Trade and Health:: Towards Building A National Strategy
Trade and Health:: Towards Building A National Strategy
Trade and Health:: Towards Building A National Strategy
Editors:
Richard Smith, Chantal Blouin, Zafar Mirza, Peter Beyer, Nick Drager
WHO Library Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
Trade and health: building a national strategy / edited by Richard Smith … [et al].
1.Commerce. 2.Public Health. 3.Health Policy. 4.National Health Programs. 5.Global Health.
6.International Cooperation. I.Smith, Richard. II.Blouin, Chantal. III.Mirza, Zafar. IV.Beyer, Peter.
V. Drager, Nick. VI.World Health Organization.
All rights reserved. Publications of the World Health Organization are available on the WHO website
(www.who.int) or can be purchased from WHO Press, World Health Organization, 20 Avenue Appia,
1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland (tel.: +41 22 791 3264; fax: +41 22 791 4857;
e-mail: bookorders@who.int).
Requests for permission to reproduce or translate WHO publications –whether for sale or for non-
commercial distribution– should be addressed to WHO Press through the WHO website
(www.who.int/about/licensing/copyright_form/en/index.html).
The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this publication do not imply the
expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the World Health Organization concerning the
legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its
frontiers or boundaries. Dotted and dashed lines on maps represent approximate border lines for which
there may not yet be full agreement.
The mention of specific companies or of certain manufacturers’ products does not imply that they
are endorsed or recommended by the World Health Organization in preference to others of a similar
nature that are not mentioned. Errors and omissions excepted, the names of proprietary products are
distinguished by initial capital letters.
All reasonable precautions have been taken by the World Health Organization to verify the information
contained in this publication. However, the published material is being distributed without warranty of
any kind, either expressed or implied. The responsibility for the interpretation and use of the material
lies with the reader. In no event shall the World Health Organization be liable for damages arising from
its use.
The named authors alone are responsible for the views expressed in this publication.
II
Preface
Globalization and the rise of international trade of goods and services in terms of volume and speed
influence human health. This influence can be both positive and negative. Our work on “trade and health” is
all about harnessing and maximizing opportunities to promote public health and minimizing the risks and
threats.
WHO and its Member States are very conscious of these opportunities and challenges. In 2006 the World
Health Assembly adopted a resolution (WHA 59.26) on international trade and health and urged Member
States to take advantage of the potential opportunities, and address the potential challenges, that trade
and trade agreements may have for health. There are a number of additional WHO resolutions and decisions
that involve the international trade and health interface. These deal with subjects such as tobacco control,
the HIV/AIDS epidemic, intellectual property, international migration of health personnel, medical tourism
as well as nutrition and alcohol policies. WHO’s work on international health regulations (IHR), which
addresses health and trade issues, epitomizes the significance that we attach to helping the international
community to prevent and respond to acute public health risks that have the potential to cross borders and
threaten people worldwide.
At the global level, WHO works closely with relevant organizations such as the World Trade Organization,
the World Intellectual Property Organization as well as the United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development. We work with the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations to develop and
promote international food standards through the Codex Alimentarius to protect the health of consumers
and ensure fair trade practices. The WHO Framework Convention of Tobacco Control (FCTC) was the first
international treaty negotiated under the auspices of WHO to tackle the globalization of the tobacco
epidemic. These are just a few examples of WHO’s involvement in trade and health related issues at global
level.
Coherence between trade and health policies at the country level is the key to effectively manage the
interface between trade and health. This requires going beyond the confines of sectoral policies to embrace
new collaborations. The first step towards policy coherence is the development of a good understanding
of the issues, based on the analysis of the situation from both a health and trade perspective. WHO has
for a long-time identified this as an area, which needs to be facilitated through technical cooperation and
provision of assistance through offering reliable empirical evidence and a menu of viable policy options.
This publication is part of WHO’s response to help develop a better understanding of the issues involved
in the interface of trade and health, generally and with reference to specific issues. We have produced
a number of important publications on trade in health services, intellectual property and public health,
and health impact of trade liberalization. Our latest publication is a product of the trilateral cooperation
between WHO, WTO and WIPO, titled “Promoting access to medical technologies and innovation:
intersections between public health, intellectual property and trade”.1 On tobacco and trade, WHO has
published “Confronting the tobacco epidemic in a new era of trade and investment liberalization” in 2012.2
This publication was initiated some years ago as part of a programme to support WHO Member States to
systematically assess their trade and health situation. The project was originally conceived as two parts:
the first, a background document on key issues in trade and health and the second, an assessment tool to
facilitate the development of national strategies on issues at the trade and health interface. We are now
pleased to make available online this background document.
I would also like to thank the WHO colleagues who reviewed the various chapters as well as all interns
working with us at different times. These include Jonathan Darrow, Ahmed Bile and Lena Schneider.
Last but not the least, I am grateful to my colleague Peter Beyer who led this project through the last mile
and made this publication possible.
Zafar Mirza
Coordinator
Public Health, Innovation & Intellectual Property
Department of Essential Medicines & Health Products
IV
Contents
Preface III
Trade and health – the linkages 1
Richard Smith, Chantal Blouin, Nick Drager
1.1 The growing challenge of trade and health 1
1.2 Overview of the relationship between trade and health 2
1.3 Overview of this book 5
Policy coherence in trade and health 7
Chantal Blouin, Nick Drager
2.1 Towards policy coherence: definitions and frameworks 7
2.2 Achieving policy coherence: key recommendations 9
2.3 Achieving policy coherence: the wider political context 16
Capacity building in trade and health 19
Alka Bhatia
3.1 Introduction 19
3.2 Trade capacity building 19
3.3 Aid for Trade 22
3.4
Integrated Framework for Trade-Related Assistance for Least Developed
Countries 25
3.5 Conclusion 32
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health 35
Richard Smith, Chantal Blouin
4.1 Introduction 35
4.2 Trade, growth and health 37
4.3 Distributional impacts of trade on income 37
4.4 Trade, government revenue and health care spending 39
4.5 Economic stability and health 39
4.6 Sources of information, key indicators and their interpretation 40
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective 45
David P. Fidler
5.1 Introduction 45
5.2 National implementation of international legal commitments: general con
siderations 45
5.3 National implementation of international legal commitments:
specific considerations related to trade and health 46
5.4 Conclusions 54
Regional trade agreements and health services 56
Mina Mashayekhi, Elisabeth Tuerk
6.1 Introduction 56
6.2 Services trade liberalization and cooperation in preferential trade agrements 63
6.3 Health services: specific experiences in selected RTAs 67
6.4 Conclusions 74
V
Trade in health services 76
Pierre Sauvé, Chantal Blouin, Aniket Bhushan, Olivier Cattaneo
7.1 Introduction 76
7.2 Trade in health-related services: characterizing the current environment 76
7.3 Evidence of the impact of trade in health services on health systems 81
7.4 Conducting a trade-related regulatory audit 86
7.5 Conclusion 90
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health 92
Corinna Hawkes, Delia Grace, Anne Marie Thow
8.1 Introduction 92
8.2 Policy measures that liberalize food trade 94
8.3 Step 1: Assessment of impact of food trade liberalization on nodes in the
food supply chain 96
8.4 Step 2: Assessment of implications for food safety, availability, price and
marketing 98
8.5 Step 3: Nutrition and health implications 103
8.6 Step 4: Implications of trade agreements for policy space to address food-
relatedill health 105
8.7. Opportunities for using trade policy to improve nutrition and health 107
8.8 Moving forward 107
Trade in medicines 117
Frederick Abbott
9.1 Introduction 117
9.2 Trade, TRIPS and TRIPS-plus 118
9.4 Ownership 123
9.5 Trade policy instruments 124
9.6 Innovation and intellectual property rights 126
9.7 Access and intellectual property rights 129
9.8 The need for a cost-benefit analysis of both pharmaceuticals and
intellectual property scope 134
9.9 Data sources, indicators and interpretation 135
9.10 Conclusion 136
9.11 Further reading 139
Contributors 141
VI
Trade and health – the linkages
Chapter 1
the role of globalization as a key factor in this relationship. Finally, section 1.3 outlines the content of the
remaining chapters of the book.
countries now have binding obligations in terms of imposition of non-tariff barriers such as Pictorial Health
Warnings on all tobacco products. The Parties to WHO-FCTC have also negotiated the Protocol to Eliminate
Illicit Trade in Tobacco Products (ITP) that is pending ratification by the requisite number of parties to come
into force.1 ITP imposes a number of non-tariff barriers/trade restrictions on the tobacco trade.
In order to begin to develop a national or regional strategy to deal with these multifarious trade and health
issues, it is helpful to systematically frame those issues first and then map out the linkages between them,
in order to create a priority order for consideration, and to assist in the development of a framework for
gathering and interpreting relevant information. The purpose of this section is to explore the implications
of international trade on health and the health sector, and thus to assist in the formulation of an informed
policy on international health and trade. This framing is illustrated in Figure 1.1
The figure aims to summarize the main determinants and linkages between trade and health. The lower
half of the figure represents the individual country under consideration, while the upper half represents the
aspects of globalization that have an impact upon the country. The three arrows between the two halves
indicate the major linkages. This is a deliberately simplified picture to provide a concise frame of reference
as background to the issues discussed in this book. A more comprehensive exposition of the various
linkages between trade and health is provided elsewhere (10,11).
1
For more details of the ITP please refer to the website of the convention: http://www.who. int/fctc/protocol/en/
3
Trade and health – the linkages
Taking the lower half of the figure first (within-country issues), the standard influences on health are
illustrated: risk factors, including genetic predisposition to disease, environmental influences on health, the
incidence of infectious disease and other factors; household economy, including factors associated with
human capital and the investment in health by individuals and households; the health sector, including
the impact of goods and services consumed principally to improve health; and the national economy,
representing the meta-influences of government structures and general economic well-being. The range of
interlinkages between these factors is also illustrated.
In the upper half (globalization issues), the influences of factors outside the national economy are
illustrated. For example, there are a wide variety of international influences upon risk factors for health,
including elevated exposure to infectious disease flowing from increased cross-border travel; increased
marketing of unhealthy products; and increased environmental degradation as a result of industrialization.
Many of these factors may be associated with negative externalities. For example, an illness contracted by
one person while on a business trip can result in risk of transmission of that illness to many others upon
return to that person’s home country. In addition, many of the risk factors at least to some extent have
public good attributes (or perhaps more accurately, “public bad” attributes). For example, the negative
effects from environmental pollution affect everyone and an individual cannot easily be excluded from
these negative effects by making different personal choices (except, perhaps, by departing the country or
region). These global externality and public good aspects of, and impacts on, health are not considered
further here, but are covered in detail elsewhere (12).
Trade also affects health through influences upon the national economy. There is an extensive literature
concerning the relationship between health and wealth (13, 14). Thus, to the extent that trade influences
economic growth, and growth is associated with improved health, then trade will be expected to influence
health through this route. Finally, trade will affect health through the direct distribution and provision of
health-related goods and services as well as the increased transfer of health-related knowledge (6). Also in
the upper half of the figure, we see the importance of international trade agreements.
Although simple, this figure therefore encapsulates the major elements of the relationship between trade
and health, and the major linkages between them. In order to develop a trade and health strategy, it is
important to understand current and pending international trade agreements as well as the way that these
international agreements have been or are likely to be implemented within a country (Chapter 5).
The blue arrows indicate the linkages between elements at the global or national level, which have been the
subject of other literature. However, of concern here are the red arrows, which indicate the need to consider
three specific forms of linkages between the global trade environment and the domestic environment.
First, trade will bring associated changes in risk factors for disease. These will include both communicable
diseases, through the greater cross-border flows of people and goods that are associated with such
diseases (for example poultry and avian influenza, cattle and bovine spongiform encephalopathy); and
noncommunicable diseases, for instance as a result of changes in the patterns of food consumption
brought about by changes in income, life style and the food industry through greater trade (Chapter 9), or
trade in hazardous or harmful substances (Chapter 8). Second, trade will have an impact upon the domestic
economy through changes in income and the distribution of that income, as well as influencing the levels
of tax receipts and the form of tax receipts. This will influence the household economy and also the ability
of government to be engaged in public finance and the provision of health care (Chapter 4). Finally, health
will also be impacted by direct trade in health-related goods and services, such as pharmaceuticals and
associated technologies, health-care workers, patients and so forth (Chapters 7 and 10). Clearly such imports
and exports will generate a variety of opportunities and risks for the health sector directly and thus have
implications for the breadth and depth of health-care provision.
As outlined in the following section, the chapters in this book are designed to provide background
information on the key aspects of trade in health in order to guide policy-makers in elaborating a national
response to trade and health-related issues, including the development of a national strategy paper on
trade and health.
4
Trade and health – the linkages
5
Trade and health – the linkages
References
1. Smith RD. Globalization: the key challenge facing health economics in the 21st century. Health
Economics, 2008, 17:1–3.
3. Smith RD, Keogh-Brown M, Barnett A, Tait J. The economy-wide impact of pandemic influenza on
the UK: a computable general equilibrium modelling experiment. British Medical Journal, 2009, 339:
b4571
4. Keogh-Brown M, Smith RD. The economic impact of SARS: how does the reality match the
predictions? Health Policy, 2008, 88:110–120.
5. Horton R. The global financial crisis: an acute threat to health. Lancet, 2009, 373(9661):355–356.
6. WTO agreements and public health: a joint study by the WHO and the WTO secretariat. Geneva,
World Health Organization and World Trade Organization, 2002.
7. Roffe P, Braun JV, Vivas-Eugui D. A new generation of regional and bilateral trade agreements:
lessons from the US-CAFTA-DR agreement. In: Blouin C, Heymann J, Drager N, eds. Trade and health:
seeking common ground. Montreal, McGill-Queen’s University Press, 2008: 41–91.
8. Blouin C, Drager N, Smith R, eds. International trade in health services and the GATS: current issues
and debates. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2005.
9. Pollock AM, Price D. Rewriting the regulations: how the World Trade Organization could accelerate
privatisation in health-care systems. Lancet, 2000, 356:1995–2000.
10. Woodward D, Drager N, Beaglehole R. Globalization and Health: A Framework for Analysis and
Action (prepared for the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health). Bulletin of the World Health
Organization 2001, 79:875–881.
11. Smith RD. Trade in health services: current challenges and future prospects of globalisation. In: Jones
AM, ed. Elgar companion to health economics, 2nd ed. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2011:164–175.
12. Smith RD et al. Global public goods for health: a health economic and public health perspective.
Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2003.
13. Bloom D, Canning D. The health and wealth of nations. Science, 2000, 287(5456): 1207–1209.
14. Pritchett L, Summers LH. Wealthier is healthier. Journal of Human Resources, 1996, XXXI:841–868.
6
Policy coherence in trade and health
Chapter 2
address. Policy coherence would mean ensuring that all policies contribute to the expansion of freedoms
that people enjoy.
What distinguishes a human development approach from a human rights approach to policy coherence?
One of the key differences is the focus on accountability that is embedded in a human rights approach.
To have a particular right is to have a claim on other people or institutions that they should help or
collaborate in ensuring access to some freedom. This insistence on a claim on others takes us beyond the
idea of human development. In the human development perspective, social progress of the valued kind is
taken to be a very good thing . . . but the normative connection between laudable goals and reasons for
action does not yield specific duties on the part of other individuals, collectivities or social institutions to
bring about human development . . . (6).
As this accountability for achieving social progress usually lies with the nation state, the human rights
approach is especially relevant for policy-makers grappling with policy coherence. Indeed, most national
governments have formal commitments and existing obligations to the right to health, either through the
inclusion of the right to health in national constitutions or by having ratified international human rights
treaties such as the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights. With the appointment
by the United Nations Commission on Human Rights of a Special Rapporteur on the right of everyone to the
enjoyment of the highest attainable standard of physical and mental health (resolution 2002/31),2 there has
been growing interest in the policy implications of the right to health. A number of documents analysing
how to approach trade policy with a view to achieving the right to health have been prepared by the
Special Rapporteur (7).
A paper by Hunt and MacNaughton proposed guidelines on how to carry out health impact assessments
of public policies, including trade policies, from a human rights perspective (8). The following excerpts
highlight the basic principles that should guide a right to health approach in assessing the coherence of
trade policy with the overarching goal of achieving human rights.
1. Explicit human rights framework. A rights-based approach to impact assessment must be explicitly
based on a human rights normative framework. The right-to-health approach developed here is based on
ICESCR [International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights] Article 12 and the Committee’s
General Comment 14 defining the normative content of Article 12 [Committee on Economic, Social and
Cultural Rights]. In selecting the appropriate human rights normative framework, States should look to the
specific human rights treaties that they have ratified as well as international consensus documents pertaining
to the particular subject of the policy.
2. Progressive realization. A rights-based approach also demands that the State take deliberate steps
to progressively realize the right to health as expeditiously and effectively as possible. Impact assessment
provides States with the methodology to do so. Integrated into policy-making processes, rights-based
impact assessment aids the State in selecting, from among policy alternatives, those policies that will most
expeditiously and effectively realize the right to health. Rights-based impact assessment will also ensure that
the State is aware when a proposal is likely to impede the right to health, and thus, can take measures to
mitigate or compensate for such impacts, avoiding any measures that might be considered retrogressive or
otherwise in violation of legal obligations.
3. Equality and non-discrimination. Rights-based impact assessment means that the principles of equality
and non-discrimination must be considered at all stages and in all aspects of the impact assessment. For
example, the principle of non-discrimination requires States to consider the likely impacts of proposals on
different groups to ensure that a policy does not adversely affect a protected group. To do such analysis
will require disaggregated information on potential impacts. Furthermore, people must be able to hold the
2
The first Special Rapporteur was Paul Hunt (New Zealand), 2002–2008, succeeded by Anand Gover (India) in August 2008.
8
Policy coherence in trade and health
State accountable for any illegal discrimination in the assessment process. The principle of equality requires
States to consider alternatives that could be more effective in promoting equality, including devoting more
resources to areas with the greatest potential to benefit poor people. It also means that all people must be
encouraged to participate in the impact assessment.
5. Information. Rights-based impact assessment also requires the State to provide information on the
proposed policy and on the process of such assessment for all stakeholders. All parties potentially affected
by the policy must be fully informed in order to meaningfully participate in the impact assessment and to
effectively hold the State accountable. The right to information also means that States must respect the
freedom of everyone to seek and receive information, to freely discuss the proposal and to propose options
for avoiding or minimizing adverse impacts on rights and alternatives that could enhance rights.
6. Accountability. A rights-based approach also demands accountability. Thus, States must ensure that
stakeholders are advised of the rights and obligations relevant to a rights-based impact assessment process
and of mechanisms of accountability that are available to them. These mechanisms must be accessible,
transparent and effective. People must be able to hold duty-bearers accountable for the process of the impact
assessment should it fail to respect their human rights.
7. Interdependence of rights. A rights-based approach also recognizes the interdependence of rights – the
fact that the enjoyment of some rights is dependent on or contributes to the enjoyment of others. It also
recognizes that impact assessments aimed at progressively realizing the right to health and thereby reducing
poverty (and vice versa) must reflect the interdependence of all human rights; economic, social, cultural,
political and civil. As poverty is defined in terms of all these rights, a rights-based approach must encompass
them all.
Social scientists have found this theoretical approach very useful in explaining the formulation of trade
policy (11), and have recently expanded this approach to explain other aspects of economic foreign policy,
such as policies regarding international finance and exchange rates, along with foreign investments. In
the case of trade policy as it relates to health, the theory would predict that the policy preferences of small
groups of actors that stand to reap large benefits would prevail. If these actors are large pharmaceutical
companies or large (semi) governmental agencies involved in health insurance or investment in health
facilities, their stakes in standards of protection for intellectual property or decisions about liberalization in
health services or insurance are high and the number of actors relatively small; hence, the strong incentives
for these actors to be politically active making it relatively easy for them to associate into a single, effective
organization. In comparison, groups of unified patients or consumers tend to be less organized and
consequently have less influence.
Given these dynamics, achieving policy coherence is therefore not simply a question of adopting the
procedural measures suggested in the recommendations below. The focus here is on some steps that
policy-makers in national governments can take to facilitate the adoption of trade policies that contribute
to, rather than hinder the achievements of national health objectives.
10
Policy coherence in trade and health
Comments from Anabel Gonzalez, former trade negotiator for Costa Rica
To promote policy coherence is not to promote inaction, either on the health front or in the trade
arena, or to engage in fruitless confrontations, but rather to promote greater understanding of
the linkages between trade and health, leading to greater interaction between policy-makers and
practitioners in these two areas. This must be done at both the technical level and the political level.
Increased coherence requires building the knowledge base on trade and health linkages, particularly
among trade and health practitioners and, in a broader sense, among the general public. From the
perspective of a trade negotiator, this information is vital in order to participate in trade negotiations.
The information, of course, must be based on sound analysis and research. Regional and international
bodies have a role in generating and disseminating such knowledge, though differences between
countries or groups of countries should also be taken into consideration. Mechanisms for addressing
specific questions or concerns in a timely fashion are part of an appropriate response.
It must remembered that a lot of the existing information appears to be geared towards the challenges
and risks implied whilst little seems to be dedicated, so far, to the opportunities and benefits that
arise from the interaction between trade and health. This dimension should also be more thoroughly
explored and recognized so that countries may incorporate relevant elements in their national
strategies, for instance in terms of investment attraction, promotion of competitiveness and tourism
development. Developing countries in particular should aim less at presenting defensive positions in
trade negotiations and more at using those negotiations as opportunities for advancing their offensive
interests, including in the trade and health areas.
Although strengthening the technical basis for discussion and decision-making, through information,
dialogue, capacity building and monitoring, will significantly improve policy coherence, ultimately decisions
on trade and health policies are of a political nature (12). This is particularly the case when there are
conflicting views as regards priorities and objectives.
11
Policy coherence in trade and health
Comments from Nik Noraihan Thani, Deputy Undersecretary, MOH, Malaysia (13)
For an effective and coherent trade and health policy, it is imperative that health and trade officials,
nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) and the private sector come together and use various
opportunities to build a collaborative relationship. Toward this end, the Malaysian Ministry of Health
conducts annual dialogues between relevant stakeholders. Members of the annual dialogue involve
three major groups: NGOs, professional bodies and industrial groups, covering a total of about 90
organizations.
Another important factor is leadership and capacity building. A committed group of key officials and
leaders knowledgeable about the issues and willing to share information on future policy decisions is
the most important element to achieve better trade and health policy coherence. Trade and health
concerns may at times be in conflict, so a strong and committed leadership should be able to address
such concerns in a constructive way and view them as opportunities for finding common ground.
The Ministry of Health is a relatively new player in the area of trade and health but recognizes the
opportunities that lie ahead, and seeks to address the concerns that arise. Toward this end, the Ministry
of Health has established a Steering Committee on Trade and Health chaired by the Secretary-General
of Health. Several subcommittees, known as expert groups, have been formed to address specific
concerns about trade in health, such as on pharmaceuticals, food safety, health care services, medical
devices and tobacco control. These expert groups bring together academic experts, civil society and
ministry representatives to discuss key health and trade issues, and will advise the Steering Committee
accordingly. The Ministry of Health also established a contact or focal point for trade officials to make it
easier for them to seek the views of the Ministry of Health.
In contrast, Latin American countries such as Argentina, the Dominican Republic, Guatemala and
Mexico provide examples of situations in which ministries of health have had little involvement in trade
negotiations or the implementation of trade agreements. Given this lack of involvement, national legislation
implementing the TRIPS Agreement in Latin America has not taken full advantage of the flexibilities
embedded in the Agreement to ensure accessibility to pharmaceutical drugs. The lack of leadership by the
health authorities may have resulted from their limited knowledge of trade rules on access to medicines,
and their relatively low level of influence outside their specific field of competence. Historically, ministries of
health have been marginalized in two ways: first, they have been excluded from foreign policy; and second,
they have been disconnected from other policy areas within domestic policy-making. Consequently,
health ministry officials have often been in more frequent contact with their counterparts abroad than
with officials in the ministries of trade or foreign affairs at home. Ensuring that ministries of health take a
proactive role in trade and health policy-making therefore requires a reversal of long-held practices.
The case of Thailand is another example of how the leadership of the health ministry, working together with
trade officials, can be a key determinant of policy coherence. Trade officials in Thailand have recognized
the role that the Ministry of Health has been playing over recent years, in terms of building a better
understanding of, and accumulating evidence with respect to, the implications of trade agreements on
the national health systems. As a result, trade officials naturally turned to the Ministry of Health when
they needed evidence on the costs of increasing intellectual property protection, in the context of trade
negotiations with the United States.
12
Policy coherence in trade and health
Box 2.3 Evidence to inform negotiation: the case of intellectual property protection in
Thailand
14
Policy coherence in trade and health
The ability to monitor the impact of trade policies following their adoption is also crucial to being able to
prepare an appropriate response. For example, Thailand has seen a large increase in the number of foreign
patients coming to receive medical care. The Ministry of Health monitored the impact of medical travel and
found that the increased demand for doctors and nurses to care for foreign patients has led to an internal
brain drain from the rural public sector to the urban private sector. Thanks to this monitoring capacity, the
Ministry could adopt a policy for scaling up the training of doctors and nurses under a special curriculum
to facilitate rural distribution (18). In some cases, in order to pool limited resources, a regional rather than a
national approach to collecting the information can be used. For example, the secretariat of the Common
Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), in partnership with officials in each member country,
coordinated comprehensive assessments of the state of trade in services (including health services) in
this region, in preparation for economic partnership agreements with the European Union and GATS
negotiations (Box 2.4). This regional approach is also relevant for other elements of the policy process
discussed here, such as the need to create institutional mechanisms for collaboration. Many low-income
countries may not have the resources to create a distinct unit or committee to deal with trade and health,
and regional collaboration may be the best way to ensure internal coherence.
International organizations such as the World Health Organization and the World Trade Organization
also have an important role to play in developing the evidence relevant to trade and health policy and
making it accessible to policy-makers. Their technical assistance and capacity-building activities need to be
coordinated and strengthened to ensure that trade and health officials receive appropriate information so
they can engage in national policy discussions.
The need for evidence-based policy-making goes beyond the direct impact of trade reforms on health. For
example, insecticides to fight malaria, such as dichlorodiphenyltrichloroethane (DDT), may, if they are used
as pesticides in agricultural production and thus enter the food chain, cause environmental and health
problems that could jeopardize export opportunities. This is an example of a situation where trade and
health policy-makers need to work together in order to ensure beneficial outcomes.
Given the strong link between poverty and poor health, officials also need better information on the impact
of trade reforms on poverty and inequity. Overall, trade openness tends to be associated with poverty
reduction (19). However, the relationship between trade and poverty varies from one country to another,
depending on such factors as the nature of the reforms at stake and initial conditions. Moreover, the impact
on poor people will also vary according to several factors, including their skill level, gender and geographic
location (for example urban or rural). Therefore, aggregate information may not reveal enough to be useful
for policy-makers. Detailed information about the poverty impact of planned or ongoing reforms is usually
not available, despite it being crucial to ensuring coherence.
15
Policy coherence in trade and health
Box 2.4 Trade in health services in COMESA: looking beyond the movement of health
personnel
16
Policy coherence in trade and health
References
1. Blouin C, Heymann J, Drager N, eds. Trade and health: seeking common ground. Montreal, McGill-
Queen’s University Press, 2008.
2. Blouin C. Trade policy and health: toward policy coherence. Bulletin of the World Health Organization,
2007, 85:3.
3. Policy coherence: vital for global development. Policy Brief. Paris, Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development, 2003.
4. Policy coherence for development: promoting institutional good practice. Paris, Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development, 2003.
6. United Nations Development Programme. Human development report: human rights and human
development. New York, Oxford University Press, 2000.
7. Hunt P. The right of everyone to the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard of physical and
mental health. Mission to the World Trade Organization, Commission on Human Rights, Geneva
2004.
8. Hunt P, MacNaughton G. Impact assessments, poverty and human rights: a case study using the
right to the highest attainable standard of health. Colchester, England, Human Rights Centre,
University of Essex, 2006.
9. Reich MR. The politics of health sector reform in developing countries: three cases of pharmaceutical
policy. Health Policy, 1995, 32:47–77.
10. Olson M. The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge,
Massachusetts, Harvard University Press, 1971.
11. Frieden J, Lake D. International relations as a social science: rigor and relevance. Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science, 2005, 600:136–156.
12. Blouin C. The role of civil society in achieving policy coherence. Presentation delivered at the
Conference on Trade and Health: Policy Coherence for Human Development, 7 October 2005.
Montreal, McGill University, Institute for Health and Social Policy.
13. Thani NN. Trade and health policy coherences at the national level: the experience from Malaysia. Paper
presented at the Conference on Trade and Health: Policy Coherence for Human Development, 7
October 2005. Montreal, McGill University, Institute for Health and Social Policy.
14. Latif AA. Developing country coordination in intellectual property standard-setting. South Centre
TRADE Working Paper No. 24. Geneva, South Centre, 2005.
15. Keayla BK, ed. Review of patent legislation of India, Indonesia, Sri Lanka and Thailand: measures to
safeguard public health. New Delhi, WHO Regional Office for South-East Asia, 2004.
17
Policy coherence in trade and health
16. Balasubramaniam K. Special determination of the Supreme Court (No. 14/2003, 15/2003, 16/2003),
the TRIPS Agreement, the Doha Declaration and the Intellectual Property Bill 2003. Law and Society
Trust Review, 2003, 13:189.
17. Third World Network. Developing countries warned against WTO-plus issues and rules in FTAs. South
North Development Monitor, 31 August 2005.
18. Pachanee CA, Wibulpolprasert S. Incoherent policies on universal coverage of health insurance and
promotion of international trade in health services in Thailand. Health Policy and Planning, 2006,
21:310–318.
19. Blouin, C, Chopra M, Van Der Hoeven R. Trade and social determinants of health. The Lancet, 2009,
373(9662):502–507.
20. Mpande-Chuulu C. COMESA. Presentation delivered at the Conference onTrade and Health: Policy
Coherence for Human Development, 7 October 2005. Montreal, McGill University, Institute for
Health and Social Policy.
18
Capacity building in trade and health
Chapter 3
3.1 Introduction
Globalization has led to greater interdependence, across countries and within countries, resulting in
an increased emphasis on strengthening multilateral cooperation for sustainable development. This is
underscored further in the global Post 2015 Sustainable Development Goals agenda, which will be the
guiding framework over the next fifteen years. To achieve meaningful results, however, this cooperation
needs to be replicated within each country when framing policies on economic and social development
are being drafted. One obvious area of such collaboration is between the trade and health sector. This
area of collaboration has been recognized in the World Health Assembly resolution on trade and health
(WHA59.26), which, among other things, calls for developing capacity at the national level to analyse
potential opportunities and challenges related to trade in the health sector. Given the growing relevance
of health issues in international trade, it is important that health officials are sensitized to the implications
that trade may have for health. Creating this sensitivity requires greater awareness regarding the interface
between trade and health, and greater policy coordination and coherence amongst trade and health
officials. There is a need to build capacity1 in developing and least developed countries to identify relevant
issues and draw up cogent action plans that leverage opportunities in this area (1).
In doing so, the capacity building initiatives being carried out by the World Trade Organization (WTO) and
other organizations must be considered.
This chapter provides an overview of such multilateral initiatives, including Aid for Trade and the Enhanced
Integrated Framework for Trade-Related Technical Assistance to Least Developed Countries. The intention is
to provide an accessible overview for use by policy-makers and other stakeholders working in the trade and
health sectors when drafting funding requests for capacity building.
1
Capacity building denotes the assistance rendered to entities, in the present context to developing countries, to upgrade performance. UNDP has defined
capacity building as the creation of an enabling environment with appropriate policy and legal frameworks, including institutional development and hu-
man resources development, recognizing that it is a long-term, continuing process requiring maximum participation by all stakeholders (1)
2
WT/MIN(11)/W/2 (1 Dec. 2011).
19
Capacity building in trade and health
The importance of technical assistance and capacity-building initiatives was underscored in the Doha
Ministerial Declaration (3), by which ministers confirmed that “technical cooperation and capacity building
are core elements of the development dimension of the multilateral trading system”. Ministers also endorsed
the New Strategy for WTO Technical Cooperation for Capacity Building, Growth and Integration and
instructed the WTO secretariat, in coordination with other relevant agencies, to support domestic efforts
for the incorporation of trade into national plans for economic development and strategies for poverty
reduction. At the sixth WTO Ministerial Conference (Hong Kong, 2005) ministers reiterated the significance
of technical assistance and capacity building by outlining concrete measures to enhance them through a
revamping of the existing Integrated Framework for Trade-Related Technical Assistance to Least Developed
Countries and a new initiative on Aid for Trade (4). At the eighth WTO Ministerial Conference (Geneva, 2011)
ministers noted the progress achieved on Aid for Trade and reiterated their commitment to provide funds so
as to enable the secretariat to continue to provide required technical assistance and capacity building.2 The
ninth WTO Ministerial Conference (Bali, 2013) noted the outcomes of the 4th Global Aid for Trade Review
(Geneva, July 2013) and reiterated the continuing need for aid for trade support to developing countries,
especially Least Developed Countries (LDCs). Ministers have directed that a new work programme on aid for
trade should be shaped by the post 2015-global development agenda.
