Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Preprint Not Peer Reviewed: Utkarsh Leo and Ram Singh

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

COVID-19 and Contractual Disputes in India

ed
Utkarsh Leo* and Ram Singh^ **

iew
Abstract: The Covid-19 pandemic has unleashed a catena of contractual disputes. Several companies
and firms have cited Covid-19 as force majeure to suspend the promised supply of goods or services,
triggering legal claims of compensation from the counterparties. Employers have refused the
promised employment, borrowers have expressed their inability to service debt contracts, and
insurance companies have denied compensation for business income losses. Even governments have

ev
been found wavering in honoring the very social contract that brings the State and Government into
existence.
In this article, we synthesise the Indian Contract Act and relevant case laws to present a legal position
on issues concerning force majeure, frustration of contract and contractual gaps. By drawing up the

rr
economic analysis of law, we examine contractual disputes from various sectors—including power-
purchase agreements, construction and transportation contracts, rental contracts, and event
management and hospitality contracts. We analyse these disputes from a legal and economic-
efficiency point of view. We categorise contractual disputes where the use of force majeure or
ee
frustration of contract is justified—from the cases where it is not. We have used economic analysis
to draw the attention of courts and policymakers towards the economic implication of their decisions.
Our analysis of the recent court orders on Covid-related-disputes suggests that in some cases, courts
seem to under-appreciate the long-term economic consequences of their rulings. Finally, we argue
that public policy, rather than judicial remedies, is better suited to address issues arising from disputes
tp

over long term contracts such as debt, employment and insurance contracts.
Keywords: Covid-19, force majeure, frustration of contract, act of god, act of government,
contractual disputes, court orders, Indian Contract Act, public policy
no

Acknowledgement: We have benefitted from useful comments and helpful suggestions from
Subhash C Pandey and Shakti Singh. We also benefitted from our interactions with Hans-Bernd
Schäfer and participants in a lecture on the subject by the second author at the GNLU Centre for Law
and Economics. We thank Aarti Malik and Samridh Sindhu for providing excellent research support.
int

Institutional and research support by the Centre for Development Economics at the Delhi School of
Economics and the University of Delhi are gratefully acknowledged.
r
ep

^Corresponding author.
*Assistant Professor, NALSAR University of Law, Hyderabad. Email: contactmrleo@nalsar.ac.in
** Professor, Delhi School of Economics and Member, Advisory Council, Delhi School of Public
Policy and Governance, University of Delhi, Delhi. Email: ramsingh@econdse.org
Pr

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
1. Introduction

ed
Various considerations motivate people for entering into legal agreements. Employment contracts
ensure supply of labour to the employer and income to the employee. Production contracts secure the
future supply of goods and services. Debt contracts provide consumers with purchasing-power, and
producers and traders with working-capital. Insurance contracts shift the burden of risk from the
insured to the insurer. Indeed, contracts serve as bedrock for exchanges related to production,

iew
commerce, and trade.
However, the Covid-19 pandemic has unleashed a catena of contractual disputes. Lockdowns, widely
adopted to contain the pandemic, have made it costly for many companies and enterprises to meet
their contractual obligations. In various cases, they find it impossible to meet the terms of the contract.
Borrowers are finding it difficult to service the debt; contractors cannot deliver projects on schedule;

ev
many employers have refused to provide the promised employment benefits; and suppliers have
delayed the supply of goods or services—consequently triggering legal claims of compensation from
the counter-parties.
In doing so, several parties have invoked Covid-19 as a force majeure (FM) event—an occurrence

rr
that is beyond the control of the parties involved and renders contractual performance
impossible.1Most contracts contain an FM clause to catalogue events like war, riot, strike, etc., in
which the parties would prefer to either terminate the agreement or put it on hold. ‘Acts of God,' such
as flood, cyclone, earthquake, hurricane, epidemic, etc., and ‘Acts of government,' like a prohibitory
ee
lockdown to contain Covid-19, are some events listed under the FM clause. Mentioning such a clause
in a contract effectively reduces the scope of any dispute between the parties involved in case of an
FM event’s occurrence. The problem is, more often than not, the clause contains ambiguous and
catch-all phrases like, ‘events including but not limited to the ones listed herein’—which can be
exploited by one of the parties involved in the agreement. Predictably enough, such contractual
tp

ambiguities are being exploited by many contracting parties during the pandemic. They are seeking
termination or suspension of business deals by citing Covid-19 as either an FM event or the reason
for invoking frustration of contract. Furthermore, ambivalent statements by government agencies
regarding the pandemic have added to the bewilderment.
no

Recent orders of the Bombay and Delhi High Court (HC) suggest a tendency among contracting
parties to use the crisis in a self-serving manner. OYO’s decision to suspend payments to partner
hotels citing commercial unprofitability due to loss of revenue; demands for rental waivers by
retailers and other commercial-tenants due to the closure of shopping malls; various electricity
distribution companies (DISCOMs) withholding monthly payments to power-producers citing
int

reduced consumer demand, suggest that the FM clause is being invoked rather arbitrarily. Therefore,
how courts and regulators adjudicate such contractual disputes will determine the distribution of
losses among the disputants, and more importantly, the quantum of the economic cost of the
pandemic.
r

In this article, we synthesise the Indian Contract Act, 1872 and relevant case laws to evolve the legal
position on issues concerning force majeure, frustration of contract and contractual gaps. In the light
ep

of the synthesised contract law, we examine claims and counterclaims of parties in power-purchase
agreements, construction contracts, air-transportation contracts, rental contracts, and event
management and hospitality contracts, among many others. We identify the contexts in which
contracting parties are using the pandemic disingenuously to extricate themselves from their
Pr

contractual commitments. Besides, we analyse the merits of contractual-disputes triggered by Covid-


19, from an economic efficiency point of view. The motivation behind the economic analysis is to
1 For an interesting analysis of FM in the context of dispute between the Centre and the States over GST shortfall, see Pandey
(2020a).
1

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
draw the attention of courts and policymakers towards the important economic implication of their
decisions.
Additionally, we examine recent rulings by the Indian courts on FM and frustration of contract from

ed
an efficiency point of view. We find that some of the court orders seem to under-appreciate the long
term economic consequences of Covid related disputes.
Finally, we examine debt contracts, employment, and insurance contracts. We argue that these long-
term contracts are quite different from typical short-term, transactional contracts. We discuss why

iew
public-policy, rather than court interventions, is better suited to mitigate the economic-losses faced
by the insureds, debtors, and employees.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we undertake an economic analysis of the law
related to force majeure and frustration of contract. In Section 3, we synthesise the Indian Contract
Act, 1872 and relevant case laws, from an economic efficiency point of view, to establish the Indian

ev
legal position on force majeure and frustration of contract. In Section 4, we offer a sectoral analysis
and discuss claims and counterclaims of parties in power-purchase agreements, construction
contracts, air-transportation contracts, rental contracts, and event management and hospitality
contracts. In Section 5, we discuss why public policy is better suited to address issues related to debt
contracts, employment and insurance contracts. In doing so, we look at some international examples.

