purchasing in
quantities greater than the 100 gallon minimum. This discount applies only to
quantities above the minimum; the first 100 gallons are charged at $12 per gallon
regardless of the total number of gallons delivered.

Management formulated the following mathematical expression for total


revenue (TR) per customer on the basis of the information given:

TR = $12(100) + [$12 − $0.05(x − 100)] (x − 100) = − 500 + 22x − 0.05x2

This is a quadratic function. The derivative formula for this function is:

18
dTR/dx= 22 − 0.10x.

NOTE:
The derivative for the TR function gives the marginal revenue (MR), i.e., the
increase in TR resulting from an additional unit of output. By the same token,
marginal cost (MC) equals the derivative of the total cost function.

This derivative reflects the fact that the rate of change is not constant. That
is, the rate of change depends on the value of the variable x, so the rate of change
will itself change as the value of g changes. This variability in the rate of change is
consistent with the fact that the rate of change of a quadratic function continually
varies. To find the rate of change in TR when a particular number of gallons is sold
to a customer, the number of gallons is substituted for x in the derivative. For
example, to find the rate of change (per gallon) in TR at 105 gallons, the following
calculation is necessary based on the derivative:

22 − 0.10(105) = 22 − 10.50 = 11.50.

That is, total revenue is changing by $11.50 at this volume of sales to a particular
customer. At sales of 110 gallons, the rate of change is $11, as determined below,
again on the basis of the derivative:

22 − 0.10(110) = 22 − 11 = 11.

In other words, total revenue is changing at the rate of $11 when sales are 110
gallons in contrast to $11.50 when sales are 105 gallons.

THE EXTREME VALUE OF A FUNCTION AND THE DERIVATIVE TESTS


The extreme value of a function (the maximum or minimum value) that the function
can assume is very important in economic decision making. Much of economics
deals with optimization, that is the maximization of profit or minimization of costs.

THE FIRST DERIVATIVE TEST


The first derivative test (or first-order condition) is used to determine extreme
points of a function (See Figure 3). It states that dy/dx = y’= f ’(x0 ) = 0 at a local
maximum or minimum point and x 0 is called an extreme (critical) value of the
function. It involves three steps: (1) find the derivative, (2) set it equal to zero, and
(3) solve for the value of x .

The second derivative is arrived at by applying the rules of differentiation to


the first derivative rather than to the original function. That is, the first derivative is
itself differentiated, and the result is the second derivative. The second derivative is
the derivative of the first derivative, denoted with d 2 y/dx2 = y”= f”(x).

19
EXAMPLE 2
Suppose y = f(x) = 3x2 . Then, dy/dx = f ’(x) = 6x. The result, 6x, is the first
derivative. The second derivative d 2 y/dx2 = y”= f”(x) = 6.

NOTE:
The second derivative is the measure of the rate of change of the first
derivative. In other words, it measures the rate of change of the slope of the original
function f(x).

FIGURE 3
MAXIMUM AND MINIMUM POINTS

THE SECOND DERIVATIVE TEST


We need to determine whether the extreme value is a maximum or a minimum. This
information can be obtained through the use of the second derivative test (or
second-order condition). The test states that

(1) The function y = f(x) reaches a local maximum at some point x = x0 if


f ’(x0 ) = 0 and f ’’(x0 ) is negative.

(2) Similarly, f(x) reaches a local minimum at some point x0 if f ’(x0 ) = 0 and
f ’’(x0 ) is positive.

(3) The function reaches an inflection point rather than a local maximum or
minimum at x = x0 if both first and second derivatives are 0, i.e., f ’(x0 ) = 0 and
f ’’(x0 ) = 0. An example of the function with no local maximum or local minimum) is
y = f(x) = x 3 .

EXAMPLE 3
Recall from Example 1: TR = −500 + 22x − 0.05x2 .

20
dTR/dx = 22 − 0.10x = 0

We set the first derivative equal to zero and solve for x, as follows:

22 − 0.10x = 0
− 0.10x = − 22
x = 220.

Note that d 2 TR/dx2 = -0.1. Since the second derivative is negative, the extreme
value of the function (x* = 220) is a maximum.

Substituting x* = 220 for x in the original function we get for the maximum
revenue the following:

− 500 + 22(220) − 0.05(220)2


= − 500 + 4,840 − 0.05(48,400)
= $1,920

EXAMPLE 4
Given y = f(x) = x3 - 12x2 + 36x + 18
To get the critical value we take the first derivative and set it equal to 0.

dy/dx = f ’(x) = 3x2 - 24x + 36 = 0


= (3x - 18)(x - 2) = 0, which indicates there are two roots in this
quadratic equation.

The dual roots are: (3x - 18) = 0 and (x - 2) = 0; therefore, x 1 = 6 and x 2 = 2.


To determine if they are maximum or minimum points, we need to do the second
derivative test, as follows:

d 2 y/dx2 = f”(x)= 6x - 24

At x 1 = 6, f”(x)= 6(6) - 24 = 8 > 0, it is a minimum.


At x 2 = 2, f”(x)= 6(2) - 24 = -12 <0, it is a maximum.

NOTE:
First Derivative Test Second Derivative Test
Maximum f ’(x0 ) = 0 f”(x0 ) < 0
Minimum f ’(x0 ) = 0 f”(x0 ) > 0

PARTIAL DERIVATIVES AND MULTIVARIATE OPTIMIZATION

21
Many functions involve multiple independent variables. It is useful to understand
the concept of multivariate optimization, the process of optimization for equations
with multiple decision variables. Total direct labor cost in a manufacturing firm
may be used to illustrate a function of two independent variables, namely (1) the
number of direct labor hours worked and (2) the hourly wage rate. As a result,
multivariate optimization is employed in the process of optimization.

The process involves partial differentiation. Quite often, we wish to know


the individual effect that a change in one independent variable (while the other (s)
are held constant) will have on the dependent variable. The process is called partial
differentiation. This designation refers to the fact that the function is differentiated
relative to only a part (specifically, one) of the group of independent variables. The
result is called the partial derivative denoted with ∂, instead of d.

NOTE:
The rules for partial differentiation are the same with the added stipulation
that the independent variables not involved in the differentiation are treated as
constants.

EXAMPLE 5
To illustrate, suppose the sales revenue function is TR = 2x2 y2 z., where x =
advertising expense in the prior period, y = salespersons’ travel expense in the prior
period, and z = units sold by competitors during the current period. Suppose
management needs to know the maximum extent to which revenue is generated by x
(advertising expense in the prior period). The procedure for finding the extreme
value is as follows:

(1) differentiate partially relative to the variable of interest,

(2) set the partial derivative equal to zero and solve for the variable of
interest, and

(3) evaluate the original function at this value to determine the extreme.

Viewing y and z as constants, the full coefficient of x2 is 2y2 z. The partial


derivative with respect to x, the variable of interest in this example is

∂TR/∂x = 4xy2 z.

Setting the partial derivative equal to zero and solving for x gives the following:

4y2 zx = 0
x = 0.

Thus the revenue function assumes its extreme value when x = 0.

22
In order to interpret this result, it will be helpful to determine whether the
extreme is a maximum or a minimum. As explained earlier, the sign of the second
derivative (the second partial derivative in the multivariate case) determines this.
The second partial derivative is determined as follows:
∂2 TR/ ∂ x2 = 4y2 z.
Since the second partial derivative is positive, the extreme value of the function is
minimal.

The fact that the extreme value of the function results when x = 0 may be
interpreted to mean that zero advertising expense in the prior period results in the
lowest possible contribution of advertising to sales revenue. Furthermore it is
implied that the contribution of advertising expense to sales revenue next period
will continue to increase as long as advertising expense continues to increase. This
indicates that the firm’s advertising expense does have a positive effect on revenue.
(Recall that the partial derivative procedure assumes that y and z remain constant,
so no inferences are drawn concerning the effect of changes in these variables on
the revenue function.)

PROFIT MAXIMIZATION
The goal of a firm is to maximize its profit. The economic theory suggests that business
decisions should be made and actions taken only when marginal revenues exceed marginal
costs. If this condition exists, a given decision should maximize the firm's profits. To find the
profit-maximizing output, we should use differential calculus.

EXAMPLE 6
Consider the following total revenue (TR) and total cost (TC) functions:

TR(Q) = $1,000Q - $5Q2 and TC(Q) = $20,000 + $200Q.

The profit function (π) then is:

π (Q) = TR(Q) -TC(Q) = $1,000Q - $5Q2 - ($20,000 + $200Q)


= $1,000Q - $5Q2 - $20,000 -$200Q
= -$20,000 + $800Q - $5Q2

Taking dπ/dQ = 0 and solve for Q yields Q* = 80 units, as follows:

dπ/dQ = $800 - $10Q = 0; Q* = 80 units

An evaluation of the second derivative of the profit function is


d2π/dQ2 = -10 < 0 , which indicates Q* = 80 is a point of profit maximization.

Figure 3 presents a graph of (a) the hypothetical total revenue, total cost, and profit
functions, and (b) the marginal revenue, marginal cost, and marginal profit functions.

23
FIGURE 4
TOTAL REVENUE, TOTAL COST, MARGINAL REVENUE, MARGINAL COST,
AND PROFIT MAXIMIZATION

CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION
Many firms face restrictions imposed on their decision variables. Examples are the limitations
imposed by the amount of resources (such as money, facilities, capacity, materials, and
personnel) available to the firm. Constrained optimization is maximization of profits with the
restrictions imposed on the availability of resources, or minimization of costs with minimum
requirements needed to be satisfied. Techniques such as the Lagrangean multiplier method
and linear programming (to be discussed in Chapter 7) are used for this purpose.
The general problem is that of finding the extreme points of the function f(x, y)
subject to equalities of the form g(x, y) = 0.

24
When the constraints take the form of equalities, classical optimization procedures
can be used to find an optimal solution. Two methods can be used: (1) The substitution
method and (2) The Lagrangean multiplier method.

THE SUBSTITUTION METHOD


The substitution method can be used when the objective function is subject to only
one constraint equality of a relatively simply nature. By substitution, we reduce the dimension
of our objective function. It involves two steps: (1) solve the equation for one of the decision
variables and then (2) substitute this expression into the objective function. The procedure
transforms the original problem into an unconstrained optimization problem so that the
differential calculus can be applied to obtain the optimal solution.

EXAMPLE 7
Suppose a firm produces its product on two assembly lines and operates with the total
cost function, TC(x, y) = 3x2 + 6y2 - xy, where x = the output produced on one assembly line
and y = the output produced on a second assembly line. Management seeks to determine the
least-cost combination of x and y, subject to the constraint that total output of the product
must be 20 units.

The constrained optimization problem can be stated as follows:


2 2
Minimize TC(x, y) = 3x + 6y - xy
Subject to: x + y = 20

First, solve the constraint equation for x, yielding x = 20 - y and plug it into the
objective function.

TC(x, y) = T(y) = 3(20 - y)2 + 6y2 - (20 - y)y = 3(400 -40y + y2) + 6y2 -20y +y2
1,200-120y+3y2+ 6y2 -20y +y2 = 1,200 - 140y + 10y2

Taking the derivative of this reduced objective function and setting it equal to zero, we obtain:
dTC/dy = -140 + 20y = 0
y = 7 units
In turn solving for x yields: x = 20 - y = 20 - 7 = 13 units.
Thus x = 13 and y = 7 is the optimal solution to the constrained cost-minimization problem.

NOTE:
The limitation of the substitution method is that it works only when there is one
constraint equation and its is possible to solve this equation for one of the decision variables.
With more than one constraint equation and/or a complicated constraint structure, the
Lagrangean multiplier method must be employed.

LAGRANGEAN MULTIPLIER TECHNIQUE


A method of solving constrained optimization problems in which the constraint (in a
form in which it will equal to zero when it is satisfied) is added to the original objective

25
function. A new, augmented objective function is called Lagrangean function, which
constitutes an unconstrained optimization problem. The function is of the form:

L(x, y, λ) = f(x, y) + λg(x, y)

The coefficient of the constraining equation g(x, y),  (read as lambda), is termed the
Lagrangean multiplier. Since the constraining equation is equal to 0, the addition of the
term λg(x, y) to the objective function f(x, y) does not change the value of the function.

This artificial variable measures the marginal change in the value of the objective
function resulting from a one-unit change in the value of the constraint. The Lagrangean
method works when (1) substitution is impractical, and (2) there exist many constraints.
Further, it provides interesting economic information. The method is illustrated using the
earlier example.

EXAMPLE 8
From Example 7, our constraint was x + y = 20. First, it should be rearranged so as
to form an expression equal to zero, g(x, y) = 0. That means the constraint x + y = 20 is
transformed to the expression 20 - x – y = 0.

Next, we define an artificial variable λ and form the Lagrangean Function (L):
L(x, y, λ) = TC(x, y) + λg(x, y) = 3x2 + 6y2 - xy + λ(20 - x - y)

Note that:
1. As long as g(x, y) is maintained equal to zero, the Lagrangean Function L(x, y, λ)
will not differ in value from the original total cost function TC(x, y). Minimizing
L(x, y, λ) will also minimize TC(x, y).
2. Taking the partial derivative with respect to λ and setting that equal to zero gives
you the original constraint.

Since L(x, y, λ) is a function of three decision variables, in order to minimize this


function, we need to:

1. Partially differentiate it with respect to each of the variables;


2. Set the partial derivatives equal to zero; and
3. Solve the resulting set of equations for the optimal values of x, y, and λ.

The partial derivatives are:


∂L(x, y, λ)/∂x = 6x - y - λ = 0
∂L(x, y, λ)/∂y = 12y - x - λ = 0
∂L(x, y, λ)/∂λ = 20 - x - y = 0

Solving three partial derivative equations simultaneously, we obtain x= 13, y =7, and λ= 71.

λ measures the marginal change in the value of the objective function due to a one-unit
change in the value of the constraint. In this example, λ=71 indicates the costs would be

26
increased by $71 if one more unit of output is produced; that is, an increase from 20 units to
21.

NOTE:
If a constrained optimization problem has more than one constraint, then a
separate λ is defined for each constraint and incorporated into the Lagrangean Function. The
λ values are analogous to the dual variables of linear programming (LP) and represent the
shadow prices of scarce resources.

MARGINAL ANALYSIS VERSUS INCREMENTAL ANALYSIS


Marginal analysis relates to an additional unit of output. Managers at any level
who have to make their functional decisions (such as marketing, operational, production,
purchasing, financing, investment, personnel, and so on) must always weigh the marginal cost
to be incurred against the marginal revenue to be derived from that decision. Many
managerial decisions, however, involve a consideration of changes that are much
broader in scope. For example, management may wish to investigate the impact on
profits of a 20 percent increase in sales or an introduction of a new product line.

Incremental analysis is frequently used in the practical equivalent of


marginal analysis. It relates to a specified managerial decision which can involve a
choice between two discrete quantities of output (e.g., 10,000 units vs. 15,000
units). It is the process of examining the impact of alternative choice decisions on
revenue, cost, or profit. It focuses attention on changes or differences between
alternatives. Managers will have to weigh the incremental cost associated with the decision
against the incremental revenue. For this reason, marginal analysis is more appropriately
called incremental analysis.

QUESTIONS
1. Define the term optimization
2. Discuss briefly the first and second derivative tests.
3. What is constrained optimization? Give two popular techniques that deal with constrained
optimization.
4. Define the Lagrangean multiplier. What is it analogous to in linear programming?
5. What is the derivative? What does it try to measure?
6. Distinguish between marginal analysis and incremental analysis.

PROBLEMS
1. ABC Boutique offers all its merchandise for sale at $20 per unit. The total cost
of producing Q units is given by TC = 40 + 4Q + .2Q2 . How many units must be
produced to maximize profit? What is the maximum profit at this level?

2. Find the maximum point on the function y = 75x - 0.25x 2 . Prove that this is a
maximum, not a minimum by evaluating the second derivative at the X value.

27
3. Find the maxima and minima points on the function y = 1,500 - 600x - 15x 2 + x 3 ,
and evaluate the second derivative to differentiate between them.

4. Your firm's economic analysis department has estimated your total revenues to
be TR(Q)=3,200Q - 6Q 2 and your total costs to be TC(Q) = 90 + 2Q2
(a) What level of Q maximizes profits?
(b) What is marginal revenue at this level of Q?
(c) What is marginal cost at this level of Q?
(d) What is the maximum level of profits?

5. Jon Electronics operates with the following total revenue (TR) and total cost
(TC) functions:
TR = $200Q - $0.5Q2 and TC = $1,000 - $40Q + $0.5Q2
(a) Determine the revenue maximizing Q (the quantity of output).
(b) Determine the cost minimizing Q.
(c) Determine the profit maximizing Q.
(d) Prove that marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC) at the profit
maximizing Q.

6. The purpose of inventory planning is to develop policies which will achieve an optimal
investment in inventory. This objective is achieved by determining the optimal level of
inventory necessary to minimize inventory related costs. Annual total inventory costs (TIC)
are the sum of carrying cost + ordering cost, i.e., TIC = C (Q/2) + S (D/Q), where C =
carrying cost per unit, S = ordering cost per order, D = annual demand (requirements) in units,
and Q = order quantity. Develop a formula for determining the economic order quantity Q*
(EOQ) by minimizing the TIC.

7. Using the Lagrangean Multiplier method, find the extreme point.


Maximize z = xy
Subject to x+y=6

8. A firm has the following profit function in which the profit variable Z is a
function of the output level of two products x and y: Z = -60 + 140x + 100y - 10 x 2
- 8y2 - 6xy. Assume that the firm has the raw materials in short supply, having only
200 units. Products x and y require 20 units and 40 units of the raw materials to
produce one unit of output. The firm wishes to determine the profit-maximizing
mix of products.
(a) Formulate the problem as a constrained optimization format.
(b) Use the substitution method to determine the quantities of x and y that will
maximize profit (Z).
(c) Use the Lagrangean Multiplier method to do the same.
(d) Give an economic interpretation of the value of λ obtained in part (c).

ANSWERS
1. Optimization is the maximization or minimization of a specific objective (i.e.,
profit or costs).

28
2. The first derivative test is a test to locate one or more extreme (maximum or
minimum) points on a function, while the second derivative test is a test to
determine whether an extreme point is either a maximum or a minimum point.
3. Constrained optimization is optimization with the restrictions imposed on the
availability of resources and other requirements. Techniques such as linear programming (LP)
and the Lagrangean multipliers are used to attack this type of problem.
4. The Lagrangean multiplier measures the marginal change in the value of the objective
function resulting from a one-unit change in the value on the right-hand side of the equality
sign in the constraint. This is analogous to the dual variables of linear programming and
represent the shadow price of a given scarce resource.
5. The derivative dy/dx measures the marginal change in y associated with a very
small change in x. It is basically the slope of a function.
6. Marginal analysis relates to a single unit of output, while incremental analysis
relates to a specified managerial decision which can involve a choice between two
discrete quantities of output (e.g., 10,000 units vs. 15,000 units). Incremental
analysis is frequently used as the practical equivalent of marginal analysis.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
Total profit (π) = total revenue(TR) - total cost(TC)
2 2
= $20Q - (40 + 4Q + .02Q ) = -40 + 16Q - .02Q

Taking the derivative with respect to Q and setting it equal to zero, we obtain
dπ/dQ = 16 - .4Q = 0, Solving for Q yields Q* = 40.
The maximum profit at Q* = 40 is:
π* = -40 + 16Q - .02Q2 = -40 + 16(40) - .02(40)2 = 568.

2.
Set dy/dx = 0: dy/dx = 75 - 0.5x =0; x = 150. Since d 2 y/dx 2 = - 0.5 < 0, at x = 150 a
maxima has been located.

3.
Set dy/dx = 0 to locate all maxima and minima.
dy/dx =-600 - 30x + 3x 2 = 0 or
(3x + 30)(x - 20) = 0 the dual solutions are x = -10; x = 20.
Taking the second derivative yields d 2 y/dx 2 = -30 + 6x
At x = -10, d 2 y/dx 2 = -30 + 6x = -30 + 6(-10) = -90 < 0 (maxima)
At x = 20, d 2 y/dx 2 = -30 + 6x = -30 + 6(20) = 90 > 0 (minima)

4.
(a) Given: TR(Q)=3,200Q - 6Q2 and TC(Q) = 90 + 2Q2
The marginal revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC) are as follows:
MR = dTR/dQ = 3,200 -12Q and MC = dTC/dQ = 4Q
At the profit-maximizing output level, MR = MC; thus
MR = 3,200 - $12Q = 4Q = MC
Solving for Q gives

29
Q* = 200 units, which is the profit-maximizing quantity of output.
(b) MR = 3,200 -12Q = 3,200 - 12(200) = 800
(c) MC = 4Q = 4(200) = 800
(e) Profits = TR - TC =3,200Q - 6Q2 -(90 + 2Q2 )= -90 + 3,200Q -8Q2 .
When Q*=200, profits are -90 + 3,200(200) - 8(200)2 = $319,910

5.
(a) Set dTR/dQ = $200 - Q = 0; Q = 200
(b) Set dTC/dQ = -$40 + Q = 0; Q = 40
(c) Total profit (π) = TR - TC = $200Q - $0.5Q2 - ($1,000 - $40Q + $0.5Q2 )
= -$1,000 + $240Q - Q2
Set dπ/dQ = $240 -2Q = 0; Q =120
(d) At Q*=120, we note:
MR = dTR/dQ = $200 - Q = $200 - 120 = $80
MC = dTC/dQ = -$40 + Q = -$40 + 120 = $80
So, MR = MC = $80

6.
Given TIC = C (Q/2) + S (D/Q), taking the derivative of TIC with respect to Q and
setting it equal to zero yields:
dTIC/dQ = C/2 - SDQ -2 = 0 ----> Q2 = 2SD/C ----> Q* = EOQ = 2 SD / C

7.
The Lagrangean function is:
L(x, y, λ) = xy + λ(6 - x - y)
Taking the partial derivative with respect to x, y, and λ, we get:
∂L/∂x = y - λ = 0
∂L/∂y = x - λ = 0
∂L/∂λ= 6 - x - y = 0
Solving them simultaneously, we obtain: x = 3, y = 3, and λ = 3.

8.
(a) The formulation is:
Maximize Z = -60 + 140x + 100y - 10x 2 - 8y2 - 6xy.
Subject to 20x + 40y = 200
(b) Solve for x in terms of y and substitute in Z yields:
20x + 40y = 200 ----> x = 200/20 - 40y/20 = 10 - 2y
Z =-60 + 140x + 100y - 10 x 2 - 8y2 - 6xy
= -60 + 140(10 -2y) + 100y - 10(10 - 2y) 2 - 8y2 - 6(10 - 2y)y
= 340 + 160y - 36y2
Using the first order condition for an extreme, we find dQ/dK and set it equal
to zero we get:
dQ/dK =160 - 72y = 0, which means y =2.22 units and x = 10 - 2y =10 - 2(2.22)
=5.56 units
(c) The Lagrangean Function is:
L(x, y, λ) = -60 + 140x + 100y - 10x 2 - 8y2 - 6xy + λ(200 - 20x - 40y)

30
Using the partial derivatives, we obtain:
∂L/∂x = 140 - 20x - 6y + 20λ = 0
∂L/∂y = 100 -16x -6y + 40λ = 0
∂L/∂λ = 200 - 20x - 40y = 0
Solving these three equations simultaneously, we find x = 5.56, y =2.22, and λ=.774
(d) λ=.774 means that profits can be increased by $.774 if one additional unit of raw
material were available; that is, an increase from 200 units to 201 units.

31
CHAPTER 3
MARKET FORCES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Define the demand function.


2. Demonstrate the demand schedule.
3. Construct and explain the demand curve.
4. Identify demand shifters.
5. Compute the average revenue.
6. Clarify the concept of marginal revenue.
7. Explain and give examples of the linear demand function.
8. Calculate and explain the point price elasticity concept.
9. Define arc elasticity.
10. Compute the income elasticity.
11. Determine and give an example of advertising elasticity.
12. Explain the concept of constant elasticity.
13. Define and give examples of substitute goods.
14. Illustrate the uses and benefits of complementary goods.
15. Define and give examples of normal goods.
16. Identify and expose inferior goods.
17. Compute the optimal price.
18. Diagram graphically the concept of supply.
19. Identify supply shifters.

Demand analysis is useful in forecasting sales, setting prices, and long range profit planning.
Demand analysis includes:

1. Quantitative expression demand --specification of demand functions


2. Calculation of various elasiticities of demand
3. Estimation of demand functions
4. Forecasting sales
5. Pricing decisions

We cover the first two topics in this chapter. The other topics are discussed in later chapters.

DEMAND FUNCTION
Economic theory tells us that demand for a particular product depends on its price,
i.e.,
Qd = f(P)

Economic theory goes one step further, stating that

32
Qd = f (P, PC, Y, A,...)

where P = its own price, PC = the prices of substitutes and complementary goods , Y =
income, A = advertising. Demand function is a mathematical relationship showing how the
quantity demanded of a good or service responds to changes in these factors. Explanatory
factors other than its own price are called demand shifters. The effect of each explanatory
factor on the quantity demanded may be estimated statistically with time-series or cross-
sectional data.

DEMAND SCHEDULE
Demand schedule is a table or tabular representation of the quantity demanded at
various possible prices during a given time period, all other things remaining equal. The data
from a demand schedule can be used to construct a demand curve.

DEMAND CURVE
Demand curve is a graph of a demand schedule, showing the negative relationship
between price and quantity demanded during a period of time, all other things remaining the
same. Price is on the vertical axis and quantity demanded is on the horizontal axis.
Notice that the change in demand from point A to B is due to a change in price. The
change in demand from point A to C is not due to price, but a shift in demand.

SHIFT IN DEMAND
Market shifters create increase or decrease in demand for a good brought about by a
change in any factor other than the price of the product. These factors include (1) consumers'
incomes, (2) the prices of substitute or complementary goods, and (3) consumers' tastes.
Graphically, a shift in demand may be represented by a parallel movement of the demand
curve.

FIGURE 1
DEMAND CURVE AND DEMAND SHIFTERS

33
MARKET DEMAND CURVE
The market demand curve for a product represents the various amounts that
consumers as a group are willing and able to purchase at various alternative prices
at a specific moment in time when other factors influencing consumer behavior are
held constant. Thus, the market demand curve isolates the relationship between
price and the quantity demanded by all consumers. It is found by summing the
quantities of a good that each consumer is willing and able to purchase at each and
every alternative price.

DEMAND AND REVENUE


The total revenue of a firm is directly related to the demand for the firm’s
product or service. Total revenue (TR) is a function of price and quantity demanded,
i.e.,
TR = f (P, Q) = P x Q
For example, if P = 500 - .02Q, then TR = PQ = (500 - .2Q)Q = 500Q - .02Q2

AVERAGE REVENUE
Average revenue (AR) is total revenue per unit of output, that is total revenue received
divided by output., i.e., AR = TR/Q = (500Q - .02Q2 )/Q = 500 - .02Q

MARGINAL REVENUE
Marginal revenue is the rate of change of total revenue with respect to quantity
demanded, i.e.,
MR = dTR/dQ = d(P x Q)/dQ = 500 - .04Q

34
FIGURE 2
AVERAGE REVENUE, MARGINAL REVENUE, AND TOTAL REVENUE

ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
Whether price cutting or an increase in advertising dollars is desirable or not
depends largely on the elasticity of demand for the product. One of the most
important concepts in demand is elasticity which tells you how sensitive quantity
demanded is to the change in a factor in the demand function. The principal factors
involved with demand elasticity are:

1. The price of the good (in the case of price elasticity)


2. The price of a substitute-product (in the case of cross elasticity)
3. Income (in the case of income elasticity)
4. Advertising (in the case of advertising elasticity)

35
PRICE ELASTICITY
Price elasticity, denoted with ep , is the ratio of a percentage change in
quantity demanded (Q) to a percentage change in price (p), as stated as a positive
term. We classify the price elasticity of demand into three categories:

Price elasticity of demand Degree of elasticity


ep >1 Elastic
ep =1 Unitary
ep <1 Inelastic

There are two types of price elasticity: (1) arc elasticity and (2) point elasticity.

1. Arc Elasticity
Arc elasticity of demand is the average responsiveness of quantity demanded to a
change in price between two different values:

(Q2 - Q1)/[(Q2 + Q1)/2] (Q2 - Q1) (P2 + P1)


ep = ----------------------- = ---------- x ----------
(P2 - P1)/[(P2 + P1)/2] (P2 - P1) (Q2 + Q1)

where P1, and Q1 are the original price and quantity, and P2 and Q2 are the new price and
quantity.

In other words, changes in Q and P are calculated as percentages of the average of


their respective original and final values. This approach eliminates the problem of
the elasticity measure being dependent on which end of the range is viewed as the
initial point and results in a more accurate measure of the average relative
relationship between the two variables over the range indicated by the data.

EXAMPLE 1
Given the following:
P Q
$.60 400,000
.50 800,000

(800,000 - (.6 + .5) 400,000 1.10


400,000)
ep = ---------------------- x --------------------- = ---------- x --------- = -.3.667
(.5 - .6) (800,000 + -.1 1,200,000
400,000)

NOTE:
A negative sign is expected, so the absolute value expression |ep | is widely
adopted in texts.

36
2. Point Elasticity
Point elasticity is the elasticity measured at a given point.

% change in Q dQ/Q dQ p
e p = --------------- = ------- = --- x ----
% change in P dP/P dP Q

where dQ/dP is the slope of the demand function Q = (P).

EXAMPLE 2
The demand function is given as Q = 200 - 6P. The price elasticity at P=4 is
computed as follows:
First, Q = 200 - 6(4) = 176
Since dQ/dP = -6, the e p at P = 4 is:
ep = -6 x (4/176) = -0.136
which means that a 1 percent change in price will bring about a 0.14% change in
demand. The product under study is considered price inelastic, since the ep is less
than 1 in absolute value.

TWO EXTREME CASES OF PRICE ELASTICITY


There are two extreme cases: (1) ep = 0 and (2) ep = ∞. If ep = 0, then the
price elasticity of demand is completely inelastic and the quantity demanded will
not change in response to change in price. The demand curve in this case is a
vertical line, as in Figure 3, panel (a). If ep = ∞, then the price elasticity of demand
is infinitely elastic and a firm can sell as many units of its product as it wants to at
the going market price, but it will lose all of its sales at a higher price. In this case
the demand curve is a horizontal line as seen in Figure 3, panel (b). These cases,
however, are very rare in reality. The demand for some products, such as table salt,
over at least some price ranges may be highly inelastic. Further, we may relate the
horizontal demand curve with the purely competitive firm.

LINEAR DEMAND CURVE AND NON-CONSTANT PRICE ELASTICITY


The information on price elasticity is useful to see the effect of a change in
price on sales. However, you should be careful to know the price elasticity in each
price range, since elasticity is not constant along the demand curve.

EXAMPLE 3
We are given the following demand function: P = 10 - 2Q or Q = 5 - .5P
In the case of a linear demand function (See Figure 4), while the slope of a straight
line demand curve is the same at all points, the elasticity for such a curve varies
from one point to the next. The reason for this is that in the ep formula
1. dQ/ dP would be constant, but
2. P/Q would fall in the case of a move down and to the right.

TOTAL REVENUE AND PRICE ELASTICITY

37
Economists have established the following relationships between price
elasticity (ep ) and total revenue (TR), which can aid a firm in setting its price.

Price ep > 1 ep = 1 ep < 1

Price rises TR falls No change TR rises


Price falls TR rises No change TR falls

EXAMPLE 4
In Example 3, we note that
TR = PQ = (10 - 2Q)Q = 10Q - 2Q2 and hence MR = 10 -4Q. Figure 5 shows the
relationship between TR, price elasticity, and marginal revenue.

1. Price elasticities can be used to answer the following types of questions:


(a) What will be the impact on sales of a 5% price increase?
(b) How great a price reduction is necessary to increase sales by 20%?

2. Firms need to be aware of the elasticity of their own demand curves when
they set product prices. For example, a profit maximizing firm would never choose
to lower its price in the inelastic range of its demand curve--such a price decrease
would only decrease total sales and at the same time increase costs, since output
would be rising. The result would be a drastic decrease in profits. In fact, when
costs are rising and the product is inelastic, the firm would have no difficulty
passing on the increases by raising the price to the customer.

3. When there are many substitutes and demand is quite elastic, increasing
prices may lead to a reduction in total revenue rather than an increase. The result
may be lower profits rather than higher profits.

3. Similarly, managers are sometimes surprised by a lack of success of price


reductions, this merely being a reflection of the fact that demand is
relatively inelastic. In such a case, they may have to rely on other
marketing efforts such as advertising and sales promotion in an attempt to
increase market share.

38
FIGURE 3
TWO EXTREME CASES OF PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

39
FIGURE 4
LINEAR DEMAND CURVE AND NON-CONSTANT PRICE ELASTICITY

40
FIGURE 5
TOTAL REVENUE, PRICE ELASTICITY, AND MARGINAL REVENUE

NOTE:
Various elasticity measures will allow marketing managers to see how
effective each of the demand determinants (i.e., advertising, price change, and
external factors) is going to be. In this way marketing resources may be utilized
more profitably and efficiently.

41
CROSS ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
Cross elasticity of demand is the responsiveness for one product to changes
in the price of some other product, holding all other factors constant. It measures
the closeness of substitutes or the degree of complementality of demand. It is
computed as

% change in Q dQ/Q dQ PX
e pX = ----------------- = ------- = --- x ----
% change in P X dP X /P X dP X Q

1. If e pX > 0, goods are substitutes. A high cross elasticity means that the
commodities are close substitutes (e.g., coffee and tea).
2. If e pX < 0, goods are complements. (e.g., high-fidelity components and
CDs)
3. If e pX = 0, goods are independent of each other.

INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND


Income elasticity of demand is the responsiveness of quantity demanded to
changes in income, holding all other factors constant. It is computed as

% change in Q dQ/Q dQ Y
eY = --------------- = ------- = --- x ----
% change in Y dY/Y dY Q

If e Y > 0, products are normal or superior goods whose demand varies directly with
income, holding prices constant. A majority of consumer goods are superior goods.
If e Y < 0, products are inferior goods. Demand will drop with rising personal
income, since, for example, people turn to more expensive foods with higher
income. Examples of inferior goods include dried beans, recapped automobile tires,
and budget-priced durable goods.

ADVERTISING ELASTICITY OF DEMAND


Advertising elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the quantity sold (or
market share) that is associated with a percentage change in the advertising expenditures of
that product.

% change in Q dQ/Q dQ A
e A = --------------- = ------- = --- x ----
% change in A dA/A dA Q

It is used as a measure of short-run advertising effectiveness. This elasticity may be


affected by a number of factors such as the stage of the product's market development, the
extent to which competitors react to the firm's advertising, either by further advertising or by

42
increased promotional efforts, the importance of other marketing factors (e.g., prices,
incomes, tastes, etc.), and the quality and quantity of the firm's past and present advertising.

MARKET SHARE ELASTICITY


It is the percentage change in a firm's market share resulting from a percentage change
in the price.
CONSTANT ELASTICITY
The second most commonly specified demand relationship is the
multiplicative form, which gives constant elasticity. The form is found in power
functions.

An example is:
b c d
Q = aP A Y (1)

where P = price, A advertising, and Y = income.

By definition,

% change in Q ∂Q P
ep = --------------- = ------- ------ (2)
% change in p ∂P Q

Differentiating equation (1) with respect to price (P), we obtain

∂Q
------ = abP b-1 Ac Yd
∂P

b-1 c d
Therefore, e p = abP A Y .(P/Q) (3)

Substituting (1) for Q in (3) gives:


b-1 c d b c d
e p = abP A Y .(P/ aP A Y ) (4)

Combining terms and canceling where possible in equation (4), we obtain


b c d
abP A Y P
ep = ------------------------ . --------------------- =b
b c d
P aP A Y

Thus, the price elasticity of demand is equal to b(whose usual sign is negative), the
exponent of the price variable in the multiplicative demand function given as in

43
equation (1). Therefore, the elasticity is not a function of the price/quantity (P/Q)
ratio and hence is constant. In a similar fashion, we can prove that (1) the income
elasticity is c, and (2) the advertising elasticity is d.

NOTE:
The power function form can be transformed into a log-linear form using
logarithm and then estimated by the least-squares method. Equation (1) is
equivalent to
log Q = log a + b log P + c log A + d log Y

The property of constant elasticity is useful, since it means that changes in one of
the independent variables, such as income, will result in proportionate changes in
quantity demanded. Note that the elasticity of a linear function changes over the
entire range of the demand curve.

EXAMPLE 5
Given the demand function in multiplicative form:
Q = 2077P -.144 P X.097 A.314
The price elasticity is always -.144, which means that a 1% reduction (increase) in
price leads to .14% increase (decrease) in demand.

OPTIMAL PRICING POLICY AND PRICE ELASTICITY


We note, without a mathematical derivation, the relationship between the
point price elasticity of demand, marginal revenue, and price:

1
MR = P 1 + ----
ep

(Note that ep is a negative number.)

This follows directly from the mathematical definition of marginal revenue (MR).
This formula is useful in setting a firm’s pricing policy. From the profit-maximizing
condition MR = MC, we can derive the formula for determining the profit-
maximizing price level, which is shown below.

MC = MR

1
MC = P 1 + ----------
ep

Solving for the optimal or profit-maximizing P*, yields

44
MC
P* = --------------------
1
1 + ----
ep

EXAMPLE 6
Suppose the manager of a toy store notes a 2.5% increase in weekly sales
following a 1% price discount on the Bamboo doll. The store’s wholesale cost per
doll plus display and marketing expenses total $30 per unit. The price elasticity of
demand is:

% change in Q -2.5
e p = --------------- = ----- = -2.5
% change in p 1

The profit-maximizing price is then:


P = $30/(1 + 1/-2.5) = $50
Suppose the manager can reduce, through quantity buying, marginal costs per unit
by $3 to $27. Then the new optimal price is:
P = $27/(1 + 1/-2.5) = $45
Thus, the profit-maximizing price would fall by $5 following a $3 reduction in the
store’s marginal costs.

SUPPLY FUNCTION
Up to this point we focused on the demand side of the market which
represents half of the forces that determine the price in a market. The other
determinant is market supply. Economic theory tells us that supply for a particular product
depends on its price, i.e.,
Qs = f(P)
Economic theory goes one step further, stating that
Qs = f (P, PX, W,...)
where P = its own price, PX = the prices of technologically related goods , W = the value of
some other variables that affect supply, such as the existing technology or weather. Supply
function is a mathematical relationship showing how the quantity supplied of a good or
service responds to changes in these factors (See Figure 6). A competitive firm will produce at
a level at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue (selling price). Thus, a change in input
prices affects marginal cost and the quantity of output supplied.

Explanatory factors other than its own price are called supply shifters. The effect of
each explanatory factor on the quantity supplied may be estimated statistically with time-
series or cross-sectional data.

SHIFT IN SUPPLY
A shift in the supply of a product is brought about by a change in any factor other than
the price of the product. Graphically, a shift in supply is illustrated as a parallel movement of

45
the supply curve. A rightward (leftward) shift, or an increase (decrease) in supply implies that
more (less) product is supplied than before the increase (decrease) at every price. Supply
shifters include (1) input prices, (2) technology, (3) number of firms, (4) substitutes in
production, and (5) excise taxes.

FIGURE 6
SUPPLY FUNCTION AND SUPPLY SHIFTERS

MARKET EQUILIBRIUM
Equilibrium in a competitive market is determined by the intersection of the market
demand and supply curves. Equilibrium price is the price of a commodity (good and service)
toward which a competitive market will move and, once there, at which it will remain. It is
the price at which the market "clears"--that is, the price determined by the intersection of the
market forces of demand and supply (Figure 7). Equilibrium quantity is the quantity that
corresponds to the equilibrium price. It is the output level at which the market "clears."
Qd = Qs

FIGURE 7
MARKET EQUILIBRIUM

46
EXAMPLE 7
The following relations describe monthly demand and supply functions for
dry cleaning services in the local area:
Qd =50 - 2P (demand)
Qs = -20 +5P (supply)
The equilibrium price-output combination is determined as follows:
At equilibrium, Qd = Qs
50 - 2P = -20 + 5P
-7P = -70; P = $10
To find the equilibrium quantity, we simply plug this price into either the demand or
the supply function. For example, using the supply function, we find that Qs = -20
+5P = -20 +5(10) = 30 units.

QUESTIONS
1. What does demand theory and analysis involve? List what is used in determining
a firm’s revenue.
2. What are demand shifters? Give examples.
3. Define total revenue, average revenue, and marginal revenue. Explain the
relationships among these.
4. What are the factors associated with demand elasticity?
5. Distinguish between arc elasticity and point elasticity.
6. What is the special feature of a linear demand curve in terms of price elasticity?
7. Describe the relationship between price elasticity of demand and total revenue.
8. Give two good examples of how price elasticity can be used for marketing
decisions.
9. How do you know whether a product is a normal good or an inferior good?

47
10. What type of function form would give constant elasticity of demand?
11. Write down the relationship between the point price elasticity of demand,
marginal revenue, and price.

