Sector Rotation Over Business Cycles
Sector Rotation Over Business Cycles
Sector Rotation Over Business Cycles
Jeffrey Stangl∗
Massey University - Department of Commerce
Ben Jacobsen
Massey University - Department of Commerce
Nuttawat Visaltanachoti
Massey University - Department of Commerce
Abstract
Sector rotation is a widely followed investment strategy popular among professional and
individual investors. Yet, despite the growth of sector investing in recent years, the
question of whether or not sector rotation outperforms an investment in the market has
not been previously answered. We examine the relative performance of a sector rotation
strategy that follows conventional market wisdom on timing sector holdings over
business-cycles from 1948-2006. We find that a sector rotation strategy guided by
conventional market wisdom on where sectors provide optimal performance and with
20/20 hindsight timing business-cycles stages would have earned a 2.01% Jensen’s alpha.
This apparent outperformance is a best case scenario that would quickly dissipate without
the benefit of hindsight and after a reasonable allowance for transaction fees. As an
alternative, we show that a strategy which simply switches to cash as the business-cycle
enters a recession provides superior returns to sector rotation. We conclude that, contrary
to conventional market wisdom, rotating sectors over business-cycles is not an optimal
investment strategy and question the widespread acceptance of sector rotation as a
strategy that provides investors with relative outperformance.
∗
Corresponding author: Massey University, Department of Commerce, Private Bag 102904, North Shore
Mail Centre, Auckland, New Zealand 0745, E-mail: j.stangl@massey.ac.nz
Sector Rotation over Business-Cycles
Abstract
Sector rotation is a widely followed investment strategy popular among professional and
individual investors. Yet, despite the growth of sector investing in recent years, the
question of whether or not sector rotation outperforms an investment in the market has
not been previously answered. We examine the relative performance of a sector rotation
strategy that follows conventional market wisdom on timing sector holdings over
business-cycles from 1948-2006. We find that a sector rotation strategy guided by
conventional market wisdom on where sectors provide optimal performance and with
20/20 hindsight timing business-cycles stages would have earned a 2.01% Jensen’s alpha.
This apparent outperformance is a best case scenario that would quickly dissipate without
the benefit of hindsight and after a reasonable allowance for transaction fees. As an
alternative, we show that a strategy which simply switches to cash as the business-cycle
enters a recession provides superior returns to sector rotation. We conclude that, contrary
to conventional market wisdom, rotating sectors over business-cycles is not an optimal
investment strategy and question the widespread acceptance of sector rotation as a
strategy that provides investors with relative outperformance.
2
I. Introduction
A sector rotation strategy is based on the idea that certain sectors provide relative strength
during different phases of the business-cycle. While rotating sectors across business-
cycles is not a new strategy, sector rotation has witnessed a large growth in popularity as
evidenced by the increasing number of sector funds introduced over the last two decades.
One group of funds alone, Fidelity Select, currently offers investors a choice of 51 sector
funds.1 The growth of sector funds has ballooned in recent years particularly with the
introduction of exchange traded funds (ETFs). In 2006, the number of sector ETFs
available doubled from 67 to 135.2 Despite growing interest in sector investing, sector
rotation investors remain reliant on conventional market wisdom and anecdotal evidence
for validation of the widely held view that rotating sectors across business-cycles
wisdom on the sectors to hold across business-cycles generates additional alpha returns.
Given the sizable amount of investment capital sector rotation attracts, we believe that
1
http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/products.shtml
2
Investment Company Institute, 2007. Investment Company Fact Book (Investment Company Institute).
3
and business-cycle movements would indicate anomalous market behavior and be of
The results of our study indicate sector rotation does not generate risk-adjusted returns in
excess of the market. We cover the period 1948-2006 with NBER defined phases of
expansion and recession divided into smaller sub-periods to coincide with business-cycle
stages where the market expects optimal sector performance.1 We find that a sector
rotation investor guided by conventional market wisdom and with 20/20 hindsight timing
business-cycles stages would have only realized a marginal 2.1% Jensen’s alpha. This
marginal outperformance is a best case scenario that comes before any allowance for
transaction fees and with the benefit of perfect hindsight. More realistically, it would
seem extremely difficult for a real-time investor to correctly time sector investments
strategy that is continually invested in the market excluding the first half of a recession.
Market-timing investors would only need to anticipate one stage of the business-cycle
and incur only one-fifth the transaction costs of a sector rotation strategy. For the same
terminal wealth and higher Sharpe ratio compared to a sector rotation investor. This
comparison illustrates that sector rotation would not be the optimal strategy, even for an
1
See DeStefano, Michael, 2004, Stock Returns and the Business Cycle., Financial Review 39, 527-547. for
an example of this methodology.
4
that, contrary to conventional market wisdom, rotating sectors over business-cycles is not
an optimal investment strategy and question the widespread acceptance of sector rotation
Our contribution to the literature is twofold. First, we believe our study is the first to
empirically document the performance and relative strength of sectors over the course of
a business-cycle. We find actual sector performance largely fails to align with the
expectations of conventional market wisdom. Secondly and more critically, we show that
contrary to conventional wisdom and despite the popularity of sector rotation among
investors, a sector rotation strategy yields only marginal outperformance that is inferior to
Our study is organized as follows. Section II provides an overview and discusses the
sector rotation strategy with terminal wealth estimations. Lastly, section VI concludes our
analysis.
II. Overview
The basic notion of sector rotation is that different economic sectors predictably and
Moreover, sector rotation investors believe the relative performance of sectors moves
5
sequentially from one sector to the next over the course of a business-cycle.1 The
conventional market lore and widely supported by the financial press. For instance,
conventional wisdom holds "if you are in the right sector at the right time, you can make
a lot of money very fast."2 The challenge for sector rotation investors in outperforming
the market is to both correctly select sectors and correctly time the business-cycle - a
The financial press provides abundant advice to investors on timing sector investments
with business-cycles. For instance, a CNN Money article warns against the implication of
an economic slowdown on sector returns after a pause in Federal Reserve Bank interest
rate hikes. The same CNN article further suggests pharmaceuticals, financials, consumer
webpage similarly advises “when the economy cools off, cyclical companies are hit
phases.” 4 Conventional market wisdom holds that cyclical industries provide the greatest
relative strength when the economy first enters a period of expansion.5 In his widely
followed practitioner guide “Sector Investing,” Stovall (1996) catalogs where sectors are
believed to provide investors with the highest returns over different stages of economic
1
Fidelity Investments, 2007, Sector Education, (Fidelity Investments).
2
http://www.nowvest.com/ Peter Lynch in Beating the Street
3
http://money.cnn.com/2006/08/08/markets/fed_pause_stocks.moneymag/index.htm
4
http://www.investopedia.com/terms/d/defensivestock.asp
5
Business Week Online, 2002, Get In, Get Out, and Move On, (McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc.).
6
Nonetheless, while conventional market wisdom abounds, until now prior empirical
research has yet to document if sector rotation is actually a viable investment strategy.
