Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Platform Strategy

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 241
At a glance
Powered by AI
The key takeaways are that platform businesses harness network effects to grow, but require learning new management rules compared to traditional businesses.

A platform business facilitates interactions between two or more interdependent groups and exhibits network effects, with a focus on growing a platform-powered ecosystem.

The main stages of developing a platform business discussed in the book are design, ignition, scaling up, and reaching maturity.

Platform Strategy

During the last decade, platform businesses such as Uber, Airbnb, Amazon
and eBay have been taking over the world. In almost every sector, traditional
businesses are under attack from digital disrupters that are effectively harnes-
sing the power of communities. But what exactly is a platform business and
why is it different?
In Platform Strategy, Laure Claire Reillier and Benoit Reillier provide a
practical guide for digital entrepreneurs and executives to understand what
platforms are, how they work and how you can build one successfully.
Using their own “rocket model” and original case studies (including Google,
Apple, Amazon), they explain how designing, igniting and scaling a plat-
form business requires learning a whole new set of management rules. Platform
Strategy also offers many fascinating insights into the future of platforms,
their regulation and governance, as well as how they can be combined with
other business models.
Laure Claire Reillier and Benoit Reillier are co-founders of Launchworks,
a leading advisory firm focused on helping organizations develop and scale
innovative business models.
Laure Claire Reillier has worked for a number of high-growth start-ups
and established tech firms. Before co-founding Launchworks, Laure Claire was
a senior executive at eBay Europe. She studied computer sciences and tele-
communications at Telecom SudParis (France) and holds an MBA from
the London Business School.
Benoit Reillier has been advising the management teams of platforms and
digital and technology companies for the past 20 years. He studied informa-
tion systems, management and telecommunications at Telecom Management
and economics and competition law at King’s College, London. He holds
MBAs from both Columbia University in New York City and London Business
School.
Platform Strategy

How to Unlock the Power of Communities


and Networks to Grow Your Business

Laure Claire Reillier


and Benoit Reillier
First published 2017
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2017 Laure Claire Reillier and Benoit Reillier
The right of Laure Claire Reillier and Benoit Reillier to be identified as authors of
this work has been asserted by them in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or
utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known
or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information
storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered
trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation without intent
to infringe.
British Library Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
A catalog record has been requested for this book

ISBN: 978-1-4724-8024-8 (hbk)


ISBN: 978-1-315-59894-9 (ebk)

Typeset in Bembo and Gill Sans


by Florence Production Ltd, Stoodleigh, Devon, UK
To the memory of Philippe Reillier
Contents

List of figures viii


List of tables x
About the authors xi
Preface xiii
Acknowledgements xvii

1 Introduction to platform businesses 1


2 The meteoric rise of platform businesses 11
3 What is a platform business? 21
4 Economic characteristics of platforms 31
5 Platforms as business models 41
6 Platform-powered ecosystems 57
7 Life stages of platforms: design 73
8 Platform ignition: proving the concept 91
9 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 105
10 Platform maturity: defending profitable growth 121
11 Platform pricing 137
12 Trust, governance and brand 153
13 Platforms, regulation and competition 173
14 Competing against platforms 193
15 The future of platforms 205

A word from the authors 216


Index 217
Figures

1.1 Airbnb global listing growth 2


2.1 Digital transformation from linear to non-linear 12
2.2 Platform-powered businesses in top 10 FT Global 500 (market cap) 13
2.3 Platform companies by region 14
2.4 The top 10 most valuable brands in the world 15
2.5 Private value of platform-powered unicorn start-ups 16
4.1 Network effects 34
5.1 The linear firm 42
5.2 Michael Porter’s value chain (1985) 43
5.3 The business model canvas 44
5.4 The rocket model 46
6.1 Amazon’s main business lines 59
6.2 Relative growth of Amazon retail vs Amazon marketplace 60
6.3 Apple’s main business lines 64
6.4 Split of Apple’s hardware vs services revenues 65
6.5 Apple App Store billings vs Hollywood US box office revenues 66
6.6 Google’s main business lines 68
7.1 The main life stages of a platform 74
7.2 Pre-launch rocket questions 77
7.3 Direct vs indirect platforms 81
8.1 Ignition rocket questions to achieve platform fit 92
9.1 Scaling-up the rocket to reach critical mass 106
9.2 User and producer acquisition sources 109
10.1 Defending platform position and growing profitably 122
10.2 Assessing platform changes on users and producers 129
12.1 Trust survey 154
12.2 The trust bank 155
12.3 The 7Cs of trust 157
12.4 BlaBlaCar driver profile 158
Figures ix

12.5 eBay star system 160


13.1 NYC taxi medallion prices (2004–2015) 179
13.2 Google’s proposed search page during negotiations 184
13.3 Uber banner appearing in Google Maps mobile searches 185
14.1 Denial 195
Tables

1.1 Comparison of the largest hotel groups vs Airbnb 3


1.2 Examples of digital platforms 5
2.1 High-level typology of sharing economy platforms 17
3.1 Simplified typology of platform and non-platform business models 27
5.1 Economic strengths and weaknesses of selected business models 53
6.1 Amazon’s ecosystem 60
6.2 Apple’s ecosystem 64
6.3 Google’s ecosystem 69
7.1 Rocket life stages 75
7.2 Hilton’s value proposition 82
7.3 Deconstructing value propositions for multisided businesses 82
7.4 Airbnb’s value propositions 83
8.1 Examples of performance metrics at platform ignition 101
9.1 Illustrative value proposition for a scaling product marketplace 113
9.2 Mapping interactions between participants – eBay illustration 116
9.3 Examples of performance metrics at platform scaling 117
10.1 Upwork’s new sliding fee structure 126
10.2 Examples of performance metrics at platform maturity 127
11.1 Seller fee examples 146
11.2 Matching platform objectives with pricing levers and examples 150
13.1 Selected Google services and some competitors’ services by year
of launch 181
About the authors

Benoit Reillier is managing director and co-founder of


Launchworks and specializes in helping businesses design
and execute winning strategies to harness the power of
communities and platform ecosystems. For the last 20 years
he has been working for and advising the boards and top
management teams of many blue-chip companies, as well
as regulators and governments.
Prior to founding Launchworks, Benoit was director
at the management consulting firm KPMG, where he
focused on strategic assignments for telecommunications,
media and technology (TMT) clients globally. He was
previously TMT practice director of expert firm LECG Europe (now FTI), and
also worked as business development director of Telia Mobile International UK,
the leading Nordic telecommunications group.
Throughout his career, Benoit has had the opportunity to work on and lead
key strategic assignments that shaped the communications, payments and
technology sectors. He participated in large-scale strategic assignments for a
number of Fortune 100 companies and provided expert advice on several
multibillion-dollar transactions, high-stakes litigations and arbitrations.
Benoit started his career working for the French government as a special advisor
on telecom-related issues and was part of the team preparing the liberalization
of the French telecom sector in the 1990s.
Benoit is a guest lecturer at leading European business school ESCP-Europe.
He holds an MSc in management sciences, a master’s degree from Institut
National des Telecommunications (now Telecoms & Management ParisSud), an
MA in economics and competition law from King’s College London and MBAs
from both London Business School and Columbia University in New York City.
Benoit can be reached at benoit@launchworks.co.
xii About the authors

Laure Claire Reillier is a director and co-founder


at Launchworks and specializes in helping platforms
ignite and scale their businesses through innovative
strategic marketing and product development. She
also manages the global expert network of Launch-
works. Laure Claire has 20 years’ experience in devel-
oping, managing and marketing products and services
for e-commerce, telecom and software companies and
has deep expertise in B2B, B2C and C2C marketing.
Before joining Launchworks, Laure Claire worked
at eBay, where she was head of proposition development for sellers in Europe.
In this role, she was responsible for product strategy and roadmap, positioning,
customer experience (online and offline), pricing and marketing communications.
Before eBay, Laure Claire managed the P&L and development of VoIP
and e-commerce services at BT Retail in the UK. She was responsible for the
commercial development and launch of new services and the management
(strategy, marketing and pricing) of existing services. She also worked as marketing
and business development director of Goodman Blue, a VoIP software start-up,
where she repositioned the company and its suite of products prior to its
acquisition by American investors in 2006.
Laure Claire started her career in 1996 at innovative software start-ups Metrica
and WatchMark. Both were later acquired by IBM, where Laure Claire worked
as a consultant, product manager and later head of marketing for Europe, where
she worked closely with many international telecom operators on performance
management solutions for mobile services.
She is a regular guest lecturer at ESCP Europe and board member of their
marketing master’s degree. She has also been a guest lecturer at London Busi-
ness School.
Laure Claire holds a Master’s degree in Computer Science and Telecoms
(Ingénieur Télécom, Paris) and a MBA from London Business School.
She can be reached at laure@launchworks.co.
Preface