PROBLEMS
1. A valve manufacturer is considering raising the price of its valves from the
current average price of $2,000 per unit. It is currently selling 600 units per month,
but trying to bring its sales down to its maximum output of 500 units per month. If
the firm’s price elasticity of demand is -2 over the range of $2,000 to $2,500 per
valve, what will the new price have to be in order to bring demand in line with
capacity?

2. Lilex Watch, Inc. is considering lowering the price of its watches from the
current $80 per unit to $70 per unit. It sells 2,000 units per month. If the watch’s
price elasticity of demand is -2, what will be the new quantity sold?

3. The Sunhee Bags, Inc. has estimated the following demand function for its deluxe
sleeping bag in the San Francisco Bay area:
P = 600 - .3Q
(a) Determine the MR and TR functions.
(b) At what price would Sunhee Bags fail to sell any sleeping bags?
(c) What is the maximum quantity Sunhee Bags could sell?
(d) What is the maximum revenue that the firm could receive?
(e) For a given percentage change in price, what would be the percentage change in
quantity demanded at the output level Q = 700?
(f) What is the arc price elasticity of demand for the quantity range of 700-800
units?

4. Given the following demand curve:


Q = 250 - .5P
Determine the corresponding total revenue (TR) function, marginal revenue (MR)
function, and the average revenue (AR) function.

5. Given the following demand curve:


P = 400 - 3Q
Determine the corresponding total revenue (TR) function, marginal revenue (MR)
function, and the average revenue (AR) function.

6. The marketing department of a compact automaker has determined the following


demand functions for their cars:

Q = 150,000 -52P + 80P C + 0.3A + 0.5Y

where Q = the number of the firm’s cars sold


weekly
P = the price of the firm’s car

48
P C = the price of a close competitor’s car
A = weekly advertising dollars spent
Y = average family disposable income

(a) If P = $12,000, P C = $10,000, A = $310,000, and Y = $25,000, derive the


demand function and determine the price elasticity of demand.
(b) Comment on the price elasticity obtained in part (a). If the firm raises price,
what will happen to total revenue?
(c) Assuming the values given in part (a), calculate the income elasticity of demand.
Interpret your answer.
(d) Determine the cross elasticity of demand between two competing cars. Interpret
your answer.

7. The demand for your product has been estimated to be


Q A = 8,500 - 4P A - 2P B + P C - .1Y, where P = price and Y = income. The relevant
price and income data are as follows: P A = 10, P B = 50, P C = 50, and Y = 40,000.
(a) Which goods are substitutes for product A? Which are complements?
(b) Is A an inferior or a normal good?
(c) How much A will be purchased?

8. (a) Derive the following formula:

1
MR = P 1 + ----
ep

(b) Explain the relationship between marginal revenue (MR) and the price elasticity
of demand (ep )

9. Suppose the manager of a toy store notes a 2% increase in weekly sales following
a 1% price discount on the Bamboo doll. The store’s wholesale cost per doll plus
display and marketing expenses total $15 per unit.
(a) What is the store’s point price elasticity of demand?
(b) Calculate the optimal price.
(c) Suppose the manager can reduce, through quantity buying, marginal costs per
unit by $1 to $14. What is the new optimal price?

10. Your company’s food product has its own price elasticity of demand of -.8. If
the price of food increased by 5 percent, what would happen to the quantity of food
demanded and the total revenue for your company’s food product?

11. The following relations describe monthly demand and supply functions for dry
cleaning services in the local area:

49
Qd = 40,000 - 4,000P (demand)
Qs = -10,000 + 10,000P (supply)

(a) At what average price level would demand equal zero?


(b) At what average price level would supply equal zero?
(c) Find the equilibrium price-output combination?

ANSWERS
1. Demand analysis include (a) quantitative expression of demand (specification of demand
functions), (b) calculation of various elasiticities of demand, (c) estimation of demand
functions, (d) forecasting sales, and (e) pricing decisions.
2. Demand shifters are factors that create increase or decrease in demand for a good brought
about by a change in any factor other than the price of the product. They include (1)
consumers' incomes, (2) the prices of substitute or complementary goods, and (3) consumers'
tastes. Graphically, a shift in demand may be represented by a parallel movement of the
demand curve.
3. Total revenue (TR) of a firm is directly related to the demand for the firm’s
product or service. Average revenue (AR) is total revenue per unit of output, that is total
revenue received divided by output., i.e., AR = TR/Q. Marginal revenue (MR) is the rate of
change of total revenue with respect to quantity demanded, i.e., MR = dTR/dQ. The total
revenue is maximized when MR is equal to zero.
4. The principal factors involved with demand elasticity are (1) the price of the
good (in the case of price elasticity), (2) the price of a substitute product (in the
case of cross elasticity), (3) income (in the case of income elasticity), and (4)
advertising (in the case of advertising elasticity).
5. Arc elasticity of demand is the average responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change
in price between two different values, while point elasticity is the elasticity measured at
a given point.
6. In the case of a linear demand function, while the slope of a straight line demand
curve is the same at all points, the elasticity for such a curve varies from one point
to the next.
7. Economists have established the following relationships between price elasticity
(ep ) and total revenue (TR), which can aid a firm in setting its price.

Price ep > 1 ep = 1 ep < 1


Price rises TR falls No change TR rises
Price falls TR rises No change TR falls

8. Price elasticities can be used to answer the following types of questions: (a) what
will be the impact on sales of a 5% price increase? (b) how great a price reduction
is necessary to increase sales by 20%?
9. If income elasticity (e Y ) is greater than zero, products are normal or superior
goods whose demand varies directly with income, holding prices constant. If e Y < 0,
products are inferior goods.
10. The multiplicative form (or power function) gives constant elasticity. The form
is found in power functions. An example is Q = aP b Ac Yd .

50
11. The relationship between the point price elasticity of demand, marginal revenue,
and price is:
1
MR = P 1 + ----
ep

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.

ep = (Q2 - Q1)/[(Q2 + Q1)/2] = (Q2 - Q1) (P2 + P1)


(P2 - P1)/[(P2 + P1)/2] (P2 - P1) (Q2 + Q1)

-2 = [(500 - 600)/(P2 - 2000)][(P2 + 2000)/(500 + 600)]


= -100(P2 + 2000)/1100/(P2 - 2000)
-2(11P2 - 22000) = -P2 - 2000
-22P2 + 44000 = -P2 - 2000
-21P2 = -46000
P2 = $2190.48

2.
-2 = [(Q2 - 2000)/( 70 - 80)][(70 + 80)/(Q2 + 2000)]
-2 = 150(Q2 - 2000)/-10(Q2 + 2000)
-2(-10Q2 - 20000) = 150Q2 - 300000
20Q2 + 40000 = 150Q2 - 300000
-130Q2 =-340000
Q2 = 2615.38

3.
(a) Given P = 600 - .3Q:
TR = PQ = (600 - .3Q)Q = 600Q - .3Q2
MR = dTR/dQ = 600 - .6Q
(b) At P = $600, Q = 0 since P = 600 - .3(0) = $600.
(c) P= 600 - .3Q, so Q = 2,000 - 10/3P
At a price of 0, Q = 2,000 - 10/3(0) = 2,000 units.
(d) TR will be maximized when MR = 0.
MR = dTR/dQ = 600 - .6Q = 0; Q = 1,000 units.
At Q = 1,000 units, TR = 600Q - .3Q2 = 600(1,000) - .3(1,000)2 = $300,000
(e)

% change in Q dQ/Q dQ p
e p = --------------- = ------- = --- x ----
% change in P dP/P dP Q

First,
dQ
--- = - 10/3

51
dP

Then, at Q = 700, P = 390


e p = -(10/3) x (390/700) = -1.86. The point elasticity of demand is -1.86, so the
percentage change in quantity demanded would be -1.86 times the percentage
change in price.
(f) Since P= 600 - .3Q,
At Q = 700, P= 600 - .3(700) = $390
At Q = 800, P= 600 - .3(800) = $360
Therefore,
Arc elasticity of demand

(Q2 - Q1) (P2 + P1) (800 - 700) (360 + 390)


---------- x ----------- = ------------ x ------------ = - 1.67
(P2 - P1) (Q2 + Q1) (360 - 390) (800 + 700)

4.
Q = 250 - .5P ----> .5P = 250 - Q ----> P = 500 - 2Q
TR = P x Q = (500 - 2Q)Q = 500Q - 2Q2
MR = dTR/dQ = 500 -4Q
AR = TR/Q = 500 - 2Q

5.
TR = P x Q = (400 - 3Q)Q = 400Q - 3Q2
MR = dTR/dQ = 400 -6Q
AR = TR/Q = 400 - 3Q

6.
(a) The demand function is:

Q = 150,000 -52P + 80P C + 0.3A + 0.5Y


= 150,000 -52P + 80(10,000) + 0.3(310,000) + 0.5(25,000)
= 1,055.500 -52P

Hence, Q = 1,055,500 - 52P = 1,055,500 -52(12,000) = 431,500

(b) The price elasticity of demand is

% change in ∂Q P
Q
ep = ----------------- = ------- . ------ = -52 (12,000/431,500) = - 1.45 = 1.45 > 1.
% change in P ∂P Q

Demand for the car is elastic and thus if the price is raised, total revenue will drop
sharply.

(c) The income elasticity is

52
% change in Q ∂Q Y
eY = --------------- = ------- . ------ = .5 (25,000/431,500) = .029< 1.
% change in Y ∂Y Q

Since the income elasticity is greater than 0 but less than 1, the car is normal but not
superior. If income goes up, demand will rise but not at the same rate of increase as
income.
(d) The cross elasticity is

% change in Q ∂Q PC
ePc = ----------------- = ------- . ------ = 80(10,000/431,500) = 1.85 > 1.
% change in P C ∂ PC Q

Since the cross elasticity is greater than 0, these two cars are substitutes.

7.
(a) C is a substitute for A, while B is a complement for A.
(b) A is an inferior good, as indicated by a negative sign associated with the income
variable.
(c) Q A = 8,500 - 4P A - 2P B + P C - .1Y = 8,500 -4(10) - 2(50) + (50) - .1(40,000) =
4,410

8.
(a) By definition,
MR = dTR/dQ = d(P x Q)/dQ = d[f(Q)x Q)]/dQ =f(Q) + f’(Q) Q = P + Q
(dP/dQ)

Q dP 1
=P1+ ------ =P1+ -----
P dQ eP

(b) We observe that

MR > 0 when ep > 1


MR = 0 when ep = 1
MR < 0 when ep < 1

9.
(a)
% change in Q -2
e p = --------------- = ----- = -2
% change in p 1

53
(b) The profit-maximizing price is then:
P = $15/(1 + 1/-2) = $30
(c) The new optimal price is:
P = $14/(1 + 1/-2) = $28
Thus, the profit-maximizing price would fall by $2 following a $1 reduction in the
store’s marginal costs.

10.
% change in Q % change in Q
e p = ----------------- ----> -.8 = ----------------
% change in P 5%

% change in Q = -.8(5) = -4%. The demand for food will fall by 4% if the price
increases by 5%. Since the price elasticity is less than 1, demand is inelastic. Thus,
the price increase will lead to an increase in your total revenue.

11.
(a) Set Qd = 0 and solve for P.
Qd = 40,000 - 4,000P = 0; P = $10.
(b) Set Qs = 0 and solve for P.
Qs = -10,000 + 10,000P = 0; P = $1
(c) At the market equilibrium, Qd = Q s.
40,000 - 4,000P = -10,000 + 10,000P
50,000 = 14,000P; P = $3.57, Substituting P = $3.57 into either the demand and the
supply function yields:
Qd = 40,000 - 4,000P = 40,000 - 4,000($3.57) = 25,720 units.

54
CHAPTER 4
QUANTITATIVE DEMAND ANALYSIS

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Design consumer surveys.


2. Conduct and discuss market experiments.
3. Discuss an identification problem.
4. Explain regression analysis.
5. Compute and give an example of linear regression.
6. Define and calculate the simple regression .
7. Explain the least-squares method .
8. Explain multiple regression method.
9. Compute the standard error of the regression coefficient.
10. Demonstrate and calculate the standard error of the estimate.
11. Illustrate and explain the coefficient of determination.

In the previous chapter, the theory of demand was developed; the concepts of
demand elasticity were introduced and analyzed. In this chapter we explore the
procedures that may be used in making empirical estimates of demand functions.
With demand estimation, we will be able to quantitatively calculate the various
elasiticities and determine the impact of a change in various factors such as price,
income, or advertising on quantity demanded. Essentially there are two major
approaches to demand estimation: Direct and statistical. Direct approaches to
demand estimation include consumer surveys and market experiments. A sample of
market data taken at a point in time is a cross-section. Statistical estimation of the
demand function primarily rests on econometrics and regression analysis.

CONSUMER SURVEYS
Consumers are questioned about their likely response to such things as
sensitivity to price change, willingness to buy, or awareness of advertising
campaigns. By aggregating the data obtained, the firm can develop a better
understanding of key factors in its demand function. An advantage is that in
short-term sales forecasting, subjective information about consumer attitudes and
expectations, obtainable only through interview methods, often makes the
difference between an accurate estimate and one that misses by a wide margin. It is
fraught with potential pitfalls. One is that consumers are frequently unable, and at
times unwilling, to provide accurate answers to hypothetical questions about how
they would respond to changes in major demand variables.

MARKET EXPERIMENTS
Market experiments involve examining the way consumers behave in real-
market situations. A firm varies prices, advertising, and other controllable variables

55
in the demand function, with the variations occurring either over time or between
markets and observes the impact on quantity demanded. An advantage is that
because important variables in the demand function such as price and advertising
are controlled by the experimenter, the firm can gain some insight regarding the
short-run effects. Wide swings in important demand-related factors can be gained.
Or a feel can be developed for the price elasticity or cross elasticity of demand for a
product. Major drawbacks are: (a) These experiments are extremely expensive to
undertake on a large scale. (b) Because of the high cost and the risk involved, the
duration of the test is likely to be short. The experimenter is thus forced to examine
short-run data and must attempt to extend it to a longer period. (c) Possible changes
in external economic conditions or competitor behavior during the market test can
undermine the validity of the results.

NOTE:
Each technique of demand estimation has important pros and cons. Firms must make
their choice of demand estimation method, or an appropriate combination of methods, on
the basis of individual estimation problem characteristics.

IDENTIFICATION PROBLEM
We often encounter a statistical problem in the estimation of the parameters of one
function such as the demand function when simultaneous relations exist. When the same
two endogenous variables appear in at least two different equations in a simultaneous
model, a problem exists of identifying which relationship can be estimated on the basis of
data, because all the variables change simultaneously. For instance, both supply curves and
demand curves may be specified with quantity as the dependent variable, and price as the
explanatory variable. Any observations available are actually all the same, namely at the
intersection point of demand and supply. It is impossible to distinguish the demand curve
from the true supply curve or any other line which passes through the intersection point.
(See Figure 1). The scatter of dots arises because both the supply curves and demand
curves are shifting (possibly in unobservable ways).

In order to distinguish between equations, their specifications require knowledge of


actual shifts in demand or supply due to changes in some factor which affects only one of
the curves. When the problem is serious, consumer surveys and market experiments can be
used to gain important demand information.

56
FIGURE 1
IDENTIFICATION PROBLEM: DEMAND AND SUPPLY

ECONOMETRICS AND REGRESSION ANALYSIS


A major empirical work is done within the framework of econometrics.
Econometrics is concerned with empirical testing of economic theory using various
estimation methods including regression analysis. The technique of regression
analysis is perhaps the best known and most frequently used technique in
developing estimates of demand function.

REGRESSION ANALYSIS
Regression analysis is a statistical procedure for estimating mathematically the average
relationship between the dependent variable and the independent variable(s). Simple regression
involves one independent variable, price or advertising in a demand function, whereas multiple
regression involves two or more variables, that is price and advertising together.

LEAST-SQUARES METHOD
The least-squares method is widely used in regression analysis for estimating the
parameter values in a regression equation. The regression method includes all the observed
data and attempts to find a line of best fit. To find this line, a technique called the
least-squares method is used.

We first assume a linear relation: Y = α + βX + e, where α and β are the true


(but unknown) population parameters of the regression line and e = an error term. In
the real world, our task is to find an estimate of α and β from a sample data. Thus
we wish to find Y' = a + bX, where a and b are estimates of α and β, respectively, and Y’
is the calculated value of Y given a particular value of X and our estimated
relationship. Then

57
Y = a + bX + u
where u is the error term for our estimated relationship and is an estimate of e, the
population error term.
Thus,
u = Y - Y'

The least-squares criterion requires that the line of best fit be such that the sum of the
squares of the errors (or the vertical distance in Figure 2 from the observed data points to the
line) is a minimum, i.e.,
Minimum: Σu2 = Σ(Y – a - bX)2

Using differential calculus we obtain the following equations, called normal equations:

ΣY = na + bΣX
ΣXY = aΣX + bΣX2

Solving the equations for b and a yields

n ∑ XY - (∑ X)(∑ Y)
b=
n ∑ X 2 − (∑ X) 2

a = Y − bX

where Y =
∑Y and X =
∑X
n n

58
FIGURE 2
SCATTERGRAPH: Y AND Y'

EXAMPLE 1

DHG Oil Company has observed the following price-quantity relationships over the
last six periods:

Quantity
Period Price (X) demanded(Y)
1 1.20 250
2 1.21 245
3 1.25 200
4 1.17 310
5 1.15 375
6 1.19 280
7.17 1660

To illustrate the computations of b and a, we will refer to the data in Table 1. All the sums
required are computed and shown below.

59
TABLE 1
COMPUTED SUMS
Quantity
Period Price (X) demanded(Y) XY X-squared Y-squared
1 1.20 250 300.00 1.4400 62,500
2 1.21 245 296.45 1.4641 60,025
3 1.25 200 250.00 1.5625 40,000
4 1.17 310 362.70 1.3689 96,100
5 1.15 375 431.25 1.3225 140,625
6 1.19 280 333.20 1.4161 78,400
7.17 1660 1973.60 8.5741 477,650

From the table above:


ΣX = 7.17; ΣY = 1660; ΣXY = 1973.60; ΣX2 = 8.5741

X = ΣX/n = 7.17/6 = 1.20; Y = ΣY/n = 1660/6 = 276.67

Substituting these values into the formula for b first:

nΣXY - (ΣX)( ΣY) (6)(1973.60) - (7.17)(1660) -60.60


b = -----------------------------= ------------------------------------= --------- = -1697.48
nΣX2 - (ΣX)2 (6)(8.5741) - (7.17)2 0.0357

_ _
a = Y - bX = 276.67 - (-1697.48)(1.20)) = 2305.15

Thus, Y' = 2305.15 – 1697.48 X

Note that ΣY2 is not used here but rather is computed for r-squared (r2).

60
FIGURE 3
SCATTER DIAGRAM

400
Quantity demanded
300
200
100
0
0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20 1.30

Price
Note: The objective of a scatter diagram is to demonstrate correlations. Each observation is
represented by a dot on a graph corresponding to a particular value of X (the independent
variable) and Y (the dependent variable).

EXAMPLE 2
Assume a price of $1.10 is to be expended for next year; the projected sales for the
next year would be computed as follows:
Y' = 2305.15 – 1697.48 X = 2305.15 – 1697.48(1.10) = $437.92

REGRESSION STATISTICS
Regression analysis is a statistical method. Hence, it uses a variety of statistics to tell
about the accuracy and reliability of the regression results. They include:
1. Correlation coefficient (r) and coefficient of determination(r2)
2. Standard error of the estimate (Se) and prediction confidence interval
3. Standard error of the regression coefficient (Sb) and confidence interval
4. t-statistic

Each of these statistics is explained below.

1. Correlation coefficient (r) and coefficient of determination (r2)


The correlation coefficient r measures the degree of correlation between Y and X.
The range of values it takes on is between -1 and +1. More widely used, however, is the
coefficient of determination, designated r2 (read as r-squared). Simply put, r2 tells us how
good the estimated regression equation is. In other words, it is a measure of "goodness of fit"
in the regression. Therefore, the higher the r2, the more confidence we have in our estimated
equation.

61
NOTE:
A low r2 is an indication that the model is inadequate for explaining the Y
variable. The general causes for this problem are:
1. Use of a wrong functional form.
2. Poor choice of an X variable as the predictor.
3. The omission of some important variable or variables from the model.

EXAMPLE 3
The statement "Sales is a function of price with r2 = 70 percent," can be interpreted as
"70 percent of the total variation of sales is explained by the regression equation and the
change in price and the remaining 30 percent is accounted for by something other than price,
such as advertising and income."

As shown in Figure 4, the total deviation of the dependent variable Y from its mean
Y can be divided into two parts.

(Y - Y ) = (Y - Y') + (Y' - Y )

(Total Deviation) (Unexplained Deviation) (Explained Deviation)

The measure of the goodness of fit of a regression line, expressed by the coefficient of
determination (r2), is made by comparing Σ (Y' - Y )2, the explained sum of squares with the
total sum of the squares Σ (Y - Y )2.

That is,
Σ (Y' - Y )2 Explained variance
r2 = -------------- = -----------------------
Σ (Y - Y )2 Total variance

Thus, the coefficient of determination represents the proportion of the total variation in Y that
is explained by the regression equation. It has the range of values between 0 and 1.

NOTE:
The sum of squares of the explained deviation plus the sum of squares of the
unexplained deviation equals the total sum of squares.

FIGURE 4
FUNDAMENTAL MEASURE OF VARIANCE (DEVIATION)

62
In a simple regression situation, however, there is a short-cut method available:

2 [n ∑ XY - (∑ X)(∑ Y)]2
r =
[n ∑ X 2 − (∑ X) 2 ][n ∑ Y 2 - (∑ Y) 2 ]

Comparing this formula with the one for b, we see that the only additional information we
need to compute r2 is ΣY2.

EXAMPLE 4
To illustrate the computations of various regression statistics, we will refer to the data
in Table 1. Using the shortcut method for r2,
2 2
[(6)(1973.60) - (7.17)(1660)] (-60.60)
2
r = −− = 
2 2
[(6)(8.5741) - (7.17) ][ (6) (477650)- (1660) ] (0.0357) (110300 )

3672.36
=  = 0.9326 = 93.26%
3937.71

This means that about 93.26 percent of the total variation in sales is explained by
price and the remaining 6.74 percent is still unexplained. A relatively high r2 indicates that the
estimated demand function is quite reliable and price is an excellent determinant of demand.

2. Standard Error of the Estimate (Se) and Prediction Confidence Interval

63
The standard error of the estimate, designated Se, is defined as the standard deviation
of the regression. It is computed as:

Se =
∑ (Y - Y' ) 2

=
∑Y 2
- a ∑ Y - b∑ XY
n-2 n-2

This statistic can be used to gain some idea of the accuracy of our predictions.

EXAMPLE 5
Going back to our example data, Se is calculated as :

(477650) - (2305.15)(1660) - (-1697.48)(1973.60)


Se = −
6-2

1247.5
=  = 17.66
4

Suppose you wish to make a prediction regarding an individual Y value--such as a


prediction about the sales when price is $1.10. Usually, we would like to have some objective
measure of the confidence we can place in our prediction, and one such measure is a
confidence (or prediction) interval constructed for Y.
A confidence interval for a predicted Y, given a value for X, can be constructed in the
following manner.

1 (X p − X) 2
Y' ± t S e 1 + +
n (∑ X) 2
∑X 2
-
n

where Y' = the predicted value of Y given a value for X;


Xp = the value of an independent variable used as the basis for prediction;
Note: t is the critical value for the level of significance employed. For example, for a
significance level of 0.025 (which is equivalent to a 95% confidence level in a two-tailed
test), the critical value of t for 4 degrees of freedom is 2.776 (See Table 5 in the Appendix).

NOTE:

64
Degrees of freedom (df) is the number of observations beyond the absolute minimum
needed to calculate a given regression line or statistic. For example, to compute a constant
term, a, at least one observation is needed; to compute a and b, at least two observations are
required; and so on.

EXAMPLE 6
If you want to have a 95 percent confidence interval of your prediction, the range for
the prediction, given a price of $1.10 would be between $356.93 and $518.91, as determined
as follows: Note that from Example 2, Y' = 2305.15 - 1697.X = 2305.15 - 1697.48($1.10) =
$437.92
The confidence interval is therefore established as follows:

2
1 (1.10 - 1.195)
$437.92 ± (2.776)(17.66) 1 +  + 
2
6 8.5741 -(7.17) /6

= $437.92 ± (2.776)(17.66) (1.638)

= $437.92 ± 80.30

which means the range for the prediction, given a price of $1.10 would be between $356.62
and $518.21. Note that $356.93 = $437.92 – 80.30 and $518.91 =$437.92 + 80.30.

NOTE:
Many managerial economics texts use Y' ± t Se for the prediction interval,
ignoring the adjustment factor. In Example 6, the interval is $437.92 ± (2.776)(17.66).

3. Standard Error of the Regression Coefficient (Sb)


The standard error of the regression coefficient, designated Sb, and the t-statistic are closely
related. Sb is calculated as:
Se
Se
Sb =
(X - X) 2

or in short-cut form
Se
Sb =
(X 2 - X ∑ X )
Sb gives an estimate of the range where the true coefficient will "actually" fall. Just as
Se was used to determine confidence intervals for your prediction, Sb can be used to estimate
confidence intervals of the true value of the regression coefficient with varying degrees of
confidence. The intervals are

65
b + t Sb

4. t-Statistic
t-statistics (or t-value) is a measure of the statistical significance of an independent
variable X in explaining the dependent variable Y. It is determined by
b-β
t = ------------
Sb

Since we wish to test the hypothesis that β = 0, we substitute β = 0 into this


formula, which means that we essentially divide the estimated regression coefficient b by
its standard error Sb. It is then compared with the table t-value to determine if the null
hypothesis is true.
Note: The t-statistic basically measures how many standard errors the coefficient is away
from zero.
The higher the t-value, the greater the confidence we have in the coefficient as a predictor.
Low t-values are indications of low reliability of the predictive power of that coefficient.

EXAMPLE 7
The Sb for our example is:
17.66
Sb = --------------------------------
√ 8.5741 - (1.195)(7.17)

17.66 17.66
= ------------------------ = ---------------- = 231.15
√ 0.00585 0.0764

b- 0 -1697.48
Thus, t-statistic = ----------- =- ----------------= -7.34
Sb 231.15

Since, t = 7.34 (the absolute value of –7.34) > 2.776 (the table t-value), we conclude that the
null hypothesis is false and therefore the b coefficient is statistically significant.

NOTE:
(1) t-statistic is more relevant to multiple regressions which have more than one b's.
(2) r2 tells you how good the forest (overall fit) is while t-statistic tells you how good
an individual tree (an independent variable) is.
In summary, the table t value, based on a degree of freedom and a level of
significance, is used:
(1)To set the prediction range -- upper and lower limits -- for the predicted value of
the dependent variable.

66
(2) To estimate confidence intervals within which the true value of the regression
coefficient falls.
(3) As a cutoff value for the t-test.

USE OF EXCEL FOR REGRESSION


Spreadsheet programs such as Excel has a regression routine which you can use
without any difficulty. You can access the regression tool by completing the following steps:
1. Click the Tools menu.
2. Click Data Analysis.
3. Click Regression.

After you choose the Regression command, the Regression dialog box appears, which asks
you to select the Y-Range, the X-Range, and the Output Range. After selecting these ranges,
you can click the OK button and Excel will calculate the least-squares values for the
parameters a and b (along with other summary statistics), as shown below.

SUMMARY OUTPUT

Regression Statistics
Multiple R 0.96572
R Square 0.93261
Adjusted R 0.91577
Square
Standard 17.5983
Error
Observations 6

ANOVA
df SS MS F Significance F
Regression 1 17144.54 17144.54 55.35873 0.001742641
Residual 4 1238.796 309.6989
Total 5 18383.33

Coefficients Standard t Stat P-value Lower 95% Upper


Error 95%
Intercept 2305.15 272.7282 8.452204 0.001073 1547.937731 3062.37
X Variable 1 -1697.48 228.1452 -7.44035 0.001743 -2330.912925 -1064.05

NOTE:
Note from the Excel regression output that
(a) b = -1697.48 and a = 2305.15; therefore, the estimated demand function is
Y’ = 2305.15 – 1697.48X
(b) r2 = .93261
(c) Se = 17.5983
(d) Sb = 228.1452

67
(e) t for the regression coefficient = -7.44035

The computer output numbers are different from manually obtained numbers
due to rounding errors. Computer numbers are more accurate since the computer
carries computations to more decimal digits.

QUESTIONS
1. Why is the identification problem often serious for demand estimation?
2. What criteria must be met if regression-based analysis is to provide an accurate
estimate of demand relationships?
3. What are "consumer surveys'? What are some of the problems associated with
the use of consumer surveys to estimate the demand for a firm's product?
4. Explain market experiments: what they are, how they may be used, and any
limitations that they might have.
5. Distinguish between simple regression and multiple regression. Give an example
of each.
6. What does a low r2 mean? What are some causes for this?
7. What are the uses of the t-table value obtained based on a given degree of
freedom and a given level of significance?
8. What are the primary use of standard errors?

PROBLEMS
1. The following are the advertising and sales data of Jupiter Corporation over an eight-
month period.

Advertising Sales
(000 omitted) (000 omitted)
320 $2,600
200 1,500
230 2,150
240 2,250
720 4,700
560 3,700
470 3,300
750 4,750

a) Develop the demand equation by using the method of least squares.


b) Compute the coefficient of determination.
c) Comment on the choice of advertising in predicting sales. Is advertising a good predictor?
2. A government economist wishes to establish the relationship between annual family
income X and savings Y. A sample of 100 families has been made and the following
calculations have been obtained (X and Y are measured in thousands of dollars):
∑X = $1,239 ∑Y = $79 ∑XY = $1,613
2 2
∑X = $17,322 ∑Y = $293

68
a) Determine the equation for the estimated regression line.
b) State the meaning of the slope b and the intercept value a.
c) Compute the coefficient of determination r2.
d) Calculate the standard error of the estimate se.
e) Write down the expression for the predicted range of Y (Use the table t-value = 1.98 with 98
degrees of freedom and a 5% significance level).
3. You want to estimate the demand function for gasoline. Given the following data
and the regression output from Excel :

Quantity
Period Price (P) demanded(Q)
1 1.20 300
2 1.30 295
3 1.25 298
4 1.33 275
5 1.27 266
6 0.99 360
7 1.15 325
8 1.36 266
9 1.19 311
10 1.22 325
12.26 3021

SUMMARY OUTPUT

Regression Statistics
Multiple R 0.9128
R Square 0.8333
Adjusted R 0.8124
Square
Standard 12.826
Error
Observations 10

ANOVA
df SS MS F Significance
F
Regression 1 6576.785 6576.785 39.97698 0.000227161
Residual 8 1316.115 164.5143
Total 9 7892.9

Coefficients Standard t Stat P-value Lower 95% Upper 95%


Error
Intercept 616.13 49.83278 12.36403 1.71E-06 501.2194022 731.0488
X Variable 1 -256.15 40.51178 -6.32274 0.000227 -349.5656425 -162.725

69
a) Write the estimated demand function.
b) What is r2 ? What does that number indicate?
c) Compute the point elasticity of demand when the price is $1. Is this product
price elastic?
d) Determine the confidence interval for the price coefficient (The table t-value
with a 5% significance level and 8 (10 - 2) degrees of freedom is 2.306).
e) What is t-value for the regression coefficient? What does that indicate?
f) Can this estimated relationship be improved? What would you suggest?

ANSWERS
1. The identification problem occurs when many factors that influence product demand
also affect product supply. When two economic relations, such as demand and supply
functions, are so interrelated so as to make empirical estimation of the relations
impossible, we say that we are unable to identify the individual functions.
2. The regression model must be properly specified. In other words, the range of factors
influencing demand must be properly identified and the correct functional form must
be employed. Many statistics such as r2 and t-tests are used to ascertain whether these
conditions are satisfied.
3. Potential and actual customers are questioned about various factors affecting
their demand for a firm's product. Two problems are: (a) consumers may not be
able to respond accurately to specific questions such as proposed price changes,
and (b) such surveys may be quite expensive.
4. A market experiment is conducted by varying those factors that supposedly
affect the demand and which are under control, such as pricing or advertising.
The experiment can be expensive and risky. It may not generate a sufficiently
large number of observations to make reliable estimates of the demand function.
5. Simple regression involves one independent variable, price or advertising in a demand
function, whereas multiple regression involves two or more variables, that is price and
advertising together.
6. A low r2 is an indication that the model is inadequate for explaining the Y
variable. The general causes for this problem are: (a) use of a wrong functional
form, (b) poor choice of an X variable as the predictor, and/or (c) the omission
of some important variable or variables from the model.
7. The t--table value is used (a) to set the prediction range -- upper and lower limits set with
a specified level of confidence (e.g., 95 percent) -- for the predicted value of the
dependent variable, (b) to set the confidence interval for regression coefficients, and (c) as
a cutoff value for the t-test.
8. The standard error of the estimate, Se, is used to set a prediction range for the value of the
dependent variable with varying degrees of confidence, while the standard error of the
regression coefficient, Sb, gives an estimate of the range where the true coefficient will
"actually" fall.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
a) Based on the method of least squares, we obtain:

70
Advertising Sales
2 2
X Y XY X Y
320 $2,600 832,000 102,400 6,760,000
200 1,500 300,000 40,000 2,250,000
230 2,150 494,500 52,900 4,622,500
240 2,250 540,000 57,600 5,062,500
720 4,700 3,384,000 518,400 22,090,000
560 3,700 2,072,000 313,600 13,690,000
470 3,300 1,551,000 220,900 10,890,000
750 4,750 3,562,500 562,500 22,562,500
3,490 24,950 12,736,000 1,868,300 87,927,500

From the table:


n = 8 ∑X = 3,490 ∑Y = 24,950 ∑XY = 12,736,000 ∑X2 = 1,868,300
Substituting these values into the formula for b first:

n∑XY - (∑X)(∑Y) (8)(12,736,000) - (3,490)(24,950)


b= -------------------- = ------------------------------------ = $5.35
2 2 2
n∑X - (∑X) (8)(1,868,300) - (3,490)

a = (∑Y/n) - b (∑X/n) = 24,950/8 - (5.35)(3,490/8) = 3,119 - 2,334 = $785


Thus, the regression model is $785 + $5.35 X

b)
2 2
r = [(8)(12,736,000) - (3,490)(24,950)]
2 2
[ (8)(1,868,300) - (3,490) ][(8)(87,927,500) - (24,950) ]

= 0.9801 = 98.01%
c) Advertising was an excellent choice in explaining the behavior of sales as the high r-
squared indicated: 98.01 percent of the total change in sales was explained by advertising
alone. Only 1.99 percent was due to chance.

2.
a)
b= (100)(1,613) - (1,239)(79) = 63,419 = 0.3218
(100)(17,322) - (1,239)(1,239) 197,079

a= 79 - (0.3218) 1,239 = -3.1971


100 100

Therefore, the estimated relationship between annual income and savings is:
-$3.1971 + $0.3218 per dollar of annual income

71
b) The b value, $0.3218, means that an average family saves about $0.32 for every dollar they
earn annually. The intercept value a (-3.1971) means that an average family has an
annual debt of $3,197.10.

c)
2 2
r = (63,419)
(197,079)[(100)(293) - (79)(79)]
2
= (63,419) = 0.885
(197,079)(23,059)
d)

293 - (-3.1971)(79) - (0.3218)(1,613)


Se =
100 - 2

= 0.520

e)

1 (X p − X) 2
Y' ± (1.98)( (0.52) 1 + +
n (∑ X) 2
∑ X2 - n

3.
a) Q = 616.13 – 256.15P
b) r2 = 83.33%, which means the total variation in quantity demand is explained by
price alone. The remaining 16.67% is still unexplained.
c) At P = $1, Q = 616.13 – 256.15P = 616.13 – 256.15($1) = 359.98

% change in Q dQ P
ePc= ---------------- = ------ . ----- = (-256.15)(1/359.98) = 0.71 < 1.
% change in P dP Q

The product is not sensitive to price change.


d) The intervals are b + t Sb = -256.15 + (2.306) (40.512) = -256.15 + 93.42.
The range then is -349.57 to -162.73
e) The t-value = -6.32, which is greater than 2 (in absolute value). The regression
coefficient is statistically significant.
f) The addition of advertising or income may improve the estimated demand
relationship.

72
CHAPTER 5
ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS FORECASTING

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Explain a naive model.


2. List the principles involved in the Delphi method.
3. Compute a moving average.
4. Explain exponential smoothing.
5. Identify and articulate the process of trend analysis.
6. Compute the mean squared error (MSE).
7. Articulate barometric forecasting.
8. Identify and give examples of an econometric model.
9. Calculate and implement input-output analysis.
10. Illustrate and discuss equilibrium.

Management typically operates under conditions of uncertainty or risk. Probably the


most important function of business is forecasting. A forecast is a starting point for planning.
The objective of forecasting is to reduce risk in decision making. In business, forecasts are the
basis for capacity planning, production and inventory planning, manpower planning, planning
for sales and market share, financial planning and budgeting, planning for research and
development, and top management's strategic planning. Sales forecasts are especially crucial
aspects of many financial management activities, including budgets, profit planning, capital
expenditure analysis, and acquisition and merger analysis.

Figure 1 illustrates how sales forecasts relate to various managerial functions of


business.

FIGURE 1
SALES FORECASTS AND MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS

73
WHO USES FORECASTS?
Forecasts are needed for marketing, production, purchasing, manpower, and financial
planning. Further, top management needs forecasts for planning and implementing long-term
strategic objectives and planning for capital expenditures. More specifically, marketing
managers use sales forecasts to determine (1) optimal sales force allocations, (2) set sales
goals, and (3) plan promotions and advertising. Other things such as market share, prices,
and trends in new product development are required.

Production planners need forecasts in order to (a) schedule production activities, (b)
order materials, (c) establish inventory levels, and (d) plan shipments. Some other areas which
need forecasts include material requirements (purchasing and procurement), labor scheduling,
equipment purchases, maintenance requirements, and plant capacity planning.

As shown in Figure 1, as soon as the company makes sure that it has enough capacity,
the production plan is developed. If the company does not have enough capacity, it will
require planning and budgeting decisions for capital spending for capacity expansion.
On this basis, the financial manager must estimate the future cash inflow and outflow.
He must plan cash and borrowing needs for the company's future operations. Forecasts of
cash flows and the rates of expenses and revenues are needed to maintain corporate liquidity
and operating efficiency. In planning for capital investments, predictions about future
economic activity are required so that returns or cash inflows accruing from the investment
may be estimated.

Forecasts must also be made of money and credit conditions and interest rates so that
the cash needs of the firm may be met at the lowest possible cost. The finance and accounting
functions must also forecast interest rates to support the acquisition of new capital, the
collection of accounts receivable to help in planning working capital needs, and capital
equipment expenditure rates to help balance the flow of funds in the organization. Sound

74
predictions of foreign exchange rates are increasingly important to financial managers of
multinational companies (MNCs).

Long-term forecasts are needed for the planning of changes in the company's capital
structure. Decisions as to whether to issue stock or debt in order to maintain the desired
financial structure of the firm require forecasts of money and credit conditions.
The personnel department requires a number of forecasts in planning for human
resources in the business. Workers must be hired and trained, and for these personnel there
must be benefits provided that are competitive with those available in the firm's labor market.
Also, trends that affect such variables as labor turnover, retirement age, absenteeism, and
tardiness need to be forecast as input for planning and decision making in this function.
Service businesses, such as banks, insurance companies, restaurants, and cruiseships,
need various projections for their operational and long-term strategic planning. Take a bank,
for example. The bank has to forecast:
.Demands of various loans and deposits
. Money and credit conditions so that it can determine the cost of money it lends

TYPES OF FORECASTS
The types of forecasts used by businesses and other organizations may be classified in
several categories, depending on the objective and the situation for which a forecast is to be
used. Three types are discussed below.

SALES FORECASTS
The sales forecast gives the expected level of sales for the company's goods or
services throughout some future period and is instrumental in the company's planning and
budgeting functions. It is the key to other forecasts and plans.

FINANCIAL FORECASTS
Although the sales forecast is the primary input to many financial decisions, some
financial forecasts need to be made independently of sales forecasts.

ECONOMIC FORECASTS
Economic forecasts, or statements of expected future business conditions, are
published by governmental agencies and private economic forecasting firms. Businesses can
use these forecasts and develop their own forecasts about external business conditions that
will affect their product demand. Economic forecasts cover a variety of topics including GDP,
levels of employment, interest rates, and foreign exchange rates.

