Chapter 4. Management Accounting in The Public Sector
Chapter 4. Management Accounting in The Public Sector
Chapter 4. Management Accounting in The Public Sector
Management
accounting in the public sector
As the public sector is managing taxpayers’ monies, appropriate management accounting
systems appear as an important feature of democratic life and the exercise of political actors’
accountability to citizens (Dorf, 2006; Freeman, 2006; Mashaw, 2006; Morgan, 2006; Rosner,
Markowitz, & Milbank Memorial Fund., 2006). Accordingly, public sector management
accounting is concerned with the producing and disclosing of figures aimed at proving the
righteous use of taxpayers’ monies, emphasising economy, efficiency and effectiveness of
public spending, performance oftentimes being collapsed to polity’s value for money
(Arnaboldi & Azzone, 2010; Jacobs, 1998).
The need for appropriate management control systems is especially vivid at times of financial
distress when resources are under major constraints, as evidenced by the Greek debt crisis
since 2008 (Morales, Gendron, & Guénin-Paracini, 2014). The problem is accentuated when a
country finds itself losing its financial sovereignty, being placed under financial control from
parties other than their own citizens, such as countries under IMF or World Bank programmes
(Annisette, 2004; Collins, Holzmann, & Mendoza, 1997; Lane, 2012; Neu & Ocampo, 2007;
Neu, Ocampo Gomez, Graham, & Heincke, 2006; Neu, Rahaman, Everett, & Akindayomi,
2010; Reinhart & Rogoff, 2011; Sikka, 2009; Uddin & Hopper, 2003; Valcke, 2010).
Governments and parliaments are demanded an account of the fair utilisation of the resources
they have been granted or loaned.
Having appropriate management accounting systems in the public sector has appeared as a
growing concern accompanying the so-called “modernisation” of government and polity has
accompanied or caused calls for greater public accountability and polity’s modernising
(Buchanan, 1986; Buchanan & Musgrave, 1999; Niskanen, 1971, 1986; Romer & Rosenthal,
1979). Grounded in a contestation of the public sector’s legitimacy and usefulness, the
proponents of modernisation argue that the public sector is a tool of political oppression and
is economically inefficient. Accordingly, even though the public sector is perceived as an
unnecessary evil, owing to its existence, needs for modernising it has been grounded in the
idea that it would benefit from learning from private sector management (Hayek, 1979). This
ideology has instilled the principles of a New Public Management (Andersson & Tenglad,
2009; Arnaboldi & Azzone, 2005; Brignall & Modell, 2000; Broadbent & Laughlin, 1998;
Clarke & Lapsley, 2004; Gendron, Cooper, & Townley, 2001; Hood, 2000; Hood & Scott,
1996; Tambulasi, 2007; Watkins & Arrington, 2007).
The management accounting concerns that have emerged from New Public Management’s
rhetoric have been implicitly underlid by the idea that the public sector is too prominent or
inefficient, the private sector being better at delivering a similar service. Various forms have
been promoted and diffused worldwide to instil a management culture borrowed from the
private sectors, such as Public-Private Partnerships (Broadbent & Laughlin, 2003b; Grimsey
& Lewis, 2005; Shaoul, Stafford, & Stapleton, 2012), privatisation (Carter & Mueller, 2006;
Craig & Amernic, 2008; Freeman, 2006; Josiah, Burton, Gallhofer, & Haslam, 2010; Jupe,
2009; McCartney & Stittle, 2006; Morales et al., 2014; Rahaman, Everett, & Neu, 2007;
Uddin & Hopper, 2001, 2003), the Private Finance Initiative in the UK (Asenova & Beck,
2010; Khadaroo, 2008) or just subcontracting relationships (Johansson, 2003; Mouritsen,
1999).
– 1 / 59 –
Management control in the public sector is the utmost form of democratic activity and
vitality, since this imposes a full transparency of public authorities’ actions. Dealing with
taxpayers’ monies and deciding on citizens’ and residents’ day-to-day life, controlling public
authorities’ action appears as the natural offshoot of the reasons for which they were initially
elected. Based on what these controls reveal, citizens can express their satisfaction or
dissatisfaction with how the country is run, namely through their votes. Controls in the public
sector rest upon specific financial management and budgeting as well as specific public policy
controls. In order to clarify the management accounting concerns at play in the public sector,
this chapter is very progressive. Borrowing from Public Administration Science and Public
Policy, it first develops the realm of the public sector, answering the question of what falls
within the public sector. Next, it exposes the main manifestation of management accounting
in the public sector: budgeting. Lastly, public policy controls are exposed, including costing,
performance management and execution control
the main controls in place in the public sector and the challenges these raise.
– 2 / 59 –
(Dreveton & Rocher, 2010; Sauviat, 2016). Beneath the central government is the region in
charge of economic development and public railway; below is the county (département) in
charge of public transport other than rail, education and social policy. At the bottom of the
administrative hierarchy are municipalities in charge of primary schools, culture and sports
and housing. In Scandinavian countries, beneath the central State are municipalities
responsible for locally implementing and executing most dimensions of the public policy
decided upon by the central government (Sauviat, 2016).
At the other extreme of the administrative spectrum are federal countries characterised by the
existence of a central state and government in charge mostly of international matters –
Defence, Foreign Policy, Currency – (Alstine, 2002; Burgess, 2006; Scott, 2011). Such
federal states are the United States of America, Germany, Australia, Belgium, Switzerland,
India or Brazil. Depending on the depth of federalism in the country, federated entities’ public
service takes different forms. For instance, in Switzerland, where federalism is most
advanced, the public service is orchestrated at the canton level whilst the federal public
service is minimal. In Belgium, federated entities are called regions and are in charge of
guaranteeing that federal policy does not undermine local language and culture. Accordingly,
regional governments are by default controlling federal policy’s local applicability and supply
if it is considered they are endangered (Husson, 2016). Similarly, in German federalism,
Länder through the Bundesrat control that federal policy does not trespass on local
governments’ competencies (Gunlicks, 2003; Heinz, 2016; Umbach, 2002).
Between these two extremes – centralised vs. federal countries –, numerous options exist,
sometimes borrowing from one model and sometimes from the other. Such is the case in
Spain where provinces are by default responsible for most of public policy matters excepting
– Catalonia and the Basque Country – these two provinces benefit from greater autonomy
enabling them to collect and administer tax at their convenience, regardless of what decisions
are made by the central government (Ruano, 2016).
In sum, what is generally understood by the State covers many different realities resulting in
differentiated forms of accountability demands and needs for management accounting. When
power is distant and centralised, accountability demands are greater than in localised power
and decision-making (Rose & Miller, 1992; Uddin & Hopper, 2001). This implies that the
civil service and its achievements in a municipality and at the central government level are not
perceived in the same way and that different accounts are demanded.
– 3 / 59 –
Individual responsibility is the core issue. Accordingly, social services and public services are
quasi-inexistent and are of relatively low quality. In between, he positions two other
countries: France and Germany. France is positioned near the United Kingdom as a liberal-
conservative model. Society rests upon the myth of social cohesion at the same time as it
claims individual responsibility as a value. He observes two kinds of social services. One
operates as in Sweden and rests upon social cohesion. The other operates like in the United
Kingdom. Esping-Andersen notes that the first model applies to people who are not social
outsiders, whereas the second applies to actual outsiders. Like the United Kingdom, France
forsakes its poorest people. Lastly, between France and Sweden, the Esping-Andersen
positions Germany as a social-conservative model. This country faces a similar situation to
France but seems to privilege social cohesion, even if resources are not sufficient. The
diagram below summarises the typology.
Since the collapse of the USSR and the institutionalisation of globalisation, each country has
been arrayed in accordance with four cultural models in Europe: Nordic countries, Anglo-
Saxon countries, Latin countries and Germanic countries, as summarised in the figure
hereafter.
Social Social Liberal Liberal model
model conservative conservative
model model
Nordic Sweden
countries Norway
Finland
Denmark
Iceland
Germanic Germany
countries Austria
Switzerland
Belgium
Luxembourg
Latin France
countries Italy
Spain
Portugal
Anglo- United
Saxon Kingdom
countries Republic of
Ireland
Netherlands
Poland
Hungary
Czech
Republic
Slovak
Republic
– 4 / 59 –
Figure 4.2. The four models developed
It proceeds from Esping-Andersen’s model that the public service’s shape and action scope
varies across countries. Notwithstanding differences, its aims, managing and structuring
remain relatively homogeneous worldwide. This is especially vivid at the civil servants’ level.
– 5 / 59 –
they choose and whereby they relinquish everything a private-sector employee could expect
(high compensation, promotions, career path choices, etc.)
– 6 / 59 –
EU member-state’s government if a national law or decree undermines the liberty of press,
women’s rights such as. restrictions on abortion right or minorities’ rights as with anti-LGBT
actions in Poland and Hungary (Mulder, 2016; Slootmaeckers & Touquet, 2016).
– 7 / 59 –
colonised by corruption, clientelism and other forms of nepotism (Josiah et al., 2010; Orchard
& Strutton, 1994; Uddin & Hopper, 2001, 2003).
Notwithstanding this neoliberal legacy, publicly owned companies still exist and remain
prevalent in numerous countries’ economy, which raises the question of their raison d’être.
Traditionally, there are three main reasons for making a company fall within governmental
action scope. Whatever the rationale for making a company a public service is, a political
logic is at play rather than economic. That is, although it can appear counter-intuitive or
economically counter-productive a company be public, it may well be politically justified. It
is this political dimension that needs to be understood. In other words, owning companies is
not necessarily evil for a government, be it national or local: this responds to local, specific
political concerns: a publicly owned company serves a public policy purpose and objective.
Firstly, a company can be run publicly rather than privately when it operates on what
economists have called “non-contestable markets” (Baumol, 1982). Those characterise
industries where entry costs are so high and return so unpredictable that private actors are
unlikely to undertake such an investment (Olson, 1974). Given the sums of money required,
these investments often appear as very specific. Not just is it a major loss quitting the market
in case of failure but also it is very difficult to resell these assets, deemed too specific to be
repurchased by another private actor (Lyons, 1995).
Secondly, a private company could take the activity over and charge citizens for the service.
The concern however is that the costs incurred by the private company may result in users
being charged high amounts of money for the service. Confronted with this situation,
governmental authorities can choose between two options. Either they pay a fee to the private
company for undertaking this activity and subsidise its use. Or they decide that is shall be
publicly run. In the former case, the main issue is the difficulty to control the costs eventually
incurred by the private company, the terms and conditions of this privilege granted to a
private business to run an activity in a monopoly situation. Also, controlling service quality
– 8 / 59 –
may be very difficult and expensive. In other words, there is no guarantee that the public
service is being run in an economic, effective and efficient way (Davies, 2016).
In the other situation, governmental authorities consider that, because of the risks associated
with the private running of a public service, this should be publicly managed
(Ernst_&_Young_LLP, 1994). The assumption is that, by keeping the public service public,
governmental authorities ensure the continuity and quality of service delivery at the same time
as its costs can be managed. Consequently, even though users pay for the service, this latter is
publicly subsidised to a large extent. Such is usually the case of public transport in most
European regions, where local governments have shares in companies otherwise privately
owned (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2018). This allows them to be on these companies’ board and
partake in decision-making, and this always under the purview of maximising the cost-
quality-continuity combination for tax-paying citizens. Resultantly, most of the time, public
transport companies are semi-private, with a significant share resorting to local governments
(Dienel & Schiefelbusch, 2009).
Thirdly, public authorities can decide that certain industries or companies have an activity
falling within the remit of industrial policy and thereby deserve to be publicly owned (Arrow,
1974). Contribution to industrial policy can be understood as an activity deemed especially
strategic for public authorities, so that having a non-publicly owned company may undermine
sovereignty. If this activity is led by a private company, public policy will be contingent on
what this company’s management decides. For instance, in Australia, utility companies are
privately owned. In 2015, the government complained that utility bills had skyrocketed and
become unbearable for the population. These companies being privately owned, the federal
government was unable to influence price-making. Contradistinctively, in most European
countries, especially France, utility companies are state-owned, so that prices are regulated
and energy is very affordable (Gémes, 2015; Usumanu, 2017).
Or, when company activity is strategic for public authorities’ sovereignty, there is a risk that,
being initially privately owned, it falls into the hands of a foreign country. The danger
confronting public authorities is that the exercise of their sovereignty be influenced by a
foreign country. In order to avert such critical situations, it is not unusual that these fall within
the public realm (Buchanan, 1998; Fonte, 2011; Mitchell & Fazi, 2017). Such cases have been
concerns in Europe (Le Corre & Sepulchre, 2016), the United States (U.S.-
China_Economic_and_Security_Review_Commission, 2017), Australia and New Zealand
(Huang & Austin, 2015) since 2010, as Chinese investors have purchased significant shares in
companies perceived as strategic for these countries, especially in the energy industry (Mines
in Australia), farming and agriculture (New Zealand and Europe) or electronics with
applications to Defence (the US). In response, these countries’ governments have either
issued new laws and regulations averting such cases to occur again and have endeavoured to
partly renationalise some of these critical companies.
When public authorities own or control companies, this is not necessarily in full. When a
company appears as critical for a government, what is needed is either a majority share
enabling to benefit from external investors’ funding with little control or a minority share
enabling to vet decisions. Depending on the type of other stockholders these companies are
likely to have (investments funds or other national industrial organisations), public
authorities’ share may vary. There is no golden rule of what is public authorities’ optimal
share. What is certain is that it is not necessarily 100%.