In addition to its Annual Technical Assistance Plan, WTO also carries out trade capacity building in
collaboration with other international organizations under the aegis of established programmes such as
the Enhanced Integrated Framework, the Joint Integrated Technical Assistance Programme, the Standards
and Trade Development Facility and the Aid for Trade initiative. The focus of the present chapter, however,
is on the Enhanced Integrated Framework and Aid for Trade, as these are an on-going initiative focusing on
a broader view of development, which is relevant for trade and health policy-makers. Box 3.1 gives a brief
description of other joint initiatives of relevance to capacity building in trade and health.
The rationale for the Aid for Trade initiative and the Integrated Framework process stems from the desire
to strengthen the capacities of developing and least developed countries to take advantage of more
open markets and to harness the multilateral trading system in support of their economic growth and
development. Given the emphasis that is presently placed on harmonization of technical assistance and a
holistic view of development, these initiatives provide an opportunity for health officials to articulate their
needs in respect of the trade and health sectors and to access financial assistance under relevant projects.
20
Capacity building in trade and health
21
Capacity building in trade and health
• a global review of Aid for Trade flows using the OECD Development Assistance Committee da-
tabase to assess whether additional resources are being delivered, to identify where gaps lie,
to highlight where improvements should be made and to increase transparency on pledges
and disbursements;
• evaluations of the Aid for Trade activities of national, regional and multilateral donors, based
on donor self-assessments;
3
As outlined in the recommendations of the task force on Aid for Trade set up by the Director-General of WTO (WT/AFT/1, dated 27 July 2006) (9).
22
Capacity building in trade and health
• country and region-based monitoring and evaluation to provide a more focused country-spe-
cific perspective on whether trade needs are being met, financial resources are being provided
and Aid for Trade is being effective on the ground.
It is critical to Aid for Trade that there be coherence between the various capacity-building initiatives being
undertaken by multilateral institutions, bilateral donors and nongovernmental organizations. Aid for Trade
requires WTO to collaborate with a range of national, regional and international actors, including those in
the private sector, to increase flows of technical and financial assistance through existing channels and to
work with developing and least developed countries to assist them in identifying their trade-related needs
that could be met by additional Aid for Trade.
In 2012, the WTO Committee on Trade and Development held a workshop on Aid for Trade and Services,
noting that trade in services has been relatively neglected in the literature despite its substantial
contribution to global trade. The secretariat’s Background Note to the workshop suggested that Aid for
Trade could help to address a number of supply-side and trade-related infrastructure constraints that
may adversely affect services sectors in certain developing countries, including (a) lack of access to export
financing, (b) poor telecommunications infrastructure, (c) weak domestic legal environment for business,
and (d) limited educational infrastructure and consequent scarcity of trained staff (10).
3.3.4 Aid for Trade flows
One of the important aspects of the monitoring and evaluating function is to assess changes in the level of
resources being made available and to identify the areas where gaps exist and improvements are required.
Accordingly, WTO, in partnership with OECD, established a joint monitoring system based on data on
global flows of development aid and on feedback from donor and partner countries. Aid for Trade flows are
profiled using the OECD Creditor Reporting System, which is the closest approximation to the categories
identified under Aid for Trade.4 Some donors have developed their own methodologies for identifying Aid
for Trade expenditures.
Between 2002 and 2005, donors committed on average US$ 21 billion per year to the aid categories most
closely associated with Aid for Trade. This figure comprises US$ 11.2 billion to build economic infrastructure;
US$ 8.9 billion to promote productive capacities (including US$ 2 billion for trade development); and
US$ 0.6 billion for increasing the understanding and implementation of trade policy and regulations (11).
The largest aid providers by volume are Japan and the United States. Other important bilateral donors are
France, Germany, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. Large multilateral and regional institutions,
for example the World Bank and the regional development banks, provide around 50% of their sector
programmes via Aid for Trade.
In the same period (2002–2005), the largest allocation of Aid for Trade was received by Asia (51%, mainly
for economic infrastructure) while Africa received 30%, Latin America and the Caribbean 7%, Europe 5%
and Oceania 1%. Most Aid for Trade went to lower middle-income countries (36%), followed by the least
developed countries (25%).
The level of aid commitments rose significantly by 2009, increasing by 60% over the baseline years of
2002–2005, according to a joint WTO/OECD publication (12). Aid to sub-Saharan Africa and the Americas
increased by 40% and almost 60%, respectively, while aid to other areas decreased: Europe by 34%, Asia
by 18%, and Oceania by 28%. These regional trends reflect increasing donations to low income countries
and simultaneous decreases in aid to middle income countries. In 2010, Aid for Trade commitments were
exceptionally high at $48 billion. However there was a shift in aid for trade flows in 2011 and 2012, as it
declined with decreasing support for infrastructure, particularly in Africa. While funding for least developed
countries (LDCs) decreased, they did not bear the brunt of the decline. The flows indicate a shift in funding
towards private sector development and value chain promotion. Aid dedicated to building productive
capacity with a trade development objective almost doubled from 2007 ($2.6 bn) to 2011 ($5.4bn).
4
Categories include: trade policy and regulations; trade development; trade-related infrastructure; building productive capacity; trade-related adjustment;
and other trade-related needs.
23
Capacity building in trade and health
In 2011, aid-for-trade commitments were made to 146 countries, with Africa registering a drop of 29
percent, while Asia received 5 percent less compared to 2010. For Latin America and the Caribbean, flows
remained at 2010 levels. Within this region however Central America and the Caribbean were the major
beneficiaries as flows almost doubled (a 93 percent increase) compared to the 2002–2005 baseline (13).
Donors and beneficiaries are increasingly prioritizing Aid for Trade in their programmes. Indeed, a spectrum
of organizations, including intergovernmental and private sector organizations, are developing Aid for Trade
strategies to enable them to better participate in the initiative. The overall trend seems to be one of positive
growth in Aid for Trade.
3.3.5 Demand-driven process
To sustain and enhance the rising trend in Aid for Trade, it is essential that it be demand-driven. Beneficiary
countries need to centralize trade development as a key element in their economic development strategies.
Donor support is more assured when political commitment is demonstrated through prioritization of
trade in national development plans, including: poverty reduction strategy papers; appropriate political
backing to carry through action plans; and preparedness to actively partner in the conception, design and
implementation of prioritized projects.
One of the foremost issues identified in various diagnostic studies is the lack of adequate capacity in
terms of skilled human resources. Moreover, many developing countries currently lack appropriate and
sufficient tools to effectively manage their own capacity development processes. Also apparent is a lack
of awareness of the far-reaching impacts that trade rules and negotiations may have on the health sector.
This could be one immediate area where assistance is required in training and awareness raising among
health professionals, specifically with respect to trade rules in the area of sanitary and phytosanitary
measures, technical barriers to trade, trade related intellectual property rights and the regulation of health
services. Through Aid for Trade the trade and health assessment tool could assist countries in assessing
their needs and capacities as a basis for drawing up concrete action plans and projects that could attract
funding and technical assistance. The new holistic approach related to access to health services and health
outcomes evidenced in the new sustainable development agenda provides further impetus for enhancing
the capacities and undertaking a needs analysis of the trade and health sector. The ultimate objective is
to capacitate developing countries to contribute to an open global trading system in which their national
development flourishes and the multilateral trading system is leveraged to increase economic efficiency
and promote good governance.
The Aid for Trade initiative supports countries in carrying out needs assessments, identifying their
priorities (for example in the trade and health sector), discovering policy gaps and considering solutions
to bridge those gaps. Solutions may take the form of technical assistance and hands-on training regarding
the implications of trade-related provisions for the health sector. Countries may require investment
in infrastructure for establishing testing laboratories, training personnel in reforming the regulatory
environment, and facilitating greater policy coherence on issues pertaining to trade in health services (14).
Improved knowledge of the challenges and opportunities that trade agreements can bring to the health
sector may enable policy-makers to better frame appropriate policy responses, including negotiating
strategies in international trade negotiations.
In keeping with the rationale of the Aid for Trade initiative, any projects that are conceived need to
demonstrate that they address national priorities. Projects envisaged in the trade and health sectors would
therefore typically involve collaboration between the ministries of trade, health, development planning, and
finance, as appropriate. For accessing any funds under Aid for Trade, the ministry of trade would normally be
the nodal agency, though this may vary from country to country. While the nodal ministry is responsible for
drawing up a comprehensive strategy on trade and development, the input outlining the priorities of other
ministries, including health, should inform this strategy.
24
Capacity building in trade and health
3.3.6 Summing up
The Aid for Trade initiative has established a framework for bringing together all stakeholders, including
beneficiary countries, donors, the private sector, regional development banks and multilateral institutions,
to work towards a common goal. It is essentially a demand-driven process, with the onus on the beneficiary
country to demonstrate a need, establish priorities and submit bankable projects to achieve the desired
outcomes. The underlying theme of coherence underlines the importance of exploring synergies between
aid programmes in health and trade. The upcoming global Post 2015 Sustainable Development Goals
Agenda also recognizes the value of development aid as well as aid for trade to address outstanding issues
and tackling new frontiers in the area of communicable and non-communicable diseases. Stemming from
the experience of implementing the MDGs, there is now more than ever a realization of the need for an
appropriate financing mechanism for achieving sustainable development, which may call for building
innovative mechanisms within the Aid for Trade agenda by leveraging not only public resources but also
private sources of finance and effective domestic resource mobilization.
In this context, both trade and health policy-makers need to focus on the need for a mutually supportive
relationship in the trade and health sectors. Such a focus would support their ability to overcome the
difficulties they face in adapting the new aid architecture to trade and health. From analysing priorities to
implementation, all development partners need to collaborate in order to make best use of the additional
funding available for better trade and health outcomes. The assessment tool being developed for health
policy officials would be of great assistance in setting the priorities in the trade and health sector and
identifying the capacity and infrastructure gaps where additional financial resources are required. Access to
these resources would be facilitated through the Aid for Trade initiative.
25
Capacity building in trade and health
At the sixth WTO Ministerial Conference in Hong Kong (2005), trade ministers endorsed the establishment of
a task force to make recommendations on institutional issues, including staffing of the Executive Secretariat,
defining the in-country approach and programming issues, and launching the replenishment process (4).
The task force acknowledged the importance of trade liberalization for improving economic conditions in
the least developed countries and achieving the Millennium Development Goal of halving poverty by 2015
(18). The task force also made recommendations focused on four broad areas:
• the need for stronger ownership of the Integrated Framework by the least developed coun-
tries and the donors, which could only be achieved by building and strengthening capacity in
the least developed countries;
• the need to fill the gap between the diagnostic trade integration study and the submission
of bankable projects, and the need to convert action matrices related to the study into living
documents that could be updated regularly to reflect changing needs;
• the necessity of a responsive management and implementation structure in order to assure
the successful functioning of the Integrated Framework; and
• most importantly, the need for adequate and predictable funding in order to meet the objec-
tives of the Integrated Framework.
There was also broad consensus during the task force deliberations that the private sector should be
included at all stages in the work of the Integrated Framework at the country level, including the diagnosis
stage.
The EIF presently supports 47 LDCs and two recently graduated countries through a multi-donor trust fund,
the EIF Trust Fund, with contributions from 23 donors. A high-level pledging event in 2007 set a funding
target of US$ 250 million over five years.5
5
https://www.enhancedif.org/en/about (Last accessed on 27 January 2014).
26
Capacity building in trade and health
The mid- term evaluation of the programme in 2012 has concluded that the EIF is extremely relevant to
the trade and economic priorities of LDCs as it supports trade mainstreaming into national development
strategies, contributes to strengthening capacities for trade-related strategies and plans and ensures
a coordinated delivery of prioritized trade-related assistance. Additional areas identified include
strengthening linkages to related donor programming and enhancing customisation of projects at country
level for greater impact. Consequently the EIF Steering Committee extended the programme mandate up to
31 December 2015, with an additional operational period for project implementation running through to 31
December 2017.6
3.4.3 Integrated Framework governance structure
The Integrated Framework governance structure is established at two levels: international and national.
Tables 3.1 and 3.2 show the principal components or bodies of the governance structure, along with their
composition and functions, at the international and national levels respectively.
6
Ibid.
27
Capacity building in trade and health
29
Capacity building in trade and health
The tier 2 financing arrangement funds the priority activities identified in each country’s diagnostic trade
integration study and its action matrix. The spending from tier 2 is related to such activities as actual
project implementation and feasibility studies; larger infrastructure projects require funding from other
mechanisms. Some examples of tier 2 funding include:
Following the recommendations of the task force for enhancement of the Integrated Framework, it was
agreed that an amount of US$ 400 million over five years would be sufficient to meet the costs associated
with domestic capacity building (tier 1). This included some activities identified in the action matrices (tier
2), and the costs of the Executive Secretariat. The size of the enhanced Integrated Framework Trust Fund
was envisioned to be about US$ 240 million, with the remaining US$ 160 million to be met through funding
from in-country donors. The amount of funding currently available totals US$ 100 million, and pledges of
US$ 182 million are to be disbursed over a five year period.
Given the well-defined governance and funding structure under the Integrated Framework, it is clear
that health officials need to be associated with the national steering committee and the national
implementation unit. An assessment tool could assist the task of mapping out priorities in the trade and
health sector and identifying the capacity gaps that need to be filled. Concrete projects for domestic
capacity building in the area of trade and health could be financed under tier 1 of the Integrated Framework
Trust Fund. Twinning with related donor programmes in health as well as customisation as per country
needs is also possible under the programme. To obtain the requisite funding, it is necessary to demonstrate,
through domestic and inter-ministerial coordination, a real need and a project with tangible benefits.
3.4.6 Diagnostic trade integration study
Perhaps the most significant part of the Integrated Framework process is the preparation of the diagnostic
trade integration study, as it generally embodies the following:
1 a comprehensive assessment of the country’s macroeconomic environment;
2. structure and pattern of trade and investment;
3. institutional and regulatory framework;
4. trade and poverty linkages;
5. business environment, standards, trade facilitation, export competitiveness; and
6. infrastructure constraints.
Based on this assessment, which has normally been led either by the World Bank or UNDP along with
the beneficiary country, an action plan (or matrix) is drawn up reflecting the priorities identified in the
diagnostic study. Care should be taken to align the action plan with the country’s national development
plan and poverty reduction strategy paper. The action plan is then executed by the beneficiary country with
technical assistance from the international development community.
30
Trade and health – the linkages
A total of 58 projects and 37 Diagnostic Trade Integration Studies (DTIS) and DTIS updates were ongoing in
43 countries in 2012–2013.7 Some of the completed studies were reviewed to assess the number of cases
where trade and health issues had been prioritized. It was discovered that, even though health issues are
an important component of what is conceived as development, they are often not specified directly in
the diagnostic trade integration study as a key priority. Thus, efforts should be made to develop a broad
strategy for enhancing competitiveness and protecting human, plant and animal health as well as “attaining
health for all at all ages”.
For instance, a number of diagnostic trade integration studies, as in the case of Uganda and Zambia, identify
the need for better coordination between the trade ministry and other ministries, including the ministry
of health, along with improved standard-setting procedures and the initiation of legal and regulatory
reform (20, 21). In other cases, as in Vanuatu, which has a high literacy rate and some positive health
indicators, emphasis is placed on improving access to health services and education (22). The diagnostic
trade integration study of the United Republic of Tanzania notes that the country is likely to continue to be
highly aid dependent, and addressing its macroeconomic issues would require balancing aid and public
expenditure between the social, infrastructure and productive sectors (23). It is nonetheless acknowledged
that higher spending on social sectors would help meet some of the Millennium Development Goals
(health, education and access to water). Senegal also attaches considerable importance to improving social
and human capital indicators, both for promoting export growth and for its long-term development (24).
From the foregoing, it is clear that linkages between trade and health are often neglected at the national
level, and diagnostic trade integration studies are thus an important aspect of the national development
strategies of least developed countries. To assist in making this linkage, coordination between trade, health
and development officials at the country level is imperative, as the issues identified should not only be a
part of the national development plans or poverty reduction strategy papers, but should also draw the
attention of donors and international organizations to supportive action they might take in that area.
Under the Integrated Framework, the diagnostic trade integration study offers a valuable opportunity for
health officials to influence the process and prioritize trade and health issues, and to seek assistance for
capacity building. Health officials can use the aforementioned trade and health assessment tool to help
them in this endeavour by identifying their current capacity and gaps in that capacity. For example, a least
developed country may identify that cross-border delivery of health services through use of information
and communication technologies, such as telemedicine, could alleviate its human resource constraints and
help increase efficiency in the health care sector. Resources for this initiative could be accessed under the
Integrated Framework after a concrete plan to achieve the objective is ratified by the Integrated Framework
national steering committee.
The trade and health assessment tool and the diagnostic trade integration study can thus play
complementary roles. The assessment tool can identify gaps in national capacity as they pertain to trade in
health products and services whilst the diagnostic trade integration study can build on this information to
guide policy-makers in the development of a national strategy on trade and health.
This self-assessment is the first step towards mobilizing resources following the development of a concrete
action plan to address these needs. Donors need to be presented with evidence of tangible plans, country
ownership and commitment. Moreover, a rational and consistent national development strategy, which
prioritizes trade and health issues and which also figures in the country’s poverty reduction strategy paper,
is the appropriate way forward to ensure capacity building in the area of trade and health.
3.4.7 Mainstreaming trade and health issues in national development plans: the way forward
An integrated policy oversight body would facilitate an efficient use of the various assistance mechanisms
that are now available to developing and least developed countries. Pursuant to the principles expressed in
the Paris Declaration, the increasing emphasis on ownership, harmonization and alignment of aid initiatives
should be adopted at both the country and regional levels. The needs assessment on trade and health
7
www.enhancedif.org/en/publication/2013-12/ (Last accessed on 27 July 2015)
31
Capacity building in trade and health
issues may be conducted by countries, bearing in mind the fact that assistance under the Aid for Trade
and the Integrated Framework initiatives is predicated on a demand-driven process, founded on political
commitment and full ownership by the beneficiary country. The needs assessments should result from a
prioritization process developed through stakeholder consultation and should have the endorsement of
donors as well as development partners. Concrete projects for capacity building in trade and health issues,
as reflected in national priorities, merit full consideration under trade capacity-building initiatives.
Thus, systematic information sharing between health and trade ministries and cooperative efforts while
employing the diagnostic tools are essential. This is an opportune moment for strengthening partnership
between WHO and WTO in capacity-building initiatives that would advance trade and health.
3.5 Conclusion
The trade and health sectors, both at the country and global levels, seek to alleviate poverty, increase
economic growth, enhance health for all and thereby promote sustainable human development (25). This
common objective calls for consistent policy approaches that are mutually supportive. Trade rules touch
upon virtually all aspects of public policy, which makes it incumbent upon policy-makers to minimize
conflicts between different sectors and explore synergies to enhance development and growth. Areas of
immediate concern to policy-makers in developing and least developed countries include the alarming
incidence of epidemics such as HIV/AIDS H1N1 (influenza), Ebola virus, the difficulty in containing food-
borne diseases which are transmitted across national borders through freer trade, and the possible opening
up of trade in health services. This calls for greater coordination of policies, and also may entail structural
adjustments.
Underpinning all of this, however, is the great need for capacity to undertake an analysis and assessment
of a country’s own requirements, priorities and the gaps that may exist in giving adequate attention to
health policy issues in trade rules. The technical assistance and capacity-building initiatives in the area
of trade are premised on a more holistic conception of development and thus afford an opportunity to
health policy officials and stakeholders to access these initiatives to address the gaps in the trade and
health sector. The two main initiatives that respond to capacity-building needs are Aid for Trade, which is
available to all developing and least developed countries; and the Integrated Framework, which is limited
to least developed countries. The trade and health assessment tool developed by WHO would be a valuable
complement to the diagnostic trade integration study and the action matrices in the Integrated Framework,
and the needs assessment and gap identification process required to be conducted under Aid for Trade.
Employed together, these instruments can prove useful in charting the needs for capacity building and
national and regional priorities for a cogent trade and health strategy.
To access resources under the Integrated Framework, health officials in least developed countries could
use the instruments mentioned above in order to: (1) take stock of the prevailing domestic regulatory
environment as it affects trade in health products, including pharmaceuticals and services; (2) provide
guidance in plotting capacity gaps and needs; and (3) assist understanding of the offensive and defensive
interests in the trade and health sector. In addition, the information generated can help policy-makers
formulate concrete action plans, such as educating health officials on the interface between the trade
and health sectors; assess the need for setting up necessary infrastructure, such as testing laboratories;
develop the regulatory framework to safeguard public health from trade in harmful products; and enhance
capacities to participate in health services negotiations. Equipped with this knowledge, health officials and
their counterparts in trade ministries are better positioned to provide evidence of a demonstrable need for
additional resources to international organizations and donors.
32
Capacity building in trade and health
References
1. Annual report of the administrator 1995. Addendum: main programme record. Executive Board of
the United Nations Development Programme and of the United Nations Population Fund, 18 March
1996
(http://www.undp.org/execbrd/archives/sessions/eb/Annual-1996/DP-1996-18-Add1.pdf ).
2. Declaration on the Contribution of the World Trade Organization to Achieving Greater Coherence in
Global Economic Policymaking. World Trade Organization
(http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/32-dcohr.pdf ).
4. Hong Kong Ministerial Declaration. Sixth WTO Ministerial Conference, December 2005
(http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/minist_e/min05_e/final_text_e.htm).
5. STDF medium-term strategy (2012–2016), Standards and Trade Development Facility, (www.
standardsfacility.org/Files/KeyDocs/STDF_367_Medium_Term_Strategy_Eng.pdf ).
6. Paris Declaration and Accra Agenda for Action. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development
(http://www.oecd.org/document/18/0,2340,en_2649_3236398_35401554_1_1_1_1,00.
html#book_1).
7. The Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness and the Accra Agenda for Action,
(www.oecd.org/dataoecd/11/41/34428351.pdf ).
8. Wood B et al., The evaluation of the Paris Declaration, phase 2, final report, Copenhagen, May 2011
(pd-website.inforce.dk/content/pdf/PD-EN-web.pdf ).
9. Aid for Trade task force. Recommendations of the task force on Aid for Trade. Geneva, World Trade
Organization, 2006.
10. Workshop on Aid for Trade and services: background note by the secretariat. WT/COMTD/AFT/W/34, 29
June 2012. WTO Committee on Trade and Development, 2012.
11. Aid for Trade at a glance 2007: 1st global review. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development and World Trade Organization, 2007
(http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/24/63/39638213.pdf ).
14. Chanda R. Trade in health services. Working Paper No. 70 (revised). Indian Council for Research on
International Economic Relations, 2001
(http://www.icrier.org/pdf/WP-RUPA.pdf ).
33
Capacity building in trade and health
15. The Integrated Framework for Least Developed Countries (LDCs): how does it fit into Aid for Trade?
Note by the WTO secretariat. World Trade Organization, 2007.
16. Evaluation of the revamped Integrated Framework For Trade-Related Technical Assistance to the
Least-Developed Countries. Capra-TFOC Consortium, November 2003.
17. Agarwal M, Cutura J. Integrated Framework for Trade-Related Technical Assistance addressing
challenges of globalization: an independent evaluation of the World Bank’s approach to global
programs – case study. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2004.
18. Report of the chairman of the task force on an Enhanced Integrated Framework, including
recommendations. WT/IFSC/W/15, 29 June 2006. World Trade Organization, Integrated Framework
Steering Committee, 2006.
19. Draft guidelines for the implementation of the enhanced Integrated Framework for LDCs:
compendium of working documents. Geneva, World Trade Organization, 2007.
23. Diagnostic trade integration study, United Republic of Tanzania. Government of the United Republic
of Tanzania, 2005
(http://www.enhancedif.org/EN%20web%20pages/Where%20we%20work/Tanzania.htm).
25. Open working Group “Zero draft” on Sustainable Development Goals, UN, 2 June 2014.
34
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
Chapter 4
4.1 Introduction
Most countries are undertaking trade reforms to increase the openness of their economy to international
trade. This is typically done through a reduction in tariffs and quotas, but can also be accomplished by
a reduction in other non-tariff barriers that limit the ease of entry of foreign goods and (especially more
recently) services into a country. Clearly the pace, extent and impact of trade reforms vary, often in response
to initial levels of openness, and depends on whether trade reforms are part of a wider domestic reform
agenda or a conditional part of borrowing from international financial institutions such as the International
Monetary Fund or the World Bank.
4.1.1 Importance of the trade–health relationship
Trade liberalization will inevitably impact human health. It is well known that medical care is only one of
many important determinants of human health, with other (perhaps more fundamental) determinants
including employment, nutrition, environmental factors, social capital and education. Through these and
other factors, there is considerable evidence of the link between health and wealth, with poverty and
income inequality being associated with poorer health (1). As the raison d’être of trade is to increase both
wealth and the availability of goods, changing trade patterns can influence both income (buying power)
and its distribution, and thus have an impact upon health.
Trade liberalization will also have an impact on the health sector, not only with respect to direct trade in
health-related goods and services, but also as a consequence of liberalization more broadly. For instance,
trade liberalization can affect overall public expenditures by allowing governments to purchase less
expensive foreign goods and services, which will in turn affect the amount of money available to fund
public health care.
However, although there is generally a positive relationship between trade liberalization and national
income (2–4), there is increasing recognition, including amongst international financial institutions such
as the World Bank, that trade liberalization in the absence of other policies will not necessarily lead to
higher growth (5). Thus, although trade liberalization generally is advantageous, the crucial factor in how
advantageous and to whom it is, is “how countries manage the process of integrating into the global
economies” (6).
For example, trade liberalization often triggers employment creation and destruction within and across
sectors, as firms adjust to the new competitive environment (7). In order to ensure that the movement of
labour is as smooth as possible and to avoid excessive unemployment, effective labour market policies will
be required. Trade can only explain a small fraction of the general increase in wage inequality observed in
both developed and developing countries in recent decades. The lion’s share of this increase in inequality
stems from the strong association between technological change and higher demand for skilled labour
(“skill-biased technical change”) (5, 8–11).
There is still a lack of sound empirical evidence demonstrating how trade liberalization links directly
and indirectly to health. Even though the positive link between increased trade, poverty reduction and
economic growth is widely accepted, evidence regarding the impact of trade liberalization on the social
determinants of health varies from one national context to another. Hence, adapting trade liberalization
35
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
to national conditions is important in ensuring desired outcomes (12, 13). This requires consideration of
“flanking” policies that may be undertaken to mitigate adverse consequences, and the design of trade
policies that reduce the potential health risks associated with freer trade whilst maximizing the positive
impact of trade liberalization on the social determinants of health.
4.1.2 Trade and health policy
As the World Commission on the Social Dimensions of Globalization noted, in a competitive international
economy there is greater vulnerability to sudden change than in protected national markets (14). Therefore,
policy-makers should continually review and update national systems of social protection that can stabilize
incomes, distribute the gains of globalization to groups that would otherwise be excluded and support the
development of new capabilities.
It is critical to distinguish social protection schemes between low-income countries and middle-income
countries. Low-income countries have very limited financial resources available to fund social protection
schemes and limited capacity to raise such funds, given that a large part of their economy is informal
or based on subsistence agriculture. Given these limited resources, social protection should focus on
interventions that contribute to long-term poverty reduction and that have multiplier effects (15), such
as health insurance schemes that protect against unexpected (and often catastrophic) medical expenses
(16–18).
Middle-income countries have a wider range of instruments available to them to reduce economic
insecurity, so a key policy issue becomes whether social protection should be universal or targeted to
particular groups. Targeted programmes may be very attractive in terms of reducing the fiscal implications
of social protection (19–21), however, evaluative and policy studies offer powerful arguments in favour of
universality. For instance, targeted coverage is exclusionary and reinforces existing social stratification and
stigmatization. Additionally, macroeconomic shocks are a rude reminder that in times of systemic crisis,
there is little that separates middle-income from lower-middle-income groups, and finally, the targeted
programmes often involve greater administrative costs and are prone to “leakage” on many levels.
In summary, trade policies adopted by national governments can affect health and health systems through
a very diverse set of channels and intermediate variables. However, these causal linkages can be difficult
to track and monitor. Moreover, in many political systems, health authorities are not in a position to
directly affect trade policy decisions at the national level. Nevertheless, their existing knowledge of the
determinants of population health and their jurisdiction over social and health policies place health policy-
makers in a privileged position to ensure that, in an increasingly global economic environment, domestic
policies and regulations are designed to maximize the potential of, and to minimize the risks presented by,
trade liberalization.
There are many national and international information sources that discuss trade and the general
macroeconomy, such as public expenditure reviews and trade policy reviews. However, the key issue facing
health policy-makers is how to interpret this information with respect to the health sector. What information
needs to be extracted? How might this information be interpreted? What health and trade policies should
be adopted in light of the information?
This chapter provides an overview of the complex relationships between trade and health focusing on
general macroeconomic factors such as the growth and distribution of national income, rather than on
direct trade in health-related goods and services (which are covered elsewhere). The aim is to acquaint
health policy-makers with some fundamental facts, concepts and evidence concerning the influence of
macroeconomic factors on population health and the health sector. The chapter thus creates a basis for later
chapters that deal with more specific trade and health issues.
36
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
37
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
Thus, although in aggregate trade liberalization may generate economic benefits for a country, it is also
likely to require adjustment at various levels, including at the individual level. This adjustment process
might cause a feeling of increased economic insecurity with implications for psychological well-being. Some
experts suggest that economic insecurity also increases the demand for more generous social insurance
that compensates individuals for a riskier environment (42–44).
Despite these distributional caveats, evidence shows that the gains from trade liberalization should
outweigh the adjustment costs and lead to net welfare gains (Box 4.1).
38
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
sector itself ). They might also translate into economic insecurity, which is closely linked to increased stress-
related illness (53).
The empirical evidence suggests that there is no link between trade liberalization and economic stability.
Rather, studies find that the institutional quality of a country determines to what extent it is able to cope
with economic shocks and is thus an important determinant of its economic stability (54). For example,
the impact of the Asian crisis in the late 1990s was felt particularly severely by some countries, revealing
institutional gaps in social protection and other areas. (Compared with the OECD average of 12.7%, East Asia
spent 1% of GDP on social protection.) In the aftermath of the Asian crisis, it was thus recommended by the
World Bank that higher-quality institutional structures be put in place to help households manage the risks
of income shocks (55).
Indicators such as these could be combined to provide useful information. For example, stable and
equitable economic growth (and trade liberalization) would be indicated by high and sustained (little
annual variance) increases in GDP, low overall unemployment and a low Gini coefficient. Trade liberalization
promotes sustained economic growth (first indicator) and should go hand in hand with promoting equitable
economic growth (latter two indicators).
The assessment of the direct and indirect impacts of trade on health can be made before the adoption of
a major trade policy change, or it can be conducted afterwards in order to monitor the changes associated
with the new trade environment. An assessment tool (see section 1.1 of Chapter 1) could be used to compile
The Gini coefficient is a commonly used measure of inequality of wealth, with a coefficient of 1 indicating large wealth disparities and a coefficient of zero
1
information about trade and health issues in a country, forming a basis for analysis of the trade reforms
under consideration.
When attempting to compile these data, what main sources could officials use to easily find the necessary
information? First, the trade policy reviews prepared by the WTO Secretariat can serve as good starting
points for the description of national trade policies and their macroeconomic context. The objective of these
reviews is to increase transparency by describing each WTO Member’s trade policies and practices, and
trade policy-making institutions.2 Trade policy reviews can also be useful for gathering information about
the impacts of trade on health. For instance, the sections reviewing recent trade trends in specific sectors
can provide information on health care services or the policies relating to patents and pharmaceutical
drugs.3 However, for now, these reviews generally do not contain information about the distributional
impacts of trade policies or the importance of tariff revenues.4 Therefore, other sources have to be used to
conduct a national assessment of trade and health.