FORECASTING METHODOLOGY
There is a wide range of forecasting techniques which the company may choose from.
There are basically three approaches to forecasting: qualitative, quantitative, and methods
used for economic forecasting. They are as follows:

1. Qualitative approach - forecasts based on judgment and opinion.


.Executive opinions

75
.Delphi technique
.Sales force polling
.Consumer surveys

2. Quantitative approach
.Naive methods
.Moving averages
.Exponential smoothing
.Trend analysis
.Decomposition of time series
.Simple regression
.Multiple regression
3. Economic forecasting methodology
.Barometric forecasting
.Econometric models
.Input-output analysis
.Opinion polling

Quantitative models work superbly as long as little or no systematic change in the


environment takes place. When patterns or relationships do change, by themselves, the
objective models are of little use. It is here where the qualitative approach based on human
judgment is indispensable. Because judgmental forecasting also bases forecasts on
observation of existing trends, they too are subject to a number of shortcomings. The
advantage, however, is that they can identify systematic change more quickly and interpret
better the effect of such change on the future.

SELECTION OF FORECASTING METHOD


The choice of a forecasting technique is significantly influenced by the stage of the
product life cycle, and sometimes by the firm or industry for which a decision is being made.
In the beginning of the product life cycle, relatively small expenditures are made for
research and market investigation. During the first phase of product introduction, these
expenditures start to increase. In the rapid growth stage, considerable amounts of money are
involved in the decisions; therefore a high level of accuracy is desirable. After the product
has entered the maturity stage, the decisions are more routine, involving marketing and
manufacturing. These are important considerations when determining the appropriate sales
forecast technique.

After evaluating the particular stages of the product, and firm and industry life cycles,
a further probe is necessary. Instead of selecting a forecasting technique by using whatever
seems applicable, decision makers should determine what is appropriate. Some of the
techniques are quite simple and rather inexpensive to develop and use, whereas others are
extremely complex, require significant amounts of time to develop, and may be quite
expensive. Some are best suited for short-term projections, whereas others are better prepared
for intermediate- or long-term forecasts.

What technique or techniques to select depends on the following criteria:

76
1. What is the cost associated with developing the forecasting model compared with
potential gains resulting from its use? The choice is one of a benefit-cost trade-off.
2. How complicated are the relationships that are being forecasted?
3. Is it for short-run or long-run purposes?
4. How much accuracy is desired?
5. Is there a minimum tolerance level of errors?
6. How much data are available? Techniques vary in the amount of data they require.

THE QUALITATIVE APPROACH


The qualitative (or judgmental) approach can be useful in formulating short-term
forecasts and also can supplement the projections based on the use of any of the qualitative
methods. Four of the better known qualitative forecasting methods are Executive Opinions,
the Delphi Method, Sales Force Polling, and Consumer Surveys.

EXECUTIVE OPINIONS
The subjective views of executives or experts from sales, production, finance,
purchasing and administration are averaged to generate a forecast about future sales. Usually
this method is used in conjunction with some quantitative method such as trend extrapolation.
The management team modifies the resulting forecast based on their expectations.
The advantage of this approach is that the forecasting is done quickly and easily,
without need of elaborate statistics. Also, the jury of executive opinions may be the only
feasible means of forecasting in the absence of adequate data. The disadvantage, however, is
that of "group think." This is a set of problems inherent to those who meet as a group.
Foremost among these problems are high cohesiveness, strong leadership, and insulation of
the group. With high cohesiveness, the group becomes increasingly conforming through
group pressure which helps stifle dissension and critical thought. Strong leadership fosters
group pressure for unanimous opinion. Insulation of the group tends to separate the group
from outside opinions, if given.

THE DELPHI METHOD


It is a group technique in which a panel of experts are individually questioned about
their perceptions of future events. The experts do not meet as a group in order to reduce the
possibility that consensus is reached because of dominant personality factors. Instead, the
forecasts and accompanying arguments are summarized by an outside party and returned to
the experts along with further questions. This continues until a consensus is reached by the
group, especially after only a few rounds. This type of method is useful and quite effective for
long-range forecasting.The technique is done by "questionnaire" format and thus it eliminates
the disadvantages of group think. There is no committee or debate. The experts are not
influenced by peer pressure to forecast a certain way, as the answer is not intended to be
reached by consensus or unanimity. Low reliability is cited as the main disadvantage of the
Delphi Method, as well as lack of consensus from the returns.

SALES-FORCE POLLING
Some companies use as a forecast source sales people who have continual contacts
with customers. They believe that the sales force who are closest to the ultimate customers
may have significant insights regarding the state of the future market. Forecasts based on

77
sales-force polling may be averaged to develop a future forecast. Or they may be used to
modify other quantitative and/or qualitative forecasts that have been generated internally in
the company. The advantages to this way of forecast are that (1) it is simple to use and
understand, (2) it uses the specialized knowledge of those closest to the action, (3) it can place
responsibility for attaining the forecast in the hands of those who most affect the actual
results, and (4) the information can be easily broken down by territory, product, customer or
salesperson.
The disadvantages include salespeople being overly optimistic or pessimistic
regarding their predictions, and inaccuracies due to broader economic events that are largely
beyond their control.

CONSUMER SURVEYS
Some companies conduct their own market surveys regarding specific consumer
purchases. Surveys may consist of telephone contacts, personal interviews, or questionnaires
as a means of obtaining data. Extensive statistical analysis is usually applied to survey results
in order to test hypotheses regarding consumer behavior.

NAIVE MODELS, MOVING AVERAGES, AND SMOOTHING METHODS


This section discusses several forecasting methods that fall in the quantitative (time-
series) approach category. Time-series methods use historical data as the basis for projection.
The discussion includes naive models, moving averages, exponential smoothing, and time
series. Regressions were covered in the previous chapter.

NAIVE MODELS
Naive forecasting models are based exclusively on historical observation of sales or
other variables such as earnings and cash flows being forecast. They do not attempt to explain
the
underlying causal relationships which produce the variable being forecast.
Naive models may be classified into two groups. One group consists of simple
projection models. These models require inputs of data from recent observations, but no
statistical analysis is performed. The second group is made up of models, which while naive,
are complex enough to require a computer. Traditional methods such as classical
decomposition, moving average, and exponential smoothing models are some examples.

Advantages: It is inexpensive to develop, store data, and operate.


Disadvantages: It does not consider any possible causal relationships that underlie the
forecasted variable.

1. A simplest example of a naive model type would be to use the actual sales of the
current period as the forecast for the next period. Let us use the symbol Y't+1 as the forecast
value and the symbol Yt as the actual value. Then, Y't+1 = Yt
2. If you consider trends, then Y't+1 = Yt + (Yt - Yt-1)
This model adds the latest observed absolute period-to-period change to the most recent
observed level of the variable.
3. If you want to incorporate the rate of change rather than the absolute amount, then

78
Yt
Y't+1 = Yt -----
Yt-1

EXAMPLE 1
Consider the following sales data:

20X1
Month Monthly Sales of Product
1 $3,050
2 2,980
3 3,670
4 2,910
5 3,340
6 4,060
7 4,750
8 5,510
9 5,280
10 5,504
11 5,810
12 6,100

We will develop forecasts for January 20X2 based on the aforementioned three models:
1. Y't+1 = Yt = $6,100
2. Y't+1 = Yt + (Yt - Yt-1) = $6,100 + ($6,100 - $5,810) = $6,100 + $290 = $6,390

3. Yt
Y't+1 = Yt ------
Yt-1

$6,100
= $6,100 x -------- = $6,100 (1.05)
$5,810

= $6,405

NOTE:
The naive models can be applied, with very little need of a computer, to develop
forecasts for sales, earnings, and cash flows. They must be compared with more sophisticated
models such as the regression method for forecasting efficiency.

79
MOVING AVERAGES
Moving averages are averages that are updated as new information is received. With
the moving average, a manager simply employs the most recent observations to calculate an
average, which is used as the forecast for the next period.

EXAMPLE 2
Assume that the marketing manager has the following sales data.

Date Actual Sales (Yt)


Jan. 1 46
2 54
3 53
4 46
5 58
6 49
7 54

In order to predict the sales for the seventh and eighth days of January, the manager
has to pick the number of observations for averaging purposes. Let us consider two cases:
one is a six-day moving average and the other is a three-day average (See Figure 2).

Case 1

46 + 54 + 53 + 46 + 58 + 49
Y'7 = 6 = 51

54 + 53 + 46 + 58 + 49 + 54
Y'8 = 6 = 52.3

where Y' = predicted

Case 2

46 + 58 + 49
Y'7 = 3 = 51

58 + 49 + 54
Y'8 = 3 = 53.6

In terms of weights given to observations, in case 1, the old data received a weight of
5/6, and the current observation got a weight of 1/6. In case 2, the old data received a weight
of only 2/3 while the current observation received a weight of 1/3.

80
Thus, the marketing manager's choice of the number of periods to use in a moving
average is a measure of the relative importance attached to old versus current data.

FIGURE 2

MOVING AVERAGE CALCULATIONS

Advantages and Disadvantages

The moving average is simple to use and easy to understand. However, there are two
shortcomings.
-It requires you to retain a great deal of data and carry it along with you from forecast period
to forecast period.
-All data in the sample are weighted equally. If more recent data are more valid than older
data, why not give it greater weight?
The forecasting method known as exponential smoothing gets around these
disadvantages.

EXPONENTIAL SMOOTHING
Exponential smoothing is a popular technique for short-run forecasting by financial
managers. It uses a weighted average of past data as the basis for a forecast. The procedure
gives heaviest weight to more recent information and smaller weights to observations in the

81
more distant past. The reason for this is that the future is more dependent upon the recent past
than on the distant past. The method is known to be effective when there is randomness and
no seasonal fluctuations in the data. One disadvantage of the method, however, is that it does
not include industrial or economic factors such as market conditions, prices, or the effects of
competitors' actions.

NOTE:
Exponential smoothing is known to be effective when there is randomness and no
seasonal fluctuations in the data.

THE MODEL:
The formula for exponential smoothing is:

Y't+1 = αYt + ( 1 - α ) Y't

or in words,

Y'new = αY old + (1 - α ) Y'old

where Y'new = Exponentially smoothed average to be used as the forecast.


Yold = Most recent actual data.
Y'old = Most recent smoothed forecast.
α = Smoothing constant.
The higher the α, the higher the weight given to the more recent information.

EXAMPLE 3

The following data on sales are given below.

Time period (t) Actual sales (1000)(Yt)


1 $60.0
2 64.0
3 58.0
4 66.0
5 70.0
6 60.0
7 70.0
8 74.0
9 62.0
10 74.0
11 68.0
12 66.0
13 60.0
14 66.0

82
15 62.0

To initialize the exponential smoothing process, we must have the initial forecast. The first
smoothed forecast to be used can be
1. First actual observations.
2. An average of the actual data for a few periods

For illustrative purposes, let us use a six-period average as the initial forecast Y'7 with a
smoothing constant of α = 0.40.

Then Y'7 = (Y1 + Y2 + Y3+ Y4 + Y5 + Y6)/6


= (60 + 64 + 58 + 66 + 70 + 60)/6 = 63

Note that Y7 = 70. Then Y'8 is computed as follows:

Y'8 = αY7 + (1 - α) Y'7


= (0.40)(70) + (0.60)(63)
= 28.0 + 37.80 = 65.80

Similarly,

Y'9 = αY8 + (1 - α) Y'8


= (0.40)(74) + (0.60)(65.80)
= 29.60 + 39.48 = 69.08

and

Y'10 = αY9 + (1 - α)Y'9


= (0.40)(62) + (0.60)(69.08)
= 24.80 + 41.45 = 66.25

By using the same procedure, the values of Y'11, Y'12, Y'13, Y'14, and Y'15 can be
calculated. The following table shows a comparison between the actual sales and predicted
sales by the exponential smoothing method.

Due to the negative and positive differences between actual sales and predicted sales,
the forecaster can use a higher or lower smoothing constant (α), in order to adjust his/her
prediction as quickly as possible to large fluctuations in the data series. For example, if the
forecast is slow in reacting to increased sales, (that is to say, if the difference is negative),
he/she might want to try a higher value. For practical purposes, the optimal may be picked
by minimizing what is known as the mean squared error (MSE), which is the average sum of
the variations between the historical sales data and the forecast values for the corresponding
periods.

MSE = (Yt - Y't)2/ (n - i)

83
where i = the number of observations used to determine the initial forecast (in our example,
i=6).

TABLE 1
COMPARISON OF ACTUAL SALES AND PREDICTED SALES
2
Predicted Difference Difference
2
Time period (t) Actual sales (Yt) sales (Y't) (Yt - Y't) (Yt - Y't)
1 $60.0
2 64.0
3 58.0
4 66.0
5 70.0
6 60.0
7 70.0 63.00 7.00 49.00
8 74.0 65.80 8.20 67.24
9 62.0 69.08 -7.08 50.13
10 74.0 66.25 7.75 60.06
11 68.0 69.35 -1.35 1.82
12 66.0 68.81 -2.81 7.90
13 60.0 67.69 -7.69 59.14
14 66.0 64.61 1.39 1.93
15 62.0 65.17 -3.17 10.05
307.27

In our example,
MSE = 307.27 / (15 - 6) = 307.27 / 9 = 34.14
The idea is to select the α that minimizes MSE.

TREND ANALYSIS
Trends are the general upward or downward movements of the average over time.
These movements may require many years of data to determine or describe them. They can be
described by a straight line or a curve. The basic forces underlying the trend include
technological advances, productivity changes, inflation, and population change.

Trend analysis is a special type of simple regression. This method involves a


regression whereby a trend line is fitted to a time series of data. In practice, however, one
typically finds linear curves used for business forecasting.

LINEAR TREND
The linear trend line equation can be shown as

Y=a+bt

where t = time.

84
The formula for the coefficients a and b are essentially the same as the cases for
simple regression. However, for regression purposes, a time period can be given a number so
that Σt = 0. When there is an odd number of periods, the period in the middle is assigned a
zero value. If there is an even number, then -1 and +1 are assigned the two periods in the
middle, so that again Σt = 0.
With Σt = 0, the formula for b and a reduces to the following:

n Σ tY
b= 
2
nΣt

ΣY
a= 
n

EXAMPLE 4

Case 1 (odd number)

20X1 20X2 20X3 20X4 20X5


t= -2 -1 0 +1 +2

Case 2 (even number)

20X1 20X2 20X3 20X4 20X5 20X6


t= -3 -2 -1 +1 +2 +3

In each case Σt = 0.

EXAMPLE 5

Consider ABC Company, whose historical sales follows.

Year Sales (in millions)


20X1 $10
20X2 12
20X3 13
20X4 16
20X5 17

Since the company has five years' data, which is an odd number, the year in the
middle is assigned a zero value.

2 2
Year t Sales(in millions)(Y) tY t Y

85
20X1 -2 $ 10 -20 4 100
20X2 -1 12 -12 1 144
20X3 0 13 0 0 169
20X4 +1 16 16 1 256
20X5 +2 17 34 4 289
0 68 18 10 958

(5)(18) 90
b=  =  = 1.8
(5)(10) 50

68
a=  = 13.6
5

Therefore, the estimated trend equation is

Y' = $13.6 + $1.8 t

To project 20X6 sales, we assign +3 to the t value for the year 20X6.

Y' = $13.6 + $1.8 (3)


= $19

ECONOMIC FORECASTING
Economic forecasting is typically concerned with predicting future values of key
economic variables such as gross domestic product, inflation, interest rates, and
unemployment.

BAROMETRIC FORECASTING
Barometric methods involve the use of economic indicators such as leading indicators
to predict turning points in economic activity. It is used primarily to identify potential future
changes in general business conditions or conditions of a specific industry rather than
conditions for a specific firm. The series chosen serve as barometers of economic change.
Types of indicators frequently used are:
1. Coincident indicators: These are the types of economic indicator series that tend to
move up and down in line with the aggregate economy and therefore are measures of current
economic activity. Examples are Gross Domestic Product (GDP), retail sales, and industrial
production.
2. Lagging indicators: These are the economic series of indicators that follow or trail
behind aggregate economic activity. There are currently six lagging indicators published by
the government comprised of unemployment rate, business expenditures, labor cost per unit,
loans outstanding, bank interest rates, and book value of manufacturing and trade inventories.

86
3. Leading indicators: More exactly known as Index of Leading Economic Indicators
(LEI) is the economic series of indicators that tend to predict future changes in economic
activity; officially called Composite Index of 10 Leading Indicators. This index was designed
to reveal the direction of the economy in the next six to nine months. This series is the
government's main barometer for forecasting business trends. Each of the series has shown a
tendency to change before the economy makes a major turn--hence, the term "leading
indicators." The index is designed to forecast economic activity six to nine months ahead
(1987=100).
The Index consists of 10 indicators, and are subject to revision. For example,
petroleum and natural gas prices were found to distort the data from crude material prices and
were subsequently dropped from that category.
The LEI is found in Business Conditions Digest published by the Bureau of
Economic Analysis of the U.S. Department of Commerce. If the index is consistently rising,
even only slightly, the economy is chugging along and a setback is unlikely. If the indicator
drops for three or more consecutive months, look for an economic slowdown and possibly a
recession in the next year or so. A rising (consecutive percentage increases in) indicator is
bullish for the economy and the stock market, and vice versa.

These 10 components of the index are adjusted for inflation. Rarely do these
components of the index all go in the same direction at once. Each factor is weighted. The
composite figure is designed to tell only in which direction business will go. It is not intended
to forecast the magnitude of future ups and downs.

As a further tool and aid to understanding business conditions, a series known as


diffusion indexes are used. Unlike a composite index such as the LEI, a diffusion index
indicates the percentage of economic series that experience increases over the time interval
being measured. Often, the 50 percent mark is used as a guide. For example, if more than 50
percent of the leading indicators are rising, it might be plausible to predict an upturn in
aggregate economic activity. In a more general sense, however, diffusion indexes can be
employed to help measure and interpret the breadth and intensity of recessions and recoveries,
the state of economic conditions, and the degree of optimism or pessimism on the part of
businessmen.

Barometric models have the following limitations:


1. No series accurately signals changes in other economic variables on a consistent
basis.
2. It may still indicate only the direction of future change, little or nothing about the
magnitude of the change.

ECONOMETRIC MODELS
The approach employs statistically based models where relationships among
economic variables are expressed in mathematical equations, single or simultaneous in nature
and then estimated using such techniques as regression methods. The simplest kind of
econometric models would be a single equation, expressing some dependent variable as a
function of some other set of variables. For example, gross domestic product (GDP) might be
expressed as a function of past GDP (GDP-t), construction activity (C), changes in the

87
unemployment rate(∆U), and the level of interest rates (I). A linear model expressing this
relation is:
GDP = a + bGDP-t + cC + d∆U + eI
Some models attempt to capture the complexity of the entire economy; they may
contain hundreds of equations that must all be estimated simultaneously. The Wharton model
is a good example. Multiple equation systems, however, are difficult and expensive to
construct.

INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS
Input-output analysis, also called interindustry analysis is the input-output approach to
forecasting. It employs historical tabular data on intersectional output and material flows to
predict demand and supply changes for individual industries. An input-output matrix table, as
shown in Figure 3, is the source of this method. The table is very useful in evaluating the
effects of a change in demand in one industry on other industries (i.e., a change in oil prices
and its resulting effect on demand for cars, then steel sales, then iron ore and limestone sales).
The total requirements table prepared as a part of the input-output table shows the direct, as
well as indirect, requirements of each industry listed in the left-hand column (supplying
industry) in order to produce one dollar’s worth of output for the industry identified at the top
of each column (producing industry). This table makes it possible to compute the impacts on
various industries in the economy which result from changes in the final demand for products
of one or more industries.

Input-output analysis for forecasting, however, suffers from two major limitations:
1. The development of accurate and updated supplements to the original Commerce
Department input-output table is prohibitively expensive.
2. The method is a linear approach to forecasting and thereby fails to capture some
possible nonlinear relations.

FIGURE 3
INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE

88
OPINION POLLING
This is a qualitative and subjective method of predicting economic activity or some
particular phase of it. The surveys include:
1. Surveys of business executives’ intentions on what to spend on plant and
equipment, made independently by McGraw-Hill, Department of Commerce, Securities and
Exchange Commission, and the Conference Board.
2. Surveys of consumers’ finances, buying plans, and confidence, made independently
by the University of Michigan and the Conference Board.
3. Surveys of business plans regarding inventory changes, made by the National
Association of Purchasing Agents.
The surveys seem to do well in forecasting turning points of business, but are not that
useful for predicting the magnitude of change.

MEASURING ACCURACY OF FORECASTS


The performance of a forecast should be checked against its own record or against that
of other forecasts. There are various statistical measures that can be used to measure
performance of the model. Of course, the performance is measured in terms of forecasting
error, where error is defined as the difference between a predicted value and the actual result.
Error (e) = Actual (A) - Forecast (F)

MEAN SQUARED ERROR (MSE)


One commonly used measure for summarizing historical errors is mean squared errors
discussed earlier.

THE U STATISTIC
There is still a number of statistical measures for measuring accuracy of the forecast.
Two standards may be identified. First, one could compare the forecast being evaluated with a
naive forecast to see if there are vast differences. The naive forecast can be anything like the
same as last year, moving average, or the output of an exponential smoothing technique. In
the second case, the forecast may be compared against the outcome when there is enough to
do so. The comparison may be against the actual level of the variable forecasted, or the
change observed may be compared with the change forecast.

The Theil U Statistic is based upon a comparison of the predicted change with the
observed change. It is calculated as:

U = 1/n Σ (F - A)2 / (1/n)Σ F2 + (1/n)Σ A2

As can be seen, U=0 is a perfect forecast, since the forecast would equal actual and
F - A = 0 for all observations. At the other extreme, U=1 would be a case of all incorrect
forecasts. The smaller the value of U, the more accurate are the forecasts. If U is greater than
or equal to 1, the predictive ability of the model is lower than a naive no-change
extrapolation.

89
QUESTIONS
1. Discuss the difference between quantitative and qualitative (judgmental)
forecasting methods. What circumstances would warrant one over the other?
2. Discuss the role of forecasting in production/operations management.
3. Illustrate, by examples of typical applications, the various types of qualitative
forecasting techniques often used.
4. Define a time series.
5. How are moving averages calculated?
6. What is exponential smoothing and when it is most effective?
7. Explain the two popular measures of forecast accuracy.
8. What are the basic steps in forecasting? Discuss each.
9. How are quantitative and judgmental forecasts used together in practice?

PROBLEMS

1. Develop a forecast for the next period, given the data below, using a 3-period moving
average,

Period Demand(Yt)
1 19
2 20
3 18
4 19
5 17

2. Consider the data below:

Period Demand(Yt)
11 81
12 75
13 82

(a) Determine a naive forecast for period 14.

(b) Using exponential smoothing with α =.2 and exponentially smoothed forecast for
period 12 = 80, what would the forecast for period 14 be?

3. Given the data below, make an appropriate forecast for the following year, using a linear
trend line.

Period Demand(Yt)
1 110
2 110

90
3 120
4 140
5 150

4. The AZ Ice Cream Shoppe has recorded the demand for a particular flavor during the first
seven days of August.

Date Actual Sales (Yt)


Aug. 1 56
2 64
3 63
4 56
5 68
6 59
7 64

Predict the sales for the eighth day of August, using (a) a five-day moving average and (b) a
three-day average.

5. Develop a forecast for period 6 using an alpha of .4 and period 1 value as the initial
forecast.

Period Number of customer complaints


1 45
2 34
3 35
4 42
5 48

6. The following time series shows the sales of a particular product over the past 12
months:

Month Sales
1 105
2 135
3 120
4 105
5 90
6 120
7 145
8 140
9 100
10 80
11 100
12 110

91
Compute the exponential-smoothing values for the time series and MSE (Assume α
= .5).

7. Data for total cash collections and credit sales are given below.

Cash collections Credit sales


(000) omitted) (000 omitted)
4 6
8 7
8 9
6 5
7 8
5 6
a) Fit a linear regression line using the method of least squares. Estimate the cash
collections when credit sales is $8.
b) Compute the coefficient of determination.
c) Does the regression equation need to be improved?

8. The Viacam Manufacturing Company makes a product called Zone. Some of the
manufacturing expenses are easily identified as fixed or directly variable with production.
Management is confronted with the problem of preparing a budget for the indirect
manufacturing costs. The following details are provided for the first 5 months of the past year:

Number of Units Indirect Manufacturing


Month Produced X Costs Y
1 100 $1,000
2 200 1,250
3 300 2,250
4 400 2,500
5 500 3,750

Determine the cost function using the method of least squares.

9. A consumer product maker’s marketing manager has developed a linear trend equation
that can be used to forecast annual sales of its popular SH shampoo:

Y =17,500 + 23,000t

(fitted using the data covering the period 1998 - 2004)

a) Are annual sales increasing or decreasing? By how much?


b) Predict sales for 2005 (Assume the t value assigned for 2001 is zero).

10. The Hume Company, Inc. has recorded the following sales (000 omitted) since its
inception in 19M2:

92
19M2 $10 19M8 $125
19M3 20 19M9 150
19M4 30 20N0 180
19M5 45 20N1 220
19M6 70 20N2 270
19M7 90

a) Calculate 20N3 sales, using the method of least squares.


b) Compute the coefficient of determination.
c) Comment on the reliability of the estimated sales equation, together with the
necessary assumptions if the estimated equation is to be used to predict sales.

ANSWERS
1. Quantitative methods are based on the analysis of historical data while qualitative
(judgmental) methods depend on expert opinion. Obviously if historical data is
unavailable, quantitative cannot be used. Such would be the case with technology
forecasts. For such data as sales and costs, quantitative approaches are useful. Quite
frequently a combination of the two is used.
2. Forecasts are needed in order to (a) plan resource requirements such as production
facilities, (b) work force levels and planning purchases of materials, and (c) for financial
planning and capacity planning.
3. Expert opinion - new technologies or new products unlike any currently on the market.
Delphi method - space travel, long range economic conditions.
Sales polling or consumer surveys - new products, restaurants, fast food, consumer
appliances.
4. A time series is a set of observations measured at successive points in time or over
successive periods of time.
5. A moving average is an average of the most recent n data values for any point in time.
6. Exponential smoothing is a weighting of the current actual value and the previous
forecast. As such, it is essentially a weighted average of the previous time series values
with more emphasis placed on the most recent observations. It is known to be effective
when there is randomness and no seasonal fluctuations in the data.
7. Forecast errors are measured by mean absolute deviation (MAD) and mean squared
error (MSE). These enable one to quantitatively measure forecast errors.
8. Since quantitative methods are slow to adapt to unexpected changes in the
environment, qualitative (judgmental) forecasts are often also used. Quantitative forecasts
are frequently modified by judgmental forecasts.
9. (a) Preliminary data analysis of scatter diagram. (b) determination of forecasts choice
of method: quantitative and/or judgmental. (c) evaluation and determination of a final
forecast - consideration of accuracy and implications of errors, data collection and
processing. (d) control and feedback - comparison of actual observations with forecasts.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1. (18+19+17)/3 = 18
2.
(a) Naive: 82

93
(b) Y'13 = αY12 + (1 - α) Y'12=(0.2)(75) + (0.8)(80) = 79
Y'14 = αY13 + (1 - α) Y'13 = (0.20)(82) + (0.80)(79) = 16.4 + 63.2 = 79.6

3.
2
Time t Demand Y tY t
1 -2 110 -220 4
2 -1 110 -110 1
3 0 120 0 0
4 1 140 140 1
5 2 150 300 4
0 630 110 10

b = 5(110)/5(10) = 11
a = 630/5 =126
Y = 126 + 11 t = 126 + 11(3) = 159 (For period 6, t = 3)

4.

(a) using a five-day moving average

63 + 56 + 68 + 59 + 64
Y'8 = 5 = 62

where Y' = predicted

(b) Using a three-day average.

68 + 59 + 64
Y'8 = 3 = 63.6

5.

Period Number of Forecast = Y't+1 = αYt + ( 1 - α ) Y't


customer complaints
1 45
2 34 45
3 35 .4(34)+.6(45)=40.6
4 42 .4(35)+.6(40.6)=38.4
5 48 .4(42)+.6(38.4)=39.8

For period 6: .4(48)+.6(39.8) =43.1

94
6.

Error
Month Sales Forecast Error Squared
1 105
2 135 105 30 900
3 120 .5(135)+.5(105)=120 0 0
4 105 .5(120)+.5(120)=120 -15 225
5 90 .5(105)+.5(120)=112.50 -22.5 506.25
6 120 .5( 90)+.5(112.5)=101.25 18.75 351.56
7 145 .5(120)+.5(101.25)=110.63 34.37 1181.30
8 140 .5(145)+.5(110.63)=127.81 12.19 148.60
9 100 .5(140)+.5(127.81)=133.91 -33.91 1149.89
10 80 .5(100)+.5(133.91)=116.95 -36.95 1365.30
11 100 .5( 80)+.5(116.95)= 98.48 1.52 2.31
12 110 .5(100)+.5( 98.48)= 99.24 10.76 115.78
5945.99
2
MSE = Σ e / (n - 1)= 5945.99/(12 -1) = 540.54

7.
a)
2 2
Y X XY X Y
4 6 24 36 16
8 7 56 49 64
8 9 72 81 64
6 5 30 25 36
7 8 56 64 49
5 6 30 36 25
$38 41 268 291 254

b= (6)(268) - (41)(38) = 50 = 0.77


(6)(291) - (41)(41) 65

a= 38/6 - (0.77)(41/6) = 1.07

The estimated regression equation is

Y' = $1.07 + $0.77X

where Y' = estimated cash collections and X = credit sales

95
The estimated cash collection for credit sales of $8 will be

Y' = $1.07 + $0.77(8) = $7.23

b)
2 2
r = (50) = = 2,500 = 0.48
2
(65)[(6)(254)-(38) ] 5,200

= 48%

which means that the credit sales account for only 48 percent of the change in cash collections.
2
c) The answer is yes. A low r (48 percent) indicates that credit sales was not good enough to fully
explain the behavior of cash collections. 52 percent is still unexplained by the estimated equation.
Often factors like interest rates may be responsible for part of the variation in cash collections.

8.
2
X Y XY X
100 $1,000 $ 100,000 10,000
200 1,250 250,000 40,000
300 2,250 675,000 90,000
400 2,500 1,000,000 160,000
500 3,750 1,875,000 250,000
1,500 10,750 3,900,000 550,000

From the table:


2
n = 5 ∑X = 1,500 ∑Y = 10,750 ∑XY = 3,900,000 ∑X = 550,000

Substituting these values into the formula for b first:

n∑XY - (∑X)(∑Y) (5)(3,900,000) - (1,500)(10,750) 3,375,000


b= ----------------- = ------------------------------- = ---------
2 2 2
n∑X - (∑X) (5)(550,000) - (1,500) 500,000

= 6.75
a = (∑Y/n) - b (∑X/n) = 10,750/5 - (6.75)(1,500/5) = $125

Thus, the regression equation is $125 + $6.75 X

9.

96
(a) Annual sales are increasing by $23,000 per year.

(b) Note that the t value for the year 2005 is 4. Hence, Y = 17,500 + 23,000 (4) = $109,500.

10.
a) For regression purposes, a year can be given a number so that the ΣX = 0. Since the company
has 11 years data, which is an odd number, the year in the middle is assigned a zero value.

Sales Y
2 2
Year X (000 omitted) XY X Y
19M2 -5 $ 10 -50 25 100
19M3 -4 $ 20 -80 16 400
19M4 -3 $ 30 -90 9 900
19M5 -2 $ 45 -90 4 2,025
19M6 -1 $ 70 -70 1 4,900
19M7 0 $ 90 0 0 8,100
19M8 +1 $ 125 125 1 15,625
19M9 +2 $ 150 300 4 22,500
20N0 +3 $ 180 540 9 32,400
20N1 +4 $ 220 880 16 48,400
20N2 +5 $ 270 1,350 25 72,900
0 $1,210 2,815 110 208,250

b= (11)(2,815) = 30,965 = $25.59


(11)(110) 1,210

a= 1,210 = $110
11

Therefore, the estimated equation is:

Y' = $110 + $25.59X

where Y' = estimated sales and X = year index value.

To calculate 20N3 sales, we assign +6 to the X value for the year 20N3.

Thus, Y' = $110 + $25.59(+6) = $263.54.

b)
2 2
r = (30,965) = 0.958
2
(1,210)[(11)(208,250) - (1,210) ]
2
c) The high r (0.958) ensures that annual sales shows an increasing trend.
97
CHAPTER 6
THEORY OF PRODUCTION

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Interpret and explain the returns to scale.


2. Explain and illustrate the production function.
3. Give examples of the linear production function.
4. Identify and explain the Leontief production function.
5. Demonstrate the Cobb-Douglas production.
6. Compute the total product.
7. Calculate and explain the average product.
8. Demonstrate and discuss marginal product.
9. Illustrate the marginal revenue product.
10. Express and illustrate the marginal rate of technical substitution.
11. Demonstrate the concept of output elasticity.
12. Explain and give example of the optimal employment rule.

Management’s production decision problems may be considered to fall into the


following four types:

1. How much, in total, shall be spent on the purchase of inputs?


2. How shall this amount be divided among the various types of inputs?
3. How much of each type of input will be allocated to each type of output?
4. How much of each final product shall the firm produce?

PRODUCTION FUNCTION
The production function is an engineering relation that defines the maximum
amount of output that can be produced with a given set of inputs. Mathematically, the
production function is denoted as:
Q = F(L, K)
where Q = the maximum amount of output, K = capital , and L = labor. The function can
take many different forms.

LINEAR PRODUCTION FUNCTION


The linear production function assumes a perfect linear relationship between all
inputs and total output:
Q = aK + bL

EXAMPLE 1
Given Q = 3K + 4L, if 9 units of capital and 4 units of labor are employed, the

98
total output will be 43 units: Q = 3(9) + 4(4) = 43.

LEONTIEF PRODUCTION FUNCTION


Also called the fixed-proportions production function, the Leontief production
function assumes that inputs are used in fixed proportions. It is given by
Q = min {aK , bL}

EXAMPLE 2
Given Q = min {3K ,4 L} , if 5 units of capital and 4 units of labor are employed,
the total output will be 15 units: Q = min {3(5),4(4)} = min {15,16} = 15. Note the
minimum of the numbers “15” and “16” is 15.

COBB-DOUGLAS PRODUCTION FUNCTION


The Cobb-Douglas production function is between the extremes of the linear
production function and the Leontief production function. Unlike the linear function, the
relationship between output and the inputs is not linear. Unlike the Leontief function,
inputs need not be used in fixed proportions. The form is:
Q = K a Lb .

EXAMPLE 3
Given Q = K 1/2 L1/2 , if 9 units of capital and 4 units of labor are employed, the
total output will be 6 units: Q = (9)1/2 (4)1/2 = (3)(2) = 6.

NOTE:
There are many other forms for production function, including constant elasticity
of substitution (CES) function, which is not covered here.

MEASURES OF PRODUCTIVITY
A useful consideration that needs to be taken into account in business decision making is
the determination of the productivity of inputs in the production process. Productivity measures are
useful for evaluating the efficiency of a production process and in making input decisions that yield
maximum profits. The three important measures of productivity are total product, average product,
and marginal product.

TOTAL PRODUCT
Total product (TP) is the maximum level of output that can be obtained with given inputs.

EXAMPLE 4
A garage door maker has the following production function:
Q = .2K 2 + .3KL + .4L2
Assume a weekly rate of use where L = 100 labor hours and K = 30 machine hours. The
total product per week is Q = .2(30)2 + .3(30)(100) + .4(100)2 = 180 + 900 + 4,000 =
5,080 units.

99
AVERAGE PRODUCT
The average product (AP) is the total amount of output divided by the amount of the input
used to produce a given amount of output. The average product of labor (APL) is equal to total
product (TP) divided by the amount of labor (L) used in the production of output (Q):
APL = Q/L.
Similarly, the average product of capital (APK) is:
APK = Q/K

EXAMPLE 5
From Example 4: Q = .2K 2 + .3KL + .4L2 and L = 100 labor hours and K = 30
machine hours.

APL = Q/L = .2K 2 /L + .3K + .4L = .2(30)2 /100 + .3(30) + .4(100) = 180 + 9 + 40 = 229
units.
APK = Q/K =.2K + .3 L + .4L2 /K = .2(30) + .3(100) + .4(100)2 /(30) = 6 + 30 + 133.33 =
169.33 units.

MARGINAL PRODUCT
The marginal product (MP) of an input is the change in the quantity of output resulting from
a one unit change in the quantity of input used. Thus, the marginal product of labor (MPL) is
∆Q/∆L = dQ/dL
and the marginal product of capital (MPK) is
∆Q/∆K= dQ/dK

EXAMPLE 6
From Example 4: Q = .2K 2 + .3KL + .4L2

MP L = ∂ Q/ ∂ L = .3K + .8L = .3(30) + .8(100) = 89


MP K = ∂Q/ ∂ K = .4K + .3L = .4(30) + .3(100) = 42

RELATIONSHIP AMONG TOTAL PRODUCT, MARGINAL PRODUCT, AND AVERAGE


PRODUCT.
The profit-oriented firm is deeply interested in how its output will vary with respect to the
quantity used of an input. The reason is that such information is essential for determining the profit-
maximizing level of output. Figure 1 shows graphically the relationship among total product,
marginal product, and average product. We observe that
a) As the usage of an input increases, MP initially increases (increasing marginal returns),
then begins to decline (decreasing marginal returns), and eventually becomes negative
(negative marginal returns).
b) AP increases when MP > AP; otherwise, MP<AP.

From 0 to 3 units of variable input, the quantity of output increases at an

100
increasing rate and the MP function is rising. Such behavior of output denotes increasing
returns to input. Diminishing marginal returns begin at point A. Between 3 and 7 units of
variable input, output increases at a decreasing rate. Because MP is a positive yet
diminishing value, this portion of the production function reflects decreasing returns to
input. Output is maximum at 7 units of input and MP, being equal to the slope of the
production function, is zero. Beyond 7 units of input, input is present in uneconomic
proportions relative to the available fixed input; the marginal products of additional units
of input are negative and negative returns to input are encountered. The AP of input
reaches its maximum value at that point where a ray drawn from the origin is just tangent
to the production function. The MP function passes through the apex of the AP product
function.

FIGURE 1
GRAPHICAL RELATIONSHIP AMONG
TOTAL PRODUCT, MARGINAL PRODUCT, AND AVERAGE PRODUCT

MARGINAL REVENUE PRODUCT


Marginal revenue product (MRP) is the net addition to total revenue attributable to the
addition of one unit of the variable productive service or the dollar value of the marginal product
101
(MP) of an input. The marginal revenue product (MRP) of an input is equal to MP multiplied by the
MR of the commodity.

OPTIMAL EMPLOYMENT RULE


A profit-maximizing firm will employ units of a variable productive service until the point is
reached at which the MRP of an input is exactly equal to the input price.
Marginal revenue product of the input (MRP i ) = Price of an input (P i )
For example, an optimal employment rule is:
Marginal revenue product of labor (MRP L) = price of labor (w),
assuming that the firm is a wage-taker.

NOTE:
We defined profit maximization as requiring that MR = MC. This was looking at the matter
from the output side. From the input side, we note MRP = P. The two rules are logically identical.
They are simply different ways of stating the maximum-profit condition.

ISOQUANT
Also known as producers' indifference curve, or isoproduct curve, an isoquant curve traces
out the combinations of any two or more inputs which give rise to the same level of output (see
Figure 2). These combinations must be the most efficient ones (i.e. any point on an isoproduct
curve shows the minimum quantities of the inputs needed to produce the given output). Isoproduct
curves are typically drawn as being convex to the origin because of the assumed substitutability of
inputs.

MARGINAL RATE OF TECHNICAL SUBSTITUTION


Marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) is the rate that measures the reduction in one
input per unit increase in the other that is just sufficient to maintain a constant level of output. The
marginal rate of technical substitution of labor and capital (MRTSLK) at a point on an isoquant is
equal to the absolute value of the slope of the isoquant at that point. It is also equal to the ratio of the
marginal products:
MRTSLK = MPK/MPL

FIGURE 2
ISOQUANTS

102
SUBSTITUTABILITY OF INPUTS
There are three general types of shapes of an isoquant, as shown in Figure 3. In
panel (a), the isoquants are right angles indicating that inputs a and b are not
substitutable (or perfect complements). In this case one particular combination of inputs
is required to produce a specified level of output. Output cannot rise without increased
quantities of both inputs. An example of this would be tires and a battery for an
automobile. In this case, the MRTS will be zero, since when an additional unit of input a
is used, there is no amount of input b that can be given up if a given level of output is to
be maintained.

The other extreme case is where inputs a and b are perfect substitutes, as shown in
panel (b). In this case inputs can be substituted for each other at a fixed rate while the
firm maintains the same level of output. The isoquant will be a straight line and have a
constant slope and MRTS . Natural gas and fuel oil are considered close substitutes in
energy production.
Panel (c) depicts, however, the most common case where inputs are imperfect
substitutes. They can be substituted for each other at changing rates. In other words, the
rate at which one input can be given up in return for one more unit of another input while
maintaining the same level of output diminishes as the amount of input a being used
increases. That is, the MRTS diminishes. In general, capital and labor are imperfect
substitutes.