Why we wrote this book


We were students when we met in the early 1990s just outside Paris, France.
We were very fortunate to study networks and computer sciences as the World
Wide Web was being invented (literally between our first and second year
of graduate studies). We discovered a small – yet global – interconnected
village of a handful of websites that could all be visited within a single day.
It was a mesmerizing experience. Previous text-based tools for searching
files and displaying information, such as Archie and Gopher, were largely
aimed at academics and didn’t stand a chance against an easy-to-use tool such
as the Web. Like many early users, we intuitively understood that this new
connectedness would have a profound impact on the world economy. We
knew that the linear production model, at the heart of our economies and
largely unchanged since the Industrial Revolution, was about to be challenged.
Much has changed since we graduated, and we have observed first-hand
how large and small firms, as well as societies, have been transformed by this
digital revolution.
At the same time, we also noticed that a deeper and probably more dis-
ruptive force was impacting an increasing number of markets. Successful firms
were not simply becoming digital, but also transforming their business model
to fully harness what the Internet enabled in terms of new interactions. It was
not about newspapers having a website or even offering an online edition,
but about new businesses using communities of contributors and readers. It
was not about simply selling online rather than in shops, but about allowing
people to interact as part of communities, to list items, to connect, to exchange
and to transact through largely centralized platforms, such as eBay. This was
in stark contrast with the way firms had been organized since the Industrial
Revolution. The linear view of the firm, with its inputs (labour, raw material,
etc.) transformed in an increasingly efficient manner into valuable outputs
xiv Preface

(products and services) was no longer able to explain how these particular
firms were operating. A case study of Ford, which would have provided
powerful management insights into how firms operated only 15 years ago,
no longer provides the insights it once did. Firms such as Apple, Amazon,
Google, Airbnb and Uber have grown at an unprecedented pace while
operating in ways that have very little to do with traditional firms such as
Ford.
We also noticed that many of these disruptive platforms were in fact
cleverly combined with traditional business models to create powerful self-
reinforcing ecosystems. Amazon, for example, used eBay’s open marketplace
model and combined it with its own digital retail model. Apple is focused
on manufacturing and selling beautifully designed products – and this generates
more than 80% of its revenues – but these devices are often bought because
of the unique apps provided by the community of external developers and
available on its App Store platform. Google’s advertising and search platforms
are also supplemented by a range of other products and services developed
by Google as part of its fast-growing ecosystem.
Our fascination and interest for these new business models, whose power
we experienced first-hand, led us to set up Launchworks, a new breed of
advisory company dedicated to helping firms unlock value by leveraging
these new platform-based business models. At the time, books on platforms
simply didn’t exist beyond a few, often quite narrow, academic publications.1
As we developed our thinking and frameworks to help platform businesses,
we realized that many firms could benefit from our experience and insights.

Who is this book for?


This book is aimed at everybody interested in better understanding the new
business models powering our economies. Business and management students
will find valuable references, frameworks and case studies to better understand
how platform business models work. Platform executives will be able to step
back from the day-to-day management to look more holistically at the unique
challenges they face as they scale their business. Lastly, business executives
working for traditional companies will gain unique insights into the inner
workings of platform-based business models, their disruption potential, and
possible strategic responses.

What is new about this book?


We noticed that platform businesses were generally treated as ‘black boxes’
by outsiders and therefore decided to shed light on how they were operating.
Preface xv

This encouraged us to define what platform businesses were doing and


how their activities were different from traditional ones, and led to the plat-
form rocket model presented in this book. We also realized that being a
platform was not a binary question and that many businesses, such as Amazon,
were in fact combining different business models. This led us to develop the
platform-powered ecosystem framework that shows at a high level which
portfolio of activities are undertaken by a company and their underly-
ing business model. We have seen first-hand how important it is for firms to
have clarity on these issues before they formulate their ‘platform strategy’.
Lastly, we used our experience, greatly enriched by many discussions with
friends, academics and colleagues with experience at platform firms such as
eBay, PayPal, Uber, Airbnb, Facebook and Google, to develop a practical
guide for those interested in designing, igniting, scaling and defending a
platform. Clearly, each platform is different, but we describe at a high level
the generic questions that platform businesses need to answer at various stages
of their development.
This process confirmed the scale of the disruption that was taking place
and gave us some further insights into the emerging field of platform strategy.
Over an astonishingly short time frame, platforms such as Uber and
Airbnb grew at a frenetic pace and society as a whole started to take notice.
In some cases, platforms attracted the ire of established players that were being
disrupted. How many times have we heard stories of hotel representatives or
taxi companies complaining about the ‘unfair competition’ of these new
innovative entrants? Yet the convenience and flexibility of the innovative and
cost-effective offerings of platforms have been too attractive to resist.
Customers have been voting with their feet and wallets – or with their mobile
phones, to be more accurate! Customer demand has fuelled the arrival of a
new breed of start-ups positioning themselves as ‘the Uber of X’ or ‘the Airbnb
of Y’, with X and Y being used for a wide range of industries and categories,
including ‘planes’, ‘holidays’, ‘boats’, etc. Yet igniting and scaling platforms
to critical mass is a notoriously difficult exercise, and we have tried to
document some of these unique challenges, as well as offer some tips and
tools to address them.

Standing on the shoulders of giants


Academics have recently redoubled their efforts to research platforms, a
relatively new field of economics known as ‘multisided markets’ only first
formalized in 2003 by French Nobel economist Jean Tirole. We are most
definitely standing on the shoulders of giants, and this book would not have
been possible without the insights and stories from countless platform
xvi Preface

executives, academics, students and clients who taught us so much over the
past few years. We acknowledge the contribution of all those who shared
their views with us, sent us their research, invited us to seminars and work-
shops, participated in some of our lectures or simply retained our firm,
Launchworks, to advise them.

Note
1 The possible exception is an early book on multisided markets by D. Evans and
R. Schmalensee, The Catalyst Code: The Strategies Behind the World’s Most Dynamic
Companies, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 2007.
Acknowledgements

While all errors and omissions are our own, we would like in particular to
thank the following individuals for sharing their insights with us as we worked
on the book.
In alphabetical order, we would like to thank: Ken Ardali, Jean-Jacques
Arnal, Andrin Bachmann, Nicolas Bailleux, Charles Baron, Matthew Bennett,
David Brackin, Verena Butt d’Espous, Sangeet Choudary, Jean-Marc Codsi,
Richard Davies, Carlos Eduardo Espinal, Richard Feasey, Jean-Marc Frangos,
Anshu Goel, Barbara Gray, Jonathan Hall, Tim Hilpert, Rob Hull, Stéphane
Kasriel, Spyros Katageorgis, Monroe Labouisse, Terence Lim, Elisabeth
Ling, Claude Lixi, Rodrigo Madanes, Frédéric Mazzella, Antonio Nieto-
Rodriguez, Keyvan Nilforoushan, Natasha Osborne-Geurts, Nilan Peris,
Didier Rappaport, Fred Reillier, Annemie Ress, Paul Ress, Ramsey R. F.
Sargent, Joe Schorge, Marie Taillard, Aude Thibaut de Maisières, Mike
Walker, Chris Webster, Taylor Wescoatt, Caspar Wolley, André Haddad,
Pascal Isbell and Albin Serviant.
Please note that while many of the people mentioned above work for,
advise or regulate some of the platform businesses we talk about in this book,
many spoke to us in a personal capacity rather than as representatives of their
employer. A small number of individuals asked to remain anonymous, and
we thank them as well.
We would also like to thank all the academics, including in particular
Marshall Van Alstyne, Annabelle Gawer, Thomas Eisenmann, Ray Fisman,
Geoff Parker, David Evans and Peter Evans, who have done much to improve
our understanding of platforms over the years. Many of them also kindly
provided feedback and/or shared their thoughts with us at a number of research
symposia and conferences.
Special thanks also go to Jonathan Norman, our publisher at Routledge,
as well as Emma Redley and Alex Atkinson, his assistants, for believing in
the project and providing ongoing support, to Philip Stirrup, our production
xviii Acknowledgements

manager, to the people at Florence Production, Laurence Paul and Andrew


Craddock for their help, to Ian Koviak and Alan Dino Hebel at the Book
Designers for designing the book cover, to Nirosha Fernando, who designed
the illustrations, to Sue Seabury, a dear friend and talented writer who
patiently reviewed a previous version of the manuscript, and to Justin Coutts,
one of our colleagues at Launchworks, who volunteered to help up with this
endeavour in general and made a very substantial contribution to the pricing
chapter in particular.
Chapter 1