rr
Lastly, in Section 6, we offer our concluding remarks.
2. Force Majeure and Contracts
ee
Legally enforceable contracts and are the foundation of the market economy and a means to enhance
trade-related social surplus. As an illustrative example, consider a sales contract where a buyer values
a good (X) at 150 (V), and the producer can manufacture X at a cost (C). They enter a contract where
the producer promises to supply the goods, six months from now, at a unit price of 120. If C=100 and
the promise is fulfilled, they each gain 30 and 20, respectively. This example captures the essence of
tp

most contracts—voluntary agreements lead to Pareto superior outcomes, thereby enhancing the social
surplus from trade and commerce. Simply put, contracts create complementary pairs of demand and
supply for the mutual benefit of contracting parties. A strong culture of enforcement of contracts
strengthens incentives to conclude more contracts and fulfill needs that would otherwise remain
unmet.
no

Generally, there is some uncertainty associated with the cost of production (C). So, C may be high or
low depending on the economic situation at the time of production. Suppose, C can take values: 50,
80, 100, 130, or 200. From an efficiency point of view, the promise should be fulfilled so long as C
< V. Efficiency demands that the supplier delivers the good even if the cost happens to be 130, and
the contract price remains 120. This condition follows from a widely used criterion in law and
int

economics, known as Kaldor-Hicks efficiency Singh (2018).

Legally enforceable contracts provide credibility to surplus enhancing promises, of the types
mentioned above. A party in breach of the contract terms must compensate the other side.
r

Accordingly, contract of carriage provides for the refund of ticket amount in case the carrier cancels
ep

the flight, due to circumstances beyond its control. A buyer refusing supply of goods at a contractually
agreed price must forgo the advance payment or pay a penalty to the promisor. In sum, contracts are
useful instruments for minimising the risk of reneging on either side. On top of it, if contract is fair it
leads to egalitarian outcome.2
Pr

2Generally, fairness is not guaranteed especially by the standard form contracts between unequal parties in terms of ability to
negotiate terms of contracts, i.e., where one dominant side – typically government or big business - presents a take-it-or-leave-it type
of somewhat one-sided contract to ordinary consumers of goods and services. However, as long as they are voluntary, even these
contracts promote efficiency.
2

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
Anyway by creating opportunities of mutual benefit, contracts encourage productive investments. A
power-producer after signing a power purchase agreement with a distribution company (DISCOM)
can make a costly investment in plant-equipment and technology without fearing refusal of supply

ed
from the distributor. Similarly, after signing a construction contract, the contractor can invest in the
material needed for construction.

However, contracts are not a panacea against all kinds of risks. In some situations, it is simply
impossible for the promisor to fulfil the promise. For example, a Covid induced ban on domestic and

iew
international travel made it impossible for airline operators to run during the lockdowns. When
performance becomes impossible, the social surplus discussed in earlier examples ceases to exist.

For such scenarios, most contracts contain an FM clause. It catalogues events—like war, earthquake,
tsunami, riot, strike, etc., that render contractual performance impossible for reasons beyond the
control of parties. Acts of government such as prohibitory-lockdowns to contain Covid-19 and acts of

ev
God like flood, cyclone, earthquake, hurricane, a named epidemic are among typical-events listed
under an FM clause. If an FM event occurs, the parties prefer to either terminate the contract or put
it on-hold. This reduces the scope of dispute between parties, should an FM event occur.

rr
One approach of cataloguing FM events is by having an exhaustive definition for such events. In
doing so, contracting parties list all categories of events—such as, tsunami, flood, terror attacks—
that may drive contracting agents to exercise the clause. Such binding definitions restrict the relief
available to parties to a particular set of events. Besides, it is time consuming and costly for
ee
contracting parties to discuss and document every conceivable event that may render performance
impossible. Moreover, some events just cannot be foreseen at the time of contracting. As a result, real
world contracts are ‘incomplete’ about the description of FM events. Therefore, most such contracts
contain a list of events, e.g., cyclone, earthquake, tsunami, and hurricane, that the involved
contracting parties envisage as a covered event, but then insert a catch-all phrase like ‘events
tp

including but not limited to the ones listed herein’. This ensures that the definition does not preclude
application of the provision to other similar events such as typhoons, tornadoes, volcanic eruptions
etc.3 Simultaneously, catch-all phrases make the contract ambiguous.

At times, an FM event can merely delay performance. An ‘act of God’, say typhoons or catastrophic
no

weather, can temporarily disrupt shipping routes and production of goods. An ‘act of government’
can briefly call a halt to construction activities leading to time overrun for the project. Similarly, a
ban on the movement of non-essentials items—as witnessed under Covid induced lockdowns—can
make it impossible for the promisor to ensure timely supply of goods or services as promised.
Sometimes, an act of God or government can leave the very purpose of the contract frustrated.
int

Plausibly, an FM event can also increase the cost of performance or reduce gains from a deal. Covid-
19 and the attendant lockdowns have either increased the cost of contractual performance for some
or have reduced contractual-profits for others. Thus, many contracting parties have sought to
terminate or suspend deals by citing the pandemic as an FM event. As a result, there is a surge in
r

contractual disputes citing Covid as FM or for invoking frustration of contract.


ep

However, the effect of Covid and lockdowns varies across contracts within a sector and also across
different sectors. Thus, a question that follows is: what general principle should courts follow to
adjudicate contractual disputes?
Pr

2.1 What does Economic Analysis tell us?

3 It is also common for parties to expressly exclude certain events from coverage.
3

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
Delayed or ambiguous rulings can aggravate the outbreak’s economic cost by disrupting supply
chains beyond the lockdown time period. By contrast, clear and consistent judgments are a public
good. They discourage opportunistic-behaviour and encourage pre-trial negotiations, thereby

ed
avoiding unnecessary litigation that has huge attendant social costs and favours the relatively rich
party.4

Economic analysis of law applied in the current context, offers the following three propositions:

iew
Proposition 1: Covid-19 and lockdowns should be treated as FM only if performance of contractual
obligations has become impossible or has caused inevitable delay.