NOTE:
The choice of which input combination to use is easy in the first two cases -panel
(a) and (b). In the first case, no input combination decision can be made. In the second
case, the decision is in favor of cheaper input. We tend to concentrate our discussion on
the case of inputs that are imperfect substitutes whose MRTS is diminishing.
103
THE STAGES OF PRODUCTION
Typically, there are three stages of production of special significance for analyzing the
efficiency with which resource inputs are used (See Figure 4). A production function that exhibits
the qualities of increasing, decreasing, and negative returns can be separated into three stages. Stage
I covers the entire range of increasing returns to variable input and the point of diminishing
marginal returns (DMR) is reached (Point A) and passed. It ends when the point of diminishing
average return (DAR) is reached (point B). Stage II covers the portion where the quantity of output
rises at a decreasing rate; accordingly, the marginal product (MP) of variable input is declining,
although it is still positive. Stage III coincides with the range of input where additional usage of
variable inputs is associated with the decline in output but MP is negative.

FIGURE 3
SUBSTITUTABILITY OF INPUTS

104
105
FIGURE 4
THREE STAGES OF PRODUCTION

ISOCOST CURVE
An isocost curve is a curve or line showing the combinations of any inputs (e.g., labor and
capital) that can be bought with a fixed sum of money. It is analogous with the consumer's budget
line, but relates to the firm's purchase of inputs. The total cost of inputs are:

wL + rK = C

where w = the wage rate (the price of labor) and r = interest rate (the price of capital). This equation
can be converted into the formula for an isocost line as follows:
K = C/r - (w/r)L
106
Thus, along an isocost line, K is a linear function of L with a vertical intercept of C/r and a slope of -
w/r. The varying values of C will create isocost lines that are parallel to each other.

EXPANSION PATH
An expansion path is a graphical device used to illustrate the amount of capital and labor
that a firm will use as it expands its operations. The optimum combination is at the point of
tangency between the isoquant and the isocost line. The expansion path is then determined by the
locus of these tangents between isoquants and isocost lines. With reference to the firm, that is the
curve traced out by joining up the factor input choices at each output level. For given input prices,
the curve indicates what the firm's chosen path of expansion (points A, B, C in Figure 5) will be in
terms of factor input combinations. With a cost-minimizing firm any point on this curve will
satisfy the condition that the ratio of the marginal physical product of any two factor input will equal
the ratio of their prices .

COST MINIMIZATION - COST-MINIMIZING INPUT RULE


The tangency of the isocost curve with the isoproduct curve defines the least-cost (optimal)
combination of inputs for the production of a given level of output. For a least-cost combination
of inputs, the following condition has to hold:

MP L MP K
-------- = -------
w r

which states that to minimize the cost of producing a given level of output, the marginal
product per dollar spent should be equal for all inputs.
Alternatively, a firm should employ inputs such that the marginal rate of technical
substitution is equal to the ratio of input prices.

MP L/MP K = w/r

EXAMPLE 7
A grower of strawberries estimates that strawberry output would increase 2,500
per month with an additional 1,000 gallons of water per month provided by an irrigation
system. Alternatively, strawberry output could be increased by 1,000 with an additional 2
tons of fertilizer per month. Assuming the cost of water is $.05 per gallon and that
fertilizer is $20 per ton, is the farm using an optimal combination of water and fertilizer?
For a least-cost combination of inputs, the following condition has to hold:

MP L MP K
-------- = -------
w r

107
MP W = 2500 and MP F = 1,000
P W = 1000 gallons per month x $.05 per gallon = $50 per month
P F = 2 tons per month x $20 per ton = $40 per month
Therefore,
2,500 1,000
------ = ----
50 40

No, 50> 25, which is not a least cost combination of inputs since output per additional
dollar spent is greater for water than for fertilizer.

FIGURE 5
ISOQUANTS, ISO-COST CURVES AND EXPANSION PATH

RETURNS TO SCALE
The returns to scale of a production system represents the increase in output
arising from a proportionate increase in all inputs. It refers to how output changes when all
inputs are increased by the same multiple. There are three possibilities: increasing, constant,
and decreasing returns to scale. If output increases by a greater multiple than that by which the
inputs are increased, then increasing returns to scale are present. In the long run, a firm may
experience increasing returns due to economies of scale. Economies and diseconomies of scale
affect a company's costs. When it experiences economies of scale, a company's long-run average
costs will decrease. Diseconomies of scale occur when the long-run average costs increase.
Economies or diseconomies of scale do not apply in the short run because many costs are fixed. In
the long run, all costs are variable.

108
If output increases by the same multiple, constant returns to scale are present. Finally, if
output increases by a smaller multiple, decreasing returns to scale are present. Returns to scale play
an important role in economic decisions. They affect the optimal scale, or plant size of a firm and its
production facilities. They also affect the nature of competition in an industry and thus are important
in determining the profitability in a particular sector of the economy.

Returns to scale Condition


Increasing return to scale Percentage increase in output > percentage
increase in inputs
Constant return to scale Percentage increase in output = percentage
increase in inputs
Decreasing return to scale Percentage increase in output < percentage
increase in inputs

Returns to scale can be evaluated in a number of ways, including the following:


1. Compare the percentage increase in output with any given percentage increase
in inputs.
2. Use a more general algebraic approach.

EXAMPLE 8
Given the production function Q = 10L + 15K + 20KL

(a) If L=K=100, then

Q 1 = 10(100) + 15(100) + 20(100)(100) = 202,500


Increase each unit by one percent yields:
Q 2 = 10(101) + 15(101) + 20(101)(101) = 206,545, which implies a 2 percent increase in
output (Q 2 / Q 1 = 1.02), and therefore, the function exhibits increasing returns to scale.

(b) Alternatively, for a k percent increase in all inputs (where k > 1) we observe:

Q 1 = 10L + 15K + 20KL


Q 2 = 10L + 15K + 20KL = 10(kL) + 15(kK) + 20(kL)(kK) = k (10L + 15K + 20kKL).
Since k > 1, Q 2 > Q 1 . So the function exhibits increasing returns to scale.

OUTPUT ELASTICITY AND RETURNS TO SCALE


The output elasticity measures how sensitive output is to a change in an input
used. It is calculated as:

% change in Q ∂Q X
eQ = --------------- = ----- . -------
% change in X ∂X Q

where X represents all inputs (capital, labor, etc.). This measure can also be used to
109
estimate returns to scale, based on the following criteria:

Output elasticity Returns to scale


eQ > 1 Increasing
eQ = 1 Constant
eQ < 1 Decreasing

QUESTIONS
1. Give several different forms of production function.
2. How does the Cobb-Douglas function differ from other forms?
3. What is marginal revenue product (MRP)? What is its significance in profit
maximization?
4. Briefly describe three stages of production.
5. What is output elasticity? How is it calculated?
6. Describe the graphical relationship between marginal product and average product.
7. State the condition for the least-cost (optimal) combination of inputs.
8. Give two examples of perfect substitutes.
9. If inputs are not substitutable, there is no decision made on input combination.
Comment.

PROBLEMS
1. Anaheim Company, a film processor, has the following production function:
Q = .5K 2 + .3KL + .4L2
Assume a weekly rate of use where L = 100 labor hours and K = 30 film developing
hours. Determine the following:
(a) The total product per week.
(b) The marginal product of labor.
(c) The marginal product of capital.

2. John-Jay Opticals, Inc., a maker of optical supplies estimated the following production
function:
Q = 20L.75 K .30
where Q = plastic cases produced per eight-hour shift, L = units of labor, and K = units of
capital employed.
(a) Calculate the number of plastic cases completed per eight-hour shift when L = 10 and
K = 100.
(b) Calculate the marginal product of labor when L = 10 and K = 100.

3. Ding-Dong Farms, Inc. is a grower of oranges. The company estimates that orange
output would increase 1,500 per month with an additional 1,000 gallons of water per
month provided by an irrigation system. Alternatively, orange output could be increased
by 900 with an additional 2 tons of fertilizer per month. Assuming the cost of water is
$.06 per gallon and that fertilizer is $25 per ton, is the farm using an optimal combination
110
of water and fertilizer? Why or why not?

4. Agasi Farms, Inc. is a grower of pears. The company estimates that pear output would
increase 1,200 per month with an additional 1,000 gallons of water per month provided
by an irrigation system. Alternatively, pear output could be increased by 1000 with an
additional 2 tons of fertilizer per month. Assuming the cost of water is $.06 per gallon
and that fertilizer is $25 per ton, is the farm using an optimal combination of water and
fertilizer? Why or why not?

5. ABC has the following production function:


Q = 12KL + .7KL2 - 1/30KL3
Determine the following:
(a) The maximum output that can be produced when K =5.
(b) The level of use of L where average product of labor (AP L) is at a maximum.
(c) The output level where diminishing returns to L occurs.

6. The Southwestern Mining Company has developed the following production function
for its coal output:
Q = 250L0.5 K 0.6
(a) Determine returns to scale and comment on it.
(b) Determine returns to scale for each factor input.

7. The Nova Coal Mining Company has developed the following production function for
its coal output:
Q = 300L0.5 K 0.5
where Q = Coal output (in thousands of tons), L = Labor (in hundreds of workers), and K
= Capital ( in hundreds of millions of dollars).
At peak production, the company is expected to employ 10,000 workers and require $900
million in capital outlays. Coal output is sold at a competitive market price of $40 per
ton.
(a) Determine the maximum annual wage the company would be willing to pay in order
to attract a force of 10,000 workers.
(b) How many workers would the company willingly hire in view of union demands for a
$20,000 annual wage?

8. The total product of labor (per hour) for a firm is given by:
Q = 30L - .5L2
(a) Determine the marginal product of labor.
(b) How many workers should the firm employ if the wage rate is $30 per hour and the
marginal revenue product is $24?

ANSWERS
1. Examples are linear production function, Leontief production function, and Cobb-
Douglas production function.
111
2. The Cobb-Douglas production function is between the extremes of the linear
production function and the Leontief production function. Unlike the linear function, the
relationship between output and the inputs is not linear. Unlike the Leontief function,
inputs need not be used in fixed proportions.
3. Marginal revenue product (MRP) is the net addition to total revenue attributable to the addition of
one unit of the variable productive service or the dollar value of the marginal product (MP) of an
input. The MRP of an input is equal to MP multiplied by the market price of the commodity. A
profit-maximizing firm will employ units of a variable productive service until the point is reached
at which the MRP of an input is exactly equal to the input price.
4. Three stages of production are of special significance for analyzing the efficiency with which
resource inputs are used. Stage I covers the entire range of increasing returns to variable input and
the point of diminishing marginal returns (DMR) is reached (Point A) and passed. It ends when the
point of diminishing average return (DAR) is reached (point B). Stage II covers the portion where
the quantity of output rises at a decreasing rate; accordingly, the marginal product (MP) of variable
input is declining, although it is still positive. Stage III coincides with the range of input where
additional usage of variable inputs is associated with the decline in output but MP is negative.
5. The output elasticity measures how sensitive output is to a change in an input used. It
is calculated as:
% change in Q ∂Q X
eQ = --------------- = ----- . -------
% change in X ∂X Q

where X represents all inputs (capital, labor, etc.). This measure can also be used to
estimate returns to scale.
6. (1) As the usage of an input increases, MP initially increases (increasing marginal returns), then
begin to decline (decreasing marginal returns), and eventually becomes negative (negative marginal
returns). (2) As long as MR increases MP > AP; otherwise, MP<AP.
7. The tangency of the isocost curve with the isoproduct curve defines the least-cost (optimal)
combination of inputs for the production of a given level of output. For a least-cost combination
of inputs, the following condition has to hold: MP W/ P W = MP F/ P F
8. In the area of baking, honey and brown sugar are often nearly perfect substitutes.
9. The statement is true. For example, an auto requires one engine, one battery, and four
wheels; no other combination will do. Another example would be yeast and flour for a
specified bread.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
(a) Q = .5(30)2 + .3(30)(100) + .4(100)2 = 450 + 900 + 4000 = 5350
(b) MP L = ∂ Q/ ∂ L = .3K + .8L = .3(30) + .8(100) = 89
(c) MP K = ∂ Q/ ∂K = K + .3L = (30) + .2(100) = 50

2.
(a) Q = 20L.75 K .30 = 20(10).75 (100).30 = 20(5.623)(3.981) = 447.70 plastic cases
(b) MP L = ∂ Q/ ∂ L = (20)(.75)L-.25 K .30 = 33.58
112
3.
For a least-cost combination of inputs, the following condition has to hold:

MP L MP K
------ = -----
w r

MP W = 1500 and MP F = 900


P W = 1000 gallons per month x $.06 per gallon = $60 per month
P F = 2 tons per month x $25 per ton = $50 per month
Therefore,
1500 900
----- = ---
60 50
No, 25> 18, which is not a least cost combination of inputs since output per additional
dollar spent is greater for water than for fertilizer.

4.
MP W = 1200 and MP F = 1000
P W = 1000 gallons per month x $.06 per gallon = $60 per month
P F = 2 tons per month x $25 per ton = $50 per month
Therefore,
1200 1000
---- = ----
60 50

Yes, 20 = 20, which is a least cost combination of inputs since output per additional
dollar spent is equal for both water than for fertilizer.

5.
(a) Q = 12KL + .7KL2 - .3KL3
at K = 5, TP L = 12(5)L + .7(5)L2 - 1/30(5)L3 = 60L + 3.5L2 - 1/6L3
Setting MP L equal to zero yields:
MP L = ∂ Q/ ∂ L = 60 + 7L - .5L2 = 0; (-.5L + 10)(L + 6) = 0
So L = 20 (Ignore L = -6) is a maximum since ∂2 Q/ ∂ L2 = 7 - L = 8 - 20 = -12 < 0.
The maximum output then is 1267 units:
At L = 20, TP L = 60L + 3.5L2 - 1/6L3 = 60(20) = 3.5(20)2 - 1/6(20)3 = 1267.
(b) TP L = 60L + 3.5L2 - 1/6L3
AP L = TP L/L= (60L + 3.5L2 - 1/6L3 )/L = 60 + 3.5L - 1/6L2
To find the maximum AP L, we set this equal to zero and solve for L, as follows:
d AP L/ d L = 3.5 - 1/3L = 0; L = 10.5, which is a maximum since d 2 AP L / d L2 = -1/3 < 0.
113
The output level where AP L is maximized is 823 units:
TP L = 60L + 3.5(10.5)2 - 1/6(10.5)3 = 823.
(c) Diminishing marginal returns begin where MP L is maximized.
MP L = ∂ Q/ ∂ L = 60 + 7L - .5L2
d MP L/dL = 7 - L = 0; L = 7, which is a maximum since d 2 MP L/dL2 = -1 < 0.
So at L = 7, TP L = 60L + 3.5L2 - 1/6L3 = 60(7) + 3.5(7)2 - 1/6(7)3 = 534.
Diminishing marginal returns to the labor input begin where output is 534 units.

6.
(a) Q = 250L0.5 K 0.6 = 250(kL)0.5 (kK)0.6 = k 0.5 k 0.6 250L0.5 K 0.6 = k 1.1 Q, i.e., k 1.1 > k,
indicates that the above production function exhibits increasing returns to scale.
(b) Returns to each factor can be determined by examining how each marginal product
changes with increased usage.
Returns to Labor:
MP L = ∂ Q/ ∂ L = 125L-0.5 K 0.6 ; d 2 MP L/dL2 = -62.5 L-1.5 K 0.6 < 0. Therefore, returns to labor
are decreasing.
Returns to Capital:
MP K = ∂ Q/ ∂K = 125L 0.5 K -0.4 , d 2 MP L/dL2 = -50L0.5 K -1.4 < 0. Therefore, returns to labor
are decreasing.

7.
(a) We use the optimal employment rule:
Price of an input (P i ) = Marginal revenue product of the input (MRP i )
For labor, Price of labor = marginal revenue product of labor, or

PL = MP L x MR Q
-.5 .5
= (150L K )($40 x 1,000 tons)
-.5 .5
= [150(100) (9) ]($40 x 1,000 tons)
= $1,800,000 per hundred workers, or
$18,000.

(b) P L = MP L x MR Q
$20,000 x 100 = (150L-.5 K .5 )($40 x 1,000 tons)
$2,000,000 = [150L-.5 (9).5 ]($40 x 1,000 tons)
$2,000,000 = [150L-.5 (9).5 ]($40 x 1,000 tons)
$2,000,000/ $18,000,000 = 150L-.5
$2,000,000/ $18,000,000 = 1/L.5
L.5 = 9
L = 81 0r, 8,100 workers. Thus, at a wage of $20,000, the company would only be willing
to hire 8,100 workers.

8.
(a) MP L = ∂Q/ ∂ L = 30 - L
(b) Using the optimal employment rule,
114
P L = MP L x MR Q
$30 = (30 - L) x $24
$30 = $720 - $24L
L = 23
The firm should hire 23 workers per hour.

115
CHAPTER 7
MULTIPLE PRODUCT PLANNING AND LINEAR PROGRAMMING

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Define linear programming (LP).


2. Define the objective function.
3. Give examples of constraints.
4. Illustrate non-negativity constraints.
5. Define and give example of a feasible solution.
6. Discuss and illustrate the basic feasible solution.
7. Compute and define the optimal solution.
8. Give examples of dual problems.
9. Explain and give examples of the shadow price.
10. Explain what the slack variable.
11. Illustrate and discuss binding constraints.
12. Explain the complementary slackness condition.
13. Demonstrate and explain the uses of activity analysis.
14. Outline and explain the process ray.
15. Illustrate the isoprofit curve.

Linear programming (LP) is a mathematical technique designed to determine an


optimal decision (or an optimal plan) chosen from a large number of possible decisions.
The optimal decision is the one that meets the specified objective of the company, subject
to various restrictions or constraints. It concerns itself with the problem of allocating
scarce resources among competing activities in an optimal manner. The optimal decision
yields the highest profit, contribution margin (CM), or revenue, or the lowest cost. A
linear programming model consists of two important ingredients:

1. Objective function . The company must define the specific objective to be achieved.
2. Constraints . Constraints are in the form of restrictions on availability of resources
or meeting minimum requirements. As the name linear programming indicates, both the
objective function and constraints must be in linear form.

NOTE:
The classical calculus methods, such as the Lagrangean multiplier technique, are
not well suitable for obtaining optimal solutions to problems with inequality constraints.
LP deals with constrained optimization problems with linear objective functions and
linear inequality constraints, while differential calculus and the Lagrangean multiplier
technique deal with problems involving linear or nonlinear objective functions and
equality constraints.
116
EXAMPLE 1
A firm wishes to find an optimal product mix. The optimal mix would be the one
that maximizes its total profit or contribution margin (CM) within the allowed budget and
production capacity. Or the firm may want to determine a least cost combination of input
materials while meeting production requirements, employing production capacities, and
using available employees.

APPLICATIONS OF LP
Applications of LP are numerous. They include:
1. Selecting least-cost mix of ingredients for manufactured products
2. Developing an optimal budget
3. Determining an optimal investment portfolio (or asset allocation)
4. Allocating an advertising budget to a variety of media.
5. Scheduling jobs to machines
6. Determining a least-cost shipping pattern
7. Scheduling flights
8. Gasoline blending
9. Optimal manpower allocation
10. Selecting the best warehouse location to minimize shipping costs.

FORMULATION OF LP
To formulate an LP problem, certain steps are followed. They are:
1. Define what is called decision variables that you are trying to solve for.
2. Express the objective function and constraints in terms of these decision variables.
All the expressions must be in linear form.
In the following example, we will use this technique to find the optimal product
mix.

EXAMPLE 2
The Omni Furniture Manufacturing Company produces two products: desk and
table. Both products require time in two processing departments, Assembly Department
and Finishing Department. Data on the two products are as follows:

Products Available
Processing Desk Table Hours
Assembly 2 per unit 4 100 hours
Finishing 3 2 90
Profit per unit $25 $40

The company wants to find the most profitable mix of these two products.
Step 1: Define the decision variables as follows:
x 1 = Number of units of desk to be produced
x 2 = Number of units of table to be produced

117
Step 2: The objective function to maximize total profit (Z) is expressed as:
Z = 25x 1 + 40x 2
Then, formulate the constraints as inequalities:
2x 1 + 4x 2 < 100 (Assembly constraint)
3x 1 + 2x 2 < 90 (Finishing constraint)
In addition, implicit in any LP formulation are the constraints that restrict x 1 and x 2 to be
nonnegative, i.e.,
x1, x2 > 0

Maximize: Z =25x 1 + 40x 2


Subject to: 2x 1 + 4x 2 < 100
3x 1 + 2x 2 < 90
x1, x2 > 0

COMPUTATION METHODS OF LP
There are solution methods available to solve LP problems. They include:
1. The simplex method
2. The graphical method
The simplex method is the technique most commonly used to solve LP problems.
It is an algorithm, which is an iteration method of computation, to move from one
solution to another until it reaches the best solution.

NOTE:
The simplex method introduces what are referred to as slack variables (denoted
with, say, s 1 and s 2 ) to convert inequalities to equalities , as follows:
2x 1 + 4x 2 < 100 ------------> 2x 1 + 4x 2 + s 1 = 100
3x 1 + 2x 2 < 90 -------------> 3x 1 + 2x 2 + s 2 = 90
where s 1 and s 2 must be nonnegative.
If the left-hand side is greater than the right side (>), which is usually the case in a
minimization problem, we say that there is a surplus. Then, we need -s 1 and -s 2 for a
conversion to equalities, instead.

The graphical solution is easier to use but limited to the LP problems involving
two (or at most three) decision variables. The graphical method follows the steps:

Step 1: Change inequalities to equalities.


Step 2: Graph the equalities. To graph the equality, (1) set one variable equal to
zero and find the value of the other and connect those two points on the graph and (2)
mark these intersections on the axes and connect them with a straight line.
Step 3: Identify the correct side for the original inequalities by shading. Repeat
steps 1-3 for each constraint.
Step 4: After all this, identify the feasible region, the area of feasible solutions .
Step 5: Solve the constraints (expressed as equalities) simultaneously for the

118
various corner points of the feasible region.
Step 6: Determine the profit or contribution margin at all corners in the region.

NOTE:
Feasible solutions are values of decision variables that satisfy all the constraints
simultaneously. They are found on and within the boundary of the feasible region. The
graphical approach is based on two important LP properties:
1. The optimal solution lies on the boundary of the feasible region, which implies
that one can ignore the (infinitely numerous) interior points of the feasible region when
searching for an optimal solution..
2. The optimal solution occurs at one of the corner points (basic feasible
solutions) of the feasible region.

EXAMPLE 3
Using the data and the LP model from Example 2, follow steps 1 through 4. We
obtain the following feasible region (shaded area).

Step 1: Change inequalities to equalities.


2x 1 + 4x 2 = 100
3x 1 + 2x 2 = 90
Step 2: Graph the equalities. To graph the equality, set one variable equal to zero, find the
value of the other, mark the points on the axes, and connect those two points with a
straight line.
For equation 1: If x 1 =0, x 2 =25; if x 2 =0, then x 1 =50, connect x 2 =25 and x 1 =50.
For equation 2: If x 1 =0, x 2 =30; if x 2 =0, then x 1 =45, connect x 2 =30 and x 1 =45.
Step 3: Identify the correct side for the original inequalities. The correct side is the line
and the area below it for less-than or equal-to constraints.
Step 4: After all this, identify the feasible region, the area of feasible solutions. The area
of feasible solutions is the duplicated area as indicated by the shaded area in Figure 1.
Step 5: Solve the constraints (expressed as equalities) simultaneously for the various
corner points of the feasible region.
Step 6: Determine the profit or contribution margin at all corners in the feasible region.
We evaluate all of the corner points as follows:

Corner Points Profit


x1 x2 $25x 1 + $40x 2
(a) 30 0 $25(30) + $40(0) =
$750
(b) 20 15 25(20) + 40(15)= 1,100
(c) 0 25 25(0) + 40(25)= 1,000
(d) 0 0 25(0) + 40(0) = 0

The corner point (b) (x 1 =20, x 2 =15) produces the most profitable solution (Z*=$1,100).
This point can be found by solving two equations that created it simultaneously, as shown
119
below.

2x 1 + 4x 2 = 100 (1)
3x 1 + 2x 2 = 90 (2)

Multiplying the second equation (2) through by 2 and subtract from (1), we obtain

2x 1 + 4x 2 = 100 (1)
- 6x 1 - 4x 2 = 180 (2)
- 4x 1 = -80
x1 = 20

Substituting x 1 = 20 into (10) or (2) yields x 2 = 15.

NOTE:
We can use a computer LP software package such as LINDO (Linear Interactive
and Discrete Optimization) and What's Best! to quickly solve an LP problem.

FIGURE 1
THE FEASIBLE REGION AND CORNER POINTS

120
THE DUAL PROBLEM IN LP
Each LP maximization problem has its corresponding dual, a minimization
problem and, conversely, each LP minimization problem has its corresponding dual, a
maximization problem. It has the following features:
(1) Both the primal and the dual will give the same values for the decision
variables in the primal objective functions at their optimal solution points.
(2) The optimal value for the primal will equal the optimal value for the dual.
(3) The dual is useful since it has many interesting economic interpretations. For
example, the dual optimal solutions give the imputed value (or shadow price) or the
opportunity cost to the firm of each of the scarce resources.

The following shows how to set up the dual problem:

where i = 1,2,...m and j =1,2,...n

In a 2 x 2 case,

To begin with, define the dual variables such as u 1 , u 2 . The number of dual variables
should be the same as the number of the constraints in the primal. And then follow the
following rules:

Primal Dual
1. Coefficients <----------> the right hand side
in the objective function in the constraints

2. The right hand side <----------> Coefficients


in the constraints in the objective
function
121
3. The constraints are ≤ <----------> Dual variables ≥ 0

4. Primal variables ≥ 0 <----------> Dual constraints are ≥

5. The matrix of <----------> Its transpose


constraints
coefficients

a11 a12 a11 a21


a21 a22 a12 a22

EXAMPLE 4
From Example 2, we have

Maximize: Z =25x 1 + 40x 2

Subject to: 2x 1 + 4x 2 < 100 (for assembly department)


3x 1 + 2x 2 < 90 (for finishing department)
x1, x2 > 0

To set up the dual, first introduce the dual variables u 1 , u 2 . There will be two variables
since there are two constraints in the primal. Then the dual can be set up as follows:

Minimize V = 100u 1
+90u 2

Subject to: 2u 1 + 3 u 2 ≥ 25 (for desk)


4u 1 + 2 u 2 ≥ 40 (for table)
u1, u2 ≥0

EXAMPLE 5
Solving the dual graphically yields u 1 * = 8.75 and u 2 * = 2.50. The optimal value
V* = 1,100. Figure 2 shows the computer software solution of the primal and dual
problems.

122
FIGURE 2
COMPUTER PRINTOUT FOR LP

VARIABLE ORIGINAL COEFF.


VARIABLE VALUE COEFF. SENS.
X 1 20 25 0 Note:X1 = 20
X 2 15 40 0 X2 = 15

CONSTRAINT ORIGINAL SLACK OR SHADOW


NUMBER RHS SURPLUS PRICE
1 100 0 8.75 Note:u1 = $8.75
1 90 0 2.50 u2 = $2.50
OBJECTIVE FUNCTION VALUE: 1100 Note: Z = $1,100

SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS

OBJECTIVE FUNCTION COEFFICIENTS

LOWER ORIGINAL UPPER


VARIABLE LIMIT COEFFICIENT LIMIT

X 1 20 25 60
X 2 16.67 40 50

RIGHT HAND SIDE

CONSTRAINT LOWER ORIGINAL UPPER


NUMBER LIMIT VALUE LIMIT

1 60 100 180
2 50 90 150

ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION OF THE DUAL PROBLEM


The dual problem has numerous economic interpretations. They are:

1. u 1 , u 2 represents a kind of valuation of the resource (capacity) in question. This


value is not a market price; rather, it is a value to be imputed to the resource. For this
reason, the value of the dual variables is referred to as shadow price or opportunity cost
for the resource. Put it another way, the shadow price is the maximum price the firm is
willing to pay for an additional unit of a given resource. For example, in Examples 4 and
5, the maximum price the firm is willing to pay for an extra hour of the assembly capacity
is $8.75, while an extra hour of the finishing capacity is only $2.50.
If the actual price is above the shadow price, the firm will not add an additional unit for
that resource.

2. Turn next to the constraint in the dual. Let us examine the first constraint:

123
2u 1 + 3 u 2 ≥ 25. The right hand side term 25 denotes the per-unit profit or contribution
margin of one desk, while 40 is for one table. Since 2 hours denotes the amount of time
used in the assembly department by desk and 3 hours denote amount of time required in
finishing department by desk, the left hand side represents the total opportunity cost of
production of one unit of desk. Thus, what this constraint requires is that the opportunity
costs of producing one desk be imputed at a level at least as large as the per-unit profit
for the product.

3. Now look at the dual objective function, V = 100u 1 +90u 2. V simply means the
total value imputed to (total opportunity cost) of the resources. Thus, the correspondence
between the primal and the dual suggest that: To maximize total profit or contribution by
finding the optimal output levels is tantamount to minimizing the total imputed value or
opportunity cost of the firm’s resources, with the proviso that the opportunity cost of
production of each product must be no less than the contribution margin from the
product.

4. Notice, however, that if the opportunity cost of production is actually to exceed


the profit, then the resource allocation must certainly be nonoptimal, because simply by
dropping the corresponding product, resources will be released therefrom and can
immediately be utilized to better advantage elsewhere. Let us check that.

2u 1 + 3 u 2 ≥ 25 (for desk)
4u 1 + 2 u 2 ≥ 40 (for table)

We know that the optimal solutions are: u 1 * = 8.75 and u 2 * = 2.50. Plugging these
numbers into the constraints yields:

2(8.75) + 3 (2.50)= 25 = 25 (for desk)


4(8.75) + 2 (2.50)= 40 = 40 (for table)

It shows that the opportunity cost equals the profit for each product, so that the resource
allocation turns out to be optimal. This results in what we call complimentary slackness
condition , which states:

A pair of primal and dual feasible solutions are optimal to the respective problems
if and only if whenever a slackness in one problem is strictly positive; the corresponding
nonnegative variable in the other problem is zero. More specifically,

(1) If a constraint of the primal is not binding (i.e., a slack exists), then the shadow
price of that constraint will be zero. If a constraint is binding (i.e., no slack exists), the
shadow price will be positive.

(2) If a constraint of the dual is not binding (i.e., opportunity cost greater than the
124
per-unit profit), then the primal variable will be zero. If a constraint is binding (i.e.,
opportunity cost equal to the per-unit profit), the primal variable is positive.

Dual constraints Primal variables

2(8.75) + 3 (2.50)= 25 = 25 (for desk) --------> x 1 *=20>0


4(8.75) + 2 (2.50)= 40 = 40 (for table) --------> x 2 *=15>0

Also,

Dual variables Primal constraints

u 1 * = 8.75 > 0 ---------> 2(20) + 4(15) = 100 = 100


u 2 * = 2.50 > 0 ---------> 3(20) + 2(15) = 90 = 90

NOTE:
1. In this example, both the primal and the dual constraints are binding (no slacks
exist or opportunity cost exactly equal to the per-unit profit). Therefore, the optimal
values of the primal and the dual are positive.
2. The shadow price is zero if the constraint is not binding because it would do you no
good to expand the capacity in an area where you are not using the full capacity that you
already have.

5. The optimal solution values for the primal and the dual are the same. To prove: Z* =
25(20) + 40(15) = 1,100 and V*= 100(8.75+ + 90(2.50) = 1,100, therefore
Z*=V*=$1,100.

ACTIVITY ANALYSIS AND SINGLE PRODUCT


The application of LP to production discussed in the previous section was
concerned with multiple products. The problem dealt with determining the optimal
combination of products (i.e., optimal product mix), given restrictions on the resources
(inputs) employed in the production process. The focus of the analysis was on output --
recall that the horizontal and vertical axes of the graphs measured the quantities of the
respective products (outputs) and that resources (inputs) were represented only as a series
of constraint lines on the outputs.

In what follows, we discuss an activity analysis which involves a single product. It


concerns itself with choosing an optimal combination of production processes to be
employed to produce the greatest quantity possible of a single product, given fixed amounts of
certain inputs. Each of the processes is considered to be an activity. LP is also used to find the

125
optimal solution.

The focus of the analysis is on inputs and the alternative production processes
within which the inputs can be employed to obtain the product. LP seeks to determine the
optimal level of each activity. The theory of production (i.e., process rays, isoquants, and
isoprofit curves) can be used to illustrate the alternative production processes and the
concept of input substitution. We will first formulate and solve the output-maximization
problem. The profit-maximization formulation will be taken up later.

FORMULATION OF THE OUTPUT-MAXIMIZATION PROBLEM


The following example illustrates how to formulate and solve the output-
maximization problem.

EXAMPLE 6
A leather-processing firm employs capital (units) and labor (units) in the dyeing of
white suede leather. Three different production processes (A, B, and C) are available for
its operation. Each process involves a different combination of labor and capital--process
A, requires 1 unit of capital and 4 units, process B, requires 2 units and 2 units, and
process C, requires 5 units and 1 unit. The firm’s capacity is limited--5 units of capital
and 8 units of labor are available per day for this dyeing operation.

Define Q A, Q B , and Q C , to be the quantity of dyed leather per day by processes A,


B, and C, respectively. Given that the objective is to maximize output subject to the
input (capital and labor) constraints, the problem can be formulated as an LP problem as
follows:

Maximize: Q = Q A + QB + Q C. (objective function)


Subject to Q A + 2Q B + 5Q C ≤ 5 (capital constraint)
4Q A+ 2Q B + Q C ≤ 8 (labor constraint)
Q A, Q B , Q C ≥ 0 (nonnegativity constraint)

GRAPHICAL APPROACH TO THE OUTPUT-MAXIMIZATION PROBLEM


The LP activity problem can be illustrated and solved graphically, using process
rays to represent the production processes, production isoquants to represent the
objective function, and a feasible region to represent the constraints.

PROCESS RAYS
A production process is one in which the inputs are combined in fixed proportions
to obtain the output. By this definition, a production process can be represented
graphically as a ray through the origin having a slope equal to the ratio of the number of
units of the respective resources required to produce one unit of output. In this example,
the three production process rays are shown in Figure 4. Along ray A, the inputs are
combined in the ratio of 4 units of labor to 1 unit of capital. Hence, ray A has a slope of
4. Similarly, along ray B the inputs are combined in the ratio of 2 units of labor to 2 units
126
of capital. Process ray C shows the inputs combined in the ratio of 1 to 5.

Each production process is assumed to display constant returns to scale. This


means that output along each ray increases proportionately with increases in the inputs.
For example, points D, G, and J represent the inputs needed to produce one, two, and
three units of output.
PRODUCTION ISOQUANTS
A production isoquant traces out the combinations of any two or more inputs which give
rise to the same level of output. The isoquants are constructed by drawing straight lines
between the points of equal output on adjacent process rays. Four isoquants,
representing output levels Q of 1, 2, 3, and 4 respectively, are shown in Figure 3. They
have parallel line segments between adjacent process rays. For example, line segment
DE is parallel to GH , and line segment EF is parallel to HI. This occurs since the
coefficients of the Q variables in the resource constraints are constants.

NOTE:
The segment of an isoquant between two production process rays implies that a
combination of the two processes is being used to produce that particular level of output.

As was indicated earlier, points along each process ray represent the output obtained if
the two inputs (labor and capital) are combined in the ratio of the respective number of
units of each resource required to produce a given unit of output. However, the points
that lie on isoquants between adjacent process rays have a slightly different
interpretation. These points represent a combination of output from each of the adjacent
production processes. For example, Point S on the "Q = 4" isoquant in Figure 3
represents a production combination using both processes B, and C,. The quantity of
output that is produced by each process can be obtained by constructing a parallelogram
such as the one shown in Figure 4. A line is drawn from Point J parallel to process ray B,
intersecting process ray C at Point L. Another line is drawn from Point S parallel to
process ray B, intersecting process ray C at Point D. From the parallelogram 0ESL, one
can determine both the quantity of output produced by each process and the respective
amount of inputs used in each process.

FIGURE 3
PRODUCTION RAYS AND PRODUCTION ISOQUANTS

127
The firm should produce one unit of output using B, since Point E is on the "Q =
1" isoquant, and three units of output using process C, since Point L is on the "Q = 3"
isoquant. This combination will yield the four units of output. At Point E, 2 units of
capital and 2 units of labor are used in process B; and at Point L, 15 units of capital and 3
units of labor are used in process C. Total capital and labor resources used in producing
the four units of output are 17 units and 5 units, respectively. All other points that lie
between the process rays can be interpreted in a similar manner.

FEASIBLE REGION
The feasible region consists of all the capital and labor input combinations that
simultaneously satisfy all constraints of the LP problem. The shaded rectangle 0TRW
shown in Figure 3 represents the feasible region for the example problem. Since a
maximum of 5 units of capital is available per day, only input combinations on or to the
left of the RW line represent possible solutions to the LP problem. Similarly, since a
maximum of 8 units of labor is available per day, possible solutions must lie on or below
the TR line. Finally, the nonnegativity constraints preclude input combinations to the left
of the 0T line and below the 0W line.

OPTIMAL SOLUTION
The combination of production processes that maximizes output subject to the
resource constraints occurs at the point on the boundary of the feasible region that lies on
the highest production isoquant. Figure 4 indicates that the optimal solution occurs at
Point R. At Point R, three units of output are obtained by using 5 units of capital and 8

128
units of labor. Constructing the parallelogram 0DRH shows that one unit of output
should be produced using process A,(Q A=1) and the remainder, two units in this case,
using process B (Q B =2).

Alternatively, from the graphical solution we see that output is maximized where
Q C =0, so we substitute this into two constraint equations, we obtain

Q A + 2Q B = 5
4Q A+ 2Q B = 8

and subtracting the second equation from the first, -3Q A=-3 or Q A=1. We then can find
Q B =2, which gives us the same solution we found graphically.

PROFIT-MAXIMIZATION PROBLEM
The production problem can also be formulated as a profit-maximization problem.

EXAMPLE 7
In Example 6, assume that the profit contribution of output produced by processes
A, B and C, are $6, $5, and $4 per unit, respectively. Provided that the firm wishes to
maximize profits (Z) instead of output (Q), the objective function becomes

Maximize: Z=6Q A + 5Q B + 4Q C

An optimal solution to this profit-maximizing LP problem can be obtained and illustrated


by isoprofit curves rather than isoquant curves.

ISOPROFIT CURVES
An isoprofit curve reflects the various combinations of products that a firm can sell to
earn a given level of profit. It is constructed by drawing straight lines between the points on
adjacent process rays having equal total profits. To illustrate, consider the "Q = 1"
isoquant from Figure 4, which is labeled MNF in Figure 5 . Let us say we want to develop
an isoprofit curve corresponding to a profit of $4. Point F is clearly on this isoprofit
curve, since one unit of output produced by process C yields a profit of $4. Point N also
represents one unit of output. However, each unit of output produced by process B yields
a profit of $5.
FIGURE 4
SOLUTION OF OUTPUT-MAXIMIZATION PROBLEM

129
FIGURE 5
SOLUTION OF PROFIT-MAXIMIZATION PROBLEM

Therefore, the point on process ray A having profit of $4 must be $4 ÷ $5 = 80 percent of


the distance from the origin (0) to Point N. This corresponds to Point B. Similarly, the
130
point on process ray A having a profit of $4 must be $4 ÷ $6 = 67 percent of the distance
from the origin (0) to Point M. This occurs at Point D. By connecting the points on
adjacent process rays with straight-line segments, one obtains the "Z = $4" isoprofit
curve. The profit curves corresponding to profits of $8, $12, and $16 are also shown in
Figure 5. As with the production isoquants, the isoprofit curves have parallel line
segments between adjacent process rays.

OPTIMAL SOLUTION
The combination of production processes that maximizes total profits subject to
the resource constraints occurs at the point on the boundary of the feasible region that
lies on the highest isoprofit curve. As shown in Figure 5, the optimal solution is a Point
L, which lies on the "Z = $16" isoprofit curve. Recalling that this solution corresponds to
Point R in Figure 5, the firm should produce one leather using process A, and two
leathers using process B, in order to maximize profits. Substituting these values for Q A
and Q B respectively (Q C = 0) into the objective function, we obtain $16. (6Q A + 5Q B +
4Q C = 6(1) + 5(2)+ 4(0) = $16). Alternatively, from the graphical solution we see that
output is maximized where Q C =0, so we substitute this into two constraint equations, we
obtain

Q A + 2Q B = 5
4Q A+ 2Q B = 8

and subtracting the second equation from the first, -3Q A=-3 or Q A=1. We then can find
Q B =2, which gives us the same solution we found graphically.

NOTE:
The production problem can be set up as a cost-minimization LP problem. The
procedure for finding an optimal solution is basically the same, except that isocost curves
are introduced to find the least-cost input combination, rather than isoprofit curves.