Indeed, market efficiency theory suggests earnings fluctuations that result from
odds with basic assumptions of market efficiency. There are several possible explanations
correlated with economic conditions. An early study by Fama and French (1989) finds
that stocks and bonds contain a term premium that coincides with business-cycle peaks
and troughs. Chordia and Shivakumar (2002) and more recently Avramov and Chordia
(2006) confirm that priced factors such as firm size, value, and momentum are correlated
The conclusion that sectors perform unequally or exhibit a lead/lag relationship across
business-cycles is found in several studies. Hou (2007) find a lead/lag effect in sector
response to the arrival of new economic information. Hong, Torous and Valkanov (2007)
and Eleswarapu and Tiwari (1996) observe that sectors with a strong link to economic
7
activity such as the retail, metals, services, and petroleum sectors lead the market by as
much as two months. Menzly and Ozbas (2004) show that the timing of industry profits
relate to its position in the production/consumption supply chain with a persistent lag
relationship exists between returns to upstream and downstream industries. This upstream
and downstream relationship is also seen to hold by Stovall (1996) who observes that
basic materials are the first industry to emerge from a recession followed in turn by
manufacturing. Stovall (1996) finds that industries related to end-user consumption, such
The question largely remains unanswered if sector rotation investors have historically
outperformed the market. The limited empirical research on the profitability of sector
rotation strategies provides conflicting results. A study of sector fund returns by Sassetti
and Tani (2003) concludes that in the medium-term sector switching is a profitable
strategy. However, they also find a long-horizon investor is still better off investing in a
market index. In contrast, Tiwari and Vijh (2005) question the ability of investors to
profitably rotate funds from one sector to another. Their findings based on sector fund
data from 1972-1999 show sector investors lack both selection and timing ability and are
unable to earn excess returns after correcting for risk and deduction of transaction fees.
of an enigma. Widely held conventional wisdom suggests a strategy which rotates sectors
dependent on the phase of a business-cycle can generate excess returns for investors.
8
Anecdotal evidence from financial practitioners supports the idea of a correlation
between sector performance and business-cycle conditions. However, there has been only
scant research in this regard. The literature does document evidence of cyclical patterns
lead/lag relationship between sectors that could result in unequal sector performance
business-cycles exists, sector investors must still correctly time sector investments with
business conditions. The ability of sector rotation funds to systematically outperform the
market seems questionable based on the results of some studies. In the analysis which
follows, we endeavor to address the question if an investor who rotates sectors across
III. Business-cycles
Sector rotation requires the correct timing of sector investments with different stages of
the business-cycle. The idea of accurately predicting business-cycles has been the bane of
econometricians and financial researchers for years. The official government agency
responsible for dating business-cycles in the U.S. is The National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER). The NBER merely tracks cycle turning points (peaks and troughs) and
can take as long as two years after the economy changes direction to publish cycle dates.
Consequently, real-time investors are unable to benefit from this information. However,
for the purpose of our study NBER defined business-cycle dates provide a necessary
9
While the NBER defines broad phases of economic expansion and recession, common
practice is to divide cycle phases into smaller sub-periods in order to better observe asset
sensitivity to business-cycle dynamics. DeStefano (2004) divides cycles into two stages
of expansion (early/late) and two stages of recession (early/late). Stovall (1996) further
divides longer periods of expansion into three stages (early/middle/late). This convention
is more aligned with common practice. We follow Stovall (1996) and partition NBER
dated phases of expansion into three equal stages (early, middle, and late) and recessions
into two equal stages (early and late). Figure I illustrates a stylized business-cycle with
phases of expansion divided into three stages and phases of recessions into two. This
study uses the five business-cycle stages as shown in Figure I for analysis of sector
Our study covers nine complete business-cycles over the period December 1948 to
December 2006. The last published NBER turning point was the economic peak dated
March 2001. To utilize all the available data, we divide the ensuing 61 month period of
our study into early expansion (30 months) and middle expansion (31 months). We make
the assumption that the economy enters the late stage of expansion starting in 2007
10
largely based on a survey of professional forecasters by the Philadelphia Federal
Reserve.1
Panel A of Table I reports business-cycle peak and business-cycle trough reference dates
published by the NBER. Additionally, the duration of business-cycles counted from peak
to peak is shown. While business-cycles have lasted an average 70 months in the years
since 1948, they exhibit a great deal of variability in duration with earlier business-cycles
In Panel B business-cycles are further divided by three stages of expansion and two
stages of recession. We count the total length of a recession to be from the first month
following a cycle peak to the subsequent cycle trough date. Periods of expansion are
counted to be from the first month following a cycle trough to subsequent cycle peak
date. From Table I we observe that expansions last on average approximately five years
and recessions less than one year. The average duration of expansions, recessions, and
The starting point of our sample is motivated by two considerations. First, restricting our
sample to post 1948 eliminates any possible business-cycle distortions caused by the
1
see Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank, 2007, Survey of Professional Forecasters, (Philadelphia Federal
Reserve Bank).
11
Great Depression or World War II.1 For instance, although the US economy was
officially in a depression during 1945, industries were still operating at full war time
production. Second, we start our sample from 1948 as several studies suggest business-
cycles are arguably different in the years since WWII. For instance, Fama (1975) finds
business-cycle length and amplitude change subsequent to adoption of the 1951 Federal
Reserve Accord. The 1951 Accord allows the Federal Reserve Bank to moderate
of counter-cyclical policies in the years since 1948 has resulted in different business-
expansions and recessions. Our five business-cycle stage dummy variables S jt take the
value one or zero conditional at time t on the current stage of the business-cycle. Dummy
variables S1t through S3t correspond with the three stages of economic expansion
(early/middle/late). Dummy variables S 4t and S5t correspond with the two stages of
1
See for example Chatterjee (1999) and Cover, James P., and Paul Pecorino, 2005, The length of US
business expansions: When did the break in the data occur?, Journal of Macroeconomics 27, 452-471.)
12
IV. Sector Performance
Our data is well known monthly industry returns, market returns, and Treasury-bill rates
from 1948-2006 obtained from the Kenneth French website.1 Market returns represent the
total value weighted returns on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks. The one-month
Treasury-bill from Ibbotson serves as a proxy for the risk-free interest rate. 48 value
weighted industry portfolios are formed by CRSP and Compustat SIC classifications. All
return data is described in further detail on the Kenneth French website. 2 For clarity of
(1996) simply observes nominal returns without any risk adjustment. Nonetheless, the
wisdom and is widely followed by investors and popular mutual funds.3 Each of the 48
the appropriate sector. Stage I (early expansion) has two sectors with a total six
1
http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/Data_Library/det_49_ind_port.html
2
http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/Data_Library
3
See for example http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/basics.shtml.cvsr
13
industries; Stage II (middle expansion) has two sectors with a total twelve industries;
Stage III (late expansion) has two sectors with a total ten industries; Stage IV (early
recession) has two sectors with a total two industries; and lastly Stage IV (late expansion)
has two sectors with a total eighteen industries. The total number of industries included in
each business-cycle stage range significantly from two in Stage IV to eighteen in Stage V
We now observe summary statistics for the entire 1948-2006 sample period and also
conditional on the stage of the business-cycle from our basic model equation (1)
5
rit − rft = ∑ α j S jt + ε t (1)
j =1
where excess industry returns rit − rft are the difference between nominal industry returns
and the one-month Treasury-bill and the S j ' s are business-cycle timing variables as
described earlier. The α j ' s can be interpreted as industry returns conditional on the stage
of the business-cycle. The error term (εt) is a white-noise error term with White (1980)
14
Table III reports average returns, standard deviations, and beta coefficients for all 48
industries, the market index, and Treasury-bills. Industries are grouped by the business-
cycle stage expected to provide optimal performance.1 Returns are then sorted from
highest to lowest beta within each group. The total number of observations for the entire
period and each business-cycle stage are shown at the top and observations by industry
are shown on the left-hand column of Table III. Note that all but five industries span the
full sample period. The exceptions are the fabricated products, precious metals, defence,
and healthcare industries which start in July 1963 and computer software industry which
We first look at summary statistics for the market and Treasury-bills. The market
averages a 7.1% return for the entire period with the highest return occurring during
Stage V (34.9%) and lowest return occurring during Stage IV (-22.8%). This represents a
sizable 57.7% difference in market returns between the beginning and end of recession.
This is all the more remarkable considering recessions last on average less than one year.