Lastly, it also appears that public authorities may partly or totally nationalise private
companies for internal political reasons and no geopolitical or economic justification. Such
can happen when a major national company is confronted with financial distress. In this case,
a possible bankruptcy would result in massive redundancy plans in the country with all the
social, economic and political consequences this can have for a government. Even in
– 9 / 59 –
neoliberal countries, such as the United States or the United Kingdom, it often happens that
governments bail out or nationalise defaulted private companies. For instance, early 2008,
confronted with Northern Rock’s bankruptcy, the British government decided to nationalise it
so as to avoid that nationals would lose their lifetime savings. This could have caused
people’s incapability of repaying their mortgages, thereby leading to the burst of the estate
market, making the country enter into a major financial and economic crisis (Brummer,
2008).
Just as with these companies’ capital structure, companies deemed strategic for a government
are different from country to country. The strategic dimension pertains to national political
and geopolitical priorities. This said, companies operating in the Defence industry as well as
utilities are symbols of national sovereignty and independence. These are generally publicly
owned or controlled. In a country like the United Arab Emirates, whose strategic priority is to
be the international civil aviation hub, it is crucial that not just the Dubai and Abu Dhabi
airports be publicly owned and controlled but also airlines – Emirates and Etihad – (Cole,
2013; Wilson, 2007). What is strategic for the United Arab Emirates is not as much for other
countries such as Malaysia or South Africa where strategic concerns are different.
– 10 / 59 –
2.1. Expenses as public policy priorities
Expenses in the public sector represent public policy choices and the priorities articulated and
decided upon by the government and the Parliament. Each of these priorities has a practical
implication for citizens’ life and financial consequences for taxpayers. Accordingly, it is
crucial to understand how these priorities are translated into financial terms and more
specifically into expenses. These comprise of civil servants’ wages, materials and equipment,
overheads, machines and buildings as well as subsidies and tax returns. Some of these
expenses can be easily known in advance as they are fixed, regardless of public policy
priorities. Some others, linked to economic circumstances, are difficult to anticipate and
forecast and are variable.
– 11 / 59 –
Paradoxically, when public policy spending is intense, recruiting valuable civil servants may
be difficult, which can be explained by two factors. On one hand, intense public policy may
be the counterpart of strong economic activity. In this case, talented people would privilege
better paid positions in the private sector (Aguar do Monte, 2017; Yassin & Langot, in press).
On the other hand, the public sector is known for growing counter-cyclically in order to avert
the impacts of economic difficulties on people (Carpenter, Doverspike, & Migue, 2012;
Maczulskij, 2013). In this situation, the number of applicants can be very high without them
necessarily offering the skills needed by the civil service (Carpenter et al., 2012; Elderei,
2017).
– 12 / 59 –
Figure 4.3. Budgeting civil servants’ wages
The manageability of wages in the civil service is very low and appears as a difficult task for
governments. Owing to the concern of employing civil servants for a lifetime, it appears more
and more that some positions, even though they are filled, will not be on a civil servant’s
status. In most developed countries, sessional staff becomes more and more in number and
weight (Bergh et al., 2017; Liguori & Steccolini, in press; Modell, 2001). Also, through the
partial or full privatisation or subcontracting of activities, governments displace civil servants’
wages to a different line on the budget, averting the incurring of a lifetime commitment’s
costs.
– 13 / 59 –
Case n°3. The Champs-Élysées Post Office
Public service’s discontinuity
Until 2010, the French Post was owning the buildings in which it was operating. Post
offices were owned in the public company’s name. On January 1st 2011, as the public
company was about to be privatised, the government decided to sell and lease-back some
properties, including the building on the Champs-Élysées Avenue in Paris. The new tenant
set a monthly rent amounting c.15,000 euros. As this post office was the largest in France
and therefore that with the highest activity level, affording such a rent was not a problem.
With inflation and the increase in property prices in Paris, in 2010, the rent reached over
30,000 euros. The post office’s activity was not sufficient to cover this rent and all other
expenses associated with it (wages, equipment, materials and other overheads).
Management endeavoured to renegotiate contract’s terms and conditions, which the
landlord rejected. As the need for a post office in this touristic area was very vivid, postal
and governmental authorities found themselves confronted with a dilemma: pay or leave.
Paying this financially unbearable rent would result in increasing the cost of public policy
at the taxpayer’s expense. On the other hand, leaving would mean that public policy is
discontinued and that the public service fails. Authorities opted for the section solution:
they quit and relocated in a cheaper building in a side-street a few blocks away. The new
premises were smaller and less prestigious than before, but rent was back about monthly
15,000 euros.
Concretely, buildings and properties owned by the public service are those hosting the
following types of activities (the list below is not exhaustive):
- Public Schools;
- Public hospitals;
- Tax Offices;
- Police Stations;
- Fire Stations;
- Military Bases;
- Public Cultural Institutions (museums, theatres, etc.);
- Public Stadiums;
- Train stations;
- Harbours;
- Etc.
Likewise, machines and equipment are needed by the public service for polity, the principles
being very similar to those guiding property. These may be needed when public policy
requires a transformation activity of materials into a final good or service. But also, these may
be needed in the maintenance activity orchestrated by the public service. As with property’s
public ownership, the principle is that civil servants must be available on call in case of
emergency whilst public sector employees are not necessarily. In order to ensure that the
public service can be run even in the time of a crisis, public ownership of equipment and
machines is deemed important (Orchard & Strutton, 1994). Such machines and equipment can
be represented in the non-exhaustive list below:
- Military vehicles and machinery;
- Fire department’s vehicles, garments and equipment;
- Ministerial and presidential vehicles;
- Toolkits in schools or hospitals;
– 14 / 59 –
- Blackboards in schools;
- Hospital beds and medical equipment;
- Snow-removing machines for winter;
- Seaside rescue boats;
- Etc.
In the civil service’s budget, fixed and overhead expenses are forecast more or less as in the
private sector. An additional constraint imposes itself on public authorities, as these assets are
owned in the name of polity and are managed through taxpayers’ monies: their aging and
need for maintenance and the subsequent anticipation of materials to purchase. Likewise, a
new public policy priority may result in need for new properties, which must be anticipated.
Future properties’ acquisition and maintenance costs fall within the remit of the public
service’s budget. The formula below summarises wages’ budgeting in the civil service.
– 15 / 59 –
exemption for donors. This can be in full or in part, leading to an equivalent amount not being
collected or being reimbursed by the tax office (Anheier & Salamon, 1994, 1996, 1997;
Havens, O'Herlihy, & Schervish, 2006; Rathgeb-Smith & Grønberg, 2006). For instance, in
France, 66% of donated amounts are tax-deductible (Archambault, 1997). In the United
Kingdom, any pound donated to a registered charity is matched by the tax office, de facto
resulting in the same public expense (Havens et al., 2006; Sargeant, 1999; Trussel & Parsons,
2007).
A trend encouraged by the spread of corporate social responsibility and sustainable
development has led individuals to undertake green investments supported by public
authorities. Depending on the country, the financial effort made in the name of environmental
policy varies. This can consist of VAT deductions from the price of “green” equipment or the
deduction of such investments’ costs from taxable income or income tax for people
undertaking these. Such “green” tax returns are aimed at contributing to the nation’s
environmental policy by encouraging environment-friendly behaviours, such as home
insulation, solar panel installation, heat pumps, electric cars or bicycles, etc. (Aidt, 2010;
Mannberg, Jansson, Pettersson, Brännlund, & Lindgren, 2014; Shazmin, Sipan, & Sapri,
2016).
In the budget, the tax return amount, exemption and decrease costs as well as their cost of
opportunity must be anticipated and accounted for. Based upon economic forecasts, the
Ministry of Finance administration can estimate the number of companies, households and
non-residents likely to claim tax back at the same time as the amounts they for which are
likely to apply. These also include tax losses that could be ascribed to changes in economic
circumstance. For instance, an economic crisis leading to higher unemployment may result in
lower income tax from newly unemployed people. For those tax returns disconnected from
public policy choices, economic forecasts are sufficient. However, when tax returns proceed
directly from public policy choices, polity’s direct and indirect impact must be estimated over
the project’s duration: number of taxpayers directly concerned, agenda and a schedule of their
costs. It is this estimate that comes to feed to the budget. The formula below summarises
fiscal policy’s budgeting.
Fiscal policy = Recurrent tax returns + Economy’s negative impact on planned tax collection
+ Tax return by public policy + Fiscal cost of opportunity by public policy
– 16 / 59 –
Figure 4.5. Budgeting fiscal policy costs
– 17 / 59 –
calls for a New Public Management and have led to hybrid situations: profit-making
companies in the context of strategic public policy. Such state-owned private companies
enable private a combination of public and private equity, the assumption being that public
funding can be leveraged by private funding and therefore be of benefit to the public
(Kurunmäki, 2004; Kurunmäki & Miller, 2006, 2011; Miller, Kurunmäki, & O'Leary, 2008;
Parker, 2012). The expenses incurred by governmental authorities pertain to their
stockholder’s activity, through possible subsidies, bailouts or contributions to equity increase
(Cuervo-Cazurra, 2018). Usually, such is the case of public transport or water utilities
(Argento & van Helden, 2009; Crowther, Carter, & Cooper, 2006; Dienel & Schiefelbusch,
2009; Ogden, 1995; Rahaman et al., 2007; Wouters, Kokke, Theeuwes, & van Donselaar,
1999).
The third form is that of outsourcing public policy to non-profits and contribute to their
financing through public subsidies (Jenkins, 2006; Minkoff & Powell, 2006; Ostrower &
Stone, 2006; Rathgeb-Smith & Grønberg, 2006). This way of outsourcing to non-profits can
take on two forms. The most common form consists of calling for applicants and paying an
annual subsidy to the one winning the market. In the other, less common form, the non-profit
organisation conducts its mission on public authorities’ behalf qua surrogates for the public
sector and contributing to a form of public realm privatisation. In this respect, the non-profit
whither polity has been devolved charges public authorities based upon its activity level,
thereby engaging in commercial transactions (Hardy & Ballis, 2013).
Privatisation, which often occurs with social work and other activities charities can take over,
exacerbates accountability demands articulated by public authorities (Freeman, 2006;
Furneaux & Ryan, 2015). This process results in stringent demands for ‘public accountability’
(Freeman, 2006; Sinclair, 1995). Non-profits are confronted with an imperative to take
responsibility for public policymakers whose decisions they are applying. The legal literature
introduces the notion of ‘surrogacy’ because non-profit acts in the name of the public sector
thereby facing the same obligations towards beneficiaries or clients but without having the
same rights or authority (Dorf, 2006).
A surrogate for public authorities, the non-profit organisation acting in their name is expected
to render an account to those authorities, their ‘public accountability’ thereby embracing
features of what Sinclair (1995, p.222) calls ‘political or Westminster accountability’.
Imposed by legal authorities, reports are demanded from citizens accounting for the use of
taxpayers’ monies and the conduct of polity. This ‘political accountability’ finds itself
necessarily resting upon ‘technocratic’ means of accountability (Joannidès, 2012; Mashaw,
2006). Such formal means of accountability appear detrimental to informal and relational
accountability (Hardy & Ballis, 2013). That is, accountability demands appear as quasi-legal
and judicial pressures exerted by public authorities on non-profits and operate at two levels.
First, non-profits must prove that they have used taxpayers’ monies consistently with the
political promises made by the government to citizens (Furneaux & Ryan, 2015; Mashaw,
2006; Morgan, 2006; Morris, McGregor-Lowndes, & Tarr, 2015). These points have long
been theorised in interdisciplinary and legal research on non-profits but have thus far drawn
little academic interest in accounting scholarship. To date, the seminal piece of work is on
Westminster’s authority over the Church of England and related charities (Laughlin, 1988,
1990), followed more recently by publications on the effects of Statement of Recommended
Practice (SORP) on UK non-profits (Connolly & Hyndman, 2001; Connolly, Hyndman, &
McConville, 2013; Dhanani & Connelly, 2012).
Second, given the privatisation of governmental activities and the associated development of
government-to-non-profit relationships, stricter accountability demands arise concerning how
the mission has been conducted. Non-profits’ accountability consists of proving not only that
money has been righteously used but also that the reason governmental authorities have
– 18 / 59 –
granted them funding is actualised, abiding by public policy standards (Rathgeb-Smith &
Grønberg, 2006). Such requirements are especially vivid when non-profits have a strong
ideological agenda, if not advocacy activities, which is often true with religious
denominations and associated charities (Hardy & Ballis, 2013; Jenkins, 2006; Minkoff &
Powell, 2006). Public authorities tend to authoritatively demand accounts of mission
completion and of political relative neutrality; public funding is implicitly conditioned on
limited activism or militancy from the non-profit under scrutiny (Jenkins, 2006). Based on
these bureaucratic obligations imposed on non-profits, the discharging of accountability is one
of the utmost duties of their boards (Ostrower & Stone, 2006). One of these duties in
particular consists of designing and implementing adequate accountability systems aimed at
responding to these ‘technocratic’ demands from governmental authorities.
Unlike public policy done directly by the public service, budgeting outsourced activities is
simpler and costs generally more predictable. When the form chosen consists of paying an
annual lump sum to a private company or a subsidy to a not-for-profit organisation, the
amount is known in advance, even if it can be renegotiated each year, depending on economic
circumstances and activity level. Given the budgetary cycle, these sums can be anticipated.
