General Theory of Law and Development: Yong-Shik Lee
General Theory of Law and Development: Yong-Shik Lee
General Theory of Law and Development: Yong-Shik Lee
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 416 R
I. Law and Development: History and Context . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 420 R
A. Law and Development “Movements” . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 420 R
B. “Law” in the Context of Law and Development . . . . . . . . . 423 R
1. Law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 423 R
2. Legal Frameworks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 424 R
† Director and Professorial Fellow, The Law and Development Institute and
Distinguished Scholar in Residence, Emory University School of Law (2015– 2016). The
author is grateful to leading scholars who read earlier versions of this manuscript and
gave helpful comments, including Professors Frank Upham (New York University),
Simon Deakin (University of Cambridge), Tom Ginsburg (University of Chicago),
Reuven Avi-Yonah (University of Michigan), Alvaro Santos (Georgetown University), Paul
J. Zwier (Emory University), Francis Snyder (Peking University), Moshe Hirsch (Hebrew
University of Jerusalem), Klaus Ziegert (University of Sydney), William H.J. Hubbard
(University of Chicago), Jide Okechuku Nzelibe (Northwestern University), Tim Murphy
(Universidad Carlos III de Madrid), Diogo R. Coutinho (University of São Paulo),
Wouter Vandenhole (University of Antwerp), Markus Kaltenborn (Ruhr University
Bochum), Alexander Volokh (Emory University), Salim Farrar (University of Sydney),
Pedro Rivas Palá (Universidad de La Coruña), Stephanie de Moerloose (Universidad
Austral), T.K. Pooe (North West University), Alessandro Romano (China-EU School of
Law), Won-Mog Choi (Ewha Womans University), Dae In Kim (Ewha Womans
University), Junji Nakagawa (University of Tokyo), Jon Mark Truby (Qatar University),
and Dr. Johan Rochel (University of Tokyo). The author also thanks Ms. Kari Bloom, Mr.
Ryan Layton, Mr. Brian McKeegan, Mr. Clinton Odel Hall, Mr. Robert Sroka, Ms. Qi Bao,
Dr. Hye Seong Mun, and the editorial staff of Cornell International Law Journal for their
editorial and research assistance.
50 CORNELL INT’L L.J. 415 (2017)
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 2 7-MAR-18 14:54
3. Institutions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 426 R
II. The Question of Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 428 R
A. What Constitutes Development? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 428 R
B. Economic and Social Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 430 R
C. Extension of the Concept of Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 432 R
III. Regulatory Impact Mechanisms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 435 R
A. Regulatory Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 436 R
1. Anticipated Policy Outcome . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 436 R
2. Organization of Law, Legal Frameworks, and
Institutions (LFIs) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 441 R
3. Adaptability to Socioeconomic Conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . 444 R
B. Regulatory Compliance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 446 R
1. General Regulatory Compliance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 447 R
2. Specific Regulatory Compliance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 448 R
C. Quality of Implementation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 450 R
1. Definition and Importance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 450 R
2. State Capacity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 451 R
3. Political Will . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 454 R
IV. Application of the General Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 456 R
A. Development of South Korea (1962– 1996): An
Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 456 R
B. Applying the General Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 458 R
1. Applying the Disciplinary Parameters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 458 R
2. Regulatory Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 458 R
3. Regulatory Compliance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 463 R
4. State Capacity and Political Will . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 465 R
Conclusion: Does Law Matter for Development? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 468 R
Introduction
Law has become the framework and vocabulary for constructing and
debating development policies,1 but law and development, an area of schol-
arship that explores the relationship between law and economic and social
progress,2 is relatively unknown and underdeveloped as an academic field
1. Development policies since the 1990s have been conceived and constructed in
the notion of legal rights. See David Kennedy, The “Rule of Law,” Political Choices, and
Development Common Sense, in THE NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT: A CRITICAL
APPRAISAL 95, 167 (David M. Trubek & Alvaro Santos eds., 2006) (discussing the chang-
ing roles of law, economics, and politics in the context of development policies).
2. Law and development, as an area of scholarship, is indeterminate and heteroge-
neous. Reflecting on these characteristics, Scott Newton commented, “It [law and devel-
opment] does not appear to possess a particular normative armature or notable
thematic consistency or much of a unifying logic or set of organizing principles. The
most one can say is that the disciplinary range of L&D is constituted by the aggregate of
studies pursued by its self-identifying adherents.” Scott Kennedy, The Dialectics of Law
and Development, in NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra note 1, at 177. The R
noted indeterminacy, lack of disciplinary clarity, and absence of an underpinning the-
ory that systematically explains the interrelations between law and development have
retarded its development as a coherent academic field.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 3 7-MAR-18 14:54
3. For a review of law and development scholarship, see Kevin E. Davis & Michael
Trebilcock, The Relationship between Law and Development: Optimists versus Skeptics, 56
AM. J. COMP. L. 895 (2008); and David M. Trubek, Law and Development 50 Years On
(University of Wisconsin Legal Studies Research Paper No. 1212, 2012), http://
ssrn.com/abstract=2161899 [https://perma.cc/ZVK2-3HPP]; see also Yong-Shik Lee,
Call for a New Analytical Model for Law and Development, 8 LAW & DEV. REV. 1, 10– 27
(2015).
4. See David M. Trubek & Marc Galanter, Scholars in Self-Estrangement: Some Reflec-
tions on the Crisis in Law and Development Studies in the United States, WIS. L. REV. 1062
(1974).
5. See John Henry Merryman, Comparative Law and Social Change: On the Origins,
Style, Decline & Revival of the Law and Development Movement, 25 AM. J. COMP. L. 457
(1977).
6. See Francis G. Snyder, The Failure of “Law and Development,” WIS. L. REV. 373
(1982); see also Francis G. Snyder, Law and Development in the Light of Dependency The-
ory, 14 LAW & SOC’Y REV. 723 (1980).
7. See Douglas C. North, Institutions, 5 J. ECON. PERSP. 97 (1991).
8. See Brian Z. Tamanaha, The Lessons of Law-and-Development Studies, 89 AM. J.
INT’L L. 470 (1995).
9. See Maxwell O. Chibundu, Law in Development: On Tapping, Gourding and Serv-
ing Palm-Wine, 29 CASE W. RES. J. INT’L L. 167 (1997).
10. See Richard A. Posner, Creating a Legal Framework for Economic Development, 13
WORLD BANK OBSERVER 1 (1998).
11. See Amy Chua, Markets, Democracy, and Ethnicity: Toward A New Paradigm for
Law and Development, 108 YALE L.J. 1 (1998).
12. See Frank B. Cross, Law and Economic Growth, 80 TEX. L. REV. 1737 (2001).
13. See Kevin E. Davis & Michael J. Trebilcock, Legal Reforms and Development, 22
THIRD WORLD Q. 21 (2001).
14. See Michael S. Barr & Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Globalization, Law and Development,
26 MICH. J. INT’L L. 1 (2004).
15. See Thomas F. McInerney, Law and Development as Democratic Practice, 38
VAND. J. TRANSNAT’L L. 109 (2005).
16. See HIRAM CHODOSH, GLOBAL JUSTICE REFORM: A COMPARATIVE METHODOLOGY
(2005).
17. See KENNETH W. DAM, THE LAW-GROWTH NEXUS: THE RULE OF LAW AND ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT (2006).
18. See Okezie Chukwumerije, Rhetoric Versus Reality: The Link Between the Rule of
Law and Economic Development, 23 EMORY INT’L L. REV. 383 (2009).
19. See Mariana Prado, Should We Adopt a “What Works” Approach in Law and Devel-
opment?, 104 NW. U.L. REV. 174 (2009).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 4 7-MAR-18 14:54
20. It is described as a “general” theory as it sets the general parameters of the disci-
pline by defining the constituent concepts of “law” and “development” and explains the
general mechanisms by which law impacts development.
21. Socioeconomic conditions refer to a range of social, political, economic, and cul-
tural conditions that are essential to the successful operation of law.
22. The World Bank is known to have embarked on over 600 such projects by 2004.
See Kerry Rittich, The Future of Law and Development: Second Generation Reforms and the
Incorporation of Social, in THE NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra note 1, at R
221.
23. See e.g., LAW REFORM IN DEVELOPING AND TRANSITIONAL STATES (Tim Lindsey ed.,
2006).
24. See Davis & Trebilcock, supra note 3, at 916; and Alvaro Santos, The World R
Bank’s Uses of the “Rule of Law” Promise in Economic Development, in THE NEW LAW AND
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra note 1, at 254. Alan Watson also discussed the problem R
associated with the legal transplant. See Alan Watson, Legal Change: Sources of Law and
Legal Change, 131 U. PA. L. REV. 1121, 1146– 47 (1983).
25. In this respect, the general theory would be necessary to solve “the problem of
knowledge” as indicated by Thomas Carothers. See Thomas Carothers, The Problem of
Knowledge, in PROMOTING THE RULE OF LAW ABROAD: IN SEARCH OF KNOWLEDGE 15, 16
(Thomas Carothers ed., 2006). The regulatory impact mechanisms may be also applied
beyond law and development to assess the impact of law (“regulatory impact”) generally.
Examples of such general application are also provided. See infra notes 173 and 203 R
(discussing the importance of state capacity concerning crime control).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 5 7-MAR-18 14:54
26. Law is designed in the process of legislation or, in the cases of customary law
and case law, by evolvement and adaptation (and in the process of its identification).
For further discussion, see Part III A.
27. For further discussion of the three sub-elements, see discussion infra Part III A.
28. See discussion infra Part III B.
29. Id.
30. See discussion infra Part III C.
31. A state refers to an organized political community directed by a sovereign gov-
ernment with control over a defined territory. For the purpose of this Article, the con-
cept of “state” includes both formal state, which is recognized by other states under
international law, and de facto state, which may not be formally recognized but func-
tions as one by the recognition and support of its constituent members. For further
discussion of the recognition of states in international law, see Hersch Lauterpacht, Rec-
ognition of States in International Law, 53 YALE L.J. 385 (1944).