Similarly, DeStefano (2004) observes that returns to the S&P 500 are highest across all
business-cycle stages during late recessions. In contrast with market returns, market
1
See for example Stovall (1996), Sam Stovall’s Sector Watch
http://www.businessweek.com/investor/list/stovall_toc01.htm, and Fidelity Sector Funds at
http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/basics.shtml.cvsr
15
volatility as measured by standard deviation, is relatively stable across business-cycles
with an average 14.5% for the entire period and a range from a low of 12.8% in Stage I to
a high of 18.2% in Stage V. Predictably, the highest Treasury-bill rates (6.4%) are
observed during Stage IV and the lowest (3.8%) during Stage I. Treasury-bill rates are a
key economic indicator that track Federal Reserve monetary policy. These rates show an
expected monotonic increase from early expansion to early recession but then decrease
Industry returns exhibit the same pattern as market averages with virtually all returns
lowest during Stage IV and highest during Stage V. The tobacco industry has the only
positive return (0.6%) with the lowest beta of all industries as the economy enters a
recession in Stage IV. When we look further at industries, the highest volatility of returns
experience their lowest volatility during Stage II. A possible explanation for the overall
low volatility found during the middle period of economic expansion is the relatively
stable industry earnings which occur between the rapid growth typical of early
expansions and decelerating growth typical of late expansions. Unequal sector volatility
communications sector (0.72) and utilities sector (0.54) are regarded by the market as
16
recession hedges and have among the lowest overall betas for the entire period. Not
surprisingly, the computer software industry (1.78) has the highest overall beta. The
lowest beta for all business-cycle stages is the utilities sector (0.33) in Stage V and
highest is the computer software sector (2.37) in Stage IV. There is some apparent
clustering within business-cycle stages with maximum betas for 14 industries occurring
in Stage V and minimum betas for 18 industries occurring in Stage III. Generally there
appears to be no pattern across cycle stages where certain sectors exhibit the highest
relative risk. Rather, industry minimum and maximum betas appear largely dispersed
industry betas and the business-cycle stage where they are expected to provide relative
outperformance. The clear exceptions are the telecom and utility sectors in Stage V.
Overall the investigation of nominal returns indicates that actual industry performance
market wisdom from Table II. Those sectors selected for late expansion, early recession,
and late recession succeed in outperforming the market. For instance, in early recession
the sectors considered optimal for that period (utilities and telecom) show an average
return of -7.6% as compares with an average -30.4% return for the worst performing
between the best and worst performing sectors for that stage. For the two remaining
periods, early and middle expansion, sector averages are within a much narrower range.
17
We are also interested in observing if there is a significant difference in nominal returns
within industries across business-cycle stages. The right-hand column of Table III reports
p-values from a Wald test of joint significance with alphas obtained from our conditional
between the five business-cycle stages. If industry returns are constant across business-
cycle stages then differences in means should be statistically indistinguishable from zero.
H o : α1 = α 2 = α 3 = α 4 = α 5
H1 : α1 ≠ α 2 ≠ α 3 ≠ α 4 ≠ α 5
with α j ' s nominal industry returns conditional on each of the five business-cycle stages
as obtained from our basic model (eq.1). Based on the results of a Wald test of joint
significance, we reject the null hypothesis of constant returns. Under the null hypothesis,
p-values are under 10% and close to zero for all but two industries. The exceptions are
computer software and precious metals. A possible explanation for these two exceptions
is the loss of statistical power due to the shorter sample size of these industries. We can
conclude from the Wald test that industry returns are not equal over the course of a
business-cycle.
18
Table IV compares Sharpe ratios and Jensen’s alphas for industries across business-cycle
stages. The Sharpe ratios provide a comparison of excess industry returns relative to risk.
Jensen’s alphas provide a measure of industry returns in excess of the risk-free rate and
adjusted for systematic market risk. Conditional Jensen’s alphas are obtained as the
intercept terms from our modified CAPM model equation (2) as follows:
5 5
rit − rft = ∑ α j S jt + ∑ β j S jt (rmt − rft ) + ε t (2)
j =1 j =1
where excess industry returns rit − rft are the difference between unadjusted industry
returns and the one-month Treasury-bill and S j ' s are business-cycle timing variables as
described earlier. The α j ' s can now be interpreted as Jensen’s alphas conditional on the
(White, 1980). Sharpe ratios are calculated as industry returns in excess of the Treasury-
bill rate divided by the standard deviation of industry returns. Industries are grouped by
19
market wisdom.1 Returns are then sorted from highest to lowest Sharpe ration within each
group.
of the six industries in the technology and transportation sectors that are expected to
outperform in Stage I, only two (shipping containers and general transportation) have
positive alphas. All industries in the technology sector have particular large negative
alphas. Automobiles (7.0%) have the highest Jensen’s alpha during early expansion
although consumer cyclical industries are not expected to show relative strength until
Stage V. On average, all Stage II sectors (capital goods, basic materials, services sectors)
underperform the market. Aircraft (3.9%) and electrical equipment (2.7%) industries
provide the best outperformance while shipbuilding (-5.8%) and personal service (-4.1%)
provide the worst. The realized outperformance of Stage III sectors largely aligns with
market expectations. Only one industry (candy and soda) underperforms the market.
Notably, the energy sectors (coal and petroleum) provide good overall outperformance
during Stage III. The two Stage IV sectors, communication (5.7%) and utilities (13.3%),
1
See for example Stovall (1996), Sam Stovall’s Sector Watch
http://www.businessweek.com/investor/list/stovall_toc01.htm, and Fidelity Sector Funds at
http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/basics.shtml.cvsr
20
also significantly outperform the market. In particular, utilities are the strongest Stage IV
perform as anticipated during late recession. Several consumer durable industries, apparel
the Stage III sectors (consumer staples and energy) that as a group provide the best Stage
V performance and not the expected sectors (consumer cyclical and financial) with
Overall, our results provide limited evidence that sectors provide relative strength during
the business-cycle stage that is predicted by conventional market wisdom. Results for
early and middle expansion suggest investors are better off in the market than sectors.
Late expansion and early recession industries perform largely as expected. While in late
transportation) have a substantially lower average Sharpe ratio than the market at 0.14
and 0.26 respectively. Sectors expected to provide relative Stage II strength also
(0.21) is the sole industry of those expected to provide relative Stage II strength that
outperforms the market. Looking at the remainder of industries during middle expansion,
those in the consumer staples sector provide the best Sharpe ratio outperformance. Sharpe
21
ratios for sectors expected to provide Stage III and Stage IV outperformance align with
market expectations. Notably, tobacco (0.01) is the only industry with a positive Sharpe
ratio during Stage IV. Capital goods is the overall worst performing sector as the
economy enters a recession with fabricated products (-0.64) the worst industry. Lastly,
only five of eighteen industries expected to provide relative strength during Stage V
realize higher Sharpe ration than the market. Although nominal industry returns are
mostly higher than the market during Stage V, investors using Sharpe ratio as a metric are
stages. The right-hand column in Table IV reports p-values from a Wald test of joint
significance for Jensen’s alphas obtained from our conditional business-cycle model with
H o : α1 = α 2 = α 3 = α 4 = α 5
H1 : α1 ≠ α 2 ≠ α 3 ≠ α 4 ≠ α 5
22
with α j ' s industry Jensen’s alphas conditional on each of the five business-cycle stages
as obtained from our model (eq.2). Based on the results of a Wald test of joint
significance, we accept the null hypothesis of constant alpha returns for 35 industries at a
particular sector with the 18 industries that have significantly different alphas distributed
across business-cycles.
Similar to our earlier analysis of alpha performance, Sharpe ratios provide a mixed
picture at best of sector performance. Investors appear to be better off invested in the
market index for every business-cycle stage except late expansion and early recession.