QUESTIONS
1. What is linear programming? Why is it called linear?
2. List six popular applications of LP for business decisions.
3. What are the two ingredients of LP?
4. What is the economic meaning of the dual solution?
5. Compare LP, differential calculus, and the Lagrangean multiplier technique.
6. How does activity analysis differ from an optimal product mix problem?
7. What are two major computational methods of LP? Briefly describe the pro and con of
each.
8. List three general properties associated with LP.
9. Explain the complementary slackness condition.

PROBLEMS
131
1. The Carson Company makes two products, X and Y. Their contribution margins are $50 and
$90, respectively. Each product goes through three processes: cutting, finishing, and painting. The
number of hours required by each process for each product and capacities available are given
below:

Hours Required in Each Process

Product Cutting Finishing Painting


X 2 4 3
Y 1 6 2
Capacities in Hours 300 500 250

Formulate the objective function and constraints to determine the optimal product mix.

2. A company fabricates and assembles two products, A and B. It takes three minutes to fabricate
each unit of A, and six minutes to fabricate each unit of B. Assembly time per unit for product A is
one minute, and for product B, nine minutes. Six hundred minutes of fabrication time and 1,800
minutes of assembly time are available. The company makes a contribution margin of $2 on each
unit of A it sells, and $1 on each unit of B.

(a) Express the problem as an LP model.


(b) Solve this problem. What quantities of A and B should be produced in order to maximize
profits? What will be the profits earned at these production levels?

3. Given the following primal, formulate its dual:

Maximize: Z =13x 1 + 40x 2

Subject to: 2x 1 + 4x 2 < 6


x 1 + 2x 2 < 10
5x 1 + 2x 2 < 25
x1, x2 > 0

4. The Zenico Chemical Company produces an industrial cleaner for carpets. This chemical is made
from a mixture of two other chemicals which both contain cleaning agent LIM and cleaning agent
LOOM. Their product must contain 175 units of agent LIM and 150 units of agent LOOM, and
weigh at least 100 pounds. Chemical A costs $8 per pound, while chemical B cost $6 per pound.
Chemical A contains one unit of agent LIM and one unit of agent LOOM. Set up the problem in the
linear programming format and solve it.

ANSWERS
1. Linear programming (LP) is a mathematical technique designed to determine an

132
optimal decision (or an optimal plan) chosen from a large number of possible decisions.
The optimal decision is the one that meets the specified objective of the company, subject
to various restrictions or constraints. It is linear because we assume both the objective
function and constraints are linear.

2. Six popular applications of LP are: selecting least-cost mix of ingredients for


manufactured products; determining the most profitable mix of products; determining an
optimal investment portfolio (or asset allocation); allocating an advertising budget to a
variety of media; scheduling jobs to machines; determining a least-cost shipping pattern.

3. Two ingredients of LP are objective function and inequality constraints (including


nonnegativity constraints).

4. The dual solution represents shadow prices or opportunity costs of resources to the
firm. They are the maximum prices the firm is willing to pay for an additional unit of
given resources. If the actual price is above the shadow price, the firm will not add an
additional unit for that resource.

5. LP deals with constrained optimization problems with linear objective functions and
linear inequality constraints, while differential calculus and the Lagrangean multiplier
technique deal with problems involving linear or nonlinear objective functions and
equality constraints.

6. Activity analysis involves a single product. It concerns itself with choosing an optimal
combination of production processes to be employed to produce the greatest quantity possible
of a single product, given fixed amounts of certain inputs. Each of the processes is considered to be
an activity. LP is also used to find the optimal solution. The application of LP can also involve
multiple products. The problem dealt with determining the optimal combination of
products (i.e., optimal product mix), given restrictions on the resources (inputs) used in
the production process.

7. Two major computational methods of LP are: (1) the simplex method and (2) the
graphical method. The simplex method is the technique most commonly used to solve LP
problems. It is an algorithm, which is an iteration method of computation, to move from
one solution to another until it reaches the best solution. The graphical approach is easier
to use but limited to the LP problems involving two (or at most three) decision variables.

8. (a). The optimal solutions lies on the boundary of the feasible region, which implies
that one can ignore the (infinitely numerous) interior points of the feasible region when
searching for an optimal solution. (b). The optimal solution occurs at one of the corner
points (basic feasible solutions) of the feasible region. (c). The optimal solution values
for the primal and the dual are the same.

9. A pair of primal and dual feasible solutions are optimal to the respective problems if

133
and only if whenever a slackness in one problem is strictly positive; the corresponding
nonnegative variable in the other problem is zero. More specifically, (1) If a constraint of
the primal is not binding (i.e., a slack exists), then the shadow price of that constraint will
be zero. If a constraint is binding (i.e., no slack exists), the shadow price will be positive.
(2) If a constraint of the dual is not binding (i.e., opportunity cost greater than the per-
unit profit), then the primal variable will be zero. If a constraint is binding (i.e.,
opportunity cost equal to the per-unit profit), the primal variable is positive.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
l.

Let X = Number of units of product X to be produced


Y = Number of units of product Y to be produced

Then, the LP formulation is as follows:

Maximize: Z= $50X + $90Y


Subject to: 2X + 1Y < 300
4X + 6Y < 500
3X + 2Y < 250
X,Y > 0

2.

(a) Let A = Number of units of product A to produce


Let B = Number of units of product B to produce

Maximize: Z= $2A + $1B


Subject to: 3A + 6B < 600 (fabrication)
1A + 9B < 1,800 (assembly)
A, B > 0

(b)

Thus, 200 units of A should be produced and no units of B. Profit will be $400 at this level.

134
3.
There are three dual variables since there are three constraints in the primal, u1 , u 2 , and u 3

Minimize V = 6u 1 +10u 2 +25u 3

Subject to: 2u 1 + u 2 + 5u 3 ≥ 13
4u 1 + 2u 2 +2u 3 ≥ 40
u1, u2, u3≥0

4.

Define A = Number of pounds of chemical A to be produced


B = Number of pounds of chemical B to be produced

Then, the LP formulation of this cost minimization problem is

Minimize: $8A + $6B

Subject to: A + 7B > 175


3A + B > 150
A + B > 100
A, B > 0

The least-cost mixture of the two chemicals A and B is: A = 25 pounds, B = 75 pounds.

135
136
CHAPTER 8
COST: THEORY AND ANALYSIS

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Distinguish between the total variable costs and the total fixed costs.
2. Illustrate the average total cost.
3. Diagram graphically the planning (envelop) curve.
4. Discuss statistical cost analysis.
5. Define incremental (differential) costs
6. Illustrate and discuss sunk costs.
7. Differentiate between implicit vs. explicit costs.
8. Give examples of shutdown costs.
9. Define relevant costs.
10. Illustrate and explain the learning curve effect.
11. Compute the break-even point.
12. Explain a cost-volume-profit (CVP) analysis.
13. Define the unit contribution margin.
14. Illustrate and discuss the operating leverage.

The costs of goods and services derive from the character of the process by which
they are produced. The analysis of cost behavior is founded, therefore, upon the
principles of production. This chapter translates the relationships among production
technology, inputs, and outputs into cost functions. The fundamental starting point in cost
analysis is that a functional relationship exists between the costs of production and the
rate of output per period of time.

COST FUNCTIONS
A cost function shows the various costs that will be incurred at various output
levels, i.e.,
Cost =f (output)
Further, the rate of output is, in turn, a function of the usage of the resource inputs:
Output =f(inputs)
Since the production function displays the relationships between input and output flows,
once the prices of the inputs are known, the costs of a specific quantity of output can be
determined.

As a result, the level and behavior of costs as a firm's rate of output changes relies
heavily on two factors: (1) the characteristic of the underlying production function and
(2) the prices paid for the inputs. The first determines the shape of the firm's cost
functions, while the second decides the level of costs. In the short run, at least one input is

137
fixed, so that a firm may not be able to achieve the best combination of inputs for its desired level of
output. Because of the presence of both fixed and variable costs in the short run, we can identify
seven different types of short-run cost curves: total fixed cost, total variable cost, total cost, average
fixed cost, average variable costs, average total cost, and marginal cost.

Note: In the long run, no resource costs are fixed. A firm can therefore vary the amount of any of its
inputs. In the short run, one or more inputs are fixed.

THE SET OF TOTAL COST CONCEPTS


Three concepts of total cost are important for analysis of a firm's cost structure in
the short run: total fixed cost (TFC), total variable cost (TVC), and total cost (TC).
Total fixed cost (TFC) is simply the sum of the quantities of the fixed inputs
multiplied by their associated prices. In the short run the level of total fixed costs is a
constant. Similarly, total variable cost (TVC) is the sum of the amounts a firm spends for
each of the variable inputs employed in the production process. Total variable cost is zero
when output is zero, because no variable inputs need be employed to produce nothing.
However, as output expands, the greater becomes the usage of variable inputs and the
greater is total variable cost.

The total cost (TC) of a given level of output in the short run is the sum of total
variable cost and total fixed cost:
TC = TVC + TFC
TVC are costs that vary in total in direct proportion to changes in activity. Examples are direct
materials and gasoline expense based on mileage driven. TFCs are costs that remain constant in
total regardless of changes in activity. Examples are rent, insurance, and taxes.

THE SET OF UNIT COST CONCEPTS


There are four major unit cost concepts: average fixed cost (AFC), average
variable cost (AVC), average total cost (ATC), and marginal cost (MC). All of these may
be derived from the total cost concepts discussed above.
Average variable cost (AVC) is total variable cost divided by the corresponding
number of units of output, or
AVC = TVC/Q
Average fixed cost (AFC) is defined as total fixed cost divided by the units of output, or
AFC = TFC/Q
Since total fixed cost is a constant amount, average fixed cost declines continuously as
the rate of production increases.

EXAMPLE 1
If TFC=$1,000, at an output of 10 units AFC= $1,000/10=$100; at an output of 20
units AFC=$1000/20= $50; at an output of 50 units AFC= $1000/50= $20; and so on.
The reduction of AFC by producing more units of output is what businesspeople
commonly call spreading the overhead.
Average total cost (ATC) is defined as total cost divided by the corresponding

138
units of output, or
ATC = TC/Q
However, since TC = TFC + TVC,

ATC = TC/Q = (TVC + TFC)/Q = TVC/Q + TFC/Q = AVC + AFC

Graphically, ATC is U-shaped because the AVC is an increasing function, while the AFC is a
continuously decreasing function of output.

MARGINAL COST
Marginal cost (MC) is the cost of producing an additional unit of output. For example, the
marginal cost of the 500th unit of output can be calculated by finding the difference in total cost at
499 units of output and total cost at 500 units of output. MC is thus the additional cost of one more
unit of output. MC is also the change in total variable cost associated with a unit change in output.
This is because total cost changes, whereas total fixed cost remains unchanged. MC may also be
thought of as the rate of change in total cost as the quantity (Q) of output changes and is simply the
first derivative of the total cost (TC) function. Thus,

MC = ∆TC/∆Q = dTC/dQ

Economists normally assume firms to be producing at a point at which marginal costs are positive
and rising. In managerial applications of this concept, MC is viewed as being equivalent to
incremental cost which is the increment in cost between the two alternatives or two discrete
volumes of output.

NOTE:
1. AFC is inversely related to the average product (AP) of the fixed inputs.
2. AVC is inversely related to the average product (AP) of the variable inputs.
3. MC is inversely related to the marginal product (MP) of added units of variable
inputs.
If L is variable input and w = its wage, then AVC = w/AP L; MC = w/MP L.

STAGES OF PRODUCTION AND SHORT-RUN COST CURVES


Figure 1 displays the relationship between a production function and the corresponding
short-run total and unit cost curves. The shape of the total cost curve is determined entirely
by the TVC curve, since fixed costs merely shift the total cost curve to a higher level.
This means that marginal costs are totally independent of fixed costs.
The TVC curve increases at a decreasing rate over the range of output where
increasing returns to variable input prevail (0 to Q 1 ). Over the range of output where
decreasing returns to variable input are encountered (Q 1 to Q 2 ) the TVC curve increases
at an increasing rate. The explanation for this behavior of TVC rests with the principle of
diminishing marginal returns (DMR). Where the quantity of output increases at an
increasing rate, marginal product (MP) is also increasing and smaller and smaller
increases in variable inputs are required to produce successive units of output. This
139
means that TVC will increase by progressively smaller amounts as output rises. But when
the point of DMR is encountered and MP starts to decline, it becomes necessary to use
larger and larger amounts of variable input to obtain equal increments of output. TVC
therefore increase at an increasing rate over this output range.

The AFC curve decreases continually as the quantity of output increases.


Geometrically speaking, the AFC curve is a rectangular hyperbola, meaning that the
curve approaches the vertical and horizontal axes asymptotically. In addition, were we to
pick any point on the AFC curve, draw lines perpendicular to the two axes, and calculate
the area of the resulting rectangle, this area will be the same irrespective of the point
chosen because this area measures AFC x Q which is equal to TFC, a constant value.
The AVC curve is U-shaped because of its inverse relationship with average product
(AP). When AP is rising, AVC must be falling, and that when AP is declining AVC must
be rising. Minimum AVC (an output of Q 2 ) corresponds to the output where AP is
maximum (X 2 units of variable input). It is at this output that the point of diminishing
average returns (DAR) is encountered and the Stage II phase of production begins. Thus
Stage I levels of output correspond to the output range where AVC is declining, whereas
Stage II quantities correspond to the range of output where AVC is rising.

The shape of the ATC curve is obtained by vertically summing the AFC and AVC
curves at each output. Because AFC decreases as output expands, the distance between
ATC and AVC gets progressively smaller. Thus, the ATC curve is asymptotic to the AVC
curve and is U-shaped.

FIGURE 1
PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS AND COST CURVES

140
Note: Panels (a) and (b) display the set of production function curves corresponding to the three
stages of production. Panel (c) represents the corresponding family of total cost functions. Panel (d)
shows the shapes of and relationships among various unit cost curves.

ATC continues to fall beyond the output where AVC is minimum because the con-
tinuing declines in AFC more than offset the slight increases in AVC. As output expands
further, however, the increases in AVC begin to override the decreases in AFC and ATC
turns upward. The minimum point on the ATC curve defines the most efficient output in
the short run.

141
The curvature of the MC function reflects its inverse relationship with MP: So
long as MP is rising, MC must be declining. But when diminishing marginal returns set
in, MC begins to rise. Hence, assuming a constant price for variable input, increasing
returns to variable input result in declining marginal costs and decreasing returns are
associated with rising marginal costs. Marginal cost is minimum at the point of DMR
where MP is maximum.

Furthermore, the MC curve intersects the AVC and ATC curves at their minimum
points—a relationship of mathematical necessity. When the cost of producing an
additional unit is less than the average total cost of the previously produced units, the
newly computed ATC will fall, being pulled down by the lower MC. Similarly, when the
cost of producing an additional unit is greater than the average total cost of the preceding
units, the new value of ATC rises, being pulled up by the higher value of MC. It follows
that ATC is minimum at the point of intersection of MC and ATC. By analogous
reasoning the MC curve must pass through the minimum point of the AVC function.
Figure 2 illustrates short-run cost curves.

NOTE:
1. The average-marginal relationship is the graphical relationship between corresponding
average and marginal curves. The relationship is the following: (1) When an average curve (AC)is
rising, its corresponding marginal curve (MC) lies above it, (2) when an AC is falling, its
corresponding MC lies below, and (3) when an AC is either at a maximum or minimum, its
corresponding MC equals AC.
2. Average costs tend to be U-shaped.
3. The symbols AC and ATC are used interchangeably.

LONG RUN COST CURVES - PLANNING CURVES


In the long run, the firm has complete input flexibility; therefore, all resource
inputs are variable. There are no total or average fixed costs in the long run since no
inputs are fixed, and the discussion of unit costs can be limited to just average costs.

Generally, a firm's long-run cost objective is to be in a position to produce the


desired output at the lowest possible cost. This means adjusting its scale of production so
as to be "the right size." Sometimes economies can be attained by dividing the production
process into smaller production units. Other times, lower unit costs can be achieved by
enlarging the scale of production. In examining how efficiency and costs are affected by
the scale of production, it is important to distinguish between plants and firms because
the cost efficiency advantages and disadvantages of each are different. Since there are no
TFC and AFC curves, we need look only at the nature and shape of the long-run average
cost (LRAC) curve.

142
FIGURE 2
SHORT-RUN COST CURVES: TOTAL, AVERAGE, AND MARGINAL COSTS
RELATIONSHIP

143
Suppose technological constraints allow a firm the choice of contracting any one
of three plant sizes: small, medium, and large. The short-run average cost (SRAC) curve
for each of these plant sizes is represented by SRAC S, SRAC M , and SRAC L in Figure 3.
Whatever size plant the firm has currently, in the long run it can convert to or construct
any one of these three plant scales. Certainly, the firm's choice of plant size is tailored by
its perceived need for future production capacity. For example, if the anticipated output
rate is 0Q 1 , the firm should elect to build the small-sized plant since it can produce 0Q 1
units of output per period of time at a cost of AC 1 , which is well below either the unit
cost of the medium-sized plant (AC 2 ) or the unit cost of the large-sized plant (AC 3 ). If the
expected output rate is 0Q 2 , the medium-sized plant plainly offers the lowest unit cost.
On the other hand, at an output of 0Q 3 the medium and large-sized plants are equally
efficient from a unit cost standpoint.

The portions of the three short-run average cost curves that are fitting for selecting
the optimum plant size are indicated by the solid, scalloped line in Figure 3. This line is
called the long run average cost curve (LRAC) and shows the minimum cost per unit of
producing each output when all resource inputs are variable and any desired scale of plant
can be built. The broken line segments of the SRAC curves all entail higher unit costs
than are capable of being achieved by operating along the LRAC curve.
In reality, a firm will have more than just three plant sizes to choose from. When
the number of alternative plant sizes approaches infinity, the LRAC curve is an
"envelope" of the short-run curves and is tangent to each of the short-run average cost
curves. This curve is the solid portion of each SRAC curve and is called the envelop or
planning curve .

The LRAC curve for a firm shows the minimum average cost of producing a
product for various firm sizes when the firm has adequate time to adjust any and all of its
inputs to optimal levels. By and large, the LRAC curves for both plants and firms are
U-shaped. The U-shape clearly implies that up to some output, being bigger can mean
greater efficiency and lower unit cost, but beyond this output larger plants and firms are
less efficient and entail higher unit costs.

The factors causing larger plants to be more efficient than smaller plants include
(1) more opportunity for specialization in the use of resource inputs; (2) the fact that the
most advanced and efficient technology is practical only when producing large volumes
of output; (3) the greater ability of larger plants to take advantage of and utilize
by-products; (4) the greater opportunities for larger plants to make volume purchases of
raw materials and thereby realize quantity discounts; and (5) the proportionately lower
costs of purchasing and installing larger machines and equipment. However, sooner or
later economies of scale will be exhausted and increases in plant size will result in
diseconomies of scale due to growing difficulties of maintaining efficient supervision and
coordination and the bottlenecks and costs of transporting materials, labor, and goods
from place to place within the plant.

144
NOTE:
1. SRAC curves relate costs and output for a specified scale of plant, while LRAC curves
identify optimal scales of plant for each production level.
2. The behavior of long-run costs is a key force in determining the number and
size of firms in a particular industry. Generally speaking, where there are significant
economies associated with mass-production technologies, the structure of an industry will
consist of a small number of large-scale producers. When there are few cost advantages
to producing in large quantities and many cost disadvantages, production units will be
large in number and small in size.

STATISTICAL COST ANALYSIS


Firms attempt to ascertain the nature of short-run or long-run cost/output relations. Cost
curves are estimated, via statistical techniques such as regression analysis, based on time-series or
cross-sectional data. Three types of functions--linear, quadratic, and cubic--especially the first two,
have been most commonly employed in fitting statistical cost functions. The choice of one or the
other depends largely on the extent to which the mathematical properties of the function represent
the economics of the particular case.

NOTE:
Although cost and production are clearly related, the nature of input prices must be
examined before any cost function can be related to the underlying production function. Input prices
and productivity jointly determine cost functions.

FIGURE 3
THE LONG-RUN AVERAGE COST CURVE AND PLANNING CURVE
145
TYPES OF COSTS
In accounting, the term "cost" is defined as a measurement, in monetary terms, of the
amount of resources used for some purpose. In economics, the term "cost" is used in many different
ways. Costs can be classified by criteria such as by behavior. Many of the cost concepts are useful
for managerial decision making and planning.

EXPLICIT AND IMPLICIT COSTS


Explicit costs are costs involving cash outlays--that is, out-of-pocket costs, while implicit
costs are costs that do not involve cash outlays and arise from the alternative use--that is
opportunity costs.

VARIABLE COSTS, FIXED COSTS, AND MIXED COSTS


From a managerial standpoint, perhaps the most important way to classify costs is by how
they behave in accordance with changes in volume or some measure of activity. By behavior, costs

146
can be classified into the following three basic categories: variable, fixed, and mixed (semivariable)
costs. Variable and fixed costs were defined previously. Mixed (or semi-variable) costs are costs that
vary with changes in volume but, unlike variable costs, do not vary in direct proportion. In other
words, these costs contain both a variable component and a fixed component. Examples are the
rental of a delivery truck, where a fixed rental fee plus a variable charge based on mileage is made;
and power costs, where the expense consists of a fixed amount plus a variable charge based on
consumption. The breakdown of costs into their variable components and their fixed components is
important in many areas of economics, such as break-even analysis, and short-term decision
making.

OPPORTUNITY COSTS
Opportunity costs are the net revenue foregone by rejecting the best alternative use of
resources such as time, money, or facilities. It is perhaps the most fundamental concept in
economics since it stresses the fact that all resources are generally limited and have alternative uses.
For example, assume a company has a choice of using its capacity to produce an extra 10,000 units
or renting it out for $20,000. The opportunity cost of using that capacity is $20,000. A further
example is the return foregone from having money tied up in accounts receivable for a longer time
because of a collection problem. If the extra funds tied up in receivables were $400,000 for a
three-month period and the firm could earn 10% per annum, the opportunity cost is $10,000
($400,000 x 3/12 x 10%).

OUT-OF-POCKET (OUTLAY) COSTS


Out-of-pocket (outlay) costs are expenditures by cash to carry on a particular activity. They
are the explicit costs that go into a firm's formal accounting records to arrive at a measure of
earnings, such as actual cash outlays made during the period for payroll, advertising, and other
operating expenses. Depreciation is not an out-of-pocket cost, since it involves no current cash
expenditure.

SUNK COSTS
Sunk costs are the costs of resources that have already been incurred at some point in the
past whose total will not be affected by any decision made now or in the future. Sunk costs are
usually past or historical costs. Sunk costs are therefore not relevant to future decisions. For
example, suppose you acquired a machine for $50,000 three years ago which has a book value of
$20,000. The $20,000 book value is a sunk cost which does not affect a future replacement decision.

INCREMENTAL (DIFFERENTIAL) COSTS


Incremental (differential) costs are costs associated with any managerial decision. This is
equivalent to the marginal cost concept but involves (1) multiple changes in output and discrete
output choices, rather than a single-unit change.

SHUTDOWN COSTS
Shutdown costs are those costs that would be incurred in the event of a temporary
suspension of activities and which could be saved if operations are allowed to continue. The concept
is important because of an economic principle that as long as a firm is at least covering its variable

147
costs, it will not discontinue operations in the short run since any surplus, known as contribution
margin, will be applied to the recovery of its fixed cost.

INCREMENTAL ANALYSIS VERSUS MARGINAL ANALYSIS


Incremental analysis is frequently used in the practical equivalent of marginal
analysis. It relates to a specified managerial decision which can involve a choice between
two discrete quantities of output (e.g., 10,000 units vs. 15,000 units). It is the process of
examining the impact of alternative choice decisions on revenue, cost, or profit. It
focuses attention on changes or differences between alternatives. Managers will have to
weigh the incremental cost associated with the decision against the incremental revenue. For this
reason, marginal analysis is more appropriately called incremental analysis. Not all costs are of
equal importance in decision making, and economists must identify these costs that are relevant to a
decision.

RELEVANT COSTS
In many business decision situations, the ultimate management decision rests on cost data
analysis. Cost data are important in many decisions, since they are the basis for profit calculations.
Cost data are classified by behavior patterns, and other criteria, as discussed previously.
However, not all costs are of equal importance in decision making, and managers must
identify the costs that are relevant to a decision. Such costs are called relevant costs. The relevant
costs are the expected future costs (and also revenues) which differ between the decision
alternatives. Therefore, sunk costs (past and historical costs) are not considered relevant in the
decision at hand. What is relevant are the incremental (or differential) costs.

Under the concept of relevant costs, which may be appropriately titled the incremental,
differential, or relevant cost approach, the decision involves the following steps:
1. Gather all costs associated with each alternative.
2. Drop the sunk costs.
3. Drop those costs which do not differ between alternatives.
4. Select the best alternative based on the remaining cost data.

EXAMPLE 2
To illustrate the irrelevance of sunk costs and the relevance of incremental costs, let us
consider a replacement decision problem. A company owns a milling machine that was purchased
three years ago for $25,000. Its present book value is $17,500. The company is contemplating
replacing this machine with a new one which will cost $50,000 and have a five-year useful life. The
new machine will generate the same amount of revenue as the old one but will substantially cut
down on variable operating costs. Annual sales and operating costs of the present machine and the
proposed replacement are based on normal sales volume of 20,000 units and are estimated as
follows:

Present Machine New Machine


Sales $60,000 $60,000
Variable Costs 35,000 20,000

148
Fixed Costs:
Depreciation (straight-line) 2,500 10,000
Insurance, Taxes, etc. 4,000 4,000
Net Income $18,500 $26,000

At first glance, it appears that the new machine provides an increase in net income of $7,500
per year. The book value of the present machine, however, is a sunk cost and is irrelevant in this
decision. Furthermore, sales and fixed costs such as insurance, taxes, etc., also are irrelevant since
they do not differ between the two alternatives being considered. Eliminating all the irrelevant costs
leaves us with only the incremental costs, as follows.

Savings in variable costs $15,000


Less: Increase in Fixed Costs 10,000 *
Net Annual Cash Saving Arising
from the New Machine $5,000
---------------------------------
*exclusive of $2,500 sunk cost

The relevant cost approach assists managers in making important decisions such as whether to
accept a below-normal selling price, which products to emphasize, whether to make or buy, whether
to sell or process further, how to formulate a bid price on a contract, and how to optimize utilization
of capacity. Table 1 summarizes guidelines for typical short-term decisions.

149
TABLE 1
DECISION GUIDELINES

Decision Description Decision Guidelines


• Special order Should a discount-priced If regular orders are not affected,
order be accepted when accept order when the revenue from
there is idle capacity? the order exceeds the incremental cost.
Fixed costs are usually irrelevant.
• Make or buy Should a part be made or Choose lower-cost option.
bought from a vendor? Fixed costs are usually irrelevant.
Often opportunity costs are present.

• Closing a segment Should a segment be dropped? Compare loss in contribution margin with
savings in fixed costs.

• Sell or process Should joint products be sold Ignore joint costs. Process further
further at split-off or processed further? if incremental revenue exceeds incremental cost.

• Scarce resources Which products should be Emphasize products with highest


emphasized when resources contribution margin (CM) per unit of scarce
are limited? resource (e.g., CM per machine hour).

LEARNING CURVE
In manufacturing, labor hours are often observed to decrease in a definite pattern as
labor operations are repeated. More specifically, as the cumulative production doubles, the
cumulative average time required per unit will be reduced by some constant percentage,
ranging typically from 10 percent to 20 percent. This reduction, and hence related costs, is
referred to as the learning curve effect.
By convention, learning curves are referred to in terms of the complements of their
improvement rates. For example, an 80 percent learning curve denotes a 20 percent decrease
in unit time with each doubling of repetitions.

EXAMPLE 3
Suppose that a project is known to have an 80 percent learning curve. It has just taken
a laborer 10 hours to produce the first unit. Then each time the cumulative output doubles, the
time per unit for that amount should be equal to the previous time multiplied by the learning
percentage. An 80 percent learning curve is shown in Figure 4.

Unit Unit time (hours)

1 10
2 0.8(10) = 8
4 0.8(8) = 6.4
8 0.8(6.4) = 5.12
16 0.8(5.12) = 4.096

150
The learning curve model is as follows:
yn = a n- b

where yn = Time for the nth unit


a = Time for the first unit (in this example, 10 hours)
b = The index of the rate of increase in productivity during learning (Log learning
rate %/log 2)

To be able to utilize linear regression, we need to convert this power (or exponential) function
form into a linear form by taking a log of both sides, which yields:
Log yn = log a - b log n
The learning rate, which is indicated by b, is estimated using least-squares regression, with
the sample data on y and n. Note that
Log (learning rate)
b= -------------------
Log 2
which means:
Log (learning rate) = b x log 2
The unit time (i.e., the number of labor hours required) for the nth can be computed using the
estimated model:
yn = a n- b

FIGURE 4
AN 80% LEARNING CURVE

151
NOTE:
This learning phenomenon is observed in the behavior of labor and labor
driven overhead. Material costs per unit may also be subject to this effect if less
scrap and waste occur as a result of learning.

EXAMPLE 4
For an 80 percent curve with a = 10 hours, the time for the third unit would be
computed as:
y3 = 10 (3 - log .8/ log 2 ) = 10 (3-..3219 ) = 7.02
Fortunately, it is not necessary to grind through this model each time a learning calculation is
made; values can be found using Table 6 (Learning Curve Coefficients) in the Appendix. The
time for the nth unit can be quickly determined by multiplying the table value by the time
required for the first unit.

EXAMPLE 5
NB Contractors, Inc. is negotiating a contract involving production of 20 jets. The
initial jet requires 200 labor-days of direct labor. Assuming an 80 percent learning curve, we
will determine the expected number of labor-days for (1) the 20th jet, and (2) all 20 jets as
follows:
Using Table 7 with n=20 and an 80 percent learning rate, we find: Unit=.381 and
Total=10,485. Therefore,
(1) Expected time for the 20th jet = 200 (.381)= 76.2 labor-days.
(2) Expected total time for all 20 jets = 200(10.485) =2,097 labor-days.

NOTE:
The learning curve theory has found useful applications in many areas, including:
1. Budgeting, purchasing, and inventory planning
2. Scheduling labor requirements
3. Setting incentive wage rates
4. Pricing new products
5. Negotiated purchasing
6. Evaluating suppliers’ price quotations

Example 6 illustrates the use of the learning curve theory for the pricing of a contract.
EXAMPLE 6
Big Mac Electronics Products, Inc. finds that new product production is affected by an
80 percent learning effect. The company has just produced 50 units of output at 100 hours per
unit. Costs were as follows:

Materials 50 units @$20 $1,000


Labor and labor-related costs:
Direct labor -- 100 hours @$8 800
Variable overhead -- 100 hours @$2 200
$2,000

152
The company has just received a contract calling for another 50 units of production. It
wants to add a 50 percent markup to the cost of materials and labor and labor-related costs. To
determine the price for this job, the first step is to build up the learning curve table.

Quantity Total time (hours) Average time (per unit)


50 100 2 hours
100 160 1.6 (.8 x 2 hours)

Thus, for the new 50 unit job, it takes 60 hours in total. The contract price is:
Materials 50 units @$20 $1,000
Labor and labor-related costs:
Direct labor -- 60 hours @$8 480
Variable overhead -- 60 hours @$2 120
$1,600
50 percent markup 800
Contract price $2,400

COST-VOLUME-PROFIT AND BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS


Cost-volume-profit (CVP) analysis allows managers to perform many useful
analyses. CVP analysis deals with how profit and costs change with a change in
volume. More specifically, it looks at the effects on profits of changes in such
factors as variable costs, fixed costs, selling prices, volume, and mix of products
sold. By studying the relationships of costs, sales, and net income, management is
better able to cope with many planning decisions. Break-even analysis , a branch of
CVP analysis, determines the break-even sales. Break-even point--the financial
crossover point when revenues exactly match costs--does not show up in corporate
earnings reports, but managers find it an extremely useful measurement in a variety
of ways.

BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS
The break-even point represents the level of sales revenue that equals the
total of the variable and fixed costs for a given volume of output at a particular
capacity use rate. For example, you might want to ask the break-even occupancy
rate (or vacancy rate) for a hotel or the break-even load rate for an airliner.
Generally, the lower the break-even point, the higher the profit and the less the
operating risk, other things being equal. The break-even point also provides
managers with insights into profit planning.

The equation approach is based on the cost-volume-profit equation which


shows the relationships among sales, variable and fixed costs, and net income.

TR = TVC + TFC + Net Income

At the break-even volume, TR = TVC + TFC + 0. Defining Q = volume in units , the


above relationship can be written in terms of Q:

153
PQ = AVC Q + TFC
(P - AVC)Q = TFC
Solving for Q yields the following formula for break-even sales volume:

TFC Total Fixed costs


Q= ------------ = -----------------
(P - AVC) Unit CM

Without proof, we can obtain the formula for break-even sales in dollars (S), as
follows:

Total Fixed costs


S= --------------------
CM ratio

NOTE:
The break-even analysis assumes: constant price, constant variable cost per
unit, and constant sales mix. Strictly speaking, it is linear break-even analysis.

EXAMPLE 7
The Wayne Company manufactures and sells doors to homebuilders. The
doors are sold for $25 each. Variable costs are $15 per door, and fixed operating
costs total $10,000. The following income (profit/loss) statement is based on a
projected sales of 2,000 units::
Total Per Unit Percentage
Sales (2,000 units) $50,000 $25 100%
Less: Variable costs 30,000 15 60
Contribution $20,000 $10 40%
margin
Less: Fixed costs 5,000
Net income $15,000

Note that (P - AVC) =($25 - $15) = $10 and (P - AVC)/P =($25 - $15)/$25 =
40%
Break-even point in units = $5,000/$10 = 500 units
Break-even point in dollars = 500 x $25 = $12,500. Alternatively,
$5,000/40% = $12,500

DETERMINATION OF TARGET INCOME VOLUME


Besides determining the break-even point, CVP analysis determines the
sales required to attain a particular income level or target net income. The formula
is:
Target income sales volume = Total fixed costs plus Target income / Unit CM

EXAMPLE 8

154
Using the same data given in Example 7, assume that the firm wishes to
attain a target income of $15,000. Then, the target income volume would be:
($5,000 + $15,000) / ($25 - $15) = $20,000 / $10 = 2,000 units

GRAPHICAL APPROACH IN A SPREADSHEET FORMAT


The graphical approach to obtaining the break-even point is based on the
so-called break-even (B-E) chart as shown in Figure 5. Sales revenue, variable
costs, and fixed costs are plotted on the vertical axis while volume, x, is plotted on
the horizontal axis. The break-even point is the point where the total sales revenue
line intersects the total cost line. The chart can also effectively report profit
potentials over a wide range of activity and therefore be used as a tool for
discussion and presentation.

OPERATING LEVERAGE
Leverage is that portion of the fixed costs which represents a risk to the firm.
Operating leverage, a measure of operating risk, refers to the fixed operating costs
found in the firm's income statement. Operating leverage is a measure of
operating risk and arises from fixed operating costs. A simple indication of
operating leverage is the effect that a change in sales has on operating income.

FIGURE 5
BREAK-EVEN CHART

The formula is:

Operating leverage at a given level of sales (Q)

Percentage change in operating income

155
= -----------------------------------------
Percentage change in sales

(P - AVC) ∆Q / (P - AVC)Q - TFC


=
∆Q / Q

(P - AVC)Q
=
(P - AVC)Q - TFC

EXAMPLE 9
Assume from Example 7 that the Wayne Company is currently selling 6,000
doors per year. Its operating leverage is:

(P - AVC) ($25 - $15)(6,000) $60,000


---------------- = --------------------------- = --------- = 1.2
(P - AVC)Q - TFC ($25 - $15)(6,000) - $10,00 $50,000
0

which means if sales increase (decrease) by 1 percent, the company can expect its
net income to increase (decrease) by 1.2 times that amount, or 1.2 percent.

NOTE:
Operating leverage is an elasticity measure, since it is the ratio of a
percentage change in operating income to a percentage change in sales.

QUESTIONS
1. Describe the graphical relationship between corresponding average cost (AC) and
marginal cost (MC) curves.
2. List the factors causing larger plants to be more efficient than smaller plants.
3. What is the managerial implication of planning curves (long-run cost curves)?
4. What does statistical cost analysis involve?
5. List the basic steps involved in incremental or relevant cost analysis.
6. Distinguish between incremental analysis and marginal analysis.
7. Give some examples of learning curve applications.
8. What is cost-volume-profit (CVP) analysis? How it is useful to managers?
9. List some assumptions underlying break-even analysis. What is the distinction
between a manager’s break-even analysis and an economist’s break-even analysis?
10. How do you measure operating risk?

156
PROBLEMS
1. Given the cost function for your firm: TC =40 + 4Q + 2Q2
(a) What is the average fixed cost (AFC) of producing 5 units of output?
(b) What is the average variable cost (AVC) of producing 5 units of output?
(c) What are the average total cost (ATC) and marginal cost (MC) of producing 5 units of
output?

2. Given the following total cost (TC) function:


200 + 75Q - 1.5Q2 + .01Q3

(a) Calculate the marginal cost (MC), average variable cost (AVC), average cost (AC), and
average fixed cost (AFC) functions.
(b) At what level of output does MC reach its minimum? AVC?
(c) Determine MC and AVC when AVC is at its minimum.
(d) Prove that short-run MC equals AVC when AVC is at its minimum.

3. A firm has the following short-run total cost function:


TC = 3,000 + 240Q - 7Q2 + Q3

(a) Write the equations for the firm’s marginal cost (MC), average variable cost (AVC), and
average total cost (ATC).
(b) Determine the output level at which MC will be minimized.
(c) Determine the output level at which AVC will be minimized.

4. A firm estimates its selling and administrative costs as


TC = $45,000 + $60Q + 3Q2
where Q = sales volume in units.

(a) What is the level of fixed selling and administrative costs?


(b) Calculate average cost at Q = 50.
(c) Calculate the level of output at which average costs would be minimized.

5. Janus Costing Inc., a leading maker of coatings, has estimated the following statistical
function for its weekly total cost over the past 26 weeks:
2
TC = $150,000 + $7Q + 0.006Q
(70,000) (2) (0.001)

2
r = 0.90
Se (standard error of the estimate) = 7.888

where Q = gallons of enamel and standard errors of the regression coefficients are in
parentheses.

(a) Comment on the result based on the regression statistics given.

157
(b) Calculate the average cost and comment on it.

6. Carson, Inc., uses a learning curve of 80 percent for all new products it develops. A trial
run of 500 units of a new product shows total labor-related costs (direct labor, indirect labor,
and fringe benefits) of $120,000. Management plans to produce 1,500 units of the new
product during the next year.

(a). Compute the expected labor-related costs for the year to produce the 1,500 units.
(b). Find the unit cost of production for next year for labor-related costs.

7. The Hunt Company has recently purchased a plant to manufacture a new product. The
following data pertain to the new operation:

Estimated annual sales 3,500 unit @ $20


Estimated Costs:
Direct materials $6.00/unit
Direct labor $1.00/unit
Factory overhead (all fixed) $12,000 per year
Selling expenses 30% sales
Administrative expenses (all fixed) $16,000 per year

(a) Determine the break-even point in units and in dollars.


(b) Determine the selling price if profit per unit is $2.04.
(c) What is the firm’s degree of operating leverage at 5,000 units?

8. The Norman Company has an annual plant capacity of 25,000 units. Predicted data on
sales and costs are given below:

Sales (20,000 units @$50) $1,000,000


Manufacturing costs:
Variable
(materials, labor, and overhead) $40 per unit
Fixed overhead $30,000
Selling and administrative expenses;
Variable
(sales commission - $1 per unit) $2 per unit
Fixed $7,000

A special order has been received from outside for 4,000 units at a selling price of $45 each.
The order will have no effect on regular sales. The usual sales commission on this order will
be reduced by one-half. Should the company accept the order? Show supporting
computations, using incremental analysis based on the concept of relevant cost.