Another important source of information is the diagnostic trade integration study (DTIS), prepared by the
World Bank in the context of the enhanced Integrated Framework for Trade-Related Technical Assistance to
Least Developed Countries (see Chapter 3) These country studies evaluate internal and external constraints
on a country’s integration into the world economy, and recommend areas where technical assistance and
policy actions can help the country overcome these barriers. In recent years, the World Bank has applied the
DTIS methodology beyond the Integrated Framework and has been using it in its dialogue with other client
countries.5
The DTIS usually includes a section on trade and poverty where one or several policy options or scenarios
are examined in terms of their impact on poverty reduction. For instance, the DTIS for Uganda highlights
how increases in tariff levels, due to regional harmonization of protection, led to higher prices of goods,
which was of particular significance for food and beverages. Because these items represent a large part
of the expenditure of poor households, the higher tariff levels had an adverse impact on poverty. When
available, the DTIS can thus be useful to understand the distributional impacts of trade policy. Other
potential sources of information are the poverty reduction strategy papers prepared in many developing
countries.
In addition to these reports, a number of indicators can be used and monitored to track the implementation
and impact of trade policy on health, and from this inform negotiations with trade policy-makers and the
design of proactive and responsive health policy. A range of readily accessible indicators from national
data sources may be used for this purpose. Collecting and interpreting these indicators will guide policy-
makers towards identifying and understanding the linkages between the general economic and health
environment and the changes engendered by trade reforms over time.
2
See http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tpr_e/tpr_e.htm
3
See, for example, trade policy review for Malaysia: http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tpr_e/tp325_e.htm
4
Trade policy reviews can also be useful for gathering information about the direct impact of trade on health. For instance, the sections reviewing recent
trade trends in specific sectors can provide information on health care
services or the policies related to patents and pharmaceutical drugs.
5
For available DTIS, see http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/TRADE/0,,contentMDK:20615178~menuPK:1574524~pagePK:148956~piPK:21
6618~theSitePK:239071,00.html
41
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
References
1. Deaton A. Health, inequality and economic development. CMH Working Paper Series WG 1:3. Geneva,
World Health Organization, Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, 2001.
2. Dollar D. Outward-oriented developing economies really do grow more rapidly: evidence from 95
LDCs, 1976–85. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 1992, 40:523–544.
3. Ben-David D. Equalizing exchange: trade liberalization and income convergence. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 1993, 108:653–679.
4. Sachs J, Warner A. Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1995, 1:1–118.
5. Winters LA. Trade liberalisation and economic performance: an overview. Economic Journal, 2004,
114(493):F4–F21.
6. Lall S. The employment impact of globalization in developing countries. In: Lee E, Vivarelli M, eds.
Understanding globalization, employment and poverty reduction. Houndmills, Palgrave Macmillan for
the ILO, 2004:73–101.
7. Ghose AK. Jobs and incomes in a globalizing world. Geneva, International Labour Office, 2003.
8. Wood A, Ridao-Cano C. Skill, trade and international inequality. Oxford Economic Papers, 1999,
51(1):89–119.
9. DR-CAFTA: Challenges and opportunities for Central America. Washington DC, World Bank, 2005.
10. Hoekman B, Winters LA. Trade and employment: stylized facts and research findings. Policy Research
Working Paper 3676. Washington DC, World Bank, 2005.
11. Milanovic B, Squire L. Does tariff liberalization increase wage inequality? Some empirical evidence.
NBER Working Paper 11046. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2005.
12. Lee E, Vivarelli M, eds. Understanding globalization, employment and poverty reduction. Houndmills,
Palgrave Macmillan for the ILO, 2004.
13. Freeman RB. Trade wars: the exaggerated impact of trade in economic debate. World Economy, 2004,
27:1–23.
14. World Commission on the Social Dimensions of Globalization. A fair globalization: creating
opportunities for all. Geneva, International Labour Organization, 2004.
15. Smith J, Subbarao K. What role for safety net transfers in very low income countries? Social Safety Nets
Primer Series. Washington DC, World Bank Institute, 2003.
16. Norton A, Conway T, Foster M. Social protection concepts and approaches: implications for policy
and practice in international development. Working Paper 143. London, Overseas Development
Institute, 2001.
17. Wagstaff A, Watanabe N, van Doorslaer E. Impoverishment, insurance, and health care payments.
Washington DC, World Bank, Health, Nutrition, and Population Network, 2001.
18. Van Ginneken W. Extending social security: policies for developing countries. International Labour
Review, 2003, 142:277–294.
42
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
19. Ravallion M. Targeted transfers in poor countries: revisiting the trade-offs and policy options. Social
Protection Discussion Paper. Washington DC, World Bank, 2003.
20. Coady DP. Designing and evaluating social safety nets: theory, evidence and policy conclusion.
Discussion Paper 172. Washington DC, International Food Policy Research Institute, 2004.
21. Pritchett L. A lecture on the political economy of targeted safety nets. Social Protection Discussion
Paper. Washington DC, World Bank, 2005.
22. Maneschi A. Comparative advantage in international trade: a historical perspective. Edward Elgar
Publishing, Cheltenham 1998.
23. World investment report: transnational corporations and competitiveness. Geneva and New York,
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1995.
24. Dollar D, Kraay A. Trade, growth and poverty. Washington DC, World Bank, 2001.
25. Mattoo A. Measuring services trade liberalization and its impact on economic growth: an illustration.
Washington DC, World Bank, 2001.
26. Bloom D, Canning D. The health and wealth of nations. Science, 2000, 287:1207–1209.
27. Pritchett L, Summers LH. Wealthier is healthier. Journal of Human Resources, 1996, 31:841–868.
28. Subbarao K, Raney L. Social gains from female education: a cross-national study. Economic
Development and Cultural Change, 1995, 44:105–128.
29. Fogel R. The relevance of Malthus for the study of mortality today: long-run influences in health,
mortality, labor force participation and population growth. Working Paper 0054. Cambridge, MA,
National Bureau of Economic Research, 1994.
30. Frankel J, Rose A. Is trade good or bad for the environment? Sorting out the causality. Review of
Economics and Statistics, 2005, 87:85–91.
31. Becker G, Tomes N. Human capital and the rise and fall of families. Journal of Labor Economics, 1986,
4:1–39.
32. Hunt P. The right of everyone to the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard of physical and
mental health. Mission to the World Trade Organization, Commission on Human Rights, 2004.
33. McKeown T. The modern rise of population. London, Edwin Arnold, 1976.
34. Smith J. Healthy bodies and thick wallets: the dual relationship between health and economic
status. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1999, 13:143–166.
35. Suhrcke M et al. Investment in health could be good for Europe’s economies. British Medical Journal,
2006, 333:1017–1019.
36. Edwards S. Openness, trade liberalization and growth in developing countries. Journal of Economic
Literature, 1993, 31:1358–1393.
37. Winters LA, McCulloch N, McKay A. Trade liberalization and poverty: the evidence so far. Journal of
Economic Literature, 2004, 62:72–115.
38. Leveine DI, Rotham D. Does trade affect child health? Journal of Health Economics, 2006, 25:538–554.
43
Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
39. Frankel J, Romer D. Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review, 1999, 89:379–399.
40. Arbache JS, Dickerson A, Green F. Trade liberalisation and wages in developing countries. Economic
Journal, 2004, 114:F73–F96.
41. Goldberg PK et al. Imported intermediate inputs and domestic product growth: evidence from India.
Working Paper 14416. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2008.
42. Garrett G. Partisan politics in the global economy. Cambridge University Press, 1998.
43. Rodrik D. Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy,
1998, 106(5):997–1032.
44. Rodrik D. Has globalization gone too far? Washington DC, Institute for International Economics, 1997.
45. Aizenman J, Jinjarak Y. Globalization and developing countries: a shrinking tax base? Working Paper
11933. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2006.
46. De Cordoba SF, Laird S, Vanzetti D. Smoke and mirrors: making sense of the WTO industrial tariff
negotiations. Policy Issues in International Trade and Commodities Study Series No. 30. New York and
Geneva, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 2006.
47. Baunsgaard T, Keen M. Tax revenue and (or?) trade liberalization. Working Paper 05/112. Washington
DC, International Monetary Fund, 2005.
48. Glenday G. Toward fiscally feasible and efficient trade liberalization. Durham, NC, Duke University,
2006.
49. Khattry B, Rao JM. Fiscal faux pas? An analysis of the revenue implications of trade liberalization.
World Development, 2002, 30(8):1431–1444.
50. Blouin C et al. Trade liberalization. Synthesis Paper 4. Geneva, WHO Commission on Social
Determinants of Health, Globalization Knowledge Network, 2006.
51. Glenday G. Trade liberalization and customs revenues: does trade liberalization lead to lower customs
revenues? The case of Kenya. African Economic Policy Discussion Paper 44. Harvard University, John F.
Kennedy School of Government, 2000.
52. Bamou E. Trade liberalization and economic performance of Cameroon and Gabon. African
Economic Research Consortium, 1999.
53. Wilkinson R, Marmot M, eds. Social determinants of health: the solid facts. Geneva, World Health
Organization, 2003.
54. Acemoglu D et al. Institutional causes, macroeconomic symptoms: volatility, crises and growth.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 2003, 50:49–123.
55. Towards an East Asian social protection strategy. Washington DC, World Bank, 1999.
44
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
Chapter 5
5.1 Introduction
This chapter focuses on the importance of implementing trade commitments in a manner that remains
sensitive to public health objectives. The discussion is divided into two levels of analysis. First, the chapter
discusses the general considerations which countries face when implementing treaty commitments.
Second, it considers specific issues that arise with respect to trade and health. Finally, the chapter concludes
with some guiding principles applicable to the national implementation of commitments in trade treaties
from a public health perspective.
provide a basis on which to implement the requirements of a treaty. Where the adoption of a new national
law is necessary, then the nature of the change required and the impact of the change on existing national
law and policy, it is important to identify these in as much detail as possible.
The need to implement a treaty obligation sometimes reveals a conflict that States must resolve. In brief, a
conflict is a situation in which simultaneous compliance with two different legal obligations is not possible.
A broader definition not only includes the “obligation versus obligation” context but also incorporates
situations where the implementation of a discretionary right accorded by one legal rule would produce a
breach of a mandatory obligation imposed by another legal rule. This type of conflict should be taken into
consideration when analysing the impact of treaty implementation on national law.
Conflicts can exist between obligations created by two or more treaties (for example, between a trade
treaty and a human rights treaty) or between obligations found in a new treaty and in existing national law.
Most legal systems have default rules that apply to resolve such conflicts, such as the “later-in-time” rule in
the United States under which, in the case of a conflict between a treaty provision and a federal statutory
provision, the one that was enacted later in time prevails. The application of such rules can produce
situations in which a country is no longer in compliance with its international legal obligations if the
national law trumps the conflicting treaty rule. It is important to understand whether the implementation
of a treaty would cause a conflict, and how such a conflict might be handled, under a policy-maker’s own
system of law.
If conflicts do not arise from treaty implementation, and if new statutory law is required to implement
a treaty effectively, then a country faces the task of adopting new national law to make effective its
international legal obligations. Again, how new statutory law is adopted is a matter generally governed by
constitutional law.
Finally, parties must monitor how the treaty is implemented internationally and within their respective
national legal systems. Of particular importance is how the treaty is interpreted and applied, perhaps
through decisions of international or national courts. Interpretations of treaties, and the national law
implementing them, might have legal consequences that affect how countries continue to abide by their
treaty commitments.
46
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
Table 5.1 List of possible health intervention categories and issues under international trade treaties
Category Examples Trade treaty issue(s)
Fiscal measures to increase Tariffs Most-favoured-nation principle
cost of products to encour- Bound commitments (i.e. caps) on tariff rates
age reduced consumption
Transparency and due process requirements
or use
Domestic taxes National treatment principle
Transparency and due process requirements
Quantitative restrictions on Import bans Prohibition on quantitative restrictions on import of goods
imports that pose a risk to Market access specific commitments with respect to imports of services
health, whether goods or
Most-favoured-nation principle
services
National treatment principle
Risk assessment and scientific evidence (for food safety measures)
Harmonization requirement (for food safety measures)
Quotas Prohibition on quantitative restrictions on import of goods
Market access specific commitments with respect to imports of services
Most-favoured-nation principle
National treatment principle
Regulation of content and Required or prohibited Risk assessment and scientific evidence (for food safety measures)
performance of goods to ingredients or compo- Harmonization requirement (for food safety measures)
protect against disease risks nents
Most-favoured-nation principle
National treatment principle
Prohibition on quantitative restrictions on imports of goods
Transparency and due process requirements
Technical regulations Most-favoured-nation principle
or standards (not in- National treatment principle
volving food safety)
Harmonization requirement
Transparency and due process requirements
Procedural requirements on how regulations and standards are adopted
and applied
Regulation of product infor- Labelling requirements Risk assessment and scientific evidence (for food safety measures)
mation Harmonization requirement (for food safety measures)
For non-food safety issues, obligations that apply to use of technical regu-
lations and standards (see above)
Advertising restrictions If construed as a measure affecting trade in goods, the measure would
have to comply with the most-favoured-nation principle, national treat-
ment principle and transparency requirement
This type of measure also affects the provision of a service (advertising),
requiring analysis of General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) or
service provisions in regional or bilateral trade agreements
Under GATS, advertising restrictions could be affected by specific com-
mitments for both market access and national treatment, if any
Under regional or bilateral trade agreements, market access and national
treatment commitments, if any, would also be of concern
47
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
48
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
Worries about public health’s permanent loss of policy space to trade interests have, however, evolved into
strategies to produce better policy coherence between trade and health. The policy coherence agenda
recognizes potential problems between trade liberalization and health protection but acknowledges that
governments retain significant policy discretion and choice in how trade commitments are implemented
and how they might affect national public health strategies. The production of a strategy paper on trade
and health based on a national needs assessment should facilitate more informed and systematic efforts at
producing policy coherence.
In the national strategy paper, issues concerning the implementation of commitments found in trade
treaties will cluster around the substantive areas of trade law involved, such as the international law on trade
in products and trade in services. The following sections undertake a thematic analysis of implementation
issues within the policy coherence agenda.
5.3.1 Macroeconomic and trade environment
Trade and trade liberalization are important to the achievement of national and international economic
growth. For the foreseeable future, therefore, policy-makers and public health authorities will have to
consider the impact of treaty commitments as they make health policy decisions.
Recent developments in international trade law are making the situation for public health more complex,
heightening the difficulties of achieving policy coherence. In addition to the trade negotiations taking
place, albeit without much progress, in the WTO’s Doha Development Round, many countries are pursuing
regional and bilateral trade agreements, many of which include more aggressive provisions on liberalizing
trade in products and services and on protecting intellectual property rights than the corresponding
provisions under the relevant WTO agreements. Thus, from a macroeconomic perspective, the national
strategy on trade and health must consider not only the WTO agreements but also the increasing number of
regional and bilateral trade agreements (see Chapter 6)
Trying to adopt a harmonized public health approach to the implications of trade agreements becomes
more difficult as the number and types of agreements multiply. This difficulty appears throughout the
process of negotiating, debating and implementing trade agreements because, generally speaking,
most public health authorities in countries, especially developing countries, do not have the capacity
to participate in and monitor every development in international trade. From the trade negotiator’s
perspective, trying to apply harmonized public health principles and criteria consistently across numerous
negotiations and agreements might seem too burdensome, given the perceived political and economic
exigencies of getting agreements finalized.
Even in this difficult environment, the protection of health as a national policy objective actually fares better
than other objectives in terms of its relationship with trade liberalization and trade treaties. Trade treaties
on products and services expressly recognize that the protection of health is an important government
function and that measures protecting health, if applied properly, will trump trade interests (see, for
example, GATT Art. XX(b)).
The WTO Dispute Settlement Body (DSB) has enunciated a set of principles that underscore WTO’s
recognition of the importance of health as a political and social objective. In various cases, the DSB has ruled
that (a) the protection of health is a national objective of vital importance; (b) WTO Members are free to
select the level of health protection they believe appropriate for their populations; (c) health effects should
be included in the case-by-case analysis of whether products or services are alike; and (d) trade restrictive
measures to protect human health are permissible under the WTO agreements so long as there are no less
restrictive alternative measures that could reasonably be expected to achieve the health policy objectives in
question (2, p. 184)
In this respect, public health has a much stronger profile in international trade law than the protection of
human rights, which is not recognized as a legitimate reason for restricting trade. In short, in implementing
trade treaties, it is possible for national policy-makers and legislators to build coherence between trade and
health.
49
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
The DSB has found certain national health measures in violation of some of these general rules. The rulings
in US–Gasoline (3) and EC–Asbestos (4) each held that the respondent WTO Member had violated the national
treatment principle in the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). In Brazil–Tyres, the DSB held that
Brazil violated the prohibition on quantitative restrictions when it applied an import ban on retreaded
automobile tyres for health-related purposes (5).2
These cases do not mean that these general principles on trade in products in GATT and other trade treaties
pose significant threats to the policy options of national public health authorities. Robust public health
action against disease threats does not require discrimination against imported products. Where imported
products pose health risks that exceed those associated with similar domestic products, the most-favoured-
nation and national treatment principles are flexible enough to allow restrictions in such circumstances and
therefore do not pose serious problems for public health. Further, as the Appellate Body held in EC–Asbestos
(4), WTO Members can factor in health risks when evaluating whether two products are like products for
purposes of the national treatment principle.
2
For an index of WTO disputes issues, see http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/dispu_e/dispu_subjects_index_e.htm?id=G14#selected_subject
50
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
For example, in Brazil–Tyres, the DSB held that Brazil’s import ban on retreaded tyres violated the prohibition
on quantitative restrictions in GATT but was necessary to protect human health. The DSB nevertheless
struck down the import ban because Brazil applied it in an unjustified manner because it imported
significant amounts of used tyres that posed essentially the same health threat as the retreaded tyres. The
inconsistency in Brazil’s trade measures had no public health justification.
Implementation of trade treaties into national law should be done in such a way as to ensure the ability
to use the health-related exceptions typically found in those treaties. As can be seen from Brazil-Tyres, it is
important to implement the law in a manner consistent with those treaties (5).
Trade in health “bads” and in health-specific products: technical regulations and standards for
products
Health “bads” are products which can result in harm to health when used.Tobacco is an example of a
public health “bad” because no use or consumption of tobacco occurs without some harm to health. Many
51
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
products contain ingredients or components (for example toxic chemicals) that may harm health if not
properly secured or made safe in the product and its use. On the other hand, health-specific products are
designed to improve or contribute to health (for example pharmaceuticals).
The general obligations of trade treaties apply to both health-specific products and health “bads”. These
obligations include the technical product regulations and standards of the WTO Agreement on Technical
Barriers to Trade (TBT Agreement). The TBT Agreement recognizes the protection of health as a legitimate
goal that can be pursued through such regulations and standards, but requires that any measures be
applied in a non-discriminatory manner, be harmonized where possible on the basis of recognized
international standards, be transparent, and be the least trade-restrictive measures possible to achieve the
level of health protection sought. Most of these obligations are similar to the rules applied generally to
trade in products and to the provisions in the SPS Agreement.
Treaty provisions on technical product regulations and standards may prove challenging to implement
into national legislation because of the sheer scope of the provisions’ coverage and the complexity of
the process of making and applying such regulations and standards. The scope of application of the TBT
Agreement is enormous, with provisions that potentially touch on a broad spectrum of existing national
laws and policies.
The US-Clove Cigarette (6) case demonstrates the importance of the TBT Agreement to health policy. In this
case, the DSB held that a U.S. law banning importation of variously flavoured cigarettes violated the national
treatment provision of the TBT Agreement because the U.S. continued to permit sales of domestically
manufactured menthol-flavoured cigarettes. Unlike GATT, the TBT Agreement does not contain any
exception to which the U.S. could appeal to justify a violation of the national treatment principle. Various
WTO Members have also filed pending claims under the TBT Agreement against Australia’s imposition of
plain-packaging requirements for all tobacco products.
31 of the TRIPS Agreement for a list of requirements). However, some developed countries or regions
— especially the United States, the European Free Trade Area (EFTA)3, and the European Union — have
negotiated regional and bilateral trade treaties that include provisions with higher levels of protection for IP
rights than those required by the TRIPS Agreement. These higher levels of protection (therefore often called
“TRIPS-plus” provisions) in regional and bilateral agreements could have even wider impact than meets the
eye because the most-favoured-nation provision in the TRIPS Agreement requires WTO Members to accord
each other the best treatment they give to any other country with respect to IP protection.
Unlike GATT and the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), the TRIPS Agreement does not contain a
provision that exempts regional and bilateral trade agreements from the application of the most-favoured-nation
principle, a distinction that may be quite important in this context. The result is that national implementation of TRIPS-
plus provisions cannot be confined to the States that are parties to the regional or bilateral agreement in question.
Instead, national implementation must accord TRIPS-plus treatment to all WTO Members under the most-favoured-
nation principle.
Whether or not a WTO Member has agreed to TRIPS-plus provisions, national implementation should be
pursued in such a way as to maximize utilization of any public health safeguards available in the treaties
(such as the provision on “limited exceptions” to patent rights in Article 30 of the TRIPS Agreement, and
the compulsory licence provision of Article 31 of that Agreement). Even where treaty flexibilities exist,
practical opposition to integrating such safeguards firmly into national law and using these flexibilities may
deter some countries from taking full advantage of the safeguards in their national policies and laws. Such
domestic opposition often connects to external pressure that countries face to include TRIPS-plus provisions
in negotiating regional and bilateral trade agreements.
5.3.3 Trade in services
Public health considerations also arise with respect to commitments countries make in trade treaties
concerning the liberalization of trade in services. As with trade in products, countries face two levels of
implementation issues. The first level involves the GATS, while the second concerns regional or bilateral
treaties that address the liberalization of trade in services. As with trade in products, the regional and
bilateral services agreements sometimes have more aggressive liberalization provisions than GATS.
GATS, discussed further in Chapter 7, contains general obligations with respect to trade in services as well
as specific commitments on market access and national treatment that WTO Members chose to undertake
in their individual Schedules of commitments (see GATS Part III). GATS imposes the most-favoured-nation
principle as a general obligation, but, as with trade in products, this principle appears to be compatible with
robust public health measures. For service sectors in which a WTO Member has agreed to additional, specific
commitments in its Schedule, any modification or withdrawal of those commitments (such as the grant of
a national monopoly) obligates that Member to provide compensation to WTO Members that have been
injured as a result (see GATS Art. XXI). Some commentators have expressed concern that the compensation
requirement might adversely affect a country’s ability to address its public health needs. Other general
obligations in GATS are mainly procedural in nature and do not raise serious public health concerns.
Unlike GATT, the general obligations of GATS do not prohibit the use of quantitative restrictions or contain
national treatment provisions. Instead, the national treatment provisions of GATS apply only to the specific
commitments undertaken by WTO Members in their Schedules pursuant to Parts III and IV of GATS (see
GATS Art. XVII, entitled “National Treatment”). GATS permits WTO Members to design the scope of their
market access and national treatment commitments, should they decide to make such commitments (see
GATS Part III).
From a national implementation perspective, the specific commitments are more important than the
general obligations because GATS provides disincentives to the modification or withdrawal of specific
commitments. These include the requirement to notify the GATS Council at least three months prior to
modification or withdrawal, the prohibition on modification or withdrawal during the first three years
after the specific commitment’s entry into force, and the requirement that other Members injured by the
EFTA includes Switzerland, Norway, Iceland and Lichtenstein.
3
53
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
modification or withdrawal be compensated (see GATS Article XXI). Importantly, few WTO Members have
made significant specific commitments in areas directly related to health services, and some have stated
that they will not entertain any requests to liberalize trade in health services during the Doha Development
Round, the completion date of which is currently uncertain.
However, the most important step from a public health perspective is not the implementation of the
specific commitments but whether such commitments should be made in the first place. Thus, attention
should be focused foremost on the national and diplomatic processes through which decisions are reached
regarding these specific commitments.
As with trade in products, regional and bilateral trade treaties may contain provisions that liberalize trade
in services more aggressively than GATS.4 National implementation of these agreements may, therefore,
be more extensive and complicated than implementation of GATS, particularly in terms of deeper market
access obligations and broader national treatment coverage. However, provisions in regional and bilateral
agreements that liberalize trade in services may not be applicable to the entire WTO membership because
GATS includes an exemption from the most-favoured-nation principle when such agreements satisfy certain
criteria (see GATS Article V).
5.4 Conclusions
The current macro-political climate favouring the pursuit of trade liberalization (whether in WTO or in
regional and bilateral settings), means that public health officials will continue to confront questions of
treaty implementation for the foreseeable future. As implementation issues arise, policy-makers should
endeavour to:
• understand the source of the international legal obligations to be implemented (i.e., does the
commitment come from a WTO agreement or a regional or bilateral agreement?);
• analyse the substance of the commitment, with particular attention to whether it affects exist-
ing or planned public health policies, strategies and authorities;
• identify any conflicts that may exist between the trade treaty commitment and national law,
and the constitutionally appropriate way to resolve such conflicts;
• understand the full range of public health actions that can legitimately be undertaken in com-
pliance with the commitment and ensure implementation policies and legislation take full
advantage of these flexibilities;
• anticipate how national implementation of trade treaty commitments may adversely affect
public health while building implementation policies and legislation aimed at mitigating such
adverse effects;
• engage in pre-emptive action by closely monitoring ongoing trade negotiations, both within
WTO and in regional and bilateral contexts by providing input to negotiators; and
• share information and collaborate with public health experts in other governments to develop
a transnational understanding of the best and worst practices with respect to the implemen-
tation of treaty commitments.
See WTO, Dataset of service commitments in regional trade agreements (RTAs), http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/serv_e/dataset_e/dataset_e.htm.
4
54
Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
References
1. Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties. United Nations, Vienna, 23 May 1969; entered into force 27
January 1980.
2. Fidler DP et al. Legal review of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) from a health
policy perspective. Globalization, Trade and Health Working Papers Series. Geneva, World Health
Organization, 2005.
3. United States: standards for reformulated and conventional gasoline. Report of the Appellate Body:
WT/DS2/AB/R, 29 April 1996. Geneva, World Trade Organization.
4. European Communities: measures affecting asbestos and asbestos-containing products. Report of the
Appellate Body: WT/DS135/AB/R, 12 March 2001. Geneva, World Trade Organization.
5. Brazil: measures affecting imports of retreaded tyres. Report of the Appellate Body: WT/DS332/AB/R, 3
December 2007. Geneva, World Trade Organization.
6. United States: measures affecting the production and sale of clove cigarettes. Report of the Appellate
Body: WT/DS406/AB/R, 4 April 2012. Geneva, World Trade Organization.
7. Australia: certain measures concerning trademarks and other plain packaging requirements
applicable to tobacco products and packaging, WT/DS434, panel established 5 May 2014. Geneva,
World Trade Organization.
55
Regional trade agreements and health services
Chapter 6
6.1 Introduction
Regional trade agreements (RTAs)1 have proliferated worldwide, particularly over the last decade. Existing
RTAs are being reinvigorated and expanded, and new ones are being negotiated. RTAs are a defining feature
of today’s international trade policy landscape. They exist on sub-regional, regional and inter-regional scales.
They are negotiated and concluded on a North–North, North–South and South–South basis, including
between regions. Many of these RTAs include provisions on services, health care, intellectual property
protection, investment and temporary movement of labour.
Progressive liberalization of services has also been pursued at the multilateral level under the WTO Doha
Round. Nevertheless, services did not receive priority attention, with progress conditioned to advancements
in agriculture and non-agricultural market access negotiations. This remains the case despite the outcome
of the recent WTO Ninth Ministerial Conference, including the trade facilitation agreement and the
ministerial decision on operationalization of the waiver concerning preferential treatment to services and
services suppliers of least developed countries. Within this framework, plurilateral, and regional initiatives
have intensified. Negotiations for a plurilateral trade in services agreement (TISA) were launched by 23 WTO
members representing 70% of the global services trade. TISA intends to build upon the General Agreement
on Trade in Services (GATS) to promote subsequent multilateralization and participation of new members
and capture autonomous and preferential liberalization (1).
The services sector contributes importantly to production in developing countries as well as global and
regional value chains. As a percentage of total value added, services represent more than half of the GDP in
Latin America and developing countries in Oceania and almost half in Africa and in developing countries in
Asia (see Figure 6.1). The services production in developing countries has grown more than 10% between
2002 and 2011 and, as a percentage of the global services production, is less than 20% in developing Asia,
less than 10% in Latin America and around 2% in Africa (see Figure 6.2). Services exports in developing
countries in Asia represent 25% of global services exports while services exports in Latin America and in
Africa represent less than 4% of global values (see Figure 6.3).
The term “preferential trade agreements” (PTAs) is utilized by some sources in place of “regional trade agreements” (RTAs). This chapter, however, follows the
1
convention of the World Trade Organization (WTO) as stated at www.wto.org/English/tratop_e/region_e/region_e.htm, which defines RTAs as involving
reciprocal concessions and PTAs as involving unilateral concessions.
56
Regional trade agreements and health services
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Developing Africa 49.5% 47.5% 48.0% 47.5% 45.7% 44.6% 44.8% 42.7% 46.9% 46.3% 46.8%
Developing America 63.3% 62.3% 61.9% 60.3% 61.0% 60.4% 61.0% 60.6% 62.9% 61.7% 61.9%
Developing Asia 50.8% 51.1% 50.6% 49.9% 49.2% 49.0% 49.2% 48.1% 49.7% 48.9% 48.1%
Developing Oceania 62.1% 62.7% 62.4% 62.3% 61.6% 60.0% 58.8% 59.1% 60.0% 57.1% 56.2%
57
Regional trade agreements and health services
20%
16%
12%
8%
4%
0%
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Developing Africa 1.3% 1.2% 1.3% 1.4% 1.5% 1.5% 1.6% 1.7% 1.8% 1.9% 1.9%
Developing America 5.8% 4.9% 4.5% 4.5% 5.1% 5.6% 5.9% 6.3% 6.3% 7.1% 7.3%
Developing Asia 10.0% 10.5% 10.4% 10.8% 11.6% 12.5% 13.5% 14.3% 15.3% 16.8% 17.9%
58
Regional trade agreements and health services
30%
20%
10%
0%
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Developing Africa 2.2% 2.2% 2.4% 2.4% 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% 2.1% 2.2%
Developing America 3.9% 3.6% 3.4% 3.2% 3.4% 3.4% 3.3% 3.3% 3.3% 3.4% 3.6% 3.6%
Developing Asia 16.9% 17.2% 16.9% 17.8% 18.6% 19.5% 20.1% 20.8% 20.3% 22.8% 23.1% 24.5%
The trend for services in RTAs is occurring in parallel with a trend of increasing intra-regional trade in
services. Among developed countries, around 80% of services trade is taking place within the region. Intra-
regional trade is also important in the South–South context. In fact, it accounts for most of the South–South
services trade of developing countries in Asia & Oceania and in America (without NAFTA countries) and half
of it in Africa, as illustrated in Figure 6.4. Intra-regional services trade is particularly significant in Asia and
Oceania, where it accounts for more than half of total services trade. However, interregional trade in services
remains below 20% in other developing country regions (2, 3).
59
Regional trade agreements and health services
50
Africa
17
91
Asia & Oceania
51
Developing Africa 7.9% 7.3% 7.3% 8.1% 11.6% 11.2% 11.0% 10.4% 10.4% 11.2% 10.9% 11.8%
Developing America 16.5% 16.7% 18.0% 18.5% 17.6% 18.0% 16.0% 14.2% 13.4% 12.7% 12.3% 11.8%
Developing Asia 35.1% 37.4% 37.8% 36.1% 35.7% 35.8% 36.9% 39.9% 43.1% 44.3% 45.3% 47.1%
Differences between developing regions can also be found in inflows of remittances. Developing Asian
countries received 47% of global remittances inflows in 2012 and African and Latin American countries
received 12% each (see Figure 6.5). Remittances inflows have grown more than 15% in developing Asian
countries and in Africa between 2003 and 2012, while growing 9% in Latin America in the same period.
60
Regional trade agreements and health services
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Developing Africa 2.4% 2.3% 3.0% 2.4% 3.1% 2.5% 2.6% 3.2% 4.4% 3.1% 2.9% 3.7%
Developing America 9.7% 9.3% 8.0% 13.1% 7.9% 6.6% 8.6% 11.6% 12.3% 13.5% 15.1% 18.1%
Developing Asia 14.7% 15.3% 21.1% 22.7% 22.7% 20.0% 18.2% 21.8% 26.7% 28.4% 26.4% 30.1%
Global foreign direct investment (FDI) flows amounted to 1.4 trillion USD between 2009 and 2011, 69%
of which were directed at services and 31% at the infrastructure services sector (ISS) in particular (1).