32. See discussion infra Part III C.
33. The terms, “economic and/or social development” and “economic and/or social
progress,” are treated as synonymous and used without distinction throughout this
Article.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 6 7-MAR-18 14:54
particularly the United States, in order to assist in the economic and social
progress of developing countries in the Third World.39
These initial efforts, referred to as the first “law and development
movement,”40 were influenced by modernization theory advanced in the
1950s and the 60s by scholars such as Walt Rostow who argued that the
modernization (development) of the Third World would be accomplished
by the diffusion of capital, institutions, and values from the First World.41
“Modern law” was believed to be the “functional prerequisite of an indus-
trial economy,”42 and law was seen as “a force which can be molded and
manipulated to alter human behavior and achieve development.”43 The
first law and development movement was largely unsuccessful due to diffi-
culty implementing laws and legal practices, including reform of legal edu-
cation, in developing countries where key socioeconomic conditions,44
which were essential to their successful implementation, did not exist and
their absence had been overlooked or ignored.45
Law and development was resuscitated in the 1980s and the 90s after
the fall of the Soviet bloc, with the proliferation of neoliberal46 law reform
projects that sought to reduce state intervention in the economy by promot-
ing the privatization and deregulation of the economy.47 This second law
and development movement was substantially larger in scale and impact
than the first, with significant effects on development projects and policies
around the world.48 The outcome of the second law and development
movement was mixed at best, failing to result in successful development for
most of the developing world.49 Moreover, some of these reforms caused
serious economic difficulties for large populations, as demonstrated by the
39. See David M. Trubek, The “Rule of Law” in Development Assistance: Past, Present,
and Future, in THE NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra note 1, at 74– 75. R
40. Id. at 74– 81.
41. Davis & Trebilcock, supra note 3, at 900. R
42. David M. Trubek, Toward a Social Theory of Law: An Essay on the Study of Law and
Development, 82 YALE L.J. 1, 6 (1972).
43. Elliot M. Berg, Law and Development: A Review of the Literature and a Critique of
“Scholar in Self-Estrangement,” 25 AM J. COMP. L. 492, 505– 06 (1977).
44. A series of presumptions or “pillars” on which the first law and development
movement proceeded, such as a cultural reform and transplantation strategy, an ad hoc
approach to reform based on simplistic theoretical assumptions, faith in spillovers from
the economy to democracy and human rights, and a development strategy that stressed
state-led import substitution, collapsed by the 1970s. See Trubek, supra note 39, at R
78– 81.
45. See Trubek & Galanter, supra note 4. R
46. The neoliberal approach is based on neoclassical economics, which emerged in
the late nineteenth century and reaffirmed, against Marxism, that the market promotes
economic efficiency and fair social distribution. Neoliberalism, which became a domi-
nant political-economic ideology in the 1980s, discouraged positive government inter-
ventions in the economy and promoted free market approaches, including privatization
and trade liberalization.
47. See David M. Trubek & Alvaro Santos, Introduction: The Third Moment in Law
and Development Theory and the Emergence of a New Critical Practice, in THE NEW LAW
AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra note 1, at 3. R
48. See id.
49. See id. at 6– 7.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 8 7-MAR-18 14:54
50. These failures indicated that “markets do not create the conditions for their own
success.” See id. For further discussion of the Asian financial crisis, see also HAIDER A.
KHAN, GLOBAL MARKETS AND FINANCIAL CRISES IN ASIA (2004).
51. See Wade Channel, Lessons Not Learned About Legal Reform, in PROMOTING THE
RULE OF LAW ABROAD: IN SEARCH OF KNOWLEDGE 137 (Thomas Carothers ed., 2006).
52. See Alvaro Santos, The World Bank’s Uses of the “Rule of Law” Promise in Economic
Development, in THE NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra note 1, at 296– 97. R
53. “Washington Consensus” refers to a set of policies that represents the lowest
common denominator of policy advice that Washington-based institutions advances,
such as fiscal discipline, a redirection of public expenditure priorities toward areas offer-
ing both high economic returns and the potential to improve income distribution (such
as primary health care, primary education, and infrastructure), tax reform to lower mar-
ginal rates and broaden the tax base, interest rate liberalization, a competitive exchange
rate, trade liberalization, liberalization of inflows of foreign direct investment, privatiza-
tion, deregulation (to abolish barriers to entry and exit), and protection of property
rights. See John Williamson, What Washington Means by Policy Reform, in LATIN AMERI-
CAN READJUSTMENT: HOW MUCH HAS HAPPENED 5, 7– 20 (John Williamson ed., 1989).
54. Certain East Asian countries, such as Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and more
recently China, have achieved remarkable economic development, rising from a state of
poverty to that of developed economies, by adopting strong state-driven industrial poli-
cies and through state involvement in the economy; however, these lessons were not
incorporated in the development projects by international development agencies, such
as the World Bank. For an account of the success of East Asian economies and the role
of the state, see YONG-SHIK LEE, RECLAIMING DEVELOPMENT IN THE WORLD TRADING SYSTEM
14– 32, 301– 33 (2016).
55. See Trubek & Santos, supra note 47, at 7– 9. R
56. For an explanation of the holistic view, see discussion infra Part II A.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 9 7-MAR-18 14:54
1. Law
“Law” generally is defined as a “body of rules of action or conduct
prescribed by controlling authority, and having binding legal force”61 or “a
specific rule or a set of rules binding on the members of a society.”62
Examples of law include provisions of statutes adopted by legislatures,
including constitutions, regulations adopted by administrative agencies,
and ordinances adopted by municipalities. In the law and development
context, “law” may be broader than what the term is perceived as based on
these formalistic characteristics. For example, binding judicial precedents
are referred to as “law” (case law) in common law countries, such as the
United States and Britain, even if such precedents are not formally consid-
ered “law” in civil law jurisdictions, such as France and Germany.63 Still,
if judicial precedents are followed with de facto binding force, then they are
considered “law” for law and development studies in both common law
and civil law countries. Scholars have recognized the existence and force
of norms other than legislation and case law.64 For the purpose of law and
development studies, “law” also includes some of these norms or informal
rules, referred to as “customary law,” that are consistently observed with
an opinio juris.65
There is a question as to whether informal norms that practically bind
the members of a society, but are not necessarily observed with an opinio
juris, should be considered “law” in the context of law and development. A
good example of such an informal norm is the “administrative guidance”66
that the Korean and Japanese governments have adopted for businesses
and industries during periods of economic development. The people of
these countries consistently followed administrative guidance, even though
it was not formally a “law” or recognized as such by the public (i.e., no
opinio juris), because their local and political cultures regarded giving such
guidance as a legitimate role of the government.67 Some suggest that “law”
should be understood very broadly, including the basic form of communal
normative ordering regardless of the presence of opinio juris.68 Per this
more expansive definition, practices such as administrative guidance as
well as all fundamental social norms, are understood to be forms of “law.”
This expansive definition blurs the distinction between law and non-legal
orders.69
2. Legal Frameworks
64. For further discussion of informal norms regulating private transactions, see
Stewart Macaulay, Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 AM.
SOC. REV. 55 (1963); ROBERT C. ELLICKSON, ORDER WITHOUT LAW: HOW NEIGHBORS SETTLE
DISPUTES (1991); and Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contrac-
tual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992).
65. The existence of a customary law may be confirmed by a judicial decision. For
further discussion of customary law, see AMANDA PERREAU-SAUSSINE & JAMES BERNARD
MURPHY, THE NATURE OF CUSTOMARY LAW: LEGAL, HISTORICAL AND PHILOSOPHICAL PERSPEC-
TIVES (2009). Customary law includes religious codes, such as Sharia law (Islamic Law)
that most Muslim-majority countries have adopted and enforced. See, e.g., SALIM FARRAR
& GHENA KRAYEM, ACCOMMODATING MUSLIMS UNDER COMMON LAW: A COMPARATIVE ANAL-
YSIS (2016).
66. “Haeng-Jung Ji-Do” (in Korean) or “Gyô-Sei Shi-Dô” (Japan).
67. For a related account of minimum judicial oversight, see Tom Ginsburg, Disman-
tling the “Developmental State”? Administrative Procedure Reform in Japan and Korea, 49
AM. J. COMP. L. 585, 594– 97 (2001).
68. See, e.g., GARRETT BARDEN & TIM MURPHY, LAW AND JUSTICE IN COMMUNITY (2010).
69. In any case, the dividing line between law and non-legal orders is by no means
clear. For instance, whether a particular informal norm is observed with an opinio juris
could be a matter of debate. See also Tim Murphy, Living Law, Normative Pluralism, and
Analytic Jurisprudence, 3 JURIS. 177 (2012).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 11 7-MAR-18 14:54
recently, China. Among this list, only Hong Kong and Singapore are classi-
fied as common law systems. Mahoney’s research also disregarded vari-
ances among common law countries and exaggerated the claimed
differences between common law and civil law countries. For example,
Singapore, a common law country, showed strong government initiatives
and activism in its economic development process.77 When the authorita-
rian rule of Pinochet ended in 1990, Chile, which maintained a civil law
system, promoted liberal policies that emphasized individual liberty and
freedom in both political and economic areas. If there is any relevance
between the legal system and its development, it is that a civil law system,
based on state-sponsored codes, appears more adoptable than a common
law system. Except for countries that were formerly under British rule,
most countries have adopted a civil law system.
3. Institutions
Lastly, the concept of “institution” is also relevant to law and develop-
ment discourse. “Institutions,” in the context of law and development,
refers to organizations, norms, and practices related to the adoption, imple-
mentation, and enforcement of law.78 The impact of law cannot be
assessed separately from relevant institutions. For example, the adoption
of a statute that imposes a criminal penalty on corruption would lack effec-
tiveness if the essential institutions that enforce it, such as an effective
prosecutorial service or an independent judiciary, were absent.79 Also,
laws that attempt to establish formal private property rights (“FPPRs”),
with the objective of enhancing economic efficiency by securing citizens’
legal rights to their property, may not be effective without the implementa-
80. For further discussion of FPPRs, see Guangdong Xu, Property Rights, Law, and
Economic Development, 6 LAW & DEV. REV. 117 (2013).
81. See Trubek & Galanter, supra note 4, at 1078– 79. R
82. DOUGLASS C. NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC PER-
FORMANCE (1990). Comparing the United States’ success with its constitution with the
lack of success Latin American countries have had with their constitutions that were
inspired by the United States, North also argued that the institutions that were previ-
ously in place affect the path that an economy takes in the future (“path dependency”).
North, supra note 7, at 110– 11. According to North, institutions provide the incentive R
structure that directs economic and political growth. See Douglass North, Big-Bang
Transformations of Economic Systems: An Introductory Note, 156 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEO-
RETICAL ECON. 3, 5 (2000). The evolution of that structure determines whether econo-
mies grow, stagnate, or decline. See North, supra note 7, at 97. R
83. See Davis & Trebilcock, supra note 13. R
84. Several studies discuss the role of institutions in economic development. Based
on empirical evidence, Frank Cross concluded that the necessity of legal institutions for
economic growth is unquestionable. See Cross, supra note 12, at 1738– 39. Kenneth R
Dam also considered legal institutions to be important for economic development. See
DAM, supra note 17, at 230– 31. Additional empirical cross-country research acknowl- R
edges the importance of institutions for development. See Daniel Kaufmann et al., Gov-
ernance Matters (World Bank Policy Research Working Papers No. 2196, 1999); see also
Dani Rodrik, Arvind Subramanian, & Francesco Trebbi, Institutions Rule: The Primacy of
Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development, 9 J. ECON. GROWTH
131 (2004).
85. Some scholars have advocated for a “cluster of institutions” that are important to
encourage investment and growth, such as constraints on government expropriation,
independent judiciary, property rights enforcement, and institutions providing equal
access to education and civil liberties. See Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, & James A.