The proposition suggests a clear and consistent criterion for dealing with FM related disputes. It
implies, courts should allow waiver of performance, ‘if and only if’ contractual performance has
become completely or temporarily impossible. Moreover, courts should apply the principle of

ev
‘ejusdem generis' while interpreting ambiguous or catch-all terms in an FM clause—‘where general
words follow an enumeration of particular things, those general words are construed of the nature
or class as those specifically mentioned’.5

rr
Granting waivers where performance is possible, but has become costlier, will encourage
opportunistic litigation, and may even be inefficient. For example, if due to Covid-19, cost (C) rises
from 100 to 130, it will be inefficient to grant a waiver, as the cost is still less than the buyer’s
valuation V = 150. Where possibility of performance gets merely delayed, as in the case of
ee
construction contracts, the promisors should not be absolved from their obligations. They can be
provided some extra-time for performing their respective contractual obligations.

As to the claim of compensation for economic losses caused by Covid-19 or the lockdowns, it is
difficult for a court, a third-party, to correctly assess contractual disputes related to such economic
tp

losses. While on the one hand, the contracting parties will know whether C has gone up or if V has
come down, the courts on the other hand would usually not. Profits and losses are salient to most
business and commercial contracts. Hence, contracting parties are generally fully aware of the
implications of various such events on their business or individual welfare. Generally, one party is in
no

a better position to reduce the risk. In other cases, one of the contracting parties is more capable of
bearing the risk.

Presumably, contracting parties know which party is in the best position to deal with a risk. It stands
to reason that while negotiating terms of the contract, contracting parties will allocate risk to the party
who can reduce or eliminate the risk at a lower cost. This minimises the cost of risks and maximises
int

the surplus from contract. In other words, contracts are used by parties for efficient allocation of risk
arising in the normal course of business. Moreover, the contract price factors in the allocation of the
relevant risks between the parties. In contrast, it is very difficult for courts to identify the least-cost-
risk-bearer of the loss as it does not possess the relevant economic information (Posner and
Rosenfield 1977). Therefore, courts should avoid changing terms of the contract and by implication
r

changing the risk allocation implicit in the contract. In reference to disputes related to the cost of the
ep

pandemic to the contracting parties, our law and economic analysis prescribes:

Proposition 2: Courts should interpret the contract narrowly.


Pr

4 Refer Singh (2003) and Singh (2004) on the effects of inconsistent rules and Singh (2012) on how the relatively rich tend to get a
better deal from litigation.
5 For details refer State v Eckhardt (1910).

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
Narrow interpretation of contract means that courts should apply the 'Four Corners Rule’ and stick
to the letter of contract for any interpretation (Posner 2004). Claims of compensation should be
allowed only if the contract explicitly mentions events like epidemic and lockdown. When the

ed
contract is silent about a risk, courts can use clearly defined and articulated default rules to study the
dispute brought forward in front of them (Cooter and Ulen 2012).6

A narrow interpretation of contracts along with a clearly defined default rule is efficient on the
following counts: One, it reduces the possibility of error by courts in assigning risk to a party least

iew
suited to bear it. Two, it discourages litigation by encouraging the contracting parties to list relevant
risk and allocating them to one of the parties. This will result in increased efficiency of the contract
in terms of risk-allocation and reduced frequency of litigation. Besides, narrow interpretation of
contracts helps secure the function of contract as a legally enforceable promise.

Sometimes, the courts change or modify the terms of the contract. Modification in contractual terms

ev
can be justified if the contract violates the law of the land or infringes upon rights of third parties or
if public interest is at stake. However, economic analysis of contract law prescribes that courts must
refrain from changing terms of the contract to redistribute gains and losses arising from a contractual
relation or for the objective of perceived social welfare. Such issues are better addressed through

rr
public policy.

Proposition 3. The issue of equity of burden or distress caused by economic losses should be
addressed through public policy.
ee
Policy matters require a high degree of participation, consultation, and collaboration; consider the
case of claims for Business Interruption Losses (BIL) caused by Covid. Pandemic-related economic
losses tend to be highly correlated. If the courts allow BIL claims on grounds of perceived public
interest, it may potentially bankrupt the insurance industry. In contrast, public policy is better suited
tp

to balance the interests of various participants such as the insurer, insured, and re-insurers, as opposed
to matters of interest to one person or a small group of people.

3. The Indian Legal Position


no

3.1 Force Majeure

The Indian Contract Act (ICA or the ‘Act’) does not define Force Majeure. However, the Supreme
Court (SC) in various cases such as Satyabrata Ghose v Mugneeram Bangur (1954), Energy
Watchdog v CERC (2017) and NAFED v Alimenta (2020) has held that when there exists an express
int

or implied FM clause in a contract, it is governed u/S 32 of the Act that deals with enforcement of
contingent contracts.7

For Covid-19 or the lockdowns to qualify as an FM event will require a case-specific-evaluation:


subject to facts, nature, and subject of the contract in question. Once the invoking party establishes
r

that the occurring event was catalogued and rendered performance impossible, it can seek suspension
ep

or termination of the contract, subject to language of the provision.8For each case, the courts will
have to individually assess: (i) whether the contract cannot be performed under any circumstance?;
(ii) whether the impossibility of performance can be attributed to Covid-19 or the lockdowns; and
Pr

6A default rule is applied by courts to interpret a contract when it is silent on an issue under-dispute.
7One of the very first judgements on the concept of force majeure is Edmund Bendit And Anr. vs Edgar Raphael Prudhomme ( AIR
1925 Mad 626).
8 For instance, in Standard Retail Private Ltd. v G.S Global Corp. (2020) the contract only allowed the seller to either terminate the

contract or delay its performance for a reasonable time period.


5

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
(iii) whether appropriate steps were taken to avoid, overcome or mitigate the event and its
consequences?

ed
For instance, in Halliburton Offshore v Vedanta Ltd. (2020)the contract explicitly listed ‘pandemic’
as an FM event. Accordingly, the Delhi HC accepted Covid-19 as an FM event according to terms of
the contract, however, refused to excuse non-performance of contractual obligations by the plaintiff
contractor (Halliburton) who had missed several deadlines much before the Covid outbreak.

iew
Most real-world contracts are incomplete about cataloguing the list of FM events. Generally, Indian
courts tend to use principles of ‘ejusdem generis’ while interpreting catch-all provisions in an FM
clause.