For developing countries, much of regional trade reflects trade in commercial services such as freight
transportation, tourism, construction and business services. However, the scope (and therefore volume)
of traded services is expanding rapidly as countries progressively privatize and liberalize those services
traditionally performed as a government function (3), such as health services. In OECD countries, where
data are available, it is possible to confirm that health exports, measured by exports of health related
travel, have reached more than US$ 6000 million in 2011 and have grown 11% between 2002 and 2011
(see Figure 6.6).
61
Regional trade agreements and health services
6000
4000
2000
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
OECD
Health related travel exports 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
OECD 1841 1967 2345 2736 3555 4278 4706 5184 6073 5571 5855 6076
Given the growth of RTAs, and their implications for health and health care, health policy-makers need
to pay attention to the respective negotiation and implementation processes with a view to achieving
coherence between trade and health policy objectives. While regional liberalization of health services
through RTAs may generate pro-development outcomes, such benefits are not automatic, and liberalization
needs to be properly paced and sequenced within the development of an adequate regulatory, institutional
and policy framework.
This chapter outlines the current scope of services trade, and especially health services trade, within the
principal current RTAs. Section 2 considers the main motivations behind the negotiation of services RTAs,
the importance of reciprocity and discrimination in trade policy with respect to RTAs and the distinct
approaches adopted between RTAs with respect to scope, structure and modalities for liberalization, all
of which are relevant for health services trade. Section 3 then considers the extent and manner in which a
selection of specific RTAs covers and liberalizes trade in health-related services, before concluding in section 4.
62
Regional trade agreements and health services
However, pro-development outcomes are not guaranteed by services trade liberalization at either the
multilateral level or at the regional level as certain preconditions must be in place in order to generate
benefits. Most important among these is that liberalization be adequately paced and sequenced, and
preceded by proper regulatory, institutional and policy frameworks (5). As proper pacing and sequencing
between domestic reform and international commitments is central for benefits to materialize, there is a
need for support to strengthen regulatory and institutional capacities in developing countries to ultimately
allow them to benefit from services trade liberalization.
Additional complexities arise from the multiplicity of forums where services trade liberalization is
negotiated. The interplay between multilateral and regional services liberalization processes creates
challenges as regards the pacing and sequencing of the different liberalization processes. Indeed, trade
liberalization may be classified into types based upon whether it is mandated through negotiated
liberalization commitments on a reciprocal basis or a unilateral basis, and whether it is discriminatory or
non-discriminatory, as illustrated in Table 6.1.
63
Regional trade agreements and health services
Different RTAs adopt different approaches to services liberalization. It is therefore necessary when assessing
the extent to which RTAs have effectively liberalized trade in services – including health services – to
examine both the services regime (framework agreement) and the commitments under it. The framework
agreement can go beyond liberalization in the sense of market access and national treatment, and also
include provisions on investment, integration of labour markets, government procurement, and reciprocal
recognition of foreign licences (such as a license to practice medicine) and qualifications. Furthermore,
numerous RTAs include sectoral initiatives for specific services sectors (6), though these cover mostly
financial services, transport (air, maritime and land), telecommunications, professional services and mode 4
trade (movement of natural persons). The last two, professional and mode 4, are clearly relevant for health
services.
6.2.2 Scope, structure, modalities, commitments and regulatory cooperation
RTAs vary as to scope, structure, modalities for liberalization, depth of commitments, and regulatory
cooperation, all of which are relevant to health services trade (3, 7).
RTA scope (sectoral and modal coverage)
RTAs tend to provide for universal sectoral coverage, although sensitive sectors such as air and maritime
transport and audiovisual services may frequently be excluded.4 In addition, some RTAs may establish
specific rules for certain services sectors (for example financial, telecommunications). While some RTAs
exclude “public services”, it seems that no RTA generally excludes health services from its sectoral coverage
(8). In fact, the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) has identified health services as one of its
twelve priority sectors;5 the Southern African Development Community (SADC), on the other hand, does not
include health services among the six priority sectors identified for liberalization.6
RTA structure
The “four modes” for delivering services defined in GATS Article I.2 have become a part of many RTAs,
including those of the Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), SADC, ASEAN, the
Andean Community, and Mercosur. However, other RTAs provide for separate treatment of investment (for
example the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)) and movement of persons (NAFTA, Australia-
Thailand Free Trade Agreement) (6, 7, 9).
RTA liberalization modalities
RTAs tend to follow either a negative or a positive list approach.7 The negative list approach begins with
a general rule that all RTA obligations apply across all sectors, but allows countries to exclude certain
sectors and modes of supply by specifically enumerating them in a list of exceptions. Restrictions that are
not initially eliminated may be subject to negotiated elimination, sometimes combined with a so-called
“ratchet mechanism”, which automatically integrates further liberalization into the agreement (10). Under
the positive list approach, in contrast, countries affirmatively list those sectors and modes of supply in
which they would like to commit to liberalization. In theory, both approaches can provide the same level
of liberalization. The positive list approach, however, provides greater flexibility in designing the scope
and pace of liberalization commitments and it is considered to be the preferred choice for developing
countries, particularly when it comes to North–South but also South–South liberalization (3). The positive
list approach was adopted in the EU–Chile, ASEAN, Mercosur, Central American Common Market, Japan-
Singapore and United States-Jordan agreements. The negative list approach has been adopted in a number
of NAFTA-type RTAs, as well as in the agreement between Canada and the Caribbean Community and
Common Market (CARICOM). In discussions on whether or not to cover services in economic partnership
agreements between the European Union and the African, Caribbean and Pacific Group of States (ACP), the
choice between positive and negative listing received great attention. Figure 6.7 provides an illustration of
negative and positive listing approaches taken in the East Asian region.
4
Note however, that some RTAs, particularly in the Latin American area, do include detailed rules on maritime transport.
5
See ASEAN economic community blueprint 21 & 36 (http://www.asean.org/archive/5187-10.pdf ).
6
The six SADC priority sectors whose liberalization has been under negotiation since 2011 are: communication; construction; energy; financial; tourism; and
transport. See http://www.sadc.int/themes/economic-development/trade-services/
7
Some refer to GATS as reflecting a hybrid approach, which combines aspects from positive listing (choosing sectors and modes that will be subject to liber-
alization commitments) and negative listing (choosing sectors and modes to exclude from liberalization commitments).
65
Regional trade agreements and health services
Figure 6.7 Classification of East Asian free trade agreements by scheduling approach
66
Regional trade agreements and health services
8
Both the scheduling and counting of commitments and reservations are subject to numerous choices, according to different interpretations of the respec-
tive agreement’s texts, lists of commitments and reservations, and the specific language therein. For methodological difficulties regarding the recording of
numbers, nature and sectoral incidence of reservations across agreements; see United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (11).
9
Services trade liberalization is mandated by Article 79 of the Cartagena Agreement.
10
Liberalization in the financial and some audiovisual services sector has been suspended by decisions 694, 696, 718 and 772. See http://www.comunidadan-
dina.org/Documentos.aspx#
11
“Schedules” are documents attached to a treaty in which additional information or party commitments or reservations are provided.
12
“Reservations” are unilateral statements made by a party when signing or acceding to a treaty whereby the party purports to exclude (or modify the legal
effect of ) certain provisions of the treaty; in lay terms, reservations are exceptions to a treaty. See Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties, Article 2(d).
67
Regional trade agreements and health services
6.3.2 Mercosur
In 1991, Mercosur countries (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay) signed the Treaty of Asunción,
according to which they pursue regional integration to accelerate economic development and social justice.
In 1997 Members of Mercosur adopted the Montevideo Protocol, which sets out a framework agreement
on trade in services with a positive list approach to liberalization. The Montevideo Protocol obligates
Member States to enter into successive annual rounds of negotiations in order to extend liberalization to
different services sectors and modes of trade. In 1998 the Protocol was complemented by four annexes, and
Members launched the first annual negotiation round. As a result of this and subsequent negotiations, new
commitments have been progressively incorporated into national schedules under the Protocol and now
go beyond what is required by GATS. The Protocol has been ratified by Argentina, Brazil and Uruguay, and
entered into force in 2005. Mercosur uses a mixed GATS-type approach that allows for the scheduling (i.e.
the promising by inscription in a “schedule” attached to the treaty) of market access and national treatment
commitments, as well as the scheduling of conditions and limitations attached to these commitments.
Mercosur contains specific regimes for particular services sectors (professional, telecommunications,
tourism, financial and transport) and modes (mode 4 and investment). Efforts are also being developed
to create a regulatory framework (good practices, technical regulations and others) envisioning the
harmonisation of the organization and provision of health services. Moreover, although the Montevideo
Protocol does not specifically address health-related services, its treatment of professional services (Article
XI) would govern some health-related services. Overall, the Mercosur region is characterized by a low
degree of regulatory harmonization. While national health systems differ considerably, selected regional
cooperation initiatives have taken place (for example a standard card allowing patients to receive health
care services in one country can be used to receive health care from an analogous health services provider
in another Mercosur country).
68
Regional trade agreements and health services
Through the annual rounds of negotiations, Mercosur Members entered into a considerable number of
liberalization commitments, which exhibit a certain pattern across Members and sectors, as illustrated in
Box 6.2. For example, under professional services, member countries committed 11 subsectors each (with
Argentina and Uruguay providing additional disaggregation), of which several relate to health.13 In addition,
under health and social services, each of these four countries committed three subsectors (hospital, other
human health and social services), with Paraguay also committing “other health services”.
Countries committed medical and dental services; veterinary services; deliveries and related services, nursing services, physiotherapeutic and paramedical
13
services. Argentina and Brazil also committed to psychology and pharmacy services and Uruguay to pharmacy services. Although Paraguay and Uruguay do
not make explicit reference to psychology services, as Paraguay does not make explicit reference to pharmacy services, these countries are also committing
to other health professional services.
69
Regional trade agreements and health services
Similarly to the Andean Community situation, none of the four Mercosur Members analysed included
a public services “carve-out” in its schedule; similarly, there are no provisions addressing health-related
subsidies. At the same time, the commitments reflect careful drafting, with schedules leaving adequate
flexibility for domestic policy-makers. Particularly for mode 1 (the cross-border provision of health services)
countries have left it unbound, or unbound for lack of technical feasibility, or specifically mention that the
mode is unbound for the lack of regulatory frameworks (in the case of Argentina, for certain professional
services). All the countries analysed tend to fully liberalize mode 2 for health services, possibly aiming to
capitalize on health tourism services. In sum, the schedules appear to reflect Members’ desire for flexibility
— as provided by the positive list approach — to carefully pick and choose commitments in these sectors
and modes where liberalization promises to be beneficial to them.
6.3.3 CAFTA-DR
The free trade agreement between the United States and Central American countries was concluded in
December 2003 after 12 months of negotiation involving Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras,
Nicaragua and the United States. The Dominican Republic became an additional party in August 2004,
creating the Dominican Republic-Central America-United States Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA-DR).
CAFTA-DR adopts the model typically used in free trade agreements to which the United States is
a party. That is, it seeks to achieve comprehensive trade liberalization through numerous chapters
on agriculture, sanitary and phytosanitary measures, technical barriers to trade, trade remedies,
government procurement, investment, trade in services, financial services, telecommunications
services, electronic commerce, intellectual property, labour and the environment.
The services chapter is also typical, with provisions on national treatment, most-favoured-nation
treatment, market access, local presence, transparency and domestic regulation. The services chapter
(Chapter 11) also contains a provision on mutual recognition (partly modeled on GATS), as well as an
annex on professional services (Annex 11.9), focusing on the development of professional licensing
standards. While the services chapter also contains a provision on domestic regulation, this provision is
largely modeled on GATS and stops short of harmonizing regulatory standards.
While CAFTA-DR’s provisions on intellectual property rights (Chapter 15) have given rise to intensive
policy debates about their potential health impacts, liberalization of health-related services has gone
almost unnoticed.
Reservations with respect to both services (Chapter 11) and investment (Chapter 10) are set out in
a single list. Reservations for both chapters are scheduled under two annexes: Annex I allows the
scheduling of reservations for existing measures related to national treatment, most-favoured-nation,
local presence, performance requirements, nationality of senior management or members of boards of
directors, and market access; Annex II allows the scheduling of reservations for future measures related
to these areas.
Among all services sectors, professional services stand out with the highest number of reservations,
particularly for Annex I (for example 46 in the case of Costa Rica, 7 for El Salvador and 9 for Honduras).
Professional services are followed by financial services, with a particular focus on banking services (with
reservations under annex III).
Several of the entries in Annex I also relate to health, with Costa Rica and the Dominican Republic
listing several health-specific reservations, as outlined in Box 6.3. Guatemala and Nicaragua do not
specify any health-specific reservations (although there is a reciprocity requirement for professional
services in Nicaragua that may impact health services providers). El Salvador, has one health-specific
reservation (a detailed authorization regime for temporary and permanent work) and Honduras
imposes higher registration fees in professional bodies for non Central American veterinarians, for
foreign microbiologists and foreign clinical chemists.
70
Regional trade agreements and health services
The United States contains one health-specific reservation, however, another reservation effectively
carves out all existing sub-federal measures (i.e. laws of a state or locality of the United States, as
opposed to the laws of the United States federal government) in all sectors from the application of the
agreement.14
Several of the reservations made to CAFTA-DR appear to be targeted towards the organization of
the labour market, particularly for those countries having few reservations. Some of the reservations
inscribed by Costa Rica and the Dominican Republic, in turn, appear to be directly influenced
by health policy objectives (for example Costa Rica requires all physicians and surgeons, dental
surgeons, microbiologists, pharmacists, nurses and nutritionists to perform the equivalent of one-year
continuous, remunerated “social service”. This reservation allows Costa Rican nationals to be given
certain types of preference (see box 6.3)).
More importantly, however, most CAFTA-DR countries15 include some sort of public services carve-out
in their lists of reservations on Annex II. The United States, for example, reserves the “right to adopt
or maintain any measure with respect to the provision of . . . the following services to the extent they
are social services established or maintained for a public purpose: income security or insurance, social
security or insurance, social welfare, public education, public training, health, and child care”.16 Costa
Rica specifically includes a carve-out for water services. Honduras also adds on Annex II a reservation
regarding the obligatory membership in a professional association of chemists or pharmacists. These
reservations point to conscious decision-making regarding the potential health implications of
opening up health-related services sectors.
Finally, the schedules of CAFTA-DR exhibit certain differences across countries. The lists of reservations
of Costa Rica and the Dominican Republic stand out for their high level of detail in health-specific
measures. This raises the question of whether these differences in schedules reflect differences in the
countries’ health systems and respective measures pursuing health policy objectives, or are due to
differing technical and negotiating capabilities and resources deployed in the negotiating process.
14
More specifically, this reservation applies to all sectors, to all five possible obligations concerned and refers to “all existing non-conforming measures of all
states of the US, the District of Columbia, and Puerto Rico”.
15
Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Honduras, Nicaragua and the United States.
16
This text is quoted from the United States schedule; similar language can be found in the schedules of the other five countries.
71
Regional trade agreements and health services
Box 6.3 Health-related reservations in CAFTA-DR schedules: examples from Costa Rica
and the Dominican Republic
Both Costa Rica and the Dominican Republic include numerous health-specific reservations in their
schedules.
Costa Rica’s health-specific reservations relate to:
• its laws for health-related professional bodies (for example those of pharmacists,
physicians and surgeons, veterinarians, nurses, dental surgeons, medical and surgical
technicians, optometrists, psychologists and chiropractors), including reciprocity
requirements for membership in most of these professional bodies;
• residency requirements (pharmacists, physicians and surgeons, veterinarians, dental
surgeons, medical and surgical technicians, and nurses);
• obligatory (although it can be waived for temporary professional practice),
remunerated “social service” (one continuous year); the slots for such services are
allocated by lottery with certain preferences given to nationals (doctors, dental
surgeons, microbiologists, pharmacists, nurses, and nutritionists).
The Dominican Republic’s health-specific reservations:
• allow foreign nationals that graduated from foreign universities to practice in the
Dominican Republic if all of the following criteria are present: (a) there is a reciprocal
agreement between the relevant governments allowing professionals to practice
in both countries (b) the service is not offered or is insufficient in the Dominican
Republic and (c) the foreigner has the degree certified for equivalency by the
appropriate agency within the Dominican Republic;
• allow foreign health professionals to practice in the Dominican Republic on a non-
profit basis, if authorized by the Dominican Ministry of Health (SESPAS), and in some
cases on a for-profit, temporary basis;
• impose residency requirements for the practice of psychology;
• require pharmacies, drug stores and industrial pharmaceutical laboratories to be at
least 500 metres from each other.
6.3.4 SADC
Regional cooperation of the Southern African Development Community (SADC) was formalized in 1992
through the Windhoek Treaty, which aims to promote a genuine and equitable regional integration.
As of 2012, Members of SADC include Angola, Botswana, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Lesotho,
Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Seychelles, South Africa, Swaziland, United Republic
of Tanzania, Zambia and Zimbabwe. Since 1996, SADC countries have embarked on a process of trade
negotiations aimed at gradually liberalizing their markets and eventually creating a common market with a
common currency.17
In 2009, SADC ministers of trade adopted a framework Protocol on Trade in Services, which was signed by
the Heads of State in August 2012. The protocol adopts a positive list approach, which will be implemented
through follow-up negotiations. Six sectors have been earmarked for priority liberalization: communication,
construction, energy, finance, tourism and transport. The list of sectors subject to liberalization negotiations
can be expanded in the future.
The SADC Protocol on Trade in Services pursues services integration with a view to: achieving the
harmonious, balanced and equitable development of the region; ensuring progress and the well-being of
http://www.sadc.int/about-sadc/integration-milestones/. All SADC countries except the Seychelles became WTO Members between 1995 and 1997.
17
72
Regional trade agreements and health services
the people of southern Africa through poverty alleviation, with the ultimate objective of its eradication; and
achieving sustainable development and meeting the challenges of globalization.
The protocol places great emphasis on achieving coherence and generating synergies with other SADC
services protocols, including the SADC Protocol on Health. The SADC Protocol on Health offers examples
of specifically health-related cooperation, including by aiming to: coordinate regional efforts on epidemic
preparedness, mapping, prevention, control and where possible the eradication of communicable and
non-communicable diseases; facilitate the establishment of a mechanism for the referral of patients for
tertiary care; promote and coordinate laboratory services; and collaborate with other relevant SADC sectors.
The activities have been set in motion, with implementation plans and several projects, including the
development of a health implementation plan and a project on reversing the “brain drain” in the health
sector from the SADC region to other countries. Under this project, the SADC secretariat has mobilized
resources for the development of policy guidelines to attract and retain health care professionals in the
public sector.
6.3.5 ASEAN
ASEAN Members (Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, Indonesia, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Malaysia,
Myanmar, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam) aim towards an ASEAN Economic Community
by 2015. In 1995, ASEAN Members signed the ASEAN Framework Agreement on Trade in Services. The
agreement adopts a positive list approach, and the long-term objective of eliminating restrictions on trade
in services is to be achieved through negotiating rounds. By 2012 eight packages of commitments had been
signed,18 including some coverage of health care services. These commitments are generally of a GATS-plus
nature (apart from mode 4, which is mostly at GATS level). Liberalization commitments are complemented
by mutual recognition arrangements19 and cooperative mechanisms.
Health services have been addressed by numerous initiatives. At the ninth ASEAN Summit in Bali, health
care was identified as one of 11 priority sectors for integration (12); at the tenth ASEAN Summit, health care
(together with the e-ASEAN initiative) was identified as a priority sector for advanced liberalization under
the ASEAN Framework Agreement for the Integration of Priority Sectors (13). The liberalization of such
priority sectors is advanced through the “ASEAN minus X” formula, which allows some countries to move
forward and enter into agreements, even if others are not yet ready to commit. The ASEAN Framework
Agreement on Services establishes that liberalization is to be complemented by mutual recognition
arrangements,20 and by 2009, arrangements had been signed with respect to nursing,21 the practice of
medicine22 and the practice of dental medicine.23
Upon closer scrutiny of the mutual recognition arrangements, it is revealed that they lack real and concrete
mutual recognition and might not meaningfully facilitate the movements of health professionals. For
example, nurses must have at least three years of work experience in the country of origin, a requirement
that effectively only facilitates the movement of experienced nurses (14).24 Similarly, medical and
dental practitioners must have at least five continuous years of work experience in their country of
origin. Moreover, the absence of complete liberalization affects not only the movement of health care
professionals, but also that of patients: Despite the importance of health care tourism in the region, further
integration to promote the portability of health insurance is lacking (13).
18
Protocol to implement the eighth package of commitments under the ASEAN Framework Agreement on Services, 28 October 2010 (http://www.asean.org/news/
item/protocol-to-implement-the-eighth-package-of-commitments-under-the-asean-framework-agreement-on-services).
19
Mutual recognition arrangements facilitate the recognition by one country of professional qualifications obtained in another country. Mutual recognition
focuses on professional services such as engineering, accountancy, architecture, surveying, medical and dental practitioners and nursing.
20
The agreement encourages Members to enter into further agreements to recognize education or experience obtained, requirements met or licences
granted in another ASEAN country.
21
ASEAN mutual recognition arrangement on nursing services, 8 December 2006 (http://www.asean.org/news/item/asean-mutual-recognition-arrangement-on-
nursing-services).
22
ASEAN mutual recognition arrangement on medical practitioners, 26 February 2009 (http://www.asean.org/news/item/asean-mutual-recognition-arrange-
ment-on-medical-practitioners-2).
23
ASEAN mutual recognition arrangement on dental practitioners, 26 February 2009 (http://www.asean.org/news/item/asean-mutual-recognition-arrangement-
on-dental-practitioners-2).
24
Interestingly, this requirement does not exist in any of the domestic laws and regulations of ASEAN countries.
73
Regional trade agreements and health services
The ASEAN process is also interesting from a coherence perspective. Meetings of ASEAN health ministers
or senior officials regularly refer to trade liberalization initiatives. In 2000, for example, the Declaration
on Healthy ASEAN 2020 called upon ASEAN to strengthen the national and collective ASEAN capacity on
issues of “health implications of globalization and trade liberalization”. In 2005, senior officials reiterated the
importance of urgently addressing the health impact of trade liberalization (including with regard to the
movement of service providers) and called for consultations with the respective services and investment
bodies (12). In 2012 ASEAN health ministers agreed that, in order to reduce tobacco consumption and
associated non-communicable diseases, tobacco must be withdrawn from the list of products scheduled to
be liberalized by 2015 within the ASEAN Free Trade Area.
6.4 Conclusions
An increasing number of RTAs cover services, including health-related services. Hence, health policy-
makers need to pay attention to the respective negotiation and implementation processes, with a view to
achieving coherence between trade and health policy objectives. RTAs pursue different approaches to the
liberalization of services and the attendant cooperative mechanisms, and frequently serve as laboratories
for innovative solutions. While regional liberalization of health and other services can generate pro-
development outcomes, such benefits are not automatic. Instead, liberalization needs to be properly paced
and sequenced with the development of adequate regulatory, institutional and policy frameworks.
At a broader level, there is a need to manage the interface between regional and multilateral services trade
liberalization and to properly design the relationship between South–South and North–South liberalization.
Given the nascent stage of the services sectors in developing countries, the implications for those sectors of
North–South reciprocal market openings in services need to be carefully assessed.
Cooperative mechanisms can offer an important contribution to making regional trade liberalization of
services contribute to development, particularly in the areas of health care and social services. A type of
cooperation that is essential from a development perspective is one which aims to enhance regulatory
development and institution building (for example financing, technical assistance, regular information
exchange and meetings, and partnerships between institutions and other collaborative projects).
Cooperation can also cover infrastructure services or support institution building or supply capacity
building. Cooperation in this area is important because improved infrastructure is a central requirement for
the efficient delivery of health care services.
Effective cooperation should be implemented over a sustained period of time prior to liberalization.
Although North–South RTAs often provide for cooperative mechanisms, the effectiveness of these
mechanisms continues to be at the forefront of regional discussions in developing regions.
74
Regional trade agreements and health services
References
1. Services, development and trade: The regulatory and institutional dimension, Note by UNCTAD
Secretariat, TD/B/C.1/MEM.4/5, forthcoming.
2. Dihel N, Eschenbach F, Shepherd B. South–South services trade. OECD Trade Policy Working Paper 39.
Paris, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2006.
4. Lesher M, Miroudot S. Analysis of the economic impact of investment provisions in regional trade
agreements. OECD Trade Policy Working Paper 36. Paris, Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development, 2006.
6. The shift towards services: World Investment Report 2004. New York and Geneva, United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development, 2004.
7. Fink C, Molinuevo M. East Asian free trade agreements in services: roaring tigers or timid pandas?
Trade Issues in East Asia. World Bank, East Asia and Pacific Region Poverty Reduction and Economic
Management, 2007.
8. Mashayekhi M, Tuerk E. Strategic considerations for developing countries: the case of GATS and
health services. In: Blouin C, Drager N, Smith R, eds. International trade in health services and the GATS:
current issues and debates. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2005.
9. Houde MF, Akshay K, Miroudot S. The interaction between investment and services chapters in selected
regional trade agreements. Working Paper. Paris, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development, 2007.
10. Preserving flexibility in IIAs: the use of reservations. Series on International Investment Policies for
Development. Geneva, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 2006.
11. Lim H, Marchetti J, Roy M. Services liberalization in the new generation of preferential trade
agreements (PTAs): how much further than the GATS? Working Paper. Geneva, World Trade
Organization, 2006.
12. Fink C, Arunanondchai J. Trade in health services in the ASEAN region. Health Promotion
International, 2006, 21(Suppl. 1):59–66.
13. Philavong B. ASEAN cooperation on trade in health services. Presentation at Prince Mahidol Award
Conference, 30 January to 1 February 2008, Bangkok.
14. Pachanee C, Wibulpolprasert S. Trade in health services in the ASEAN context. In: Blouin C, Heymann
J, Drager N, eds. Trade and health: seeking common ground. Montreal, McGill-Queen’s University
Press, 2007.
75
Trade in health services
Chapter 7
7.1 Introduction
This chapter outlines the current trends and issues with regard to trade in health (and health-related)
services, giving particular attention to domestic regulation in the context of this trading environment.1
Given that existing literature already provides substantial coverage of certain aspects of trade in health
services, as well as a comprehensive and widely available framework specifically focused upon health
services trade (1), this chapter’s added value lies primarily in its focused consideration of regulatory issues.
The chapter starts with a brief review of the key characteristics of the trade policy environment within which
the interface between services, trade and health has been approached (2, 3). This is followed by an overview
of possible benefits and risks to national health systems associated with the liberalization of trade in health
services. The chapter then focuses on how to conduct a trade-related regulatory audit with a view to better
understanding how domestic regulation related to health services can affect international trade in health
services, how international trade agreements can affect domestic regulatory space in the health sector, and
how to design more coherent policies in the areas of trade and health. It also incorporates a series of specific
case studies.
1
Health (and health-related) services will be referred to simply as “health services” throughout this chapter. The World Trade Organization’s General Agree-
ment on Trade in Services divides all services into 12 categories, of which four contain health and health-related services (business, communication, finan-
cial and health-related and social services). The definition of health services used in this chapter comprises all services, in the four categories, pertaining to
health care.
2
These four Modes of supplying services are defined in Article I of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). See Chapter 6.
76
Trade in health services
It is worthy to note from the outset that trade and investment agreements typically do not cover “services
supplied in the exercise of governmental authority” (GATS Article I). Under GATS (and most PTAs), services
that fall under the “exercise of governmental authority” are defined as services “supplied neither on a
commercial basis, nor in competition with one or more service suppliers” in the domestic market. This
implies that countries have carved out a regulatory space that shields domestic regulatory measures from
the reach of trade and investment provisions in sectors characterized by significant public good attributes
such as in the fields of public health, public education or national defense. In addition, the GATS allows WTO
Members to attach limitations to their commitments in order to preserve the right to implement measures
inconsistent with full market access or national treatment obligations. Much the same leeway is afforded to
PTA signatories.
However, the notion of “services supplied in the exercise of governmental authority” is seldom defined
in trade and investment agreements. In part, this reflects the fact that countries differ markedly in their
collective preferences and the degree to which the responsibility of service provision is entrusted to the
public sector. The above discussion is of potentially great significance in considering whether, how and
to what extent domestic regulatory conduct in the health sector can be affected by trade and investment
agreements.
It is also noteworthy that relatively few WTO Members have made commitments with respect to health and
social services, compared to the number of Members having made commitments in other service sectors.
Figure 7.1 reveals how, alongside education with which it shares several policy sensitivities, the health sector
ranks among the least committed of all major service sectors covered by the GATS. The data in Table 7.1
confirm such trends, showing that only 56 of the WTO’s 160 Members have to date scheduled commitments
in health services, just over a third of the membership (35%), representing the lowest coverage ratio of all
sectors and connoting a keen desire for the preservation of policy space in the formulation of health care
policies. Such a trend is also broadly seen at the PTA level despite the greater overall level of market opening
achieved in the health field under the latter agreements.
Moreover, even where WTO Members do undertake commitments, it should be kept in mind that such
commitments do not necessarily entail full market access, but can be limited in scope and retain existing
restrictive practices. Conversely, WTO Members can engage in trade in health services even if they have not
made any commitments under GATS.
To date, low-income economies have limited scope for trading health services, due to the combination of
acute resource constraints (particularly human resources) in health care and poor health care infrastructure.
Thus, commitments pertaining to trade and investment in health services have been undertaken
predominantly by middle-income and developed countries. However, regardless of development levels,
very few countries have to date assigned a significant role to trade and investment policy in managing or
shaping the development of the health sector (4–7).
77
Trade in health services
Figure 7.1 Sectoral distribution of market access commitments under the GATS
Note: Figure 7.1 lists the service sectors in accordance with the classification system used under the GATS. Such a classification does
not correspond to the definition of health services used in this chapter (see Footnote 1).
78
Trade in health services
*The European Union commitments reflected as one schedule in this table are those of the EC-12.
Source: WTO-World Bank I-TIP Services database, June 2015.
Despite the above caveats, the overall level of negotiating activity and policy engagement in health
services trade and investment is growing, due to several factors. On the demand side, demographic change
(particularly population ageing) is occurring in both developed and developing countries, and the resulting
increase in demand for the services of health care professionals must contend with pressures to contain
health budgets and the scope trade offers to alleviate such costs in some instances. On the supply side,
new technologies are facilitating the remote supply of an increasing range of health services (including
to isolated populations in developing countries). In addition, there has been a continued liberalization
of cross-border investment in health-related services, indeed the emergence of multinational health
care firms, several of which originate in developing countries. Moreover, the sector continues to witness
significant doses of cross-border mobility of health care professionals. As with many other sectors, progress
in addressing trade and investment in health services has also tended to proceed more extensively under
PTAs than at the WTO level. This can be seen in Table 7.2, which calculates implicit margins of preference
across major service sectors flowing from the greater liberalization achieved under preferential agreements
relative to the GATS and the latest negotiating offers made in the Doha Round (8). On an index scale that
runs from 0 to 100, the level of liberalization achieved in health services in the most liberal PTA (34) is more
than four times that observed in the GATS (9). This implies relatively high derived preference margins in
the sector, reaching 76% in the PTA that has achieved the greatest degree of market opening in the health
sector. It bears recalling, however, that such preference margins originate in a sector that shows, as under
the WTO, the lowest absolute level of preferential liberalization.
79
Trade in health services
A growing number of developing countries, particularly middle- and higher-income developing countries,
today regard health services, especially those that can be combined with tourism-related activities, as a
potentially significant source of foreign exchange earnings, foreign investment and skills upgrading, which
ultimately might contribute to economic growth and development. Several such countries are devoting
significant policy attention to building health-related export clusters, with some having developed targeted
trade and investment promotion strategies in the sector.
Although the health sector received the fewest overall commitments (market access and national
treatment) in the Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations (1986–1994) and in subsequent
negotiations regarding accession to the WTO, the increasing profile of trade in health services reflects the
importance of appropriate domestic regulation combined with effective institutional and enforcement
capacities.
80
Trade in health services
81
Trade in health services
Medical transcription is the process of writing down (or encoding electronically) the oral dictation of
health professionals regarding patient treatment, diagnosis, etc. Outsourcing from the United States
has been the main driver of the global medical transcription business. Since the entry into force of
the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of 1996 (“HIPAA”, which requires businesses to
safeguard private medical data), the demand for medical transcription services in the United States has
expanded rapidly, growing at an estimated 20% per year, coupled with a 10% per year decline in the
number of transcriptionists in the United States .
The first large medical transcription company, Outsource Transcription Philippines, was founded
in the late 1990s. As the third-largest English-speaking nation in the world, with a large workforce,
94% literacy rate and a strategic location with an ideal 12-hour time difference from the east coast
of the United States, the Philippines possesses key inherent advantages as a “first-choice [medical
transcription] outsourcing destination” for advanced country institutions (Business World Philippines ).