Introduction to platform
businesses

Uber, the world’s largest taxi company, owns no vehicles. Facebook, the
world’s most popular media owner, creates no content. Alibaba, the most
valuable retailer, has no inventory. And Airbnb, the world’s largest
accommodation provider, owns no real estate. Something interesting is
happening.
Tom Goodwin

In 2007, designers Brian Chesky and Joe Gebbia struggled to pay their rent
in San Francisco when they noticed that the city’s hotels were fully booked
for an upcoming design conference. They came up with the idea of renting
out three airbeds in their loft and cooking breakfast for their guests. The next
day, they designed a website, originally called airbedandbreakfast.com. In less
than a week, they had three guests, paying $80 each a night. When the guests
left, thinking this could become a big idea, they asked a former roommate
of Joe’s, engineer Nathan Blecharczyk, to help them develop the site that we
know today as Airbnb.
For the first few years, the team failed to raise money. The vision of a
trusted community marketplace for people to list, discover and share private
accommodation around the world did not appeal to venture capitalists (VCs),
who couldn’t see a big enough market. But Brian, Joe and Nathan persisted
and found ingenious ways to keep going. In 2008, the company ran out of
cash, so they had to find creative ways to make money quickly. As the
presidential campaign was in full swing and both sides were keen to show
support for their favourite candidates, the Airbnb team decided to sell special
edition Cheerios cereal boxes for both presidential candidates called ‘Obama
O’s’ and ‘Cap’n McCains’ for $40 each. They made $30,000 in a few weeks.
By early 2009, they were invited to join the Y Combinator, one of the
leading incubator programmes in San Francisco, and got $20,000 of funding
from well-known angel investor Paul Graham. A seed round of $600,000 led
2 Introduction to platform businesses

by Sequoia Capital followed shortly afterwards.1 Even so, the business did
not take off. The Airbnb team realized that the photos of places advertised
on their website were not appealing. According to Brian Chesky, ‘A web
startup would say, “Let’s send emails, teach [users] professional photography,
and test them.” We said, “Screw that.”’2 They rented a $5,000 camera and
went door to door, taking professional pictures of as many New York listings
as possible. Revenues doubled quickly to $400/week and the site started
to grow. Brian knew at this point that it was not just about pretty pictures,
but that Airbnb first had to ‘create the perfect experience [. . .] and then scale
that experience.’ In April 2012, the team started monetizing the service by
charging up to 15% on the bookings. More funding rounds followed,3 which
enabled Airbnb to hire more staff to focus on the customer experience and
market the platform in order to scale the business.
Their success came down to three things: ease of joining for host and
guest; effective matching of hosts and guests; and safe and easy transactions
for all.
Since then, Airbnb has grown exponentially (see Figure 1.1), from 50,000
listings in 2011 to more than 2 million in April 2016.4 And this is not just
inventory. It is estimated that roughly half a million people around the world
sleep in an Airbnb rented accommodation at peak time.

Figure 1.1 Airbnb global listing growth


Source: VentureBeat, Airbnb website, Launchworks analysis
Introduction to platform businesses 3

Airbnb is currently active in 34,000 cities in 190 countries, and has had 35
million nights booked.5 Airbnb raised $1.5 billion in June 2015, which is one
of the largest private funding rounds ever. The company is estimated to be
worth $30 billion,6 which means that in less than 10 years, the travel accom-
modation platform has become one of the most valuable privately owned
start-ups, worth more than the largest hotel chains Wyndham, Intercontinental
and Hyatt, who own extensive portfolios of prime real estate globally.
And Airbnb owns no property.
While there’s been an overwhelming response from customers, Airbnb’s
high-growth success story has not been without resistance from hoteliers,
who claim that individuals renting their rooms or entire homes to visitors
represents an ‘unfair competition’ to their trade. There is emerging evidence7
that Airbnb is not only growing the market, but also increasingly competing
against hotels, who have to respond with new services and lower prices.
Interestingly, these lower prices benefit all consumers, and not just Airbnb
clients. Yet Airbnb has also been under growing pressure from city authorities
regarding housing regulations and tax laws. We’ll come back to these issues
in Chapter 13 on platforms and regulation.

Table 1.1 Comparison of the largest hotel groups vs Airbnb

Company Market Number Number Year of


capitalization of hotels of rooms launch
of private managed provided
valuation8
($ billions)
Airbnb 30 billion 0 2,000,000 2007
Hilton Worldwide (including 23.3 billion 4,7269 775,866 1919
Conrad, Waldorf Astoria)
Marriott10 (including The Ritz 17.8 billion 5,700 1,200,000 1927
Carlton, W Hotels, Sheraton,
Le Méridien
Accor Group11 (including Raffles, 11.2 billion 3,942 570,000 1967
Sofitel, Novotel, Mercure)
Intercontinental Hotels Group12 8.3 billion 4,921 722,575 1946
(including Crowne Plaza,
Holiday Inn, Holiday Inn Express)
Wyndham Worldwide13 (including 7.56 billion 7,670 667,000 1981
Ramada, Travelodge, Super 8,
Days Inn)
Hyatt Hotels14 (including Hyatt 6.87 billion 679 172,587 1957
Park, Regency, Place, House, Ziva,
Andaz)
4 Introduction to platform businesses

UNLOCKING ECONOMIC VALUE WITH EBAY


Using eBay as an example, let’s say that you have a large table with
matching chairs that no longer fits with your newly redecorated flat.
For you, this second-hand furniture almost has a negative value; it takes
up space, and given the very reasonable price you paid for it at IKEA
several years ago, you don’t want to spend time trying to find somebody
to take this set off your hands. Conversely, think about a nearby student
who has a tight budget and is looking for a table and chairs for her new
pad. She wants to save money and doesn’t care about ‘new’ stuff. The
student is prepared to pay £50 for the entire set. eBay can match you
and this potential buyer, with very limited friction. Let’s say the student’s
bid of £30 is the highest and that she is the happy winner of the auction.
The value created by the platform intermediation is then £20 (£50
willingness to pay minus £30 winning auction bid) for the buyer plus
£35 for the seller (that’s the £30 plus the negative price you were
attaching to the no longer adequate table set that was taking up space:
say £5). So out of ‘thin air’, the platform managed to create £55 of
economic value. Now scale this by millions of transactions every day
across all the platform companies (including car and house rental
companies, e-commerce marketplaces, etc.) and you get a sense of the
transformational potential of platform businesses.

Platform models have become mainstream


Airbnb epitomizes the rise of digital platform businesses. In the same way as
eBay connects buyers and sellers, Airbnb creates communities of hosts and
guests and enables them to transact globally. Unlike traditional businesses,
platforms don’t produce anything and don’t just distribute goods or services.
What they do is directly connect different customer groups to enable transactions.
eBay, a well-known company, creates value by simply connecting buyers and
sellers.
For thousands of years, markets have been physical and local. Connecting
groups of buyers and sellers has played a big part in the fabric of human society.
Farmers’ markets and matchmakers have been around for thousand of years.
But something extraordinary has happened in the last 20 years: technology
has enabled these business models to scale to a global level. The very first
platforms that scaled globally were the credit cards companies such as Discover,
Introduction to platform businesses 5

Visa, Mastercard and Amex. But no one scaled as quickly or as globally as


new technology-focused players such as Apple, Google and eBay, all under-
pinned by digital platforms.
Many more have followed suit, reinventing entire parts of consumer
industries, from media (Facebook), retail (Amazon), transport (Uber), tele-
coms (WhatsApp), payments (PayPal), music (SoundCloud), accommodation
(Airbnb) and many other sectors.
This platform colonization extends to the enterprise domain as well in an
increasing number of verticals: wholesale goods (Alibaba), talent platforms
(Upwork), operating systems (Windows), etc.
In most business literature, platforms are either considered as ‘black boxes’
serving what economists call ‘multisided markets’, or assumed to operate like
traditional firms. Unfortunately, neither approach provides much insight into
platform businesses themselves. Many commentators use the generic term
‘platform’ to describe a ‘technology platform’ that encompasses processors, access
devices such as mobile phones, PCs and tablets, software applications, etc. These
loose definitions often lead to vague notions of platforms that encompass firms
with very different business models. We’ll come back for more detailed defin-
itions of digital platforms in Chapter 3, but for the time being we’ll use a simple
definition for platform businesses as those connecting members of communities and
enabling them to transact. We’ll also define platform-powered businesses as firms
that have parts of their business underpinned by platforms.