ANSWERS
1. The average-marginal relationship between corresponding average and marginal curves is
the following: (1) When an average curve (AC) is rising, its corresponding marginal curve

158
(MC) lies above it, (2) when an AC is falling, its corresponding MC lies below, and (3) when
an AC is either at a maximum or minimum, its corresponding MC equals AC.
2. The factors causing larger plants to be more efficient than smaller plants include
(1) more opportunity for specialization in the use of resource inputs; (2) the fact
that the most advanced and efficient technology is practical only when producing
large volumes of output; (3) the greater ability of larger plants to take advantage of
and utilize by-products; (4) the greater opportunities for larger plants to make
volume purchases of raw materials and thereby realize quantity discounts; and (5)
the proportionately lower costs of purchasing and installing larger machines and
equipment.
3. A planning curve is a locus of points representing the least unit cost of producing the
corresponding output. Firms determine the size of plant by reference to this curve.
4. Statistical cost analysis is an empirical attempt to ascertain the nature of short-run or long-
run cost/output relations. Cost curves are estimated, via statistical techniques such as
regression analysis, based on time-series or cross-sectional data. Three types of functions--
linear, quadratic, and cubic--especially the first two, have been most commonly employed in
fitting statistical cost functions. The choice of one or the other depends largely on the extent to
which the mathematical properties of the function represent the economics of the particular
case.
5. The incremental, differential, or relevant cost approach involves the following steps:
1. Gather all costs associated with each alternative.
2. Drop the sunk costs.
3. Drop those costs which do not differ between alternatives.
4. Select the best alternative based on the remaining cost data.
6. Incremental analysis is frequently used in the practical equivalent of marginal
analysis. It relates to a specified managerial decision which can involve a choice
between two discrete quantities of output (e.g., 10,000 units vs. 15,000 units), while
marginal analysis focuses on the impact on revenue or costs of one unit change in
volume.
7. The learning curve theory has found useful applications in many areas, including: (a)
Budgeting, purchasing, and inventory planning, (b) scheduling labor requirements, (c) setting
incentive wage rates, (d) pricing new products, and (e) evaluating suppliers’ price quotations.
8. Cost-volume-profit (CVP) analysis helps managers perform many useful
analyses. It allows managers to look at the effects on profits of changes in such
factors as variable costs, fixed costs, selling prices, volume, and mix of products
sold.
9. A manager’s break-even analysis assumes: constant price, constant variable cost
per unit, and constant sales mix. Strictly speaking, it is linear break-even analysis.
On the other hand, an economist’s break-even analysis may produce more than one
break-even sales volume.
10. Operating leverage is used to measure operating risk. It tells you how sensitive
income is to a change in sales. It is essentially an elasticity measure, since it is the
ratio of a percentage change in operating income to a percentage change in sales.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS

159
1.

(a) FC =40 ; AFC = FC/Q = 40/5 = $8


2
(b) VC = 4Q + 2Q ; AVC = VC/Q = = 4 + 2Q = 4 + 2(5) = $14
(c) ATC = AVC + AFC = $14 + $8 = $22; MC = dTC/dQ = 4 + 4Q = 4 + 4(5) = $24

2.
2
(a) MC = d TC/ d Q = 75 - 3Q + .03Q
2
AVC = TVC/Q = 75 - 1.5Q + .01Q
2
AC = TC/Q = 200/Q + 75 - 1.5Q + .01Q
AFC = 200/Q
2
(b) MC = d TC/ d Q = 75 - 3Q + .03Q
d MC/ d Q = -3 + .06Q = 0; Q = 50, so MC is minimized at an output level of 50
units.
2
AVC = TVC/Q = 75 - 1.5Q + .01Q
d AVC/ d Q = -1.5 + .02Q = 0; Q = 75, so AVC is minimized at an output level of 75
units.
AFC = 200/Q

(c) From part (b), Q = 75 when AVC is minimized


2 2
AVC = 75 - 1.5Q + .01Q = 75 - 1.5(75) + .01(75) = 75 - 112.5 + 56.25 = 18.75
2 2
MC = 75 - 3Q + .03Q = 75 - 3(75) + .-3(75) = 75 - 225 + 168.75 = 18.75.

(d) MC = AVC = 18.75 This proves that MC equals AVC when AVC is at its
minimum in a short-run situation.

3.
2
(a) MC = d TC/ d Q = 240 - 14Q + 3Q
2
AVC = TVC/Q = 240 - 7Q + Q
2
ATC = TC/Q = 3,000/Q +240Q - 7Q + Q
2
(b) From part (a), MC = 240 - 14Q + 3Q
d MC/ d Q = -14 + 6Q = 0; Q = 2.33
2
(c) From part (a), AVC = 240 - 7Q + Q
d AVC/ d Q = -7 + 2Q = 0; Q = 3.5

4.

(a) $45,000, which is the intercept term for TC at Q = 0.

160
(b) ATC = TC/Q = 45000/Q + 60 + 3Q = 45000/50 + 60 + 3(50) = $1,110.

(c) Set dATC/dQ = 0;

2 2
dATC/dQ =-45000/Q + 3 = 0; Q = 45000/3 = 15000; Q = = 122.
2 2 3
Note d ATC/dQ = 45000/Q > 0, Q = 122 is at a minimum.

5.
2
(a) r = 0.90 implying that this quadratic cost model accounts for 90 percent of total cost. It is
a good fit. t-statistic for each coefficient (7/2 = 3.5 and .006/0001 - 6) exceeds the t-table
value = 2.069 (at a 5% level and n - k = 26 - 3 = 23 degrees of freedom). So these coefficient
estimates are reliable.

(b) ATC = TC/Q = 150000/Q + 7 + .0006Q.


Thus we see that AC will first fall, then rise as output expands, and will be “U-shaped.”

6.

(a) The 80 percent learning theory says that as cumulative quantities double, average time per
unit falls to only 80 percent of the previous time. Therefore, the following data can be
constructed:

Quantity Time Cost Average Cost per Unit


500 units $120,000 $240 per unit
1,000 192,000 192 (80% x $240)
2,000 308,000 154 (80% x $192)

Thus,

Quantity Total Cost


2,000 $308,000
500 120,000
1,500 $188,000

(b) Thus expected labor-related costs for the 1,500 units of output is $188,000 and $125.33
per unit ($188,000/1,500 units).

7.

(a)
Variable Costs
Direct materials $ 6.00
Direct labor 1.00
Selling expenses 6.00
$13.00 per unit

161
Fixed Costs
Factory overhead $12,000
Administrative 16,000
$28,000

Break even point in units = $28,000/($20 - $13) = $4,000 units


Break-even point in dollars = 4,000 units x $20 = $80,000

(b) TR = TVC + TFC + Net Income

Let P = the selling price


then, 3,500P = $7(3,500) + .3P(3,500) + 28,000 + 2.04(3,500)
2,450P = $59,640
P = $24.34

(c) Its operating leverage is:

(P - AVC) ($20 - $13)(5,000) $35,000


-------------------- = ----------------------------- = -------- =5
(P - AVC)Q - TFC ($20 - $13)(5,000) - $28,00 $ 7,000
0

which means if sales increase (decrease) by 1 percent, the company can expect its
net income to increase (decrease) by 5 times that amount, or 5 percent.

8.

Note that fixed costs will continue regardless and therefore are irrelevant to this
decision.

Incremental revenue (4,000 units @ $45) $180,000


Less: Incremental costs
Variable manufacturing
(4,000 units @$40) 160,000
Variable selling and administrative
(4,000 @ $1.50*) 6,000
Incremental gain in favor of accepting the order $14,000

* $1.50 = $2 (variable selling and administrative expenses) - $.50 (sales commission to


be saved)

162
CHAPTER 9
MARKETS AND THE BEHAVIOR OF THE FIRM

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Explain the conditions for perfect competition.


2. Illustrate monopolistic competition.
3. Define and discuss Oligopoly.
4. Compute the four-firm concentration ratio.
5. Illustrate and implement the concepts related to Herfindahl-Hirshman.
6. Explain the Rothschild Index
7. Compute the Lerner Index.

Market structure refers to such factors as the number of firms in an industry, the
relative size of the firms (industry concentration), demand conditions, ease of entry and exit,
and technological and cost conditions. Different industries have different structures, and these
influence the decisions to be made by the manager. Competition proceeds along different
lines, depending on whether there are many or few firms in the industry and whether their
products are identical or differentiated. From this standpoint, four main forms of market
structure and types of competition exist:

1. Perfect competition: many sellers of a standardized product.


2. Monopolistic competition: many sellers of a differentiated product.
3. Oligopoly: few sellers of either a standardized or a differentiated product.
4. Monopoly: a single seller of a product for which there is no close substitute.

PERFECT COMPETITION
Perfect competition is an economic model or market structure possessing the
following characteristics: (1) each firm is so small relative to the market that it can exert no
perceptible influence on price; (2) the product is homogeneous; (3) there is free mobility of all
resources, including free entry and exit of firms into and out of the industry; and (4) all buyers
and sellers in the market possess complete and perfect knowledge.

A firm in a perfectly competitive industry operates at an output level where price (or
marginal revenue) equals marginal cost and profits are maximized (see Figure 1). In reality,
there is no industry that is perfectly competitive. Empirical evidence suggests that agricultural
and lumber industries provide close approximations to perfect competition.

EXAMPLE 1
If P = $10 then TR = PQ = $10Q and MR = $10 (Note that this indicates MR = P in a
perfectly competitive market). Assuming TC = 6 + 4Q + Q2, then MC = dTC/dQ = 4 + 2Q.
Total profit is: π = TR – TC = 10Q – (6 + 4Q + Q2) = -6 + 6Q – Q2.

163
In order to maximize π we take the derivative of π with respect to Q, set it equal to zero, and
solve for Q: dπ/dQ = 6 –2Q = 0; Q = 3 units.

LONG-RUN
In the short run, a firm should continue operating as long as selling price exceeds
average variable cost (a contribution margin is earned). If selling price drops below average
variable cost, variable costs as well as fixed costs are no longer being met, and the firm
should shut down. Under pure competition, the portion of a firm's marginal cost (MC) curve
above its average variable cost curve (the firm cannot cover its variable costs below this
shutdown point) is also its supply curve in the short run. Because the firm is a price taker [the
marginal revenue (MR) curve is horizontal], increases in supply can occur only at higher
prices because the firm produces at the level at which MR equals MC.

In the long-run, all inputs are free to vary. Average cost will tend to be just equal to
price and all excessive profits will be eliminated. If P exceeds AC, more firms will enter the
market, supply will increase, and price will be driven down to the equilibrium, zero-profit
level (see Figure 2). It is economic profit that is zero at long run equilibrium; the accounting
profit likely will be positive.

In summary, at the long-run profit-maximizing level of output under perfect


competition. equilibrium will be achieved at a point where P = MR = MC = AC, and the firm
is producing at its most efficient level of output; i.e., where long-run average costs are
minimized.

FIGURE 1
PERFECT COMPETITION – SHORT-RUN EQUILIBRIUM

164
FIGURE 2
PERFECT COMPETITION – LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
The distinguishing features of monopolistic competition are that there are (1)
many small, owner managed firms selling differentiated, yet similar, products; (2)
each firm has the ability to influence its sales by changing its prices; (3) each firm
has downsloping, but highly elastic, demand curves; (4) a firm can enter and leave
the industry with relative ease; (5) the actions of any one firm have a small effect
upon rival firms; and (6) firms behave as if they seek to maximize profits.
The firm in monopolistic competition has three basic strategies for pursuing
its principal goal of maximum profits— price changes, variations in its product, and
promotional activity. Like every type of firm, a firm in monopolistic competition
will maximize short run profits by producing at the output rate where MR= MC.

OLIGOPOLY
Markets are said to be oligopolistic whenever a small number of firms supply
the dominant share of an industry's total output. The interdependence among
oligopolists extends to all facets of competition: price, output, promotional
strategies, innovation, customer service policies, acquisitions and mergers, and so
on. Since rival firms may have numerous alternative courses of action, anticipating
their actions and reactions introduces a new and exceedingly complex dimension to
the firm's decision process. But trying to anticipate the competitive response of
rival firms is an exercise no oligopolist can afford to neglect, for the probability is
high that a change in a firm's competitive tactics will elicit prompt and pointed
reactions from rival firms. The great uncertainty is how one's rivals will react.

For this reason, there is no nice, neat, clear-cut equilibrium position toward
which all firms tend to move—such as we found in perfect competition and

165
monopolistic competition. In oligopoly, a wide variety of materially different
competitive circumstances can and do exist, no one of which is demonstrably more
typical than others. As a consequence, oligopoly theory consists of dozens of
models, each depicting certain facets of oligopolistic conduct and performance, but
none telling a complete story of competition among the few.

GAME THEORY
Game theory deals with competitive situations where two or more participants
pursue conflicting objectives. The theory attempts to provide optimal strategies for the
participants. In games, the participants are competitors; the success of one is usually at the
expense of the other. Each company selects and executes those strategies which he believes
will result in "winning the game." This theory attempts to explain the price-output decisions
of firms in oligopolistic industries and the labor contract negotiations between management
and labor. There are many different types of games which reflect different conflict situations.
A two-person, zero-sum game is an example. In this game, the participants have exactly
opposite interests; that is, one player’s gain is the other player’s loss.

EXAMPLE 2
A two-person game can be represented in a matrix format. Assume that two rival
firms are considering advertising or product differentiation strategies that will have
predictable effects on the share of the total market obtained by each.

PAYOFF MATRIX FOR A TWO-FIRM, ZERO-SUM GAME


(Outcomes in terms of Firm A’s percentage share of Market)
B’s Strategy

A’s Strategy B1 B2 B3 Value of game


B
A1 85 60 45A
B B A
A2 80 70 55 55
A3 15A 35 50

It has been shown in theory that a two-person, zero-sum game will have a
determinate solution as long as a specific rule, known as the minimax principle,
holds and mixed strategies are permitted. This principle assumes that for each
strategy one chooses, the opposition will choose a strategy that maximizes its share
of the payoff. Therefore, one chooses a strategy that minimizes the opponent’s
maximum gain. To illustrate, in the above example,

(a) A will choose strategy A 2 B3 = 55, which is mathematically

max min aij = A 2 B3 = 55


i j

It indicates that A should choose the strategy which maximizes the minimum payoff
associated with each row of the game matrix (places the letter A in the upper right-
hand corner)

166
(b) B will choose strategy A 2 B3 = 55, which is mathematically

min max aij = A 2 B3 = 55


j i

which indicates B should choose the strategy which minimizes the maximum payoff
(placed the letter B in the upper left-hand corner).

(c) Whenever A’s minimum gain is equal to B’s maximum loss or, in other
words, when

max min aij = min max aij = ai*j* = v = A 2 B3 = 55


i j j i

The game is said to have a saddle point or equilibrium at (i*, j*) and the value of
the game (v) is equal to ai*j*. For the example (i*=2, j*=3) constitutes a saddle point
and the value of the game (v) is equal to 55% market share.

MONOPOLY
A key difference between the market situation confronting a pure monopolist
and that confronting other enterprises is that the firm's demand curve coincides with
the industry demand curve. The firm is the industry. The price-output decision for a
profit-maximizing monopolist is illustrated in Figure 3.

Just as in the case of perfect competition, profit is maximized at the price


output combination where MR = MC. Apparently, for a negative-sloping demand
curve (e.g., P = a –bQ), the MR function is not the same as the demand function. If
P = a –bQ then TR = PQ = aQ –bQ 2 and MR = a –2bQ. So the slope of the demand
function is –b, and the MR function –2b.

FIGURE 3

167
MONOPOLIST’S EQUILIBRIUM

EXAMPLE 3
Assume a monopolist is faced with the demand function,

Q = 400 –2P (or P = 200 - 0.5Q) and TC = 35Q + 0.05Q 2

The profit-maximizing output will be at MR =MC.


First, TR = PQ = (200 - 0.5Q)Q = 200Q - 0.5Q 2 . So MR = 200 - Q

Note that MC = 35 + 0.1Q

Setting MR = MC yields 200 - Q = 35 + 0.1Q; Q = 150 units


Substituting Q = 136 back into the demand function yields:

P = 200 - 0.5Q = 200 - 0.5Q(150) = $125

Hence, the profit-maximizing monopolist would produce 150 units and charge a
price of $125 each. This yields a profit of

π = TR – TC = PQ - (35Q + 0.05Q 2 ) = ($125)(150) – [(35(150) + 0.05(150)2 ] =


$12,375.

INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION
Different industries have different market structures, and these influence the decisions
to be made by the manager. The following provides an overview of the major structural
variables and how they are measured.

168
MEASURES OF INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION
There are two common measures used to gauge the degree of concentration in an
industry. (1) Concentration Ratios and (2) Herfindahl-Hirshman Index.

Concentration Ratios
Concentration ratios measure how much of the total output in an industry is manufactured by
the largest firms in that industry. A high concentration ratio is an indicator of monopolistic
power. The most popular concentration ratio is the four-firm concentration ratio (C4). It is the
fraction of total industry sales produced by the four largest firms in the industry. The ratio is
given by
C4 = (S1 + S2 + S3 + S4)/ST = w1 + w2 + w3 + w4

where ST = the total sales of all firms in the industry, S1, S2, S3, and S4 = the sales of the four
largest firms, and w1, w2,, w3, and w4 = market shares of the four largest firms.

EXAMPLE 4
An industry is made up of six firms. Four firms have sales of $1 million each,
and two firms have sales of $500,000 each. Then the four-firm concentration ratio
for this industry is 80%, as computed below.
Total industry sales are S T = $5 million. The sales of the four largest firms =
$4 million. The ratio is $4 million/$ 5 million = .8 = 80%

Herfindahl-Hirshman Index
The Herfindahl-Hirshman Index (HHI) is the sum of the squared market shares
multiplied by 10,000 to eliminate the need for decimals.

10,000 Σ w i 2

By squaring the market shares before adding them up, the index weights firms with
high market shares more heavily.

EXAMPLE 5
Suppose an industry consists of three firms. Two firms have sales of
$1million each, and one firm has sales of $3 million. Since total industry sales are
S T = $5 million, the largest firm has a market share of .6 = 3/5 and the other two
firms have a market share of .2 = 1/5 each. Thus, the Herfindahl-Hirshman index for
this industry is

10,000[(.6)2 + (.2)2 + (.2)2 ] = 4,400

Note that the four-firm concentration ratio is 1, since the top three firms account for
all industry sales.

NOTE:
1. Four-firm concentration ratios are between 0 and 1. Being close to 0
indicates markets in which there are many sellers, giving rise to much competition,

169
while being close to 1 indicates markets in which there is little competition among
producers for sales to consumers.
2. The value of the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index lies between 0 and 10,000. A
value of 10,000 exists when a monopolist exists in the industry. A value of zero
results when there are numerous infinitesimally small firms.

EXAMPLE 6 (Antitrust guidelines)


In an effort to provide guidelines as to what type of business combinations
would and would not be challenged in antitrust actions, the Justice Department uses
the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index. It essentially breaks all business combinations into
the three broad types: horizontal integration, vertical integration, and
conglomeration.

Market Share Squared Likelihood of Challenge


Less than 1,000 Unlikely
1,000 – 1,800 Possible
More than 1,800 Likely

Consider this hypothetical market share breakdown in the widget industry:

Widget Industry Market Share Data


Market Share Market Share Squared
Company A 41% 1,681
Company B 26% 676
Company C 18% 324
Company D 8% 64
Company E 5% 25
Company F 2% 4

Note: The Federal Trade Commission (FTC), in conjunction with the antitrust
division of the Justice Department, has broad authority to enforce the antitrust laws.
Since mergers may lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly under the terms
of the Clayton Act, they are scrutinized by the FTC and the Justice Department.

What does this mean?


It is obvious that Company A cannot combine with either Company B or C, but how
about Company E? Company A would be prohibited from combining with any other
company. Combining the market shares of Company A and any other company and
then squaring them would produce a number higher than 1,800.

Wrong Calculation

Market Share Market Share Squared


Company A 41% 1,681
Company F 2% 4

170
1,685

Note: Do not make this mistake unless you are hungry for attention by the antitrust
division of the Justice Department.)

Correct Calculation

Market Share Market Share Squared


Company A 41%
Company F 2%
43% 1,849

MEASURES OF INDUSTRY CHARACTERISTICS


Industries also differ with regard to the underlying demand and market
conditions. Presented below are two measures describing industry characteristics:
the Rothschild Index and the Lerner Index.

THE ROTHSCHILD INDEX


The elasticity of demand for products tends to vary from industry to industry.
Moreover, the elasticity of demand for an individual firm's products generally will
differ from the market elasticity of demand for the products. The Rothschild Index
(R) provides a measure of how price sensitive an individual firm's demand is
relative to the entire market. It is computed as
R = e T/e I

where e T is the elasticity of demand for the total market and e I is the elasticity of
demand for the product of an individual firm.
The Rothschild Index takes on a value between 0 and 1.
(a) When R = 1, the individual firm faces a demand curve that has the same
sensitivity to price as the market demand curve.
(b) When R is close to 0, an industry is composed of many firms, each
producing similar products.

EXAMPLE 7
The industry elasticity of demand for softwood lumber is 1 and the elasticity
of demand for an individual lumber mill is 5. The Rothschild Index for this industry
is 1/5 = 0.2.

THE LERNER INDEX


In addition to structural differences across industries, the conduct, or
behavior, of firms also tends to differ across industries. Some industries charge
higher markups than other industries. The Lerner Index (L) provides a measure of
how much firms in an industry mark up their prices over marginal cost.

L = (P - MC)/P
(a) In industries in which firms rigorously compete for consumer sales by

171
attempting to charge the lowest price in the market, L is close to zero.
(b) When firms do not rigorously compete for consumers through price
competition, L is closer to l.

EXAMPLE 8
A firm in the lumber industry has a marginal cost of $200 and charges a price
of $220. The Lerner Index is ($220 – $200)/$220 = .09.

QUESTIONS

1. List the major determinants of market structure.


2. State the conditions that yields a perfectly competitive market.
3. What is the condition for the long-run profit-maximizing level of output for a
perfect competitor?
4. Do the four-firm concentration ratio and the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index always provide
an accurate evaluation of market power? Explain.
5. List two measures describing industry characteristics and briefly define each.

PROBLEMS

1. Stellar Company is operating under highly competitive market conditions. The going price
for its product is P = $250. If the firm’s marginal cost function is MC = -300 + 20Q then what
is the firm’s profit maximizing output?

2. Marie Clothing is operating under highly competitive market conditions and has the
following long run total cost function: TC = 45 - 2.5Q + .04Q2
If the firm’s cost function remains stable, what will be the long-run price for Marie’s product?

3. Nolo, Inc. is a monopolist facing the following demand and total cost functions:
Q = 25 - .5P
TC = 50 + 2Q
(a) What is the firm’s inverse demand function?
(b) What are the profit-maximizing levels of output and price?
(c) What will be the level of profits?

4. There are six firms in an industry. Firm A has 40 percent of the market, Firm B has 30
percent, and the remaining firms have 7.5 percent each.
(a) Compute the four-firm concentration ratio.
(b) Compute the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index.

ANSWERS
1. Market structure refers to such factors as the number of firms in an industry, the relative
size of the firms (industry concentration), demand conditions, ease of entry and exit, and
technological and cost conditions.

172
2. The conditions for perfect competition includes: (1) each firm is so small relative to the
market that it can exert no perceptible influence on price; (2) the product is homogeneous; (3)
there is free mobility of all resources, including free entry and exit of firms into and out of the
industry; and (4) all buyers and sellers in the market possess complete and perfect knowledge.
3. In the long-run, equilibrium will be achieved at a point where P = MR = MC = AC, and the
firm is producing at its most efficient level of output; i.e., where long-run average costs are
minimized.
4. These two statistics measure different aspects of market structure and therefore may not
accurately describe the degree of market power. Both neglect the geographical market, and
foreign competition.
5. They are the Rothschild and the Lerner indexes. The Rothschild Index measures how price
sensitive an individual firm's demand is relative to the entire market, while the Lerner Index
(L) measures how much firms in an industry markup their prices over marginal cost.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
Profits are maximized where MR = MC.
MR = P = 250; MC = -300 + 20Q
250 = -300 + 20Q; Q* = 27.5

2.
The long-run equilibrium price will be where P = minimum LAC, where
LAC = LTC/Q = 45 - 2.5Q + .04Q2
We find minimum LAC where dLAC/dQ = 0
dLAC/dQ = - 2.5 + .08Q = 0
Q = 31.25
At Q = 31.25, LAC = 45 - 2.5Q + .04Q2 = = 45 - 2.5(31.25) + .04(31.25)2 = $20
The long-run price for the firm’s product will be $20.

3.
(a) P = 50 - 2Q
(b) TR = PQ = (50 - 2Q)Q = 50Q - 2Q 2
At profit maximizing output, MR = MC
MR = d TR/ d Q = 50 - 4Q; MC = d TC/ d Q = 2
Hence. 50 - 4Q = 2; Q* = 12; P = 50 - 2Q = 50 - 2(12) = $26
(c) Profits = TR - TC = 50Q - 2Q 2 - (50 + 2Q) = -50 + 48Q -2Q 2 = -50 + 48(12) -
2(12)2
= $238.

4.
(a) The four-firm concentration ratio = .4 + .3 + .075 + .075 = .85 = 85%
(b) The Herfindahl-Hirshman Index = 10,000[(.4)2 + (.3)2 + (.075)2 + (.075)2 + (.075)2 +
(.075)2] = 2,725

173
CHAPTER 10
PRICING POLICIES AND STRATEGIES

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Define the cost-based price.


2. Illustrate and explain markup pricing.
3. Formulate and discuss optimal pricing.
4. Explain the concept of price discrimination.
5. Articulate and give examples of two-part pricing.
6. Define and illustrate block pricing.
7. Demonstrate and explain commodity bundling.
8. Define and discuss peak load pricing.
9. Explain skimming pricing.
10. Define and demonstrate penetrating pricing.

In this chapter, we examine a number of pricing methods and polices used in practice.
We begin with the most popular pricing approach, cost-plus pricing . We also take a look at
how to utilize economic theory to reach a profit-maximizing pricing decision. The marginal
cost concept and demand elasticity play key roles in achieving profit maximization. Further,
we examine various pricing strategies for firms that may yield even greater profits, such as
price discrimination, two-part pricing, block pricing, and peak-load pricing,. The price
discrimination method is also analyzed as a way for firms with market power to deal with
pricing problems posed by multiple products. Two common pricing polices--skimming and
penetrating--are also presented.

COST-BASED PRICING
Cost-based pricing is a widely used pricing technique that involves:
(a) Define an appropriate cost base, typically average unit cost of producing and
marketing a product or service and
(b) Add a percentage markup. The markup on cost formula is

Price - Cost
Markup on cost = --------------------
Cost

EXAMPLE 1
A firm's unit cost is $3.00 and the unit price is $3.90, the 30% markup is calculated as
($3.90 - $3.00)/$3.00 = 30%
Solving the markup on cost formula for price provides the expression that determines price in
a cost-plus pricing system, i.e.,
Price = Cost(1 + Markup on Cost) = $3.00(1 + .3) = $3.90

174
Despite its popularity, a cost-plus pricing system is subject to some criticisms: (a) it
fails to take into account demand as measured in terms of buyers' desires and purchasing
power and (b) it does not reflect competition in terms of rivals' reactions and the possible
entry of new firms.

OPTIMAL PRICING POLICY AND PRICE ELASTICITY


We note, without a mathematical derivation, the relationship between the
point price elasticity of demand, marginal revenue, and price:

This follows directly from the mathematical definition of marginal revenue


(MR).
This formula is useful in setting a firm’s pricing policy. From the profit-maximizing
condition MR = MC, we can derive the formula for determining the profit-
maximizing price level, which is shown below.

MC = MR

1
MC = P 1 + ----
ep

Solving for the optimal or profit-maximizing P*, yields

MC
P* = ----------------
1
1 + ----
ep

EXAMPLE 2
ABC summer catalog of outdoor sporting shoes features $5 off the regular
$40 price on a popular Z model. Customer response was more than enthusiastic,
with sales rising from 10,000 to 20,000 units. The company buys shoes from a local
wholesale distributor for $28, and incurs $4 in marginal marketing costs per unit.
Then the price elasticity of demand is:

175
% change in Q (20,000 - 10,000)/10,000 1
ep = ----------------- = --------------------------- = --- = -8
% change in p (35 - 40)/40 .125

The profit-maximizing price is then:


P = $32/(1 + 1/-8) = $36.6

MARKUP PRICING AND PROFIT MAXIMIZATION


Most firms differentiate markups for different products on the basis of price
elasticities and competitive pressure. This section tries to identify the precise
relation between the price elasticity and the optimal markups on cost and price.
First, recall that

1
P* = MC -------------------
1
1 + ----
ep

The formula implies that the profit-maximizing price is obtained by


multiplying MC by

1
--------------
1
1 + ----
ep

Recall that price = cost (1 + markup on cost). Substituting this into the left-hand

1
MC (1 + markup on cost) = MC --------------
1
1 + ----
ep
side of the formula, we obtain:

176
Simplifying the expression and solving for “markup on cost” yields:

1
Markup on cost = -------------- - 1 = -1/(ep+ 1)
1
1 + ----
ep

The optimal markup on cost = OMC* = -1/(ep + 1).

EXAMPLE 3
In Example 2 , we note eP = -8. The optimal markup on cost is:
OMC* = -1/(ep + 1) = -1/(-8 + 1) = -1/-7 = 0.1429 or 14.29%
Note that the more elastic the demand for a product (the more “price
sensitive” it is), the smaller optimal margin. Products with relatively price-
insensitive demand will be optimally priced with higher markups.

STRATEGIES THAT YIELD EVEN GREATER PROFITS


The analysis in the previous section demonstrated how a manager can
implement the familiar MR = MC rule for setting the profit maximizing price.
Given estimates of demand and cost functions, such a price can be computed
directly. Alternatively, given publicly available estimates of demand elasticities, a
manager can implement the rule by using the appropriate markup formula.
In some markets, managers can enhance profits above those they would earn
by simply charging a single per unit price to all consumers. Several pricing
strategies can be used to yield profits above those earned by simply charging a
single price where MR = MC.

Pricing strategies are price discrimination, two-part pricing, block pricing,


and commodity bundling which are strategies appropriate for firms with various
cost structures and degrees of market interdependence. Thus, these strategies can
enhance profits of firms in industries with monopolistic, monopolistically
competitive, or oligopolistic structures.

PRICE DISCRIMINATION
Price discrimination is defined as the act of selling the same good or service,
produced under a single control (i.e., by a monopolist), at different prices to
different buyers. Price discrimination exists when a multiproduct firm prices

177
closely-related products in such a manner that the differences in their prices are not
proportional to the differences in their marginal costs of production and
distribution.
Price discrimination can be encountered in the:

a) First degree : Separate prices for each consumer. This creates maximum
profits for sellers.
b) Second degree: Block-rates or quantity discounts based on usage.
c) Third degree: Different prices for each customer class defined on the
basis of age, sex, income, etc. This is the most common type of price
discrimination. Examples are: (1) Stores offer "student discounts," (2)
Hotels and restaurants offer senior citizen discounts, and (3) Telephone
companies charge lower rates on weekends than during the day, implying
that businesses may pay a higher price for telephone services than
households.

NOTE:
(1) If the following conditions are satisfied, a firm can enhance profits by engaging
in price discrimination:
(a) There is no resale market for the product.
(b) The firm has a good idea of identifying who belongs to which consumer
type.
(c) Consumers are divided into two or more types, with one type having a
more elastic demand than the others.
(2) A firm that can segment its market will maximize profits by operating in such a
way that MR = MC in each market segment.

EXAMPLE 4
Suppose the demand and total cost (TC) functions facing a monopolist are
given by:
P 1 = 10 – Q 1 (or Q 1 = 10 – P 1 )
P 2 = 6 – Q 2 (or Q 2 = 6 – P 2 )
TC = 4 + (Q 1 + Q 2 )

Total combined profit in the two markets equals:

π = TR – TC = P 1 Q 1 + P 2 Q 2 – [4 + (Q 1 + Q 2 )]
= (10 – Q 1 )Q 1 + (6 – Q2)Q2 - [4 + (Q 1 + Q 2 )]
2 2
= -4 + 9Q 1 – Q 1 + 5Q 2 – Q 2

In order to maximize profits, we find partial derivatives of profit with respect to Q 1


and Q 2 , set them equal to zero, and solve for them.

∂π/ ∂Q 1 = 9 –2Q 1 = 0; Q 1 = 4.5


∂π/ ∂Q 2 = 5 –2Q 2 = 0; Q 2 = 2.5

178
Substituting Q 1 and Q 2 into the demand and profit functions yields:
P 1 = $5.5, P 2 = $3.5, and π = $22.5

NOTE:
The general profit maximizing rule for the firm seeking price discriminations is that
the firm should produce and sell in each market until marginal revenue in each market is
equal to the firm’s marginal cost, i.e., MR1 = MR2= MC. Otherwise, consumers in the
higher price market will be able to buy the product in the lower priced market.

PREDATORY PRICING
Predatory pricing is intentionally pricing below cost to eliminate competition
and reduce supply. Federal statutes and many state laws prohibit the practice. The
U.S. Supreme Court has held that pricing is predatory when two conditions are met:
(1) the seller’s price is below “an appropriate measure of its costs,” and (2) it has a
reasonable prospect of recovering the resulting loss through higher prices or greater
market share.

TWO PART PRICING


Companies with market power can magnify profits using two part pricing .
With two part pricing, a firm charges a fixed fee for the right to buy its products or
services, plus a per unit charge for each unit purchased. This pricing strategy is
commonly used by such establishments as athletic clubs, golf courses and health
clubs. They typically charge a fixed "initiation fee" plus a charge (either per month
or per visit) to use the facilities. Buying clubs are another good example. By paying
a membership fee in those clubs, members get to buy products at '”wholesale cost."

BLOCK PRICING
Block pricing is another way a firm with market power can increase profits.
An example is the purchase of toilet paper in packages of three rolls or cans of soft
drinks in a six pack. By packaging units of a product and selling them as one
package, the firm earns more than by posting a simple per unit price. Block pricing
enhances profits by forcing consumers to make all-or-none decisions to purchase
units of a good.

COMMODITY BUNDLING
Commodity bundling reflects the practice of bundling two or more different
products together and selling them at a single "bundle price." For example, travel
agencies often sell "package deals" that include airfare, hotel, and meals at a
bundled price instead of pricing each component of a vacation separately. PC
makers bundle computers, monitors, and software and sell them at a bundled price.
Many car dealers bundle options such as air conditioning, power steering, and
automatic transmission and sell them at a “special package price."

STRATEGIES FOR SPECIAL COST AND DEMAND STRUCTURES


There are pricing strategies available to firms with special cost and demand

179
structures to maximize profits. They include peak load pricing and cross
subsidization.

PEAK LOAD PRICING


When demand is higher at some times of the day than at other times, a firm
may enhance profits by peak load pricing . This practice involves charging a higher
price during peak times than is charged during off peak times. Many markets have
periods in which demand is high and periods in which demand is low. Toll roads,
utility companies, and airlines all tend to have this feature. When the demand
during peak times is so high that the capacity of the firm cannot serve all customers
at the same price, the firm can use peak load pricing to enhance its profits.

NOTE:
Peak load pricing is similar to price discrimination but, due to capacity limitations, the
firm is unable to fully equate the marginal revenues of those who purchase at different times.

CROSS SUBSIDIZATION
Whenever the demand for two products made by a company are interrelated
through costs or demand, the firm may increase profits by cross subsidization . It
involves selling one product at or below cost and the other product above cost. This
way, the company's profits made with one product are used to subsidize sales of
another product. Consider a firm that sells two different types of computer software.
One type is a Windows system, and the other is an application that runs on the
window (say, a spreadsheet).

Clearly there are economies of scope and cost complementarities in making


the two products jointly; cost savings arise due to designing the software within the
firm. Furthermore, the demand for the two products is likely to be interdependent;
the spreadsheet is valuable to a consumer only to the extent that it runs on a
version of the window. In such instances, a firm may find it profitable to sell one of
the products at (or below) cost and charge a relatively higher price for the other
product. For instance, the firm may price the Windows system at (or below) cost to
induce numerous consumers to use it to run their computers. Once consumers
commit to the company’s version of Windows, the firm can charge a higher price for
its applications software.

NOTE:
The advantages of cross subsidization are: it allows the company to sell multiple
products, which leads to cost savings in the presence of economies of scope. If the two
products have demands that are interdependent, the firm can induce consumers to buy more
of each product than they would otherwise.

180
PRICING POLICIES
Many firms use two pricing tactics, depending upon the type of goal they
wish to accomplish with pricing. They are skimming and penetrating pricing
policies.

MARKET SKIMMING PRICING


Market-skimming pricing is the method of pricing that involves setting a high initial
price for a new product, with a progressively lowering of the price as time passes and as the
market broaden and matures. The objective of this pricing method is to maximize short-term
profits. This strategy is used when a new product is introduced at the highest price possible
given the benefits of the product. For market skimming to work, the product must appear to
be worth its price, the costs of producing a small volume cannot be so high that they eliminate
the advantage of charging more, and competitors cannot enter the market and undercut the
price.

PENETRATING PRICING
A pricing policy that involves setting low initial prices in order to gain quick
acceptance in a broad portion of the market. It calls for the sacrifice of some short-term profits
in order to gain a better long-term market share. The lower price is then often raised as the
product moves into its growth stage. One objective is to obtain a committed customer. This
policy is also used by a firm when consumer demand is price-elastic.

QUESTIONS
1. What criticisms is cost-plus pricing subject to?
2. Explain the difference between markup on cost and markup on price.
3. What is the role of sunk costs in short-run managerial decision making?
4. State three important conditions for price discrimination to work well.
5. A local family doctor read an article published by AMA estimating that elasticity
of demand for the representative family practice is -2. How much should the
family doctor markup her price over marginal cost?
6. Explain why theaters sometimes give senior citizen discounts.
7. Many restaurants offer free appetizers with a two-drink minimum during a
limited number of hours. Is this profit-maximizing behavior?
8. Give some examples of firms using peak-load pricing. Can they enhance their
profits using this pricing practice?
9. Give some examples of firms using two-part pricing.

PROBLEMS

1. A monopolist is profit maximizing when the price elasticity of demand is -2 and


price is $5. What is the monopolist's marginal cost?

181
2. As an owner of a local market, you sell a gallon of milk for $2. If your elasticity
of demand for milk sold at your store is -2.5, what are your profit-maximizing
markup and price?

3. Carlos Service Stations is contemplating selling mugs imprinted with its logo.
Preliminary estimates suggests the following demand function: Q = 10,000 - 2,000P

(a) How many mugs could Carlos sell at $1.50 each; at $2.00 each?
(b) What price must Carlos charge to sell 8,000 mugs?
(c) At what price would quantity be zero?
(d) How many mugs should Carlos have ready if it decides to give the mugs away
for promotional purposes?
(e) Calculate the point elasticity of demand at a price of $1.50.
(f) At what price is the elasticity of demand equal to -1 (i.e., unitary )?

4. Suppose the demand function for Stacy Flowers is given by P(Q) = 10 - 2Q and
the cost function is TC(Q) = 2Q. What is the profit-maximizing level of output and
price for this firm?

5. Yumi summer catalog of outdoor sporting shoes features $3 off the regular $36
price on a popular Z model. Customer response was more than enthusiastic, with
sales rising from 15,000 to 25,000 units. The company’s buys shoes from a local
wholesale distributor for $28, and incurs $3.5 in marginal marketing costs per unit.

(a) Determine the point price elasticity of demand.


(b) Is the regular $36 price optimal in the sense of maximizing Yumi's profits on the
shoes?

ANSWERS
1. A cost-plus pricing system suffers from some criticisms: (a) it fails to take into account
demand as measured in terms of buyers' desires and purchasing power and (b) it does not
reflect competition in terms of rivals' reactions and the possible entry of new firms.
2. Markup on cost is the profit margin for a product expressed as a percentage of unit cost,
while markup on price is the profit margin expressed as a percentage of price, rather than
unit cost.
3. Sunk costs are unaffected by decisions made now or in the future and are therefore
irrelevant in the short-run decision making.
4. If the following conditions are satisfied, a firm can enhance profits by engaging in
price discrimination: (a) There is no resale market for the product, (b) The firm has a
good idea of identifying who belongs to which consumer type, and (c) Consumers are
divided into two or more types, with one type having a more elastic demand than the
others.
5.

182
MC
P* = -------------------- = MC /[1 + 1/-2)] = 2MC
1
1 + ----
ep
The doctor should charge her price twice over the marginal cost.
6. Since seniors have a more elastic demand than non-senior citizens, a lower price
is charged to them to maximize the profits.
7. It may be an example of cross-subsidization. The appetizers are typically salty,
leading customers to buy more drinks than would otherwise be the case.
8. Toll roads, utility companies, and airlines are good examples. When the demand
during peak times is so high that the capacity of the firm cannot serve all customers
at the same price, the firm can use peak load pricing to enhance its profits.
9. This pricing strategy is commonly used by such establishments as athletic clubs,
golf courses and health clubs.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
1
MC = P 1 + ---- = $5[ 1 + 1/-2] = $2.5
ep

2.
MC
P* = ----------------- = $2 /[1 + 1/-2.5)] = $3.33
1
1 + ----
ep

3.
(a) At $1.50, Q = 10,000 - 2,000(1.5) = 7,000
At $2.00, Q = 10,000 - 2,000(2) = 6,000

(b) Set Q = 8,000 and solve for P


8,000 = 10,000 - 2,000P; P = $1.00

(c) Set Q = 0 and solve for P


0 = 10,000 - 2,000P; P = $5.00

(d) Set P = 0 and solve for Q


Q = 10,000 - 2,000(0); Q = 10,000
(e) We know from (a) that at $1.50, Q = 10,000 - 2,000(1.5) = 7,000

183
% change in dQ/Q dQ p 1.50
Q
ep = --------------- = ------ = --- x --- = (-2000) ------- = -.43
% change in P dP/P dP Q 7,000

(f) Demand is unit elastic where MR = 0. To find MR, write the demand curve in
inverse form. Q = 10,000 - 2,000P or P = 5 - .0005Q
TR = PQ = (5 - .0005Q)Q = 5Q - .0005Q 2
Set MR = 0 and solve for Q:
MR = d TR/ d Q = 5 - .001Q = 0; Q = 5,000
Substitute to solve for P:
P = 5 - .0005Q = 5 - .0005(5,000) = $2.50
The demand elasticity is unitary at a price of $2.50.