Robinson, The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,
91 AM. ECON. REV. 1369, 1371– 72 (2001). By contrast, others have observed that insti-
tutions, such as the independent judiciary and formal property rights, are not essential
to successful economic growth. See Posner, supra note 10, at 2; see also Frank Upham, R
The Paradoxical Roles of Property Rights in Growth and Development, 8 LAW & DEV. REV.
253 (2015). Dani Rodrik has enumerated five market-supporting institutions, including
property rights, regulatory institutions, institutions for macroeconomic stabilization,
institutions for social insurance, and institutions of conflict management. See Dani
Rodrik, Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They Are and How to Acquire Them, 35
STUD. COMP. INT’L DEV. 3, 6– 10 (2000).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 14 7-MAR-18 14:54
The substance of “development” and its focus have changed over time.
In the 50s and 60s, development primarily meant economic growth or
improvement in national income, reflecting efforts to relieve populations in
developing countries89 of prevalent poverty and to reduce economic gaps
between developed and developing countries.90 The concept of develop-
ment has become more holistic since then, emphasizing non-economic val-
ues believed to enhance human life, such as political participation, right to
property, gender equality, access to a clean and safe environment, and the
91. See Santos, supra note 24, at 256– 66 (discussing the rule of law); see also BRIAN R
TAMANAHA, ON THE RULE OF LAW: HISTORY, POLITICS, THEORY (2004).
92. See Gordon, supra note 90, at 13 (stating that the holistic view of development R
includes some of the social rights that are also relevant to enhance the economic and
technological capacity of society, such as access to education, in the ambit of
development).
93. See AMARTYA SEN, DEVELOPMENT AS FREEDOM (1999); see also Rittich, supra note
22, at 208. R
94. UNDP, What is Human Development?, http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/what-
human-development [https://perma.cc/Y6EK-JR4J].
95. Id.
96. See World Bank, Comprehensive Development Framework, http://www.world
bank.org/en/webarchives/archive?url=httpzzxxweb.worldbank.org/archive/website
01013/WEB/0__PAGEP.HTM&mdk=22201409 [https://perma.cc/K89F-33RS].
97. See United Nations, supra note 59. R
98. Bhupinder Chimni, The Sen Conception of Development and Contemporary Inter-
national Law Discourse: Some Parallels, 1 LAW & DEV. REV. 3 (2008).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 16 7-MAR-18 14:54
99. For a discussion of the successful development of the NICs, see supra note 75. R
100. SONGOK HAN THORNTON & WILLIAM H. THORNTON, DEVELOPMENT WITHOUT FREE-
DOM: THE POLITICS OF ASIAN GLOBALIZATION (2008).
101. Kerry Rittich also observed that the most outstanding examples of both eco-
nomic growth and social progress can be found in the NICs. See Rittich, supra note 22, R
at 239.
102. Prioritizing and sequencing would also be consistent with the objectives of sus-
tainable development, because the advocated approach actually allows developing coun-
tries to secure the resources to achieve SDGs.
103. See, e.g., Matleena Kniivilä, Industrial Development and Economic Growth: Impli-
cations for Poverty Reduction and Income Inequality, in INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT FOR THE
21ST CENTURY: SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT PERSPECTIVES 295, 312 (David O’Connor &
Mónica Kjöllerström eds., 2007) (accounting the rural-urban gap in Indonesia).
104. See Rittich, supra note 22, at 207, 216. See also World Bank, Engendering Devel- R
opment: Through Gender Equality in Rights, Resources and Voice 88– 92 (World Bank Pol-
icy Research Report No. 21776, 2001), http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 17 7-MAR-18 14:54
512911468327401785/Engendering-development-through-gender-equality-in-rights-
resources-and-voice https://perma.cc/H587-JUQ2].
105. World Bank, Poverty Forecasts, http://www.worldbank.org/en/publication/
global-monitoring-report/poverty-forecasts-2015 [https://perma.cc/34RT-J336]. (The
amount in dollars ($) is in U.S. dollars throughout this Article unless indicated other-
wise.) Two seminal books in law and development also focus on economic develop-
ment. See THE NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT (David M. Trubek & Alvaro
Santos eds., 2006), supra note 1; and DAM, supra note 17. R
106. See World Bank, Development and Human Rights: The Role of the World Bank 8
(1998), http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/820031468767358922/Develop-
ment-and-human-rights-the-role-of-the-World-Bank (discussing the importance of eco-
nomic development for the enhancement of human rights) [https://perma.cc/MDJ7-
CKYH].
107. See discussion supra Part II A.
108. See Lee, supra note 3, at 4. R
109. See Obergefell v. Hodges, 135 S. Ct. 2584, 2588 (2015) (legalizing marriages
between individuals of the same sex (“same-sex marriage”) by requiring all States to
issue a marriage license to same-sex couples.) However, as of December 2017, the
majority of countries have not legally recognized same-sex marriage.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 18 7-MAR-18 14:54
115. For a discussion of the neoliberal approach, see supra note 46. R
116. The OECD observed increasing wage gaps and household income inequality in a
large majority of OECD countries. See OECD, DIVIDED WE STAND: WHY INEQUALITY KEEPS
RISING 22 (2011). For example, according to the U.S. Census Bureau, New Orleans and
Detroit are among the most impoverished major cities in the United States, with 27.8
percent and 39.3 percent of their populations living below the poverty line ($24,008 for
a family of four), respectively, as of 2014. See Karen Bouffard, Census Bureau: Detroit Is
the Biggest Poor City in the U.S., DET. NEWS (Sept. 16, 2015), http://www.detroitnews.
com/story/news/local/michigan/2015/09/16/census-us-uninsured-drops-income-stag
nates/32499231 [https://perma.cc/E3BP-MY2U]. Both cities also suffer from high
crime rates and low public-school rating. See Peter Harkness, Detroit and New Orleans
Have More in Common Than Most Think, GOVERNING (Jan. 2016), http://www.govern-
ing.com/columns/potomac-chronicle/gov-detroit-new-orleans-resilience.html) [https://
perma.cc/7J7R-X5JE].
117. Analysts have cited widening income gaps and the resulting poverty as reasons
for the result of Britain’s 2016 referendum to exit the European Union and for the out-
come of the 2016 U.S. presidential election. See John Harris, If You Have Got money, You
Vote in . . . If You Haven’t, You Vote out, THE GUARDIAN (June 24, 2016), https://www.the
guardian.com/politics/commentisfree/2016/jun/24/divided-britain-brexit-money-class-
inequality-westminster [https://perma.cc/4K3T-KZLA]; and Trip Gabriel, How Erie Went
Red: The Economy Sank, and Trump Rose, N.Y. TIMES (Nov. 12, 2016), https://
www.nytimes.com/2016/11/13/us/politics/pennsylvania-trump-votes.html [https://
perma.cc/NH5H-GS6H].
118. Reflecting this reality, national, regional, and local governments in developed
countries have set up offices to foster “economic development.” Examples include Eco-
nomic Development Administration (EDA) established under the U.S. Department of
Commerce, the Georgia Department of Economic Development in the State of Georgia,
USA, and the Office of Economic Development in the City of New Orleans. See EDA,
U.S. ECON. DEV. AGENCY, https://www.eda.gov/ [https://perma.cc/WC7C-CSJT]; About
Us, GA. DEP’T ECON. DEV., http://www.georgia.org/about-us/ [https://perma.cc/FM2G-
UCT6]; and Office of Economic Development, CITY OF NEW ORLEANS, https://
www.nola.gov/economic-development/ (last visited Nov. 17, 2017).
119. See Mohamed A. El-Erian, Why Advanced Economies Need to Learn from Develop-
ing Nations, BLOOMBERG VIEW (July 11, 2016),https://www.bloomberg.com/view/arti
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 20 7-MAR-18 14:54
cles/2016-07-11/why-advanced-economies-need-to-learn-from-developing-nations
[https://perma.cc/J686-DRYE].
120. See id. Applied to developed countries, the definition of economic development,
introduced in the previous section, could be adjusted to “the process of the structural
transformation of an economy to one generating higher productivity and increases in
income for the majority of populations” (without the reference to “one based primarily
on the production of primary products,” because developed countries are not such econ-
omies). I also offer a discussion on the possible legal and institutional approaches to
address economic problems in the United States in my forthcoming article, Law and
Economic Development in the United States: Toward a New Paradigm (on file with the
author).
121. For a further observation on this point, see supra note 117. R
122. See, e.g., Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, 15 U.S.C.
§§ 3101– 52; and Jobs and Growth Act, S.C. 2012, c 31 (Can.).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 21 7-MAR-18 14:54
123. For example, the U.S. federal government supported $110.6 billion in aid for
relief, recovery and rebuilding efforts in the Gulf Coast of Louisiana following the Hurri-
cane Katrina. See DEP’T ST., Hurricane Katrina: What Government Is Doing, http://
www.state.gov/documents/organization/150082.pdf [https://perma.cc/YC68-TNGE].
By contrast, a relatively modest amount, $350 million of the federal aid, has been spent
on the bankrupt city of Detroit. See Harkness, supra note 116. R
124. This is generally the case except small-scaled support for “economically
depressed areas” provided by the EDA under the authority of Public Works and Eco-
nomic Development Act (PWEDA). 42 U.S.C. § 3161. In 2016, the EDA supported 649
development projects for the total grant of 261 million, averaging around 400,000 per
project. EDA, 2016 Annual Report (2016), https://www.eda.gov/annual-reports/fy2016/
[https://perma.cc/GY9G-YWWZ].
125. The local and regional governments may provide incentives in the form of tax
reduction or exemptions, but the finances of many regional and local governments may
not be strong enough to afford meaningful tax relief and other concessions in lieu of
direct subsidy payments. For a relevant discussion on the insufficient state budget, see
Lucy Dadayan & Donald J. Boyd, By The Numbers: 2016: Another Lackluster Year for State
Tax Revenue, ROCKEFELLER INST. GOV’T (May 2017), http://www.rockinst.org/pdf/gov-
ernment_finance/2017-05-08-By-numbers-brief-no9.pdf [https://perma.cc/6BUZ-
QSVF].