Medical transcription is one of the five subsectors identified by the Philippines Department of Trade
and Industry in its campaign to promote the country as a global hub for outsourced information
technology (IT)-enabled services (12). The government of the Philippines has lent strong support to
the medical transcription industry by implementing an e-commerce law, adopting the Data Privacy Act
(2012) and setting up the Information Technology and Electronic Commerce Council. The government
has also aided in developing and expanding the IT infrastructure of the country. These efforts
have borne fruit as medical transcription outsourcing to the Philippines has over the past decade
experienced the fastest growth among all outsourcing sectors in the Philippines.
Despite this growth, the Philippines’ market share is still quite small compared to the potential market
size. Prospects for further rapid growth remain bright, given the anticipated surge in outsourcing as
hospitals in developed countries have yet to convert records into electronic formats as is increasingly
required by law, and in light of future reforms that are expected to promote greater use of IT in health
care management. Furthermore, the vast majority of companies exporting these services from the
Philippines are owned by investors from the OECD area. Hence the expectation is that, as the benefits
of outsourcing are more fully understood, the Philippines will be well positioned to benefit from
outsourcing of other aspects of health-related administrative operations. Privacy concerns have so far
not inhibited outsourcing from the United States to the Philippines. Patient information is protected
though service contracts between importing hospitals in the United States and exporting transcription
companies in the Philippines.
According to one estimate, the United States health care system could save up to US$ 1.4 billion annually
if only one in ten patients were to go abroad for a limited set of 15 highly tradable, low-risk treatments
(13). However, a significant limitation to medical travel is that of insurance portability across borders (see
Box 7.2). In addition, some critics of “medical tourism” question whether the quality of health services
procured abroad would be adequate, or whether the risk of substandard care procured abroad might
actually increase costs to the importing country, for example if patients return home disabled or in need of
corrective treatment. Recourse to mutual recognition procedures and the certification of quality standards
thus assume crucial importance in the context of this Mode of service supply.
Box 7.2 Medical travel and the portability of medical insurance coverage
One of the most significant barriers to health services exports under Mode 2 (medical travel) is the
lack of portability of health insurance overseas. Even where opportunities for cost savings exist, the
absence of an insurance framework that covers treatments received overseas limits the potential gains
that can arise from medical travel. Two of the most obvious concerns insurers have about extending
coverage overseas are the quality of treatment in foreign hospitals and the potential for higher costs
arising from possible follow-up treatments.
The first concern is increasingly allayed by quality signaling through accreditation, the presence of
a growing number of health care professionals at hospitals in developing countries that have been
trained in developed countries, and international collaboration agreements between reputable
medical establishments. The second concern, (the cost of follow-up treatments) can be addressed
through increased collaboration among global networks of hospitals and medical facilities and by
limiting the list of treatments eligible for coverage overseas.
However, there may be further reasons that prevent insurers from extending coverage abroad: insurers
may face high costs of monitoring care received overseas; where coverage is provided by public health
schemes, institutional impediments might be significant. For instance, allowing participation of foreign
providers in government-controlled schemes would require changes to social security laws. Despite
these impediments, promising examples of cross-border health insurance coverage can be cited. For
instance, Tricare covers both emergency and non-emergency care for both active-duty and retired
United States military personnel and their families, for treatment received while stationed overseas.
Some multinational corporations and international organizations such as the World Bank also offer
plans that reimburse employees for both emergency and non-emergency care received abroad. These
plans treat overseas providers as “out of network”, which results in higher out-of-pocket employee
co-payment.
The potential risks of Mode 2 trade are similar to those noted above for cross-border supply (Mode 1). The
development of Mode 2 trade activities geared towards foreign consumers of health care services may
attract scarce human resources away from health care institutions that serve the local population. It might
also increase local prices due to the rise in demand and thus reduce access for the local population; and
public investment might be reallocated to provide high-quality health to foreign patients, to the detriment
of the health care needs of poorer segments of the host country population. These negative effects might
be mitigated in the medium- to long-term by a supply-side response, such as an increase in foreign direct
investment or the expansion of education and training of health care professionals.
83
Trade in health services
Several countries are actively seeking to attract a greater number of medical travellers and health-
related tourists. Three of the top six destinations for medical travel in the world today can be found in the
Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) region: Malaysia, Singapore and Thailand. Much of this
trade involves patients from other ASEAN countries. Similarly, Cuba is a long-standing hub for foreign
patients from countries in South and North America and the Caribbean, whilst Jordan has long been
referred to as the “medical centre of the Arab world” (14) (see Box 7.3), though its positon as regional leader
has in recent years been increasingly challenged by new suppliers established in the Arabic peninsula (e.g.
Dubai in the United Arab Emirates, and Qatar).
Due to the high quality of medical services provided, Arab patients started visiting Jordan for medical
treatment as early as the 1970s. In the 1990s, Jordan began to consciously promote its health services
exports. In 1998, the Ministry of Health established an office at the Queen Alia Airport to facilitate the
entry of foreign patients (15).
While Jordan has invested in upgrading and modernizing its public hospitals and medical schools,
it is Jordan’s private sector hospitals that dominate the market for medical travel. The private sector
accounts for 54% of the hospitals in the country and 46% of available beds. Jordan’s private hospitals
are state of the art and many have links with renowned hospitals and medical centres in Europe and
North America.
The Jordanian experience highlights the importance of public–private collaboration. A special
directorate, established by the government in partnership with the private sector, lays out the vision
and strategy for promoting medical travel to Jordan. The vast majority of foreign patients in Jordan
come from the Arab world, mainly Bahrain, Libya, Saudi Arabia, Sudan, Syrian Arab Republic, West Bank
and Gaza Strip, Yemen and others. The majority of patients seek treatment in cardiology, neurology,
bone disease and other internal diseases.
Medical travel to Jordan further highlights the importance of bilateral relationships and protocols
between sending and receiving countries. As in the case of Cuba and a few Asian health service
exporters, some of the patients coming to Jordan enjoy the coverage of home country medical
insurance funds. For instance, a protocol was signed between Jordan and the Algerian Social Security
Fund, with the terms of payment for treatment in Jordan linked to the Algerian social security system.
Jordan has medical cooperation protocols with several other countries, while private sector hospitals
have their own agreements with governments and private clients in foreign countries (15).
While the Jordanian Ministry of Health plays a limited role in trade policy formulation, it is notable
that the Ministry is represented at the Jordan Investment Board and actively functions on the board in
matters related to the health sector. Success in the promotion of medical travel has prompted Jordan
to create incentives for national and foreign private investment in the health sector.
However, Jordan is facing stiff competition in the medical travel sector from countries in the Gulf
region, such as the United Arab Emirates, as well as from Lebanon and Tunisia. There has been a large
recent inflow of foreign patients into Lebanon, with the majority coming from Gulf countries. The
American University of Beirut Medical Center attracts a large share of foreign patients to the country.
The Lebanese Ministry of Health has established a joint commission to promote “medical tourism”
and an independent company was designated to promote medical travel on behalf of participating
hospitals.
84
Trade in health services
Exclusions typically do not give governments the right to confiscate foreign investments or to breach certain other obligations when pursuing public health
3
objectives.
85
Trade in health services
A potential benefit of the movement of health care professionals via Mode 4 trade is the promotion of
knowledge spillovers, that is, the dissemination of clinical knowledge and skills among professionals.
Conversely, a potential drawback of Mode 4 trade is that temporary mobility may encourage movement of
a more permanent nature, such that health care professionals needed domestically, and often trained at
considerable local cost, depart from their home country (the so-called “brain drain” problem).
86
Trade in health services
Liberalization of services markets often necessitates regulatory reform, which in turn involves consideration
of a number of questions, including:
• Purpose: What is the purpose of the regulation, e.g. protecting consumers or the environment,
promoting competition, or ensuring universal access to a service?
• Design: Will the proposed regulation be effective in achieving its stated objective? If so, is it
the most efficient way to achieve the objective? Factors to consider may include whether the
regulation is reasonable, objective in its application and transparent, proportional to the ob-
jective being pursued, and linked to international standards.
• Implementation: How will the regulation be implemented? Are there transparent and im-
partial procedures for implementing the regulation? Can persons or entities affected by the
regulation provide input prior to its adoption? Do persons or entities adversely affected by the
regulation have any recourse? Do the relevant government agencies have the requisite skills,
financial resources and political legitimacy to implement the regulation?
• Evaluation: Has the regulation been effective? Have the expected outcomes been achieved?
What costs have been incurred in implementing the regulation? Are these costs reasonable
relative to the outcome? Which challenges had to be overcome?
Different countries may consider certain questions to be more pressing than others, or may wish to take
other factors into consideration. This can be a challenging process, in particular for developing countries
with limited administrative capacity and many countries requiring significant training and technical
assistance regarding the implementation of regulations following market opening.
Neither the GATS and nor PTAs prescribe the type of regulations that governments should enact in any
given sector. Instead, they allow countries to formulate their own regulations subject to the general
requirements that those regulations be non-discriminatory, proportional and transparent (see Box 7.4
above). In addition, such regulations should not constitute “disguised restrictions” to trade and investment.
GATS Article VI (and its PTA equivalents) addressing the issue of non-discriminatory domestic regulation
requires that, in those sectors or sub-sectors where specific commitments have been undertaken, all
measures be “administered in a reasonable, objective and impartial manner”. In addition, countries must
provide for the prompt judicial or administrative review of administrative decisions affecting trade in
services. (Article VI.2)
GATS Article VI also lays down specific rules on domestic regulation pertaining to qualification requirements
and procedures, technical standards and licensing requirements. The Agreement stipulates that domestic
regulations should not be devised in a way that nullifies or impairs the benefits that other treaty members
should reasonably expect in light of a country’s market-opening commitments. That is, a commitment to
open a market to foreign service providers will be of little commercial value if the qualification requirements
or procedures applied make it all but impossible for the foreign providers to deliver the services in question,
even if they are technically qualified to do so. Trade and investment agreements encourage countries to
regulate in a manner that, whenever feasible, is least restrictive to trade and investment (i.e. minimizes the
adverse effect on cross-border activity).
7.4.1 Important questions during negotiation of trade services
The process of negotiating services trade is both time consuming and information intensive. Questions that
may arise during the negotiation process include the following:
87
Trade in health services
• ensure that key policy objectives are met in the most efficient manner (that is, in a manner
that is least wasteful and distorting to trade and investment);
• identify antiquated or inefficient regulations and adopt international best practices;
• encourage, where feasible, the adoption of market access-friendly regulations;
• build trust within the government through whole-of-government dialogue and enhanced
inter-agency coordination;
• deepen dialogue between key government stakeholders (both regional and local), producers
and consumers.
One useful starting point for engaging in such an audit is to prepare a list of domestic regulations that, but
for country reservations (exceptions), would not conform to treaty obligations (e.g. national treatment,
market access and most-favoured-nation treatment). This list should include a comprehensive description of:
88
Trade in health services
• identify regulations in need of reform in order to harness the benefits and mitigate the nega-
tive impacts of trade liberalization;
• provide a comprehensive overview of the trade and investment-restrictive components of a
country’s regulatory regime;
• assess the continued need for trade or investment-restrictive regulations;
• identify measures that may be offered during negotiations for scheduling (i.e. incorporation)
into trade agreements;
• provide a complete inventory of existing discriminatory measures, which may help to antici-
pate partner country negotiating requests.
7.5 Conclusion
This chapter has provided a brief overview of the key elements of trade and investment regulation in health
services, including some of the main opportunities and risks arising from such trade, illustrated by various
country case studies. The chapter examined selected aspects related to regulation of the domestic health
sector within the context of increased liberalization of international trade in services, highlighting both
the policy space and the various benefits and challenges of liberalizing trade in health services in Modes 1
through 4. A brief discussion then followed of key aspects related to the conduct of a trade-related audit of
domestic regulation in the services sector and some of the benefits of such an audit.
The chapter has made clear that, for a variety of reasons, governments of both developed and developing
countries have generally adopted a policy stance imbued with significant regulatory precaution in
approaching the relationship between trade and investment liberalization and domestic health care
reforms. At the same time, many countries, particularly in the developing world, have been actively
promoting trade and cross-border investment in health services. While such promotion efforts have chiefly
taken the form of unilateral domestic reforms, international negotiations conducted along preferential lines
and other treaties increasingly feature discussions of – and liberalization commitments on – cross-border
trade and investment in health services.
By and large, governments opting to make binding international commitments on trade and investment in
health services enjoy considerable latitude in deciding on the nature, pace and extent of market opening.
International agreements generally include obligations to maintain transparency and to progressively
lift discriminatory and anti-competitive measures. Yet governments must fully grasp, in advance, the
likely effects of their policy choices. In addition, they should possess or develop sufficient technical
expertise at the interface of trade and health policy to allow for the effective implementation of trade and
investment policies that engage the health sector. A trade-related regulatory audit in the health sector
may be of considerable use in this regard. Such an audit may allow governments to understand their own
regulatory regimes, identify gaps in domestic regulation and regulatory implementation capacities, and
also anticipate the negotiating requests of trading partners. All of this can help a government assess the
country’s readiness to engage in legally binding commitments relating to the health sector and the benefits
(and downside risks) of assigning a more central role to trade and investment policy and international
negotiations in the conduct of health care policy.
90
Trade in health services
References
1. Chanda R and RDSmith. Trade in health services and GATS: a framework for policy makers. In: Blouin
C, Drager N, Smith RD, eds. International trade in health services and the GATS: current issues and
debates. Washington DC, World Bank, 2005: appendix.
2. Blouin C, Drager N, Smith RD, eds. International trade in health services and the GATS: current issues
and debates. Washington DC, World Bank, 2005.
4. Lautier M. Les exportations de services de santé des pays en développement: le cas tunisien. Notes
and Documents No. 25. Agence Française de Développement, 2005.
5. Mackintosh M, Koivusalo M. Health systems and commercialization: in search of good sense. In:
Mackintosh M, Koivusalo M, eds. Commercialization of health care: global and local dynamics and
policy responses. Houndmills, Palgrave Macmillan, 2006.
6. Holden C. Privatization and trade in health services: a review of the evidence. International Journal of
Health Services, 2005, 35:675–689.
7. Smith R. Foreign direct investment and trade in health services: a review of the literature. Social
Science and Medicine, 2004, 59:2313–2323.
8. Sauvé, P. and A. Shingal (2011), “Reflections on the Preferential Liberalization of Services Trade”, in
Journal of World Trade, Vol. 45, No. 5, pp. 953-63.
9. Chanda R. Trade in health services. Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 2002, 80:158–163.
10. Mitra S. Medical tourism: the way to go. Health Care Market Insights. Frost and Sullivan, 2007.
11. Fink C and J.Arunanondchai J. Trade in health services in the ASEAN region. Health Promotion
International, 2006, 21(Suppl. 1):59–66.
12. Rodolfo CS. Expanding RP-US linkages in business process outsourcing. Discussion Paper. Manila,
Philippines Institute for Development Studies, 2006.
13. Mattoo A, Rathindran R. Does health insurance impede trade in health care services? Policy Research
Working Paper 3667. Washington DC, World Bank, 2005.
14. Chanda R. Trade in health services. Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, Working Group 4,
Working Paper 5. Geneva, World Health Organization, 2001.
15. Trade in health services: case study on Jordan. Cairo, World Health Organization Regional Office for the
Eastern Mediterranean, 2004.
91
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Chapter 8
8.1 Introduction
By its very nature, liberalizing food trade facilitates trade in food products and services across national
borders. Measures included in trade agreements also enhance the ability of the large-scale private
agro-food industry to conduct business transnationally and expand in countries previously dominated
by small-scale production and retail. Through these processes, trade liberalization has the potential to
influence food-related nutrition and health issues. The pathways of impact are broadly conceptualized in
Figure 8.1. Measures designed to liberalize trade influence the entire food supply chain. Changes along
the food supply chain then influence the environment in which consumers make food choices i.e., the
availability of foodstuffs (amount, type and nutritional quality), the safety of that food, what it costs, and
how it is marketed. These factors, established as important components of national and household food
security, influence the choices people make about the food they eat. These affect the diets of consumers
and, therefore the prevalence of foodborne diseases, undernutrition, and obesity and diet-related non-
communicable diseases (DR-NCDs).
In addition to these links, there are a range of indirect effects through which trade liberalization could affect
human nutrition and health. These include the effects on household incomes, and the inadvertent entry of
emerging human, animal, and plant diseases.
There is no precedent of countries undertaking impact assessments trying to predict the effect of policies
designed to liberalize trade, or entire trade agreements, on food-related health. Following an overview of
the different measures taken to liberalize food trade, this chapter goes through the four basic steps that can
be taken to conduct such an assessment: (1) an assessment of the types of impacts trade liberalization could
have, on a selected sub-set of key nodes in the food supply chain; (2) an assessment of the subsequent
impact on food safety, food availability, food prices and food marketing; (3) an assessment on the food-
related health outcomes themselves, namely foodborne diseases, undernutrition, and obesity and DR-NCDs;
(4) an assessment of the implications of trade agreements on the policy space required to address these
health conditions. In practice, the assessed impacts will vary widely between policies and national and local
contexts; this chapter generically highlights potential impacts and provides examples of reported impacts
where available. The chapter ends by raising some possible opportunities for using trade policy to improve
nutrition and health.
92
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Figure 8.1 Conceptual framework of the linkages between trade liberalization and food-relatedhealth
Sources. Adapted from Hawkes (5), Thow (6), Friel at al. (7)
93
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
• reduce financial and regulatory barriers to food imports and exports across national borders,
such as the reduction of tariffs and the removal of quotas and export taxes;
• harmonize, remove, or increase the transparency of national food-related regulations, such as
sanitary and phytosanitary measures, and food labelling regulations;
• encourage foreign direct investment in the agro-food industry, such as removing limits on the
percentage of domestic companies that can be owned by foreign businesses, implementing
protection for investors, protecting intellectual property rights and providing provisions for
dispute settlement;
• reduce financial and technical barriers to the trade in services used by the agri-food industry,
such as banking, telecommunications and real estate;
• decrease government support to domestic food production and state-managed entities, such
as through the privatization of state-marketing boards, removal of domestic agricultural subsi-
dies, and equal treatment of foreign and domestic food businesses in public procurement;
• support the development of infrastructure and capacity for trade and investment, by provid-
ing transportation routes and storage facilities, more efficient port facilities and the establish-
ment and funding of export promotion agencies.
These measures have been advanced through three main mechanisms: international, regional and bilateral
trade agreements, international investment agreements, and national investment in infrastructure. The
growth in trade agreements has been particularly notable since the 1990s. The completion of the Uruguay
Round of multilateral trade talks in 1994 marked a new era in food trade, with the founding of the World
Trade Organization (WTO), its multilateral Agreement on Agriculture and a range of other agreements (Box
8.1). Though multilateral agreements have proved critical in the trade liberalization of foodstuffs, since the
2000s regional and bilateral trade agreements, such as the Central American Free Trade Agreement and the
Trans-Pacific Strategic Economic Partnership Agreement, have grown in importance and scale.
94
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Box 8.1. WTO multilateral trade agreements relevant to the trade of food and agricultural
products (implemented 1995).
Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture. Pledges signatory countries to reduce tariffs (market access
provisions), export subsidies (export competition provisions) and domestic agricultural support
(domestic support provisions). The agreement focused on reducing subsidies for agricultural
production in high income countries.
Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS). Sets out rules for national
measures that aim to reduce hazards to animal, plant and human health, including food safety
regulations; it incorporates by reference the food safety guidelines and recommendations established
by the Joint FAO/WHO Codex Alimentarius Commission. It recognizes that countries have a legitimate
interest to protect human health from unsafe food, but upholds the principle that these measures
should distort trade as little as possible.
Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement (TBT). Establishes obligations to ensure that national mandatory
regulations, voluntary standards and conformity assessment procedures – including those affecting
food – do not create unnecessary obstacles to trade. They are designed to ensure that technical
regulations that apply to imported as well as domestic products are non-discriminatory and not
unnecessarily trade restrictive, while also permitting countries the policy space to develop appropriate
regulation to achieve domestic policy objectives based on scientific evidence.
Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS). Imposes obligations on
countries to provide minimum protection to a range of intellectual property rights, including on food
products (e.g. patents on seeds, geographical indications of commercial identification).
Dispute Settlement. The WTO’s procedure for resolving trade disputes.
General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). Contains measures designed to liberalize trade in
services, such as cross border trade in telecommunications services and advertising.
Agreement on Trade-Related Investment Measures (TRIMs). Prohibits trade-related investment measures,
such as local content requirements, that are inconsistent with basic WTO agreement provisions on
non-discrimination and fair treatment of foreign investors. They aim to ensure compensation for
expropriation of an investment (e.g. direct taking of a title or property) or for other measures having
an equivalent effect (e.g. destroying the economic value of an investment) to ensure fair and equitable
treatment.
95
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
• Lower barriers to imports can increase competition from lower-priced imports thus reducing
incentives for domestic production. On the other hand, lower costs of imported agricultural
inputs can increase production incentives, such as through the introduction of more intensive
production methods.
• Introduction of food safety standards can create barriers to market access for small-scale pro-
ducers. It also can facilitate access to export markets.
• Rules on intellectual property can affect access to seeds and plant varieties.
• Policies limiting domestic support (e.g. subsidies) for the agricultural sector can reduce production
incentives for the previously supported foods.
• Policies that increase the ability of foreign investors to buy and use agricultural land can increase
global production and generate money for host countries. There is often controversy over dis-
placement of local people and sharing of benefits (8).
• Lower barriers to exporting to other countries can encourage conversion to higher-value crops
destined for international trade (9). Evidence suggests that trade reforms tend to benefit
farmers producing export crops, but generally have negative impacts on farmers producing
import-competing foodstuffs (10).
96
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
17 million tons to 44 million tons between 1980 and 2007, and into least developed countries from 4 million
tons to 22 million tons.2 Trade in processed agricultural products more than doubled between 1995 to 2008
from more than USD 211 billion to almost half a trillion US dollars, faster than the rate of agricultural goods
overall (14). Traded processed commodities include sugar and vegetable oils; by-products of processing
used as food ingredients by food manufacturers (e.g. whey, potato starch, mechanically recovered meat);
and highly processed foods like baked goods. Exports from high-income OECD countries – responsible
for the vast majority of trade in processed products - more than doubled, increasing from USD 169 billion
in 1995 to USD 363 billion in 2008. Exports from low-and middle- income countries increased even more,
tripling and even quadrupling their exports during this time (14).
8.3.4. Food processing
As already indicated, food processing takes a whole range of forms, from basic packing to local flour
production, to large scale sugar and edible oil processing and the complex manufacturing of ready-to-eat
foods. Most food processing companies are small- and medium-sized enterprises, but large companies have
become more significant in the era of trade liberalization.
Trade liberalization influences food processing, and processors, in a range of ways. Trade in services alters
the business environment for processors. Food-related regulations, notably food safety and labelling
standards, influence the burden of compliance. One of the most important influencers has been Foreign
Direct Investment (FDI). FDI into processing and manufacturing foods for the host market grew significantly
from the1980s till the 2010s, mainly from high income countries (4). FDI from companies in the United
States into food processing grew from US$ 9 billion in 1980 to US$ 38.2 billion in 2000 (15). Between 1990
and 2009, FDI in the food, beverage (and tobacco) sectors of high-income countries increased 11-fold;
investment in these sectors in low and middle income economies increased fourfold and is projected to
continue to rise (16). The beverage sector accounts for most of the food-related FDI originating in the United
States; while the processed food industry is one of the top 10 sectors attracting FDI in India.
The use of FDI in the processed foods market reflects the economic advantage of FDI over imports and
exports: it enables companies to locate closer to their customer base, and circumvent the still relatively high
tariffs on processed foods (17); tailor their products to consumer preferences in the country and comply
more easily with national regulations and standards.
8.3.5 Retailing
FDI has also been directed to supermarkets and other forms of modern retailing, such as “convenience store”
formats. FDI from United States-based supermarket chains grew to nearly US$ 13 billion in 1999, up from
around US$ 4 billion in 1990 (18) indicating dramatic rates of growth. In China, for example, the supermarket
sector is growing at a rate of 30–40% sales growth per year (19). As a result, supermarkets have emerged as
bigger players in the food system (20, 21). The number of food service outlets has also increased significantly
as a result of FDI: United States-based food companies invested US$ 5.7 billion in overseas eating and
drinking establishments in 1998 (18).
Despite the growth in modern retailing, most perishable products in African and Asian developing countries
continued to be accessed through traditional or informal value chains (22). Even in more developed
countries, wet markets are often preferred: in Malaysia, for example, where supermarkets are commonplace,
traditional markets remain the preferred place for buying fresh meat (23). Wet markets persist because of
their ability to provide foods with attributes valued by customers including: accessibility; affordability; local
products; and, a trust relation with sellers (24).
8.3.6. Supply chain organization
Measures designed to liberalize trade have had the effect of changing the way food supply chains are
structured and organized. For example, although most food is still produced for national consumption
within national borders, food supply chains increasingly extend beyond national borders. Trade patterns
have become more complex, with foodstuffs and ingredients moving around the globe in an often
FAOSTAT food balance sheets: http://faostat.fao.org/site/354/default.aspx.
2
97
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
complicated and dynamic web of interactions. Trade liberalization can also have the effect of creating
greater unity between diverse production systems between countries in terms of crops, livestock and fish
varieties grown and produced, producer characteristics, regulatory frameworks, and technical expertise (25).
Concentration and control by large companies have become more prevalent as a result of changing
trade policies. Companies are more easily able to undergo vertical integration, so exerting influence over
the length of the supply chain. They are also more easily able to horizontally integrate through mergers,
acquisitions and joint ventures, so becoming larger. The degree of transnationalization (measured by foreign
assets and foreign sales) of the world’s largest transnational food companies (TNCs) has been increasing
since at least the early 1990s. Between 1990 and 2001, the foreign sales of TNCs within the world’s largest
100 TNCs rose from US$ 88.8 billion to US$ 234.1 billion, with total foreign assets rising from US$ 34.0 billion
to US$ 257.7 billion (4, 26). The food retail market is also becoming more concentrated through the process
of mergers and acquisitions. In 2004, Wal-Mart was estimated to have 6.1% of the global grocery market,
with the French company Carrefour at 2.3% (20, 21).
However, in many countries supermarkets and integrated agri-business are growing from a small base, so
even double-digit growth would not achieve significant market penetration in the near term. There is also
persistent opposition to “supermarketization” and globalization in some countries: India continues to see
strong opposition to the entry of foreign supermarkets from domestic retailers and political parties, who
believe it will cause mass job losses in a sector that is mostly dominated by small, family-run shops.
8.4 Step 2: Assessment of implications for food safety, availability, price and
marketing
The effects of the liberalization of food trade on food safety, availability (volume and variety), prices, quality
and marketing are not straightforward, and depend on the nature of implementing legislation and other
contextual factors (27).
8.4.1 Food safety risks
The implications of trade liberalization on food safety are both negative and positive. On the negative
side, increased food trade may introduce new safety hazards, revive previously controlled risks, and
spread contaminated food widely (28, 29). This is especially noticeable when the hazard is not found in
the importing country: for example, the parasite Cyclospora cyetanensis is not indigenous to the United
States and several major outbreaks have been traced to produce imported from Latin America (30). More
unusually, trade may lead to the identification a hitherto unsuspected food safety problems in domestic
markets, for example, in Abidjan the problem of chemicals in traditionally smoked fish was not discovered
until fish was exported to diaspora populations in France (31).
Although most food imported into low-income countries can be reliably considered of higher sanitary
quality than food in the domestic markets, low-income countries may also be more vulnerable to illegal
imports of unsafe food. A study in Tanzania found that, despite the national import prohibition of Chinese
milk products and unlabeled milk powder in Tanzania, 6% of milk powder samples were contaminated with
melamine (32). Another risk introduced by more trade is that the increased complexity of the food supply
makes the source of food safety risks more difficult to trace (33).
The increasing dominance of private sector actors at specific nodes in the supply chain has important
implications for food safety. The privatization of parastatals has the effect of changing the competitive
dynamics of the informal versus formal marketing sectors. This may lead to challenges in managing food
safety by the national authorities, as has been shown in the case of the dairy sector. Dairy production
in low and middle income countries has increasingly shifted from a formal sector heavily supported by
development agencies and the public sector to a largely autonomous informal sector, with associated
increasing difficulties of inspection and regulation (34).
98
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Consumer demand for meat and other livestock products has created incentives for greater private
investment in the intensification of animal production, which brings corresponding changes in the nature
of food safety risks. Positive implications can arise when large private food companies with complex
supply chains put structures into place to reduce risk, such as the adoption of “private standards” (which
may be voluntary or legally-mandated) (35). These standards may raise the regulatory bar for food safety
in countries where regulation is weak or lacking and may also prevent dumping of sub-standard food in
developing country markets (36). There are potential spillover health benefits of participating in export
markets. One study in Kenya found farmers who were given training and monitored for compliance used
safer chemicals and had fewer reported health problems. However, the results are not consistent – another a
study found no benefits for producers involved in seafood for export in Brazil (37).
Even though large-scale, intensive, export-oriented or compliant agriculture is focused on ensuring
biosecurity, there are clear linkages between intensification and disease emergence (38). Around 75% of
new human diseases emerge from animals. Although most new diseases emerge from wildlife, intensive,
industrial livestock systems appear to present more risk than extensive, traditional systems (39). Another
adverse trend in veterinary public health is the result of increasing privatization of animal health services
with negative implications for disease reporting and management (40).
There have also been important evolutions in public regulation of food safety of imported products,
especially perishable animal and plant products which are most associated with foodborne disease. The
SPS Agreement is reported to have increased the use of scientific risk assessment in the formulation of
food safety measures (41). The requirement to adhere to the SPS Agreement presents an opportunity for
developing countries to upgrade national food safety programmes with assistance from international
and bilateral agencies (42, 43). For example, countries are adopting the hazard analysis and critical control
point (HACCP) system -the international system recommended by Codex – as a foundation for control of
biological, chemical and physical hazards in food (28). The SPS Agreement has also provided a forum for
negotiating the reduction of food safety risks. Between 1995 and 2004, WTO Members made 330 complaints
about food safety, plant and animal health regulations and other issues to the SPS Committee (44). The
main items of concern were bovine spongiform encephalopathy (BSE), toxins, heavy metals, and foodborne
microbial pathogens.
Nevertheless, concerns have been raised that adherence to internationally agreed standards may represent
a reduction in the stringency of national food safety standards in high-income countries (45). And in
low-income countries it is reported that “importing” models of food safety management systems from
high-income countries may lead to ill-suited systems with counter-productive implications for food safety
risks (46). There is also evidence that countries with similar SPS regulations tend to trade with each other,
suggesting that the spread of food safety standards is restricted to specific countries rather than globally
(47). Indeed, an assessment of progress in the implementation of the SPS agreement indicated there had
been relatively slow progress in harmonizing regulations, although transparency had increased (48).
8.4.2 Food availability (amount, type and quality)
It is hard to estimate the net impacts of trade liberalization on food availability since, as noted by
McCorriston et al. (49, p. 54), “it may be only one part of a package of economic reforms introduced by
developing countries and there may be specific characteristics of the environment in which these reforms
were undertaken that will determine [food] availability”. The most direct potential effect is through the
changing balance of imports, exports and domestic food production. For example, domestic production
of a particular foodstuff may decline – but be compensated for by an increase of imports. Exports may
increase, but so may domestic production.
Global food availability increased significantly in the era of trade liberalization, but with significant variation
between countries and foods. A comparative study of the effect of trade reform on food security by the
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) found significant differences in the effects
on food availability between countries. For example, in China per capita supplies of the principal nutrients
99
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
grew significantly in the post-reform period. In contrast, rates of change were very modest in Malawi, and
declined in the United Republic of Tanzania (10).
The evidence is clear, however, that trade liberalization tends to increase the overall amount of food, feed
and raw materials imported into a country (50). Analysis suggests that imports have moved countries
with insufficient domestic food production towards food adequacy (51) and that national food availability
increases when countries shift to net-importing status (52). Cross-country studies also indicate that food
trade associated with more diverse food supply in middle and high-income countries (although not low-
income countries, 53).
Imports also alter the relative availability of different foods. For example, trade can be directly associated with
changes in national availability of different types of vegetable oils (Box 8.2). The implementation of free trade
agreements in Central America and Mexico have been found to be associated with changes in the availability
of meat, dairy products, processed foods, temperate (imported) fruits and/or animal food (54, 55, 43). Taking
the case of Central America during a period of liberalization in the 1990s, imports of processed cheese slices
grew by over three thousand percent – making a product available that had previously not been sold in these
countries (54). In Pacific Island countries, imports (or in this case “dumping”) of high-fat meats led directly to
an increasing availability, while the availability of traditional root crops declined (56).