The consumer staple and energy sectors provide the clearest Sharpe ratio outperformance
over the entire business-cycle in late expansion. Otherwise there is no definite pattern of
where sectors and industries provide the best outperformance using either Jensen’s alphas
or Sharpe ratios as a performance metric. Moreover, the results from our Wald test of
joint significance indicate there is no difference in alpha returns for most industries
Next, we compare payoffs for a hypothetical dollar investment from December 1948
through December 2006 for three different strategies: market index, sector rotation, and
the growth in value for each strategy over the 58 year period. We also report at the
23
bottom of Figure II terminal values and Sharpe ratios for each strategy and Jensen’s alpha
for the sector rotation strategy. Shaded areas on Figure II indicate NBER defined periods
of recession.
We first compare our sector rotation strategy to a simple investment in the market index.
Our sector rotation strategy constructs portfolios by business-cycle stage with equal
weighting for all industries included in that stage. For example, there are six industries in
the Stage I (early expansion) portfolio held in weights of 1/6 each. Portfolios for each of
the remaining four business-cycle stages are constructed likewise. Portfolios are rotated
at each stage of the business-cycle. The market index strategy simply invests 100% in the
market index continually from the start to the end of the sample period.
A sector rotation strategy outperforms the market index with terminal values of $1,094
and $372 respectively for the entire 1948-2006 period. Moreover, sector rotation has a
Jensen’s alpha of 2.1% for the full period that is significant at a 10% level. The overall
risk/return trade-off measured by the Sharpe ratio is also marginally better for sector
rotation (0.15) than for the market (0.13). However, the outperformance of sector
rotation relative to the market index is uneven across the different business-cycle stages.
Sector rotation underperforms the market index in both Stage I and Stage II with negative
alphas of -5.3% and -1.0% respectively. Sharpe ratios for the market index are also
24
higher than those for sector rotation during both periods. Underperformance of the sector
rotation strategy during Stage I and Stage II comes as no surprise given our earlier
observation of the performance of sectors assigned to those two stages. Sector rotation
provides the highest outperformance during Stage IV with a 10.3% Jensen’s alpha and a
Sharpe ratio that, while negative (-0.15), is vastly superior to the market Sharpe ratio (-
0.43). However, the outperformance of sector rotation during Stage IV can be attributed
to simply holding the two lowest beta sectors (utilities and communications) during a
Sector rotation shows much higher volatility than the market during periods of economic
crisis as Figure II illustrates for the 1987 market crash, 1997/98 Asian economic crisis,
and 2001 dot-com collapse. The amplified volatility seen in the sector rotation strategy
A profitable sector rotation strategy requires correctly timing the different stages of a
business-cycle. The 2.1% outperformance of our sector rotation strategy comes from the
anticipate all business-cycle stages. The marginal outperformance we find for a sector
rotation strategy is a best case scenario that would quickly dissipate without perfect
hindsight and with an allowance for normal transaction fees. Our results suggest that,
25
although an investor with the ability to forecast business-cycles with 100% accuracy
could marginally outperform the market, with more realistic assumptions it is unlikely
Market-timing is a strategy that invests fully in the market for all periods except the first
period of a recession when only cash is held. Studies such as Siegel (1991) and Brocato
and Steed (1998) among others document that investors should switch entirely from
stocks to cash as the economy enters a recession. Our analysis similarly confirms that
investors are better off completely out of equities during early recession. However, as
conditions.
Results for the market-timing strategy are shown at the bottom of Figure II. The terminal
value for market-timing is slightly higher than sector rotation at $1,142 and $1,094
respectively. Overall, market-timing (0.18) also outperforms sector rotation (0.15) from a
Sharpe ratio perspective. The obvious advantages to market-timing over sector rotation is
the need to forecast only one business-cycle stage rather five stages and a significant
diversification than sector rotation. Even for an investor with the ability to correctly time
26
VI. Conclusion
We recognize certain limitations of our study. The partitioning of business-cycles into
returns within broadly defined NBER economic phases. However, all business-cycles
have somewhat different dynamics that our partitioning might fail to capture.
Additionally, recessions that are relatively short in duration with a limited number of
The results of our study show that a sector rotation strategy following conventional
market wisdom on which sectors to rotate over the different stages of a business-cycle is
not an optimal investment strategy. A sector rotation investor with the benefit of perfect
hindsight timing business-cycles stages would have only realized a 2.1% Jensen’s alpha
from 1948-2006. This marginal outperformance would quickly dissipate without the
benefit of 20/20 hindsight and after deducting transaction fees. Alternatively, we find that
a much simpler market-timing strategy that shifts to cash early in a recession and holds
conclude that, contrary to conventional market wisdom, rotating sectors over business-
cycles is not an optimal investment strategy and question the widespread acceptance of
27
Table I
Notes: Panel A shows NBER reference dates for business cycle peaks and troughs from
1948 to December 2006. Business cycles are measured from the first month following a
peak to subsequent peak. Periods of recession are counted as the first month following a
cycle peak to the subsequent trough. Periods of economic expansion are counted as the
first month following a cycle trough to subsequent peak. The last available NBER cycle
date is the trough recorded March 2001. Estimates of early and middle stages of current
expansion phase are based on available consensus forecasts.1
Panel B shows total duration in months for recessions and expansions based on NBER
turning points from Panel A. Further, similar to previous research we divide expansions
into three equal stages (early, middle, and late) and recessions into two equal stages
(early and late) to observe how sector returns align with market expectations.2 The
average duration of each stage is shown at bottom of Panel B.
Panel A: NBER business-cycle dates
Peak Trough Peak Months
11/48 10/49 07/53 56
07/53 05/54 08/57 49
08/57 04/58 04/60 32
04/60 02/61 12/69 116
12/69 11/70 11/73 47
11/73 03/75 01/80 74
01/80 07/80 07/81 18
07/81 11/82 07/90 108
07/90 03/91 03/01 128
03/01 11/01 NA NA
1
See Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 2007, The Survey of Professional Forecasters, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review 1–13. http://www.phil.frb.org/files/spf/survq207.html
2
See for example Stovall (1996), Sam Stovall’s Sector Watch
http://www.businessweek.com/investor/list/stovall_toc01.htm, and Fidelity Sector Funds at
http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/basics.shtml.cvsr
28
Table II
Notes: Table shows the stages of business cycle where previous studies and conventional
market wisdom suggest sectors are expected to provide relative outperformance. Periods
of expansion are divided into three equal stages (early, middle, and late) and are Periods
of recession are divided into two equal stages (early and late). Industry portfolios are
grouped by the first two digits of their SIC classification codes.1 Each of the 48 industries
portfolios in our study is assigned to a unique business cycle stage by their appropriate
sector (shown in bold).
Three Stages of Expansion Two Stages of Recession
Stage I Stage II Stage III Stage IV Stage V
Technology: Basic Materials: Consumer Staples: Utilities: Consumer Cyclical:
Computer Software Precious Metals Agriculture Gas & Electrical Utilities Apparel
Measuring & Control Equip. Chemicals Beer & Liquor Telecom Automobiles & Trucks
Computers Steel Works Etc Candy & Soda Business Supplies
Electronic Equipment Non-Metallic & Metal Minin Food Products Construction
Transportation: Capital Goods: Healthcare Construction Materials
General Transportation Fabricated Products Medical Equipment Consumer Goods
Shipping Containers Defense Pharmaceutical Products Entertainment
Machinery Tobacco Products Printing & Publishing
Ships & Railroad Equip. Energy: Recreation
Aircraft Coal Restaraunts, Hotels, Motels
Electrical Equipment Petroleum & Natural Gas Retail
Services: Rubber & Plastic Products
Business Services Textiles
Personal Services Wholesale
Financial:
Banking
Insurance
Real Estate
Trading
1
For a complete description of SIC codes included in each industry portfolio see
http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/Data_Library/det_49_ind_port.html
29
Table III
Notes: Table reports descriptive statistics for value weighted industry returns, market
returns, and Treasury-bill rates for full period and by business cycle stages. Periods of
expansion are divided into three stages and recessions into two stages. Returns are shown
in excess of the risk-free rate as annualized percentage points. Industry returns are
ordered by the stage with expected outperformance then from lowest to highest market
beta. Averages are shown by business cycle stage. We also report p-values from a Wald
test of joint significance under the null hypothesis of equal returns across all cycle stages.