126. See discussion infra Part III C. See generally PETER J. BOETTKE & PETER T. LEESON,
THE ECONOMIC ROLE OF THE STATE (2015); Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and the Economic
Role of the State in the New Millennium, 12 INDUS. & CORP. CHANGE 3 (2003); and George
J. Stigler & Paul A. Samuelson, A Dialogue on the Proper Role of the State (Grad. Sch. Bus.,
U. Chicago Selected Papers No. 7, 1968).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 22 7-MAR-18 14:54
A. Regulatory Design
The first analytical step in assessing regulatory impact is the analysis
of law’s design (regulatory design) with respect to a particular development
objective, such as economic growth.127 The analysis of regulatory design
begins with the assessment of anticipated policy outcomes, the first of the
three sub-elements as introduced above.
common law rule that denies damages for ameliorative waste (an improve-
ment to an estate that changes its character) advancing the policy of
encouraging improvements on land and economic development.131
Anticipated policy outcomes are the specific outcomes that are antici-
pated as a result of the implementation of such policies. In the first exam-
ple, the increase in trade and economic growth would be the anticipated
policy outcome,132 and, in the subsequent examples, the improvement of
gender equality and the increased improvements on land would be the
anticipated policy outcomes. The explicit regulatory objectives stated in
laws do not always identify anticipated policy outcomes nor does the legis-
lature otherwise make them clear.133 Regardless of pronounced regulatory
objectives, objective assessment identifies policy outcomes, often aided by
the methods of social sciences as further discussed below. A study has
indicated that laws may cause a variety of transformations (anticipated
policy outcomes) beyond their explicit purposes (regulatory objectives).134
The anticipated policy outcome is analyzed with references made to
the theories and analytics of relevant social sciences, which, depending on
the type of development objective pursued, may include economics, sociol-
ogy, political science, anthropology, and development studies. Reference is
also made to their methodologies,135 including those adopted in the Regu-
latory Impact Analysis (RIA).136 In adopting a social science analysis, con-
sideration should be given to its imprecise nature; since social sciences
131. Id. For further discussion, see Thomas W. Merrill, Melms v. Pabst Brewing Co.
and the Doctrine of Waste in American Property Law, 94 MARQ. L. REV. 1055 (2011).
132. Following the implementation of the United States– Korea Free Trade Agreement,
trade between the United States and Korea increased by $23.5 billion between 2011 and
2015. See United States Trade Representative (USTR), Fact Sheet: Four Year Snapshot:
The U.S. Korea Free Trade Agreement (Mar. 2016), https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-
offices/press-office/fact-sheets/2016/March/Four-Year-Snapshot-KORUS [https://
perma.cc/CS7L-XEZF].
133. See Rittich, supra note 22, at 212– 13. R
134. Id. at 216.
135. Those methodologies include statistical and econometrical methods. The latter
often adopts a regression analysis, which is a statistical process for estimating the rela-
tionships among independent and dependent variables. For further discussion, see gen-
erally Angus Deaton, Data and Econometric Tools for Development Analysis, in 3
HANDBOOK OF DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS 1785 (J. Behrman & T.N. Srinivasan eds.,
1995); and David A. Freedman, STATISTICAL MODELS: THEORY AND PRACTICE (2009).
136. An RIA is a process for identifying and assessing the expected effects of regula-
tory proposals. It adopts relevant analytical methods such as benefit/cost analysis. For
further discussion, see generally Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Develop-
ment [OECD], INTRODUCTORY HANDBOOK FOR UNDERTAKING REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS
(RIA), VERSION 1.0 (Oct. 2008), http://www.oecd.org/gov/regulatory-policy/
44789472.pdf [https://perma.cc/MBZ3-EPTW]. For further discussion of RIAs, see
generally Robert W. Hahn, Jason K. Burnett, Yee-Ho I. Chan, Elizabeth A. Mader, &
Petrea R. Moyle, Assessing Regulatory Impact Analyses: The Failure of Agencies to Comply
with Executive Order 12,866, 23 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL’Y 859 (2000); Thomas O.
McGarity, Regulatory Analysis and Regulatory Reform, 65 TEX. L. REV. 1243 (1987); Clau-
dio M. Radaelli, The Diffusion of Regulatory Impact Analysis: Best Practice or Lesson-Draw-
ing?, 43 EUR. J. POL. RES. 723 (2004); and Jacopo Torriti & Ragnar E. Löfstedt, The First
Five Years of the EU Impact Assessment System: A Risk Economics Perspective on Gaps
between Rationale and Practice, 15 J. RISK RES. 169 (2012).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 24 7-MAR-18 14:54
137. For example, using the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model, the USITC
estimated that trade between the United States and Korea would increase after the imple-
mentation of the U.S.-Korea FTA. Specifically, the USITC estimated that merchandise
exports to Korea would increase by $9.7 to 10.9 billion once the FTA is fully imple-
mented, merchandise imports from Korea would increase by $6.4 to 6.9 billion, reduc-
ing the U.S. trade deficit against Korea by $2.8 billion to 4.5 billion. See USITC, supra
note 129, at xvii. With the implementation of the FTA in March, 2012, U.S.-Korea trade R
indeed increased by $12 billion between 2011 and 2015, but the U.S. trade deficit with
Korea did not decrease as estimated, but actually increased by $14.4 billion between
2011 and 2016, showing the inexact nature of the earlier assessment. See USTR, 2017
Trade Policy Agenda and 2016 Annual Report, https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/
reports/2017/AnnualReport/Chapter%20III%20-%20Bilat-
eral%20Trade%20Agreements.pdf [https://perma.cc/E986-QQDZ].
138. Development economists, such as Rosenstein-Rodan, Mandelbaum, Lewis, Ros-
tow, Kuznets, Gerschenkron, Hirschman, and Kindleberger, advocated the state-led
development strategy as the key to development, although they did not exactly agree on
how the state should lead economic growth. For example, Rosenstein-Rodan supported
the “big push,” which is a coordinated investment program across the board (“balanced
growth theory”). By contrast, Hirschman advocated a policy of promoting a few key
sectors with strong linkages to other sectors (“unbalanced growth theory”). See Paul
Krugman, The Rise and Fall of Development Economics, http://web.mit.edu/krugman/
www/dishpan.html [https://perma.cc/ZD5Y-89CQ]; see also Pranab Bardhan, Econom-
ics of Development and the Development of Economics, 7 J. ECON. PERS. 129 (1993) (dis-
cussing the contribution made by development economists). This period of
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 25 7-MAR-18 14:54
“development economics” coincides with the first law and development movement. For
a discussion of the first law and development movement, see supra Part I A.
139. See Newton, supra note 2, at 182. R
140. For an explanation of the neoliberal approach, see supra note 46. R
141. See Williamson, supra note 53 for an explanation of the “Washington Consen- R
sus,” which forms the basis of the neoliberal approach.
142. For a discussion of Chile’s economic development, see supra note 76. R
143. This observation, however, is subject to the criticism that nearly all major sectors
of the Chilean economy owe their existence to state intervention under the Pinochet
regime. See James M. Cypher, Is Chile a Neoliberal Success?, DOLLARS & SENSE: REAL
WORLD ECONOMICS (Sept.– Oct. 2004), [https://perma.cc/D4Q6-GMUB]. See also Ron-
ald J. Gibson & Curtis J. Milhaupt, Economically Benevolent Dictators: Lessons for Devel-
oping Democracies, 59 AM. J. COMP. L. 227 (2011).
144. State-led development refers to the development approach adopted by a “develop-
mental state” that assumes the key role for economic development and “creates [eco-
nomic development] plans, relocate[s] surplus, combat[s] resistance, invest[s] and
manage[s] key sectors, and control[s] foreign capital.” Trubek and Santos, supra note
47, at 5. Perhaps an exception among the NICs is Hong Kong, which is known to have R
adopted a laissez-faire economic policy with minimal government involvement. In con-
trast, Catherine Schenk suggested that this perception was a myth. She argued that the
government subsidized industry indirectly through public housing, which restrained
rise in the cost of living that would have threatened Hong Kong’s labor-cost advantage in
manufacturing. See Catherine Schenk, Economic History of Hong Kong, EH.NET ENCYCLO-
PEDIA (Mar. 16, 2008), http://eh.net/encyclopedia/economic-history-of-hong-kong/
[https://perma.cc/2Q93-J5KM].
145. For a discussion of the successful economic development of the NICs, see supra
note 75. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 26 7-MAR-18 14:54
146. The early stages of economic development, which should be distinguished from
Rostow’s five stages of economic growth, refers to the initial state of economic develop-
ment with the characteristics of over-dependency on primary industries (non-manufac-
turing industries), low-level industrialization, and low per-capita income, as compared
to the later stages of economic development referring to the more advanced economic
state with sustained economic growth, industrialization, and higher (mid-level) per cap-
ita income. Per capita income is used to classify economies into different groups; as of
November 2017, the World Bank defined low-income economies as those with a gross
national income (GNI) per capita of $1005 or less; lower middle-income economies, a
GNI per capita between $1006 and $3955; upper middle-income economies, a GNI per
capita between $3956 and $12,235; and high-income economies, a GNI per capita of
$12,236 or more. World Bank, Data: Country and Lending Groups, http://data.world
bank.org/about/country-and-lending-groups [https://perma.cc/DTD7-VSQ6].
147. The public choice theory and the rent-seeking idea associated with government
failures, adopted by the neoliberal policy analytic, would lead to this conclusion.
148. See Dani Rodrik, Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century 15 (JOHN F. KEN-
NEDY SCH. GOV’T, Harv. U. Faculty Research Working Papers Series, RWP04-047, 2004),
https://www.sss.ias.edu/files/pdfs/Rodrik/Research/industrial-policy-twenty-first-cen
tury.pdf [https://perma.cc/JU5K-6M49].
149. See id. at 6; see also KATHARINA PISTOR & PHILIP A. WELLONS, THE ROLE OF LAW
AND LEGAL INSTITUTIONS IN ASIAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, 1960– 1995 (1999).
150. See LEE, supra note 54, at 305– 09. Several scholars, including Dani Rodrik, R
Charles Sabel, Sanjay Reddy, and Ricardo Hausmann, also emphasized the importance
of public-private partnership to develop strategies and make investment choices for eco-
nomic development. See also Trubek, supra note 3, at 6. R
151. See supra note 144 (for an explanation of the developmental state). R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 27 7-MAR-18 14:54
that of the contemporary private sector, influence policy outcome that law
is anticipated to deliver in the context of development. As noted above, a
law focusing on the state’s facilitation of development can be more effective
in the early stages of economic development, when the relative capability
and institutional strength of the government is superior to those of the
underdeveloped private sector.152 By contrast, a law focusing on privatiza-
tion and deregulation could be more effective in the later stages of eco-
nomic development when the private sector has acquired institutional
strength and experiences, as demonstrated by the successful policy transi-
tion in the NICs.153 Economics also began to recognize the complimentary
roles of the state and the market, providing support for this type of
policy.154
152. It may not be the case that the state is more capable than the private sector in all
of the countries at the early stages of economic development. Multinational enterprises
running businesses in these countries could also be effective, but their contributions to
the economic development of the host countries could be limited due to potential incon-
sistencies between their (global) corporate interests and the long-term development
interests of the host countries.