3.2 Frustration of contract

ev
The ICA does not define the word ‘frustration’. The SC in Boothalinga Agencies v V. T. C.
Poriaswami (1969) has held that the doctrine comes within the purview of Section 56 of the ICA
(which provides that an agreement to do an impossible or illegal act, after the contract is made, is
void).The doctrine provides relief to parties in the absence of an FM clause.9 In NAFED v Alimenta

rr
(2020) the SC has held—“Section 32 of the Contract Act applies in case the agreement itself provides
for contingencies upon happening of which contract cannot be carried out […] In case an act becomes
impossible at a future date, and that exigency is not provided in the agreement […] the contract
becomes void as provided in Section 56[…]”.
ee
Indian courts offer relief u/S 56, on grounds of subsequent impossibility, in cases wherein an ex-post
event, that was beyond the control of parties, has destroyed the entire purpose or basis of contract.
Mukherjee J. in Satyabrata Ghose v Mugneeram Bangur (1954) has explained that “[…] the word
‘impossible' has not been used in the sense of physical or literal impossibility. The performance of an
tp

act may not be literally impossible, but it may be impracticable and useless from the point of view of
the object and purpose which the parties had in view. Therefore, if an untoward event or change of
circumstances totally upsets the very foundation upon which the parties rested their bargain, it can
very well be said that the promisor finds it impossible to do the act which he promised to do […].”
no

In other words, to allow a claim of frustration, the courts test the extent to which the occurrence of
an ex-post event has upset the foundation of the bargain that was agreed or contemplated at the time
of contract formation.10

As to the interpretation of the contract, in the spirit of the four corner rule Section 92 of the Indian
int

Evidence Act, 1872, says that oral evidence is not admissible to contradict or vary the terms of a
contract. Finally, the ICA does not explicitly deal with the issue of economic unaffordability of a
contract. However, in several notable judgments including Alopi Parshad v Union of India
(1960) 11 and Naihati Jute Mills v Hyaliram Jagannath (1968)the SC has held that a contractual
obligation becoming economically arduous is not a ground for absolving a party of its commitment.12
r
ep

9 However, relief under frustration is not available: (i) if frustration is self-induced; (ii) or about completed contracts of lease. See, Raja
Dhruv Dev v Harmohinder Singh (1968) where the SC held: “Section 56 is not applicable where the rights and obligations of the parties
have arisen under an agreement of lease”. Also, see Ramanand v Girish Soni (2020).
10For greater details refer Energy Watchdog v CERC (2017).
11 In this case the SC held that the promisor (supplier of ghee) could not wriggle out of his pre-war contract merely because World

War II had increased his costs. It held that commercial difficulty did not amount to impossibility to perform.
Pr

12 This is true in the internationally. E.g, see Tsakiroglou & Co Ltd v Noblee Thorl GmbH [1962] AC 93. The appellants/seller had

agreed to ship groundnuts by sea to Hamburg. The seller argued that he could not ensure supply as after signing of the contract, the
Suez Canal was closed to navigation due to the military operations by the Great Britain and France against Egypt. The contract had a
force majeure clause. However, the court held that closing of Suez Canal did not make the delivery impossible. Appellant goods

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
4. Litigation over contractual disputes: Sectoral analysis

ed
4.1 Power Purchase Agreements

Citing Covid related reasons, DISCOMs have invoked FM under their power purchase agreements
(PPAs) by suspending payments to power producers. Power-producers, on the other hand, have
argued that the lockdown has not affected the distribution companies’ ability to off-take electricity as

iew
power-generation and distribution was an essential service and faced no restrictions during the
lockdowns.13

Covid-19 or lockdowns have not made performance of contractual obligations temporarily or


completely impossible, therefore it cannot be treated as an FM event under requirements mentioned
in Proposition 1. Moreover, as discussed, an agreement becoming commercially onerous or an

ev
instance of reduced demand do not qualify as FM or serve as a ground for termination of contract.
The SC in Energy Watchdog v CERC (2017)has reinforced this view by observing that an increase in
the cost of coal or the agreement becoming onerous to perform are not FM events.14

rr
4.2 Construction Contracts

The contract between home buyers and developers are governed by the Real Estate (Regulation and
Development) Act (RERA), 2016. The RERA Act provides for a penalty for non-performance or
ee
delayed delivery of the apartment/building/plot. Due to the lockdowns, construction activities in real-
estate projects came to a grinding halt. So, promoters have cited Covid for invoking FM u/S 6 of the
Act and have filed an application for extension of registration to avoid liability for delay in giving
possession (Section 18).
tp

An FM claim by real-estate developers has merit because it directly halted the construction activity
for real-estate projects. Therefore, the developers are justified in asking for the relief of extension and
waiver of liability payments.
no

Moreover, even after the lockdowns are lifted or relaxed, the supply chain of construction material
has remained broken in addition to shortage of labour. Hence, the delay in completing projects.
Although theMinistry of Home Affairs (MHA) did allow construction work, it was subject to on-site
worker availability with no workers to be brought from outside. 15 This obstructed the timely
completion of work, and therefore qualifies as an FM event (satisfying requirements of Proposition
1). Therefore, the Finance Minister was spot-on in providing a six-month extension—on account of
int

the lockdowns, an act of government—for all real-estate projects registered under the Real Estate
Regulatory Authority.

However, the defence of lockdowns should not be allowed to justify pre-Covid delays. In Halliburton
Offshore Services Inc. v Vedanta Ltd. (2020) the Delhi HC categorically stated— “[…] Every breach
r

or non-performance cannot be justified or excused merely on the invocation of Covid-19 as a Force


ep

Majeure condition.” It further added, “[…] a Force Majeure clause is to be interpreted narrowly and
not broadly. Parties ought to be compelled to adhere to contractual terms and conditions and excusing
Pr

could have shipped around the Cape of Good Hope, even though this route was almost twice as long and the freightage would have
cost much more.
13 See Annexure to the MHA order dated 24 March, 2020.
14 The SC observed this while referring to 'exclusions to an FM clause’ in the PPA. Such exclusions to FM (e.g., agreement becoming

commercially onerous) are present in most PPAs.


15See Ministry of Home Affairs order dated 1 May, 2020.

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
non-performance would be only in exceptional situations […]”. Accordingly, the court denied relief
to the contractor who had breached terms of the contract even before the lockdowns.

ed
4.3 Air-Transportation Contracts

A booked air-ticket is a contract between the airline and the passenger. Government-mandated
lockdowns placed a ban on domestic and international air travel. Citing FM, airline operators
cancelled the tickets booked for travel during the period of ban. Instead of refunding the ticket

iew
amount—airlines have sought to convert them into credit shells usable only for buying future tickets
from the same carrier even when Civil Aviation Requirements clearly provide for refunding of ticket
amount to the customers. They have justified their actions on grounds of zero revenue and reduced
global earnings. On the other hand, customers have filed claims for refund of the full amount for
cancelled tickets, either booked in advance or during the lockdown. They have argued that offering
credit shells instead of refunds are unjustly enriching the airlines.