Table 1.2 Examples of digital platforms

Digital platforms connecting Users Producers


communities of users and
producers and enabling
them to transact
eBay, Alibaba Buyers of goods Sellers of goods
Airbnb, Onefinestay Guests Hosts
Uber, Lyft Passengers Taxis
Turo, Drivy Car renters Car owners
BlaBlaCar, Waze Carpool Passengers Car drivers
YouTube, Facebook Viewers Content producers and
advertisers
Amex, Visa, Mastercard Card owners Merchants
Upwork, Hired Businesses Freelancers
Tinder, Match.com, Happn Single guys dating Single girls dating
UberEATS, Deliveroo Buyers of meals at home Restaurants
AngelList, Seedrs Investors in start-ups Start-ups seeking capital
TaskRabbit, Stootie Buyers of services Providers of services
Kickstarter, Indiegogo Buyers of new products Providers of new products
6 Introduction to platform businesses

Since many platform businesses are digital in nature, we use the term digital
platform for businesses digitally connecting members of communities to enable
them to transact.
Platform business models can be tailored to meet a wide range of needs.
They include:

• Marketplaces, which attract, match and connect those looking to provide


a product or service (producers) with those looking to buy that product
or service (users).
• Social and content networks, which enable users to communicate with
each other by sharing information, comments, messages, videos and
pictures, and then connect users with third parties such as advertisers,
developers and content providers.
• Credit card and payment platforms, which attract users on one side to
pay for goods and services, and merchants on the other side to be able
to take their payment.
• Operating systems for computers, mobiles, game consoles, VR equipment
and associated app stores, which match users with software applications
produced by developers.

Some platforms can combine different aspects. For example WeChat is a


social network combining an app store with payment functionality.

Why platform models are different


A closer examination of these businesses suggests that they all share features
unique to platforms, and do not follow traditional management principles.
These new companies are made of powerful platform ecosystems uniquely
able to attract, match and connect people to enable them to transact. These platforms
often use ‘open’ business models that do not require stocking or manufacturing
anything, but harness the power of communities to enable transactions. This
is very different from traditional organizations, which tend to run as ‘linear
pipes’. Traditional organizations use their linear ‘value chains’ – a term
famously coined by 1980s strategy guru Michael Porter – to buy and transform
raw materials (inputs) into products or services (outputs) before selling them
at a profit.
This ‘input/output’ view of the world and associated management frame-
works have provided helpful insights into many traditional firms’ operations.
Indeed, it is the value chains of car manufacturers, oil companies, hotel groups
and utilities that have powered the growth of our economies since the
Introduction to platform businesses 7

Industrial Revolution. But for many twenty-first-century platform businesses,


this framework lost much of its usefulness.
While platforms and open business models are not new, their ‘mathematical
formalization’ is very recent. The underlying economics of such busi-
nesses were first set out in a 2003 scholarly article by 2014 economic Nobel
Prize winner Jean Tirole.15 His seminal work was primarily focused on market
dynamics and antitrust concerns rather than the management of plat-
form businesses themselves. Since then, new platform-powered challengers
have emerged, and have been disrupting entrenched competitors with their
meteoric rise. More importantly, these new model companies have revealed
that some markets, once thought to be ‘traditional’, such as taxis and hotels,
could in fact be served more efficiently with innovative and open platform
business models enabled by digital technologies. In many cases, platforms are
able to bring to bear the power of communities to become real competitors
to established companies. Ride-sharing, for example, used to be a marginal
activity, often seen as unsafe. BlaBlaCar has managed to redefine this market
by creating a vibrant and trusted community with more than 20 million
members over 18 countries in 2016. It is now seen by Guillaume Pepy,16
CEO of French Railways SNCF, as a key competitor.
Companies didn’t wait for academics to rewrite the rules of management,
and early platforms mostly proceeded through trial and error. However, we
are now in a position to observe many successful (and less successful) platforms
and review their past experiments so that we can learn from them and derive
useful management principles for those that will follow. New platforms need
not suffer through all the mistakes of early platform pioneers. Additionally,
traditional companies faced with platform competition are looking for ways
to stay in the game, and much can be learned from the reactions of established
players disrupted by platforms. We will also show how old and new business
models can be combined to create entire self-reinforcing platform-powered
ecosystems. We will use a range of platform examples, such as eBay, Amazon,
Google and Apple, as case studies throughout the book to guide us and provide
illustrations of key business insights behind the success of these platform-
powered businesses.

• Chapter 2 explores the meteoric rise of platform business models over the
past decade.
• Chapter 3 reviews platform definitions in the academic literature, looks
at the various types of platforms and proposes basic characteristics common
to most platforms.
• Chapter 4 reviews the key economic characteristics of platforms, including
network effects, externalities, critical mass and tipping point.
8 Introduction to platform businesses

• Chapter 5 compares and contrasts traditional business ‘value chains’ such


as manufacturing, service provision and distribution with various platform
business models. It then proposes a typology based on the Launchworks
platform rocket framework and its various core components: acquiring,
matching, connecting, transacting and optimizing functions.
• Chapter 6 examines how successful companies such as Google, Apple,
Amazon, Facebook and Microsoft have been able to design unique organ-
izations – and self-reinforcing ecosystems – powered by platforms.
• Chapter 7 looks at the key life stages of platforms businesses and provides
insights into the pre-launch phase of platform businesses.
• Chapter 8 focuses on the issues associated with platforms at launch and
the strategies to successfully ignite the two sides of platform businesses.
• Chapter 9 addresses the key questions faced by the high-growth challenges
of scaling platforms.
• Chapter 10 looks at the management challenges associated with established
platforms that need to nurture and defend their ecosystem.
• Chapter 11 examines the unique pricing and incentive challenges faced
by platform companies throughout their development.
• Chapter 12 discusses how trust needs to be nurtured by platforms and
supported by the right governance principles, community management
frameworks and brand attributes.
• Chapter 13 looks at the interplay between platforms, regulations and
competition law, and discusses the complex balance that governments and
regulatory authorities need to strike to unlock value creation while pro-
tecting consumers.
• Chapter 14 examines the challenges faced by traditional firms being
disrupted by platforms and possible responses. It reviews past failures,
highlights the relative strengths and weaknesses of existing business models
competing against platforms and offers insights into strategic options.
• Chapter 15 provides a broader perspective into the future of platforms
and their interplay with work, management, technology and the emer-
gence of the sharing economy. It highlights some of the changes we are
likely to see in the years to come and the extent to which platform eco-
systems will both create new markets and continue to colonize existing
ones.

Notes
1 Telegraph, 7 September 2012, www.telegraph.co.uk/technology/news/9525267/Airbnb-
The-story-behind-the-1.3bn-room-letting-website.html.
2 Fast Company, www.fastcompany.com/3017358/most-innovative-companies-2012/
19airbnb.
Introduction to platform businesses 9

3 Following the Sequoia round, Airbnb went on to raise a series A round of $7.2 million
in 2010. Wall Street Journal, 25 July 2011, http://blogs.wsj.com/venturecapital/2011/
07/25/airbnb-from-y-combinator-to-112m-funding-in-three-years/.
4 VentureBeat, 19 June 2014, http://venturebeat.com/2014/06/19/uber-and-airbnbs-
incredible-growth-in-4-charts/ and Airbnb website at www.airbnb.co.uk/about/
about-us.
5 www.airbnb.co.uk/about/about-us.
6 CB Insights, 1 August 2016, www.wired.com/2015/12/airbnb-confirms-1-5-billion-
funding-round-now-valued-at-25-5-billion/. By the end of 2014, Airbnb had raised over
$800 million. ‘Airbnb Is Raising a Monster Round at a $20B Valuation’, TechCrunch,
27 February 2015, http://techcrunch.com/2015/02/27/airbnb-2/.
7 G. Zervas and D. Proserpio, ‘The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating the Impact
of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry’, Boston University, 27 January 2016.
8 As of 23 September 2016.
9 http://news.hiltonworldwide.com/assets/HWW/docs/brandFactSheets/HWW_
Corporate_Fact_Sheet.pdf.
10 www.marriott.com/marriott/aboutmarriott.mi.
11 As of 30 June 2016, www.accorhotels-group.com/en/brands/key-figures.html.
12 www.ihgplc.com/files/pdf/factsheets/factsheet_worldstats.pdf, 31 March 2015.
13 www.wyndhamworldwide.com/category/wyndham-hotel-group, June 2015.
14 Hyatt Hotels Q3 2016 earnings, available at http://investors.hyatt.com/files/doc_
financials/q3_2016/Q3-2016-Earnings-Release.pdf
15 See J. Rochet and J. Tirole, ‘Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, Journal of
the European Economic Association, 1(4), 2003, 990–1029. While Rochet and Tirole’s
contribution formalised the economics of two-sided markets, academics before them
also made significant contributions to the field. See for example G. Parker and M. Van
Alstyne, Internetwork Externalities and Free Information Goods, New York, NY, Proceedings
of the 2nd ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, 2000, pp. 107–16. See also M. Katz
and C. Shapiro, ‘Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility’, The American
Economic Review, Volume 75, Issue 3, June 1985, pp. 424–40. And J. Farrell and G.
Saloner (1988), ‘Coordination through Committees and Markets’, RAND Journal of
Economics, 19, issue 2, pp. 235–52.
16 http://business.lesechos.fr/directions-generales/strategie/business-plan/0203024730098-
guillaume-pepy-imagine-la-sncf-de-demain-9282.php, September 2013.
Chapter 2