4.
TR = PQ = (10 - 2Q)Q = 10Q - 2Q 2 MR = 10 - 4Q. Since TC(Q) = 2Q. MC = 2.
Setting MR = MC yields, 10 -4Q = 2.
So Q* = 2. Substituting this into the demand function yields the profit-maximizing
price:
P(Q) = 10 - 2Q = 10 - 2(2) = $6.

5.
(a) The price elasticity of demand is:
% change in Q (25,000 -
15,000)/15,000
ep = --------------- = --------------------------- = -8
% change in p (33 - 36)/36

(b) The profit-maximizing price is:


P = $31.5(1 + 1/-8) = $36
The answer is yes; the regular $36 is the profit-maximizing price.

184
CHAPTER 11
LONG -TERM INVESTMENT DECISIONS
(CAPITAL BUDGETING )

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Construct a guide for capital budgeting


2. Compute and explain the time value of money.
3. Calculate and demonstrate after-tax cash inflows.
4. Compute the net present value (NPV).
5. Explain how to compute the internal rate of return (IRR).
6. Ascertain and discuss the cost of capital.
7. Demonstrate and give examples of the profitability index.
8. Discuss how capital rationing works.

Capital budgeting is the process of planning for and evaluating long-tern capital
expenditure decisions. There are many investment decisions that the firm may have to make
in order to grow. Examples of capital budgeting applications are product line selection, keep
or sell a business segment, lease or buy, and which asset to invest in.

WHAT ARE THE TYPES OF INVESTMENT PROJECTS?


There are typically two types of long-term investment decisions:

1. Expansion decisions in terms of obtaining new facilities or expanding existing


ones: Examples include:
(a) Investments in property, plant, and equipment as well as other types of assets.
(b) Resource commitments in the form of new product development, market research,
introduction of a computer network, refunding of long-term debt, and so on.
(c) Mergers and acquisitions in the form of buying another company to add a new
product or service line.
2. Replacement decisions replacing obsolete assets with new ones. Examples include
replacing an old machine with a high-tech machine.

WHAT ARE THE FEATURES OF INVESTMENT PROJECTS?


Long-term investments have three important features:
1. They typically involve a large amount of initial cash outlays which tend to have a
long-term impact on the firm's future profitability. Therefore, this initial cash outlay needs to
be justified on a cost-benefit basis.
2. There are expected recurring cash inflows (for example, increased revenues,
savings in cash operating expenses, etc.) over the life of the investment project. This
frequently requires considering the time value of money.
3. Corporate income taxes could make a difference in the accept or reject decision.
Therefore, income tax factors must be taken into account in every capital budgeting decision.

185
UNDERSTANDING THE CONCEPT OF TIME VALUE OF MONEY
A dollar now is worth more than a dollar to be received later. This statement sums up
an important principle: money has a time value. The reason is that you could invest the dollar
now and have more than a dollar at the specified later date.

Time value of money is an important consideration in making business decisions. For


example, compound interest computations are required to calculate future sums of money
emanating from an investment. Discounting (present value) is the opposite of compounding.
It is used to appraise the future cash flow of capital budgeting proposals. Many applications
of time value of money exist in accounting, economics, finance, and other business areas.

How Do You Calculate Future Values - How Money Grows?


A dollar in hand today has more of a worth than a dollar to be received in the future
due to the interest it could generate from putting the funds in an investment. Compounding
interest means that interest earns interest. Let us define:

Fn = future value: the amount of money at the end of year n


P = principal
i = annual interest rate
n = number of years
Then,

F1 = the amount of money at the end of year 1


= principal and interest = P + iP = P(1+i)
F2 = the amount of money at the end of year 2
2
= F1(1+i) = P(1+i)(1+i) = P(1+i)

The future value of an investment compounded annually at rate i for n years is


Fn = P(1+i)n = P . T1(i,n)
where T1(i,n) is the compound amount of $1 and can be found in Table 1 in the Appendix.
Note:
(1+i)n = T1(i,n) is the future value interest factor, FVIF.

EXAMPLE 1
You place $100,000 in a bank account earning 10 percent interest compounded
annually. How much money will be accumulated after 6 years? Note that Fn = P(1+i)n
F6 = $100,000 (1 + 0.10)6 = $100,000 T1(10%,6 years)
From Table 1, the T1 for 6 years at 10 percent is 1.772.
Therefore, F6 = $100,000 (1.772) = $177,720.

Future Value of an Annuity


An annuity is defined as a series of payments (or receipts) of a fixed amount for a
stated number of periods. We assume period-end payments. The future value of an
annuity is a compound annuity of depositing or investing in equal amount of money at year-
end for a specified time period.

186
Let Sn = the future value on an n-year annuity
A = the amount of an annuity

Then we can write


n-1 n-2 0
Sn = A(1+i) + A(1+i) + ... + A(1+i)
n-1 n-2 0
= A[(1+i) +(1+i) + ... + (1+i) ]

n-1 (1 +i)n - 1
t
= A . ∑ (1+i) = A • = A . T2(i,n )
t=0 i

where T2(i,n) represents the future value of an annuity of $1 for n years compounded at i
percent and can be found in Table 2 in the Appendix. Note: T2(i,n) is the future value interest
factor for an annuity, FVIFA.

EXAMPLE 2
You want to know how much you will have in a bank account after 10 years by
depositing $20,000 at the end of each year for the next 10 years. The annual interest rate is
12 percent. The T2(12%,10 years) is given in Table 2 as 7.549. Therefore,

S10 = $20,000 T2(12%,10) = $20,000 (7.549) = $350,980

What Is Present Value - How Much Money Is Worth Now?


Present value is the value today of future cash flows. The computation of present
values (discounting) is the opposite of determining the compounded future value. The
interest rate i is referred to as the discount rate. The discount rate we use is more commonly
called the cost of capital, which is the minimum rate of return required by the investor.

Recall that Fn = P(1+i)n


Therefore,

Fn 1
P= = Fn = Fn . T3(i,n)
n n
(1 + i) (1 + i)

where T3(i,n) represents the present value of $1 and is given in Table 3 in the Appendix.
Note: T3(i,n) is the present value interest factor, PVIF.

EXAMPLE 3
You have the option of receiving $60,000 6 years from now. If you earn 15 percent on
your money, how much should you pay for this investment? To answer this query, you need
to compute the present value of $60,000 to be received 6 years from now at a 15 percent rate
of discount. F6 is $60,000, i is 15 percent, and n is 6 years. T3(15%,6) from Table 3 is 0.432.

187
1
P = $60,000 = $60,000 T3(15%,6) = $60,000(0.432) = $25,920
6
(1 + 0.15)

This means that you can earn 15 percent on your money, and you would be indifferent
to receiving $25,920 now or $60,000 6 years from today because the amounts are time
equivalent. Stated another way, you could invest $25,920 today at 15 percent and have
$60,000 in 6 years.

Present Value of an Annuity


Interest received from notes, bonds, pension funds, and insurance contracts
involve annuities. To compare these financial instruments, the present value of each must
be determined. The present value of an annuity (Pn) is solved as follows:

1 1 1
Pn = A + A. + ... + A.
1 2 n
(1 + i) (1 + i) (1 + i)

1 1 1
=A + + ... +
1 2 n
(1 + i) (1 + i) (1 + i)

n 1 1 1
= A.∑ = A. 1- = A. T4(i,n)
t
t=1 (1+i) i (1 + i)

where A = the amount of an annuity and T4(i,n) represents the present value of an annuity of
$1 discounted at i percent for n years and is found in Table 4 in the Appendix. Note: T4(i,n) is
the present value interest factor for an annuity, PVIFA.

EXAMPLE 4
Assume an annuity of $10,000 for 3 years at 10% discount. Then the present value is
Pn = A . T4(i,n)
P3 = $10,000 T4(10%, 3 years) = $10,000 (2.487) = $24,870

NOTE:

188
There are many financial calculators that contain pre-programmed formulas to
perform many present value and future value applications. Furthermore, spreadsheet software
such as Microsoft’s Excel, Quattro, and Lotus 1-2-3 have built-in financial functions to
perform many such applications.

A BASIC FRAMEWORK FOR CAPITAL BUDGETING


The economic theory of the firm suggests that to maximize its profit, a firm should
operate at the point where the marginal cost of an additional unit of output just equals the
marginal revenue derived from that output. This rule may be equally applicable to the capital
budgeting process. The marginal cost may be thought as the firm’s cost of capital--that is, the
cost of successive increments of capital acquired by the firm, while the marginal revenue may
be regarded as the rates of return earned on succeeding investments. Figure 1 illustrates this
concept.

The projects are indicated by lettered bars on the graph. For example, Project A requires an
outlay of $2 million and is expected to generate a 24 percent return. Project B will cost $1
million ($3 million minus $2 million on the horizontal axis) and generate a 22 percent return,
and so on. The marginal cost of capital (MCC) line represents the cost of each additional
dollar raised in the capital markets. The MCC is a weighted average of the costs of the
different financing sources. If the cost of any source of financing increases, the
MCC curve will rise. The MCC curve is upward sloping because the lowest cost
financing sources are assumed to be used first. Thus, as cumulative debt increases,
the cost of debt also increases.

Graphically, the projects are arranged in descending order by their rates of return,
indicating that no firm has an unlimited number of investment opportunities which all
generate lofty returns. As new products are made, new markets entered, and cost-saving high
tech adopted, the number of highly profitable projects tends to diminish. Using this basic
framework, the firm should embark on A,B,C,D, and E, since their returns exceed the firm’s
MCC.
The remainder of this chapter takes up some practical, analytical tools that are helpful
in making capital budgeting decisions.

FIGURE 1
SIMPLIFIED CAPITAL BUDGETING PROCESS

189
HOW DO YOU MEASURE INVESTMENT WORTH?
Several popular methods of evaluating investment projects are as follows:

1. Net present value (NPV)


2. Internal rate of return (IRR)
3. Profitability index (Benefit/cost ratio)
The NPV method and the IRR method are called discounted cash flow (DCF) methods.
Each of these methods are discussed below.

1. Net Present Value


Net present value (NPV) equals the present value (PV)of cash inflows from a
proposal less the initial investment (I):
NPV = PV - I
The present value of future cash flows is determined using the cost of capital (or
minimum required rate of return) as the discount rate. When cash inflows are equal, the
present value would be
PV = A . T4 (i, n)
where A is the amount of the annuity.
Decision rule: If NPV is positive, accept the project. Otherwise reject it.

EXAMPLE 5
Consider the following investment:

Initial investment $37,910


Estimated life 5 years
Annual cash inflows after taxes $10,000
Cost of capital (minimum required rate of return) 8%

Present value of the cash inflows is

190
PV = A.T4(i,n)
= $10,000. T4(8%,5 years)
= $10,000 (3.993) $39,930
Initial investment (I) 37,910
Net present value (NPV = PV - I) $ 2,020

Since the NPV of the investment is positive, the investment should be accepted.

The advantages of the NPV method are that it obviously recognizes the time value of
money and it is easy to compute whether the cash flows form an annuity or vary from period
to period.

NOTE:
If cash inflows are different from year to year, you should compute the present value
separately year by year using Table 3.

2. Internal Rate of Return


Internal rate of return (IRR), a project’s yield or real return, is defined as the rate of
interest that equates I with the PV of future cash inflows.
In other words,
at IRR I = PV or NPV = 0
Decision rule: Accept the project if the IRR exceeds the cost of capital. Otherwise, reject
it.

EXAMPLE 6
Assume the same data given in Example 5, and set the following equality (I = PV):

$37,910 = $10,000 . T4(i,5 years)

$37,910
T4(i,5 years) = --------- = 3.791
$10,000

which is right on 10% in the 5-year line of Table 4.


Since the IRR of the investment is greater than the cost of capital (8 percent), accept
the project.
The advantage of using the IRR method is that it does consider the time value of
money and, therefore, it gives a more exact and realistic yield on the project.
The shortcomings of this method are that (1) it is time-consuming to compute, (2) it
fails to recognize the varying sizes of investment in competing projects, and (3) it is not
unusual for the project with nonconventional patterns of cash flows (i.e., negative cash flows
in some periods) to have multiple IRRs.

3. Profitability Index

191
The profitability index, also called benefit/cost ratio, is the ratio of the total PV of
future cash inflows to the initial investment, that is, PV/I. This index is used as a means of
ranking projects in descending order of attractiveness.
Decision rule: If the profitability index is greater than 1, then accept the project.

EXAMPLE 7
Using the data in Example 5, the profitability index is

PV $39,930
-------- = ------------- = 1.05
I $37,910
Since this project generates $1.05 for each dollar invested (i.e., its profitability index is greater
than 1), accept the project.

The profitability index has the advantage of putting all projects on the same relative
basis regardless of size.

CAPITAL RATIONING
(PROJECT RANKING WITH A LIMITED BUDGET)
Many companies set a ceiling on the capital spending budget. Capital rationing deals
with choosing the combination of acceptable projects that generate the highest overall NPV.
The profitability index is used to rank projects when funds are limited.

EXAMPLE 8
The Westmont Company has a fixed budget of $250,000. It wants to select a mix of
acceptable projects from the following:

Projects I($) PV($) NPV($) Profitability Index Ranking


H 70,000 112,000 42,000 1.6 1
I 100,000 145,000 45,000 1.45 2
J 115,000 126,500 11,500 1.10 5
K 80,000 100,000 20,000 1.25 3
L 60,000 57,000 -3,000 0.95 6
M 82,000 95,000 13,000 1.16 4

The ranking resulting from the profitability index shows that the company should select
projects H, I, and K.

I PV
H $70,000 $112,000
I 100,000 145,000
K 80,000 100,000
$250,000 $357,000
Therefore,

NPV = $357,000 - $250,000 = $107,000

192
HOW DO INCOME TAXES AFFECT INVESTMENT DECISIONS?
Income taxes have to be considered in capital budgeting decisions. The project that
looks good on a before-tax basis may have to be rejected on an after-tax basis and vice versa.
Income taxes usually impact both the amount and the timing of cash flows. Because net
income, not cash inflows, is subject to tax, after-tax cash inflows are different from after-tax
net income. To calculate after-tax cash flows, depreciation, which is not a cash outlay, must
be added to profits after taxes.
After-tax cash inflows = after-tax net income + depreciation

EXAMPLE 9
The Navistar Company estimates that it can generate sales of $67,000 and incur
annual cost of operations of $52,000 for the next ten years if it buys a special-purpose
machine at a cost of $100,000. No residual value is expected. Depreciation is by straight-line.
Assume that the income tax rate is 30%, and the after-tax cost of capital (minimum required
rate of return) is 10%. After-tax cash inflows can be calculated as follows:
Note that depreciation by straight-line is $100,000/10 = $10,000 per year. Thus,

After-tax cash inflows = after-tax net income + depreciation


= ($67,000 - $52,000)(1 - .3) + $10,000
= $15,000 (.7) + $10,000
= $10,500 + $10,000 = 20,500

To see if this machine should be purchased, the net present value can be calculated.

PV = $20,500 T4(10%, 10 years) = $20,500 (6.145)=$125,972.50


Thus, NPV = PV - I = $125,972.50 - $100,000 = $25,972.50
Since NPV is positive, the machine should be bought.

Note: Use of accelerated methods such as the sum-of-years-digits, double declining, and
Modified Accelerated Cost Recovery (MACRS) methods would increase after-tax cash flows.
MACRS is an accelerated method of depreciation under which depreciation expense
will be greater during the early years of an asset’s life. Thus, the outflows for
income taxes will be less in the early years, but greater in the later years, and the
NPV (present value of net cash inflows-investment) will be increased. The
profitability index (present value of net cash inflows/the investment) must increase
if the NPV increases.

EXAMPLE 10
The treasurer of a small appliance maker estimates the cash inflows, outflows, and net
cash flows before taxes shown in columns 1, 2, and 3 of the table below, if it buys a high tech
machine at a cost of $1,000,000. No residual value is expected. Life is 5 years. Depreciation is
by straight-line. Assume that the income tax rate is 35%, and the after-tax cost of capital
(minimum required rate of return) is 10%. The process of arriving at net cash flow after taxes
are shown in columns 4, 5, 6, 7, and 8.

193
Net
Net Cash Depreciation Cash Flow
Flow (noncash Net Income Income Net Income After
Cash Cash Before Expense) Before Taxes After Taxes
Inflow Ouflow Taxes (4)=.2 x Taxes (6) = .35 x Taxes (8)=(3)-(6)
Year (1) (2) (3)=(1)-(2) 1,000,000 (5)=(3)-(4) (5) (7)=(5)-(6) or (7)+(4)
1 $ 1,000,000 $ 625,000 $ 375,000 $ 200,000 $ 175,000 $ 61,250 $ 113,750 $ 313,750
2 $ 900,000 $ 610,000 $ 290,000 $ 200,000 $ 90,000 $ 31,500 $ 58,500 $ 258,500
3 $ 925,000 $ 635,000 $ 290,000 $ 200,000 $ 90,000 $ 31,500 $ 58,500 $ 258,500
4 $ 930,000 $ 605,000 $ 325,000 $ 200,000 $ 125,000 $ 43,750 $ 81,250 $ 281,250
5 $ 825,000 $ 557,000 $ 268,000 $ 200,000 $ 68,000 $ 23,800 $ 44,200 $ 244,200

EXAMPLE 11
The NPV of the machine can be calculated using Table 3, as shown below.

Net
Cash Flow
After T3 at 10% Present
Year Taxes Table value Value
0 $ (1,000,000) $ 1.000 $ (1,000,000)
1 $ 313,750 $ 0.909 $ 285,199
2 $ 258,500 $ 0.826 $ 213,521
3 $ 258,500 $ 0.751 $ 194,134
4 $ 281,250 $ 0.683 $ 192,094
5 $ 244,200 $ 0.621 $ 151,648
NPV = $ 36,596

THE POSTAUDIT
The last step in capital budgeting is a postaudit review that should be performed by
an individual independent of the decision. Actual operating costs and cash receipts from sales
should be determined and compared with the costs and revenues estimated when the project
was originally reviewed and accepted. The postaudit review performs functions including:

1. Informs management about the accuracy of projections of cash flows.


2. May identify additional factors that might have been forgotten in a particular
project.
3. Sees how effectively and efficiently the process is working.

COST OF CAPITAL AND THE DISCOUNT RATE

The cost of capital is defined as the return rate required to maintain the company’s
market value (or market price of stock). Project managers must know the cost of capital
(minimum required rate of return). It was used either as a discount rate under the NPV
method or as a hurdle rate under the IRR method earlier in the chapter. The cost of capital is a
weighted average cost of a company’s financing instruments including bonds, preferred
stock, common stock, and retained earnings.

194
Cost of Debt

The cost of debt is stated on an after-tax basis, since the interest on the debt is tax
deductible. However, the cost of preferred stock is the stated annual dividend rate. This rate is
not adjusted for income taxes because the preferred dividend, unlike debt interest, is not a
deductible expense in computing corporate income taxes.

EXAMPLE 12

Assume that the Hume Company issues a $1,000, 7 percent, 10-year bond whose
net proceeds are $960. The tax rate is 40 percent. Then, the after-tax cost of debt is:

7.00% (1-0.4) = 4.2%

EXAMPLE 13

The Hume company has preferred stock that pays a $12 dividend per share and has a
market price per share of $100. Then the cost of preferred stock is:

Dividend per share $12


------------------- = ---- = 12%
Price per share $100

Cost of Common Stock

The cost of common stock is the rate of return investors demand on a company’s
common stock. One way to measure the cost of common stock is to use the Gordon's growth
model. The model is

D1
Po = -------
r-g

where Po = value (or market price) of common stock


D1 = dividend to be received in 1 year
r = investor's required rate of return
g = rate of growth (assumed to be constant over time)

Solving the model for r results in the formula for the cost of common stock:

D1
r= ------- +g
Po

EXAMPLE 14

195
The market price of the Hume Company's stock is $50. The current year dividend
will be $6 per share. The anticipated annual growth rate in dividends is 8 percent. The cost of
common stock equals:

D1 $6
---- +g= ---- + 8% = 20%
Po $50

Cost of Retained Earnings

The cost of retained earnings is closely tied to the cost of common stock, because
the cost of equity obtained by retained earnings is the same as the rate of return investors
demand on the company’s common stock.

Computing the Overall Cost of Capital

The company’s overall cost of capital is the weighted average of the individual
financing costs. The weights are the proportion of each type of financing to the total
financing. The formula is

∑ (percentage of the total capital structure by each source of financing x cost of capital for
each source)

The computation of overall cost of capital is illustrated in the following example.

EXAMPLE 15

Assume that the capital structure at the latest statement date is indicative of the
proportions of financing that the company intends to use over time:

Cost
Mortgage bonds ($1,000 par) $20,000,000 4.20% (from Example 12)
Preferred stock ($100 par) 5,000,000 12.00 (from Example 13)
Common stock ($40 par) 20,000,000 20.00 (from Example 14)
Retained earnings 5,000,000 20.00
Total $50,000,000

These proportions would be applied to the assumed individual explicit after-tax costs below:

Source Weights Cost Weighted Cost


Debt 40% (a) 4.20% 1.68% (b)
Preferred stock 10 12.00% 1.20
Common stock 40 20.00% 8.00
Retained earnings 10 20.00% 2.00
100% 12.88%

196
(a) $20,000,000/$50,000,000 = .40 = 40%
(b) 4.20% x 40% = 1.68%

Overall cost of capital is 12.88%

By computing a company's cost of capital, we can determine its minimum rate of


return, which is used as the discount rate in present value calculations. A company's cost of
capital is also an indicator of risk. For example, if your company's cost of financing increases,
it is being viewed as more risky by investors and creditors, who are demanding higher return
on their investments in the form of higher dividend and interest rates.

QUESTIONS
1. Define the term capital budgeting.
2. What is the profitability index, and of what value is it?
3. How would you define the internal rate of return of a capital project?
4. What is the definition of the net present value (NPV) of a project? What is the decision
rule under the NPV method?
5. How would you define the cost of capital?
6. What role does the cost of capital play in the IRR method and in the NPV method?
7. What is the purpose of a postaudit?

PROBLEMS

1. The following data are given for Barron's Aluminum Company:

Initial cost of proposed equipment $80,000


Estimated useful life 7 years
Estimated annual savings in cash
operating expenses (after taxes) $20,000
Predicted residual value at the end
of the useful life $ 4,000
Cost of capital after taxes 12%

Compute the following:

(a) Present value of estimated annual savings


(b) Present value of estimated residual value
(c) Total present value of estimated cash inflows
(d) Net present value (NPV)
(e) Internal rate of return (IRR)

2. The Travis Company is considering a capital outlay of $75,000. Net annual cash inflows
after taxes are estimated at $15,000 for 10 years. Straight-line depreciation is to be used, with
no residual value. Compute the items listed below.

197
1. Net present value (NPV), assuming a cost of capital after tax of 12 percent.
2. Internal rate of return (IRR)

3. Fill in the blanks for each of the following independent cases. Assume an investment
useful life of 10 years.

Annual Cash Cost of


Inflow Investment Capital IRR NPV
1. $200,000 $898,800 14% (a) (b)
2. $140,000 (c) 14% 20% (d)
3. (e) $200,000 (f) 14% $35,624
4. (g) $300,000 12% (h) $39,000

4. Horn Corp. invested in a four-year project. Horn's cost of capital after taxes is 8 percent.
Additional data about the project follows:

Cash Inflow from Operations, Present Value of


Year After Taxes $1 at 8%
1 $3,000 0.926
2 $3,500 0.857
3 $2,400 0.794
4 $2,600 0.735

Assuming a positive net present value of $500, what was the amount of the original
investment?

5. Gene, Inc., bought equipment with a useful life of eight years and no residual value.
Straight-line depreciation is used. It was anticipated to result cash inflow from operations, net
of income taxes, of $4,000. The present value of an ordinary annuity of $1 for eight periods
at 10 percent is 5.335. The present value of $1 for eight periods at 10 percent is 0.467.
Assume Gene used an internal rate of return of 10 percent. How much was the amount of the
initial investment?

6. UCB Corporation is considering five different investment opportunities. The company's


cost of capital is 12 percent. Data on these opportunities under consideration are given below:

Profitability
Index
Project Investment PV at 12% (rounded)
(a) $70,000 $80,000 1.14
(b) 40,000 46,000 1.15
(c) 25,000 27,453 1.10
(d) 20,000 21,000 1.05
(e) 18,000 17,000 0.94

Rank these five projects in descending order of preference, based to profitability

198
index, Which projects should be chosen if $110,000 is the spending limit?

ANSWERS
1. Capital budgeting is the process of evaluating alternative capital projects and selecting
alternatives that provide the most profitable return on available funds.

2. The profitability index is the present value of the expected after-tax cash inflows of
investment divided by the initial cash outlay. The higher the index, the more profitable
the project per dollar of investment.

3. The internal rate of return is the rate of return that equates the present value of future
expected cash inflows from an investment with the cost of the investment; it is the rate at
which the net present value of the project is zero.

4. The NPV of a project is given by the present value of the expected cash inflows that it
will generate minus the initial cost. Projects are acceptable if their NPV s are greater than
zero.

5. The cost of capital is the minimum return that is necessary for a firm to maintain its value
and grow.

6. Under the IRR method, the cost of capital is a cut-off point for deciding which projects
are acceptable for further consideration. Under the NPV method, the cost of capital is the
discount rate used to calculate the present value of the cash inflows.

7. The purpose of a post-audit is to determine whether or not a project is living up to its


expectations by comparing actual costs and benefits with estimated costs and benefits.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.

(a) $20,000 x PV factor of an annuity of $1 at 12% for 7 years = $20,000 x 4.564 = $91,280
(b) $4,000 x PV factor of $1 = $4,000 x 0.452 = $1,808
(c) Total PV = $91,280 + 1,808 = $93,088
(d) NPV = PV - I = $93,088 - $80,000 = $13,088
(e) At IRR, I = PV.

Thus,
$80,000 = $20,000 x PV factor
PV factor = $80,000 / $20,000 = 4.00

which is, in the seven-year line, somewhere between 16% and 18%.

2.

199
1. Net present value (NPV) = PV of cash inflows after taxes

[discounted at the cost of capital (12%) ] - Initial investment


= $15,000 x T4 - $75,000 = $15,000 (5.650) - $75,000 = $9,750

2. Internal rate of return(IRR) = Rate which equates the amount invested with the present value of
cash inflows generated by the project

Therefore, we set the following equation:

$75,000 = $15,000 (PV Factor)


PV Factor = $75,000 / $15,000 = 5

which stands between 14 percent and 16 percent.

Table Value
14% 5.216 5.216
True rate 5,000
16% 4,833
Difference 0.383 0.216

Using interpolation,

IRR = 14% + [(5.216 - 5.0000) / (5.216 - 4.833)] (16% - 14%)


= 14% + [ (0.216) / (0.383)] (2%)
= 14% + (0.564)(2%) = 14% + 1.13% = 15.13%

3.

1. (a) 18% ($898,800/$200,000 = 4.494, the present value factor for 18% and 10 years)

(b) $144,400; ($200,000 x 5.216 = $1,043,200, so NPV = $1,043,200 - $898,800 =


$144,400)

2. (c) $586,880; ($140,000 x 4.192, the present value factor for 20% and 10 years; at
IRR, PV = I)

(d) $143,360; ($140,000 x 5.216 = $730,240, so NPV = $730,240 - $568,880 =


$143,360)
3. (e) $38,344; ($200,000/5.216 factor for 14% and 10 years)

(f) 10%; NPV = PV - I; PV= NPV + I;

Total PV = $35,624 + $200,000; $235,624 / $38,344

200
= 6.145, the present value factor for 10%

4. (g) $60,000; (Total PV = $39,000 + $300,000 = $339,000 / 5.650 factor for 12% =
$60,000)

(h) About 15%; ($300,000/$60,000 = 5, which stands halfway between 14% and 16%)

4.

Since NPV = PV - I, I= PV- NPV:

Year Cash Inflow Present Value of $1 Total PV


1 $3,000 0.926 $2,778
2 3,500 0.857 3,000
3 2,400 0.794 1,906
4 2,600 0.735 1,911
Present value of future inflows(PV) $9,595
Net present value (NPV) 500
Initial outlay (1) $9,095

5.

By definition, at IRR, PV = I or NPV= 0. To determine the amount of initial investment, all that
is needed is to compute the present value of $4,000 a year for 8 periods.

PV = $4,000 x 5.335 = $21,340

6.

Order of Preference
Profitability Index
(a) 2
(b) 1
(c) 3
(d) 4
(e) 5

Projects(a) and (b) should be selected, where combined NPV would be $16,000 ($6,000 +
$10,000) with the limited budget of $110,000.

201
CHAPTER 12
RISK IN PROJECT ANALYSIS

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. Explain factors involved in risk.


2. Compute the expected value.
3. Calculate and demonstrate the standard deviation.
4. Formulate and give examples of the coefficient of variation.
5. Diagram the decision tree.
6. Compute and explain the risk-adjusted discount rate.
7. Interpret the certainty equivalent.
8. Give examples and demonstrate the process of simulation.

Risk analysis is the process of measuring and analyzing the risks associated with
managerial and investment decisions. It is important especially in making capital investment
decisions because of the large amount of capital involved and the long-term nature of the
investment being considered. The higher the risk associated with a proposed project, the greater
the return that must be earned to compensate for that risk. Note: Decision making under risk
entails consideration of multiple possible future states of nature for each choice. The decision is
under risk if a probability distribution for these states is known. Thus, the states of nature will be
mutually exclusive, and the sum of their probabilities will equal 1.0. Risk increases as the
variability of outcomes becomes greater. In practice, however, the terms risk and uncertainty are
often treated as synonyms.

RISK
Risk refers to the variability of cash flow (or earnings) around the expected value
(return). Risk can be measured in either absolute or relative terms. Statistics such as standard
deviation and coefficient of deviation are used to measure risk

EXPECTED VALUE
Expected value is a weighted average using the probabilities as weights. For decisions
involving uncertainty, the concept of expected value provides a rational means for selecting the
best course of action.

The expected value ( r ) is found by multiplying the profit outcome for ith possible event
by the probability of each profit outcome.

r =∑ ri pi

where ri is the profit outcome for ith possible event and pi is the probability of occurrence of that
profit outcome.
202
EXAMPLE 1
Consider two investment proposals, A and B, with the following probability distribution of
cash flows in each of the next five years:

Cash Inflows
Probability (.2) (.6) (.2)
A $200 300 400
B $100 300 500

The expected value of the cash inflow in proposal A is:


$200(.2) + 300(.6) + 400(.2) = $300
The expected value of the cash inflow in proposal B is:
$100(.2) + 300(.6) + 500(.2) = $300

Note: A rational economic decision maker (one completely guided by objective criteria) will use
expected monetary value to maximize gains under conditions of risk because (s)he is risk-neutral
(the utility of a gain equals the disutility of a loss of the same absolute amount). Expected value
represents the long-term average payoff for repeated trials. The best choice is the one having the
highest expected value (sum of the products of the possible outcomes and their respective
probabilities).

STANDARD DEVIATION
Whenever we talk about the expected value, one statistic that goes with it is standard
deviation. Standard deviation is a statistic that measures the tendency of data to be spread out or is
also a measure of the dispersion of a probability distribution. The smaller the deviation, the tighter
the distribution, and thus, the lower the riskiness of the project. It is intuitively a margin of error
associated with a given expected value. Economists can make important inferences from past data
with this measure. It is the square root of the mean of the squared deviations from the expected
value ( r ). The standard deviation, denoted with the Greek letter σ , read as sigma, is calculated as
follows:
σ = ∑ (r - r )2 pi
where
r =∑ ri pi

To calculate σ, we proceed as follows:


Step 1. First compute the expected rate of return ( r )
Step 2. Subtract each possible return from r to obtain a set of deviations (r - r )
Step 3. Square each deviation, multiply the squared deviation by the probability of occurrence for
its respective return, and sum these products to obtain the variance (σ2 ):
σ2 =∑ (r - r )2 p
Step 4. Finally, take the square root of the variance to obtain the standard deviation (σ).
The standard deviation can be used to measure the variation of such items as the expected
203
profits, expected contribution margin, or expected cash flows. It can also be used to assess the
risk associated with investment projects.

EXAMPLE 2
In Example 1, the standard deviations of proposals A and B are computed as follows:

2 2 2
For A: σA = ($200-300) (.2) + (300-300) (.6) + (400-300) (.2) = $63.25

2 2 2
For B: σB = ($100 -300) (.2) + (300-300) (.6) + (500-300) (.2) = $126.49

Proposal B is more risky than proposal A since its standard deviation is greater.

COEFFICIENT OF VARIATION
Coefficient of variation is a popular measure of relative risk. It represents the degree of
risk per unit of return. It is computed by dividing the standard deviation by the expected value.

σ/ r

EXAMPLE 3
Consider two projects with the following data:

Proposal Expected Value Standard Deviation


A $230 $107.7
B 250 208.57

The coefficient of variation for each proposal is:


For A: $107.7/$230=.47
For B: $208.57/$250=.83.
Therefore, because the coefficient is a relative measure of risk, B is considered more risky
than A.

UTILITY THEORY AND RISK


In theory, three possible profiles in risk tolerance or attitudes toward risk exist.
They are: aversion to risk, neutrality to risk, and preference for risk. Each decision
maker's attitude toward risk is determined by his or her utility of income or wealth.

1. A risk-averse decision maker displays a diminishing marginal utility of income


or wealth. This is a common, but not universal, attitude. A risk-averse manager tends to
choose options that have very little variation about expected monetary returns.
2. A risk-indifferent decision maker has a constant marginal utility of income or
wealth. She neither seeks nor avoids risk. (S)he will choose investments for which the

204
expected monetary values are equal to the manager’s subjectively perceived utility
values (expressed in utils, an arbitrary measure). Thus, she has a linear utility function,
one in which the monetary amounts and utilities have a constant or directly proportional
relationship. Accordingly, (s)he is indifferent to risk.
3. A risk-seeker’s marginal utility of income or wealth increases. A risk-seeking
manager chooses risk. A risk seeker prefers investments that have the potential for large
gains even though large losses may also be possible. The utility function for the risk
seeker increases at an increasing rate; i.e., riskier investments are appealing.

Managerial decisions cannot be based solely on expected outcomes, but must


incorporate an analysis of risk attitudes. Figure 1 shows the relations between money
and its utility for three types of decision makers: (a) a risk averter, (b) risk-neutral
manager, and (c) risk seeker.

FIGURE 1
RISK PROFILES AND MONEY/UTILITY RELATIONS

EXAMPLE 4
You are considering two investment choices, each costing $5,000. Cash inflows of
possible outcomes and their associated probabilities are:
Investment A Investment B
Cash inflows Probability Cash inflows Probability
$ 6,000 0.25 $ 5,000 0.3
8,000 0.50 9,000 0.5
10,000 0.25 10,000 0.2

Assume that your utility function is given by the following table:

Money $5,000 6,000 7,000 8,000 9,000 10,000


205
Utility (Utils) 125 144 161 176 189 200

First, the expected value of the cash inflow in Investment A is:

$6000(.25) + 8000(.5) + 10000(.25) = $8000


The expected value of the cash inflow in Investment B is:
$5000(.3) + 9000(.5) + 10000(.2) = $8000

Second, the standard deviations of Investments A and B are computed as follows:

For A:

2 2 2
σA = ($6000 - 8000) (.25) + (8000 - 8000) (.5) + (10000 - 8000) (.25)
= $1414.21

For B:

2 2 2
σB = ($5000 - 8000) (.3) + (9000 - 8000) (.5) + (10000 - 8000) (.2)

= $2000

Investment B is more risky than Investment A.


Third, the expected utility, E(U), of each investment is computed as follows:
For Investment A:
E(UA) = 144(.25) + 176(.5) + 200(.25) = 174 utils
For Investment B:
E(UB) = 125(.3) + 189(.5) + 200(.2) =172 utils

Based on the expected utility, you should choose Investment A. Since you are a risk
averter, having a diminishing marginal utility of money, you would prefer the investment with less
risk, with equal expected dollar returns. Note that your utility does not increase by 19 (144 minus
125) as your income increases by $1,000.

NOTE:
The utility function can take various mathematical forms: for example,
1. U = 30 + 2X (X = money or income) indicates a constant marginal utility of income
(i.e., risk neutral)
2. U = 30X - X2 indicates a diminishing marginal utility of income (i.e., risk aversion).
3. U = 20X + X2 indicates an increasing marginal utility of income (i.e., risk seeking).

206
Note: The decision rule that selects the strategy with the highest utility payoff if the worst state
of nature occurs is the maximin rule.The maximin rule determines the minimum payoff for each
decision and then chooses the decision with the maximum payoff. It is a conservative criterion
adopted by risk-averse players, that is, those for whom the disutility of a loss exceeds the utility of
an equal gain.

RISK ANALYSIS IN CAPITAL BUDGETING


Risk analysis is important in making capital investment decisions because of the large
amount of capital involved and the long-term nature of the investments being considered.
The higher the risk associated with a proposed project, the greater the rate of return that must
be earned on the project to compensate for that risk.
Since different investment projects involve different risks, it is important to incorporate
risk into the analysis of capital budgeting. There are several methods for incorporating risk,
including:
1. Probability distributions
2. Risk-adjusted discount rate
3. Certainty equivalent
4. Simulation
5. Sensitivity analysis
6. Decision trees (or probability trees)

PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTIONS
Expected values of a probability distribution may be computed. Before any capital
budgeting method is applied, compute the expected cash inflows, or in some cases, the expected
life of the asset.

EXAMPLE 5
A firm is considering a $30,000 investment in equipment that will generate cash savings
from operating costs. The following estimates regarding cash savings and useful life, along
with their respective probabilities of occurrence, have been made:

Annual Cash Savings Probability Useful Life Probability


$6,000 0.2 4 years 0.2
$8,000 0.5 5 years 0.6
$10,000 0.3 6 years 0.2

Then, the expected annual saving is:

$6,000 (0.2) = $1,200


$8,000 (0.5) = 4,000
$10,000 (0.3) = 3,000
$8,200

207
The expected useful life is:

4 (0.2) = 0.8
5 (0.6) = 3.0
6 (0.2) = 1.2
5 years

The expected NPV is computed as follows (assuming a 10 percent cost of capital):

NPV = PV - I = $8,200 T4(10%,5) - $30,000


= $8,200 (3.7908) - $30,000 = $31,085 - $30,000 = $1,085

The expected IRR is computed as follows: By definition, at IRR,

I = PV
$30,000 = $8,200 T4 (r,5)

$30,000
T4(r,,5) = ---------- = 3.6585
$8,200

which is about halfway between 10 percent and 12 percent in Table 4 in the Appendix, so that we
can estimate the rate to be about 11 percent. Therefore, the equipment should be purchased, since
(1) NPV = $1,085, which is positive, and/or (2) IRR = 11 percent, which is greater than the cost
of capital of 10 percent.

RISK-ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE


This method of risk analysis adjusts the cost of capital (or discount rate) upward as
projects become riskier, i.e., a risk-adjusted discount rate is the riskless rate plus a risk premium.
Therefore, by increasing the discount rate from 10 percent to 15 percent, the expected cash
flow from the investment must be relatively larger or the increased discount rate will generate a
negative NPV, and the proposed acquisition/investment would be turned down. The expected
cash flows are discounted at the risk-adjusted discount rate and then the usual capital budgeting
criteria such as NPV and IRR are applied.

NOTE:
The use of the risk-adjusted discount rate is based on the assumption that investors
demand higher returns for riskier projects.

EXAMPLE 6
A firm is considering an investment project with an expected life of 3 years. It requires an
initial investment of $35,000. The firm estimates the following data in each of the next
4 years:
208
After-Tax Cash Inflow Probability
-$5,000 0.2
$10,000 0.3
$30,000 0.3
$50,000 0.2

Assuming a risk-adjusted required rate of return (after taxes) of 20 percent is appropriate


for the investment projects of this level or risk, compute the risk-adjusted NPV. First, the present
value is:
PV= -$5,000(0.2) + $10,000(0.3) + $30,000(0.3) + $50,000(0.2)=$21,000
The expected NPV = $21,000 T4(20%,3) - $35,000
= 21,000 (2,107)-$35,000 = $44,247 - $35,000 = $9,247

CERTAINTY EQUIVALENT APPROACH


The certainty equivalent approach to risk analysis is to convert cash flows from
individual projects into risk adjusted certainty equivalent cash flows. The approach is drawn
directly from the concept of utility theory. This method forces the decision maker to specify at
what point the firm is indifferent to the choice between a certain sum of money and the expected
value of a risky sum.