ev
The lockdowns made it impossible for the airlines to fly customers. So, the airlines are fully justified
in cancelling the booking. However, restitution of the advanced payment goes hand-in-hand with
termination of contract, that is, cancellation of the booked tickets.16Restitution prevents a party to a

rr
void contract from retaining received benefits. Airlines have violated this principle. Moreover, they
have violated Civil Aviation Requirements which says that “the option of holding the refund as a
credit shell is the prerogative of the customer.” Furthermore, efficiency suggests that airlines are the
least-cost-risk-bearer.
ee
The Ministry of Civil Aviation (MoCA) ordered the airlines to provide a full refund for tickets booked
during the first lockdown period. However, there was no relief for customers who booked tickets
before the lockdown was announced on March 24, 2020. That is why, a petition was filed by Pravasi
Legal Cell (see Pravasi Legal Cell v Union of India (2020)) seeking relief for the refund of air tickets,
tp

booked prior to the lockdown. While dealing with the issue, the SC has asked the airlines to try hard
to refund the tickets booked by passengers before the lockdown within a period of 15 days. In case
the airlines are unable to do so, they are required to create a credit shell that will remain valid until
31 March 2021.
no

4.4 Rental Contracts

Lease agreements or leave and license agreements, depending upon the case, serve as contracts
between commercial tenants (such as: restaurants, retailers, multiplexes) and premise owners. In the
aftermath of Covid-19, tenants have sought rental-waivers from premise owners, citing FM due to
int

government-ordered closure of non-essential businesses.

Lease agreements ordinarily contain an FM clause. However, a virus outbreak or a pandemic are not
among the typical elements of the FM clause. Unsurprisingly, the Delhi HC in Ramanand v Girish
Soni (2020)has observed that claims for waiver of rent by the tenants are only permissible if FM
r

clause expressly provides for it. In the absence of an FM clause, the relationship between parties is
ep

governed by u/S 108 (B)(e) of the Transfer of Property Act, 1882 which requires the property to be
‘wholly destroyed or rendered permanently unfit for use’ for invoking a waiver. In Raja Dhruv Dev
v Harmohinder Singh (1968), the SC interpreted the phrase 'substantially and permanently unfit' and
held that temporary non-use does not entitle a tenant to invoke this section.
Pr

16 A similar logic applies to transportation contracts between Indian Railways and its passengers and freight customers, and road
transport agencies and their customers.
8

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
Thus, there is no contractual relief available to the commercial tenants. The issue of equity of burden
or distress caused by such economic losses should be addressed through public policy, as discussed
in Proposition 3.

ed
4.5 Event Management and Hospitality Contracts

Public gatherings were made illegal during the lockdown period. This sudden change in law was an
FM event for the promising parties to event contracts—caterers and event managers, venue-owners,

iew
wedding planners, and vendors for decor & entertainment—who could not have provided the
promised service. It was no surprise that the lockdowns resulted in cancellation of a substantial
amount of pre-scheduled events, such as weddings.

Service providers have claimed FM, citing impossibility of contractually agreed performance. On the
other hand, clients who had provided security deposit/initial booking amount to service providers

ev
filed claims for refund due to frustration of contract for those pre-scheduled events that were upended
due to the government order.

Since an act of government made contractual performance by service providers impossible, it thus

rr
qualifies as an FM event (meeting requirements of Proposition 1). At the same time, from the side of
the clients the contract is frustrated. The purpose for which the contract was entered into no more
exists. For example, holding a private wedding after the government order was passed—destroys the
older contract with the venue owner—which was entered to host a party.
ee
Similarly, measures to contain Covid-19 have impacted the hospitality sector. For example, OYO has
cited Covid-related reasons for claiming frustration of contract with partner-hotels signed under the
minimum-guarantee deal—a model that guarantees revenue regardless of business generated. It
claimed that in a post-Covid world, it was impossible to discharge contractual obligations under
tp

minimum guarantee.

Affected hotels have argued that OYO was in default of paying its minimum guarantee, since
December 2018, 17 and was using the pandemic to brush away its contractual obligations.
no

For reasons cited earlier, OYO cannot renege on its contractual obligations on account of reduced
profits due to Covid-19, unless the contract explicitly allows such a termination. If OYO has been in
default since 2018, then it is using the pandemic disingenuously to extricate itself from its contractual
commitments. Furthermore, OYO seems to be the superior risk bearer because: (i) terms of the
minimum guarantee deal were framed by OYO (Hung et al 2018). Thus, it could have spread the risk
int

of such pandemic-related business losses through insurance.

5. Contracts versus Public Policy


r

In most cases, one party contracts with one other party. In other instances, a legal person contracts
with multiple parties For example, an insurance company offers a standard form insurance contract
ep

to many others; a commercial bank signs a standard contract with many debtor individuals or small
firms. In such scenarios, the losses caused by FM tend to be highly correlated. That is, an FM event
can simultaneously affect several contracting parties from one side of the contract. For this reason,
standard insurance policies normally do not allow compensation for epidemics. On the other hand,
Pr

an all risk/open-peril commercial insurance policy designed for epidemics asks for a higher premium.

17 See The Financial Express 4 April, 2020 [Accessed 5 July, 2020].

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
The premium charged under an insurance policy is theoretically a function of risk covered, higher the
risk covered, higher the premium. It is no surprise that such policies have found very few takers.18

ed
Moreover, loan contracts, employment contracts, and insurance contracts are quite different from
typical contracts. In such atypical cases, one party to a contract—such as banks, employers and
insurance companies—have much deeper pockets compared to those of debtors, employees, and the
insureds. It can be tempting for the courts to allocate the burden of Covid related loss to the side with
a deeper pocket.19

iew
In rest of this section, we consider these contractual issues one by one.

5.1 Insurance Contract

Mall owners, airline operators, wedding venue-owners have filed claims for BIL due to government-

ev
ordered closures, which they claim is an FM event. On the other hand, insurance companies argue
that BIL can only be claimed for financial losses arising out of damage to business equipment or
premises, unless the insurance is a comprehensive all-risk/open-peril policy—without the exclusion
of pandemics.20

rr
Most insurance policies require a physical loss to trigger coverage from perils such as fire, windstorm,
burglary, and loss of income from machinery breakdown. Neither the lockdown nor the pandemic
have caused actual physical damage to the property. For example, if a shopping mall closes operations
ee
to keep safe from contamination, such business closures do not amount to direct physical loss to the
property.21 Therefore, from a legal viewpoint, insurers are not liable for BIL. In this context, the 'rule
of contra proferentem’22 cannot be helpful to the insured. The SC in Sushilaben Indravadan Gandhi
v The New India Assurance Company (2020)has observed that the 'rule of contra proferentem’ is to
be applied only if there is real ambiguity in the wording of the policy, which is not the case in the
tp

matter at hand. In fact, as far as accident insurance is concerned, the SC has tended to interpret
insurance contracts strictly,23 in the spirit of Proposition 2. From an economic efficiency point of
view, a similar approach is incredibly important while dealing with insurance claims for correlated
business losses.
no