153. See PISTOR & WELLONS, supra note 149, at 110– 11. R
154. Michael Trebilcock observed a changing trend in development economics. He
stated,
[b]y the late 1990s, the consensus in development economics had shifted dra-
matically. The Washington Consensus was agreed to have often been a fail-
ure . . . . A more promising approach is represented by the New Development
Economics (NDE) which eschews truisms such as “getting institutions right”
and represents a break with big-picture paradigms that advance one-size-fits-all
solutions . . . . Drawing on the neoclassical paradigm, it recognizes that markets
are not nearly as inefficient as the early structuralists believed; rather the funda-
mental principle of rational responses to incentives continues to organize eco-
nomic behavior. Further, with the rise of the New Institutional Economics,
[which emphasizes legal institutions as a major factor for economic development
(see North, supra note 7)], the distinction between government and markets has R
become blurred— each operating via similar fundamental mechanisms. As such,
NDE advocates a complementary role for governments and markets, finding
both to be susceptible to failures in coordination, imperfect information, and
agency problems.
Michael Trebilcock, Between Theories of Trade and Development: The Future of the World
Trading System 8– 9 (University of Toronto Law Working Paper Series No. 2014– 10,
2014).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 28 7-MAR-18 14:54
160. See id. at 8 n. 36. These areas include property rights (including intellectual
property rights), political governance, the regulatory framework for business transac-
tions, state industrial promotion, public health and the environment, taxation, corporate
governance, competition law, banking and financing, labor, corruption, the criminaliza-
tion of economic offences, and the international legal framework (i.e., international eco-
nomic law and international development law). In the original article, id., the legal
system as well as compliance and enforcement were also included among these areas,
but their impact on development is analyzed in this Article under the context of the
general theory. An assessment will be made as to whether it is still necessary to perform
a separate analysis under the ADM.
161. These countries may include the NICs, Chile, Spain, and others undergoing suc-
cessful economic development in recent decades, such as China, Vietnam, and Rwanda.
For a discussion of the successful development of these countries, see LEE, supra note 54, R
chs. 1.4, 10; RICARDO FRENCH DAVIS, ECONOMIC REFORMS IN CHILE: FROM DICTATORSHIP TO
DEMOCRACY 1– 28 (2002); World Bank, The Economic Development of Spain (1963), http:/
/documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/764341468782083806/The-economic-develop-
ment-of-Spain [https://perma.cc/B8EF-KHD8]; Bui Tat Thang, After the War: 25 Years of
Economic Development in Vietnam, NIRA REV. (2000), http://www.nira.or.jp/past/publ/
review/2000spring/06thang.pdf [https://perma.cc/8ZFV-DXZU]; and World Bank,
Rwanda Overview, http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/rwanda/overview [https://
perma.cc/G595-NKEP].
162. See Lee, supra note 3, at 29– 35. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 30 7-MAR-18 14:54
163. The ADM also identifies and analyzes key socioeconomic conditions for the
implementation of LFIs. See Lee, supra note 3, at 9. The ADM may present different sets R
of LFIs for a reference, in accordance with the socioeconomic conditions of the host
country, including the country’s stage of economic development.
164. Practitioners and advisors have cautioned against neglecting these differences on
the ground. See, e.g., Thomas W. Waelde & James L. Gunderson, Legislative Reform in
Transition Economies: Western Transplants: A Short-Cut to Social Market Economy Status?,
43 INT’L & COMP. L.Q. 347, 349 (1994).
165. The Qur’an characterizes charging an interest as unfair, as implied by the use of
an Arabic word “zulm” meaning oppression or exploitation. The Qur’an, 2:279. Thus
“Islamic banking,” a banking practice compliant with the rules of Sharia law, has been
developed. For further discussion of Islamic banking, see generally A. ABDUL RAHEEM,
ISLAMIC BANKING: PRINCIPLES, PRACTICES AND PERFORMANCE (2013).
166. See Lee, supra note 3, at 29. R
167. Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 31 7-MAR-18 14:54
168. See supra note 146 (for an explanation of stages of economic development). R
169. As relevant to socioeconomic conditions, Richard Posner opined that precisely
written rules, rather than institutions, such as the working judiciary, that are expensive
to develop or abstract legal standards that require sophisticated legal technique to apply,
are more conductive to economic development in developing countries with limited eco-
nomic resources and weak legal traditions. See Posner, supra note 10, at 2– 10. R
170. See id. at 5– 6 (adopting foreign laws).
171. Uniform Electronic Transactions Act (1999).
172. Securities Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1– 16 (2012).
173. Id. The foregoing analysis of regulatory design is also applicable beyond law and
development and explains regulatory impact generally. For example, France has enacted
a law that bans face covering in public places, including those practiced in Islam religion
such as the burka and the niqab. See Loi 2010– 1192 du 11 octobre 2010 interdisant la
dissimulation du visage dans l’espace public [Law 2010-1192 of October 11, 2010 ban-
ning the covering of one’s face in public], Oct. 11, 2010. The stated regulatory objec-
tives are the enhancement of pubic security and facilitation of minimal social
interactions by prohibiting the concealment of face in public places, and these objectives
are not directly related to development.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 32 7-MAR-18 14:54
B. Regulatory Compliance
This section discusses the second element of the regulatory impact
mechanisms, “regulatory compliance,” which refers to compliance with law
by those who are subject to the application of law. This section also exam-
ines the factors influencing regulatory compliance, some of which are asso-
ciated with historical, economic, cultural, and political conditions that may
largely be immune to top-down attempts at reform174 and some others
associated more directly with state action, such as regulatory enforcement.
Regulatory compliance in the context of law and development does
not mean only the absence of rule violations, but also the knowledge of law
and participation in the processes mandated by law. For example, judicial
reform would not be as effective where only a small minority of a popula-
tion uses the court for dispute resolution.175 Strong regulatory compliance
is an essential precondition to the success of law reform, and a reform that
does not take regulatory compliance into consideration may end up a
hollow declaration without real impact. For this reason, regulatory compli-
ance is one of the key elements in determining regulatory impact on
development.
Regulatory compliance can be classified into general regulatory com-
pliance, which refers to the general level of regulatory compliance in a
given jurisdiction, and specific regulatory compliance, which pertains to a
particular law. In a place where general regulatory compliance is not
strong, regulatory impact on development may generally be weak. But,
Applying the analysis of regulatory design, the anticipated policy outcomes include
the enhancement of public security by facilitating identification of a suspect individual,
although the law’s positive effect on the minimal social interactions would be more con-
troversial. The law is also supported by the effective organization of legal frameworks
and institutions: the law is in the form of legitimate statutory enactment that is effective
throughout France (effective legal framework) and supported by the enforcement of
police and public prosecution that effectively imposes a penalty for a violation (effective
institution).
The law raises further issues with its adaptability to socioeconomic conditions. Even
if the actual number of Muslim population in France wearing full face covering might
not be large, millions of Muslims and non-Muslims in French society nevertheless sup-
port the freedom to engage in this religious practice, resulting in a conflict and division
in French society. See Edward Cody, Tensions flare in France over veil ban, WASH. POST
(Aug. 9, 2012), https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/tensions-flare-in-france-over-
veil-ban/2012/08/08/67b56fc2-e150-11e1-98e7-89d659f9c106_story.html?utm_term=
.2a15a15b3dea [https://perma.cc/C76N-HLYC]. The law’s adaptability to the socioeco-
nomic conditions on the ground (i.e., incompatibility to the religious practice and belief)
is weakened due to this conflict, diminishing the effectiveness of its regulatory design
and regulatory impact. The application of the regulatory design analysis reveals the
weakness of the French law, as demonstrated by widespread resistance to the law.
174. See Davis & Trebilcock, supra note 3, at 920. R
175. This lack of use may be a result of limited access to the court due to the cost of
litigation, absence of the knowledge required to use the court, the physical remoteness of
the court, or cultural reasons, i.e., local residents may prefer to use informal, traditional
venues to resolve disputes. Thus, a recent study indicated the necessity to engage cus-
tomary dispute resolution processes in developing countries. See Paul Zwier, Human
Rights for Women in Liberia (and West Africa): Integrating Formal and Informal Rule of
Law Reforms through the Carter Center’s Community Justice Advisor Project, 10 LAW &
DEV. REV. 187 (2017).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 33 7-MAR-18 14:54
176. H.L.A. Hart also considered that regulatory compliance (“allegiance to the sys-
tem”) may be based on various elements, such as “calculations of long-term self-interest;
disinterested interest in others; an unreflecting inherited or traditional attitude; or the
mere wish to do as others do.” H.L.A. HART, THE CONCEPT OF LAW 203 (1994).
177. Colin B. Picker, International Trade and Development Law: A Legal Cultural Cri-
tique, 4 LAW & DEV. REV. 43, 46 (2011).
178. Id.
179. Id.
180. For a relevant discussion, see Michael Ilg, Profit, Persuasion, and Fidelity: Why
People Follow the Rule of Law, 10 LAW & DEV. REV. 275 (2017).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 34 7-MAR-18 14:54
lic and fit the socioeconomic conditions are more likely to command
strong compliance and active participation by the public. Well-designed
and implemented LFIs in fact have been spread and complied with beyond
their original jurisdictions. For example, the highly-developed Roman law
not only laid the foundation for the Roman Empire, but it remained a work-
ing reference for the development of modern law in Europe and beyond,
centuries after Rome itself perished.181 Also, a vast number of countries in
Asia, Africa, and North America have adopted the modern civil law system,
developed by France and Germany, and the common law system, by
England. Additionally, a number of countries around the world have
adopted and referenced the institutions of the British parliamentary gov-
ernment system and the American presidential system as the standard
forms of modern democratic government. These examples illustrate the
importance of regulatory design and implementation to induce
compliance.
Lastly, the strength of regulatory enforcement also affects general reg-
ulatory compliance. The likelihood of regulatory compliance increases
where a violation is sanctioned with a real penalty, including financial and
penal ones, as a result of regulatory enforcement. Therefore, enforcement
induces compliance, with a threat of a penalty, and enforcement is also an
evaluative criterion for determining the level of the rule of law.182 Enforce-
ment also requires considerable resources and capacity on the part of the
state, such as efficient monitoring, policing, and the appropriate execution
of penalties, which can be an issue for developing countries that lack suffi-
cient personnel, financial resources, and technical expertise. Thus, the
enforcement issue goes to the question of state capacity, which will be dis-
cussed in the next section.
181. For a further discussion of Roman law, see generally Adolf Berger, Encyclopedic
Dictionary of Roman Law (1953); and H.F. Jolowicz, Historical Introduction to the
Study of Roman Law (1996). See also Henry Sumner Maine, Ancient Law: Its Connec-
tion with the Early History of Society, and Its Relation to Modern Ideas 75– 78 (1861).
182. See World Justice Project, Rule of Law Index 2015 (2015), http://worldjus-
ticeproject.org/sites/default/files/roli_2015_0.pdf) [https://perma.cc/HV68-YJJM]. For
´
further discussion of compliance theories and relevant literature review, see Julien Eti-
enne, La Conformation Des Gouvernes, 60 REVUE FRANÇAISE DE SCIENCE POLITIQUE 493
(2010), English version available at http://www.cairn-int.info/article-E_RFSP_603_
0493— compliance-theories.htm [https://perma.cc/TD24-3Z28].