The meteoric rise of platform


businesses

Over the past 20 years or so, platform businesses have grown at an


unprecedented pace and have been able to overtake many traditional busi-
nesses. Often, this significant shift in business models and value creation has
been overshadowed by the much broader digitalization trend. Not only have
platform businesses grown at a faster pace than traditional ones, but they
have also created more shareholder value and attracted more venture capital
(VC) investment. It is therefore not a surprise to see that platforms are now
powering many of the best-known brands in the world and are at the heart
of most sharing economy initiatives.

Digital transformation and new platform business


models
Over the last 20 years, digital technologies have significantly disrupted
traditional businesses. Their physical assets – think bricks-and-mortar stores
– are no longer a source of competitive advantage. Harnessing digital
distribution models has become a must. In fact, the digital transition has been
high on board agendas of most traditional businesses trying to respond to and
compete with digital and Internet-enabled entrants.
However, this transition from traditional offline to online (illustrated by
arrow number 1 in Figure 2.1) has overshadowed a more fundamental shift
in value: the evolution to new digital platform business models (illustrated by
arrows 2, 3 and 4 pointing to the upper-right quadrant).
Many firms, busy with the digital translation of their existing model, may
forget that the advent of digital technologies is also a key enabler of new,
different and often more powerful business models such as ‘platforms’. We
believe it is the emergence of these digital platform models that has been the
most disruptive in many sectors, including retail (eBay, Amazon), travel
(Uber) and accommodation (Airbnb). This shift is far from over, and many
12 The meteoric rise of platform businesses

Figure 2.1 Digital transformation from linear to non-linear


Source: Launchworks

new industries are now being disrupted by these digital platforms (for example,
healthcare, recruitment, professional services and energy).
Of course, some traditional businesses have realized that the digital transition
(arrow 1) was not enough and have started to develop platform capabilities
to compete (arrow 2). For example, retail giants are now going beyond their
initial e-commerce offerings and are trying to harness the power of platforms
(top arrow), where merchants can directly sell to customers. The recent
acquisition of digital marketplace Jet.com by Walmart for $3.3 billion can be
seen in that light. An increasing number of retailers who had only made limited
digital investments early on are now investigating digital platforms as add-on
businesses (arrow 3).
Amazon is also an interesting example, as while it started as a pure e-
commerce reseller with a curated but limited range of goods for sale, it quickly
added a marketplace platform to complement its reseller model. The latter
now represents well over 50% of its total e-commerce revenues.1 Zalando,
the successful e-commerce fashion company, is also turning itself into a fully
fledged platform business.2
The meteoric rise of platform businesses 13

Lastly, a number of traditional platform businesses, such as estate agents,


have further developed their online presence (arrow 4), although in many
cases faster and more agile platform competitors such as Zoopla managed to
enter the market and are now ahead of the game. Many traditional dating
agencies also found themselves replaced by native digital dating platforms such
as Happn, Match.com, eHarmony or Tinder.
Of course, many firms also combine different business models, such as
platforms and traditional businesses, in order to create what we call platform-
powered ecosystems. We will explore their business models, as well as
Amazon’s, in more detail in Chapter 6.

Platform growth and market capitalization


In the third quarter of 2016, the five largest companies in the world
were platform-powered: Apple, Google, Microsoft, Amazon and Facebook
(the famous GAFAMs).3 Just 10 years ago, only one – Microsoft – made the
cut.4 The total market capitalization of platform-powered businesses
in the top 10 of the FT Global 500 index went from $280 billion 10 years
ago (11% of the total then) to $2.2 trillion in the third quarter of 2016 (59%
of the total), as shown in Figure 2.2. And this is not just about market capital-
ization since recent research shows that platform businesses have significantly
higher sales growth, return on assets and gross profits than traditional ones.5
In 2015, Apple grew by 28%, Google by 14%, Amazon by 20%, Microsoft
by 7.6% and Facebook by 44%. Many of these relatively new businesses have

Figure 2.2 Platform-powered businesses in top 10 FT Global 500 (market cap)


Source: FT Global 500 list of companies, Launchworks analysis
14 The meteoric rise of platform businesses

Figure 2.3 Platform companies by region


Source: Peter C. Evans, Global Platform Survey, CGE 2016

managed to develop complex ecosystems, often powered by a core ‘platform’


that acts as a catalyst for enabling transactions between different customer
groups.
Peter Evans and Annabelle Gawer recently published one of the very first
studies on platform businesses, aimed at identifying platforms around the world
and gathering relevant data on their size and value. As Figure 2.3 shows, most
of the 176 largest platforms identified are to be found in the US, followed
by Asia and Europe. The estimated market capitalization of these companies
is in excess of $4.3 trillion and they have more than 1.3 million employees
in total. This excludes the so-called spillover effects, such as induced jobs
created, impact of increased choices and reduced prices for consumers.

Platforms and brand power


Platform companies are not only creating economic value, but they have also
established themselves, sometimes in only a few years, as the best-known
companies in the world. When we look at which brands people value most,
platform-powered businesses score particularly well. It may be surprising to
see such high brand recognition since most of these firms were founded less
than 20 years ago. A 2016 study from Millward Brown of the top 100 most
valuable brands in the world6 reveals that many platform businesses make the
list. As illustrated in Figure 2.4, the top 10 includes Apple, Google, Microsoft,
Facebook, Visa and Amazon, as well as AT&T and Verizon, which are
sometimes considered as platforms.7 In fact, the top eight brands are platform-
powered companies. Only McDonald’s (in 9th position) and IBM (in 10th
position) do not (yet) match our definition.8
The meteoric rise of platform businesses 15

Figure 2.4 The top 10 most valuable brands in the world (US$ millions)10
Source: Milliward Brown 2016, Launchworks analysis

And platforms can, of course, be found further down in the rankings.


Chinese e-commerce marketplace Alibaba, with revenues superior to Amazon
and eBay combined, is now in 18th position after entering the top 100 for
the first time in 2015.9

‘Unicorn’ platforms as market disruptors


While we have seen that platforms are behind many of today’s largest com-
panies and best-known brands, they are also powering many fast-growing
start-ups that are attracting significant private investments (e.g. VC and private
equity money). Many of these platform-powered start-ups have been able to
reach very significant scale without listing on public markets. Airbnb and Uber
are cases in point.11 In only a few years, they, and others, have managed to
secure market valuations in excess of $1 billion, gaining the nickname of
‘unicorns’.12
Aileen Lee famously coined the unicorn metaphor in 2013,13 but it looks
like unicorn companies are not as rare as they once were, and perhaps should
be called instead the new ‘workhorses’. Today, there are no fewer than 177
such companies14 that are worth over $1 billion each (the original definition
of a ‘unicorn’). As illustrated in Figure 2.5, many of them exhibit strong
platform characteristics.15
For example, Didi Chuxing (formerly Didi Kuaidi), headquartered in
China, and Lyft, in the US, are platforms matching drivers and passengers
16 The meteoric rise of platform businesses

Figure 2.5 Private value of platform-powered unicorn start-ups (US$ billions)


Source: CB Insights, 1 August 2016, Launchworks analysis

like Uber, and both have raised significant private investments. Snapchat is a
well-known and fast-growing communications platform that famously turned
down a multibillion-dollar offer from Facebook in 2014. Stripe is a fast-
growing payment platform for e-commerce merchants.