5.2 Debt Contracts

A debt contract is a commercial arrangement between a lender and the borrower at a specified rate of
interest. In the wake of Covid-19, many debtors have found themselves to be incapable of servicing
their loan. In view of the severity of the crisis, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) allowed a moratorium
int

on equated monthly instalments (EMIs) for all term loans for six months.24

However, in Gajendra Sharma v Union of India (2020)and other connected petitions, several
borrowers have filed a petition u/A 32 of the Constitution to declare the RBI notification ultra vires
r

18In 2018, an insurance product called Pathogen RX was offered by Marsh in collaboration with Munich Re and Metabiota to protect
ep

businesses in the U.S from an infectious-disease outbreak.[Accessed 3 June 2020]. Although, it was unable to sell a single policy for
months, see The New York Times5 March 2020 [Accessed 14 June 2020].
19 As such, employment contracts are governed by a number of labor laws limiting the negotiation space between the employer and

employee and therefore the flexibility within employment contracts.


20 Generally pandemics are excluded from coverage. One of the reasons being; during the SARS outbreak, insurers paid BIL worth

$16 million to a hotel chain in Asia; seeThe Washington Post 2 April 2020 [Accessed 13 June, 2020].
Pr

21Alanduraiappar Koil Chithakkadu v T.S.A. Hamid (1962) the Madras HC


22 A rule of interpretation where ambiguity in the wording of the policy/contract is to be resolved against the party who prepared it.
23 In Export Credit Guarantee Corporation of India Ltd. v M/S. Garg Sons International (2014) the SC held: “It is a settled legal

proposition that while construing the terms of a contract of insurance, the words used therein must be given paramount importance,
and it is not open for the Court to add, delete or substitute any words.”
24 See RBI’s Press releases dated 27 March, 2020 and 22 May, 2020.

10

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
to the extent that it charges interest on the interest due on loan amount during the moratorium period.
In these petitions before the SC, a demand for waiver of interest for the period of moratorium has
been made. The petitioners have claimed that charging of interest on loans is violative of the right to

ed
life and right to livelihood guaranteed u/A 21 of the Constitution since means of livelihood was
curtailed due to the lockdown.

Technically, the moratorium does not prohibit servicing of the debt contract. Applying the proposition
2 here suggests that the courts should interpret debt contracts like any other contract and interpret

iew
them narrowly. As discussed earlier, the contract price depends on how the risks are allocated between
the contracting parties. A bank will charge a higher interest rate if it needs to forgo the interest amount
on larger counts of risks faced by the debtors. Therefore, allowing an interest waiver can be
counterproductive. It will lead to increased interest rates for future debt contracts, thereby hurting the
long-term interest of borrowers and investors. In addition, allowing the demand for an interest rate
waiver can jeopardise the stability and financial health of banks, harm everyone in the process.

ev
This is not to say that the predicament of many debtors of personal loans and small and mid-size
enterprises (SMEs) is not genuine. However, larger public policy issues are involved here in
balancing the interests of borrowers with those of bank depositors and investors, who can be even

rr
more numerous than the borrowers. Hence, the only way to help such entities is through additional
fiscal support. In a welcome mover, the government has formally notified a scheme under which it
will bear the cost of compound interest during the moratorium period for small loans and credit card
dues up to Rs.2 crore. 25
ee
5.3 Employment contracts

The above logic also applies to employment contracts that are explicitly based on the principle of
‘no-work-no-wage’.26 Employment contracts ensure supply of labour to the employer and income to
tp

the employee. It is a voluntary exchange wherein wages and labour act as consideration for employees
and employers, respectively. Due to government-ordered-lockdowns, such exchanges were either
prohibited—in non-essential businesses—or limited—in essential businesses. In a notification, the
MHA ordered employers to make payment of wages to workers in industries, commercial
establishments, and shops without deductions for the lockdown period. 27 Subsequently, the
no

government has withdrawn the order with effect from 18 May, 2020.28 However, the initial order
remains effective for an interim period of 50 days.

Employers have challenged the order in several petitions. In Ficus Pax Private Ltd. v Union of India
(2020)employers have argued; the order i) interfered with the right of employers by forcing their
int

establishments into insolvency, and even caused a loss of control of business; (ii) violated the
principle of ‘equal-work-equal-pay’ and ‘no-work-no-pay’ as it did not distinguish between workers
not working or workers working in permitted establishments during the lockdown; and (iii) was
arbitrary, unreasonable and violative of Article 14, 19(1)(g) of the Constitution.
r

On strict application of contract law, the contention of employers has merit. Employers are not
ep

contractually bound to pay wages to their employees not at work—unless the contract entitled the

25 Government has also decided that the small borrowers who did not avail the moratorium and paid their dues on time will also be
given a cashback by the government to maintain parity between those who availed and did not avail the moratorium. See Pandey
Pr

(2020b).
26 For greater details, refer the definition of wages u/S 2(h), Industrial Disputes Act, 1947. Also, see Section 7(2) and Section 9 of the

Payment of Wages Act, 1936 which authorises the employer to make deductions for absence from duty grounds. Also, see the SC’s
ruling in Airport Authority of India v S.N. Das (2008).
27 See the MHA order dated 29 March, 2020.
28 See the MHA order dated 17 May, 2020.

11

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
workers to wages. Moreover, the economic stimulus packages provided to medium scale industries
had no explicit concessional component meant for bearing the burden of payment of wages.

ed
Rather than being guided by a contractual perspective, it seems the SC is overly concerned about
workers’ interests. As an interim measure, the court has held that efforts must be made to sort out
differences via negotiation and it has asked the Centre and States not to prosecute private
establishments, factories for non-payment of wages. The court has further instructed that if parties

iew
are unable to settle the issue through negotiation, a request can be submitted to the concerned labour
authority.

The stance of the Aurangabad bench of the Bombay HC is even more curious. In Rashtriya Shramik
Aghadi v State of Maharashtra (2020)the petitioner—a contract labourers’ union—has argued that
members of the union were willing and able to work for the Temple Trust in the aftermath of Covid-

ev
19. However, due to closure of places of worship during the lockdown, they were unable to do so.
The Aurangabad bench observed that the employer cannot use the principle of ‘no-work-no-wage'.