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 35 7-MAR-18 14:54
fit for a group in a population and cause a net loss for another simultane-
ously. For example, traders would generally welcome a free trade
agreement (“FTA”), as the FTA lowers trade barriers, such as customs tar-
iffs, and their costs in trade. For this reason, they would have an interest in
complying with the law necessary for the adoption of the FTA, such as a
statute implementing the FTA. In contrast, domestic producers competing
with the imported products and domestic laborers whose jobs might be
adversely affected by the imports may well oppose the FTA and the domes-
tic law implementing it, as the FTA lowers the cost of imports, thereby mak-
ing competing domestic products less competitive in the domestic market.
To improve specific regulatory compliance in the presence of conflicts of
interests among different groups, a government will endeavor to devise the
implementation of law in such a way as to reduce the perceived loss and
provide compensation to the losing groups.186 However, the government
may not always be “neutral” in this divide, and its ideological orientations
and political preferences also affect the divide and its outcome. For exam-
ple, the government supporting free trade would try to find a way to legis-
late for the FTA despite the perceived loss to a population group.
C. Quality of Implementation
1. Definition and Importance
186. In the cited FTA example, Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) Programs under
the Trade Expansion Act of 1962 and as defined further under the Trade Act of 1974
serve this purpose. See 19 U.S.C. §§ 1911– 1920 and §§ 2341– 2356.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 37 7-MAR-18 14:54
2. State Capacity
187. See Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, Apr. 15,
1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 1C, THE
LEGAL TEXTS: THE RESULTS OF THE URUGUAY ROUND OF MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS
320 (1999), 1869 U.N.T.S. 299, 33 I.L.M. 1197 (1994).
188. See J. Michael Finger, The WTO’s Special Burden on Less Developed Countries, 19
CATO J. 425, 435 (2000).
189. Traditional community forums, rather than state courts, may hear and adjudi-
cate claims based on customary law, as is the case in many underdeveloped regions. See
Zwier, supra note 175. R
190. A state delegates its role of implementation when, for example, it contracts with
a private company to operate a correctional facility. A commentator has also observed a
trend of the “third sectorization of law and policy” in which numerous non-state, non-
market civil organizations such as voluntary associations, NGOs, and religious groups
become independent sources of normative authority. See Rittich, supra note 22, at 223. R
191. For a definition of a state, see supra note 31. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 38 7-MAR-18 14:54
192. Freedom of contract refers to the freedom of individuals and legal persons
(legally recognized entities) including corporations, to form contracts and determine
contractual terms. Freedom of contract is essential to the free market economy. See
David Bernstein, Freedom of Contract (Geo. Mason Univ. Sch. of Law: Law & Econ. Ctr.
Research Paper Series No. 08– 51, 2008).
193. This explains the initial failure and economic confusion after the unprepared
privatization in the former Soviet countries after the fall of communism in the 1980s
where the state lacked the capacity to implement LFIs necessary for the market econ-
omy. For a discussion of the economic difficulty faced by the former Soviet countries,
see William W. Hogan, Economic Reforms in the Sovereign States of the Former Soviet
Union (Brookings Papers on Economic Activity No. 2, 1991), https://www.brookings.
edu/wp-content/uploads/1991/06/1991b_bpea_hogan.pdf [https://perma.cc/KH5J-PZ
XR].
194. See Davis & Trebilcock, supra note 3, at 922– 23. R
195. For a discussion of the Confucian tradition in East Asia, see generally CON-
FUCIAN TRADITIONS IN EAST ASIAN MODERNITY (Tu Wei-Ming ed., 1996).
196. See generally ROY HOFHEINZ, JR. & KENT E. CALDER, THE EAST ASIA EDGE: WHY AN
ENTIRE REGION IS OVERTAKING THE WEST IN TECHNOLOGY, EXPORTS AND MANAGEMENT
(1982); LUCIAN W. PYE, ASIAN POWER AND POLITICS: THE CULTURAL DIMENSIONS OF
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 39 7-MAR-18 14:54
State capacity was also a determining factor for other countries that
successfully accomplished economic development. Germany achieved
remarkable economic development in the late nineteenth century when
Otto von Bismarck adopted state-led developmental policies, aided by sub-
stantially increased state capacity as a result of Germany’s unification.197
A similar development took place in the United States when President Lin-
coln led the Union to victory in the Civil War and stopped the Southern
States’ secession from the Union (an outcome that would have weakened
the state capacity of the United States), followed by North-based industrial-
ization and trade protection for industrial development.198 Generals
Franco and Pinochet also implemented strong state-backed economic
reforms in Spain and Chile, respectively, which paved the path for their
economic development, notwithstanding the authoritarian and repressive
nature of their regimes.199 By contrast, weak states in Africa and Latin
America200 could not successfully implement the LFIs needed for eco-
nomic development for much of the twentieth century.201
State capacity is an overarching factor that is not only essential to the
implementation of law, but also influences the two other elements of the
regulatory impact mechanisms, regulatory design and regulatory compli-
ance. The state’s evaluative and analytical capacity influences regulatory
design, particularly legislation. Its capacity to enforce and raise public
AUTHORITY (1985); and IN SEARCH OF AN EAST ASIAN DEVELOPMENT MODEL (Peter L. Berger
& Hsin-Huang Michael Hsiao eds., 1988).
197. See OTTO PFLANZE, BISMARCK AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF GERMANY, VOLUME II: THE
PERIOD OF CONSOLIDATION, 1871– 1880, at 67– 92, 207– 45 (1990).
198. Henry Clay, Abraham Lincoln’s early mentor, is known to have advocated the
“American System” of trade protection in opposition to what he called the “British Sys-
tem” of free trade, which, he argued, was part of the British imperialist system that con-
signed the United States to the role of primary product exporter. See P. CONKIN,
PROPHETS OF PROSPERITY: AMERICA’S FIRST POLITICAL ECONOMISTS 302 (1980).
199. These policies included the 1959 Spanish Stabilization Plan and Pinochet’s mar-
ket-oriented reforms deliberated in 1973– 75 and implemented afterwards. See Leandro
Prados de la Escosura, Joan Rosés, & Isabel Sanz Villarroya, Stabilisation and Growth
under Dictatorships: Lessons from Franco’s Spain, VOX: CEPR’S POLICY PORTAL (Mar. 22,
2010), http://voxeu.org/article/stabilisation-and-growth-under-dictatorships-new-les-
sons-franco-s-spain [https://perma.cc/GT28-4M7M]; and Robert A. Packenham & Wil-
liam Ratliff, What Pinochet Did for Chile, HOOVER DIGEST (Jan. 30, 2007), http://
www.hoover.org/research/what-pinochet-did-chile [https://perma.cc/2R9J-8QMJ].
200. For further discussion on weak states, see Robert Rotberg, Failed States, Col-
lapsed States, Weak States: Causes and Indicators, in STATE FAILURE AND STATE WEAKNESS
IN A TIME OF TERROR 1 (Robert Rotberg ed., 2003); and Susan E. Rice & Stewart Patrick,
Index of State Weakness in the Developing World, BROOKINGS INST. (Feb. 26, 2008), https:/
/www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/02_weak_states_index.pdf [https:/
/perma.cc/SZ7W-7N6X].
201. However, state capacity should not be confused with the state’s ability and will-
ingness to use or abuse its power. A state being “weak,” lacking the cited key capacities
to meet their development objectives, does not mean that it is completely powerless.
Some of the weak states, as listed in the Index of State Weakness in the Developing
World, were known to use brutal force against their own populations, including torture
and summary executions. See Rice & Patrick, supra note 200. For another account of
the mismatch between “state power” and “state capacity” (in the context of transnational
law enforcement), see Mariano-Florentino Cuéllar, The Mismatch between State Power
and State Capacity in Transnational Law Enforcement, 22 BERKELEY J. INT’L L. 15 (2004).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 40 7-MAR-18 14:54
3. Political Will
202. See, e.g., Frank Holmes, FATCA: Good Intentions, Poor Design, U.S. GLOBAL INVES-
TORS (June 25, 2014), http://www.usfunds.com/investor-library/frank-talk/fatca-good-
intentions-bad-execution/#.V-28rIKQL3g [https://perma.cc/246B-QURS].
203. See, e.g., Cody, supra note 173 (reporting religion-based public resistance to the R
French law that prohibits face covering in public places). A recent study has highlighted
the importance of state capacity to regulatory impact concerning crime control. The
study has concluded that the suppression of sexual and gender-based violence has not
been very effective in Liberia where the government has enacted laws that substantially
increase penalties for these crimes, but the state lacks the capacity to implement these
laws effectively, due to absence of resources to supply sufficient police force,
prosecutorial services, and courts to monitor, prosecute, convict, and punish offenders.
See Zwier supra note 175. The weak state capacity, prevailing in developing countries, R
has resulted in poor regulatory impact. See Rotberg, supra note 200. R
204. For a general definition of political will, see Political will, OXFORD LIVING DICTION-
ARIES, https://en.oxforddictionaries.com/definition/political_will [https://perma.cc/
L3G8-R45Q]. Political will, in the context of development, should be distinguished from
a mere interest in development facilitation, which the leadership of almost every devel-
oping country would have, given the state of their economies. Political will is more than
a mere interest, which may be demonstrated by the continued implementation of consis-
tent development policies for an extended period of time, allocating substantial political
and economic capital.
205. Conversely, successful economic development and improved state capacity, such
as increased financial resources, may also reinforce political will. Initial success can
provide encouragement and motivation for the continuation of a successful development
path, and improved state capacity, such as a larger government budget and development
funds, as well as a larger staff, can generate better conditions under which to carry out
the will.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 41 7-MAR-18 14:54
206. For a discussion of the development of Spain under General Franco and of Chile
under Pinochet, see supra note 76. The East Asian countries also had legendary political R
leaders devoted to national development, such as Park Jung Hee of Korea (1917– 1979),
Chang Kai-shek of Taiwan (1885– 1975), Lee Kuan Yew of Singapore (1923– 2015), and
Deng Xiaoping of China (1904– 1997).
207. See Daekeun Park & Changyong Rhee, Saving, growth, and demographic change in
Korea, 19 J. JAPANESE INT’L ECON. 394, 394– 95, 410 (2005).
208. See ADAM PRZEWORSKI ET AL., DEMOCRACY AND DEVELOPMENT: POLITICAL INSTITU-
TIONS AND WELL-BEING IN THE WORLD 1950– 1990, at 143 (2000).
209. For instance, India, which is considered a democracy, has shown substantial
economic growth in recent decades. Democratized Chile also benefitted from the eco-
nomic reforms completed during the authoritarian regime of Pinochet. For a further
discussion of Chile’s development under the Pinochet regime, see supra note 143. R
210. It took several decades before democratic India could finally embark on sus-
tained economic growth, whereas authoritarian NICs and China achieved much more
rapid economic development.