Under this approach, first determine a certainty equivalent adjustment factor, α, as:

Certain sum
α= ----------------------------
Equivalent risky sum

Once α‘s are obtained, they are multiplied by the original cash flow to obtain the equivalent
certain cash flow. Then, the accept-or-reject decision is made, using the normal capital
budgeting criteria. The risk-free rate of return is used as the discount rate under the NPV
method and as the cutoff rate under the IRR method.

EXAMPLE 7
XYZ, Inc., with a 14 percent cost of capital after taxes is considering a project with an
expected life of 4 years. The project requires an initial certain cash outlay of $50,000. The
expected cash inflows and certainty equivalent coefficients are as follows:

Year After-Tax Cash Flow Certainty Equivalent Adjustment Factor


1 $10,000 0.95
2 15,000 0.80
3 20,000 0.70
4 25,000 0.60

209
Assuming that the risk-free rate of return is 5 percent, the NPV and IRR are computed as follows:

First, the equivalent certain cash inflows are obtained as follows:

After-Tax Equivalent
Cash Certain
Year Inflow α Cash Inflow PV at 5% PV
1 $10,000 0.95 $ 9,500 0.9524 $9,048
2 15,000 0.80 12,000 0.9070 10,884
3 20,000 0.70 14,000 0.8638 12,093
4 25,000 0.60 15,000 0.8227 12,341
44,366

NPV = $44,366 - $50,000 = -$5,634

By trial and error, we obtain 4 percent as the IRR. Therefore, the project should be rejected,
since (1) NPV = -$5,634, which is negative and/or (2) IRR = 4 percent is less than the risk-free
rate of 5 percent.

SIMULATION
This risk analysis method is frequently called Monte Carlo simulation. It requires
that a probability distribution be constructed for each of the important variables affecting
the project's cash flows. Since a computer is used to generate many results using random
numbers, project simulation is expensive.

SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS
Forecasts of many calculated NPVs under various alternative functions are compared
to see how sensitive NPV is to changing conditions. It may be found that a certain variable or
group of variables, once their assumptions are changed or relaxed, drastically alters the NPV.
This results in a much riskier asset than was originally forecast.

DECISION TREES
Some firms use decision trees (probability trees) to evaluate the risk of capital budgeting
proposals. A decision tree is a graphical method of showing the sequence of possible
outcomes. A capital budgeting tree would show the cash flows and NPV of the project under
different possible circumstances. The decision tree method has the following advantages: (1)
It visually lays out all the possible outcomes of the proposed project and makes management
aware of the adverse possibilities, and (2) the conditional nature of successive years' cash flows
can be expressly depicted. The disadvantages are: (1) most problems are too complex to
permit year-by-year depiction and (2) it does not recognize risk.

Note: In a decision tree, the events following from a decision are mutually exclusive. Also, all
possible events are included. Thus, the sum of the probabilities of the events is 1.0.

210
EXAMPLE 8
Assume XYZ Corporation wishes to introduce one of two products to the market this year.
The probabilities and present values (PV) of projected cash inflows are given below:

Product Initial investment PV of cash inflows Probabilities


A $225,000 1.00
$450,000 0.40
200,000 0.50
-100,000 0.10

B 80,000 1.00
320,000 0.20
100,000 0.60
-150,000 0.20

A decision tree analyzing the two products is given in Figure 2.

FIGURE 2

Based on the expected NPV, choose product A over product B. This analysis fails to
recognize the risk factor in project analysis.

QUESTIONS
1. What is risk analysis in capital budgeting?
211
2. How do you define risk?
3. What is meant by the term expected value?
4. What kinds of attitudes toward risk exist?
5. List five common categories of risk.
6. How does the standard deviation differ from the coefficient of variation?
7. What is a risk-adjusted discount rate?
8. Define a certainty equivalent adjustment factor. How is it used?
9. What is a decision tree? Explain how is it used, and discuss the problem inherent in
its application to capital project analysis.

PROBLEMS
1. Assume likely rate of return (including dividends and price changes), depending upon the
economic climate (i.e., prosperity, normal, and stagflation).

State of economy Return (r ) Probability (p )


Prosperity 20% .5
Normal 10 .3
Stagflation -5 .2

(a) Compute the expected return.


(b) Compute the standard deviation

2. The probabilities and net cash inflows of an investment are:

Probability Net Cash Inflows


0.2 $ 60
0.1 80
0.3 90
0.2 115
0.2 150

(a) Calculate the expected value, standard deviation, and coefficient of variation.
(b) Is this investment considered relatively risky or riskless? Why?

3. The sales manager of the Electronic Toy Company is considering two toys: a doll and a game.
The toys have discrete probability distributions of cash inflows in each of the next three years.

Event Doll Probability Game


Prosperity $20,000 0.2 $42,000
Normal 15,000 0.5 20,000
Recession 9,000 0.3 (5,000)

1. For each toy item, compute

212
(a) The expected value of the cash inflows in each of the next three years
(b) The standard deviation
(c) The coefficient of variation

2. Which toy would you select, and why?

4. Handu, Inc., is contemplating a capital investment project with an expected useful


life of 10 years that requires an initial cash outlay of $225,000. The company estimates
the following data:

Annual Cash Inflows ($) Probabilities


0 0.10
50,000 0.20
65,000 0.40
70,000 0.20
90,000 0.10

(a) Assuming a risk-adjusted required rate of return of 25 percent is appropriate for


projects of this level of risk, calculate the risk-adjusted NPV of the project.
(Given T4(25%, l0) = 3.8135)
(b) Should the project be accepted?

5. Moore Corporation is considering the purchase of a new machine that will last 5
years and require a cash outlay of $300,000. The firm has a 12 percent cost of capital
rate and its after-tax risk-free rate is 9 percent. The company has expected cash inflows
and certainty equivalents for these cash inflows, as follows:

Year After-Tax Cash Certainty


Inflows ($) Equivalent
1 100,000 1.00
2 100,000 0.95
3 100,000 0.90
4 100,000 0.80
5 100,000 0.70

(a) Calculate the unadjusted NPV and the certainty equivalent NPV.
(b) Determine if the machine should be purchased.

6. Based on the industry supply and demand analysis, Madden Corporation wishes to
build a full-scale manufacturing facility. It is considering:

A. Build a large plant, costing $6 million.


B. Build a small plant, costing $2 million.

213
The probabilities of various demands and present values of projected cash inflows for
these demand situations are given below.

Demand PV of
Action Conditions Cash Inflows Probabilities
($)
A High $8 million 0.5
Medium 4 million 0.3
Low 1.5 million 0.2

B High $3 million 0.5


Medium 2 million 0.3
Low 1.5 million 0.2

(a) Construct a decision tree to analyze the two options.


(b) Which option would you choose? Comment on your decision.

ANSWERS
1. Risk analysis is the process of measuring and analyzing the risks associated with managerial
and investment decisions.
2. Risk refers to the variability of cash flow (or earnings) around the expected value (return).
3. Expected value is a weighted average using the probabilities as weights. For decisions
involving risk or uncertainty, the concept of expected value provides a rational means for
selecting the best course of action.
4. (a) a risk averter, (b) risk-neutral manager, and (c) risk seeker.
5. Liquidity risk. The chance that corporate assets or investments may not be sold on short notice
for its market value. (2) Inflation (purchasing power) risk. The failure of corporate agreements
involving a fixed payment (such as leases and corporate bonds) to earn a return to keep up
with increasing price levels. (3) Interest rate risk. The variability in the value of an asset to
changing interest rates and money conditions. For example, if interest rates increase
(decrease), bond (stock) prices decrease (increase). (4) Business risk. The risk associated with
changes in a firm's sales. This may be due to operating difficulties such as strike and
technological obsolescence. (5) Market risk. The change in the price of a portfolio of
investments arising from changes in the overall stock market, irrespective of the fundamental
financial condition of the company. For instance, stock prices of companies may be impacted
by bull or bear markets.
6. Risk can be measured in either absolute or relative terms. Standard deviation and coefficient
of variation are used to measure risk. Standard deviation is a measure of absolute risk, while
the coefficient of variation is used to measure relative risk.
7. This method of risk analysis adjusts the cost of capital (or discount rate) upward as
projects become riskier, i.e., a risk-adjusted discount rate is the riskless rate plus a risk
premium.
214
8. A certainty equivalent adjustment factor, α, is defined as:

Certain sum
α= ----------------------------
Equivalent risky sum

Once α‘s are obtained, they are multiplied by the original cash flow to obtain the equivalent
certain cash flow. Then, the accept-or-reject decision is made, using the normal capital
budgeting criteria.
9. A decision tree is a graphical method of showing the sequence of possible outcomes.
A capital budgeting tree would show the cash flows and NPV of the project under
different possible circumstances. The disadvantages are: (1) most problems are too
complex to permit year-by-year depiction and (2) it fails to recognize risk.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.

(a) The expected rate is:

r = (20%)(.5) + (10%)(.3) + (-5%)(.2) =12%

On average, your annual return is 12%, ranging from a 5 percent loss to 20 percent gain.

(b)

Return Probability
2 2
(r ) (p ) rp (r - r ) (r - r ) (r - r ) p
20% .5 10% 8% 64 32
10 .3 3 -2 4 1.2
-5 .2 -1 -17 289 57.8
r =12% 91
91 =9.54%

The expected annual return has an average variation of 9.54 percent.

2.

(a)

Expected value =

($60)(0.2) + ($80)(0.1) + ($90)(0.3) + ($115)(0.2) + ($150)(0.2) = $100

215
Standard deviation =

2 2 2 2 2
(0.2)($60 - $100) + (0.1)($80 - $100) + (0.3)($90 - $100) + (0.2)($115 - $100) + (0.2)($150 - $100) = $30.58

Coefficient of variation = $30.58/$100 = 0.3

(b)

The investment is relatively riskless because the coefficient of variation is low.

3.

(a) For the doll:

Expected value =

($20,000)(0.2) + ($15,000)(0.5) + ($9,000)(0.3) = $4,000 + $7,500 + $2,700 = $14,200

For the game:

Expected value =

($42,000)(0.2) + ($20,000)(0.5) + ($5,000)(0.3) = $8,400 + $10,000 + $1,500 = $19,900

(b) For the doll:

2 2 2
($20000 - 14200) (.2) + ($15000 - 14200) (.5) + ($9000 -14200) (.3)

= $3,893.58

For the game:

2 2 2
($42000 -16900) (.2) + ($20000 - 16900) (.5) + ($5000 - 16900) (.3)

= $16,573.77

(c) The coefficient of variation is:

216
For the doll $3,893.58 / $14,200 = 0.274
For the game $16,573.77/$19,900 = 0.833.

2. Since the coefficient is a relative measure of risk, the game is said to have a greater degree of
risk than the doll. Therefore, the doll is the better choice.

4.

(a )

r = $0(0.10) + $50,000(0.2) + $65,000(0.4) + $70,000(0.2) +


$90,000(0.1)
= $0 + $10,000 + $26,000 + $14,000 + $9,000 = $59,000

Expected NPV = PV- I

= $59,000 T4(25%, l0) - $225,000 = $210,689- $225,000 = -$14,311

(b) Reject the project, since the expected NPV is negative.

5.

(a)

NPV = PV ~ I = $100,000 T4(12%,5) - $300,000


= $100,000(3.605)- $300,000 = $360,500 - $300,000 =
$60,500

After-Tax Certainty Certain


Year Cash Inflows Equivalents Cash Inflows PV at 9% PV {$)
($) ($)
1 100,000 1.00 100,000 0.917 91,700
2 100,000 0.95 95,000 0.842 79,990
3 100,000 0.90 90,000 0.772 69,480
4 100,000 0.80 80,000 0.708 56,640
5 100,000 0.70 70,000 0.650 45,500
343,310

Certainty equivalent NPV= $343,310- $300,000= $43,310

(b) Because of a positive NPV, the machine should be purchased.

7.

217
(a) Expected NPVs for A and B are as follows:

Demand PV of
Action Conditions Cash Inflows ($) Probabilities (1)x (2)
(1) (2)
A High $8 million 0.5 $4 million
Medium 4 million 0.3 1.2 million
Low 1.5 million 0.2 0.3 million
PV $5.5 million
I 6.0 million
Expected -0.5 million
NPV =

B High $3 million 0.5 $1.5 million


Medium 2 million 0.3 .6 million
Low 1.5 million 0.2 .3 million
PV $2.4 million
I 2.0 million
Expected 0.4 million
NPV =

(b) Choose Option B since its expected NPV is greater than Option A’s. This approach
does not tell us how risky each option is.

218
CHAPTER 13
A MANAGER'S GUIDE TO GOVERNMENT IN THE MARKET PLACE

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

After studying this chapter you will be able to:

1. List and give examples of an antitrust policy.


2. Explain the implications of the Clayton Antitrust Act.
3. Identify the role of the Robinson-Patman Act.
4. Characterize and outline the components of the Sherman Antitrust Act.
5. Differentiate between positive and negative externalities.
6. Explain and give examples of public goods.
7. Compute and illustrate the benefit-cost ratio.

An important element of the competitive environment is the growing importance


of government involvement in the market economy. Recent changes in the method and
scope of government regulation, including moves toward deregulation, affect the entire
spectrum of economic activity, from industrials, to financial institutions (banks, savings
and loans, insurance, etc.), to power and transportation utilities. Both state and federal
regulation and antitrust policy constitute important constraints on many managerial
decisions. As a result, their analysis constitutes an important aspect of managerial
economics. This chapter presents the role of government in the market economy,
including:

(a) economic and political rationale for regulation,


(b) direct regulation of firms possessing substantial market power,
(c) antitrust policy designed to maintain a "workable" level of competition in the
economy, and
(d) public expenditure decisions and cost-benefit analysis.

THE RATIONALE FOR REGULATION


Government regulation is sometimes justified on the basis of its ability to correct
various market imperfections or market failures which lead to inefficiency and waste.

Most often, market failure is thought to be caused by:

(a) Structural problems: too few buyers or sellers.


(b) Incentive problems: externalities such as pollution.

Government regulation is sometimes justified on the basis of political


considerations. Primary among such considerations are desires to:

219
(a) Preserve Consumer Choice: A wide variety of production enhances personal
freedom.
(b) Limit Economic and Political Power: Unchecked economic and political power
could threaten basic liberties.

ANTITRUST POLICY: GOVERNMENT REGULATION OF


MARKET CONDUCT AND STRUCTURE
Antitrust policy is a set of legislations aimed at prohibiting monopolies,
restraints of trade, price fixing and discrimination, exorbitant quantity discounts to
large buyers, and conspiracies to suppress competition. Federal statutes include the
Sherman Antitrust Act, Clayton Antitrust Act, Robinson-Patman Act, and
Cellar-Kefauver Act.

Antitrust laws are designed to promote more efficient allocation of resources,


greater choice for consumers, greater business opportunities, fairness in economic
behavior, and avoidance of concentrated political power resulting from economic
power. Competition results in greater output and lower prices than other market
structures.

Sherman Antitrust Act (1890)


The cornerstone of U.S. antitrust policy is contained in Sections I and 2 of the
Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890:
Section 1: Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states, or with
foreign nations, is hereby declared to be illegal. Every person who shall make
any such contract or engage in any such combination or conspiracy shall be
deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof shall be punished by a fine
not exceeding five thousand dollars (one million dollars if a corporation, or, if
any other person, one hundred thousand dollars) or by imprisonment not
exceeding one (three) years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the
court.
Section 2 : Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or
combine or conspire with any person or persons, to monopolize any part of the
trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be
deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by a fine
not exceeding five thousand dollars (one million dollars if a corporation, or, if
any other person, one hundred thousand dollars) or by imprisonment not
exceeding one (three) years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the
court.

Clayton Act (1914)


The Clayton Act was designed to overcome some of the ambiguity of the
Sherman Act by explicitly prohibiting certain behavior. The Clayton Antitrust Act is one of
three major antitrust laws, passed as an amendment to the Sherman Antitrust Act in 1914. The Act

220
listed four illegal practices in restraint of competition. It outlawed price discrimination, tying
contracts and exclusive dealerships, and horizontal mergers. It also outlawed interlocking
directorates (the practice of having the same people serve as directors of two or more competing
firms).
Section 2: Forbade price discrimination between firms which tended to lessen
competition. This section was later amended by the Robinson-Patman Act (1936).
It is important to remember that price discrimination between consumers, such as
senior citizen discounts for bus service, is legal.
Section 3 : Made leases or any sales contracts which lessened competition illegal.
This provision was aimed at so-called tying contracts.
Section 7 : Forbade stock mergers for monopoly purposes.

Robinson-Patman Act (1936)


The Robinson Patman Act (1936) is an amendment to strengthen Section 2 of the
Clayton Act regarding price discrimination. For example, Section 2(a) of the Robinson
Patman Act amends Section 2 of the Clayton Act and makes price discrimination illegal
if it is designed to lessen competition or create a monopoly:
Section 2 (a): That it shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in
the course of such commerce, either directly or indirectly, to discriminate in
price between different purchasers of commodities of like grade and quality,
…where such discrimination may be substantially to lessen competition or tend
to create a monopoly in line of commerce, or to injure, destroy, or prevent
competition.
Price discrimination that arises because of cost or quality differences is permitted under
the act, as is price discrimination when it is necessary to meet a competitor's price in a
market. Still, there is considerable ambiguity regarding whether a particular type of
price discrimination is illegal under the law.

Cellar-Kefauver Act (1950)


The Cellar-Kefauver Act (1950) strengthened Section 7 of the Clayton Act by
making it more difficult for firms to engage in mergers and acquisitions without
violating the law:
Section 7: That no corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital and no
corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the Federal Trade Commission shall
acquire the whole or any part of the assets of another corporation engaged also in
commerce, where in any line of commerce in any section of the country, the
effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend
to create a monopoly.

Enforcement
The Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade
Commission (FTC) are charged with the task of enforcing antitrust regulations. The
FTC has limited judicial power; taking violators to court falls almost exclusively on the

221
Antitrust Division of the DOJ. Instead, the FTC issues cease-and-desist orders based
on information gathered in a specific case. If the cease-and-desist order is not followed,
the FTC may levy a fine of up to $10,000 on the guilty party. If further noncompliance
occurs, the FTC usually enjoins the DOJ for further prosecution.

RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND THE SUPPLY OF PUBLIC GOODS


The resource allocation question applies both to privately produced goods and to
public sector output. In theory the amount of any good that should be supplied at a
point in time is that quantity which equates the marginal social cost (MSC) of the good
with its marginal social benefit (MSB).

First, the marginal private economic cost of a good includes all explicit and
implicit costs of its production that are borne by the producer. A product's marginal
social cost differs from its marginal private cost by the amount of external costs
(third-party costs) that accompany the production of an incremental unit of output. This
cost includes the value to consumers of any alternative product or products whose
production is reduced or eliminated.
In a similar fashion we can define marginal social benefit as the sum of marginal
private benefits and marginal external, or third-party, benefits. The private benefits
accrue to those who directly pay a price for the good, while the external benefits are
enjoyed by either the purchaser or the nonpurchasers but are not accounted for in the
product's market price.
A good should be provided up to the quantity where MSC = MSB. A theoretically
optimal allocation of society's resources exists when for all goods the condition that
MSB = MSC is attained.

EXAMPLE 1
Assume a two-good case, where a and b are the goods, where both costs and
benefits are measured in dollars, and where initially we have

MSBa = MSC a = 20
MSBb = MSC b = 40

Thus, the social cost of producing the marginal or last unit of a is $20, while that of
producing the marginal unit of b is $40. Obviously, it is also true that

MSB a MSBb
------ = ------ =1
MSC a MSC b

First, for a given income distribution, efficient resource allocation will take place
when, for n goods,
MSB a MSBb MSBn
---- = ----- = ….. ------- = 1
222
MSC a MSC b MSC n

This condition simply means that a dollar's worth of social benefit is received
for an additional dollar spent on the production of each good. Any deviation from this
condition would result in a situation where too much of some good (or goods) and too
little of some other good (or goods) is produced.

NOTE:
1.The optimal quantity of a public good (Q*) is produced where the MSB of the
good equals its MSC. At Q*, net social benefit—the difference between total social
benefit t and total social cost-is maximized. Production beyond Q* would add more to
social cost than to social benefit.
2. No incremental activity (j) should be undertaken where MSC j > MSBj

PUBLIC PROJECT ANALYSIS AND COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS


In public project analysis, we seek to evaluate investments from the point of view of
society as a whole. This means that we need to determine social benefits deriving from public
projects and social costs incurred to launch those projects. A social benefit is any gain in utility
and a social cost is any loss of utility as measured by the opportunity cost of the project in
question.

We use cost-benefit analysis, which is simply the extension of capital project


analysis, as discussed in Chapter 11, to public sector microeconomic decisions. The
steps usually taken in the construction of a cost-benefit analysis for a public-sector
undertaking are as follows:

1. Specify objectives and identify constraints.


2. Formulate alternative means of meeting objectives.
3. Estimate costs of each alternative.
4. Estimate benefits attributable to each alternative.
5. Select the best alternative.
The benefit-cost (B/C) ratio or profitability index is widely used for public expenditure decisions.

CLASSIFICATION OF GOODS
Most goods originate with private sectors. They are categorized as private goods, and
those that are governmental in origin are public goods. Public goods are nonrival and
nonexclusionary in consumption and therefore benefit persons other than those who buy the
goods. A good is nonrival in consumption if the consumption of the good by one person does not
preclude other people from also consuming the good. A good is nonexclusionary if, once
provided, no one can be excluded from consuming it. Examples of public goods are radio signals,
lighthouses, national defense, and clean air.

In order to determine which public goods or projects are worthwhile, and their optimal
magnitude, we have to quantify the expected stream of costs and the value of the benefits, and
223
whether revenues can be collected or not. Since any public project involves expected future
flows of costs and benefits, we need to deal with the issue of appropriate discounting. What is a
proper social discount rate is an unresolved issue.

NOTE:
Whether market interest rates adequately reflect the time preferences of society or the
productivity of public projects is always subject to debate.

SOCIAL GOODS AND EXTERNALITIES


When goods are public or social goods, there are always nonmarket interactions in which
people are forced to provide resources to others while receiving full compensation or in which
people receive benefits without having to make appropriate payments. These nonmarket flows of
burdens and benefits are known as externalities. Externalities are third-party spillover, or
neighborhood, effects. Externalities are the positive (external economies) or negative (external
diseconomies) effects that market exchanges have on people who do not participate directly in
those exchanges.

Positive externalities include the social benefits conferred by a firm in training workers
who become available to work for other firms that incur no training costs. Negative externalities
are costs of producing, marketing, consuming a product that is not borne by the product's
manufacturers or consumers. These types of externalities include traffic congestion and air
pollution. The term technological externalities is often used and is distinguished from pecuniary
externalities. Quantifying these externalities and including them in estimates of social benefits
and social costs may not be an easy task.

EXAMPLE 2
State Senator Dan Smith has proposed a new state supported convention facility
in the state's capitol. The convention facility would provide the state with annual social
benefits of $500,000 (in lease receipts and in positive externalities) and would cost
$4,000,000. The project has a 15 year life. The state planning board normally uses a 9%
discount rate when evaluating capital projects. To determine if the state legislature
should adopt Smith's proposal, we can calculate the benefit-cost (B/C) ratio. The present
value of the benefit is: $500,000 at 9% for 15 years = $500,000 x 8.061= $4,030,500.
B/C = 4,030,500/4,000,000 = 1.008, thus the state should accept Smith's proposal
because it has a B/C ratio greater than 1.

QUESTIONS
1. Compare the application of the marginality concept in the private and public sectors.
2. Give an example of a public good. Explain why it is a public good.
3. Give four reasons why free markets may fail to provide the socially efficient output
of goods or services.
4. Explain the implications of the Robinson Patman Act for business decisions.
5. List the basic steps used in cost-benefit analysis.
224
6. Describe the importance of externalities in the analysis of public goods? Do market
prices of private goods adequately reflect externalities?
5. What principle determines the optimal allocation of public goods? Discuss why this
principle equally applies to privately produced goods.

PROBLEMS
1. City Council member Norm Henteleff has proposed a new airport facility. The
facility would provide the state with $300,000 in net cash flow (lending fees, rent, etc.)
and would cost $1,800,000. The project has a 20 year life. The City’s planning board
normally uses a 10% discount rate when evaluating capital projects. Should the city
council adopt Smith's proposal? Use the cost-benefit ratio.

2. Which of the following projects would be acceptable from a cost-benefit standpoint if


the applicable discount rate is 6%?

Project Annual Annual Capital


Project Life Benefits Costs Outlay
A 20 $50,000 $20,000 $300,000
B 15 $ 5,000 $ 1,000 $ 40,000
C 10 $30,000 $ 7,000 $150,000

ANSWERS
1. In public sector economic analysis, the concept of marginal revenue and marginal
cost can be translated into marginal social benefit and marginal social cost. It is
important to recognize that while it may be difficult to achieve the demand and cost
functions necessary to determine if a firm is operating at MR=MC, it may be next to
impossible to determine the social benefits attributable to a public project, and
extremely difficult to determine public cost.
2. National defense is an example of a public good, since once it is provided, no
citizens in a country can be excluded from the benefits.
3. They are (1) market power, (2) externalities, (3) public goods, and (4) incomplete information.
4. Section 2(a) of the Robinson Patman Act makes price discrimination illegal. Basically, this Act
helps maintain market competition. Price discrimination due to cost differences or required to
meet competition is not illegal.
5. The basic steps taken in the construction of a cost-benefit analysis for a public-sector
undertaking are as follows: (a)Specify objectives and identify constraints, (b) Formulate
alternative means of meeting objectives, (c) Estimate costs of each alternative, (d)
Estimate benefits attributable to each alternative, and (e) Select the best alternative.
6. Public goods generate benefits to parties who do not engage in a market transaction
to obtain them. These benefits are called "external benefits," or simply externalities.
The market prices of privately produced goods do not reflect externalities, however,
since it is difficult or impossible to force those who enjoy the externalities to pay for
them.
7. The rule states that the optimal allocation of a public good is achieved when the
225
marginal social cost of the good equals its marginal social benefit. The principle is
essentially the same as the profit maximizing principle of MR = MC.

SOLUTIONS TO PROBLEMS
1.
The present value of the benefit is: $300,000 at 10% for 20 years = $300,000 x 8.514
$2,554,200. B/C = 2,554,200/1,800,000 = 1.419, thus the council should accept
Henteleff’s proposal because it has a B/C ratio greater than 1.

2.
Project A:
PV of annual net benefits = (50,000 - 20,000) = 30,000 x 11.47 = 344,100
B/C = 344,100/300,000 = 1.147; acceptable.
Project B:
PV of annual net benefits = (5,000 - 1,000) = 4,000 x 9.712 = 38,848
B/C = 38,848/40,000 = 0.9712, not acceptable.
Project C:
PV of annual net benefits = (30,000 - 7,000) = 23,000 x 7.360 = 169,280
B/C = 169,280/150,000 = 1.129, acceptable.

226
APPENDIX

• Table 1 Future Value of $1 = T1(i,n) = FVIF


• Table 2 Future Value of an Annuity of $1 = T2(i,n) = FVIFA
• Table 3 Present Value of $1 = T3(i,n) = PVIF
• Table 4 Present Value of an Annuity of $1 = T4(i,n) = PVIFA
• Table 5 Critical Values for the t-Statistic
• Table 6 Learning Curve Coefficients

227
TABLE 1
FUTURE VALUE OF $1 = T1(I,N) = FVIF

228
TABLE 2
FUTURE VALUE OF AN ANNUITY OF $1 = T2(I,N) = FVIFA

229
TABLE 3
PRESENT VALUE OF $1 = T3(I,N) = PVIF

230
231
TABLE 4
PRESENT VALUE OF AN ANNUITY OF $1 = T4(I,N) = PVIFA

232
TABLE 5

233
TABLE 6
LEARNING CURVE COEFFICIENTS

234
GLOSSARY
ACCOUNTING PROFITS difference between the total revenue and the cost of producing goods
or services.

ACTIVITY ANALYSIS evaluation involving the determination of the combination of


production processes that maximizes output (or profits), subject to the restrictions on
the required resources (inputs).

ANTI-TRUST POLICY policy encouraging fair and free trade and competition.

AVERAGE PRODUCT total amount of output divided by the amount of the input used to
produce the output.

AVERAGE REVENUE total revenue per unit of output, that is total revenue received divided by
output.

AVERAGE VARIABLE COST total variable cost divided by the corresponding number
of units of output.

BAROMETRIC FORECASTING use of economic indicators such as leading indicators to predict


turning points in economic activity.

BASIC FEASIBLE SOLUTIONS corner point solutions of the feasible region that
satisfy all the constraints simultaneously.

BLOCK PRICING pricing under which units of a product are sold as one package.

BREAK-EVEN POINT level of sales revenue that equals the total of the variable and
fixed costs for a given volume of output at a particular capacity use rate.

CAPITAL BUDGETING process of making long-term planning and capital expenditure


decisions.

CAPITAL RATIONING situation that exists when a firm has more acceptable projects than it has
funds available to invest. The projects are ranked in priority order.

CERTAINTY EQUIVALENT APPROACH approach that converts cash flows from individual
projects into risk adjusted certainty equivalent cash flows.

CLAYTON ANTITRUST ACT one of three major antitrust laws, passed as an amendment to the
Sherman Antitrust Act in 1914. It outlawed price discrimination, tying contracts and exclusive
dealerships, and horizontal mergers.

235
COBB-DOUGLAS PRODUCTION FUNCTION production function that assumes
some degree of substitutability among inputs. The relationship between output and the
inputs is not linear.

COEFFICIENT OF DETERMINATION proportion of the total variation in the


dependent variable that is explained by the regression equation.

COEFFICIENT OF VARIATION ratio of the standard deviation to the expected value. A relative
measure of risk.

COMMODITY BUNDLING practice of bundling several different products together and


selling them at a single "bundle price."

CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION optimization with the restrictions imposed on the availability


of resources and other requirements. Techniques such as linear programming (LP) and the
Lagrangean multipliers are used for this purpose.

CONSUMER SURVEYS method that involves interviewing potential customers to


estimate demand relations.

CORRELATION COEFFICIENT measure of the degree of correlation between the two


variables.

COST OF CAPITAL rate of return that investors expect to receive from the firm.

COST-BASED PRICE widely used pricing technique that involves an appropriate cost base plus
the markup--usually calculated as some percentage of the cost base.

COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS appraisal that attempts to determine whether the favorable results
of an alternative are sufficient to justify the cost of taking that alternative. This analysis is widely
used in connection with capital expenditure projects in the government sector.

CROSS ELASTICITY responsiveness of one product to changes in the price of some


other product, holding all other factors constant.

CROSS SUBSIDIZATION pricing method in which the firm may enhance profits by
selling one product at or below cost and the other product above cost.

DECISION TREE graphical method of showing the sequence of possible outcomes.

DEMAND CURVE graph of a demand schedule Price is on the vertical axis and quantity
demanded is on the horizontal axis.

DEMAND FUNCTION mathematical relationship showing how the quantity demanded of a

236
good or service responds to changes in a number of economic factors such as its own price, the
prices of substitutes and complementary goods, income, and advertising.

DEMAND SCHEDULE table or tabular representation of the quantity demanded at various


possible prices during a given time period, all other things remaining equal. The data from a
demand schedule can be used to construct a demand curve.

DERIVATIVE instantaneous rate of change of a function at a given point or the slope


of its tangent. It is a specification of the marginal relation in economics.

DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW (DCF) TECHNIQUES methods of selecting and ranking


investment proposals such as the net present value (NPV) and internal rate of return (IRR)
methods where time value of money is taken into account.

DURBIN-WATSON STATISTIC summary measure of the amount of autocorrelation (or serial


correlation) in the error terms of the regression.

ECONOMETRIC MODELS statistically based models where relationships among economic


variables are expressed in mathematical equations, single or simultaneous in nature, and then
estimated using such techniques as regression methods.

ECONOMETRICS branch of economics concerned with empirical testing of economic theory


using various statistical methods such as regression analysis.

ECONOMIC PROFITS difference between the total revenue and the total opportunity costs.

EQUILIBRIUM PRICE price of a commodity (good and service) toward which a competitive
market will move and, once there, at which it will remain.

EXPANSION PATH graphical device used to illustrate the amount of capital and labor that a
firm will use as it expands its operations.

EXPECTED UTILITY weighted average of utilities using the probabilities as weights.

EXPECTED VALUE weighted average using the probabilities as weights.

EXPONENTIAL SMOOTHING forecasting technique that uses a weighted moving


average of past data as the basis for a forecast.

EXTERNALITIES positive (beneficial) or negative (harmful) effects that market exchanges have
on people who do not participate directly in those exchanges.

FIRST DERIVATIVE TEST test to locate one or more extreme (maximum or


minimum) points on a function.

237
FOUR-FIRM CONCENTRATION RATIO fraction of total industry sales produced by the four
largest firms in the industry.

GOODNESS-OF-FIT degree to which a model fits the observed data.

HERFINDAHL-HIRSHMAN INDEX sum of the squared market shares.

IDENTIFICATION PROBLEM statistical problem encountered in the estimation of the


parameters of one function such as the demand function when simultaneous relations exist.

INCREMENTAL (DIFFERENTIAL) COSTS costs associated with any managerial decision. This
is equivalent to the marginal cost concept but involves multiple changes in output and discrete
output choices, rather than a single-unit change.

INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS models concerned with the flow of goods among industries in an
economy or among branches of a large organization.

INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN (IRR) rate earned on a proposal. It is the rate of interest that
equates the initial investment with the present value of future cash inflows.

ISO-COST CURVE curve or line showing the combinations of any inputs that can be bought
with a fixed sum of money.

LAGRANGEAN MULTIPLIER measure of the marginal change in the value of the objective
function resulting from a one-unit change in the value on the right-hand side of the equality sign
in the constraint.

LEARNING CURVE EFFECT reduction in labor hours as the cumulative production doubles,
ranging typically from 10 percent to 20 percent.

LEAST-SQUARES METHOD statistical method in regression analysis aiming at finding a


regression line of best fit.

LEONTIEF PRODUCTION FUNCTION production function in which inputs are used


in fixed proportions.

LERNER INDEX measure of the difference between price and marginal cost as a
percentage of the product's price.

LINEAR PRODUCTION FUNCTION production function that assumes a perfect linear


relationship between all inputs and total output.

LINEAR PROGRAMMING (LP) mathematical technique designed to determine an


optimal decision (or an optimal plan) chosen from a large number of possible decisions.

238
LINEAR REGRESSION regression that deals with a straight line relationship between
variables.

LONG RUN AVERAGE COST CURVE curve showing the minimum cost per unit of
producing each output when all resource inputs are variable.

MARGINAL COST cost of making an additional unit of output.

MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS branch of economics, that is economics applied in managerial


decision making.

MARGINAL REVENUE change of total revenue with respect to quantity demanded.

MARGINAL ANALYSIS analysis that ensures that for the profit to be maximized, marginal
revenues equal marginal costs.

MARGINAL PRODUCT change in the quantity of output resulting from a one unit change in
the quantity of input used.

MARGINAL RATE OF TECHNICAL SUBSTITUTION rate that measures reduction in one


input per unit increase in the other that is just sufficient to maintain a constant level of output.

MARGINAL REVENUE PRODUCT net addition to total revenue attributable to the addition of
one unit of the variable productive service.

MARKET EXPERIMENTATION studies of consumer behavior in actual or simulated


market settings.

MARKUP ON COST the profit margin expressed as a percentage of unit cost.

MEAN SQUARED ERROR (MSE) average sum of the variations between the historical sales
data and the forecast values for the corresponding periods.

MOVING AVERAGE in a time series an average that is updated as new information is


received.

MULTICOLLINEARITY condition that exists when the independent variables are highly
correlated with each other.

MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS statistical procedure that attempts to assess the


relationship between the dependent variable and two or more independent variables.

NET PRESENT VALUE METHOD technique widely used for evaluating investment projects.
Under the net present value method, the present value (PV) of all cash inflows from the project is

239
compared against the initial investment (I).

OPERATING LEVERAGE measure of operating risk; the ratio of a percentage change


in operating income to a percentage change in sales volume.

OPPORTUNITY COSTS net benefits forgone by rejecting the next-best use of a resource.

OPTIMAL EMPLOYMENT RULE profit-maximizing rule that says that the marginal
revenue product of an input is exactly equal to the input price.

OPTIMAL PRICE typically profit maximizing price.

OPTIMIZATION maximization or minimization of a special goal.

PARTIAL DERIVATIVE derivative with respect to one variable in question, holding


the other variables constant.

PEAK LOAD PRICING pricing that charges a higher price during peak times than is
charged during off peak times.

PENETRATING PRICING pricing policy that involves setting low initial prices in order to gain
quick acceptance in a broad portion of the market.

PERFECT COMPETITION market structure possessing the following characteristics: (1) large
number of small firms; (2) homogeneous products; (3) free entry and exit; and (4) perfect
communication between buyers and sellers.

PLANNING (ENVELOPE) CURVE locus of points representing the least unit cost of producing
the corresponding output.

POINT PRICE ELASTICITY ratio of a percentage change in quantity demanded to a


percentage change in price.

PRESENT VALUE ANALYSIS technique used widely to account for the timing of cash inflows
and outflows.

PRIMAL AND DUAL PROBLEMS pair of related maximization and minimization


problems in linear programming

PRODUCTION FUNCTION engineering relation that defines the maximum amount of


output that can be produced with a given set of inputs.

PROFIT MAXIMIZATION hypothesis that the goal of a firm is to maximize its profit.

240
PUBLIC GOODS goods that are nonrival and nonexclusionary in consumption and therefore
benefit persons other than those who buy the goods.

REGRESSION ANALYSIS statistical procedure for estimating mathematically the average


relationship between the dependent variable (sales, for example) and one or more independent
variables (price and advertising, for example).

REGRESSION EQUATION (MODEL) forecasting model which relates the dependent variable
(sales, for example) to one or more independent variables (advertising and income, for example).

RELEVANT COSTS expected future costs (or revenues) which differ between decision
alternatives.

RETURNS TO SCALE increase in output arising from a proportionate increase in all


inputs.

RISK AVERSION displaying a diminishing marginal utility of income or wealth.

RISK variability of actual cash flow around the expected cash flows.

RISK-ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE riskless rate plus a risk premium.

ROTHSCHILD INDEX measure of the sensitivity to price of a product group as a


whole relative to the sensitivity of the quantity demanded of a single firm to a change in
its price.

r-SQUARED see coefficient of determination.

SECOND DERIVATIVE TEST test to determine whether an extreme point is either a


maximum or a minimum point.

SHADOW PRICES implicit values or opportunity costs associated with given


resources in an LP problem.

SHERMAN ANTITRUST ACT first law (1890) passed in the U.S. to prohibit a
company's attempt to monopolize.

SHORT-RUN COST CURVES cost curves for which inputs of production are both variable and
fixed.

SIMPLE REGRESSION regression analysis which involves one independent variable.

SKIMMING PRICING method of pricing that involves setting a high initial price for a new
product, with a progressively lowering of the price as time passes, and as the market broaden and

241
matures.

STANDARD DEVIATION square root of the mean of the squared deviations from the expected
value. An absolute measure of risk.

STANDARD ERROR OF THE ESTIMATE standard deviation of the regression. The statistic
can be used to gain some idea of the accuracy of our predictions.

STANDARD ERROR OF THE REGRESSION COEFFICIENT measure of the amount of


sampling error in a regression coefficient.

STATISTICAL COST ANALYSIS empirical studies that attempt to ascertain the nature of short-
run or long-run cost/output relations.

SUNK COSTS costs of resources that have already been incurred at some point in the past whose
total will not be affected by any decision made now or in the future.

SUPPLY FUNCTION mathematical relationship showing how the quantity supplied of a good or
service responds to changes in these factors.

THE GRAPHICAL METHOD graphical approach to solving a linear programming


(LP) problem. It is easier to use but limited to the LP problems involving two (or at
most three) decision variables.

THE SIMPLEX METHOD linear programming algorithm, which is an iteration method


of computation, to move from one corner point solution to another until it reaches the
best solution.

TOTAL FIXED COSTS costs that remain constant in total regardless of changes in activity.

TOTAL VARIABLE COSTS costs that vary in total in direct proportion to changes in activity.

TREND ANALYSIS statistical procedure for estimating mathematically the average


relationship between the dependent variable (sales, for example) and time. Trends are the
general upward or downward movements of the average over time.

t-TEST test for statistical significance of the regression coefficients.

TWO PART PRICING pricing that charge a per unit price that equals marginal cost, plus a
fixed fee for the right to buy the good or service.

UNIT CONTRIBUTION MARGIN selling price minus average variable cost.

VALUE OF THE FIRM present value of the firm’s expected future cash flows or profits,

242
discounted back to the present at an appropriate interest rate.

WEALTH MAXIMIZATION stockholders value maximization, which is a long-term goal.


Wealth maximization is generally preferred because it considers (1) wealth for the long term, (2)
risk or uncertainty, (3) timing of returns, and (4) the stockholders' return.

243

You might also like