It held that “[...] this Court cannot turn a Nelson's eye to an extraordinary situation on account of the
Corona virus/Covid-19 pandemic. Able bodied persons, who are willing and desirous to offer their

rr
services in deference to their deployment as contract labourers in the security and house-keeping
sector of the Trust, are unable to work since the temples and places of worships in the entire nation
have been closed for securing the containment of Covid-19 pandemic. Even the principal employer
is unable to allot the work to such employees in such situation [...]”
ee
That is, the court has accepted the fact that the inability of the Trust to employ workers was due to
the act of government. Moreover, neither workers nor the court has argued whether the Trust was
contractually bound to pay the wages. Still, the court ruled that “the principle of “no work no wages”
tp

cannot be made applicable in such extraordinary circumstances.” It ordered that full wages be paid
for the months of March, April and May2020.

Such rulings of the higher judiciary can create obligations for employers well beyond their contractual
responsibilities. While big employers can absorb the cost of uncontracted wages, many small and
no

medium employers do not have pockets deep enough to bear the costs imposed on them by such
judicial findings. The latter are bound to resist paying wages during the lockdown. The result will be
unnecessary litigation that small employers and workers can ill afford.

5.4 Public Policy


int

Lives and livelihoods should trump over financial interests of firms, banks and corporations.
However, changing the terms of contract is not the way to go about it! The contractual disputes to
reallocate Covid-related losses is a zero-sum game as both parties—debtors & banks, insureds &
insurers—are hit hard by the crisis. Reallocating losses from the insured to insurance companies or
r

shifting the burden of lost income from workers to employers or from borrowers to banks will
ep

momentarily help many needy people and firms, but will jeopardise their long term interests, as
explained above. Importantly, it will reduce the certainty of contractual transactions, a pivot for
business and economic activity.

Steering the economy through such large-scale economic losses caused by the pandemic require
Pr

political, fiscal, and financial policy measures. Therefore, public policy is better suited to protect the
welfare of millions of people affected by Covid or lockdowns. For instance, in the United States of
America, the proposed Pandemic Risk Insurance Act, 2020 establishes a system of shared public and
private compensation of BIL incurred during a pandemic or an outbreak of a communicable disease.
12

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
Compensation is paid by the government, if the aggregate-industry-insured-losses exceed the
threshold amount fixed by the policy.

ed
Another case in point is Singapore's Covid-19 Temporary Measures Act, 2020 that offers a temporary
and targeted protection to individuals and businesses unable to perform contractual obligations due
to Covid-19. Instead of absolving contractual obligations, the act suspends performance of obligations
for an initial period of six months. This allows the affected parties to work out a solution without the
threat of litigation. The rental-relief framework under the Act provides for a 'fair sharing of economic

iew
hardship between the Government, landlords and tenants’. This balances the interest of all
participants: (i) it offers rental relief to eligible SMEs for two months through government assistance
and additional relief for two months supported by property owners;(ii) simultaneously, the
Government helps property owners facing cash-flow constraints through deferment of loan payments
and waiver of property tax of up to 100%.29

ev
Similarly, the Kingdom of Denmark has addressed the impact of Covid-19 through public policy.
The Danish Parliament passed a law on salary compensation for companies affected by Covid-19.30
It offers a temporary wage funding scheme that prevents Covid related layoffs in private companies.31
Besides, the government has offered a temporary subsidy scheme to recover fixed costs expenses

rr
such as: rent, insurance, maintenance in the form of support packages to companies losing at least
35% of their turnover due to Covid-19.

Another good example of using public policy comes from the Republic of Germany. The Bundestag
ee
has passed the Covid-19 Mitigation Act to deal with consequences of Covid-19.32 The new law offers
comprehensive protection to companies affected by the pandemic and offers them an opportunity to
overcome insolvency. At the same time, it protects lenders from clawback and lender’s liability risk.

In contrast, India is yet to witness a Covid related legislation. However, to cushion the economic
tp

consequences of the pandemic the Covid-19 Regulatory Package of the RBI has offered a moratorium
on EMIs for all term loans, until 31 August 2020 To an extent, the package has mitigated the effect
of debt servicing due to the temporary disruption of cash flow. Similarly, the Insolvency and
Bankruptcy Code (Amendment) Ordinance, 2020, has amended the IBC by restricting the filing of
no

any application for corporate insolvency resolution process for a period of six months.

Such policy moves will surely help maintain the status of businesses affected by Covid and
lockdowns without the threat of insolvency. However, it is can be more appropriate to provide banks
withan added fiscal stimulus, rather than forcing banks to forgo interest payments and become
unviable in the process.
int

Similarly, the workers who have lost their jobs should be compensated directly by the government
through direct benefit transfers or through funds available under Employee State Insurance
Corporation or, through economic stimulus packages.
r

The common and widely shared economic losses addressed through public policy enhance the social
ep

surplus and preserves the sanctity of contractual relations and associated benefits.
Pr

29See Additional Loan and Cash flow Support for Landlords and Businesses Affected by Covid-19. [Accessed 5 September, 2020]
Also, refer Overview of the Government cash grant and rental waiver obligations.
30Act on the Legal Position of Employers and Employees in Wage Compensation of Companies in connection with Covid-19.
31Private companies who were facing a need to layoff at least 30% of their workforce or 50 employees.
32Act to Mitigate the Consequences of the COVID-19 Pandemic under Civil, Insolvency and Criminal Procedure Law, 2020.

13

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
6. Conclusion

ed
We have argued that Covid-19 is not force majeure per-se! It is the lockdowns and not the virus that
has made it impossible for airlines, hotels, caterers and other service providers to deliver as promised;
contractors to complete real-estate and infrastructure projects on schedule, among others. Under such
contexts, the promising party is justified to use the force majeure clause. However, this does not
imply that the promisor is excused from fulfilling conditions attendant to the use of force majeure

iew
clause. In other contractual disputes, such as those involving power producers and electricity
distribution companies or OYO it appears that parties have used the force majeure clause or invoked
the doctrine of frustration disingenuously to extricate themselves from their contractual
commitments, often to cover continuing pre-Covid defaults.

The economic analysis of disputes covered in the article has attempted to draw the attention of courts

ev
and policymakers towards the economic implication of their decisions. We have used the inferences
following from economic analysis to explain how clear and predictable judicial rulings can enhance
social-efficiency by encouraging parties to settle their issues through bilateral negotiations or other
alternative dispute resolution mechanisms, thereby avoiding socially wasteful costs of litigation.

rr
However, for multi-party contracts where economic losses are highly correlated, public policy is
better suited to cater the interests of all participants. Our analysis of the recent court orders on Covid
related disputes suggests that in several cases, courts seem to under-appreciate the long-term
economic consequences of their rulings.
ee
References
Act on the Legal Position of Employers and Employees in Wage Compensation of Companies in connection with
tp

Covid-19.
Act to Mitigate the Consequences of the COVID-19 Pandemic under Civil, Insolvency and Criminal Procedure Law,
2020.
Airport Authority of India & Ors. v Shambhu Nath Das(2008): 11 SCC 498.
Alanduraiappar Koil Chithakkadu v T.S.A. Hamid And Another (1962): SCC On-line Mad 102.
no

Boothalinga Agencies v. T. C. Poriaswami Nadar (1969): 1 SCR 65.