What is more difficult to anticipate are the costs incurred by public authorities in their role as
stockholder in a hybrid company. Some of such company’s activities may develop so fast that
its stockholders are regularly solicited to contribute in increase in its equity. Conversely,
when a publicly owned hybrid company is confronted with an unprecedented crisis, it may be
needed to bail it out, resulting in unexpected high amounts of public funding, such as AIG and
Northern Rock when they failed (Brummer, 2008; Cunningham, 2013; Graham, 2008).
Precisely because these are unexpected, they cannot be explicitly budgeted but may be
accounted for as provisions for risks. The formula below summarises the budgeting of
outsourced activities.
– 19 / 59 –
offices (e.g. Catalonia in Spain). Basically, seven types of taxes and fees are collected to
finance polity priorities: company tax, household, Value Added Tax (a.k.a. known as Goods
and Services Tax), stamp duty and Council rates, excises, and tax on energy. What is
understood as fiscal policy relates to the interplay between all these taxes and fees and reflects
a nation’s priorities. Some countries encourage households and labour by taxing companies
and financial activities. With globalisation and the ease wherewith companies and private
investors can leave a country and relocate overseas, there has been a fiscal turn since the
2000s in many Western countries consisting of lowering tax on corporations and financial
activities (Justman, Thisse, & van Ypersele, 2005; Morer, Ansel, Michelik, & Girandola,
2017).
Company tax = Corporate profit forecast x tax rate – Tax return (tax basis x tax rate)
– 20 / 59 –
– Bankruptcy – Launch
Income tax = GDP per social class x weight of each social class x tax rate – Tax shield
– 21 / 59 –
2.2.1.3. Value Added Tax
The third known tax collected from public authorities is the Value Added Tax, a.k.a. Goods
and Services Tax. This tax is ultimately paid by the end user, provided this latter is based in
the same country as the one where the good or service was purchased. This rule applies to
most countries in the world except the European Union, where each country is considered a
state within a sort of a federation (Siemens (von), 1921). Paid by the end customer, VAT is
often summarised as a consumption tax paid by households. In other words, any service or
good sold within a country to its residents is subjected to VAT. Ultimately paid by the
customer, VAT is not directly paid by companies. In its philosophy, VAT is a tax on what
results from the transformation process. Supposedly, at each stage in the transformation
process, the profit margin made by a company is taxed. In this process, companies pay their
suppliers, including VAT, at the same time as they collect VAT from their corporate clients.
More or less, tax collection and tax payment are balanced, hence companies are not really
impacted by the effect of VAT (Siemens (von), 1921).
Tax collection is contingent upon consumption level but can find itself very lucrative for
public policy’s financing. It therefore confronts governments with a dilemma. On one hand,
being a consumption tax, VAT appears as unjust, mostly affecting those households whose
resources are spent on consumption more than on savings or investment. That is, VAT
allegedly affects households on low income in proportion more than households on higher
income. The former spend most of their earnings in day-to-day consumption whilst the latter
do not spend the same proportion of their income. Resultantly, the purchase power of those
people on low income is more strongly affected than that of others, thereby creating a form of
injustice (Siemens (von), 1921).
On the other hand, its grounding in local consumption supposedly makes tax evasion difficult
at the same time as this generates high resources. For governments, temptation can be high to
apply a high VAT rate whither taxpayers are captive. This temptation may be aggravated by
the fact that, in most countries, this tax payment is not perceived by customers. When selling
prices are all inclusive, although the amount of VAT paid is mentioned, customers do not
really realise they paid a tax.
Given the highlighted injustice caused by VAT payment, numerous countries have opted for
differentiated tax rates, depending on the goods: first-necessity or vital goods are taxed less
than others. Differentiating tax rates according to the type of product is aimed at reducing the
impact of the economic and social injustice a consumption tax raises.
When budgeting resources generated from VAT collection, public authorities need to rely on
economic models highlighting the class weighting in GDP as well as consumption propensity
for each class. In case of a single VAT rate, such a model is sufficient to articulate the total
amount of tax that can be collected. If, which is more likely to occur, differentiated VAT rates
operate in the country, the economic model needs to highlight the type of goods likely to be
purchased by each class with a special emphasis placed on low income, because this class
comprehends more consuming taxpayers (Siemens (von), 1921).
In sum, budgeting VAT requires a fair understanding of class weighting in the country as well
as consumption structure for each class, viz. a convincing and detailed consumption model.
The model is fed with the anticipated growth rate for each component of overall estimated
consumption for the year to come. The formula below summarises VAT’s budgeting.
– 22 / 59 –
Figure 4.9. Budgeting VAT collection
2.2.1.4. Excises
Nowadays, in most countries, certain types of goods are subjected to specific taxes, often in
addition to VAT. Albeit, in history, excises have existed before VAT was created for the first
time in France in 1966. Since the Middle Ages, excises were tax on specific goods imposed
by the King on people in order to finance royal wars (Hart, 2000). In the twenty-first century,
excises apply mostly to two types of goods and services deemed out of first necessity.
The first and best-known category is that of goods falling within the remit of health policy by
undermining consumers’ health. The risk on people’s health is such that, if individuals
consume these goods, they may end up being treated by the Medicare and then be a cost for
society. In all countries, the first good falling within these excises’ remit is tobacco. This first
category of goods, in countries where they are allowed, also comprises of alcohol and some
drugs (e.g. Marijuana in Colorado).
The second category of goods subjected to excises are luxury goods subjected to a surtax
aimed at reducing the injustice on low-incomers caused by VAT. The notion of unnecessary,
luxury goods is contingent upon the philosophy at play in the country. That is, some countries
would consider that spirits and liquors are luxury goods whilst others will emphasise sportster
cars, boats (e.g. yachts) or artworks. In others, it could be chocolate or anything else.
Supposedly, excises apply to what economists commonly call superior goods, goods whose
consumption increases with resources (Bergstrom, 1982; Chaloupka, Kostova, & Shang,
2014).
In sum, apart from tobacco and alcohol, luxury goods pose two types of difficulties. Firstly,
precisely because they are unnecessary goods, their consumption does not follow clear
economic rules. Secondly, as these goods concern a minority in the population, the associated
excises are not a major resource for governments. These still exist mainly for political
reasons: reducing social injustice and inequalities and showing to the public it is done.
Accordingly, in budgeting excises, governments mostly focus on taxes generated from
tobacco and alcohol. As these goods directly concern public health, these excises also relate to
public policy aimed at reducing their consumption, which is most of the time publicly
regulated or controlled. With these excises, governments can determine an acceptable level of
consumption and impose a tax rate on it.
– 23 / 59 –
national specificities, every country does collect tax from its immigration policy: applications
for a visa, residency or citizenship.
Usually, stamp duties serve to finance local governments whilst other taxes contribute to
central governments’ resources. Accordingly, in most countries, stamp duties also rest upon
the sole fact of being located on a given territory. Such taxes can take different names and
forms and be differently computed. For instance, Switzerland is the sole country on earth
applying a capitation: a tax paid by each resident or citizen for living in the country. Other
European countries apply a dwelling tax collected by municipalities (e.g. France and
Belgium). In other countries, such stamp duties are called Council Rate and correspond to
taxes paid for local governments’ common expenses, such as roads, waste removal, street
cleaning, etc. (e.g. Australia or New Zealand). Likewise, countries characterised by heavy
lorry traffic can impose on a traffic tax paid by each vehicle driving on their roads (e.g.
Switzerland, Belgium, Luxemburg, the Netherlands).
Resources generated from individual interactions with public authorities can be hardly
anticipated. Such interactions occur incidentally and are not meant to be recurrent. Therefore,
budgeting these is extremely difficult. Notwithstanding this difficulty, those stamp duties
collected from immigration policy can be anticipated, as governments determine how many
foreigners are allowed or expected. Together with Immigration authorities, the government
can determine how much can be collected from each category. Similarly, stamp duties relating
to location, paid annually, can be anticipated on the basis of the expected population for the
following year. To some extent, such taxes are contingent upon territory attractiveness and
proceed from attractiveness policies. The formula below summarises stamp duties’ budgeting.
Stamp duties = Past year’s tax from interaction with public authorities
+ Expected immigration x Stamp by category
+ Expected population x Location tax
– 24 / 59 –
Owing to its founder, this tax has been nicknames Tobin Tax and long critiqued, presented as
an utopia. Until the 2008 financial crisis, this tax’ proponents were associated with leftist
movements, that have influenced Occupy Wall Street and others in the world (Gitlin, 2013;
Samuel, 2012). Claiming economic realism, its opponents were alleging that such a tax could
be realistically applicable only if all countries in the world were applying it. To them, if just
one country did not apply this tax, financial transactions would move thither, thereby known
as a tax heaven for investors. Resultantly, countries implementing this tax would lose major
resources from trading activities: investors would leave, thereby leading to major redundancy
plans and high unemployment rates (Weaver, 2003).
Budgeting resources from Financial Transaction Tax rests upon macro-financial models
estimating national market capitalisation and trading activity. Usually, such models can be
found in three types of institutions. Firstly, market authority agencies articulate such models
for the conduct of their own activities. Secondly, investment institutions do devise their own
models to anticipate their own gains for the year to come. Thirdly, economic and financial
intergovernmental organisations do forecast capital markets’ activity, e.g. the International
Monetary Fund, the World Bank or the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development. It is less common that governments devise their own models; they would rather
rely on these already existing (Buchanan, 1979). The formula below summarises the
budgeting of resources from Financial Transaction Tax.
– 25 / 59 –
Environmental Taxes = Estimated economic activity for polluting industries
x estimated pollution units x tax on pollution unit
– 26 / 59 –
activity: they advise overseas businesses locating activities in their jurisdiction and charge
them for this. Chambers of Commerce also charge local businesses willing to expand or
needing an introduction to others. Owned by Finance ministries in most countries, chambers
of commerce do have a commercial activity, acting qua facilitators or enablers for private
companies (Bennett, 2011).
Budgeting these commercial activities and associated revenues operates exactly in the same
terms as planning and forecasting. The formula below summarises this.
Revenues from financial activities = Bond interest + loan interest + expected capital gains +
expected dividends
– 27 / 59 –
Figure 4.15. Budgeting resources from financial activities
– 28 / 59 –
was in a capacity of engaging in partnerships and alliances with Volvo and then Nissan
and Mitsubishi (Cröger, 2016; Rakowski & Patz, 2009). In 2017, Renault appears as the
world leader on the automotive market (Ghosn, 2018).
Although some situations have been successful, as evidenced in the case of Renault, many
others have revealed dysfunctions in formerly publicly owned companies and led to losses in
skills. Such is especially vivid in the case of privatised companies whose activities supposedly
serve public interests. The risk is that the search for economy, efficiency and effectiveness
leads to managerial decisions undermining public policy. Decisions can be made without
public authorities having a say. Such is manifest in the case of economically non-profitable
activities a privatised company terminates at the expense of public policy’s national
continuity. Or, in the name of economy, efficiency and effectiveness, redundancy plans can be
orchestrated, resulting in massive unemployment and social dramas in entire regions (Carter
& Mueller, 2006; Funnell et al., 2009; Jupe, 2009).
– 29 / 59 –
strategic activity towards the public good. In this case, privatisation is not too contestable.
Privatisation can however be contested when profitable companies on the long-term are sold
to generate short-term resources, thereby depriving the government from perennial and
sustainable resources. Resources from privatisation are received once and are not expected to
be reiterated. Such was the case in France in 2001 when the socialist government decided to
privatise publicly owned motorways. Opponents would argue that the tolls drivers were
paying to utilise these motorways were perennial and secure long-term resources relinquished
after privatisation (Carter & Mueller, 2006; Funnell et al., 2009; Jupe, 2009).
Also, it often happens that the government of a severely indebted country be urged to
privatise public companies so as to reimburse creditors, as Greece has been since 2008
(Morales et al., 2014) or Latin American countries since the 1986 Mexico crisis (Collins et
al., 1997; Neu, Everett, & Rahaman, 2009; Neu, Leiser, & Ocampo, 2008). Profitable and
economically viable activities end up being privatised to pay for non-productive expenses,
thereby hindering public policy democratically decided through polls.
Whatever the rationale for privatisation and the economic context are, budgeting takes the
same form as capital budgeting in private companies prior to a takeover or an IPO. That is, as
with private companies being listed, to be attractive to investors, initial stocks’ selling price
must offer a discount. Resultantly, the resources generated from privatisation are less than
company worth, as summarised in the formula below.
– 30 / 59 –
Although there is no single path to public default, some recurrent patterns can albeit be
identified. Given the amounts of money needed by the public sector when it borrows,
conventional banks cannot respond, counting on their clients’ deposits. Likewise,
governments cannot count on funding from the Central Bank, this latter being independent
and, in most cases, not allowed to lend money to governments. Public authorities can count on
two options. The first option consists of borrowing directly from another government and
repaying it according to the contract terms and conditions. Given the amounts needed, this
option can only occur occasionally for a specific programme. It is rather the second option
whither governments have recourse: the issuance of treasury bonds on capital markets.
Until the European debt crisis, these treasury bonds were considered the risk-free asset and
were therefore serving as a basis for pricing other assets, as evidenced in the CAPM
(Markowitz, 1952). The principle underpinning treasury bonds is the borrower annually pays
a fixed interest unto loan maturity. At maturity, the principal is reimbursed. Treasury bonds’
viability rests upon a series of implicit assumptions. One is that the public investments shall
generate a residual value at the end of the project sufficient to pay for the principal. Unto
maturity, this public investment is supposed to generate cash flows paying for the annual
interest. Another assumption is that, with inflation, the value of the principal owed at maturity
will be less than it was when it was issued. The third assumption is that sovereign default is
impossible: in case of problems, public authorities can privatise the public sector, reduce
public spending or increase taxes.