Full Period Expansion Recession
Stage I Stage II Stage III Stage IV Stage V
(697 obs.) (206 obs.) (208 obs.) (179 obs.) (53 obs.) (51 obs.) Wald
obs Mean σ β Mean σ β Mean σ β Mean σ β Mean σ β Mean σ β Prob.
Early Expansion:
Shipping Containers 697 7.3% 18.5% 0.98 13.3% 17.0% 0.96 11.2% 16.8% 0.97 -4.0% 20.0% 0.98 -12.6% 17.5% 0.96 34.8% 22.6% 1.08 0%
Transportation 697 6.0% 19.2% 1.07 19.7% 16.6% 1.00 8.1% 17.3% 1.07 -5.7% 19.9% 1.01 -30.5% 20.4% 1.09 37.4% 24.9% 1.24 0%
Measuring & Control 697 6.7% 23.9% 1.33 5.4% 21.7% 1.36 13.4% 21.0% 1.29 3.5% 25.5% 1.37 -29.3% 26.8% 1.26 47.9% 29.4% 1.37 0%
Computers 697 8.0% 23.9% 1.25 9.2% 22.5% 1.41 11.6% 20.0% 1.14 3.7% 26.7% 1.24 -24.2% 20.5% 1.03 48.7% 32.2% 1.41 0%
Electronic Equipment 697 6.8% 25.5% 1.44 12.3% 24.4% 1.51 10.4% 21.2% 1.30 0.2% 28.6% 1.59 -30.6% 26.1% 1.39 46.1% 29.2% 1.33 0%
Computer Software 498 -3.4% 42.2% 1.78 -4.3% 32.5% 1.69 6.1% 35.1% 1.35 -5.7% 46.7% 2.18 -54.8% 56.3% 2.37 50.9% 63.1% 1.41 13%
avg: 5.2% 25.5% 1.31 9.3% 22.5% 1.32 10.1% 21.9% 1.19 -1.3% 27.9% 1.39 -30.4% 27.9% 1.35 44.3% 33.6% 1.31
Middle Expansion:
Precious Metals 522 2.5% 35.2% 0.68 1.0% 33.3% 0.41 3.0% 31.6% 0.74 3.0% 37.3% 0.50 -23.2% 39.1% 0.91 39.5% 47.0% 1.15 60%
Fabricated Products 522 -0.7% 24.2% 1.11 2.5% 23.3% 1.18 8.2% 20.0% 1.01 -1.6% 24.0% 0.97 -51.0% 31.2% 1.37 14.7% 32.3% 1.17 0%
Business Services 697 6.1% 18.7% 1.10 9.0% 17.2% 1.11 8.6% 15.9% 1.04 3.0% 19.9% 1.13 -28.5% 21.9% 1.13 44.0% 22.1% 1.08 0%
Defense 522 5.9% 23.5% 0.84 11.0% 20.6% 0.66 11.3% 20.7% 1.07 -5.0% 26.2% 0.69 -27.7% 25.0% 0.90 55.0% 29.8% 0.77 1%
Chemicals 697 6.0% 17.6% 1.01 15.3% 16.5% 1.07 7.7% 16.7% 1.12 -4.0% 17.8% 0.88 -15.6% 17.6% 0.95 25.6% 21.1% 1.07 0%
Aircraft 697 8.8% 23.1% 1.13 17.7% 20.2% 1.02 14.9% 20.8% 1.16 -3.1% 24.5% 1.10 -25.6% 27.0% 1.27 38.5% 29.0% 1.20 0%
Shipbuilding & Railroad 697 5.4% 21.6% 1.00 14.0% 21.2% 1.03 4.4% 18.9% 1.16 2.2% 21.5% 0.80 -27.4% 28.2% 1.22 30.2% 22.8% 0.87 1%
Personal Services 697 4.4% 22.9% 1.08 11.9% 16.6% 0.83 6.3% 21.7% 1.16 -3.1% 26.4% 1.17 -34.9% 28.3% 1.12 53.6% 23.3% 0.99 0%
Mining 697 6.0% 21.0% 1.00 12.4% 19.4% 0.93 8.2% 22.3% 1.20 5.0% 18.9% 0.85 -32.8% 23.5% 0.97 25.5% 22.4% 1.04 0%
Machinery 697 6.4% 19.2% 1.17 13.6% 17.0% 1.14 11.9% 17.9% 1.21 -0.3% 19.3% 1.11 -31.6% 20.8% 1.17 30.6% 25.1% 1.24 0%
Steel Works 697 4.3% 22.7% 1.25 12.0% 21.3% 1.34 9.4% 21.7% 1.25 -3.4% 24.1% 1.30 -30.3% 22.3% 1.10 26.7% 24.5% 1.14 0%
Electrical Equipment 697 9.0% 20.3% 1.19 13.1% 18.5% 1.20 14.7% 19.1% 1.27 4.5% 20.9% 1.17 -27.5% 21.0% 1.04 33.6% 24.5% 1.20 0%
avg: 5.3% 22.5% 1.05 11.1% 20.4% 0.99 9.1% 20.6% 1.12 -0.2% 23.4% 0.97 -29.7% 25.5% 1.10 34.8% 27.0% 1.08
Late Expansion:
Tobacco Products 697 9.6% 20.2% 0.66 3.4% 22.2% 0.91 12.2% 18.4% 0.87 9.2% 21.4% 0.42 0.6% 15.5% 0.39 38.6% 18.2% 0.61 4%
Food Products 697 7.9% 14.4% 0.71 8.9% 13.5% 0.73 8.7% 12.9% 0.78 1.7% 15.6% 0.60 -6.3% 15.8% 0.76 42.8% 16.0% 0.70 0%
Petroleum & Natural 697 8.5% 17.4% 0.81 16.5% 15.1% 0.77 10.1% 17.1% 0.90 5.0% 16.8% 0.67 -24.4% 22.5% 1.02 24.9% 19.1% 0.78 0%
Candy & Soda 697 6.7% 21.7% 0.80 11.4% 21.0% 0.85 13.3% 18.0% 0.75 -2.6% 23.3% 0.67 -20.9% 23.2% 0.78 30.9% 27.6% 0.99 1%
Pharmaceutical 697 8.9% 17.4% 0.86 5.0% 17.4% 1.02 15.6% 16.5% 0.97 5.9% 16.6% 0.69 -10.9% 18.0% 0.83 33.7% 21.2% 0.85 1%
Beer & Liquor 697 7.7% 17.6% 0.82 8.5% 14.0% 0.73 11.3% 16.7% 0.90 3.0% 20.0% 0.79 -16.2% 16.1% 0.78 37.8% 23.2% 0.89 0%
Medical Equipment 697 8.8% 19.0% 0.92 6.9% 18.2% 1.02 9.4% 18.6% 0.97 6.4% 17.4% 0.82 -10.7% 21.2% 0.88 50.4% 23.5% 0.96 1%
Agriculture 697 3.7% 22.0% 0.93 4.6% 19.7% 0.93 10.1% 18.5% 0.86 1.5% 24.9% 0.93 -31.1% 27.3% 1.11 28.8% 23.2% 0.84 0%
Coal 697 7.6% 28.8% 1.07 13.7% 25.9% 1.11 2.6% 25.5% 1.10 15.3% 32.4% 0.99 -38.3% 28.0% 1.06 43.8% 34.4% 1.03 0%