Confederation of Danish Employers, The Danish Wage Compensation Scheme Helping Companies And Employees
Through The Covid-19 Pandemic dated 16 June, 2020, [Accessed 29 September 2020].
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas, ed. (2012): Law And Economics (Addison-Wesley), 349-52.
Covid-19 (Temporary Measures) Act 2020.
Energy Watchdog v Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (2017): 14 SCC 80.
int

Export Credit Guarantee Corporation of India Ltd. v M/s. Garg Sons International (2014): 1 SCC 686.
Ficus Pax Private Limited & Ors. v Union of India & Ors. (2020): SCC Online SC 481.
Frankel, Todd (2020): “Insurers knew the damage a viral pandemic could wreak on businesses. So they excluded
coverage”, The Washington Post, 2 April.
Gajendra Sharma v Union of India and Another (2020): W.P. (civil) 825.
r

Hung, Kevin, Mark, Carman, Yeung, May, Chan, Emily and Graham, Colin (2018): “The role of the hotel industry
ep

in the response to emerging epidemics: a case study of SARS in 2003 and H1N1 swine flu in 2009 in Hong Kong,”
Globalization and Health, Vol. 14(1), No. 117.https://doi.org/10.1186/s12992-018-0438-6
Inland Revenue Authority of Singapore, Government cash grant (announced in Fortitude Budget), [Accessed 13
September 2020].
Inland Revenue Authority of Singapore, Property Tax Rebate for Non-Residential Properties in 2020, [Accessed 13
Pr

September 2020].
Marsh, Pathogen RX An Exclusive Solution for Pandemic and Epidemic Risks, [Accessed 3 June 2020].
Ministry of Civil Aviation, GoI, Order No. (AV.11011/1/2020-US-(AG)-MoCA) dated 23 March 2020, [Accessed
1 April 2020].
14

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741
Ministry of Civil Aviation, GoI, Office Memo. (F. No. AV-29011/27/2020-DT) dated 16 April 2020, [Accessed 23
April 2020].
Ministry of Civil Aviation, GoI, Order No. (AV-13011/1/2020-US(SS)-MoCA) dated 21 May 2020, [Accessed 27

ed
May 2020].
Ministry of Home Affairs, GoI, Annexure to Ministry of Home Affairs Order (40-3/2020) dated 24 March 2020,
[Accessed 15 April 2020].
Ministry of Home Affairs, GoI, Order No. (40-3/2020-DM-I(A)) dated 29 March 2020, [Accessed 1 April 2020].
Ministry of Home Affairs, GoI, Order No. 40-3/2020-DM-I(A) dated 1 May 2020, [Accessed 11 May 2020].

iew
Ministry of Home Affairs, GoI, Order No. 40-3/2020-DM-I(A) dated 17 May 2020, [Accessed 24 May 2020].
Ministry of Power, GoI, No. (23/22/2019-R&R Part-4) dated 6 April 2020, [Accessed 15 April 2020].
Monetary Authority of Singapore, Media Releases, Additional Loan and Cashflow Support for Landlords and
Businesses Affected by Covid-19 dated 3 June, 2020, [Accessed 13 September 2020].
M/S. Alopi Parshad & Sons, Ltd. v The Union of India (1960): 2 SCR 793.
M/S. Halliburton Offshore Services Inc. v Vedanta Ltd. & Another (2020): SCC Online Del 542.
Narmada Bachao Andolan v Union of India (2000): 10 SCC 664.

ev
National Agricultural Cooperative Marketing Federation of India v Alimenta S.A. (2020): SCC Online SC 381.
Pandey, Subhash C (2020a) ‘Acid test for GST’The Pioneer, 02 September 2020
Pandey, Subhash C (2020b) ‘interest’ The Pioneer, 02 September 2020
Posner, Richard (2004): “Law and Economics of Contract Interpretation," Texas Law Review, Vol 83, pp 1596-1608.

rr
Posner, Richard and Rosenfield, Andrew (1977): “Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An
Economic Analysis”, The Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 6, No.1, pp 90-117.
Pravasi Legal Cell v Union of India & Others (2020): SCC Online SC 799.
PTI (2020): “OYO suspends payment of monthly benchmark revenue to hotels; invokes force majeure,” Financial
ee
Express, 4 April.
Raja Dhruv Dev Chand v Harmohinder Singh & Another (1968): 3 SCR 339.
Ramanand and Others v Dr. Girish Soni & Another (2020): SCC Online Del 635.
Rashtriya Shramik Aghadi v The State of Maharashtra & Others. (2020): SCC Online Bom 634.
Reserve Bank of India, Press Release, Statement on Development and Regulatory Policies dated 27 March 2020,
tp

[Accessed 30 March 2020].


Reserve Bank of India, Press Release, Statement on Development and Regulatory Policies dated 22 May 2020,
[Accessed 28 May 2020].
Satyabrata Ghose v Mugneeram Bangur & Others (1954): SCR 310.
Singh, Ram (2003): "Efficiency of ‘simple’ liability rules when courts make erroneous estimation of the damage",
no

European Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 16, pp. 39-58.


Singh, Ram (2004): “Economics of Judicial Decision Making, Indian Tort Law: Motor Accident Cases (special
article),” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 39, No. 25, pp 2613-2616.
Singh, Ram (2004): "‘Full’ Compensation Criteria: An Enquiry into Relative Merits", European Journal of Law and
Economics, Vol. 18, pp. 223-237.
Singh, Ram (2012): “Inefficiency and Abuse of Compulsory Land Acquisition: An enquiry into the way forward,”
int

Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XLVII, No. 19, pp 46-52.


Singh Ram (2018): Economic Efficiency. In: Marciano A., Ramello G. (eds) Encyclopedia of Law and Economics.
Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7883-6_206-1
Standard Retail Private Ltd. v G.S Global Corp. & Others ( 2020): SCC Online Bom 704.
r

Sushilaben Indravadan Gandhi & Another v The New India Assurance Company Ltd. & Others (2020): SCC Online
SC 367.
ep

The Naihati Jute Mills Ltd. v Hyaliram Jagannath (1968): 1 SCR 821.
The State vs Eckhardt (1910): 232 Mo. 49.
Walsh, Mary W. (2020): “Coronavirus Will Cost Businesses Billions. Insurance May Not Help”, The New York
Times, 5 March.
Pr

15

This preprint research paper has not been peer reviewed. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3720741

You might also like