Trade liberalization has an effect on availability of foods to consumers not just by direct imports and exports
of those foods, but by influencing domestic manufacturing. The increase of imports of ingredients used
by the processed food industry has facilitated the domestic production of processed foods. For example,
there has been a rapid increase of exports of whey from cheese-producing countries into middle-income
countries for use as a food ingredient (57). Increased imports of lower-cost animal feed (in many cases,
from developed countries with subsidized production) have increased the availability of feed in developing
countries. This has facilitated increased animal production at a lower cost, leading to increased availability
(54, 5).
Processes extending beyond imports and exports can also explain changes in food availability. For example,
FDI liberalization through trade agreements with the United States has been shown to significantly increase
the availability of soft drinks within the signatory country (58). Exports of processed foods from the United
States have been shown to be growing fastest in countries where modern grocery retailing is growing the
fastest, suggesting that the growth of supermarkets also facilitates the growth of processed food markets
(59).
100
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Box 8.2. Trade liberalization and the availability and prices of vegetable oils
Higher imports have driven increased domestic supply (defined by FAO as “[p]roduction + imports –
exports + changes in stocks”3) of vegetable oils in low- and middle-income countries (Table 8.1). The
most traded oils are palm oil and soybean oil, which have become the world’s most consumed edible
oils. A handful of key countries are responsible for most of the exports, notably Argentina, Brazil,
Indonesia, Malaysia and the United States. There has also been an overall trend towards the decline in
world vegetable oil prices, driven by lower costs of production in key exporting countries (2, 60).
Both the increase in imports and the decline in prices have been directly facilitated by trade
liberalization: policies were implemented in exporting countries to facilitate exports (for example
reduction of export tariffs), while importing countries reduced barriers to imports (for example
reduction of import tariffs) (61). These changes have enabled greater consumption of vegetable oils
in importing countries. Increases of consumption have been particularly notable in major importing
countries such as China and India (62).
Table 8.1 Domestic supply and import quantity of vegetable oils, 1980 and 2003
Country group 1980 2003 % increase 1980–2003
Domestic supply Developed countries 20.6 37.9 84.0
(million tonnes) Developed countries 20.8 65.1 213.0
Import quantity Developed countries 7.1 21.2 198.6
(million tonnes)
Developed countries 6.0 28.6 376.7
Calories available (per capi- Developed countries 310.9 421.7 35.6
ta per day)
Developed countries 132.6 239.1 80.3
Imports as proportion of Developed countries 34.5 55.9 62.3
domestic supply (%)
Developed countries 28.8 43.9 52.3
101
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Increased trade in advertising and other telecommunications services facilitates the commercial promotion
of highly processed foods. The ability to advertise and promote is a major pull factor for inward investment
by large TNCs into developing countries. Processed foods are commonly advertised and marketed all over
the world, using a wide range of communications channels and marketing (67). Estimates from Asia suggest
that food makes up a significant proportion of child-targeted advertising, ranging from 25% in the Republic
of Korea to 70% in Malaysia (68). Studies in Latin America suggest a high proportion of advertising during
children’s programming are for processed foods, such as sweetened beverages, candy, sugar-sweetened
cereals and chips.
During the 1990s, domestic advertising expenditures by the two leading soft drink and fast food companies
declined in the United States but increased elsewhere, reflecting the recognition by those companies of the
increased growth potential in newer markets (67). The United States, however, remains the world largest
market for advertisers. The total amount spent on advertising by leading food companies in 2009 was $1.79
billion.
The average annual number of foodborne illnesses associated with fresh produce more than doubled between 1973–1987 and 1988–1991, a trend that
4
Informal trade – much less amenable to regulation – may also be a more important cause of foodborne
diseases of exotic origin. It seems likely that a significant proportion of import-associated foodborne
diseases in high income countries arises as a result of non-commercial or illegal importation of perishable
foods rather than commercial food imports. For example, in many cases unsafe cheese entering the United
States comes from Mexico and enters the country for personal consumption without undergoing sanitary
inspection (74). In the UK, around 12,000 tons of meat are illegally imported each year, from countries
which typically have much higher levels of hazards in meat than in the UK (75). Recent studies have shown
presence of pathogens in illegal meat imports (76).
In low- and middle-income countries, there is likewise little evidence that a lead reason for the spread of
foodborne diseases is trade liberalization. Most poor countries are net food importers, and imported food
is typically of higher sanitary quality than food in the domestic markets. Yet there is also little evidence that
control of foodborne disease in low and middle-income countries has been aided by the increased attention
to food safety regulation arising from trade liberalization. Most food sold in the domestic markets of poor
countries is still not subject to effective food safety management. International processes established to
implement the SPS Agreement, such as the WTO SPS Committee, for example, are largely utilized by high-
income countries (77).
8.5.2 Undernutrition
According to the FAO, during 2011–2013 over 840 million people were unable to meet the daily nutritional
requirements for a healthy life (78). The aggregate global burden of undernutrition is estimated to have
caused over 3 million child deaths in 2011 (79). Despite steady improvements, stunting prevalence in
children under five affected at least 165 million children in 2011(79).
Although there is evidence on the impact of trade liberalization on food availability, and prices (see
sections 8.4.2 and 8.4.3), there is little written evidence of the direct impact of trade liberalization on the
prevalence of undernutrition in countries and communities. Indicators that there may be impacts come
from the relationship between food availability and indicators of undernutrition. At the national level, there
is some evidence from across countries that national availability and prices are linked to national levels
of undernourishment. Cross-country studies using data from the 1990s indicate a direct relationship with
national food availability of rates of undernourishment (80). Smith and Haddad (81) show that increased
national food availability has consistently been one factor associated with declines of stunting since the
1970s. Food supply diversity in middle and high- (not low-) income countries is also associated with lower
rates of several measures of undernutrition (53). On prices, there is evidence from the food price crisis of
2006–2008 which showed that high food prices increased undernutrition, especially in young children (82,
83).
Nevertheless, the particular impact of these national-level trends is likely to play out very differently among
different groups. For example, trade liberalization may influence household nutrition among farming
families by affected their incentives to produce for the market, or, through a pathway not discussed in this
chapter, their income stream. This impact is likely to be very different to low-income consumers in urban
areas, which itself may be very different from high-income households. The impact of trade liberalization on
undernutrition is thus likely to emerge in different ways depending on the specific role played by trade on
food availability and prices, the household context, and the role played by food relative to other immediate
determinants in influencing undernutrition.
8.5.3 Obesity and diet-related non-communicable diseases
Non-communicable diseases are a serious global public health problem. According to the World Health
Organization (WHO), NCDs are the largest cause of death in the world, killing more than 36 million people
each year. Nearly 80% of NCDs deaths (29 million) occur in low- and middle-income countries. More than
nine million of all deaths attributed to NCDs occur before the age of 70; 82% of these “premature” deaths
occurred in low- and middle-income countries (84). The global prevalence of the leading NCDs is projected
to increase substantially over the next two decades. A related problem is the rising number of people who
are overweight or obese. WHO predicts that by 2015, approximately 2.3 billion adults will be overweight
and more than 700 million will be obese (85).
104
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Poor diet is a leading risk factor for obesity and DR-NCDs. The scientific evidence shows that diets high in
fats (especially saturated fats and trans fatty acids), free sugars and salt, and low in fruits, vegetables, pulses
(legumes), whole grains and nuts, pose significant risks for NCDS (86). Changes in food availability outlined
in section 8.4.2 have facilitated a shift away from diets high in cereals and complex carbohydrates towards
energy-dense, nutrient-poor diets with greater amounts of meat, fats, sweeteners and processed foods (87).
Table 8.1 shows the increasing availability of vegetable oils, which are now used in large quantities in home-
cooked foods, in restaurant foods, and as saturated and trans-fats in processed foods. Lower-middle-income
countries experienced particularly rapid rates of growth in sales of packaged foods between 1996 and 2002
(Table 8.2). Food marketing used to promote these foods has also grown in scale and intensity, as have the
stores that sell them.
Of all the food-related health conditions linked to trade liberalization, the association with NCDs appears
to be the most evident. Analysis of the available data suggests that trade agreements and liberalization are
associated with increased intake of soft drinks and fast food (88, 89). Island communities which are very
reliant on imports present a particular case in point. Evidence from the Pacific Islands, for example, shows
that trade has been a key factor in their epidemic of NCDs (90). Analysis points to a correlation between
imports and expenditure on unhealthy foods (91).
Table 8.2 Annual average growth in retail sales of packaged foods, 1996–2002
Per capita retail sales of pack- Total retail growth of pack- Per capita growth of pack-
Country group aged foods 2002 (US$) aged foods 1996–2002 (%) aged foods (%)
High-income 979 3.2 2.5
Upper-middle-income 298 8.1 6.7
Lower-middle-income 143 28.8 28.1
Low-income 63 12.9 11.9
Source: Euromonitor International.
8.6 Step 4: Implications of trade agreements for policy space to address food-
relatedill health
Trade policy has the potential to limit the “freedom, scope, and mechanisms that governments have to
choose, design, and implement public policies to fulfil their aims” (92), because they may conflict with the
aims of trade liberalization, such as the encouragement of private investment. For example:
• Agreements on technical regulations such as the SPS, TBT and equivalent clauses in regional and
bilateral trade agreements. Technical regulations are legitimate from a trade perspective if they
do not discriminate between imported and domestically produced foods. However, they may
still be contested on the basis of lack of strong scientific evidence. For example, a proposal by
the government of Thailand to introduce traffic light labelling on packaged foods was queried
in the WTO TBT Committee on the basis of the limited evidence base for traffic light labelling
(16). Trade agreements may also influence the process of developing regulations. For example,
the recently concluded Korea–US Free Trade Agreement, which include provisions that allow
persons [a national or an enterprise] of the other party to participate in development of stan-
dards and technical regulations (93).
• WTO Agreement on Agriculture. To enhance food security, many countries subsidize – or have
proposed subsidizing – the production of staple foods, traditional fruits, vegetables and tu-
bers (94). This form of subsidy could be perceived as being inconsistent with the WTO Agree-
ment on Agriculture, which provides that governments should reduce domestic agricultural
subsidies (Box 8.1). WTO member governments have already committed to progressive reduc-
tions in subsidies on a multilateral level, which are being gradually implemented.
105
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
• Agreements on Investor Protection. New bilateral and regional trade agreements are more ex-
tensive in their investor protections relative to the WTO TRIMS Agreement. In some cases they
include an Investor State Dispute Settlement (ISDS) mechanism, which was previously only
found in Investment Treaties. An ISDS mechanism gives private investors the right to bring
disputes against states directly; in WTO forums, only states, not private entities, can bring
disputes against other states. For example, Philip Morris Asia used the ISDS mechanism in the
Australia–Hong Kong Special Administrative Region Investment Agreement to challenge a
tobacco “plain packaging” policy on the grounds that the measure expropriated trademarks
and undermined good will indirectly (95). Researchers have thus raised concerns that this lim-
its policy space for policies designed to reduce markets for certain types of foods (for example,
highly processed foods, which are commonly the subject of foreign direct investment) (16). For
example, investors might claim that restrictions on advertising, or on the levels of fats, sugars
and salt permissible in energy-dense foods and beverages, constitute indirect expropriation
because they reduce the value of an investment.
To date, trade agreements have typically contained clauses to ensure that they do not interfere with
legitimate (i.e. not disguised trade barriers) to protect human health. The Agreements of the WTO generally
have latitude to enable countries to implement measures that are supported by evidence to demonstrate
that they are reasonable to achieve legitimate public health outcomes (96). In particular, Article XX(b) of the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade clarifies that a country may implement measures to protect health
so long as they are not applied in a manner that would constitute arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination
between countries or a disguised restriction on trade. Despite commitments in the Agreement on
Agriculture to reduce subsidies, analysis suggests that there is space for subsidies to achieve legitimate
public health measures under the Agreement on Agriculture (95) and in 2013, a multilateral decision on
food security at the 9th WTO Ministerial Meeting Bali permitted subsidies for traditional staple crops (97).
Investment treaties usually also allow latitude for public health measures. For example, the United
States Model Bilateral Investment Treaty provides that “except in rare circumstances, non-discriminatory
regulatory action by a Party that is designed and applied to protect legitimate public welfare objectives,
such as public health, safety, and the environment, does not constitute indirect expropriations”. A similar
clause is reiterated by the UN Conference on Trade and Development in its explanation of what comprises
expropriation (98).
There is, however, very little latitude for trade bans. WTO provisions require that foodstuffs produced
domestically and in other countries should be treated equally, so bans can only be justified if the country
can prove the import cannot be substituted by a foodstuff produced domestically. For example, in 2007 in
response to concern over the impact of fatty meat on health and the “dumping” of perceived “low quality”
food on the market, the Government of Samoa banned turkey tail imports (99). In relation to international
trade, Samoa received a request from the United States for further information about the ban and as a result
of acceding to the WTO in 2012, the ban was lifted and a 300% import duty was set for two years followed
by a 100% import duty. There are also concerns that the next generation of trade agreements – such as
the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership – will significantly extend earlier trade agreements and
allow greater protection for investors, and less latitude for governments to implement regulations 1016).
In addition, even though policy space may exist, governments –particularly developing country
governments –face challenges in understanding and utilizing this policy space (102). There are two main
challenges:
• Engagement with the public health sector. Health policy makers and those in an advisory capac-
ity are rarely included in formal discussions of trade and investment policy decisions, and only
sometimes are able to participate informally. The health sector may also show little interest in
such discussions, not understanding their potential implications. The lack of understanding of
the reciprocal benefit to each of the two sectors is often the reason for this lack of engagement
106
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
• Limited capacity in the public sector in low- and middle- income countries for developing trade-
compliant nutrition policy options and for defending these options. Addressing nutrition and
NCDs require complex multisectoral approaches. In addition, scientific evidence for such ap-
proaches is often contested by private sector interest. The burden of proof to initiate or defend
such regulation in international arbitration is resource intensive; the threat of challenge and/or
query on the scientific evidence base thus presents a deterrent to the introduction of nutrition
and health-promoting policies and, therefore, to “regulatory freeze.”
8.7. Opportunities for using trade policy to improve nutrition and health
There are a number of specific opportunities for utilizing policy space within the current trade and
investment architecture to improve nutrition and health. For example, the formal participation of
the principal nutritionist in Samoa’s accession committee to WTO demonstrates that strengthening
engagement between health and trade is possible (103). In this instance, participation from the nutrition
sector enabled development of an ongoing strategy to mitigate the effect of the removal of the ban on
turkey tails, and to ensure that policy space was enshrined for an alternative health policy approach i.e.
the implementation of a high sales tax (104). Similarly, the Bali decision on food security represents an
opportunity to enhance trade-related food policy space to support both food security and NCDs prevention
(105). Countries can now consider opportunities to subsidize relatively healthy traditional staple foods as
part of strategies for both food security and NCDs prevention.
A comprehensive and multi-pronged approach to nutrition policy may be another strategy for countries to
maintain policy space for nutrition and strengthen their position in the event of a dispute. Based on analysis
of previous health-related WTO panel decisions, von Tigerstrom (96) argues that using several different
types of regulations would increase the defensibility of nutrition policies. National governments can also
strengthen the defensibility of nutrition policy measures by specifically noting their commitment to health
and nutrition in investment policy strategies (16). This would help to manage the legitimate expectations
of investors, to minimize the possibility that subsequent regulation cannot be construed as indirect
expropriation.
With respect to preventing DR-NCDs, one opportunity is afforded by inclusion of technical measures related
to NCDs prevention in the Codex Alimentarius. The Codex Alimentarius Commission was asked by WHO in
2005 to consider its role in NCDs prevention in relation to the Global Strategy on Diet, Physical Activity and
Health. Potential measures include making guidelines on nutrition labelling and food composition more
health-friendly. For example, Codex now includes nutrient reference values for nutrients associated with
NCDs: saturated fatty acids and sodium, and recommends mandatory nutrition labeling (101).
Finally, there is an opportunity for improving policy coherence between trade and nutrition in the forum
of Aid for Trade, which represents a growing component of global aid commitments (102). Aid for Trade
includes strategic investments to improve internal and cross-border transport as well as storage, technology
and infrastructure, in addition to agricultural development. For example, targeting fruit and vegetable
production using Aid for Trade funds could help to increase availability and contribute to improved health and
food security (103).
The Framework for Action for implementing the Rome Declaration included recommendations to:
• s trengthen local food production and processing, especially by smallholder and family farm-
ers, giving special attention to women’s empowerment, while recognizing that efficient and
effective trade is key to achieving nutrition objectives” (R9);
• ncourage governments, United Nations agencies, programmes and funds, the World Trade
e
Organization and other international organizations to identify opportunities to achieve global
food and nutrition targets, through trade and investment policies (R17), and
• i mprove the availability and access of the food supply through appropriate trade agreements
and policies and endeavor to ensure that such agreements and policies do not have a nega-
tive impact on the right to adequate food in other countries (R18).
These recommendations provide a framework for governments to make commitments to assess the food-
related nutrition and health impacts of trade and trade policy and to identify trade as an opportunity to
improve nutrition. As this chapter has shown, assessing the impact of trade liberalization on nutrition and
food-related health is not straightforward. The impacts depend on if and how the effects are transmitted
throughout food supply chains, how this then affects food environments, and then nutrition and health.
Diagnosing health related outcomes thus requires tracing those changes, and the incentives which
influence them. There will inevitably be trade-offs identified as part of this process. For example, in the case
of food safety, standards may raise the regulatory bar for food safety in countries where regulation is weak
or lacking. But they may also give private companies considerable negotiating power with governments
when developing food safety regulations, which may create barriers to market access for small-scale
producers. A rigorous analytical approach to diagnosis will go some way to enabling national governments
to determine the potential effects of trade liberalization on food-related health and inform their policy
making in this area.
108
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
References
1. Aksoy MA. The evolution of agricultural trade flows. In: Aksoy MA, Beghin JC, eds. Global agricultural
trade and developing countries. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2005.
2. The state of agricultural commodity markets, 2004. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the
United Nations, 2004.
3. Hawkes C, Murphy S. An overview of global food trade. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager
N, Dubé L, eds. Trade, food, diet and health: perspectives and policy options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell,
2010.
4. World investment report 2006. Geneva, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 2006.
5. Hawkes C, Murphy S. An overview of global food trade. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N,
Dub L, eds. Trade, food, diet and health: perspectives and policy options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
6. Thow AM. The implications of trade liberalization for diet and health. (www.globalizationand health.
com/content/5/1/5 (Last access on June 24, 2015).
7. Friel, S., Hattersley, L., Snowdon, W.et al, Monitoring the impacts of trade agreements on food
environments, Obesity Reviews, 2013, 14(Supplement S1), 120–134.
8. African agriculture, transformation and outlook. New Partnership for Africa’s Development
(NEPAD), Johannesburg, November 2013.
9. Gulati A, Minot N, Delgado C, Bora S. Growth in high-value agriculture in Asia and the emergence
of vertical links with farmers. In: Swinnen J, ed. Global supply chains, standards, and the poor. CABI,
2007:91.
10. Thomas H, Trade reforms and food security: country case studies and synthesis. Rome, Food and
Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 2006.
11. Rashid, S, Gulati, A. Cummings, Jr., R. From parastatals to private trade 2008
http://ebrary.ifpri.org/cdm/singleitem/collection/p15738coll2/id/124986/rec/39
(Last access on June 24, 2015)
12. Bureau, J, Jean S. The Impact of Regional Trade Agreements on Trade in Agricultural Products. OECD
Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 65. OECD Publishing, 2013
(http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k3xznkz60vk-en).
13. Wesley E, Peterson F. A billion dollars a day: the economics and politics of agricultural subsidies, John
Wiley & Sons, 2009.
14. Liapis, P. Changing Patterns of Trade in Processed Agricultural Products. OECD Food, Agriculture and
Fisheries Papers, No. 47, OECD Publishing, 2011
(http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kgc3mq19s6d-en).
15. Bolling C, Somwaru A. US food companies access foreign markets through direct investment. Food
Review, 2001, 24:23–28.
16. Thow AM, McGrady B. Protecting policy space for public health nutrition in an era of international
investment agreements. Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 2014
(www. Who.int/bulletin/volumes/92/2/13-120543/en/). 109
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
17. Martinez SW. The U.S. food marketing system: recent developments, 1997–2006. Economic Research
Report 42. Washington, DC, United States Department of Agriculture, 2007.
18. Harris JM, Kaufman PR, Martinez SW, Price C. The US food marketing system, 2002. Washington, DC,
United States Department of Agriculture, 2002.
19. Hu D, Reardon T, Rozelle S, Timmer P, Wang HL. The emergence of supermarkets with Chinese
characteristics: challenges and opportunities for China’s agricultural development. Development
Policy Review, 2004, 22:557–586.
20. Murphy S. Concentrated market power and agricultural trade.ECOFAIR Trade Dialogue Discussion
paper No. 1 2006, available online under
http://www.iatp.org/files/451_2_89014.pdf (Last access on June 24, 2015)
21. Vorley B. Food, Inc.: Corporate concentration from farm to consumer. London, International Institute for
Environment and Development, 2003.
22. Gómez MI, Ricketts KD. Food Value Chain Transformations in Developing Countries: Selected
Hypotheses on Nutritional Implications. Food Policy, 2013, 42:139–150.
23. Chamhuri N, Batt PJ. Exploring the factors influencing consumers’ choice of retail store when
purchasing fresh meat in Malaysia. International Food and Agribusiness Management Review 2013,
16(3): 99–122 (ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/156463/2/20120080.pdf ).
24. Jabbar, MA, Baker, D, Fadiga, ML (eds). Demand for livestock products in developing countries with
a focus on quality and safety attributes: Evidence from case studies. Research Report 24. Nairobi,
Kenya, ILRI, 2010.
25. Henson S, Humphrey J. Understanding the complexities of private standards in global agri-food
chains as they impact developing countries. Journal of Development Studies, 2010, 46(9):1628–
1646.
26. Hawkes C. The role of foreign direct investment in the nutrition transition. Public Health Nutrition,
2005, 8:357–365.
27. Thow AM. Trade liberalisation and the nutrition transition: mapping the pathways for public health
nutritionists. Public Health Nutrition, 2009, 12(11):2150–2158.
28. Buzby JC, Unnevehr L. Food safety and international trade. Agriculture Information Bulletin AIB789.
Washington, DC, United States Department of Agriculture, 2004.
29. Perry BD, Grace D, Sones K. Current drivers and future directions of global livestock disease
dynamics. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 2013, 110(52):20871–20877 ( doi:
10.1073/pnas.1012953108). Epub 2011 May 16.
30. Abanyie F, Harvey, RR, Harris JR et al. 2013 multistate outbreaks of Cyclospora cayetanensis
infections associated with fresh produce: focus on the Texas investigations. Epidemiology and
Infection 2015, 1–8.
31. Roesel K, Grace D (eds). Food safety and informal markets: Animal products in sub-Saharan Africa.
Oxford, UK, Routledge, 2014 (http://www.routledge.com/books/details/9781138818736/).
110
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
32. Schoder D. Melamine milk powder and infant formula sold in East Africa. Journal of Food protection,
2010, 73(9):1709–1714.
34. Grace D, Randolph T, Omore A, Schelling E, Bonfoh B. Place of Food Safety in Evolving Pro-Poor
Dairy Policy in East and West Africa. Revue d’élevage et de médecine vétérinaire des pays tropicaux,
2007, 60 (1–4): 153–162.
35. Henson S, Humphrey J. Understanding the complexities of private standards in global agri-food chains as
they impact developing countries. Journal of Development Studies, 2010, 46(9):1628–1646.
36. Unnevehr L, Grace D. Aflatoxins: Finding solutions for improved food safety. 2020 vision focus 20
series. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington D.C., 2013.
37. Unnevehr, L. Ronchi, L. Food safety and developing markets: Research findings and research
gaps. International Food Policy Research Institute, 2014. (https://books.google.com/books?id=xb_
OBAAAQBAJ&pgis=1).
38. Jones B, Grace D, Kock R et al. How do agricultural intensification and environmental change affect
zoonoses with a wildlife-livestock interface? A systematic review. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences USA, 2013, 110(21): 8399–8404.
39. Jones KE, Patel NG, Levy MA. et al. Global trends in emerging infectious diseases. Nature (London),
2008, 451, 990–993.
40. Perry BD, Grace D, Sones K. Current drivers and future directions of global livestock disease
dynamics. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 2011, doi
10.1073/pnas.1012953108.
41. Josling T, Roberts D, Orden D. Food regulation and trade. Washington DC, Institute for International
Economics, 2004.
42. Henson S. Food safety issues in international trade. In: Unnevehr L, ed. Food safety in food security
and food trade. Vision 2020 Focus Briefs. Washington DC, International Food Policy Research
Institute, 2003.
43. Food safety and globalization of trade in food: a challenge for the public health sector. Geneva, World
Health Organization, 1998. http://www.who.int/foodsafety/publications/fs_management/en/
globalization.pdf.
44. Roberts D, Unnevehr L. Resolving trade disputes arising from trends in food safety regulation: the
role of the multilateral governance framework. World Trade Review, 2005, 4:469–497.
45. Silverglade BA. The WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures: weakening food
safety regulations to facilitate trade? Food and Drug Law Journal, 2000, 55:517–524.
46. Grace D, Randolph T, Omore A, Schelling E, Bonfoh B. Place of Food Safety in Evolving Pro-Poor Dairy
Policy in East and West Africa. Revue d’élevage et de médecine vétérinaire des pays tropicaux, 2007,
60(1–4): 153–162.
111
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
47. Wu F, Guclu H. Aflatoxin Regulations in a Network of Global Maize Trade. PLoS ONE 2012, 7(9):
e45151. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0045151.
48. Josling, T, Orden D, Roberts D. National food regulations and the WTO Agreement on Sanitary
and Phytosanitary Measures: implications for trade-related measures to promote healthy diets. In:
Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L, eds. Trade, food, diet and health: perspectives and
policy options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
49. McCorriston S, Hemming DJ, Lamontagne-Godwin, JD, et al. What is the evidence of the impact of
agricultural trade liberalisation on food security in developing countries? A systematic review. London:
EPPICentre, Social Science Research Unit, Institute of Education, University of London, 2013.
50. Thow AM. The implications of trade liberalization for diet and health
(www.globalizationand health.com/content/5/1/5 2009).
51. Porkka M, Kummu M, Siebert S, Varis O. From Food Insufficiency towards Trade Dependency: A
Historical Analysis of Global Food Availability. PLoS ONE 2013, 8(12): e82714.
doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0082714.
52. Brooks J, Matthews, A. Trade Dimensions of Food Security. OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries
Papers, No. 77, OECD Publishing, 2015
(http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5js65xn790nv-en).
53. Remans, R. Wood, S.A. , Saha, N. et. al. Measuring nutritional diversity of national food supplies.
Global Food Security 3, no. 3 (2014): 174-182.
54. Thow AM, Hawkes C. The implications of trade liberalization for diet and health: a case study from
Central America. Globalization and Health, 2009, 5:5
(http://www.globalizationandhealth.com/content/5/1/5).
55. Hawkes C, Thow AM. The implications of the Central American Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA) for the
nutrition transition in Central America. Pan American Journal of Public Health, 2008, 24(5): 345–360.
56. Thow AM, Swinburn B, Colagiuri S et al. Trade and food policy: case studies from three Pacific Island
Countries. Food Policy, 2010, 35:556–564.
57. Igumbor EU, Sanders D, Puoane TR et al. ‘‘Big Food,’’ the Consumer Food Environment, Health,
and the Policy Response in South Africa. PLoS Med 2012, 9(7): e1001253. doi:10.1371/journal.
pmed.1001253.
58. Stuckler D, McKee M, Basu S. Global saturation of “risky commodities”: the role of global producers
in increased population consumption of processed food, tobacco, and alcohol. PLoS Med 2012,
9:e1001235.
59. Tandon, S. Landes, M.R. and Woolverton, A. The Expansion of Modern Grocery Retailing and Trade in
Developing Countries. ERR-122. U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, Economic Research Service July 2011.
60. Commodity forecasts (real 2005 prices). Washington DC, World Bank 2004.
61. Hawkes C. The influence of trade liberalisation on global dietary change: the case of vegetable oils,
meat and highly processed foods. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L, eds. Trade,
food, diet and health: perspectives and policy options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
112
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
62. Hawkes C. Uneven dietary development: linking the policies and processes of globalization with the
nutrition transition, obesity and diet-related chronic diseases. Global Health, 2006, 2:4: 1-18.
64. Reardon T, Henson S, Gulati A. Links between supermarkets and food prices, diet diversity and food
safety in developing countries. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L (eds.) Trade, food,
diet and health: perspectives and policy options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
65. Drewnowski, A, Hanks AS, Smith WG et al. International trade food and diet costs, and the global
obesity epidemic. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L (eds.) Trade, food, diet and
health: perspectives and policy options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
66. Hawkes C. Trade liberalization and the nutrition transition: three case studies. In: Hawkes C, Blouin
C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L (eds.) Trade, Food, Diet and Health: Perspectives and Policy Options.
Oxford: Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
67. Hawkes C. Marketing activities of global soft drink and fast food companies in emerging markets: a
review. In: Globalization, diets and noncommunicable diseases. Geneva, World Health Organization,
2002.
68. Escalante de Cruz A. The junk food generation: a multi-country survey of the influence of television
advertisements on children. Kuala Lumpur, Consumers International Asia Pacific Office, 2004.
69. Costard S, Bryony AJ, Beatriz ML et al. Introduction of African swine fever into the European Union
through illegal importation of pork and pork products.PLoS One 8, no. 4 (2013).
70. Kaferstein FK. Food safety as a public health issue for developing countries. In: Unnevehr L, ed. Food
safety in food security and food trade. Vision 2020 Focus Briefs. Washington DC, International Food
Policy Research Institute, 2003.
71. Center for Disease Control and Prevention. Multistate outbreak of listeriosis linked to imported
Frescolina Marte brand ricotta salata cheese (final update). Atlanta, GA: US Department of Health
and Human Services; 2012. Available at
http://www.cdc.gov/listeria/outbreaks/cheese-09-12/index.html
72. Gould L. Foodborne disease outbreaks associated with food imported into the United States,
2005–2010. Presented at the International Conference on Emerging Infectious Diseases; March 11-
14, 2012; Atlanta.
73. Gould, L.H. Surveillance for Foodborne Disease Outbreaks United States, 2009–2010, Center for
Disease Control and Prevention Weekly, 2013 available online under:
www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm6203a1.htm). (Last accessed online June 24, 2015)
74. Brown CM, Cetron MS. Crossing Borders. MMWR Morbidity Mortatiity Weekly Report, 57, 2008,
432–435
(http://cid.oxfordjournals.org/content/57/1/v.full.pdf+html).
75. Hartnett E, Amie A, Miles S et.al. A quantitative assessment of the risks from illegally imported meat
contaminated with foot and mouth disease virus to Great Britain. Risk Analysis, 2007, 27(1): 187–202.
113
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
76. Smith KM, Anthony SJ, Switzer WM et al. Zoonotic Viruses Associated with Illegally Imported Wildlife
Products. PLoS ONE 2012, 7(1): e29505. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0029505
77. Roberts D, Josling T. Tracking the Implementation of Internationally Agreed Standards in Food and
Agricultural Production. International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 2011(http://www.
agritrade.org/Publications/documents/Harmonization.pdf).
78. UN Food and Agriculture Organization. The State of Food Security in the World 2013. Rome: FAO, 2013
(http://www.fao.org/docrep/018/i3434e/i3434e.pdf ).
79. Black RE, Cesar GV, Walker SP et al. Maternal and child undernutrition and overweight in low-income
and middle-income countries. The Lancet, 2013, 382(9890): 427–451 (http://www.thelancet.com/
journals/lancet/article/PIIS0140-6736(13)60937-X/fulltext).
80. Thomas HC. Trade Reforms and Food Security: country case studies and synthesis. Food & Agriculture
Organisation, Rome, 2006.
81. Smith L, Haddad L. Reducing Child Undernutrition: Past Drivers and Priorities for the Post‐MDG Era.
IDS Working Papers2014, 441: 1–47.
82. Compton J, Wiggins S, Keats S. Impact of the global food crisis on the poor: what is the
evidence. London,Overseas Development Institute, 2010, 9: 9.
83. Global Monitoring Report 2012. Food Prices, Nutrition, and the Millennium Development Goals. 2012,
(http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTDECPROSPECTS/0,,contentMDK:23148901~page
PK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:476883,00.html)
85. Obesity and overweight. WHO Fact Sheet 311. Geneva, World Health Organization, 2006.
86. Diet, nutrition and the prevention of chronic diseases. Report of a Joint WHO/FAO Expert Consultation.
WHO Technical Report Series No. 916. Geneva, World Health Organization, 2003.