211. See HA-JOON CHANG, KICKING AWAY THE LADDER: DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY IN HIS-
TORICAL PERSPECTIVE 69– 124 (2002).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 42 7-MAR-18 14:54
information, and the rule of law, which may not be achievable without
economic development in place.
The inherent difficulty with elective democracy does not mean that
dictatorships or authoritarian regimes are the answer; these regimes also
do not automatically generate the political commitment and devotion to
development. The political will necessary for development is not deter-
mined by the length of time when one is in power. Otherwise, a number of
authoritarian regimes and dictatorships still existing would have made pro-
gress in development, but that is not the case. This reality presents a
dilemma— while authoritarian leaders in successful developing countries
have led their countries to decades of successful economic development, a
system of dictatorship or authoritarian governance does not guarantee the
appointment of a “good leader” with the requisite political will.212 There is
no political system that guarantees a leader who will uphold the political
will for development, ready to resist popular demand for short-term eco-
nomic gain in order to meet long-term development objectives. The cited
systematic issues with elective democracies and the uncertainty character-
izing authoritarian regimes are likely a reason that only a small number of
countries have achieved development successfully since the Second World
War.
With a long history of over 5000 years,214 Korea has gone through
treacherous modern times, including a period of colonization by Japan
(1910– 1945), the division of the country into North and South Koreas
(1945), and a major war (the Korean War, 1950– 1953). Despite its ardu-
ous path, the country achieved unprecedented success in development
from the 1960s to the 1990s.215 This part examines Korea’s development
policies and discusses how changes in LFIs affected development in Korea,
applying the analytical elements presented in the preceding discussion.
Korea is chosen for its unique reference value as a “model” develop-
ment case. As of the early 1960s, Korea had much of the characteristics
shared by many developing countries today, such as low per-capita income
causing prevalent poverty, an economy relying heavily on primary, non-
manufacturing industries, low levels of technology and entrepreneurship
in society, insufficient capital, poor endowment of natural resources, over-
population in a relatively small territory, internal political instability, and
external threats to its security.216 Successfully overcoming these unfavora-
ble conditions, Korea’s economy progressed from one relying on low-pro-
ductive primary industries and characterized by absolute poverty in the
1960s to an advanced economy based on large industrial capacity generat-
ing high per-capita income by the mid-1990s.217 The Korean development
process exhibits all major stages of economic development in an easily
traceable time period of three decades, raising its reference value, and suc-
cessful social and political development from authoritarian rule to elective
democracy based on the rule of law by the 1990s.
The examination of Korean development will also fill the gaps in law
and development studies identified by leading scholars. They point out
that law reform projects and development studies have not properly refer-
enced and incorporated the successful development experiences of the East
Asian countries.218 Scholars have emphasized the essential importance of
studying them in the context of law and development,219 and this Article
214. For a history of Korea, see KYUNG MOON HWANG, A HISTORY OF KOREA (2016);
MICHAEL J. SETH, A HISTORY OF KOREA: FROM ANTIQUITY TO THE PRESENT (2010); and
CARTER J. ECKERT, KI-BAIK LEE, YOUNG ICK LEW, MICHAEL ROBINSON, & EDWARD W. WAG-
NER, KOREA OLD AND NEW: A HISTORY (1991).
215. In 1962, Korea’s GNI per capita was mere $120, lower than most other develop-
ing countries in Asia, Africa, and Latin America at the time. As a result of successful
economic development, its GNI increased to $13,040 in 1996, which was a high-income
country category as defined by the World Bank at that time, with income distribution
better than some of the most advanced developed countries, including the United States.
See GNI per capita, Atlas method, WORLD BANK, http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/
NY.GNP.PCAP.CD?end=2014&start=1962&year_low_desc=false [https://perma.cc/
BT6X-5Y6T].
216. As a result, Korea’ per capital GDP grew at only one percent a year prior to 1962.
See KWANG-SUK KIM & JOON-KYUNG PARK, SOURCES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH IN KOREA:
1963– 1982 6 (1985).
217. See supra note 215. R
218. See John Ohnesorge, Developing Development Theory: Law and Development
Orthodoxies and the Northeast Asian Experience, 28 U. PA. J. INT’L ECON. L. 219 (2007);
Trubek, supra note 3; and Newton, supra note 2, at 187. R
219. See Ohnesorge, id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 44 7-MAR-18 14:54
2. Regulatory Design
The primary objective of Korea’s development policies was to relieve
the majority of its population from extreme poverty.221 To meet this objec-
tive, the government sought to develop industries that would generate sus-
tainable income for the majority of its population. The government
adopted export-led development policies, which were necessary to over-
come the constraints of insufficient purchasing power within the domestic
market due to prevalent poverty,222 and focused on developing manufac-
turing industries that utilized the abundant labor which were both edu-
220. For the role of customary law for development, see PETER ØREBECH ET AL., THE
ROLE OF CUSTOMARY LAW IN SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT (2005).
221. See supra note 215. R
222. Empirical studies concluded that exports lead to economic growth under certain
conditions and that export promotion policies are effective in increasing exports. See
Michael Michaely, Exports and Growth: An Empirical Investigation, 4 J. DEV. ECON. 49
(1977); Woo S. Jung & Gyu Lee, The Effectiveness of Export Promotion Policies: The Case
of Korea 122 WELTWIRTSCHAFTLICHES ARCHIV 340 (1986); and Sae Ran Koh & Jai S. Mah,
The Effect of Export Composition on Economic Growth: The Case of Korea, 47 J. DEVELOP-
ING AREAS 171 (2013). See also Pangestu, supra note 77 (discussing an evolution of R
industrial policies of the NICs).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 45 7-MAR-18 14:54
223. The other NICs also adopted this type of export-led, development policies based
on building manufacturing industries, with varying details. For an evolution of indus-
trial policies of the NICs, see Pangestu, supra note 77. R
224. See HISTORY OF ECONOMIC LAWS IN KOREA FROM LIBERATION TO PRESENT, VOLUME 1,
at 216– 27 (Duol Kim ed., 2011).
225. See id. at 222– 27.
226. For a discussion of development economics in the 50s and the 60s, see supra
note 138. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 46 7-MAR-18 14:54
initially uncertain. The Korean government did not have sufficient finan-
cial and industrial resources to implement these policies, and the United
States, the primary aid provider for Korea at the time, reportedly had con-
cerns that its development policies emphasizing the role of the state in
economic development might lead to a socialist development model.227
The latter did not happen, but the government played an essential role in
the economic development initiatives. The government developed and exe-
cuted the Five-Year Economic Development Plans from 1962 to 1996,
which stipulated specific economic-development and industrial-promotion
goals, including target economic growth and export promotion for each of
the five-year terms.228 It also coordinated and supported private sector
activities that were consistent with its development goals through its con-
trol of bank loans and grant of government subsidies.229 The government
supported strategically chosen leading industries, which were likely to
spur growth in other related industries, through various measures, such as
tax incentives, policy loans, favorable exchange rates for exporters, a flexi-
ble import tariff regime that supported exporters, and inducement of social
support for economic development through extensive public campaigns
and education.230
Substantial flexibility and adaptability were other key features of
Korean development policies. The government set its export expansion
and industrial development goals according to what was feasible given the
available resources, technology, and industrial experiences at the time. In
the 1960s, Korea focused on labor-intensive industries, such as textile and
clothing, which did not require large capital or technological resources
unavailable then, and promoted exports of these products to generate
income. The country subsequently transitioned into more advanced and
potentially more profitable industries, such as heavy and chemical indus-
tries in the 1970s and electronics in the 1980s, that required larger capital,
technology, and industrial knowhow, using the resources and experiences
that Korean producers had gained from successful exports.231
The market performance of the supported industries, particularly in
export markets, was a benchmark of success for economic development
efforts. Even if the government took the initiative in economic develop-
ment, with development planning and regulatory support, private sector
227. Lee Jong-Seuk, The Launching of Economic Development Plan (The Half Century of
Korean Economy), E DAILY (May 5, 2005), http://www.edaily.co.kr/news/
news_detail.asp?newsId=01331686576565968&mediaCodeNo=257&OutLnkChk=Y
(Kor.) [https://perma.cc/XMY3-MMTZ].
228. For further details of the Five-Year Plans, see LEE, supra note 54, at 304– 05. R
229. See id. at 305– 09. These subsidies had distributive effects, allocating resources
to those industries considered at the time that would have the strongest growth effect for
the economy, resulting in the high economic growth in the 60s and the 70s. In addition
to this policy, other factors, such as pre-war industrial experience, land reform, the rise
of national firms, administrative quality, and precision in policy targeting, are known to
have contributed to this success. See ALICE H. AMSDEN, ASIA’S NEXT GIANT: SOUTH KOREA
AND LATE INDUSTRIALIZATION (1989).
230. See LEE, supra note 54, at 305– 13. R
231. See id. at 303– 05.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 47 7-MAR-18 14:54
232. See generally SOCIALIST MODELS OF DEVELOPMENT (Charles K. Wilber & Kenneth
P. Jameson eds., 1982).
233. For further discussion of the socialist market economy, see CHINA’S TRANSITION
TO A SOCIALIST MARKET ECONOMY (Osman Suliman ed., 1998).
234. World Bank, GNI per capita, supra note 215. According to the Bank of Korea, R
Korea’ GNI per capita in 1962 (nominal USD) was even lower, at $91. Bank of Korea,
Economic Statistics System, http://ecos.bok.or.kr/ [https://perma.cc/Q7KR-QL6L].
235. As a result of successful economic development, the Korean economy grew at the
remarkable rate of 8.75 percent on average per annum from 1991 to 1996, the highest
among the NICs. See Feenstra, Inklaar, & Timmer, supra note 75. R
236. See World Bank, GNI per capita (current USD), supra note 215. The interna- R
tional community recognized Korea’s remarkable economic success, and as a result,
Korea became the second Asian country to host the Olympic Games in 1988.
237. The analysis of the anticipated policy outcome also explains the change of eco-
nomic conditions in Korea after 1996; after a long period of unprecedented economic
growth and prosperity, Korea faced a financial crisis in 1997, caused by a short-term
shortage of foreign exchanges. Unable to resolve this crisis, Korea requested a bailout
from the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and the latter, in return for the bailout,
demanded neoliberal changes in policies and law which would reduce the role of the
state in the economy, more so than the government had been implementing since the
1980s. Korea was compelled to accept this demand to avoid national default, but the
policy outcome that the demanded changes attempted to deliver, such as one to balance
the financial market through hikes in interest rates, was not consistent with the decades
of economic management and practices in Korea that supported a substantial number of
firms with short-term loans on a rolling basis. These abrupt changes demanded by the
IMF caused over 3000 companies to fail and millions to lose jobs, reduced industrial
investments, and lowered economic growth, which have never recovered to the pre-crisis
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 48 7-MAR-18 14:54
level. For further discussion of the financial crisis in Korea and in other Asian countries
in the 1990s, see KHAN, supra note 50. R
238. For an explanation of a civil law system, see supra note 63. R
239. The other major codes include the criminal code, the civil procedure code, the
criminal procedure code, and the administrative code.