Platforms power the sharing economy movement


Lastly, platforms are at the heart of the emerging ‘sharing economy’ since
many enable the redistribution, sharing and/or reuse of excess capacity in
goods and services. The term ‘sharing economy’, which was first introduced
in 2010, describes a ‘social revolution’ based on the ‘sharing of resources across
multiple platforms’ in a way that creates values for all participants.16
eBay was an early precursor of this trend by allowing people to resell their
little-used assets directly and easily, but many other companies have followed
suit. The main categories emerging include platforms to buy, hire, share,
The meteoric rise of platform businesses 17

Table 2.1 High-level typology of sharing economy platforms (number of platforms in


parentheses)

Borrow Buy Hire someone Share Swap


I can lend you You can buy stuff I can help you with We can drive We can swap stuff
some money (38) I no longer need your chores (37) somewhere we no longer need
(20) together (22) (11)
You can borrow You can buy my I can teach you Come have dinner You can stay at my
my car (36) clothes (10) some skills (26) at my house (13) house and I’ll stay
at yours (9)
I can lend you I can buy I can show you You can work We can swap some
money for your something for around town (24) from my living clothes (5)
business (33) you next time I room (6)
go abroad (6)
You can stay in You can buy I can deliver your We can share a We can swap our
my spare room currency (5) parcel (22) taxi (4) goods (2)
(32)
You can borrow You can buy my I can cook you You can camp in You can gift your
stuff you don’t car (5) dinner (11) my backyard (3) old stuff (2)
want to buy (20)
Other companies Other companies Other companies Other companies Other companies
(180) (78) (187) (19) (8)
Total: 339 Total: 124 Total: 307 Total: 67 Total: 37
Source: Adapted from JustPark, www.justpark.com/creative/sharing-economy-index/, with indicative number
of companies identified in given category given in parenthesis, February 2016

borrow or swap a multitude of things. Seed swap exchanges are helping


farmers, clothes and handbags are being shared for relevant occasions, thousands
of student books are being swapped, rides and cars are now routinely shared
on long and short journeys, the use of expensive real estate is increasingly
optimized (flats, offices, parking spaces) and even money now changes
hands directly with peer-to-peer lending or currency exchange thanks to
specifically designed digital platforms. A very cursory review of sharing
economy platforms17 lists close to 900 companies and new ones are appearing
every day. The categories in which the main ones are operating are shown
in Table 2.1.
The new rules of management are being rewritten to allow for more power-
ful and innovative platform ecosystems to emerge and compete with other
established businesses, as well as create entirely new markets.
And this is just the beginning.
18 The meteoric rise of platform businesses

Notes
1 ChannelAdvisor blog, www.channeladvisor.com/blog/?pn=scot/amazons-q4-results-
marketplace-surges-proves-it-is-the-amazon-profit-cow.
2 See, for example, blog post of Marcel Weiß dated 19 November 2015, https://
earlymoves.com/2015/11/19/zalando-we-want-to-become-an-open-fashion-platform/.
3 Financial Times Global 500 rankings, 30 September 2016.
4 FT Global 500 list of largest companies, 31 March 2006 and 31 March 2016, and
Launchworks analysis.
5 See B. Libert, M. Beck, J. Wind, The Network Imperative, Boston: Harvard Business
Review press, 2016.
6 BrandZ(tm) Top 100 Most Valuable Global Brands 2016, Millward Brown, http://
wppbaz.com/admin/uploads/files/BZ_Global_2016_Report.pdf.
7 We recognize that telecommunications operators, such as Verizon and AT&T, operate
somewhat differently than other platform-powered ecosystems. In fact, some may argue
they operate more like traditional businesses than digital platforms. Yet we believe
operators were an early wave of platforms that attracted users, matched them first using
switchboards, then with directories and yellow pages, to connect them and allow them
to transact. They also originally benefited from network effects, yet were not able to
innovate as fast as the new ‘Internet players’. Telecoms operators are, however,
increasingly investing in digital platform capabilities to avoid commoditization (such as
the acquisition of Yahoo by Verizon). We note that their exclusion from this list would
still result in more than 75% of the combined value of the top 10 brands in the world
coming from platform-powered businesses.
8 IBM is often seen as a platform in the technical sense of the term, and associated with
both hardware standards and operating system capabilities. Yet today’s business is largely
run as a technology advisory company rather than a digital platform. We note, however,
that the firm is investing in new capabilities that may allow it to transition to a platform-
powered ecosystem model.
9 Alibaba raised $25 billion on the NYSE in September 2014.
10 This is the value of the intangible asset of the brand itself.
11 At the time of writing, neither Airbnb nor Uber are quoted on the stock market, so
market valuations for these firms are based on the implied value of their last private
round of financing.
12 A unicorn, a legendary animal that has been described since antiquity as a beast with a
pointed horn on its forehead, is notoriously difficult to find. Private companies reaching
a $1 billion mark valuation were so rare until 2010 that they were coined unicorns.
13 http://techcrunch.com/2013/11/02/welcome-to-the-unicorn-club/, 2 November 2013.
14. Data from CB Insights, 28 September 2016, www.cbinsights.com/research-unicorn-
companies.
15 As we will see later on in this book, sky-high valuation at a given point in time is in
no way a guarantee of success, and even firms exhibiting strong platform characteristics
are not immune to failure. In fact, ‘unicorpses’, defined as ‘dead companies once valued
at more than $1 billion’, are likely to be observed soon. In the meantime, and irrespective
of market volatility, it is interesting to see overall patterns of value creation around
platform businesses.
The meteoric rise of platform businesses 19

16 See early definitions of the sharing economy in R. Botsman and R. Rogers, What’s
Mine Is Yours: The Rise of Collaborative Consumption, New York: Harper Business, 2010.
More recently, A. Stephany, The Business of Sharing, London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2015.
17 www.justpark.com/creative/sharing-economy-index/, February 2016.
Chapter 3

What is a platform business?

Narrowing the search: platform definitions


The very definition of what is a platform business is fraught with difficulty.
The term is widely used in a range of contexts, by academics and practitioners
alike, and the generic dictionary definitions are not overly helpful.1 At a very
basic level, it appears that the term platform is often used to define ‘something
upon which one can build/put something else’. A physical representation could
be a plank, a raised floor or a pair of shoes with thick soles, such as the ones
often worn by Lady Gaga. A figurative use could be a political platform or
even a technological one. This is a very generic use of the term, and we
believe a more precise definition is required for what we refer to as a ‘platform
business model’, such as eBay or others.
Defining platform businesses is not simply an academic pursuit, but a
critical first step for executives to better understand how their markets are
being disrupted. Too wide a definition would run the risk of overestimating
the impact of these new business models while not being able to identify
what is unique about them. Too narrow a definition would simply miss
important firms with platform characteristics. Deciding on a definition is
therefore a prerequisite to the development of any platform strategy or market
response. It is so important that we almost always start our consulting projects
at Launchworks with this very topic to ensure that all the senior executives
have a shared understanding of what a platform business is.
In the field of academia, the term is primarily used by three different types
of scholars:2

(a) Those concerned with the development of products.3


A manufacturer might, for example, say that ‘the Jaguar X-Type uses the
same platform as the Ford Mondeo’ or ‘74X Boeing planes share the same
platform’.
22 What is a platform business?

(b) Those concerned with technology.4


An engineer might, for example, say that the Intel platform benefited from
the replacement of DOS by Windows.
(c) Those concerned with economic transactions.5
Economists might, for example, say that eBay is a platform operating in
a multisided market and enabling transactions between different consumer
groups.