87. Popkin BM. The nutrition transition and its health implications in lower-income countries. Public
Health Nutrition, 1998, 1(1): 5-21.
88. Stuckler D, McKee M, Ebrahim S, Basu S. Manufacturing epidemics: the role of global producers in
increased consumption of unhealthy commodities including processed foods, alcohol, and tobacco.
PLoS Med 2012, 9(6): e1001235. doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.1001235.
89. De Vogli R, Kouvonenb A, Gimeno D. The influence of market deregulation on fast food
consumption and body mass index: a cross-national time series analysis. Bulletin of the World Health
Organization, 2014, 92:99–107A.
90. Thow AM, Snowdon W. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L (eds). Trade, Food, Diet
and Health: Perspectives and Policy Options. Oxford, Wiley Blackwell, 2010.
114
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
91. Sahal Estimé M, Lutz B, Strobel F. Trade as a structural driver of dietary risk factors for
noncommunicable diseases in the Pacific: an analysis of household income and expenditure
survey data. Globalization and Health 2014, 10:48 (http://www.globalizationandhealth.com/
content/10/1/48).
92 Koivusalo M, Schrecker T, Labonté R. Globalization and Policy Space for Health and Social
Determinants of Health. In: Labonte R, Packer C, Runnels V, eds). Globalization and Health: Pathways,
Evidence and Policy. London, Routledge, 2009.
93. Office of the United States Trade Representative. Korea - US (KORUS) Free Trade Agreement Final
Text. 2012,
(https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/korus-fta/final-text).
94. Atkins V. Agricultural Trade Policy Instruments to Promote Healthy Diets in Developing Countries:
An Assessment of the Opportunities within the Framework of the WTO Agreement on Agriculture
and the Doha Development Agenda. In: Hawkes C, Blouin C, Henson S, Drager N, Dubé L (eds). Trade,
Food, Diet and Health: Perspectives and Policy Options. Oxford: Wiley Blackwell, 2010, 264–278.
95. Notice of arbitration, Australia / Hong Kong Agreement for the Promotion and Protection of
Investments; investor: Philip Morris Asia Limited. Melbourne: Arthur Allens Robinson; 2011, (www.
ag.gov.au/Internationalrelations/InternationalLaw/Documents/Philip% 20Morris%20Asia%20
Limited%20Notice%20of%20Arbitration%2021%20November%202011.pdf )
(accessed 1 October 2013).
96. Von Tigerstrom B. How Do International Trade Obligations Affect Policy Options for Obesity
Prevention? Lessons from Recent Developments in Trade and Tobacco Control. Canadian Journal of
Diabetes 2013, 37:182–188.
97. World Trade Organization. Public stockholding for food security purposes. Ministerial decision of
7 December 2013. WT/MIN(13)/38. WT/L/913. Ministerial Conference, Ninth Session. Bali, 3–6
December 2013.WTO, 2013.
98 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Expropriation. New York & Geneva, UNCTAD,
2012 (UNCTAD Series on Issues in International Investment Agreements II) (http://unctad.org/en/
Docs/unctaddiaeia2011d7_en.pdf ,accessed 1 October 2013).
99. Thow AM,Swinburn B, Colagiuri S. Trade and food policy: case studies from three Pacific Island
countries. Food Policy, 2010, 35(6): 556–564.
101. Thow AM, Snowdon W, Labonté R, et al. Will the next generation of preferential trade and
investment agreements undermine prevention of noncommunicable diseases? A prospective policy
analysis of the Trans Pacific Partnership Agreement. Health Policy, 2015, 119(1):88–96.
102. Jewell J, Hawkes C, Allen K. Law and obesity prevention: Addressing some key questions for the public
health community. WCRF International Policy and Public Affairs Working Paper No 1. London: WCRF
International, 2013 (http://www.wcrf.org/PDFs/WCRF-International-Law-and-Obesity-Prevention.pdf).
115
Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
103. Thow AM, Downs SM, Leeder SR. Policy for the Prevention of Diet-Related Non-Communicable
Diseases in the Asia-Pacific Region. In: Griffiths SM, Tang JL, and Yeoh EK (eds). Routledge Handbook
of Global Public Health in Asia, Routledge, New York 2014.
104. World Trade Organization. Report of the working party on the accession of Samoa to the World Trade
Organization. Geneva , WTO, 2011.
105. World trade organization. Public stockholding for food security purposes. Ministerial decision of 7
december 2013. Wt/min(13)/38. Wto, 2013.
106. Food and Agriculture Organization. Codex Alimentarius. Guidelines on nutrition labelling. CAC/GL
2-1985. Rome, FAO, 2013,
(http://www.fao.org/ag/humannutrition/33309-01d4d1dd1abc825f0582d9e5a2eda4a74.pdf).
107. World Trade Organization, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Aid for trade
at a glance. Connecting to value chains. Paris, OECD, 2013.
108. Thow AM, Priyadarshi S. Aid for Trade: an opportunity to increase fruit and vegetable supply. Bulletin
of the World Health Organization, 2013, 91(1):57–63.
116
Trade in medicines
Chapter 9
Trade in medicines
Frederick Abbott
Annual worldwide spending on medicines is anticipated to exceed $1.2 trillion by 2016 (1). Developing
countries, and particularly so-called emerging markets, will account for a substantial portion of the growth
in spending on medicines. A good part of global market demand will be satisfied by medicines that, in
whole or in part, are developed and manufactured in countries other than where they are ultimately used
by patients (2). Governments and patient populations are affected by trading rules affecting medicines
development, production and trade, in terms of access to treatments and affordability. This chapter
addresses those rules.
9.1 Introduction
A government has two primary interests with respect to trade in medicines. The first is the interest in
protecting and promoting public health, which involves (among other things) providing citizens with the
range of products necessary to prevent, diagnose and treat disease. The second is the interest in promoting
economic welfare, including development and employment. These two interests are often complementary,
although they may, in some circumstances, conflict. One of the most difficult tasks for policy-makers and
regulators in the field of public health is to find the right balance between public health and commercial
interests.
It is not surprising that trade in medicines (and related supplies) has been the subject of intensive
international dialogue over the past several decades. The debate began in earnest in the 1970s when, on
one side, multinational pharmaceutical producers based in developed countries expressed growing concern
over alleged misappropriation of their patented technology by enterprises based in developing countries.
At the same time, developing countries expressed deepening concern over the imbalance between
developed and developing countries with regard to technological capacity and ownership of technology.
This dialogue played out in a series of negotiations at the United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development (UNCTAD), the World International Property Organization (WIPO) and ultimately at meetings
of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) during the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations,
which culminated in 1995 in the entry into force of the World Trade Organization (WTO) Agreement on
Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement).
The debate concerning TRIPS and the impact of patent and other intellectual property (IP) protection on
access to medicines is considered below. However, there are three other aspects of pharmaceutical trade
that affect access to medicines, and these aspects also demand attention.
First, production, distribution and trade in pharmaceuticals and related supplies are subject to government
regulatory control at a number of levels (2, p. 47- 52). Countries maintain substantially different regulatory
standards to assure the safety and efficacy of the pharmaceutical supply chain. There can be good reasons
why governments adopt different standards, such as to take account of differences in local environment
likely to affect the condition of medicines as they are stored, distributed and used. However, in some
cases differential regulation may unnecessarily hinder the cross-border movement of pharmaceuticals,
particularly among regions that share public health interests and trade policy objectives.
Second, attention to assuring affordable access to existing medicines and related supplies should not
disguise the fact that innovation is fundamentally important in making progress against disease burdens
via the creation of new medicines. It is important that policy-makers consider the health of both current
117
Trade in medicines
and future populations. Future populations, for example, could benefit immensely from a vaccine against
HIV infection, as such a vaccine could eventually allow public health workers to entirely avoid most of the
problems associated with providing a continuous supply of antiretroviral treatment. It is therefore critical
to encourage the research and development of future products while ensuring access to those that already
exist. There is considerable debate about how best to encourage research and development, however, and
using a patent system is not the only option (3).
Third, while the ultimate objective of government policy with respect to trade in medicines and related
supplies is to promote and protect public health, the pharmaceutical industry may be an important part
of the national economy, providing employment and affecting the balance of trade. Governments may
choose to promote the development and maintenance of a strong local pharmaceutical industry as a part
of national economic development policy. It is important to keep in focus the link between industrial policy
and public health objectives as a strong local pharmaceutical industry does not automatically assure that
local public health needs are properly addressed (4).
This chapter assesses the role of the pharmaceutical industry in economic development and discusses
means to ensure adequate access to existing medicines. There is no generally accepted model for creating
an optimal balance between commercial interests and public health interests, or between the health
of current and future populations. All countries, at whatever stage of development and with whatever
population characteristics, struggle to provide the best possible health care for their citizens. Some have
developed more effective programmes than others. But, because countries differ widely in the availability of
financial resources and in patterns of disease (based, among other things, on nutrition, working conditions,
climate and geography), there is no single model that will create the best solution for every country.
However, there are trade and regulatory tools that governments can use to promote particular policies that
should be well suited to conditions within the country. The objective here is to identify those tools and how
they may be effectively used.
The remainder of this chapter is split into seven principal sections. It begins by outlining the core aspects of
TRIPS and TRIPS-plus provisions relevant to trade and access to medicine, providing the central legislative
background to the issue of trade and medicines, before considering six elements of analysis: (1) assessment
of what is being traded; (2) ownership of medicines and pharmaceutical trade; (3) trade policy instruments;
(4) innovation and intellectual property; (5) access and intellectual property; and (6) the relationship
between pharmaceuticals and intellectual property scope. As mentioned in Chapter 1, an assessment tool
could be used to compile information related to trade and medicines at the national level, in order to inform
policy development on the matter.
Developing countries that took advantage of this option, such as India, were not obligated by the TRIPS Agreement to provide immediate means for
1
processing and granting patent applications, but only for receiving such applications so they could later be either granted or rejected (this is the so-called
“mailbox” provision; see TRIPS Art. 70.8). When the transition period ended, the mailbox applications would be examined, and if patents were granted
the terms would commence from the initial mailbox filing date (i.e., for whatever remainder of the 20-year term). The transition arrangement included a
complex obligation to grant “exclusive marketing rights” (EMRs) for a maximum of five years based on local filing of a patent application, local regulatory
marketing approval, and the grant of a corresponding foreign patent and foreign marketing approval (TRIPS Art. 70.9).
118
Trade in medicines
Least-developed country (LDC) Members of the WTO were initially accorded an 11-year transition period to
implement the TRIPS Agreement (Article 66.1). This transition period has been extended twice, first until 1
July 2013,2 later until 1 July 2021.3 In parallel, LDCs benefit from a specific transition period that authorizes
them not to adopt or enforce pharmaceutical patent protection and data protection,4 nor to extend
exclusive marketing rights (EMRs),5 until 1 January 2016. Because the general extension until 1 July 2021
for TRIPS implementation by LDCs does not prevent them from “rolling back” existing IP protections that
may have been granted,6 it appears that a renewal of the specific pharmaceutical-related extension that will
otherwise expire on 1 January 2016 is not needed to authorize LDCs to continue to disapply pharmaceutical
patent protection, data protection and the EMRs (Article 70.9) provision of TRIPS. Nonetheless, LDCs might
decide to seek such a specific extension to avoid any doubts on this issue.
The early experience of developing countries with implementation of the TRIPS Agreement was
problematic. South Africa confronted challenges by developed-country governments and multinational
pharmaceutical enterprises following adoption of public health legislation in 1997. South Africa prevailed,
but by the end of this episode the TRIPS Agreement was widely perceived as an obstacle to addressing
public health problems. Members of WTO reacted to this by recognizing the importance of allowing
governments to pursue flexible policies with respect to the protection of public health, which recognition
was expressed in the 2001 Doha Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and Public Health.7 The Doha
Declaration was followed in 2003 by the adoption of a “waiver decision”8 that facilitated the export of
pharmaceutical products under compulsory licence. In 2005 the General Council of the WTO adopted a
Protocol Amending the TRIPS Agreement9 which, once accepted by a sufficient number of Members, will
formally transform the 2003 waiver into a part of the TRIPS Agreement.10 As of 2014, the Protocol had not
yet been accepted by a sufficient number of Members to bring it into force, but the waiver decision remains
in effect.
Despite the Doha Declaration and associated events, the political situation with respect to access to
medicines has remained difficult. Throughout 2007–2008 Brazil and Thailand came under pressure from
multinational industries and supporting governments for having issued compulsory licenses. India has
seen its 2005 pharmaceutical patent law, and subsequent administrative and judicial decisions applying
it, harshly criticized by the multinational pharmaceutical industry as well as right-holder groups such as
the US Chamber of Commerce. India’s grant in 2011 of a compulsory license on an important anti-cancer
drug benefitted a substantial group of patients needing treatment, but this grant also garnered significant
criticism from right-holder interest groups. While India’s patent law, patent office and court decisions are
consistent with the TRIPS Agreement, foreign industry groups argue they reflect problematic policy. India,
on its side, has reaffirmed a strong stance in favour of protecting the public health of its population despite
the criticism from foreign industry groups.
9.2.2 From TRIPS to TRIPS-plus
“TRIPS-plus” is a non-technical term that is used to refer to intellectual property rules that extend the scope
of covered subject matter or provide higher levels of protection than is required by the TRIPS Agreement.
While TRIPS-plus is often used in reference to bilateral and regional free trade (and economic partnership)
agreements (FTAs and EPAs), TRIPS-plus rules are also part of multilateral agreements, and may be found in
national legislation.
TRIPS-plus provisions have raised concerns among a number of affected stakeholder groups, including
in the area of information technologies, but for present purposes refer to provisions that affect the
2
Decision of the Council for TRIPS of 29 November 2005, IP/C/40, 30 Nov. 2005.
3
Decision of the Council for TRIPS of 11 June 2013, IP/C/64, 12 June 2013.
4
Decision of the Council for TRIPS of 27 June 2002, IP/C/25, 1 July 2002.
5
General Council, Decision of 8 July 2002, WT/L/478, 12 July 2002.
6
The terms of the extension until 1 July 2013 expressly precluded LDCs from making changes to their laws and regulations that resulted in a lesser degree of
consistency with TRIPS (i.e. “rolling back”). The extension until 1 July 2021 does not include such an express preclusion.
7
WT/MIN(01)/DEC/2.
8
WT/L/540 and Corr.1.
9
WT/L/641.
10
The amendment will technically apply only to the Members that have accepted it, although the waiver decision will continue to apply to other Members.
119
Trade in medicines
scope or duration of intellectual property protection for pharmaceuticals and related products. Patents
establish rights to exclude third parties from making, using, selling, offering for sale and importing (for
these purposes) medicines for a limited term.11 They provide the basis for pricing at above “competitive
market” prices, and in doing so limit affordability and access to newer treatments. Requirements to provide
periods of marketing exclusivity based on submission of data to regulatory authorities likewise limit the
introduction of generic medicines. Other forms of intellectual property, such as trademark and copyright,
may also influence affordability and access. When TRIPS-plus requirements are introduced regarding
these forms of intellectual property, they enhance the ability of patent and other IP right holders to limit
competition. From the standpoint of affordability and access to medicines, TRIPS-plus rules must be
approached with caution. Patents, in particular, are thought to encourage innovation and the development
of new medicines, and this is not to suggest that patent protection as such is detrimental from a public
health standpoint. The policy objective is to properly balance the innovation-encouraging aspects of patent
protection with the need for access and affordability. The proper balance may be different for different
countries and regions.
What types of innovation justify the award of patent-based marketing exclusivity? Because pharmaceutical
companies often use minor changes in technology (such as changes in recommended dosage or route of
administration, or slight changes in chemical structure that produce similar results in the body) to promote
newer medicines to both doctors and patients, a patent on a minor change may effectively extend the
marketing exclusivity enjoyed by the patent holder in a given therapeutic class. The older less expensive
product will remain off patent. However, to the extent that doctors and patients can be persuaded to
select the expensive new medicine instead of the old, patents on minor changes can and do facilitate the
maintenance of originator as opposed to generic pricing.
One of the most important TRIPS-plus issues associated with bilateral and regional trade agreements
involves the treatment of clinical data submitted in connection with government approval of
pharmaceutical products. Article 39.3 of the TRIPS Agreement requires WTO Members to protect against
“unfair commercial use” of undisclosed clinical data submitted to the government with respect to new
chemical entities in the pharmaceutical sector. WTO rules leave substantial discretion to Members regarding
how to implement this obligation (2, p. 63- 67). Some developed country WTO Members are dissatisfied with
this level of discretion and seek to negotiate stronger “marketing exclusivity” requirements in bilateral or
regional agreements.
Such TRIPS-plus marketing exclusivity requirements potentially have serious consequences with respect to
the introduction of generic products in national markets. In the first place, the introduction of a fixed term
of marketing exclusivity is nowhere mandated in the TRIPS Agreement, but a number of bilateral or regional
agreements, notably those to which the United States or the European Free Trade Association12 are parties,
incorporate minimum terms that may sometimes be extended based on submission of supplementary
clinical data. In some ongoing regional trade agreement negotiations demands are being made to provide
extended periods of marketing exclusivity for originator biological medicines that may substantially delay
the introduction of generic biologicals. Second, Article 39.3 of the TRIPS Agreement could be understood to
mean that a government is obligated to protect only such regulatory data that has been submitted to it in
the course of the drug approval process (2, p. 65). A number of bilateral and regional agreements, however,
impose an obligation to grant marketing exclusivity based on submission of data in foreign countries, or
to grant marketing exclusivity on the basis of an approval granted in a foreign country. Third, a number
of bilateral and regional agreements subtly extend the scope of products to which marketing exclusivity
applies from “new chemical entities” to “previously unapproved products”. This means that products that
may be older and already generic in a foreign country must be treated as a new product if previously
unapproved in the country where approval is sought.
The net result of all these requirements may be to significantly reduce the prospects for registration of
generic versions of originator pharmaceutical products. At the same time, policy-makers should take into
11
To be clear, as confirmed by the Doha Declaration, the patent right to block importation does not prevent a country from authorizing parallel importation of
patented medicines.
12
The European Free Trade Association (EFTA) comprises Iceland, Lichtenstein, Norway, and Switzerland.
120
Trade in medicines
account that there should be some incentive to register originator products for the local market, whether
that incentive is directed towards the originator or a generic provider. If the generic provider is unable to
locally provide the clinical data that was relied on for an initial registration abroad, there needs to be some
local mechanism for assuring that drug regulatory approval is based on sound criteria.
Another aspect of the commitments in bilateral and regional agreements relates to so-called “patent
linkage”, that is, the linking of drug regulatory authority (DRA) approval with patent status (2, p. 171- 173).
In the absence of patent linkage requirements, a DRA generally would not consider the patent status of a
medicine when regulatory approval is sought. Patent linkage provisions, however, may facilitate blocking of
regulatory approval by the patent holder. Patent linkage may take a variety of forms. The particular choice
of form may have a significant impact on the extent to which linkage facilitates the blocking of market entry
of generic products. In one of its stronger forms, a linkage provision could prohibit a DRA from approving
generic medicines where a patent has been listed (notified to the authority) with respect to the originator
medicine. In a somewhat weaker form, a linkage mechanism might require notice to the patent holder
upon submission of an application to the DRA by a generic company, and the patent holder would then
have the opportunity to initiate a patent infringement action in court. Because courts in some jurisdictions
grant preliminary injunctions without close examination of the validity of the patents on which the requests
are based, even this seemingly less intrusive form of linkage may be quite problematic from an access
standpoint. Such preliminary injunctions may remain in effect throughout the duration of the court case. As
a practical matter, almost any form of linkage will adversely affect the ability of generic producers to enter
the market, although a system limited to requiring originators to list relevant patents when applying for
marketing authorization (without requiring notice to the originator when generic approval is sought) might
be useful in promoting transparency for third parties regarding potential patent claims.
Another problem raised by linkage provisions in a number of bilateral and regional agreements is that,
by their express terms, they may appear to preclude the grant of a compulsory licence unless the patent
holder gives its consent. That is, because a drug may not be put on the market without DRA approval, if the
drug regulatory authority is prohibited from approving a drug during the term of a corresponding patent,
effective use of a compulsory license on the patent might remain blocked by the regulatory restriction.
In a number of agreements, this potential conflict was addressed by the negotiation of “side letters” that
were intended to permit the parties to avoid the blocking of compulsory licensing. However, the legal
status of these letters is uncertain, and in any case such letters typically include their own conditions.
Some agreements expressly incorporate into the intellectual property chapter itself the type of exception
necessary to permit the registration of medicines for which compulsory licences have been granted.
A number of bilateral and regional trade agreements include chapters on the protection of investments and
investors, and include intellectual property among the subject matter of protection. Including intellectual
property in a chapter on investments is controversial because intellectual property protection (such as
provided by patent) is often secured based on activities undertaken outside a host state, and does not
represent local investment. Traditionally the protection of investments by a host state under international
law was directed toward property purchased and/or developed within the host state. In addition,
intellectual property rights can and are legislatively or judicially changed in scope or duration from time to
time, and these changes do not bear relationship to local investments of capital by the right-holders. It is
therefore not clear that intellectual property should be treated the same as other investment property.
In some bilateral or regional agreements, there is a specific provision indicating that a compulsory license
issued in conformity with the TRIPS Agreement does not constitute the taking of an investment. While this
suggests that compulsory licensing may not be the subject of investment chapter dispute, this may be
somewhat deceptive because an investor may bring a claim on grounds that a compulsory license did not
conform to the TRIPS Agreement requirements. If nothing else, this will require a government to spend
resources defending against such a claim.
In some cases, bilateral or regional agreements provide a mechanism for third-party arbitration of
investment disputes, which allow private parties to initiate claims against host governments. In this context,
121
Trade in medicines
diplomatic relations between the country parties to the agreement may not be an important factor at the
dispute settlement phase. Private investors may be as aggressive as they wish. The government must be
prepared to address those investors. Canada has been brought to dispute settlement under the NAFTA
by Eli Lilly, an originator pharmaceutical company, on grounds that a certain judicial doctrine interpreting
Canada’s patent law constitutes an unlawful taking of Eli Lilly’s patent rights. This represents a very
substantial intrusion into the judicial processes of Canada, and is contrary to the respect traditionally shown
to courts interpreting national law. The risks to the authority of national courts around the world from this
type of investment chapter arbitration should not be underestimated.
So-called “non-violation complaints” are an arcane subject, more or less specific to international trade law.
The essence of a non-violation complaint is that the complained-against party has not violated the terms of
the agreement, but has nullified or impaired some benefit that the complaining party legitimately expected
to receive when it entered into the agreement. The WTO dispute settlement system generally permits the
filing of non-violation complaints (see, for example, GATT Article XXIII(1)(b)). This practice evolved based on
the complex relationships between tariffs, subsidies and other measures that affect trade in goods.13 But,
up until now, it has not permitted such complaints in the field of TRIPS. Article 64 of the TRIPS Agreement
specifically imposed a five-year moratorium on non-violation complaints, which period has been repeatedly
extended (see for example WT/L/783). By authorizing non-violation complaints with respect to intellectual
property in a bilateral or regional trade agreement, however, a country opens itself up to a wide range of
claims that it may not have expected to defend (6). It is difficult to know what the other party to a bilateral
or regional agreement thought it would gain as an intellectual property-related benefit of the agreement,
and what might therefore form the basis for a non-violation complaint.
A number of bilateral and regional trade agreements include enforcement provisions in the intellectual
property chapter. These commitments often go beyond those that are required by the TRIPS Agreement.
A government must exercise caution to avoid adopting potentially onerous penalties on generic
pharmaceutical producers, as such penalties might have a “chilling effect” on the drug supply. One
interesting feature of a number of bilateral and regional trade agreements is a provision that authorizes
claims by intellectual property rights holder interest groups, such as pharmaceutical industry associations.
If such interest groups are authorized to initiate patent infringement claims on behalf of their members, this
may increase the number of claims that are brought, as local association representatives may find it easier
than foreign patent holders to file and manage litigation claims.
palliatives (such as aspirin, ibuprofen and codeine). Such medicines (and their components) tend to be
available from a wide range of suppliers on the international market at reasonable prices, and they are
often formulated from APIs and excipients (inactive ingredients) into finished products within the national
market.
However, there are a small number of medicines on the WHO Model List of Essential Medicines, particularly
within certain therapeutic classes such as antiretroviral therapy, for which the drugs are relatively new and
for which the patents have not yet expired. For these medicines, there may be a limited number of suppliers
(and comparatively high prices) on the international market. As a consequence of the pre-1995 invention of
most first-line antiretroviral treatments and the operation of TRIPS Agreement transition rules, most first-
line antiretrovirals were not patented in many countries and should remain available from generic suppliers
based in countries such as India. However, the international supply situation for newer second- and third-
line antiretrovirals is more problematic because the relevant patents have not yet expired, meaning that
prices may remain high for a number of years.
Characteristics of the local environment will necessarily shape the demand for drugs. The extent to which
HIV/AIDS is present among the national population, other things being equal, will determine the level of
demand for antiretrovirals in the country. Climate and geography may affect the type of formulation used or
preferred for the local environment. Most countries share prevalence of coronary disease, diabetes, cancer
and other so-called Type I diseases,14 and demand for treatment for such diseases is high in most countries,
even if the supply (or access) situation is widely different depending upon economic and other factors.
9.4 Ownership
As indicated earlier, governments have two principal interests with respect to the national pharmaceutical
sector: assuring that citizens have adequate access to safe and effective medicines, and developing and
maintaining a well-functioning domestic pharmaceutical industry. In principle, the public health interest
and the commercial interest may be perfectly complementary: a well-functioning domestic pharmaceutical
industry may be able to supply safe and effective medicines at competitive prices, while at the same
time boosting national employment and improving the balance of trade by substituting domestically
produced pharmaceuticals for imports, or even by exporting domestically produced pharmaceuticals.
A well-functioning domestic pharmaceutical manufacturing industry may also contribute to productive
research and development, generating revenues and improving the balance of trade through licenses with
manufacturers in other countries.
In addition to promoting employment and improvement in the balance of trade, a well-functioning
domestic pharmaceutical manufacturing industry may help to protect public health security and ensure
that local health needs are adequately addressed. While in ordinary circumstances a country may be well-
served by relying on imports of pharmaceutical products, in times of international public health stress such
reliance may prove problematic. Foreign sources of supply may elect to divert products based on their own
public health needs or based upon ability to pay. Thus, for example, in response to the threat of an avian
influenza epidemic, a number of countries announced their intention to reverse engineer the antiviral
medicine considered most efficacious in treating the virus and to produce it locally, in order to ensure that
national needs were met.
However, while public health security may weigh in favour of maintaining an adequate capacity to
manufacture pharmaceutical products in times of urgency, as a general proposition very few countries are
in a position to be self-sufficient in the development and production of the entire range of pharmaceutical
therapies. Moreover, from the standpoint of effective allocation of global resources, it would probably not
be welfare-enhancing for each country to attempt to reach pharmaceutical self-sufficiency. For many types
of products and services, the global community may be better off if production is concentrated in those
14 A Type I disease is one that is present in large numbers in both rich and poor countries, such as influenza or tobacco-related diseases. A Type II disease is one
that occurs in both rich and poor countries, but that is more prevalent in poor countries, such as HIV/AIDS. A Type III disease is one that overwhelmingly or
exclusively occurs in developing countries, such as trypanosomiasis. Type II and Type III diseases may be collectively referred to as “neglected diseases”. See
(9, p.19).
123
Trade in medicines
countries that are more efficient in producing them. There may be countervailing reasons why countries
want to retain greater self-sufficiency in certain sectors. For example, a certain level of agricultural self-
sufficiency may be important to assure public welfare in times of war or natural calamity. In light of the
various interests in the medicines sector: health, economic, and security considerations, each country must
find its own appropriate balance between domestic production and reliance on imports.
The question whether local ownership or control in the pharmaceutical manufacturing sector is important
to a country is difficult to answer. Local ownership may imply that profits from businesses are more
likely to be reinvested within the country, though this is not necessarily the case. Similarly, local owners
may be more responsive to addressing local conditions and to addressing concerns expressed by the
government, and less likely to close manufacturing facilities in response to short-term fluctuations in
economic conditions because of their direct connection to the community. If lower-income countries
maintain adequate infrastructure to allow efficient production of pharmaceuticals, locally owned and
operated pharmaceutical facilities may emerge as lowest-cost suppliers. Yet, a subsidiary of a foreign-owned
multinational company might be substantially similar to a locally owned pharmaceutical manufacturer from
a public health economic and social standpoint. Also, distinctions between “local” and “foreign” businesses
may not be so easy to define, as shareholders, lenders, managers, employees and other stakeholders may
have ties to multiple jurisdictions, and as joint venture relationships in one form or another (including
product development agreements, licensing, intermediate manufacturing, etc.) are important elements of
the pharmaceutical industry.
corruption. Although importers can normally determine the tariff rate of a given good, they may not be
able to determine, at the time of planning and investing in manufacture, the extent to which a quota for a
particular good has been or will be filled. Not only does this create uncertainty, it also places in the customs
authorities a substantial amount of power to manipulate the system for entry of goods into the country.
Third, quotas present problems of allocation because, in theory, one major importer might rapidly occupy
a country’s full quota, leaving no room for import competition. WTO rules provide that, in situations in
which quotas are used, a system for geographical allocation among WTO Members should be implemented.
Fourth, quotas require complex and therefore expensive systems of licensing and recordkeeping, and are
thus wasteful of scarce resources.
One of the great challenges of international trade regulation is to distinguish between measures adopted
by governments to achieve legitimate public policy objectives, and measures adopted for the purpose of
shielding the domestic market from foreign competition. An important premise underlying the WTO system
is that, all else being equal, opening national markets to competition from foreign-sourced goods and
services (while obtaining reciprocal access to the foreign market) is beneficial because this promotes the
efficient allocation of global resources, which should benefit all WTO Member countries. At the same time,
few if any governments fully embrace this premise. For example, many governments have long protected
domestic agricultural markets on grounds of food security. Similarly, governments recognize that abrupt
changes to trade regulations can have a disruptive impact on national employment (and other factors
involving the domestic allocation of resources), and typically seek to build in transitional arrangements
when adjusting trade policy. The WTO Agreement on Safeguards allows the temporary implementation of
trade barriers, including quotas, where rapidly rising imports threaten to cause serious injury to domestic
industry.
As noted earlier, governments may have legitimate policy reasons for seeking to develop and maintain local
pharmaceutical production, as well as promote local research and development. In some circumstances this
may be difficult to accomplish unless domestic producers are temporarily afforded some form of advantage
over more highly capitalized and technologically advanced foreign competitors. A difficult question is how
to promote local industry without inhibiting access to medicines.
Because of WTO national treatment rules, governments are generally prohibited from providing express
preferences to local producers. However, there is an exception to the national treatment rule (Article III:8
of GATT ) that permits preferential treatment in the area of government procurement, so long as it is not
done for purposes of commercial resale. A government that purchases pharmaceuticals for use in a national
health programme may be able to grant preferences under this exception. If a WTO Member is party to the
“plurilateral” (optional for WTO Members) Agreement on Government Procurement, it may have accepted
non-discrimination commitments in this area, but even then exceptions exist, including threshold purchase
values as well as any exceptions contained in a given country’s specific schedule of commitments.
Governments often provide direct or indirect financial support to the national pharmaceutical industry
through subsidies to research institutions that provide essential inputs into the development of new
products or production processes. The use of subsidies for specific industries is restricted by the WTO
Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, but governments nevertheless find ways of
providing support for the development of local industry.
National governments sometimes grant preferences to local producers through the adoption of local
manufacturing or regulatory compliance standards that are different from the standards under which
originator versions of the products initially were approved by foreign regulators. For example, DRAs may
require stability data from the testing of drugs that are unique to the local environment, and that import
drug suppliers might generally be unable to supply without incurring substantial additional costs. Such an
apparently neutral requirement may in practice act as a substantial trade barrier.
It is certainly to be expected that national governments require pharmaceutical importers to seek approval
for and register their products. Health regulatory authorities may also require importers to properly store
their products and to provide suitable arrangements for recalling products that cause difficulties.
125
Trade in medicines
One of the principal purposes of a regional trade agreement is to establish tariff or quota preferences
among member countries, as permitted by GATT Art. XXIV. Because regulatory barriers may also restrict
cross-border trade, regional trade agreements may also seek to facilitate the removal of regulatory barriers,
such as by harmonizing national regulations or providing for mutual recognition of regulatory approvals.