240. See LEE, supra note 54, at 313. R
241. See id.
242. See id. at 307– 08.
243. See id. at 312.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 49 7-MAR-18 14:54
3. Regulatory Compliance
In 1996, by the time Korea’s development era was being ended, Korea
marked the percentile rank of 71.4 (0 to 100) for the rule of law assessment
by the World Bank.247 Assuming the validity of this rating, it indicates a
relatively high level of general regulatory compliance, without which the
rule of law would not be feasible. At least in part, Korea’s political and
cultural tradition explains its strength of regulatory compliance. In the
Confucian tradition shared by Korea and other East Asian countries, the
state is responsible for the wellbeing of its subjects, and the citizens, in
turn, perceived their compliance with policies and laws that the state set
up to meet this obligation, as a political and moral duty.248 Additionally,
the colonial government of Japan (1910– 1945) and the subsequent author-
itarian regimes, which sought to control the Korean population with strict
rules of law, imposed severe penalties for any violation, and thus com-
pelled regulatory compliance,249 even though it was passive compliance
due to fear of penalty.250
The Korean government was able to turn this passive compliance into
active compliance. Aided by the early success of its initial development
policies, the government was able to instill confidence in its citizens that
they could escape poverty by trusting the government and cooperating
with one another. Specifically, Koreans actively complied with develop-
ment-facilitating laws and policies, such as encouraging savings by offer-
ing high interest rates and promoting strong work ethics which was
subsequently compensated by rising wages and increased employment
244. HISTORY OF ECONOMIC LAWS IN KOREA FROM LIBERATION TO PRESENT, supra note
224, at 15. The ruling party supporting the government maintained the majority in the R
Korean legislature until 1988, and this legislative control enabled the government to
make timely legislative adjustments and new enactments.
245. Id. at 15– 16.
246. Id. at 16– 17.
247. WORD BANK, Worldwide Governance Indicators, http://info.worldbank.org/gover
nance/wgi/index.aspx#reports [https://perma.cc/P37N-M5LF].
248. For a discussion of the Confucian tradition in East Asia, see supra note 195. R
249. Control was tighter in the political area in an effort to prevent direct challenges
to the regime. For a relevant discussion, see MARTIN HART-LANDSBERG, THE RUSH TO
DEVELOPMENT: ECONOMIC CHANGE AND POLITICAL STRUGGLE IN KOREA (1993).
250. See supra Part III B.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 50 7-MAR-18 14:54
251. In 1993, Korea’s average annual working hours and savings rate were as high as
2656 hours and 34.0 percent, respectively. OECD, Hours Worked, OECD Data, https://
data.oecd.org/emp/hours-worked.htm [https://perma.cc/D34D-YQ8C] and Park
Daekeun & Changyong Rhee, A Study on the Savings Rates in Korea: Synthetic Cohort
Analysis, KOREA INSTITUTE OF PUBLIC FINANCE RESEARCH REPORT (May 1997).
252. The illiteracy rate in Korea was 4.1 percent in 1958. See National Archives of
Korea, The Path that Hangul (Korean Alphabet) Waked on, http://theme.archives.go.kr/
next/hangeulPolicy/business. (Kor.) [https://perma.cc/94VK-GUAE].
253. Korea’s Gini co-efficient, which shows income distribution, was 0.28– 0.29 in the
90s (based on the disposable income), which was lower (i.e. better income distribution)
than most other countries such as the United States (0.34).
254. However, this sense of partnership has been weakened since the late 1990s
because the growth of large corporations (“Chaebols”) has not been translated into the
growth of national economy, employment, and household income, as was the case from
the 60s to the 80s.
255. For a discussion of these codes, see supra note 239. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 51 7-MAR-18 14:54
261. The number increased to over 315,000 in 1965. See National Index System,
Annual Public Official Status, http://www.index.go.kr/potal/main/EachDtlPageDetail.do
?idx_cd=1016 (Kor.) [https://perma.cc/5DTH-X69W].
262. Dr. Nam Duk Woo, a former Minister of EPB from 1974 to 1978 is a good exam-
ple of Korea’s elite bureaucrat. Dr. Woo was initially an academic with a doctorate train-
ing in the United States and subsequently led Korea’s economic success after joining the
administration under Park.
263. For further discussion of the development of administration in Korea, see supra
note 214. R
264. Korea was not free of corruption of its government officials, just as many other
developing countries, during the period of its development. The difference lied in the
extent of corruption, rather than its existence, which was not extensive enough to over-
turn the successful process of development. The situation of corruption improved in
Korea when the government was able to offer public officials improved salaries as a
result of economic development and the improved government budget. The process of
political democratization, which took place in the 90s, also made public officials more
accountable to the public and deterred corruption.
265. See LEE, supra note 54, at 313. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 53 7-MAR-18 14:54
economic paradigm in Korea to one that emphasizes on the role of the private sector. In
contrast, an expert cited that the reduced government oversight in the economy resulted
from the dissolution of the EPB was a cause of the 1997 financial crisis. See Lee Tae
Hee, Issues and Solutions at the Time of the IMF, THE HANKYOREH, Dec. 17, 1997, 3 (Kor.).
272. President Kim Dae Joong continued with neoliberal economic reforms that
reduced government’s control of the economy and strengthened the private sector’s
autonomy, including a neoliberal labor reform that relaxed the legal preconditions to
dismissal. The IMF required these reforms as a condition for its bailout package for
Korea. The package was imperative for Korea to recover from the financial crisis, but
after the reforms, Korea’s economic growth slowed down to approximately four percent
per annum and never returned to its pre-crisis level. For a discussion of Korea’s finan-
cial crisis and the IMF conditionalities, see KHAN, supra note 50, at 60– 75. R
273. The analysis has also shown how changes in LFIs, particularly in the aftermath
of the financial crisis in the 1990s, have affected development and economic perform-
ance. See supra note 237. There is also a contrasting observation that the function R
served by law was limited in the development of Korea because there were fewer courts,
lawyers, and institutions promoting Western-style legal learning during Korea’s develop-
ment periods from the 1960s to the 1980s. Y.H. Jung, How Did Law Matter for Korean
Economic Development?: Evidence from 1970s, paper prepared for the Korean Economic
Association Conference (June 2012). As seen from the preceding discussion, there is a
sufficient scope for considering the role of law in Korean economic development in con-
junction with its institutional arrangements, since the government meticulously legis-
lated all of the major development policies during the development era and implemented
them by legal means.
274. As shown in the preceding part, regulatory impact mechanisms are also applica-
ble beyond law and development and can be adopted to explain regulatory impact gener-
ally. See supra notes 173 and 203. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 55 7-MAR-18 14:54
275. Scholars may have known these elements implicitly, but it is necessary to formu-
late them in a theoretical framework to explain systematically the causal mechanisms
between law and development. Regulatory impact (Ir) can be described as a function of
regulatory design (Dr), regulatory compliance (Cr), and quality of implementation (Qi): Ir
= f(Dr, Cr, Qi). This Article has also discussed the impact of development on law albeit
briefly and advanced additional elements, such as “regulatory adjustment” and “regula-
tory reinforcement” to explain this impact. See discussion supra Part III A.
276. See also Rachel Kleinfeld, Competing Definitions of the Rule of Law, in PROMOTING
THE RULE OF LAW ABROAD, supra note 25, at 56– 59. R
277. See Trubek & Santos, supra note 47, at 3. R
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 56 7-MAR-18 14:54
East Asian countries278 lies in the fact that, throughout much of their
development periods from the 1960s to the 1980s, these countries
achieved remarkable economic development under authoritarian regimes
adopting state-led development. This outcome seems to defy the liberal
propositions of Max Weber and Friedrich Hayek279 as well as the
neoliberal market prescriptions. As to the governance issue, what is identi-
fied as social development, including democratic governance, varies
according to the time and place and is influenced by cultural orientation,
tradition, and socioeconomic constraints in place.280 The resource con-
straints and poverty issues that still prevail in many developing countries
create practical difficulties in fostering both economic and social develop-
ment simultaneously and with equal strength. Thus, each developing
country needs to decide how to sequence and prioritize different develop-
ment goals in accordance with its own needs, preferences, and available
resources.
History has shown that increased individual economic capacity
obtained as a result of successful economic development tends to create
internal pressure for a more democratic and representative form of govern-
ment. For example, East Asian countries, such as Korea and Taiwan, priori-
tized economic development in the 1960s and 1970s. However, once they
achieved a substantial level of economic development by the 1980s, they
embarked on democratic reforms in response to strong public demand.281
This process of “democratization” after successful economic development
also occurred in other countries, such as Spain and Chile, suggesting that
economic development tends to spur social development.282
The preceding discussions enable us to address a key question that
has been raised and debated for decades: “Does law matter for develop-
ment?”283 Classical thinkers such as Weber and Hayek advocated for the
relevance and importance of formal and rational laws that afford predict-
278. See Ohnesorge, supra note 218, at 282– 83; and Trubek, supra note 3, at 4. R
279. For further discussion of their propositions, see supra Part I A.
280. See discussion supra Part II B.
281. For a relevant discussion, see HART-LANDSBERG, supra note 249; LIQUIN CAO, R
LANYING HUANG & IVAN Y. SUN, POLICING IN TAIWAN: FROM AUTHORITARIANISM TO DEMOC-
RACY (2014); and ALAN M. WACHMAN, TAIWAN: NATIONAL IDENTITY AND DEMOCRATIZATION
(1994). By contrast, the 1989 student protest in China, at a time when the country was
still in the early stages of economic development, did not lead to social and political
transformation.
282. Trubek recounted that the transition from economic growth to democracy and
protection of individual rights did not occur by the 1970s. He described how reformers
saw the possibility that legalism, instrumentalism, and authoritarianism might form a
stable amalgam so that their efforts to improve economic law and lawyering could
strengthen authoritarian rule. See David Trubek, The “Rule of Law” in Development Assis-
tance: Past, Present, and Future, in THE NEW LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, supra
note 1, at 79. Still, the transition did occur by the 1990s in successful developing coun- R
tries, such as the NICs, Spain, and Chile; the length of time before the transition could
take place was perhaps longer than the reformers had initially expected.
283. This question is whether or not law affects development. It should be distin-
guished from an inquiry about whether law should be considered to be an end in itself
or an objective of development. See Kennedy, supra note 1, at 157. For the latter ques- R
tion, see supra Part II B, on the identification of social development.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\50-3\CIN302.txt unknown Seq: 57 7-MAR-18 14:54