PLATFORM
A business creating significant value through the acquisition, matching
and connection of two or more customer groups to enable them to
transact.
Examples: eBay, Airbnb, Uber

While there is some overlap in terms of usage across these different defin-
itions, we believe it is very important to be clear about what we mean by
the word ‘platform’ from the outset. We propose to define platform businesses
as ‘businesses creating significant value through the acquisition and/or match-
ing, interaction and connection of two or more customer groups to enable
them to transact’.6
Since much of the academic work on platforms has been done in the context
of competition economics or antitrust,7 we will review some of this work
and discuss its implications for management. We will then review more recent
definitions against our own definition based on the activities of platform
businesses, as well as the characteristics of the underlying markets they serve.
We will also see that platforms are not all equal, but come in a range of
shapes, colours and sizes. They may allow you to buy, rent, swap and borrow
products, services or currencies. They may be open to third parties or closed,
have direct distribution to consumers and producers or indirect ones and they
may have a broad selection of differentiated goods or a narrow one with
homogeneous products and services. All these differences call for different
types of governance and business architecture within the overall platform
framework. Lastly, we will see that many companies are not pure platforms,
but ‘platform-powered ecosystems’ mixing different business models.
What is a platform business? 23

Economics of platforms and multisided markets


The concept of ‘multisided markets’ is a relatively recent one. As previously
mentioned, we owe to the world of antitrust law the earliest detailed economic
analysis of businesses operating as platforms. Visa and Mastercard may not
have used the term multisided markets when they launched, but their
operations – of connecting card users and merchants – clearly exhibited the
economic characteristics of platform businesses.8
The concept of multisided markets started to be formalized by academics in
2000. Geoff Parker and Marshall Van Alstyne were among the first economists
to look closely at platform business models while trying to understand how
firms such as Microsoft could sustainably offer free software.9 Shortly after, Jean-
Charles Rochet and Jean Tirole published a seminal paper on the economics
of card platforms in 2002. Their research proposed a new economic model of
the price relationships used on both sides of a multisided market to better
coordinate demand.10 While the main focus area of the paper was credit cards,
the analysis and key findings apply more widely. The key insight of Rochet
and Tirole was that the price paid by clients of the platform on one side of
its market (the commission merchants paid for cards to be accepted at their
shops) enabled very attractive subsidized pricing on the other side of the market
(free cards for consumers).11 This was a significant departure from traditional
markets, where pricing below costs for a service is not sustainable and may even
be anticompetitive if designed to force competitors out of the market.
Platforms need to design their pricing strategies in such a way that overall value
for the platform is maximized. Note that many different equilibria could
have been reached in the cards market (fees for merchants and free cards for
consumers, or expensive card fees for consumers and no fees for merchants,
or anything in between), but that the current payment schemes ended up
with a heavily subsidized consumer side as an equilibrium (e.g. merchants tend
to pay for the bulk of card payment system costs). We note that regulators have
also invited themselves to the debate and are in some markets, such as the EU,
starting to regulate some of these platform fees. We will discuss some of these
aspects in more detail in Chapter 13 on the regulation of platform businesses.
Some of the principles that can be used to help determine the price struc-
ture, level and dynamics of platform businesses are discussed in Chapter 11.

A review of existing definitions


A number of other economists built upon the work of Rochet and Tirole
to propose slightly different economic models and apply the emerging corpus
of work on platforms to different industries and market sectors.12
24 What is a platform business?

Evans and Schmalensee subsequently offered a broader definition using the


notion of ‘economic catalyst’ with (i) two or more groups of customers; (ii)
who need each other in some way; (iii) but who cannot capture the value
of mutual interactions on their own; and (iv) rely on the catalyst to facilitate
value-creating interactions between them.13
Evans has since written extensively about multisided markets and catalyst
businesses in the context of payment networks and cards,14 as well as in broader
antitrust contexts.15 His definition of ‘catalyst’ businesses16 also has the merit
of decoupling the underlying economics of the markets being served and
the business model of the companies serving them. For example, previous
definitions of platforms that focused on the features of the market served,
rather than the platform businesses themselves, would not have considered
the taxi market as a multisided market (since it was initially served by tra-
ditional non-platform businesses). It is, however, undeniable that Uber
uses a platform-centric business model to disrupt a market that previously
operated in a traditional manner. We therefore prefer to refer to these as
platform businesses (or platform-powered ecosystems) rather than platform
markets.

Platforms as ‘catalysts’
Evans also proposed a broad classification of ‘catalysts’ consistent with his
original definition. The three main business types identified were: (i) market
makers; (ii) audience builders; and (iii) demand coordinators.
Although Evans considers all of these businesses as platforms, the distinctions
between them are important:

(i) Market makers: eBay has created a unique global marketplace where sellers
and buyers of an incredibly wide range of goods meet. eBay is valued at
more than $35 billion17 and generated in excess of $83 billion of Gross
Merchandise Value (GMV)18 in 2016 without offering any product
whatsoever, but simply by connecting buyers and sellers through its online
platform and being paid a small percentage of the transaction19 for this
facilitation. Uber and Airbnb are in the same category.
(ii) Audience builders: Some platforms focus on allowing users to share and/or
consume content. This in turn attracts advertisers who need ‘eyeballs’ for
their campaigns. Evans argues that media firms, and many publications,
operate in such ‘audience building’ multisided markets.
(iii) Demand coordinators: A third type of platform business focuses on coord-
inating demand within a given ecosystem. Unlike market makers, demand
coordinators often have a broader group of stakeholders and ecosystem
What is a platform business? 25

participants. Operating systems (OS) fall into this category since they are
designed for users, licensed by hardware manufacturers and used by
application developers. The more applications available for a given OS, the
higher its utility or value. At the same time, app developers are only able
to invest in the development required if there are either currently or
prospectively enough users of the OS to cover their costs and eventually
make a profit.

Economists also showed that since platforms were connecting two markets,
they had a unique ability to price differently from traditional businesses.
In fact, they noticed that platform businesses were able to offer free services
not simply on a temporary basis or during promotions, but on a sustainable
basis.20 This has far-reaching implications, since it means that the very basis
of competition can be dramatically changed by platforms and that non-
platform businesses may find themselves ‘priced out’ of the market. This
phenomenon will be discussed in more detail in Chapter 14, where we will
examine why existing firms struggle to compete against platform businesses
and what options are available to them.
Hagiu and Wright also proposed a focused definition of ‘multisided
platforms’ (MSP). Their proposed definition is:

Multisided platforms (MSPs) are organizations that create value primarily


by enabling direct interactions between two (or more) distinct types of
affiliated customers.21

This is a significant departure from previous market-based definitions. In


our view, it provides a helpful starting point for analysing platform businesses
because it deals with some of the ‘over-inclusiveness’ implied by broader
definitions. For example, it excludes supermarkets or traditional consulting
organizations that were sometimes wrongly considered to be platforms with
earlier definitions.
This definition is more circumspect regarding the platform nature of many
media companies: only media firms whose primary source of value creation
is the direct interaction between customer groups would strictly be included.
With that definition, many traditional newspapers don’t make the cut.
The recent global platform survey initiative22 led by Peter Evans and
Annabelle Gawer also dealt with the definition conundrum by using a high-
level typology of platforms, including transaction platforms, integrated
platforms, investment platforms and innovation platforms.
This is also consistent with the most recent definition proposed by Parker,
Van Alstyne and Choudary:23
26 What is a platform business?

Platform: A business based on enabling value-creating interactions between


external producers and consumers. The platform provides an open,
participative infrastructure for these interactions and sets governance
conditions for them. The platform’s overarching purpose is to consummate
matches among users and facilitate the exchange of goods, services or social
currency, thereby enabling value creation for all participants.

Building on these definitions, we believe that platforms should include organ-


izations that create value by enabling interactions, direct or indirect.
For us, platform businesses are ‘businesses creating significant value through
the acquisition, and/or matching, interaction and connection of two or more
customer groups to enable them to transact’.
This definition is consistent with platforms as marketplaces, as well as with
some types of information platforms matching consumers of content with con-
tent contributors. Platforms can connect consumers, or businesses, or a mix.24
Target groups on both sides of the platform often have different characteris-
tics, although in some cases, such as eBay, the overlap between buyers and
sellers can be significant.25 Our definition also includes businesses where the
connection between consumer groups is indirect, such as credit card companies
like Visa or Mastercard,26 where banks often act as intermediaries on the
consumer side (by distributing cards) and on the merchant side (by selling card
services to merchants).
However, our definition excludes businesses such as Netflix, considered to
be digital resellers. It also excludes companies such as Intel, which makes
computer chips, and IBM, which provides consulting services. However, we
recognize that these firms shape the development of key standards and
technologies – alone and in partnership with others – and have the potential
to become platform-powered ecosystems.
These differences in terms of definitions also highlight the fact that platform
businesses are not binary in nature, but can be placed on a ‘continuum’
depending on their underlying economics at a given point in time and how
much value the business derives from the transactions it enables. For example,
companies such as IBM did try to become fully fledged platforms by
developing their own operating systems (OS/2) to attract both application
developments and enterprise users. Since this initiative failed, IBM developed
alternative business models (hardware sales initially later abandoned in favour
of high-value technology consulting).
These notions will be revisited when we discuss platform ecosystems and their
governance in more detail. We will further explore how platforms often power
entire ecosystems and what the competition implications of such models are.
For example, the online resale model of Amazon (a linear business) and its
What is a platform business? 27

marketplace (a platform) are both crucial elements of the firm’s ecosystem.


A review of these platform-powered ecosystems will provide interesting
insights into the competitive dynamics of platforms and help us understand the
interplay between platform business models and traditional ones.