Healthcare 522 0.9% 35.9% 1.25 8.9% 27.3% 1.11 -3.9% 33.9% 1.20 3.2% 41.0% 1.34 -51.5% 41.9% 1.18 73.9% 40.5% 1.18 1%
avg: 7.0% 21.4% 0.88 8.8% 19.4% 0.92 8.9% 19.6% 0.93 4.9% 22.9% 0.79 -21.0% 22.9% 0.88 40.6% 24.7% 0.88
Early Contraction:
Communication 697 5.5% 14.7% 0.72 8.1% 15.7% 0.89 7.8% 11.8% 0.63 0.8% 16.2% 0.74 -9.6% 14.3% 0.65 20.3% 15.5% 0.60 3%
Utilities 697 6.2% 13.0% 0.54 9.4% 12.6% 0.67 7.4% 11.0% 0.51 0.1% 13.4% 0.33 -5.5% 16.4% 0.76 25.2% 15.3% 0.64 2%
avg: 5.9% 13.9% 0.63 8.7% 14.2% 0.78 7.6% 11.4% 0.57 0.4% 14.8% 0.54 -7.6% 15.3% 0.71 22.7% 15.4% 0.62
Late Contraction:
Insurance 697 6.9% 18.4% 0.88 11.4% 17.1% 0.92 8.1% 15.6% 0.87 1.3% 20.1% 0.80 -18.4% 22.4% 1.05 37.6% 20.4% 0.86 0%
Rubber & Plastic 697 7.6% 19.7% 1.04 12.4% 17.2% 1.02 13.8% 18.5% 1.14 0.6% 21.3% 1.01 -26.7% 21.3% 1.01 33.8% 22.1% 0.89 0%
Consumer Goods 697 7.1% 16.2% 0.87 11.9% 14.5% 0.88 9.7% 15.2% 1.00 -2.1% 16.1% 0.70 -15.0% 17.6% 0.81 41.1% 20.8% 1.01 0%
Printing & Publishing 697 8.1% 19.5% 1.04 10.7% 17.8% 1.01 12.6% 16.8% 1.02 0.6% 20.0% 1.02 -24.7% 24.4% 1.16 54.4% 22.7% 1.02 0%
Automobiles & Truck 697 6.0% 20.3% 1.03 20.1% 19.1% 1.00 5.6% 18.8% 1.16 -4.1% 20.5% 1.00 -25.4% 19.8% 0.81 31.8% 24.6% 1.04 0%
Apparel 697 7.2% 21.2% 1.08 13.9% 18.2% 1.07 9.9% 18.9% 1.10 -2.0% 23.3% 1.07 -29.4% 20.3% 0.92 58.5% 27.0% 1.06 0%
Textiles 697 4.6% 20.1% 0.99 15.5% 18.8% 1.02 5.3% 17.7% 0.99 -5.8% 20.8% 0.91 -26.4% 21.1% 0.89 41.1% 24.6% 1.07 0%
Trading 697 8.9% 18.1% 1.11 15.6% 15.6% 1.09 13.2% 14.9% 1.01 0.5% 20.3% 1.16 -27.2% 21.5% 1.21 44.9% 21.4% 1.09 0%
Retail 697 7.0% 17.7% 0.99 10.9% 15.5% 0.95 4.7% 16.7% 1.03 3.0% 18.1% 0.97 -16.5% 18.3% 0.90 47.7% 23.5% 1.11 0%
Banking 697 8.8% 18.0% 0.95 11.7% 17.1% 1.02 9.6% 15.2% 0.90 3.1% 18.9% 0.90 -12.0% 20.5% 0.98 41.3% 23.1% 1.11 2%
Construction Material 697 6.9% 18.5% 1.10 13.0% 15.9% 1.05 11.2% 16.4% 1.13 -1.3% 20.0% 1.05 -28.0% 19.7% 1.09 43.9% 23.3% 1.16 0%
Wholesale 697 6.7% 18.7% 1.08 10.5% 15.3% 1.02 8.1% 17.9% 1.17 3.6% 20.3% 1.06 -24.4% 17.5% 0.94 38.2% 24.8% 1.17 0%
Real Estate 697 3.3% 23.4% 1.10 9.1% 20.9% 1.00 5.5% 19.6% 1.03 -0.4% 24.4% 1.02 -38.3% 28.3% 1.37 45.8% 30.4% 1.18 0%
Business Supplies 697 7.1% 19.2% 1.00 17.7% 17.7% 0.96 6.4% 17.9% 1.10 -1.1% 18.7% 0.83 -24.2% 20.6% 0.93 41.0% 24.5% 1.20 0%
Recreation 697 5.4% 24.8% 1.16 7.7% 23.0% 1.17 7.3% 23.5% 1.30 0.1% 25.4% 1.00 -26.4% 24.3% 1.10 55.6% 31.0% 1.21 0%
Entertainment 697 9.1% 23.9% 1.25 10.9% 21.7% 1.20 13.3% 20.7% 1.25 0.8% 25.9% 1.32 -12.2% 28.0% 1.43 44.1% 30.6% 1.25 8%
Restaraunts & Hotels 697 8.5% 22.3% 1.10 12.4% 19.9% 1.08 12.0% 17.4% 1.00 4.3% 25.9% 1.12 -28.8% 24.4% 1.12 45.6% 28.2% 1.26 0%
Construction 697 6.0% 23.6% 1.26 6.7% 21.1% 1.19 8.2% 20.9% 1.20 8.5% 24.2% 1.23 -40.6% 23.7% 1.21 55.7% 32.5% 1.47 0%
avg: 7.0% 20.2% 1.06 12.3% 18.1% 1.04 9.1% 17.9% 1.08 0.5% 21.3% 1.01 -24.7% 21.9% 1.05 44.6% 25.3% 1.12
Market 7.1% 14.5% 1.00 12.7% 12.8% 1.00 9.6% 13.0% 1.00 0.8% 15.0% 1.00 -22.8% 16.0% 1.00 34.9% 18.1% 1.00
Treasury-bill 4.8% 0.8% - 3.8% 0.8% - 4.4% 0.6% - 5.9% 0.7% - 6.4% 1.2% - 5.0% 1.0% -
30
Table IV
Notes: Table reports Jensen’s alphas and Sharpe ratio performance measures for value
weighted industry returns. Results are shown for the full period and also returns
conditional on each of five business cycle stages. Jensen’s alphas are reported as
annualized rates with t-stats based on White (1980) heteroskedasticity consistent standard
errors. Sharpe ratios are calculated as excess industry returns divided by its standard
deviation. Industry returns are ordered by the business cycle stage where they are
expected to provide relative outperformance then from lowest to highest Sharpe ratio. We
also report probability from a Wald test of joint significance under the null hypothesis of
equal Jensen’s alphas by industry for all five business cycle stages.