A reason why the Public Choice has become the dominant paradigm in public economics lies
in the mismatch between politics and economics. A government is elected for a limited term
and, even if it is re-elected, it will be in office for a shorter time than loans. That is, a
government issues debt and cannot be held accountable for this at maturity. Resultantly,
according to Public Choice proponents, there is an incentive for governments to so borrow as
to exceeding reimbursement capacities. As, once voted in, each government does the same,
public debt so increases as to being unbearable. After a few decades, if no public-sector
reforms are undertaken, sovereign bankruptcy shall occur (Buchanan & Musgrave, 1999;
Orchard & Strutton, 1994).
– 31 / 59 –
next government, became unbearable, causing municipalities’ and other governments’
insolvency (Bayoumi, 2017).
Be the primary budget in deficit or in surplus, it includes the amounts that can be borrowed
and the expected instalment from this loan as well as instalment from previous debt and
principal for those arriving at maturity. The formula below summarises this.
Public debt = New loan – New loan instalment – Old loan instalments – Old loan principal
payment
More appropriate than a principle saying that the budget must be balanced would be one on
the way it is and the weight of debt. This has been the case since 1993 with the Maastricht
convergence criteria explicitly setting an upper limit to public debt, 60% of the GDP and
sanctions for government breaching this principle. Discussions around public debt should not
just focus on cost cutting but should also emphasise how a government can collect income
and generate secure revenues for the future, not just through tax and fees.
– 32 / 59 –
In a country whose Parliament only counts one Chamber (e.g. New Zealand or Israel),
once this budget is approved, it becomes effective. In countries where the Parliament
counts two Chambers (most countries), the approved budget is then submitted to the
second House. There, it is discussed for another fortnight and bares numerous
amendments submitted both to the government and the first Chamber. The government
usually takes two weeks to articulate their own comments and amendments on the
budget’s second draft. Mid-October, the first Chamber receives this second draft amended
by the government and votes its approval. This approved budget is submitted anew to the
second Chamber where it takes c. two weeks to approve or amend it. If the budget is
approved in the same terms by both Houses of Parliament, it becomes effective. If, as it
often happens, the second Chamber does not approve the same budget as the first House,
this latter has together with the government the last word. This occurs two weeks later,
early November (Robert, 1994). All in all, five months are spent on preparing the nation’s
budget, this exercise being the utmost form of democratic activity and vitality.
– 33 / 59 –
allocated to a lesser or greater extent to units manufactured. Likewise, costing poses a series
of problems in non-manufacturing companies, especially when intangible assets are at stake.
Costing the public sector crystallises these difficulties already raised in private companies. As
the public sector deals with public monies and its management relates to democratic vitality, it
is implicitly assumed that this should rest upon absorption costing, whereby all costs,
including initial investments, hidden costs and sunk costs. But also, owing to increasing
governments’ risk aversion, expressed in the Precaution principle, not just all known induced
costs should be accounted for but also unknown costs (de Loo & Lowe, 2017; Hammit,
Rogers, Sand, & Wiener, 2013). To some extent, these costs relate externalities. That is,
governments should be capable of identifying all possible costly externalities and account for
them as part of polity cost. These aforementioned two difficulties lead to considering two
types of programmes and two approaches to polity costing.
The first type of programmes would be recurrent programmes whose cost is relatively
predictable, because in advance the traditional cost of running them is known in advance and
new investments can be anticipated. Such can be the case of kingly activities: public schools
(Agyemang, 2009; Bracci, 2009; Broadbent, Jacobs, & Laughlin, 1999; Edwards, Ezzamel,
McLean, & Robson, 2002), foreign affairs, justice and prisons, police and military (Andrew,
2007; Chwastiak, 2006; Collier, 2006; Funnell, 2006; Gallhofer & Haslam, 1991, 2006;
Hamilton & Ó hógartaigh, 2009). These traditional public policy programmes’ costs can be
accounted for in a relatively conventional manner, as developed in this chapter’s previous
sections).
The second type of programmes rests upon two components. On one hand, there are those
new programmes launched for the first time as costing systems are required. On the other
hand, there are these non-recurrent programmes. The first category comprises of new policies
implemented by a government newly appointed, including costs incurred by the improving or
upgrading of existing programmes (e.g. splitting classes into small groups, which results in
hiring more teaching staff and occupying more classroom space). The second category
consists of unexpected events or activities handled by public authorities. To date, mainly three
types of programmes have fallen within this category: the bailing out of defaulting national
private companies, such as Northern Rock (Brummer, 2008), the national insuring of natural
disasters’ casualties (Vakis, 2006), overseas military actions for peacekeeping or
peacemaking in conflict areas (Davis, 1995).
For these reasons, it appears that unexpected events handled by the public sector raise costs
that cannot be anticipated either. Overseas military operations’ cost is contingent on the
difficulties faced on the battle field, the number of soldiers and materials to be sent as well as
the amount of time they are staying. But also, in many cases, the overseas army that fought
locally is also in charge of reconstruction, whose costs depends on the extent of damages
undergone. All told, such costs, which can be very high, can never be anticipated and
estimated. That is, the concerned government must find resources instantly to be in a capacity
of financing them. The sole possibility for anticipating such costs’ occurring relates to
geopolitical intelligence whereby militaries and diplomats can envisage regions likely to be
concerned by conflicts calling for international intervention
(Government_Accountability_Office, 2018). Such a situation can confront governments in the
US, in the UK, France or Russia, known for sending forces overseas. Contrary to private
businesses, governments do not need to provision such geopolitical risks. Whilst the total cost
of a public policy programme can be estimated, what may pose some difficulties is the cost
per unit, since so doing would necessarily require a comprehensive model for allocating these
fixed and overhead costs, as evidenced in the example below.
– 34 / 59 –
Case n°9. Costing a soldier
Issues in adopting a costing system
In a country’s budget, the total amounts granted to Defence are known, covering
militaries’ wages, the acquisition of new equipment and the maintenance of existing ones.
Dividing this by the number of soldiers does not allow to estimate how much a single
soldier costs. Owing to career structure, the cost of a soldier should certainly be
considered from the Cadets’ school unto death, be it at war or during peacetime. The list
costs is not exhaustive but will comprehend the following:
- At Cadets’ school:
Cadets’ school training (Cadet’s compensation, equipment, food and beverage,
medical surveillance, instructor’s wages, buildings, etc.)
- After school, during peacetime:
Flat wage, promotions-related wage, uniform, equipment, material, barracks,
accommodation, medical surveillance, drills, etc.
- During wartime:
Bonuses for overseas operations, equipment, material, uniforms, transport,
accommodation, medical assistance, possible repatriation, etc.
- Post-war costs:
If the soldier dies at war, allowance to the family and children’s education, family
accommodation, funeral, remembrance ceremonies, training for reintegration into
civil society, etc.
All the above costs are quite clear during peacetime as these are relatively predictable.
World War I illustrated the problem of soldiers’ costing (Gallhofer & Haslam, 1991, 2006;
Keynes, 1919). It was not too difficult planning and accounting for those. A problem
arises during wartime: training can be predicted, unless it has to be shortened because the
war’s start. Such was the case of European officers who joined military schools between
1914 and 1916. In this case, the cost of training is less, but induces unexpected costs,
those costs relating to sending officers to the battlefront without sufficient training. They
might not make the right decisions, thereby leading to extra costs (materials lost,
commanded soldiers’ dying or missing). Given the short duration of their military training,
they were not perfectly accurate at utilising their weapons and ammunitions, causing
massive wastes. This was aggravated by the fact that, in real-life, targets were armed and
were moving.
In the war’s aftermath, other costs for a soldier are borne by the defeated country: cost of
reconstruction, as incurred by Germany after World War I. Such was Germany’s case
when the Peace Treaty signed with France was anticipating an annual fee to be paid to the
victorious country. These would last until 1985 and include pensions and medical
treatment to veterans, the total cost of reconstructing villages and public infrastructures.
To these costs were associated reparations for the moral pain caused to France and all
those families who lost relatives at war. All told, the total cost of a soldier in the defeated
German Army was far more than just the cost of wages, overheads and materials.
– 35 / 59 –
3.1.2. Measuring policy’s impact
The logic of cost control in public services also implies that the public policy’s outcomes be
anticipated and measured. These positive externalities need to be first inventoried. Once this
is done is it necessary to assign to them a metric, relating to public policy’s announced
objectives. Within a New Public Management logic, these measures should ideally be
financialised, hence polity’s efficiency can be assessed with greater clarity. Owing to
management framework, prior to launching new programmes, ministries are now required to
conduct impact studies and prepare a schedule of impact. In order to be convincing for the
parliament ultimately voting the budget, these impact studies must be extremely detailed and
accurate.
These impact studies can be conducted by four types of bodies. In a series of cases, it is the
ministry itself that conducts them, basing their estimates on proofed econometric models. In
this case, model credentials mean study credibility. The main risk associated with this option
precisely lies in that the ministry is both judge and party in this matter. The models used may
be overly optimistic and the promised impact may not eventuate. Therefore, many countries
privilege the second option consisting of impact studies ordered from independent
governmental agencies whose role is to produce an independent opinion and advice on public
policy. As these agencies are totally independent, their advice counts. The third option
consists of calling on scholars known for the works on the subject matter. Be they paid extra
money or not for their impact study, what is advertised is their expertise at a particular
subject. Their conclusions are not contestable and rarely contested. Pursuant to the New
Public Management philosophy, the impact study is outsourced to external consultants,
deemed experts at the subject matter and independent from governmental authorities.
– 36 / 59 –
previous campaign, and if voters want the same policy to be conducted, they may re-elect
them. Conversely, if promises have not been kept or achievements not satisfactory, citizens
may decide to vote for another party or coalition. In other words, the disclosing of results
associated with KPIs for polity appears as the utmost form of political accountability to
citizens (Broadbent et al., 1996; Broadbent & Laughlin, 2003a). Therefore, controlling the
civil service, ministers and their representatives are also in a position enabling them to choose
those KPIs that best reflect what they want to tell their electorate. Some KPIs are more likely
to highlight weaknesses or loopholes whilst others are more likely to confirm expected
achievements. Within such a political-strategic context, it is understandable that the choice of
KPIs for polity is a highly political and sensitive exercise (Benito, Montesinos, & Bastida,
2008).
Assuming that the choice of KPIs is a form of political activism or campaigning, it also
appears that these must be intelligible to citizens. The intelligibility imperative can be met at
the expense of KPI accuracy. As what matters to governments in office is to disclose the
promised results, the KPIs chosen are likely to be approximate measures of what has
eventually been done and achieved. Therefore, in political debates, either on television or at
the House of Parliament, the results disclosed by a government in office are often challenged
by the opposition. Very often, opponents to the government present their own KPIs. The
metrics associated therewith are often less flattering than those presented by the government.
Inspired by the Public Choice doctrine, New Public Management proponents have claimed
that performance management in the public sector is especially important to determine the
righteous use of taxpayers’ monies and enable democratic control over governments. As is
often the case, this ambitious programme can be perverted by political activism and may lead
to creative behaviours (Benito et al., 2008), if not proving counter-productive. Given the
power of the visual enabled through the use of political KPIs (Quattrone, 2009), the political
sphere may find over-relying on numbers, facts and figures, thereby highlighting a process of
accountingisation (Kraus, 2012). In order to prove in good faith their action and results,
ministers and ministries’ spokespersons would tend to feed their discourses with a profusion
of numbers that may distract the audience from the general political point made. It has been
noticed that political discourses have lost direction and meaning, because they mostly reflect
debates on numbers and their honesty. It is therefore no real surprise that citizens have over
years lost interest in the public thing and political debates, even abstaining from polling
(Badiou, 2005).
– 37 / 59 –
sector more than in private-sector organisations, there is a risk that the metrics employed
become an end per se and be not just an aid for governments and policymaking. At the
grassroots level, these public policy controls may become problematic, because they require
new expertise and duties from local civil servants, oftentimes disorganising the public service.
The implementing of controls borrowed from the private sector has often resulted in civil
servants, experts at one field, acting as hybrids (Kurunmäki & Miller, 2006, 2011; Miller et
al., 2008). They have been devolved some control tasks and duties outwith their expertise
area. This poses two series of problems. Firstly, being a good professional in one field does
not necessarily mean that the civil servant has the necessary managerial skills for public
policy control. This professional, e.g. an acknowledged professor in medicine head of a
hospital department, does not necessarily have management, accounting or finance skills.
Secondly, when an expert at one field is required to take over managerial duties, this
mechanically results in less time spent on their core competency and activity. Such distracting
from their core occupation may result in them progressively losing their initial skills. For
instance, a surgeon doing more computations than operations may lose gesture accuracy and
become deskilled over time (Chua, 1995; Coombs, 1987). Ultimately, there is a real risk that
core skills be lost and service quality lowered. Opponents to managerialism and
accountingisation in the public sector warn agains these risks implied by performance
management in the public sector (Mueller & Carter, 2007; Saravanamuthu & Filling, 2004).
– 38 / 59 –
- number of solved cases
As arrest does not necessarily mean that the person has eventually breached the law,
committed a crime and been convicted, number of convictions has slowly arisen as an
alternative measure of PCs’ performance. What is emphasised is the number of people
arrested who have been prosecuted and eventually convicted. In order to achieve high,
many PCs have been encouraged to privilege cases that can be relatively easily solved.