The reduction or removal of regulatory barriers is particularly important with respect to the pharmaceutical
sector because regulation of the safety and efficacy of pharmaceutical products plays a substantial role in
the marketing of such products, and reducing barriers on a regional basis may facilitate the establishment
of production facilities that can efficiently supply regional requirements.
In addition to regional trade agreements, countries may benefit from agreements such as the United States
Generalized System of Preferences (GSP), which unilaterally grants preferential access to the United States
market, for the purpose of promoting economic growth in the developing world. The GSP is not a regional
trade agreement because reciprocal market access is not necessarily provided by beneficiary countries to
the United States.
126
Trade in medicines
One of the broad trends in public research and development over the past two decades has been to offer
incentives to researchers making use of public funding, such as permitting researchers to take title to
patents issued based upon their research, or at least to allocate a share of patent-based income to those
researchers. An example is the United States Patent and Trademark Law Amendments Act (Bayh-Dole Act) of
1980, which permits recipients of federal funding to own patents arising from their research. In recent years
a number of countries (including Brazil, the Philippines and South Africa) have adopted similar legislation, in
some cases adapting the legislation to their national circumstances (2, p. 33). Singapore, which has engaged
in intensive national efforts to promote research and development in the pharmaceutical sector, provides
mechanisms for researchers to share in the profits deriving from the exploitation of publicly funded
inventions.
While the broad trend appears to favour allowing researchers to financially benefit more directly from
publicly funded research, such incentive solutions are not without their problems. The most common
criticism of Bayh-Dole style legislation is that the public, which initially funded the relevant research, must
generally pay higher prices if resulting medicines inventions are patented by the private sector, in essence
“paying twice” for the same research. Others reply that critics underestimate the extent of investment and
the risk taken in moving potential new treatments from the basic research phase to marketing approval and
manufacture, and argue that eliminating Bayh-Dole type incentives would make it even more difficult to
introduce new medicines.
In any event, there is general agreement that Bayh-Dole style legislation should ensure that the public
shares fairly in the outcome of any research and development that it sponsored. This might, for example, be
accomplished by reserving to the government a right to grant nonexclusive licences to additional suppliers
if the needs of the public are not being adequately met. In fact, the United States Bayh-Dole legislation
includes a provision allowing the funding agency to withhold the grant of a patent in “exceptional
circumstances” and also grants the government so-called “march-in” rights, allowing it to issue nonexclusive
licences following a patent grant if the needs of the public are not being adequately met. In more than
thirty years, however, march-in rights have never been successfully utilized, despite recent efforts by access-
oriented groups demanding that the United States National Institutes of Health (NIH) make use of them.
The NIH, which administers funding for pharmaceutical research, has taken the position that high prices do
not constitute a lack of availability or improper exploitation, and that action to moderate prices must be
addressed by specific U.S. congressional action. The NIH has taken the position that if drugs are available
– even if they are unaffordable for many patients – that patents are being sufficiently used, and it is up
to Congress or state health authorities to find ways to pay for them. In order to avoid this type of result,
Bayh-Dole legislation adopted by developing countries should probably include specific reference to price
moderation as an objective of a march-in system.
One of the most significant changes brought about by the WTO TRIPS Agreement was to impose upon WTO
Member governments a requirement to provide patent protection in the field of pharmaceuticals, as well as
to impose a minimum 20-year duration of the patent term. The TRIPS Agreement also required governments
to prevent the unfair commercial use of undisclosed regulatory data on new chemical entities in the
pharmaceutical sector, and some countries have implemented that obligation by granting pharmaceutical
originators a period of marketing exclusivity which, at least until recently, has generally run concurrently
with the patent term.16
Yet, the distinction between patents and marketing exclusivity based on submissions to regulatory
authorities may be unappreciated. Patents are often challenged in courts for having been improvidently
granted. There may have been an inconsequential modification of a previously known substance that
did not satisfy the inventive step requirement, or there may have been prior art that anticipated the
claimed invention. There are a variety of grounds on which patents may be challenged and found wanting.
Pharmaceutical patent holders are therefore worried about the strength of protection they may have.
Marketing exclusivity based on regulatory submission is different. Such exclusivity typically cannot
The introduction of a 12-year term of marketing exclusivity for biologic drugs in the United States, for example, may result in periods of marketing exclusiv-
16
This does not mean that the grant of regulatory approval, and associated grant of marketing exclusivity, can never be challenged. But such challenges are
17
not common, and the pathways to initiate and pursue such challenges are not well established.
128
Trade in medicines
129
Trade in medicines
whether that incremental innovation justifies what in some cases may constitute a very large price
premium on the product. National governments may, for example, wish to enact laws that encourage or
require generic substitution when feasible. Because such “generic substitution” laws normally only apply
to identical dosage forms, chemical entities, and routes of administration, governments additionally
may wish to consider policies that encourage appropriate substitution of alternate treatments that may
not be identical products per se, but rather are considered therapeutically “substitutable” products. Also,
cost controls may be accomplished at least in part through pharmaceutical benefit or insurance plans
limiting reimbursement based on an assessment of whether new patented treatments do, in fact, confer
a meaningful benefit. Just as pharmaceutical companies have an interest in charging higher prices
to maximize profits, government insurance schemes and private insurance companies typically have
an incentive to reduce expenses, including to keep premiums within the reach of consumers. Private
pharmaceutical benefit plans are usually part of a competitive market.
Another approach adopted by some governments has been to expressly limit the extent to which additional
patents may be granted with respect to different forms of the same chemical entity or compound. Notable
in this regard is Section 3(d) of the India Patents Act, which prohibits the granting of patents on new forms
of known substances unless the patent applicant is able to show a significant improvement in efficacy.
In 2013, the Supreme Court of India affirmed the denial of a patent applied for by Novartis on a form of
imatinib mesylate (Gleevec or Glivec) because the applicant failed to show a significant enhancement in
therapeutic efficacy.
Patents are typically granted by a national patent office, which may operate under the authority of a larger
ministry, such as the ministry of commerce. In some countries, such as Brazil, the public health regulatory
authority (for Brazil, ANVISA) reviews pharmaceutical patent applications with respect to the criteria of
patentability, and must give its approval before a patent may be issued by the national patent office (for
Brazil, INPI).
The patent offices of some countries do not perform a substantive examination of patent applications
prior to the grant of patents, but merely register patents based upon properly completed paperwork and
appropriate fees. The system in these countries is therefore known as a “registration system”, as opposed
to an “examination system”. As a consequence, provided that procedural requirements are met and fees
are paid, an applicant may obtain a patent on virtually anything. Registration systems impose substantial
burdens on potential competitors that might wish to enter the market, but must first challenge patents that
have been issued without examination. The public ultimately bears the economic cost of market access
restrictions imposed by the patents. For countries that want to introduce an examination system, but do not
have the resources to adequately assess the range of potential pharmaceutical inventions, some use might
be made of the substantive examination conducted by an International Preliminary Examining Authority
under the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT) system. However, the PCT has advantages and disadvantages,
and it is important for the government to consider the way the PCT will be implemented, if it is used (13).
A number of countries permit third-party challenges to patent applications that have been filed but not
yet approved. This is referred to as “pre-grant opposition” and it is typically conducted as a patent office
administrative procedure. The advantage of pre-grant opposition is that competitors and the public
may avoid bearing the burden of market access restrictions based upon improvidently granted patents.
Alternately, or sometimes in addition, many countries permit challenges at the patent office immediately
following the grant of a patent and for some period of time thereafter. This is referred to as “post-grant
opposition” and is also conducted as a patent office administrative procedure, sometimes with recourse to
a judicial body on appeal. A patent may be affirmed, revoked or its claims modified as a result of post-grant
opposition. One of the main advantages of both pre- and post-grant opposition is that it typically may be
initiated by any person with an interest to do so, and is not limited to a party against whom an infringement
action has or may be initiated. In this regard, opposition proceedings are distinguished from ordinary
judicial proceedings seeking invalidation of patents. In ordinary judicial proceedings, patent invalidity is
often initiated as a defence to alleged patent infringement (although judicial invalidation proceedings
may in some cases also be initiated as a stand-alone matter). Both pre-grant and post-grant opposition
130
Trade in medicines
procedures are adopted in recognition that patent offices and examiners are frequently overburdened,
and may grant patents on inventions that do not, in fact, meet the criteria of patentability. Administrative
proceedings leverage the knowledge and interest of private third parties to remedy improvidently granted
patents and thereby reduce the strain that would otherwise be placed on the courts. They may often be a
more cost-effective way than ordinary civil litigation to test the validity of patents.
Frequently, products that are “on patent” in one country are unpatented or otherwise “off patent” in other
countries. In part this can be explained by the fact that rarely will pharmaceutical companies choose to
incur the substantial costs of obtaining and maintaining a patent in all of the world’s markets, particularly in
light of the relatively small markets in some countries.
Even if a particular medicine, such as an antiretroviral, is patented in a given country, the government
has the option by the terms of Article 31 of the TRIPS Agreement to issue a compulsory licence either
to manufacture locally or to permit importation. If there is insufficient capacity within the country to
produce the medicine, under the WTO “waiver decision” described earlier, the government or a private
party may request that another country issue a compulsory license for export.19 Also as discussed earlier,
least developed WTO Member countries are permitted not to enforce pharmaceutical patent protection
until 2016 (or later, based on a general extension of the requirement for TRIPS compliance until 2021).
These countries may undertake domestic manufacture or importation, at least with respect to the TRIPS
Agreement, without formally issuing a compulsory licence. A number of countries are not yet Members of
the WTO and so do not have obligations under the TRIPS Agreement (although they may be party to other
international agreements that include intellectual property-related obligations).
Compulsory licensing can be a core component of a country’s patent law that is useful in ameliorating the
potentially harsh short-term consequences of patents on public health. Even if a compulsory licence is not
ultimately issued, a government can use the threat of compulsory licensing during price negotiations with
patent holders. The patent holder knows that if agreement is not reached, the government may grant a
compulsory licence to itself or its contractors (a so-called “government use” licence), or to a private party for
commercial exploitation. Governments may find that the possibility of a compulsory licence is sufficient to
moderate prices. In a growing number of cases, compulsory licences for pharmaceutical products have in
fact been issued.
Compulsory licensing tends to be controversial at the international level because the home country of the
patent holder has an interest in earning income from exploitation of the patent and may not be particularly
interested in the hardships within the country granting the compulsory licence. The exporting country
views the compulsory licence as a loss of income, while the country granting the compulsory licence may
view it as the solution to an important public health problem. A country granting a compulsory licence that
affects foreign patent holders must therefore be prepared to respond to some level of criticism from trade
officials of the exporting country, even if its actions in granting a compulsory licence are entirely lawful
under international trade and intellectual property rules.
Policy-makers should be aware that under Article 31 of the TRIPS Agreement, patent holders must receive
“adequate remuneration” in the circumstances of the case, generally in the form of a royalty, if a compulsory
licence is granted. The appropriate amount of the royalty may be the subject of debate, although there are
guidelines that may be helpful in some circumstances (14).
Article 31 leaves open to governments to determine the grounds that justify the granting of a compulsory
licence. It does, however, impose a number of requirements relating to the grant of a compulsory licence,
including the obligation to first make reasonable efforts to negotiate a voluntary licence with the patent
holder (but see the exceptions below), and to consider licences on their individual merits. Article 31 also
requires that the licence be non-exclusive and, as noted above, that adequate remuneration be paid to the
right holder.
131
Trade in medicines
The obligation to negotiate may be dispensed within the case of national emergency or other
circumstances of extreme urgency, or for public non-commercial use. It should be emphasized that the
existence of a national emergency is not a requirement for the grant of a compulsory license, but merely
relates to the requirement of prior negotiation (2, p. 73). The Doha Declaration20 re-emphasized that
governments may grant compulsory licences on grounds of their own choosing21 and that governments
have discretion to determine what constitutes a national emergency.22 The Doha Declaration also
specifically noted that HIV/AIDS, malaria, tuberculosis and other epidemics may constitute national
emergencies.23
Governments may also opt for parallel importation, which refers to the importation of drugs under patent
in the importing country that have been lawfully placed on the market outside the country. The TRIPS
Agreement leaves to WTO Members the choice of permitting parallel importation of patented medicines,
which flexibility was confirmed by paragraph 5(d) of the Doha Declaration. Parallel importation may help a
country to lower the cost of patented medicines because it allows for the purchase and importation of the
lowest-priced version of the same medicine from anywhere in the world.
The basic concept of parallel importation is somewhat controversial, and was deliberately left unaddressed
in the TRIPS Agreement (see Art. 6). Governments may address parallel importation in different ways, and
are not required to treat each form of intellectual property in the same way. Proponents of “international
exhaustion” regimes argue that patent rights should be considered exhausted (used up) once the product
is lawfully sold anywhere in the world, meaning that parallel importation into a second country can occur
even if a patent exists in that second country. Because international exhaustion facilitates global purchasing
at the lowest price, it should therefore be considered by developing country governments. (In contrast,
it has been argued that if developed countries implement international exhaustion rules, businesses may
respond by declining to offer products at lower prices in lower-income markets, since arbitrageurs could
then buy products at the lower price and resell them in the developed country market). An alternative to an
international exhaustion regime is a “national exhaustion” regime, under which the first authorized sale of
patented product exhausts rights only with respect to the country in which the sale took place. This means
that parallel importation may not be able to occur if a patent exists in the importing country. There is a third
option for “regional exhaustion” under which a patented product placed on the market in any country of
the regional group will be deemed to exhaust the patents in all members of the group, thereby facilitating
access to the lowest-priced medicines within the regional group.
Even under an international exhaustion regime, there are different schools of thought regarding the precise
circumstances under which parallel importation is permitted. Some respected commentators take the view
that pharmaceutical products lawfully placed on the market under compulsory licence may be parallel
imported, while others have rejected this view on the ground that such products have not been placed on
the market with the patent holder’s consent.24
In some countries, such as South Africa, authorization of parallel importation of patented medicines is
expressly incorporated into legislation. In many countries, rules on parallel importation are made by
judicial decision. If a country authorizes parallel importation of patented medicines, it typically must also
authorize parallel importation with respect to the patent holder’s trademark, as most pharmaceutical
product packaging will include a trademark name. Parallel importation of trademarked goods is a permitted
option under the TRIPS Agreement. Finally, because certain aspects of the packaging or documentation
accompanying pharmaceutical products may be protected by copyright, it may also be useful to formally
authorize parallel importation of any copyrighted works associated with pharmaceutical products.
20
WT/MIN(01)/Dec/2.
21
Doha Declaration paragraph 5(b).
22
Doha Declaration paragraph 5(c).
23
Doha Declaration paragraph 5(d).
24
There has not been significant commentator discussion of whether goods initially placed on the market by or with the consent of the patent holder, but in a
country where the pharmaceutical product is not patented, are subject to lawful parallel importation. The European Court of Justice approved this practice
within the European Union.
132
Trade in medicines
Article 39.3 of the TRIPS Agreement requires WTO Members to protect undisclosed regulatory data
regarding new chemical entities in the pharmaceutical sector against unfair commercial use. Some
governments have implemented this obligation by establishing marketing exclusivity periods with respect
to pharmaceutical products newly approved by public health regulatory authorities. The scope of this
marketing exclusivity obligation varies both as to the duration and as to the types of products that are
covered.
For example, the United States applies a five-year marketing exclusivity period for new chemical entities
that runs concurrently with (and therefore typically expires before) the expiration of the patent term
covering the relevant product. Marketing exclusivity generally is only granted with respect to the first
approval of the same substance or compound. However, a three-year period of marketing exclusivity
may be granted based on the conduct of significant new clinical studies that result in approvals for a new
indication, which exclusivity generally applies only to that new indication.25 With respect to biologics, the
United States employs a 12-year exclusivity period, which may in some cases be longer than the patent
period that remains at the time the product is approved for sale.
The European Union provides an “8+2+1” marketing exclusivity period. That is, there is an eight-year period
of complete exclusivity, followed by a two-year period in which generic producers are permitted to prepare
and submit applications for approval upon expiration of the exclusivity period, and a potential one-year
extension based on a new therapeutic indication showing significant clinical benefit.
Although Article 39.3 of the TRIPS Agreement requires Members to protect undisclosed regulatory data
regarding new chemical entities against unfair commercial use, it does not require this protection to be in
the form of marketing exclusivity (2, p. 63-67). There are other methods for preventing “unfair commercial
use” of regulatory data, including providing a private right of action to those submitting such data against
third parties that they claim are engaging in unfair conduct.
Potential obstacles to the introduction of generic products that can arise out of “patent linkage” with
regulatory approval procedures were discussed in section 10.2.2 above.
Article 30 of the TRIPS Agreement allows WTO Members to adopt a regulatory review or so-called “Bolar”
exception that allows generic producers to undertake the activities necessary to make a submission to
the DRA for marketing approval during the term of an originator patent. Otherwise, a prospective generic
submitter going through the process of reverse engineering, procuring or producing the necessary
chemicals, testing for bioequivalence, and so forth, might be considered to infringe rights of the patent
holder. A regulatory review exception, as discussed in the next paragraph, may be sufficiently broad to
authorize a range of third-party research regarding pharmaceutical products that are covered by patent (as
it does in the United States), but it may also be framed to cover only those activities specifically needed for
approval of generic versions of originator products. This is a matter within national discretion.
Finally, another important exception to the rights of patent holders, allowed by Article 30 of the TRIPS
Agreement, is the so-called “research exemption”. A research exemption permits persons other than the
patent holder to make use of the invention for purposes of understanding the mechanism of action and
for developing other new products. A research exemption can be broad. For example, the United States
Supreme Court (in Merck v. Integra Lifesciences, 545 U.S. 193 (2005)) held that the United States regulatory
review exception permits third parties to use patented pharmaceutical inventions for the conduct of
preclinical and clinical research on new drugs, provided only that the researcher has some reasonable
expectation that a new drug application will eventually be submitted to the United States Food and
Drug Administration, even if no such application is ever submitted. In some countries, a patent research
exemption is expressly incorporated in patent or other legislation. In other countries, such an exemption
is made by judicial decision. The scope of the patent research exemption varies rather widely among
countries.
Zeneca Inc. v. Shalala, 1999 WL 728104, at *12 (D. Md. Aug. 11, 1999); ViroPharma, Inc. v. Hamburg, 898 F.Supp.2d 1, 7 (D.D.C. 2012).
25
133
Trade in medicines
can perform the same task, even if in a somewhat less effective way; and (b) the structure of the local
pharmaceutical infrastructure that may encourage or discourage purchases of the new product. It is difficult
to create an economic model that can accurately account for these factors.
Assumptions must also be made concerning the impact of intellectual property rules on the quality and
number of new products that will be brought to market. One of the underlying theories of strengthening
intellectual property protection is that it will encourage the development of more new products. While
some level of intellectual property protection can encourage investment and thereby promote invention, it
is not necessarily true that ever stronger protection will yield larger or more rapid technical or therapeutic
gains. This is in part because new inventions often build upon older inventions. Therefore, if legal
protection of older inventions is too strong or lasts for an excessive period of time, it is not inconceivable
that such protection could slow the rate of innovation. Even where innovation is increased, policy-makers
must consider whether the adverse effects on the public arising from enhanced intellectual property
protection outweigh any additional incentives created. In short, while one needs only to observe the market
to see that patent protection is correlated with higher prices, the correlation between longer or stronger
patents and an increased rate of invention is much less straightforward.
Despite the apparent difficulties in determining how changes in intellectual property laws will affect future
invention and aggregate cost, some notable efforts have been made to reduce the uncertainty (15). In the
course of Australian and Colombian debates on the Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement (16) and
the Colombia–United States Free Trade Agreement (17), studies were prepared on the prospective impact
of the intellectual property rights chapters on the price and total cost of medicines. The International Centre
for Trade and Sustainable Development has produced a publication that assesses the impact of TRIPS-plus
provision on the price and total cost of medicines in Costa Rica (18).
Data regarding the ownership of pharmaceutical production capacity may or may not be formally compiled
by the government. However, for most countries, studies by university researchers or nongovernmental
organizations, including financial media outlets, often contain fairly detailed data regarding the character
of business ownership. In addition, most national pharmaceutical industries are organized into one or more
industry associations, which may be broken down as between local enterprises and foreign multinational
enterprises, and from which data regarding ownership patterns may be obtained. The government will, of
course, know whether there are government-owned pharmaceutical production facilities.
Although most national governments maintain data on the percentage of gross domestic product (GDP)
spent on research and development, there are also various external sources where such information is
listed. See, for example, the data centre of the UNESCO Institute for Statistics.29
It may be more difficult to determine the level of research and development specifically in the
pharmaceutical sector because this involves an aggregation of public and private data that may not
be readily available. However, it should at least be possible to determine government spending on
pharmaceutical-related research and development as a percentage of GDP, or as a percentage of the
government research and development budget.
The national patent office should maintain data on the number of patents applied for and granted with
respect to pharmaceutical products. Pharmaceutical patent applications typically include an International
Patent Classification (IPC) designation, which should permit analysis based on classification. Pharmaceutical
preparations are generally, but not exclusively, classified under IPC symbol A61K.30
9.10 Conclusion
There is no generally accepted optimal model for regulating the production and distribution of
pharmaceutical products and related supplies, including with respect to international trade. Governments
pursue a variety of policies intended to strengthen national capacity to produce and distribute
pharmaceutical products and related supplies, and a variety of policies intended to promote public access
to those products.
Domestically, Europe and the United States pursue very different policies with respect to pharmaceutical
regulation, with Europe relying heavily on price controls to moderate the impact of patented medicines
on national budgets. Although the United States pharmaceutical sector is not subject to price controls
per se, there are a wide range of regulatory measures that may influence prices. These include state
generic substitution laws, and federal regulatory measures, such as reference pricing controls used by the
Veterans Administration. The past fifteen years have witnessed a proliferation of bilateral and regional
trade agreements generally intended to reduce or eliminate barriers to the free movement of goods
and services. A significant number of these agreements include chapters covering intellectual property
rights and regulatory data with respect to pharmaceuticals, as well as chapters devoted to investment
protection. Commitments with respect to patents and regulatory data, as well as commitments with
respect to enforcement and investment protection, have raised concerns among public health authorities,
development-related multilateral institutions and nongovernmental organizations. These concerns focus on
the possibility that a broader scope of patent and regulatory data protection will adversely affect prices and
access to newer medicines, particularly among more vulnerable parts of developing country populations.
29
See http://stats.uis.unesco.org/unesco/TableViewer/document.aspx?ReportId=143&IF_Language=eng, which includes data on employment research
and development; and the OECD Main Science and Technology Indicators, 2011/2 edition, available at http://www.oecd.org/document/26/0,3343,
en_2649_37427_1901082_1_1_1_37427,00.html
30
Information regarding the classification system is available at http://www.wipo.int/classifications/ipc/en/index.html.
136
Trade in medicines
References
1. The global use of medicines: Outlook through 2016. Report by the IMS Institute for Healthcare
Informatics, 2012.
2. World Health Organization, World Intellectual Property Organization, World Trade Organization,
Promoting access to medical technologies and innovation: Intersections between public health,
intellectual property and trade. Geneva, 2012: 192–195.
3. World Health Organization. Public health, innovation and intellectual property rights. Report of
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and Public Health. Geneva, World Health
Organization, 2006.
4. World Health Organization. Local production for access to medical products: Developing a
framework to improve public health. Policy Brief, Geneva, World Health Organization. 2011.
5. Abbott FM, Correa, CM. World Trade Organization accession agreements: Intellectual property issues,
2007. Quaker United Nations Office Global Economic Issues Publication, May 2007, at p. 12, (SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1915338).
6. Abbott FM. Non-violation nullification or impairment causes of action under the TRIPS agreement
and the fifth Ministerial Conference: A warning and reminder. Geneva, Quaker United Nations Office
(Geneva) (QUNO), Occasional Paper No. 11, July 2003.
7. Abbott FM, Dukes G. Global pharmaceutical policy. Cheltenham UK, Edward Elgar Publishing, 2009:
16–61.
8. World Health Organization. Trends in local production of medicines and related technology Transfer.
Geneva, WHO, 2011.
9. WHO Regional Office for SouthEast Asia. International trade and health: a reference guide. Geneva,
WHO, 2009.
10. International encyclopedia of comparative law. ed. Viktor Knapp. Tübingen, Mohr Siebeck 1976.
11. Research and development to meet health needs in developing countries: strengthening global financing
and coordination. Report of the Consultative Expert Working Group on Research and Development:
Financing and Coordination. Geneva, WHO (2012).
12. Abbott FM. The Judgment In Novartis v. India: What The Supreme Court Of India Said. Intellectual
Property Watch, April 4, 2013 (www.ip-watch.org).
13. Regional assessment of patent and related issues and access to medicines: CARICOM member states and
the Dominican Republic (HERA) (December 31, 2009). Health Research for Action Final Report - Main
Report, Vol. 1, 2009 (SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=190997).
14. UNDP-WHO. Remuneration guidelines for non-voluntary use of a patent on medical technologies, health
economics and drugs. TCM Series No. 18. Geneva, World Health Organization, 2005 (http://www.who.
int/hiv/amds/WHOTCM2005.1_OMS.pdf ).
15. Chaudhuri S, Goldberg PK, Gia P. Estimating the effects of global patent protection in
pharmaceuticals: a case study of quinolones in India. American Economic Review, 96(5) 2006, 1477–
1514.
137
Trade in medicines
16. Drahos P, Faunce T, Goddard M et al. The FTA and the PBS: a submission to the Senate Select Committee
on the U.S.-Australia Free Trade Agreement. 2004 (https://www.google.ch/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&
frm=1&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CCkQFjAA&url=https%3A%2F%2Fwww.anu.edu.au%2Ffellows%2
Fpdrahos%2Freports%2Fpdfs%2F2004ftapbssubmission.pdf&ei=uKd2Va2PA4TfywPPrIKICQ&usg=A
FQjCNGVErUZefKXh6koLZHYsRrZzYXLuA&bvm=bv.95039771,d.bGQ).
17. Cortes Gamba ME et al. Modelo prospectivo del impacto de la protección a la propiedad intelectual
sobre el acceso a medicamentos en Colombia [Prospective model of the impact of intellectual
property protection on access to medications in Colombia]. Bogotá, Organización Panamericana
de la Salud, (PAHO), Fundación Instituto para la investigación del medicamento en los sistemas de
salud, (IFARMA) 2004.
138
Trade in medicines
Abbott FM, Van Puymbroeck RV. Compulsory licensing for public health: giving effect to the decision
on implementation of paragraph 6 of the Doha Declaration on the Trips Agreement and Public
Health – a guide and model documents. Working Paper 61. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2005.
Bermudez J, Oliveira M, eds. Intellectual property in the context of the WTO TRIPS Agreement:
challenges for public health. Rio de Janeiro, Oswaldo Cruz Foundation, 2004.
Boyle J. The public domain: enclosing the commons of the mind, Yale University Press, 2008.
Chamas C. Developing innovative capacity in Brazil to meet health needs. Report of the Centre for the
Management of Intellectual Property in Health Research and Development to the Commission on
Intellectual Property Rights. Geneva, World Health Organization, 2005.
Dukes G. The law and ethics of the pharmaceutical industry. San Diego, CA, Elsevier, 2006.
Fink C, Reichenmiller P. Tightening TRIPS: the intellectual property provisions of recent US free trade
agreements. Trade Note 20. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2005.
Ministry of Trade and Industry. Science and Technology Plan 2010: sustaining innovation-driven
growth. Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, 2006.
Moïse P, Docteur E. Pharmaceutical pricing and reimbursement policies in Mexico. Health Working
Papers. Paris, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Directorate for
Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, Health Committee, 2007.
Roffe P, Tansey G, Vivas-Eugui D, eds. Negotiating health: intellectual property and access to medicines.
London, Earthscan, 2005.
Tayler Y. Battling HIV/AIDS: a decision makers’ guide to the procurement of medicines and related
supplies. Washington, DC, World Bank, 2004.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development and International Centre for Trade and
Sustainable Development. Resource book on TRIPS and development. Cambridge University Press,
2005.
United States Department of Health and Human Services. Report on prescription drug importation.
United States Department of Health and Human Services, Task Force on Drug Importation, 2004.
United States Federal Trade Commission. To promote innovation: the proper balance of competition
and patent law and policy. United States Federal Trade Commission, 2003.
United States Government Accountability Office. New drug development: science, business,
regulatory, and intellectual property issues cited as hampering drug development efforts. Report
GAO-07-49. United States Government Accountability Office, 2006.
139
Trade in medicines
World Health Organization. Local Production for Access to Medical Products Developing a
Framework to Improve Public Health. Policy Brief, Geneva, World Health Organization, 2011.
World Health Organization. Public health, innovation and intellectual property rights. Report of
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and Public Health. Geneva, World Health
Organization, 2006.
WHO, WIPO and WTO. Promoting access to medical technologies and innovation: Intersections
between public health, intellectual property and trade. Geneva, 2012.
140
Contributors
Chapter 1 Trade and health - the linkages
Richard Smith, Chantal Blouin, Nick Drager
Chapter 2 Policy coherence in trade and health
Chantal Blouin, Nick Drager
Chapter 3 Capacity building in trade and health
Alka Bhatia
Chapter 4 Macroeconomic aspects of trade and health
Richard Smith, Chantal Blouin
Chapter 5 Implementing trade commitments with a public health perspective
David P. Fidler
Chapter 6 Regional trade agreements and health services
Mina Mashayeki, Elisabeth Tuerk
Chapter 7 Trade in health services
Pierre Sauvé, Chantal Blouin, Aniket Bhushan, Olivier Cattaneo
Chapter 8 Trade liberalization, food, nutrition and health
Corinna Hawkes, Delia Grace, Anne Marie Thow
Chapter 9 Trade in medicines
Frederick Abbott
Contributors:
Frederick Abbott, Edward Ball Eminent Scholar Professor of International Law at Florida State University College of Law
Peter Beyer, Senior Advisor, Department of Essential Medicines & Health Products, WHO
Alka Bhatia, Economic Advisor and Head of Strategy & Policy Unit at United Nations Development Programme (UNDP)
Aniket Bhushan, Adjunct Research Professor at the Norman Paterson School of International Affairs, Carleton University
Canada
Chantal Blouin, Researcher, Institut national de santé publique du Québec, Canada
Olivier Cattaneo, Lecturer, Jackson Institute for Global Affairs, Yale University, and Senior Trade Specialist with the World
Bank, Washington, D.C.
Nick Drager, former Director of the Department of Ethics, Equity, Trade and Human Rights, WHO; Honorary Professor,
London School of Hygiene & Tropical Medicine; Professor of Practice, McGill University; Adjunct Professor, University of
Ottawa; and Senior Fellow, Graduate Institute, Geneva.
David P. Fidler, James Louis Calamaras Professor, Indiana University Maurer School of Law, and Associate Fellow, Centre
on Global Health Security, Chatham House
Delia Grace, Program Leader Food Safety and Zoonoses, International Livestock Research Institute, Kenya
Corinna Hawkes, Honorary Fellow at the City University London Centre for Food Policy, and Senior Adviser at the
Leverhulme Center for Integrative Research into Agriculture and Health, London
Mina Mashayekhi, Head of Trade Negotiations and Commercial Diplomacy Branch of UNCTAD’s Division on
International Trade in Goods, Services, and Commodities
Zafar Mirza, Coordinator Public Health, Innovation & Intellectual Property at Department of Essential Medicines &
Health Products, WHO
Pierre Sauvé, Director of External Programmes and Academic Partnerships and faculty member at the World Trade
Institute, University of Bern, Switzerland
Richard Smith, Professor of Health System Economics, Faculty of Public Health and Policy, London School of Hygiene
and Tropical Medicine
Anne Marie Thow, Lecturer in health policy at the Menzies Centre for Health Policy, University of Sydney
Elisabeth Tuerk, Chief, International Investment Agreements section of the Division on Investment and Enterprise,
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD)
141
142
Health and trade have long been interconnected. The increasing trade of medical products
and of health-related services provides many opportunities for improving people’s lives world-
wide. However, the deepened liberalization of trade has also posed new challenges to national
health authorities. National health authorities are confronted with heightened trade in harm-
ful products impacting nutrition habits and associated rise in non-communicable diseases,
increased movement of health personnel, medical tourism, and higher levels of intellectual
property protection impacting medicine prices.
Trade and Health: Towards building a national strategy provides useful background informa-
tion for policy-makers to formulate a coherent national response to trade and health-related
issues. With free trade agreements being negotiated continuously, often without sufficient
involvement of health experts, the core evidence presented in this book can enable health
policy-makers to engage, where health and trade linkages occur, to protect health and thus
strike a balance between public health and the further liberalization of global trade.