Full Period Expansion Recession
Stage I Stage II Stage III Stage IV Stage V Wald
Alpha t-stat Sharpe Alpha t-stat Sharpe Alpha t-stat Sharpe Alpha t-stat Sharpe Alpha t-stat Sharpe Alpha t-stat Sharpe Prob
Early Expansion:
Computer Software -10.6% -2.25 -0.02 -15.7% -2.26 -0.04 -5.3% -0.67 0.05 -8.7% -1.00 -0.04 5.0% 0.20 -0.39 7.5% 0.22 0.19 76%
Measuring & Control -2.3% -1.22 0.08 -10.1% -3.42 0.07 1.2% 0.39 0.17 2.4% 0.61 0.04 -3.9% -0.47 -0.37 -0.2% -0.02 0.39 4%
Computers -0.5% -0.25 0.09 -7.3% -2.25 0.11 1.0% 0.30 0.16 2.7% 0.54 0.04 -2.8% -0.43 -0.39 -0.9% -0.08 0.36 34%
Electronic Equipment -2.9% -1.48 0.07 -5.8% -1.58 0.14 -1.5% -0.50 0.14 -0.9% -0.23 0.00 -2.6% -0.38 -0.40 -0.4% -0.04 0.38 89%
Shipping Containers 0.6% 0.40 0.11 1.4% 0.47 0.21 2.1% 0.74 0.18 -4.7% -1.35 -0.06 10.0% 2.46 -0.22 -1.2% -0.19 0.39 10%
Transportation -1.2% -0.83 0.09 6.7% 2.54 0.31 -1.6% -0.61 0.13 -6.4% -1.94 -0.08 -9.3% -1.73 -0.51 -3.8% -0.64 0.37 1%
avg: -2.8% 0.07 -5.1% 0.14 -0.7% 0.14 -2.6% -0.02 -0.6% -0.38 0.2% 0.35
Middle Expansion:
Precious Metals -0.6% -0.11 0.02 -2.2% -0.22 0.01 -3.0% -0.35 0.03 2.2% 0.21 0.02 5.2% 0.23 -0.19 5.6% 0.20 0.21 99%
Shipbuilding & Railroad -1.3% -0.57 0.07 1.2% 0.26 0.18 -5.8% -2.00 0.07 1.6% 0.35 0.03 -2.4% -0.22 -0.33 1.3% 0.11 0.34 58%
Personal Services -2.7% -1.24 0.06 1.7% 0.52 0.20 -4.1% -1.17 0.08 -3.9% -0.78 -0.03 -14.2% -1.65 -0.43 15.9% 2.04 0.54 6%
Mining -0.8% -0.37 0.08 1.0% 0.27 0.18 -2.6% -0.65 0.10 4.3% 1.17 0.07 -14.7% -1.98 -0.49 -7.2% -1.00 0.30 15%
Fabricated Products -5.6% -2.14 -0.01 -6.6% -1.22 0.03 -0.3% -0.08 0.11 -3.1% -0.58 -0.02 -19.9% -1.49 -0.64 -13.8% -1.14 0.12 50%
Steel Works -4.0% -2.23 0.05 -4.2% -1.35 0.15 -2.0% -0.54 0.12 -4.3% -1.20 -0.04 -8.9% -1.42 -0.46 -9.0% -1.06 0.28 86%
Chemicals -0.8% -0.66 0.10 1.9% 0.83 0.25 -2.5% -1.23 0.13 -4.6% -1.54 -0.07 6.1% 1.61 -0.28 -8.0% -1.81 0.32 4%
Business Services -1.3% -1.02 0.09 -4.3% -1.76 0.14 -0.9% -0.47 0.15 2.2% 0.79 0.04 -5.9% -1.03 -0.44 5.5% 1.01 0.48 25%
Defense 1.9% 0.64 0.07 5.5% 0.94 0.15 2.0% 0.48 0.15 -6.0% -0.89 -0.06 -0.8% -0.05 -0.37 29.0% 1.63 0.43 39%
Machinery -1.5% -1.19 0.09 -0.4% -0.20 0.22 0.7% 0.29 0.18 -1.2% -0.46 -0.01 -9.1% -1.88 -0.53 -8.8% -1.31 30%
Aircraft 1.0% 0.44 0.11 4.6% 1.24 0.24 3.9% 1.06 0.19 -3.9% -0.84 -0.04 1.1% 0.12 -0.32 -2.0% -0.14 0.33 66%
Electrical Equipment 0.8% 0.57 0.12 -1.6% -0.69 0.19 2.7% 1.06 0.21 3.6% 1.21 0.06 -6.5% -1.04 -0.44 -5.6% -1.08 0.35 26%
avg: -1.2% 0.07 -0.3% 0.16 -1.0% 0.13 -1.1% 0.00 -5.8% -0.41 0.2% 0.33
Late Expansion:
Candy & Soda 1.3% 0.51 0.09 0.9% 0.20 0.15 6.0% 1.61 0.20 -3.1% -0.57 -0.03 -4.5% -0.45 -0.29 -1.7% -0.11 0.28 64%
Agriculture -2.4% -1.03 0.05 -6.1% -1.61 0.07 2.1% 0.58 0.15 0.8% 0.15 0.02 -9.6% -0.97 -0.39 0.9% 0.09 0.32 49%
Healthcare -4.6% -1.03 0.01 0.0% 0.00 0.09 -12.9% -1.77 -0.03 1.2% 0.12 0.02 -25.8% -1.21 -0.48 31.5% 1.49 0.40 17%
Food Products 3.0% 2.17 0.15 0.0% 0.02 0.18 1.4% 0.74 0.19 1.2% 0.38 0.03 12.4% 2.01 -0.12 16.8% 2.72 0.66 5%
Beer & Liquor 2.1% 1.18 0.12 -0.3% -0.14 0.17 2.8% 0.96 0.18 2.4% 0.56 0.04 1.1% 0.19 -0.32 6.7% 0.59 0.41 91%
Petroleum & Natural 2.9% 1.70 0.14 6.5% 2.33 0.29 1.7% 0.56 0.16 4.5% 1.25 0.08 -3.0% -0.45 -0.36 -0.1% -0.02 0.34 59%
Pharmaceutical 2.9% 1.79 0.14 -6.8% -2.46 0.08 6.2% 2.27 0.25 5.4% 1.56 0.10 8.7% 1.39 -0.19 4.7% 0.64 0.40 1%
Medical Equipment 2.4% 1.33 0.13 -5.0% -1.61 0.11 0.5% 0.14 0.14 5.8% 1.76 0.10 10.2% 1.22 -0.16 14.3% 1.63 0.51 5%
Tobacco Products 4.9% 2.01 0.13 -7.0% -1.42 0.04 3.9% 1.14 0.18 8.8% 1.60 0.12 10.5% 1.41 0.01 16.4% 1.73 0.53 9%
Coal 0.3% 0.09 0.07 -0.1% -0.01 0.14 -6.9% -1.39 0.03 14.5% 1.81 0.13 -19.9% -1.95 -0.49 7.2% 0.48 0.31 6%
avg: 1.3% 0.10 -1.8% 0.13 0.5% 0.15 4.2% 0.06 -2.0% -0.28 9.7% 0.42
Early Contraction:
Communication 0.6% 0.46 0.11 -2.6% -1.00 0.14 2.0% 0.93 0.18 0.2% 0.08 0.01 5.7% 1.29 -0.20 1.0% 0.16 0.35 51%
Utilities 2.5% 1.75 0.13 1.2% 0.48 0.21 2.8% 1.19 0.19 -0.2% -0.06 0.00 13.3% 2.43 -0.10 4.0% 0.78 0.43 29%
avg: 1.6% 0.02 1.6% 0.02 1.6% 0.02 1.6% 0.02 1.6% 0.02 1.6% 0.02
Late Contraction:
Automobiles & Truck -0.9% -0.52 0.08 7.0% 2.06 0.28 -4.7% -1.71 0.08 -4.8% -1.33 -0.06 -9.2% -1.15 -0.43 -2.3% -0.29 0.33 5%
Entertainment 0.5% 0.24 0.11 -3.5% -0.89 0.14 1.6% 0.49 0.17 -0.2% -0.04 0.01 23.4% 2.97 -0.13 0.6% 0.05 0.35 5%
Real Estate -3.9% -1.74 0.04 -2.9% -0.75 0.12 -3.7% -1.15 0.08 -1.1% -0.23 0.00 -13.5% -1.60 -0.49 4.1% 0.40 0.36 68%
Wholesale -0.6% -0.44 0.10 -1.8% -0.91 0.19 -2.5% -1.05 0.13 2.8% 0.83 0.05 -5.0% -1.17 -0.46 -1.4% -0.25 0.38 63%
Rubber & Plastic 0.5% 0.27 0.11 -0.2% -0.06 0.20 2.9% 1.02 0.20 -0.2% -0.05 0.01 -6.3% -0.88 -0.42 3.4% 0.40 0.39 77%
Restaraunts & Hotels 0.9% 0.43 0.11 -0.8% -0.24 0.17 2.6% 0.90 0.19 3.4% 0.66 0.05 -6.3% -0.89 -0.40 1.3% 0.14 0.39 76%
Construction -2.4% -1.23 0.07 -7.2% -2.00 0.09 -2.6% -0.76 0.11 7.5% 1.79 0.10 -19.8% -2.76 -0.63 2.2% 0.20 0.40 1%
Textiles -2.0% -1.03 0.07 2.6% 0.71 0.22 -3.5% -1.05 0.08 -6.4% -1.63 -0.08 -8.5% -1.24 -0.42 3.9% 0.48 0.41 34%
Business Supplies 0.3% 0.18 0.10 5.3% 1.57 0.27 -3.5% -1.37 0.10 -1.7% -0.49 -0.02 -5.0% -0.67 -0.39 -0.2% -0.03 0.42 31%