This has implied that cases requiring heavy teams and resources and long-term
investigations were discouraged. Instead of endeavouring to dismantle drug trafficking
networks or chasing a serial rapist in a district, PCs were encouraged to give tickets for
wrong car parking or excessive speed.
It has resulted from these KPIs that Police Constables were high performers with excellent
records. At the same time, independent agencies have denounced major dysfunctions in
police core activity and highlighted a dual phenomenon. On one hand, notwithstanding
increased performance, police forces were less and less popular among the public. On the
other hand, the insecurity feeling has grown amidst the population. This was explained by
the conjunction of two factors. Firstly, by solving simple cases at the expense of the
population, police forces have increased their own unpopularity. Secondly, in order to
disclose high performance figures, victims of assaults were encouraged by PCs not to
lodge complaints, under various pretext, such as insufficient evidence. It was revealed that
these complaints would have related to cases that could not be solved (e.g. a stolen
handbag, a robbery in absence of CCTV surveillance, etc.) Ultimately, police forces were
accused to not to serve the public (Caless & Owens, 2016; Oliver, 1996).
– 39 / 59 –
controls in French, British and American jails may focus on convicts’ health and rights’
protection. Differently, controls in Norwegian or Dutch prisons may emphasise high-quality
continuity (Chabbal, 2009, 2014). As the focus of execution control is specific to each public
policy programme, there is obviously no general rule as to what is being investigated and how
this is done. Albeit, some recurrent patterns as to who controls exist, conveying mainly three
forms: independent agencies, the Parliament and parliamentary committees, and citizens.
– 40 / 59 –
Bank can do this with countries benefitting from their loans (e.g. Argentina since the 2001
default, Greece, Spain and Portugal since the European debt crisis).
– 41 / 59 –
looking after them. Some critical public policy items requiring an urgent response from the
government may result in surprise visits to the field. Such is often the case when it comes to
detention conditions or refugee policy after an agency disclosed a report highlighting major
dysfunctions (Chabbal, 2009, 2014; Kyle & Peacey, 2002). Based upon these observations,
MPs can interpellate the government before the House of Parliament and expect responses.
3.2.3.4. Citizens
As every single control is exerted on behalf and in the name of citizens (not just taxpayers),
these may be invited to partake in some control activities. this can take on numerous forms.
The best-known of these is the publicity of trials and investigations whereby citizens willing
to attend are allowed to. In some countries, these citizens are entitled to ask questions as MPs
would. In some others, they are not but can observe follow the discussions and make their
own judgement.
The best-known form of public policy execution control by citizen occurs through polls. With
their votes, citizens iterate their confidence in the government in office or, on the contrary,
manifest their disapproval. In this latter case, they exert an ex post execution control by either
re-electing the same people or voting their opponents in. Since the early 1990s, a new
phenomenon has characterised most developed countries, votes for extremists. After the
collapse of the USSR, right-extremists have collected a growing number of votes. Since the
2008 global financial crisis and its discontents, Capitalism has been dramatically called into
question, resulting in the uprise of a new extreme-leftist movements jointly to the alt-right,
such as Occupy Wall Street (Carter, 2005; Gitlin, 2013; Hainsworth, 2008; Samuel, 2012).
This is the utmost form of control the Public Choice has been highlighting: approval or
disapproval through vote, with the belief that radical votes express a stronger rejection of
current public policy.
Another form of execution control exerted by citizens consists of having some participating in
various trialling or auditioning panels. These citizens are then selected to partake in
parliamentarians’ control activities. In this capacity, they are entitled the same rights as MPs
in terms of access to the field and rights to be answered by the concerned people. What
however differs from MPs’ rights is that these citizens, not elected and therefore not
representing their peer citizens, are not allowed to publicly interpellate the government before
the Parliament House. Other non-constitutional means are possible, such as interpellation
through a commentary published in a newspaper and calling for a response or any public
utterance before the media and calling for a response from an official. This often happens
when it comes to civil rights protection or guarantee, such as abortion right, same-sex
marriage, minorities’ protection or in change in legal majority age. The best-known example
is that of the civil rights movement in the United States between 1941 and 1968 (Lawson,
2008; Luders, 2010).
A third form of execution control citizens can exert lies the use of their petition right. In some
countries, such as Switzerland or Italy, when a petition regularly signed by 10% of the
electorate is submitted to the parliament, this has to be discussed as a law project. In the Swiss
case, this petition must be submitted by the parliament to a public consultation taking the
form of a referendum. In the Italian case, the petition must be discussed before the Parliament,
so that a law can be resultantly voted. Apart from these two specific cases where citizens’
petition right is set in the constitution, numerous other forms exist. One of them consists of
the fact that MPs, being elected in a county, can receive proposals from their voters. If they
feel that they can support the proposal by submitting it to the Parliament in their own name,
citizens can have their control right represented and born by someone. In countries like
France, such has long been the case with citizens urging their local MPs to review laws
– 42 / 59 –
organising hunting and fishing in regional areas. In the twenty-first century, with the advent
of social media, and as evidenced through Occupy Wall Street in the US the Indognados in
Spain or Nuit Debout in France between 2009 and 2016, citizens can petition electronically
and attract governments’ or parliamentarians’ attention re subjects that matter to them. In the
case of these new social movements, leftist representatives have relayed people’s aspirations
before the parliament and in political debates (Staggenborg, 2015).
The last form is well-known under the derogatory term lobbying and characterises the
European Union as well as the United States (Baumgartner, Berry, Hojnacki, Kimball, &
Leech, 2009; Zetter, 2014). In Brussels and in Washington, group representatives (citizens,
industries, companies, non-profits, etc.) are headquartered, attend parliamentary debates and
public auditions, and regularly submit proposals to parliamentarians or EU commissioners.
These proposals consist of entirely laws or regulations written, using legal terms and
presented as they would look if voted. In these cases, as in that of citizens addressing their
local MP, the parliamentarian or commissioner concerned appropriates the project and
supports it before his or her peers for discussion and vote. In the US, the best-known lobbying
activities relate to the tobacco industry, the National Rifle Association or Evangelical
movements. In the European Union, lobbies are expressly allowed into the European
Parliament and the European Commission where they can have offices and are accredited
spokespartners. In this capacity, they are regularly solicited on public policy mattes likely to
have an impact on them. These lobbies to the European Union can be syndicates, unions,
charities or any other organised body (De Raeve, 2017).
Conclusion
This chapter showed how public sector accounting and controls are conceived of and
practiced in democratic countries. Since the English Revolution, it has appeared that
controlling how taxpayers’ monies are utilised and how public policy is executed are the core
of democratic activity and vitality. Therefore, discussing management accounting and control
in the public sector is always a politically sensitive question, systematically highlighting
different worldviews or notions of government.
Borrowed from the Public Choice, itself inspiring the New Public Management movement,
controls in the public sector have highlighted increasing calls for governments’ public and
political accountability to citizens. This has raised new questions pertaining to the scope and
span of controls in the public sector. Whilst the New Public Management movement suggests
that public sector controls should borrow from those at work in the private sector this chapter
has endeavoured to highlight some of the limits and problems such controls would raise. Such
has been done through the highlighting of the main arguments presented by their proponents
and opponents.
Regardless of political or ideological disputes, it does appear that management accounting and
controls in the public sector are aimed at proving to taxpayers that their monies have been
used for the purpose they were collected: public policy objectives. In return, as polity
influences people’s lives, governments are held accountable for the effective conduct of the
policy for which they were elected. This includes all types of operation and execution
controls.
All told, in the case of the public sector, strategic management accounting consists of
identifying what counts as public policy priorities and follow through. It also appears that the
choice of a control or an accounting system is in itself politically sensitive, insofar as different
things can be emphasised. In sum, depending on who, government or opponents, needs
management accounting figures, the management control system eventually needed and
– 43 / 59 –
utilised differs. This reinforces one more time the idea that management control and
accounting can in no way and by no means produce neutral and objective figures. These are
always oriented towards an end.
– 44 / 59 –
Bibliography
Abbott, M., & Doucouliagos, C. (2009). Competition and efficiency: overseas students and
technical efficiency in Australian and New Zealand universities. Education
Economics, 17(1), 31-57.
Adkisson, R. V., & Mohammed, M. (2014). Tax structure and state economic growth during
the Great Recession. The Social Science Journal, 51(1), 79-89.
Aguar do Monte, P. (2017). Public versus private sector: Do workers’ behave differently?
EconomiA, 18(2), 229-243.
Agyemang, G. (2009). Responsibility and accountability without direct control? - Local
education authorities and the seeking of influence in the UK schools sector.
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 22(5), 762-788.
Aidt, T. S. (2010). Green taxes: Refunding rules and lobbying. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 60(1), 31-43.
Airbus. (2018). Flying as one – one team, one path, one future Annual report. Amsterdam:
Airbus.
Alpe, E. N., & Whitworth, P. E. (1956). The Law of Stamp Duties: Jordan.
Alstine, M. P. V. (2002). The Judicial Power and Treaty Delegation. California Law Review,
90(4), 1263-1303.
Andersson, T., & Tenglad, S. (2009). When complexity meets culture: new public
management in the Swedish police. Qualitative Research in Accounting &
Management, 6(1/2), 41-56.
Andrew, J. (2007). Prisons, the profit motive and other challenges to accountability. Critical
Perspectives on Accounting, 18(8), 877-904.
Anheier, H., & Salamon, L. (1994). The emerging sector: the nonprofit sector in comparative
perspective. An overview. Baltimore: The John Hopkins Sector Series.
Anheier, H., & Salamon, L. (1996). The emerging nonprofit sector: an overview. Manchester:
Manchester University Press.
Anheier, H., & Salamon, L. (1997). Defining the emerging sector: a cross-national analysis.
Baltimore: The John Hopkins Sector Series.
Annisette, M. (2004). The true nature of the World Bank. Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, 15(3), 303-323.
Anthony, R. N. (1965). Planning and control systems: a framework for analysis. Boston:
Harvard Business School Publishing.
Anthony, R. N. (1988). The management control function. Boston: Harvard Business School
Publishing.
Anthony, R. N., Dearden, J., & Bedford, N. M. (1984). Management Control Systems.
Homewood: Il: Irwin.
Archambault, E. (1997). France. In L. Salamon & H. Anheier (Eds.), Defining the nonprofit
sector: a cross-national analysis (pp. 103-127). Baltimore: The John Hopkins Sector
Series.
Argento, D., & van Helden, J. (2009). Reforming the Dutch water chain: how radical
ambitions turned into a moderate pace of change. Journal of Accounting &
Organizational Change, 5(3), 321-343.
Arnaboldi, M., & Azzone, G. (2005). Performance measurement and change: the case of
Italian new public administration. International Journal of Business Performance
Management, 7(1), 1-15.
– 45 / 59 –
Arnaboldi, M., & Azzone, G. (2010). Constructing performance measurement in the public
sector. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 21(4), 266-282.
Arrow, K. J. (1974). The Limits of Organization (Fels Lectures on Public Policy Analysis).
New York: W. W. Norton & Company
Asenova, D., & Beck, M. (2010). Crucial silences: When accountability met PFI and finance
capital. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 21(1), 1-13.
Ashkanasy, N., Falkus, S., & Callan, V. (2000). Predictors of Ethical Code Use and Ethical
Tolerance in the Public Sector. Journal of Business Ethics, 25(3), 237-253.
Badiou, A. (2005). Metapolitics. London: Verso.
Badiou, A. (2008). The Communist hypothesis. New Left Review, 49, 29-42.
Badiou, A. (2012). The rebirth of history. London: Verso.
Baldwin, A., & Andersen, K. (2017). You Can't Spell America Without Me: The Really
Tremendous Inside Story of My Fantastic First Year as President Donald J. Trump (A
So-Called Parody). New York: Bentham Press.
Baumgartner, F. R., Berry, J. M., Hojnacki, M., Kimball, D. C., & Leech, B. K. (2009).
Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, And Why. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press.
Baumol, W. J. (1982). Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure.
American Economic Review, 72(1), 1-15.
Bayoumi, T. (2017). Unfinished Business: The Unexplored Causes of the Financial Crisis
and the Lessons Yet to be Learned. Yale: Yale University Press.
Benito, B., Montesinos, V., & Bastida, F. (2008). An example of creative accounting in public
sector: The private financing of infrastructures in Spain. Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, 19(7), 963-986.
Bennett, R. J. (2011). Local Business Voice: The History of Chambers of Commerce in
Britain, Ireland, and Revolutionary America, 1760-2011. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Bergh, A., Dackehag, M., & Rode, M. (2017). Are OECD policy recommendations for public
sector reform biased against welfare states? Evidence from a new database. European
Journal of Political Economy, 48(June), 3-15.
Bergstrom, T. C. (1982). On Capturing Oil Rents with a National Excise Tax. The American
Economic Review, 72(1), 194-201.
Bezançon, X. (1997). Les services publics en France. Paris: Presses de l'Ecole Nationale des
Ponts et Chaussées
Boje, D. (2001). Carnivalesque Resistance to global Spectacle: a Critical Postmodern Theory
of Public Administration. Administrative Theory and Practice, 23(3), 431-458.
Boland Jr, R. J., Sharma, A. K., & Afonso, P. S. (2008). Designing management control in
hybrid organizations: The role of path creation and morphogenesis. Accounting,
Organizations and Society, 33(7-8), 899-914.
Bracci, E. (2009). Autonomy, responsibility and accountability in the Italian school system.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 20(3), 293-312.
Brammer, S. (2009). Co-operation Between National Competition Agencies in the
Enforcement of EC Competition Law. London: Hart Publishing.
Brignall, S., & Modell, S. (2000). An institutional perspective on performance measurement
and management in the [`]new public sector'. Management Accounting Research,
11(3), 281-306.
Broadbent, J., Dietrich, M., & Laughlin, R. (1996). The development of principal-agent,
contracting and accountability relationships in the public sector: conceptual and
cultural problems. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 7(3), 259-284.
– 46 / 59 –
Broadbent, J., Jacobs, K., & Laughlin, R. (1999). Comparing schools in the U.K. and New
Zealand: individualizing and socializing accountabilities and some implications for
management control. Management Accounting Research, 10(4), 339-361.
Broadbent, J., & Laughlin, R. (1998). Resisting the "new public management": Absorption
and absorbing groups in schools and GP practices in the UK. Accounting, Auditing &
Accountability Journal, 11(4), 403 - 435.
Broadbent, J., & Laughlin, R. (2003a). Control and legitimation in government accountability
processes: the private finance initiative in the UK. Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, 14(1-2), 23-48.
Broadbent, J., & Laughlin, R. (2003b). Public private partnerships: an introduction.
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 16(3), 332 - 341.
Brummer, A. (2008). The Crunch: The Scandal of Northern Rock and the Escalating Credit
Crisis. London: Random House Business.
Buchanan, J. M. (1979). What should economists do? : Liberty Fund Inc.
Buchanan, J. M. (1986). The Constitution of Economic Polic – Nobel Prize lecture. American
Economic Review, 77(3), 243-250.
Buchanan, J. M., & Musgrave, R. A. (1999). Public Finance and Public Choice: Two
Contrasting Visions of the State. Boston: MIT Press.
Buchanan, P. J. (1998). The Great Betrayal: How American Sovereignty and Social Justice
Are Being Sacrificed to the Gods of the Global Economy. New York: Little Brown and
Company.
Burgess, M. (2006). Comparative Federalism: Theory and Practice. London: Routledge.
Burns, D., Hambleton, R., & Hoggett, P. (1994). The Politics of Decentralisation:
Revitalising Local Democracy: Revitalising Local Government (Public Policy and
Politics). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Caless, B., & Owens, J. (2016). Police and Crime Commissioners: The Transformation of
Police Accountability. London: Policy Press.
Callon, M. (2009). Civilizing markets: Carbon trading between in vitro and in vivo
experiments. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34(3-4), 535-548.
Carnegie, G. D., & West, B. P. (2005). Making accounting accountable in the public sector.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 16(7), 905-928.
Carpenter, J., Doverspike, D., & Migue, R. F. (2012). Public service motivation as a predictor
of attraction to the public sector. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 80(2), 509-523.
Carter, C., & Mueller, F. (2006). The colonisation of strategy: Financialisation in a post-
privatisation context. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 17(8), 967-985.
Carter, E. (2005). The Extreme Right in Western Europe: Success or Failure? Manchester:
Manchester University Press.
Chabbal, J. (2009). L'indignation publique à l'épreuve des indignations morales. In M. Catla,
F. Cantelli, M. Roca i Escoda & J. Stavo-Debauge (Eds.), Sensibilités pragmatiques:
enquêter sur l'action publique (Vol. 163-178). Paris: P.I.E. Peter Lang.
Chabbal, J. (2014). Changer la prison : la cause du Parlement. L'intrusion parlementaire
dans les politiques pénitentiaires françaises (1999--2009). Thèse de doctorat,
Université Paris Dauphine, Université Paris Dauphine.
Chaloupka, F. J., Kostova, D., & Shang, C. (2014). Cigarette Excise Tax Structure and
Cigarette Prices: Evidence From the Global Adult Tobacco Survey and the U.S.
National Adult Tobacco Survey. Nicotine & Tobacco Research, 16(Suppl_1), S3-S9.
Chamon, M. (2016). EU Agencies: Legal and Political Limits to the Transformation of the
EU Administration. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Charpentier, F. (2009). Les retraites en France et dans le monde: nouvelles problématiques:
Economica.
– 47 / 59 –
Chevallier, J. (2015). Le service public. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Chua, W. F. (1995). Experts, networks and inscriptions in the fabrication of accounting
images: A story of the representation of three public hospitals. Accounting,
Organizations and Society, 20(2–3), 111-145.
Chwastiak, M. (2006). Rationality, performance measures and representations of reality:
planning, programming and budgeting and the Vietnam war. Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, 17(1), 29-55.
Clarke, P., & Lapsley, I. (2004). Management accounting in the new public sector.
Management Accounting Research, 15(3), 243-245.
Claston, I. (2011). Managing the public sector: Mission impossible? London: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Cole, A. (2013). Analysis of the Etihad Airways. London: GRIN Publishing.
Cole, B., & Cooper, C. (2006). Deskilling in the 21st century: The case of rail privatisation.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 17(5), 601-625.
Collier, P. M. (2006). Costing police services: The politicization of accounting. Critical
Perspectives on Accounting, 17(1), 57-86.
Collins, F., Holzmann, O., & Mendoza, R. (1997). Strategy, budgeting and crisis in Latin
America. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 22(7), 669-689.
Connolly, C., & Hyndman, N. (2001). A Comparative Study on the Impact of Revised SORP
2 on British and Irish Charities. Financial Accountability & Management, 17(1), 73-
97.
Connolly, C., Hyndman, N., & McConville, D. (2013). UK charity accounting: An exercise in
widening stakeholder engagement. The British Accounting Review, 45(1), 58-69.
Coombs, R. W. (1987). Accounting for the control of doctors: Management information
systems in hospitals. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 12(4), 389-404.
Craig, R., & Amernic, J. (2008). A privatization success story: accounting and narrative
expression over time. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 21(8), 1085-
1115.
Cröger, N. (2016). The Renault-Nissan alliance. London: GRIN Publishing.
Crompton, G., & Jupe, R. (2003). 'Such a silly scheme*: the privatisation of Britain's railways
1992-2002. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 14(6), 617-645.
Crowther, D., Carter, C., & Cooper, S. (2006). The poetics of corporate reporting: Evidence
from the UK water industry. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 17(2-3), 175-201.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2018). State-Owned Multinationals – Governments in Global Business.
London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Cummine, A. (2016). Citizens' Wealth: Why (and How) Sovereign Funds Should be Managed
by the People for the People. Yale: Yale University Press.
Cunningham, L. (2013). The AIG story. London: John Willey & Sons Ltd.
Dann, S. (1996). Public sector reform and the long‐term public servant. International Journal
of Public Sector Management, 9(2), 28-35.
Davies, R. (2016). Public Good by Private Means. New York: Alliance Publishing Trust.
Davis, L. E. (1995). Peacekeeping & Peacemaking: RAND Summer Institute.
de Loo, I., & Lowe, A. (2017). “[T]here are known knowns … things we know that we
know”: Some reflections on the nature and practice of interpretive accounting
research. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 30(8), 1796-1819.
De Raeve, P. (2017). EU Lobby Strategies Fitting a New Political Context. London: Lap
Lambert Academic Publishing.
Dekker, T. J. (2015). Paying Our High Public Officials: Evaluating the Political
Justifications of Top Wages in the Public Sector. London: Routledge.
– 48 / 59 –
des Cars, L., & Nahyan, S. S. b. T. A. (2013). Louvre Abu Dhabi: Birth of a Museum. Paris:
Flammarion.
Dhanani, A., & Connelly, C. (2012). Discharging not-for-profit accountability: UK charities
and public discourse. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 25(7), 1140-
1169.
Dickson, M., Postel-Vinay, F., & Turon, H. (2014). The lifetime earnings premium in the
public sector: The view from Europe. Labour Economics, 31(December), 141-161.
Dienel, H.-L., & Schiefelbusch, M. (Eds.). (2009). Public Transport and its Users – The
Passenger's Perspective in Planning and Customer Care. London: Routledge.
Dima, B., Dima, Ş. M., & Barna, F. (2014). The signaling effect of tax rates under fiscal
competition: A (Shannonian) transfer entropy approach. Economic Modelling, 42,
373-381.
Dorf, M. D. (2006). Problem-solving courts and the judicial accountabiltiy deficit. In M. W.
Dowdle (Ed.), Public accountability – Designs, dilemmas and experiences (pp. 301-
328). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dreveton, B., & Rocher, S. (2010). Lost in translation : Etude de la construction d'un outil de
contrôle de gestion dans une région Française. Comptabilité Contrôle Audit, 16(1), 83-
100.
Dreyfus, P. (2001). Une nationalisation réussie, Renault. Paris: Fayard.
Edwards, P., Ezzamel, M., McLean, C., & Robson, K. (2002). Budgeting and Strategy in
Schools: The Elusive Link. Financial Accountability & Management, 16(4), 309-334.
Elderei, H. (2017). Islamic work ethics as a moderator between motivation and workplace
performance: job satisfaction and performance in the Abu Dhabi public sector. DBA
thesis, DBA thesis, Grenoble École de Management.
Ericsson, N. R. (2017). Economic forecasting in theory and practice: An interview with David
F. Hendry. International Journal of Forecasting, 33(2), 523-542.
Ernst_&_Young_LLP. (1994). Privatization: Investing in State-Owned Enterprises Around
the World. New York: Wiley & Sons Publishing.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1992). The three worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1996). Welfare States in Transition: National Adaptations in Global
Economies. London: Sage publications.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1999). Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies. Oxford:
Oxford Uniersity Press.
Esquiroi, J. L. (2008). The Failed Law of Latin America. The American Journal of
Comparative Law, 56(1), 75-124.
Estella, A. (2002). The Eu Principle of Subsidiarity and Its Critique (Oxford Studies in
European Law). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Fabozzi, F. J., & Markowitz, H. (2011). The theory and practice of investment management :
asset allocation, valuation, portfolio construction, and strategies (2nd ed.). Hoboken,
N.J.: Wiley.
Fabri, C., & Fressoz, P. (2011). Implementing a Balanced Scorecard to improve the
performance of public administration: The case of the city Aix-les-Bains and its social
cohesion policy. In B. Heesen (Ed.), Effective Strategy Execution: Improving
Performance with Business Intelligence. New York: Springer.
Farrell, C. M. (2005). Governance in the UK Public Sector: the Involvement of the Governing
Board. Public Administration, 83(1), 89-110.
Fonte, J. (2011). Sovereignty or Submission: Will Americans Rule Themselves or be Ruled by
Others? New York: Ingram Publisher Services.
– 49 / 59 –
Freeman, J. (2006). Extending public accountability through privatization: from public law to
publicization. In M. W. Dowdle (Ed.), Public accountability – Designs, dilemmas and
experiences (pp. 83-111). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Funnell, W. (2006). National efficiency, military accounting and the business of war. Critical
Perspectives on Accounting, 17(6), 719-751.
Funnell, W., Jupe, R., & Andrew, J. (2009). In Government we Trust: Market Failure and the
Delusions of Privatisation (Vol. Pluto Press): London.
Furet, F. (1981). Interpreting the French Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Furet, F. (1996). The French Revolution. London: Blackwell.
Furneaux, C., & Ryan, N. (2015). Nonprofit service delivery for government: accountability
relationships and mechanisms. In Z. Hoque & L. Parker (Eds.), Performance
management in nonprofit organizations: global perspectives (pp. 185-210). London:
Routledge.
Gaisbauer, H. P., Schweiger, G., & Sedmak, C. (2015). Outlining the field of tax justice. In H.
P. Gaisbauer, G. Schweiger & C. Sedmak (Eds.), Philosophical Explorations of
Justice and Taxation (pp. 1-14). London: Springer.
Gallagher, M. E. (2006). Mobilizing the Law in China: "Informed Disenchantment" and the
Development of Legal Consciousness. Law & Society Review, 40(4), 783-816.
Gallhofer, S., & Haslam, J. (1991). The aura of accounting in the context of a crisis: Germany
and the first world war. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 16(5–6), 487-520.
Gallhofer, S., & Haslam, J. (2006). Mobilising accounting in the radical media during the
First World War and its aftermath: The case of Forward in the context of Red
Clydeside. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 17(2–3), 224-252.
Garvey, P. (2017). Taking Control: How to Prepare Your School for Ofsted Inspection.
Woolbridge: John Catt Educational Ltd
Gémes, A. (2015). New Business Models for Electric Utility Companies: An Imperative for
Change. Berlin: AV Akademikerverlag.
Gendron, Y., Cooper, D., & Townley, B. (2001). In the name of accountablity: state auditing,
independence and new public management. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability
Journal, 14(3), 278-310.
Ghosn, C. (2018). Renault's 2017 annual report Annual report. Paris: Renault S.A.
Gitlin, T. (2013). Occupy Nation: The Roots, the Spirit, and the Promise of Occupy Wall
Street. New York: It Books.
Government_Accountability_Office, U. S. (2018). FORCE STRUCTURE: Improved Cost
Information and Analysis Needed to Guide Overseas Military Posture Decisions.
Washington: CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform.
Graham, C. (2008). Fearful asymmetry: The consumption of accounting signs in the Algoma
Steel pension bailout. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 33(7-8), 756-782.
Grana, K. (2018). The Principle of Subsidiarity and its Enforcement in the EU Legal Order:
The Role of National Parliaments in the Early Warning System (Parliamentary
Democracy in Europe). London: Hart Publishing.
Greene, C. D., & Turner, R. L. (2011). China's Sovereign Wealth Fund: Developments &
Policy Implications (China in the 21st Century). London: Nova Science Publishers.
Grimsey, D., & Lewis, M. K. (2005). Are Public Private Partnerships value for money?:
Evaluating alternative approaches and comparing academic and practitioner views.