Recreation -2.3% -0.95 0.06 -6.1% -1.46 0.09 -4.4% -1.10 0.09 -0.7% -0.13 0.00 -3.8% -0.43 -0.36 10.2% 0.74 0.42 77%
Banking 2.2% 1.40 0.14 -0.8% -0.29 0.19 1.3% 0.52 0.17 2.5% 0.71 0.05 11.3% 1.61 -0.18 2.6% 0.47 0.44 59%
Construction Material -0.5% -0.38 0.11 0.0% 0.02 0.22 0.7% 0.38 0.19 -2.0% -0.63 -0.02 -6.2% -1.26 -0.48 3.3% 0.60 0.46 64%
Insurance 0.9% 0.52 0.11 0.1% 0.05 0.18 0.2% 0.07 0.14 0.7% 0.16 0.02 5.2% 0.68 -0.26 7.5% 0.89 0.46 89%
Retail 0.2% 0.17 0.11 -0.7% -0.32 0.19 -4.4% -1.75 0.08 2.3% 0.81 0.05 3.7% 0.74 -0.29 7.4% 1.33 0.49 19%
Consumer Goods 1.2% 0.85 0.12 1.1% 0.43 0.23 0.5% 0.25 0.18 -2.6% -0.85 -0.04 3.3% 0.55 -0.27 5.8% 0.79 0.49 77%
Apparel -0.1% -0.06 0.10 0.6% 0.22 0.21 -0.3% -0.08 0.14 -2.8% -0.63 -0.03 -11.5% -1.72 -0.49 17.1% 1.68 0.50 18%
Trading 1.2% 1.09 0.14 1.9% 1.16 0.27 3.6% 1.98 0.24 -0.4% -0.14 0.01 -2.2% -0.55 -0.42 6.1% 1.21 0.51 51%
Printing & Publishing 1.0% 0.60 0.12 -1.6% -0.50 0.17 3.0% 1.16 0.20 -0.1% -0.04 0.01 -0.3% -0.03 -0.33 15.4% 2.68 0.57 12%
avg: -0.2% 0.10 -0.4% 0.19 -0.7% 0.14 -0.2% 0.01 -2.8% -0.38 4.8% 0.43
Market - - 0.13 - - 0.26 - - 0.20 - - 0.01 - - -0.43 - - 0.46
31
Figure I
NBER peak
Expansion Recession
1
See for example Stovall (1996) and references by Fidelity Sector Funds at
http://personal.fidelity.com/products/funds/content/sector/basics.shtml.cvsr
32
Figure II
Notes: Table reports end-of-period wealth from an initial investment of one dollar for
each of the four investment strategies shown over the period 1948-2006. The market
strategy simply holds the market portfolio for the entire period. Sector rotation strategy
holds sector portfolios in equal weights during the business cycle stage in which they are
expected to perform optimally. Market-timing holds the market portfolio for all business
cycle stages except the early stage of a recession when cash is held. Jensen’s alphas are
obtained from a standard CAPM model. Jensen’s alphas are reported as annualized rates
with t-stats based on White heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors. Sharpe ratios
are calculated as strategy returns in excess of the risk-free rate divided by its standard
deviation. Shaded areas indicate NBER defined periods of recession.
End-Of-Period Wealth
$1,200
Market Timing
$1,000
$800
$600
Sector Rotation
$400
$200
Market
$0
48
50
52
54
56
58
60
62
64
66
68
70
72
74
76
78
80
82
84
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
06
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
33
References
Avramov, Doron, and Tarun Chordia, 2006, Asset Pricing Models and Financial Market
Anomalies, Review of Economic Studies 19, 1001-1040.
Brocato, Joe, and Steve Steed, 1998, Optimal Asset Allocation Over the Business Cycle,
The Financial Review 33, 129-148.
Business Week Online, 2002, Get In, Get Out, and Move On, (McGraw-Hill Companies,
Inc.).
Chordia, Tarun, and Lakshmanan Shivakumar, 2002, Momentum, Business Cycle, and
Time-varying Expected Returns., Journal of Finance 57, 985.
Cover, James P., and Paul Pecorino, 2005, The length of US business expansions: When
did the break in the data occur?, Journal of Macroeconomics 27, 452-471.
DeStefano, Michael, 2004, Stock Returns and the Business Cycle., Financial Review 39,
527-547.
Eleswarapu, Venkat R., and Ashish Tiwari, 1996, Business Cycles And Stock Market
Returns: Evidence Using Industry-Based Portfolios., Journal of Financial
Research 19, 121.
Fama, Eugene F., 1975, Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation., American
Economic Review 65, 269.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1989, Business conditions and expected
returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 25, 23-49.
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 2007, The Survey of Professional Forecasters,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review 1–13.
Fidelity Investments, 2007, Sector Education, (Fidelity Investments).
Hong, Harrison, Walter Torous, and Rossen Valkanov, 2007, Do industries lead stock
markets?, Journal of Financial Economics 83, 367-396.
Hou, Kewei, 2007, Industry Information Diffusion and the Lead-Lag Effect in Stock
Returns, Review of Financial Studies.
Investment Company Institute, 2007. Investment Company Fact Book (Investment
Company Institute).
Menzly, Lior, and Oguzhan Ozbas, 2004, Cross-Industry Momentum, Working Paper
Series (SSRN).
Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank, 2007, Survey of Professional Forecasters,
(Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank).
Sassetti, Paolo, and Massimiliano Tani, 2003, Dynamic Asset Allocation Using
Systematic Sector Rotation, Working Paper.
Siegel, Jeremy, 1991, Does it pay stock investors to forecast the business cycle, Journal
of Portfolio Management.
Stovall, Sam, 1996. 1995 Standard & Poor's Guide to Sector Investing (McGraw-Hill).
Tiwari, Ashish, and Anand Vijh, 2005, Sector Fund Performance: Analysis of Cash Flow
Volatility and Returns, Working Paper.
White, Halbert, 1980, A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator And
A Direct Test For Heteroskedasticity, Econometrica 48, 817-838.
34