Accounting Forum, 29(4), 345-378.
Grolle, S. (2009). Privatisation of public space. London: GRIN Publishing.
Gunlicks, A. (2003). The Länder and German federalism (issues in Germn politics).
Manchester: Manchester University Press.
– 50 / 59 –
Hainsworth, P. (2008). The Extreme Right in Western Europe. London: Routledge.
Hajamini, M., & Falahi, M. A. (2018). Economic growth and government size in developed
European countries: A panel threshold approach. Economic Analysis and Policy, 58,
1-13.
Hamilton, G., & Ó hógartaigh, C. (2009). The Third Policeman: 'The true and fair view',
language and the habitus of accounting. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 20(8),
910-920.
Hammit, J., Rogers, M., Sand, P., & Wiener, J. (2013). The Reality of Precaution: Comparing
Risk Regulation in the United States and Europe. London: Routledge.
Hardy, L., & Ballis, H. (2013). Accountability and giving accounts: Informal reporting
practices in a religious corporation. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal,
26(4), 539-566.
Hart, M. t. (2000). Warfare and Capitalism: The Impact of the Economy on State Making in
Northwestern Europe, Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries. Review (Fernand
Braudel Center), 23(2), 209-228.
Havens, J. J., O'Herlihy, M. A., & Schervish, P. (2006). Charitable giving: how much, by
whom, to what and how? In W. Powell & R. Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit sector –
A research handbook (pp. 542-567). Yale: Yale University Press.
Hayek, F. v. (1979). The road to Serfdom. London: Routledge.
Heinz, D. (2016). Birds of the Same Feather: Federalism and Decentralisation in Germany. In
J. Ruano & M. Profiroiou (Eds.), The Sage Handbook of decentralisation in Europe
(pp. 15-45). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Herath, S. K., Wickramasinghe, D., & Indriani, M. W. (2010). Improving efficiency and
accountability: a case study on outsourcing strategies in higher educationin Sri Lanka.
International Journal of Managerial and Financial Accounting, 2(3), 275.-304.
Hill, C. (1991). The World Turned Upside Down: Radical Ideas During the English
Revolution. London: Penguin History.
Hood, C. (2000). The art of the State: culture, rhetoric, and Public Management. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Hood, C., & Scott, C. (1996). 'Bureaucratic regulation and New Public Management in the
United Kingdom: Mirror-Image or Developments? Journal of Law and Society, 23,
321-345.
Hoskin, K. W., & Macve, R. H. (1988). The genesis of accountability: The west point
connections. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13(1), 37-73.
Howard, S. (2017). Leadership Lessons From The Volkswagen Saga. London: Caliente Press.
Huang, X., & Austin, I. (2015). Chinese Investment in Australia: Unique Insights from the
Mining Industry. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Husson, J.-F. (2016). Federalism and Decentralisation in Belgium. In J. Ruano & M.
Profiroiou (Eds.), The Palgrave Handbook of decentralisation in Europe (pp. 47-75).
London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Inc._IBP. (2016). European Space Agency and Programs Handbook: Strategic Information
and Contacts. New York: IBP USA.
Jacobs, K. (1998). Value for money auditing in New Zealand: competing for control in the
public sector. The British Accounting Review, 30(4), 343-360.
Jacobs, K. (2005). Hybridisation or Polarisation: Doctors and Accounting in the UK,
Germany and Italy. Financial Accountability & Management, 21(2), 135-162.
Jamieson, C. (1991). Stamp Duties in the European Community: Harmonisation by
Abolition? Brit. Tax Rev., 1991, 318-319.
Jeffrey, C., & Reilly, A. (2002). Devolution to the Regions: What Does It Mean for Local
Government in England? LGA Reports (pp. 77). London: LGA.
– 51 / 59 –
Jenkins, J. C. (2006). Nonprofit organizations and political advocacy. In W. Powell & R.
Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit sector – A research handbook (pp. 307-332). Yale:
Yale University Press.
Jensen, P. H. (2012). Public Sector Outsourcing Contracts: The Impact of Uncertainty,
Incentives and Transaction Costs on Contractual Relationships Berlin: AV
Akademikerverlag.
Jensen, R. E. (1990). Working within neoclassical theory and “modern theory≓ of finance to
detect and measure monopoly power components of ex post accounting rate of return.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 1(1), 69-101.
Joannidès, V. (2012). Accounterability and the problematics of accountability. Critical
Perspectives on Accounting, 23(3), 244-257.
Johansson, S. (2003). Independent Movement or Government Subcontractor? – Strategic
Responses of Voluntary Organizations to Institutional Processes. [10.1111/1468-
0408.00171]. Financial Accountability & Management, 19(3), 209-224.
Josiah, J., Burton, B., Gallhofer, S., & Haslam, J. (2010). Accounting for privatisation in
Africa? Reflections from a critical interdisciplinary perspective. Critical Perspectives
on Accounting, 21(5), 374-389.
Jupe, R. (2009). A "fresh start" of the "worst of all words"? A critical financial analysis of the
performance and regulation of Network Rail in Britain's privatised railway system.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 20(2), 175-204.
Jupe, R., & Crompton, G. (2006). "A deficient performance": The regulation of the train
operating companies in Britain's privatised railway system. Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, 17(8), 1035-1065.
Justman, M., Thisse, J.-F., & van Ypersele, T. (2005). Fiscal competition and regional
differentiation. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35(6), 848-861.
Kaplan, R., & Johnson, T. (1987). Relevance Lost: Rise and Fall of Management Accounting.
Boston: Harvard University Press.
Kaplan, R., & Norton, D. (2008). Execution Premium. Linking Strategy to Operations for
Competitive Advantage. Boston: Harvard University Press.
Keynes, J. M. (1919). The economic consequences of the peace. London: Macmillan & Co.
Khadaroo, I. (2008). The actual evaluation of school PFI bids for value for money in the UK
public sector. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 19(8), 1321-1345.
Kliver, P. (2013). The Early Warning System for the Principle of Subsidiarity (Routledge
Research in EU Law). London: Routledge.
Kraus, K. (2012). Heterogeneous accountingisation: Accounting and inter-organisational
cooperation in home care services. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal,
25(7), 1080-1112.
Kurunmäki, L. (2004). A hybrid profession – the acquisition of management accounting
expertise by medical professionals. Accounting, Organizations & Society, 29, 327-
347.
Kurunmäki, L., Lapsley, I., & Melia, K. (2003). Accountingization v. legitimation: a
comparative study of the use of accounting information in intensive care.
Management Accounting Research, 14(2), 112-139.
Kurunmäki, L., & Miller, P. (2006). Modernising Government: The Calculating Self,
Hybridisation and Performance Measurement. Financial Accountability &
Management, 22(1), 87-106.
Kurunmäki, L., & Miller, P. (2011). Regulatory hybrids: Partnerships, budgeting and
modernising government. Management Accounting Research, 22(4), 220-241.
Kyle, C., & Peacey, J. (Eds.). (2002). Parliament at Work: Parliamentary Committees,
Political Power and Public Access in Early Modern England. London: Boydell Press.
– 52 / 59 –
Lane, P. R. (2012). The European Sovereign Debt Crisis. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 26(3), 49-67.
Latour, B. (2009). The making of law: an ethnography of the Conseil d'État. London: Polity
Press.
Laughlin, R. (1988). Accounting in its Social Context: An Analysis of the Accounting
Systems of the Church of England. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal,
1(2), 19-42.
Laughlin, R. (1990). A model of financial accountability and the Church of England.
Financial Accountability & Management, 6(2), 93-114.
Lawson, S. F. (2008). Running for Freedom: Civil Rights and Black Politics in America Since
1941. New York: Wiley-Blackwell.
Lawton, A., & Rose, A. G. (1994). Organisation and Management in the Public Sector.
London: Financial Times Management.
Le Corre, P., & Sepulchre, A. (2016). China's Offensive in Europe. London: Brookings
Institution Press.
Liguori, M., & Steccolini, I. (in press). The power of language in legitimating public-sector
reforms: When politicians “talk” accounting. The British Accounting Review.
Luders, J. E. (2010). The Civil Rights Movement and the Logic of Social Change. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Lyons, B. (1995). Specific investment, economies of scale, and the make-or-buy decision: A
test of transaction cost theory. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,
26(3), 431-443.
MacKenzie, D. (2009). Making things the same: Gases, emission rights and the politics of
carbon markets. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34(3–4), 440-455.
Maczulskij, T. (2013). Public–private sector wage differentials and the business cycle.
Economic Systems, 37(2), 284-301.
Mahaffrey, J. (2015). Atomic Accidents: A History of Nuclear Meltdowns and Disasters:
From the Ozark Mountains to Fukushima. London: Pegasus.
Mannberg, A., Jansson, J., Pettersson, T., Brännlund, R., & Lindgren, U. (2014). Do tax
incentives affect households ׳adoption of ‘green’ cars? A panel study of the Stockholm
congestion tax. Energy Policy, 74, 286-299.
Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance, 7, 77-91.
Mashaw, J. L. (2006). Accountability and institutional design : some thoughts on the grammar
of governance. In M. W. Dowdle (Ed.), Public accountability – Designs, dilemmas
and experiences (pp. 115-156). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McCartney, S., & Stittle, J. (2006). 'Not our problem': UK Government's fiscal obligations
towards the privatised railway network. Accounting Forum, 30(2), 139-153.
Miller, P., Kurunmäki, L., & O'Leary, T. (2008). Accounting, hybrids and the management of
risk. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 33(7-8), 942-967.
Miller, R. (2016). Desert Kingdoms to Global Powers: The Rise of the Arab Gulf. Yale: Yale
University Press.
Miller, W. (2017). Royal Mail Liners 1925-1971 London: Amberley Publishing.
Min, V. (2017). How To Get Into West Point: The Insider's Guide To The USMA Application
Process
Minkoff, D., & Powell, W. W. (2006). Nonprofit mission: constancy, responsiveness, or
deflection? In W. Powell & R. Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit sector – A research
handbook (pp. 591-611). Yale: Yale University Press.
Minzner, C. F. (2011). China's Turn Against Law. The American Journal of Comparative
Law, 59(4), 935-984.
– 53 / 59 –
Mitchell, W., & Fazi, T. (2017). Reclaiming the State: A Progressive Vision of Sovereignty
for a Post-Neoliberal World. London: Pluto Press.
Modell, S. (2001). Performance measurement and institutional processes: a study of
managerial responses to public sector reform. Management Accounting Research,
12(4), 437-464.
Monsen, N. (2006). Historical development of local government accounting in Norway.
Financial Accountability & Management, 22(4), 359-380.
Montagnon, P. (2002). Saint Cyr : Deux siècles au service de la France. Paris: Pygmalion.
Morales, J., Gendron, Y., & Guénin-Paracini, H. (2014). State privatization and the
unrelenting expansion of neoliberalism: The case of the Greek financial crisis. Critical
Perspectives on Accounting, 25(6), 423-445.
Morer, M., Ansel, D., Michelik, F., & Girandola, F. (2017). Sunk cost of local elected
representatives in situation of fiscal competition: An example of escalating
commitment. Revue Européenne de Psychologie Appliquée.
Morgan, B. (2006). Technocratic vs. convivial accountability. In M. W. Dowdle (Ed.), Public
accountability – Designs, dilemmas and experiences (pp. 243-268). Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Morris, D., McGregor-Lowndes, M., & Tarr, J.-A. (2015). Government grants – an abrogation
or management of risks? In Z. Hoque & L. Parker (Eds.), Performance management
in nonprofit organizations: global perspectives (pp. 369-393). London: Routledge.
Mouritsen, J. (1999). The flexible firm: strategies for a subcontractor's management control.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 24(1), 31-55.
Mueller, F., & Carter, C. (2007). 'We are all managers now': Managerialism and professional
engineering in UK electricity utilities. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32(1-
2), 181-195.
Mulder, J. (2016). EU Non-Discrimination Law in the Courts: Approaches to Sex and
Sexualities Discrimination in EU Law. London: Hart Publishing.
Munday, R. (2016). Agency: Law and Principles. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Neu, D., Everett, J., & Rahaman, A. S. (2009). Accounting assembalges, desire, and the body
without organs - A case study of international development lending in Latin America.
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 22(3), 319-350.
Neu, D., Leiser, S., & Ocampo, E. (2008). Diffusing finanical practices in Latin American
higher education: understanding the intersection ebtween global influance and the
local context. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 21(1), 49-77.
Neu, D., & Ocampo, E. (2007). Doing missionary work: The World Bank and the diffusion of
financial practices. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 18(3), 363-389.
Neu, D., Ocampo Gomez, E., Graham, C., & Heincke, M. (2006). “Informing” technologies
and the World Bank. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 31(7), 635-662.
Neu, D., Rahaman, A. S., Everett, J., & Akindayomi, A. (2010). The sign value of accounting:
IMF structural adjustment programs and African banking reform. Critical
Perspectives on Accounting, 21(5), 402-419.
Newhouse, J. (2008). Boeing Versus Airbus: The Inside Story of the Greatest International
Competition in Business. New York: Vintage Books USA.
Niskanen, W. A. J. (1971). Bureaucracy and Representative Government. New York: Aldine
Transaction.
Niskanen, W. A. J. (1986). Bureaucracy and Public Economics. New York: Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Oates, W. E. (2001). Fiscal competition and European Union: contrasting perspectives.
Regional Science and Urban Economics, 31(2), 133-145.
– 54 / 59 –
Ogden, S. G. (1995). Profit sharing and organizational change - attempts to promote
employee commitment in the newly privatized water industry in England and Wales.
Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 8(4), 23-47.
Oliver, I. (1996). Police, Government and Accountability. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Olson, M. (1974). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.
Harvard: Harvard University Press.
Orchard, L., & Strutton, H. (1994). Public Goods, Public Enterprise, Public Choice:
Theoretical Foundations of the Contemporary Attack on Government. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Ostrower, F., & Stone, M. M. (2006). Governance: research trends, gaps and future prospects.
In W. Powell & R. Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit sector – a research handbook (pp.
612-628). Beverly Hills: Yale University Press.
Ottow, A. (2015). Market and Competition Authorities: Good Agency Principles. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Owens, R. J., & Wedeking, J. P. (2011). Justices and Legal Clarity: Analyzing the
Complexity of U.S. Supreme Court Opinions. Law & Society Review, 45(4), 1027-
1061.
Parker, L. D. (2012). From Privatised to Hybrid Corporatised Higher Education: A Global
Financial Management Discourse. Financial Accountability & Management, 28(3),
247-268.
Pavlatos, O., & Kostakis, H. (2015). Management accounting practices before and during
economic crisis: Evidence from Greece. Advances in Accounting, 31(1), 150-164.
Pollack, M. A. (2002). The Engines Of European Integration: Delegation, Agency and
Agenda Setting in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Quattrone, P. (2009). Books to be practiced: Memory, the power of the visual, and the success
of accounting. Accounting, Organizations & Society, 34(1), 85-118.
Rahaman, A. S., Everett, J., & Neu, D. (2007). Accounting and the move to privatize water
services in Africa. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 20(5), 637-670.
Rakowski, N., & Patz, M. (2009). An overview and analysis of strategic alliances on the
example of the car manufacturer Renault. London: GRIN Publishing.
Rathgeb-Smith, S., & Grønberg, K. A. (2006). Scope and theory of government-nonprofit
relations. In W. Powell & R. Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit secteor – A research
handbook (pp. 221-242). Yale: Yale University Press.
Rawls, J. (2001). Justice as Fairness: A Restatement. Harvard: Harvard University Press.
Reid, E. M., & Toffel, M. W. (2009). Responding to public and private politics: Corporate
disclosure of climate change strategies. Strategic Management Journal, 30(11), 1157-
1178.
Reiden, R. (2001). Improving the Economy, Efficiency, and Effectiveness of Not-for-Profits:
Conducting Operational Reviews. London: Wiley.
Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2011). From Financial Crash to Debt Crisis. American
Economic Review, 101(5), 1676-1706.
Robert, H. M. (1994). Robert's Rules of Order: A Simplified, Updated Version of the Classic
Manual of Parliamentary Procedure. Berkeley: Berkeley Books.
Roger D. Billings Jr. (2001). Why Business Fails in Russia. The International Lawyer, 35(1),
123-136.
Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1979). The Elusive Median Vote. Journal of Public Economics,
12(2), 143-170.
Rose, N., & Miller, P. (1992). Political power beyond the State: problematics of government.
British Journal of Sociology, 43(2), 173-205.
– 55 / 59 –
Rosen, M., & Young, A. (2016). Who are Refugees and Migrants? What Makes People Leave
their Homes? And Other Big Questions. London: Wayland.
Rosner, D., Markowitz, G. E., & Milbank Memorial Fund. (2006). Are we ready? : public
health since 9/11. Berkeley
New York: University of California Press ;
Milbank Memorial Fund.
Roşoiu, I. (2015). The Impact of the Government Revenues and Expenditures on the
Economic Growth. Procedia Economics and Finance, 32, 526-533.
Ruano, J. (2016). Functional Federalism in a Complex State: The Case of Spain. In J. Ruano
& M. Profiroiou (Eds.), The Sage Handbook of decentralisation in Europe (pp. 77-
101). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Samuel, J. (2012). Occupy Wall Street, A Leftist, Anarchist Cult. New York: CreateSpace
Independent Publishing Platform.
Saravanamuthu, K., & Filling, S. (2004). A critical response to managerialism in the
Academy. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 15(4-5), 437-452.
Sargeant, A. (1999). Charitable giving: Towards a model of donor behaviour. Journal of
Marketing Management, 15(4), 215-238.
Sauviat, A. (2016). Decentralisation in France: A Principle in Permanent Evolution. In J.
Ruano & M. Profiroiou (Eds.), The Sage Handbook of decentralisation in Europe (pp.
157-200). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Scott, K. (2011). Federalism: A Normative Theory and its Practical Relevance. London:
Continuum.
Sedmak, C., & Gaisbauer, H. P. (2015). Fiscal Justice and Justified Trust. In H. P. Gaisbauer,
G. Schweiger & C. Sedmak (Eds.), Philosophical Explorations of Justice and
Taxation (pp. 17-31). London: Springer.
Seligmen, J. (2013). The Transformation of Wall Street: A History of the Securities and
Exchange Commission and Modern Corporate Finance. Aspen: Aspen Publishers.
Serritzlew, S. (2005). Breaking budgets: an empirical examination of Danish municipalities.
Financial Accountability & Management, 21(4), 413-435.
Shaoul, J. (1998). Charging for capital in the NHS trusts: to improve efficiency? Management
Accounting Research, 9(1), 95-112.
Shaoul, J., Stafford, A., & Stapleton, P. (2012). Accountability and corporate governance of
public private partnerships. Critical Perspectives on Accounting(0).
Shapiro, S. P. (2009). Wayward Capitalists: Target of the Securities and Exchange
Commission. Yale: Yale University Press.
Sharma, U., & Lawrence, S. (2009). Global remedies for local needs: Corporate governance
and public sector reforms in Fiji. Pacific Accounting Review, 21(3), 260-285.
Shazmin, S. A. A., Sipan, I., & Sapri, M. (2016). Property tax assessment incentives for green
building: A review. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 60, 536-548.
Sherrer, C. (2017). Public Banks in the Age of Financialization: A Comparative Perspective.
London: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Siemens (von), C.-F. (1921). Veredelte Umsatzsteuer. Berlin: Selbstverlag.
Sikka, P. (2009). Financial crisis and the silence of the auditors. Accounting, Organizations
and Society, 34(6-7), 868-873.
Simoncini, M. (2018). Administrative Regulation Beyond the Non-Delegation Doctrine: A
Study on EU Agencies London: Hart Publishing.
Simons, R. (2000). Performance measurement and control systems for implementing strategy.
Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Sinclair, A. (1995). The chameleon of accountability: Forms and discourses. Accounting,
Organizations and Society, 20(2-3), 219-237.
– 56 / 59 –
Singer, R. G. (2000). The Proposed Duty to Inquire as Affected by Recent Criminal Law
Decisions in the United States Supreme Court. Buffalo Criminal Law Review, 3(2),
701-754.
Skaerbaek, P. (2009). Public sector auditor identities in making efficiency auditable: The
National Audit Office of Denmark as independent auditor and modernizer.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34(8), 971-987.
Slootmaeckers, K., & Touquet, H. (2016). The EU Enlargement and Gay Politics: The Impact
of Eastern Enlargement on Rights, Activism and Prejudice. London: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Smyth, S. (2015). Co-operatives or Public Services: social housing and accountability.
Journal of Accounting & Organizational Change, 9(forthcoming).
Spence, C. Accounting for the dissolution of a nation state: Scotland and the Treaty of Union.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, In Press, Corrected Proof.
Staggenborg, S. (2015). Social movements. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Stalebrink, O. J., & Sacco, J. F. (2007). Rationalization of financial statement fraud in
government: An Austrian perspective. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 18(4),
489-507.
Stanny, E., & Ely, K. (2008). Corporate environmental disclosures about the effects of
climate change. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management,
15(6), 338-348.
Stiglitz, J. (2003). Globalization and its discontents. New York: Penguin.
Stiglitz, J., & Rosengard, J. (2015). Economics of the Public Sector. New York: W. W.
Norton & Company.
Stoilova, D. (2017). Tax structure and economic growth: Evidence from the European Union.
Contaduría y Administración, 62(3), 1041-1057.
Suzuki, T. (2003). The epistemology of macroeconomic reality: The Keynesian Revolution
from an accounting point of view. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 28(5), 471-
517.
Taha, N. (2013). Forensic accounting applicability: the case of Lebanon. Doctorate of
Business Administration DBA thesis, Grenoble École de Management, Grenoble.
Tambulasi, R. (2007). Who is fooling who?: New public management-oriented management
accounting and political control in the Malawi's local governance. Journal of
Accounting & Organizational Change, 3(3), 302 - 328.
Tănăsescu, i. E., & Oliva, E. (2018). Constitutional Law and the EU Balanced Budget
Principle. London: Routledge.
Thévenet, J.-P. (1996). Louis Renault : Histoire d'une tragédie et d'une nationalisation. Paris:
Londreys.
Thiel (van), S., Verhoest, K., Bouckaert, G., & Lægreid, P. (2016). Lessons and
Recommendations for the Practice of Agencification. In K. Verhoest, G. Bouckaert, S.
Thiel (van) & P. Lægreid (Eds.), Government Agencies Practices and Lessons from 30
Countries (pp. 413-439). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Thiel, S. (2012). Comparing agencies across countries. In K. Verhoest, S. Thiel (van), G.
Bouckaert & P. Lægreid (Eds.), Government Agencies: Practices and Lessons from 30
Countries (Public sector organizations) (pp. 18-26). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Thomas J. Miceli. (2009). Legal Change: Selective Litigation, Judicial Bias, and Precedent.
The Journal of Legal Studies, 38(1), 157-168.
Tilton, T. (1974). The social origins of liberal democracy: the Swedish case. The American
Political Science Review, 68, 561-571.
Timoshenko, K., & Adhikari, P. (2009). Exploring Russian central government accounting in
its context. Journal of Accounting & Organizational Change, 5(4), 490-513.
– 57 / 59 –
Tinkelman, D., & Mankaney, K. (2007). When is administrative efficiency associated with
charitable donations? Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 36(1), 41-64.
Tobin, J. (1978). A proposal for international monetary reform. Eastern Economic Journal,
4(3/4), 153-159.
Tobin, J. (1996). A currency transactions tax, why and how. Open Econmies Review, 7, 493-
499.
Trussel, J. M., & Parsons, L. M. (2007). Financial Reporting Factors Affecting Donations to
Charitable Organizations. Advances in Accounting, 23, 263-285.
U.S.-China_Economic_and_Security_Review_Commission. (2017). Chinese Investment in
the United States: Impacts and Issues for Policymakers. Washington: CreateSpace
Independent Publishing Platform.
Uddin, S., & Hopper, T. (2001). A Bangladesh soap opera: privatisation, accounting, and
regimes of control in a less developed country. Accounting,Organizations and Society,
26(7-8), 643-672.
Uddin, S., & Hopper, T. (2003). Accounting for privatisation in Bangladesh: testing World
Bank claims. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 14(7), 739-774.
Umbach, M. (Ed.). (2002). German Federalism: Past, Present and Future (New Perspectives
in German Political Studies). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Usumanu, A. (2017). Assessment of Performance Management System in a Power Utility
Company. New York: LAP LAMBERT Academic Publishing.
Vakis, R. (2006). Complementing natural disasters management: The role of social
protection. Washington, DC: The World Bank Social Protection Paper, 543.
Valcke, C. (2010). The French response to the World Bank's 'Doing Business' reports. The
University of Toronto Law Journal, 60(2), 197-217.
Vinnari, E., & Skærbæak, P. (2014). The uncertainties of risk management: A field study on
risk management internal audit practices in a Finnish municipality. Accounting,
Auditing & Accountability Journal, 27(3), 489-526.
Vinten, G. (2007). Bystanding public services accounting. Critical Perspectives on
Accounting, 18(7), 829-830.
von der Pfordten, D. (2015). Justice, Equality and Taxation. In H. P. Gaisbauer, G. Schweiger
& C. Sedmak (Eds.), Philosophical Explorations of Justice and Taxation (pp. 47-65).
London: Springer.
Watkins, A. L., & Arrington, C. E. (2007). Accounting, New Public Management and
American Politics: Theoretical Insights into the National Performance Review.
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 18(1), 33-58.
Weaver, J. (2003). Debating the Tobin Tax: New Rules for Global Finance. London:
Automated Graphic Systems.
Weber, M. (1922). Economy and Society. Berkeley: The University of California Press.
Wettestad, J., & Gulbrandsen, L. H. (Eds.). (2017). The Evolution of Carbon Markets –
Design and Diffusion. London: Routledge.
White-House, Federal-Bureau-of-Investigation, National-Security-Agency, US-Congress,
National-Intelligence-Council, & Bazan, E. B. (2017). Attempt to Impeach Donald
Trump - Declassified Government Documents, Investigation of Russian Election
Interference & Legislative Procedures for the Impeachment: ... of James Comey and
other Documents. New York: Madison & Adams Press.
Wilson, G. (2007). Emirates: The Airline of the Future. Media Prima.
Wilson, J. (1991). What Government Agencies Do And Why They Do It. London: Basic
Books.
Wouters, M., Kokke, K., Theeuwes, J., & van Donselaar, K. (1999). Identification of critical
operational performance measures— a research note on a benchmarking study in the
– 58 / 59 –
transportation and distribution sector. Management Accounting Research, 10(4), 439-
452.
Yassin, S., & Langot, F. (in press). Informality, public employment and employment
protection in developing countries. Journal of Comparative Economics.
Zetter, L. (2014). Lobbying: The Art of Political Persuasion. London: Harriman House
Publishing.
– 59 / 59 –