Platforms compared to other business models


Table 3.1 summarizes our proposed definitions of platforms and other tradi-
tional business models such as distributors and ‘input/output’ businesses.
The proposed definition focuses on the businesses serving these markets as
opposed to the market themselves, since the demand on the various sides of
the market can also sometimes be served by traditional businesses.
As a platform, eBay acquires, matches and connects buyers and sellers and
allows them to transact directly. Also, we note that eBay doesn’t set the price
of the goods that are being exchanged on its platform.27
As a UK retailer and a distributor, Tesco (like Walmart in the US, Metro
in Germany, Carrefour in France, etc.) resells goods from a selected range
of suppliers and distributes them through its network of shops, its online site28
and delivery services. Tesco owns the customer relationship, the pricing and
product placement of goods and services sold. It stocks the products, pays its
staff at the tills and (hopefully) makes a margin on its operations as a result
of all these activities. However, it doesn’t connect different communities to
allow them to transact. It is a distributor/reseller.
Honda produces a range of cars and motorbikes globally. In order to do
so, it acquires raw materials, as well as parts from suppliers, and assembles
them into cars that meet their Honda design specifications. Once the vehicles
are manufactured, they are distributed by a ‘reseller’, in this case the dealership
network. Honda’s business is essentially an ‘input’/’output’ business.29
It is, however, worth noting that traditional firms can transform themselves
into platforms or even in some cases add platform capabilities to their existing
business models, as we will discuss in later chapters.

Table 3.1 Simplified typology of platform and non-platform business models

Platform Retailer/reseller Input/output business


Acquires, matches and/or Buys goods and/or services Buys inputs (e.g. raw materials,
connects different customer from selected producers energy, services) and combines
groups and enables and runs a value-added them to produce a product/
transactions distribution business service sold at a margin
eBay Tesco Honda
28 What is a platform business?

Platform-powered ecosystems
As we have seen, companies such as Apple, Google, Amazon, Microsoft and
Facebook are among the largest in the world. Yet very few are pure platform
businesses. Instead, these successful companies are underpinned by a mix of
business models, including platforms, and are therefore ‘platform-powered’.
The term ‘ecosystem’ is often defined in a business context as a group of
interdependent organizations collectively providing goods and services to their
customers.30 A platform-powered ecosystem can then be defined as a group
of organizations – under the same ownership or strategically linked – that
derives significant value from at least one platform business.
These platform ecosystems leverage the interplay between the various
business models that are part of the ecosystem to reinforce customer
propositions and create stickiness, often with spectacular success. These ideas
will be further explored in Chapter 6.
With the definitions out of the way, we can examine management principles
in more detail and look under the hood of platforms.

PLATFORM-POWERED ECOSYSTEM
A business comprising of a mix of business models, including platforms.
Examples: Amazon, Apple, Google, Alibaba, Microsoft

Notes
1 The Oxford English Dictionary states that a platform is ‘a raised level surface on which
people or things can stand, usually a discrete structure intended for a particular activity
or operation’.
2 See A. Gawer, Platforms, Markets and Innovation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2009, p.
45, as well as Y. Baldwin and J. Woodard, The Architecture of Platforms: A Unified View,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School, 2009, for a discussion of the architecture of
platforms across disciplines.
3 S. Wheelwright and K. Clark, Revolutionizing Product Development: Quantum Leaps in
Speed, Efficiency and Quality, New York: Free Press, 1992.
4 T. Bresnahan and S. Greenstein, ‘Technological Competition and the Structure of the
Computer Industry’, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 47, 1999, 1–40.
5 J. Rochet and J. Tirole, ‘Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, Journal of the
European Economic Association, 1(4), 2003, 990–1029.
6 Strictly speaking, businesses need not be Internet-enabled to have a platform business
model (e.g. shopping malls or estate agents), but many of the platform businesses we
What is a platform business? 29

will review in this book are digital platforms that have harnessed the power of the Internet
and big data to develop their offerings, often globally.
7 Also called antitrust, competition economics is concerned with competition between
firms and potential abuse of market power justifying market intervention.
8 See, for example, W. Baxter, ‘Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and
Economic Perspectives’, Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 1983, 541–88, for an early
discussion of pricing considerations in card markets (interchange fees).
9 Geoffrey Parker and Marshall van Alstyne, ‘Information Complements, Substitutes,
and Strategic Product Design’, ICIS 2000 Proceedings, Paper 2, 2000.
10 We will see in Chapter 11 how important these new ‘platform equations’ are for pricing
strategies.
11 This meets the definition of Rochet and Tirole: ‘A market is two sided if the platf-
orm can affect the volume of transactions by charging more to one side of the market
and reducing the price paid by the other side by an equal amount; in other words, the
price structure matters, and the platform must design it so as to bring both sides on
board’.
12 See B. Caillaud and B. Jullien, ‘Chicken and Egg: Competition among Intermediation
Service Providers’, RAND Journal of Economics, 34(2), 2003, 309–28, who departed from
the payment cards industry to explore and model in more details the expected market
equilibrium of competing platforms (including estate agents, dating agencies and
marketplaces) under a range of scenarios. G. Parker and W. Van Alstyne, ‘Two-Sided
Network Effects: A Theory of Information Product Design’, Management Science, 51(10),
2005, 1494–504, subsequently developed a model of ‘two sided network externality’
capturing network effects, price discrimination and product differentiation. Mark
Armstrong, ‘Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3),
September 2006, 668–91, also proposed a model of multisided markets built upon similar
theoretical foundations (but focused on membership externalities, as opposed to usage
ones, as originally modelled by Rochet and Tirole) and offered a generic definition based
primarily on the scale of the benefits derived by one side of the market depending upon
the size of the other side.
13 Richard Schmalensee and David S. Evans, ‘Industrial Organization of Markets with Two-
Sided Platforms’, Competition Policy International, 3(1), Spring 2007.
14 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, Paying with Plastic: The Digital Revolution in Buying and
Borrowing, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2005, for a review of the economics of card
payments.
15 D. Evans, R. Schmalensee, M. Noel, H. Chang and D. Garcia-Swartz, ‘Platform
Economics: Essays on Multi-Sided Businesses’, Competition Policy International, 2011, for
competition issues arising in multisided businesses.
16 Also referred to as ‘matchmakers’. See D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, Matchmakers: The
New Economics of Multisided Platforms, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press,
2016.
17 As of 26 September 2016.
18 GMV stands for gross merchandise value and is used in online platforms to indicate a
total sales value for merchandise sold through a particular marketplace over a certain
time frame.
19 Typically final value fees are between 5% and 11% on eBay.
30 What is a platform business?

20 In fact, prices could even be negative on one side of the business on a sustainable basis.
See David S. Evans and Richard Schmalensee, ‘The Antitrust Analysis of Multi-Sided
Platform Businesses’ (Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics Working Paper
No. 623, 2012).
21 Andrei Hagiu and Julian Wright, ‘Multi-Sided Platforms’, Harvard Business School
Working Paper 12-024, October 2011.
22 P. Evans and A. Gawer, ‘The Rise of the Platform Enterprise’, Center for Global
Enterprise, January 2016.
23 G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York: W. W.
Norton & Company, 2016.
24 What marketers call B2B (business to business), B2C (business to consumer) and C2C
(consumer to consumer).
25 By targeting communities that are both buyers and sellers, such as stamps or rare coin
collectors in the early days of eBay, some platforms have been able to ignite their platform
more quickly and overcome some of the friction caused by the ‘chicken-and-egg’
problem, discussed in Chapter 8.
26 Card companies connect merchants and card users indirectly through merchant acquirers
and card issuers (usually banks).
27 While many platforms let their producers and users set the price themselves, some try
to internalize supply and demand to set uniform prices (e.g. Uber).
28 Many ecommerce sites today operate under a retailer/reseller model.
29 Please note that we are of course simplifying business typologies in order to illustrate
the differences between business models. For example, while Honda’s core business is
manufacturing ‘input’ and ‘output’ business for cars and engines, it also has significant
R&D activities in artificial intelligence and robotics.
30 ‘Business Ecosystem’, Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, London: Palgrave
Macmillan (2014).
Chapter 4

Economic characteristics
of platforms

This book is not an economics text, but knowledge of some economics


concepts is useful to understand how platforms differ from more traditional
firms. This chapter reviews some of the key economic principles underpinning
platform businesses. If you’re already familiar with the concepts of externalities,
demand- and supply-side economies of scale, network effects, critical mass,
tipping point, pricing elasticity, substitutes and complements, feel free to move
straight to the next chapter.

Externalities
We can all benefit from and be harmed by things that are not within our
control. When people join networks (be it social networks or telecoms
networks), all the other network users benefit since the network’s reach –
and therefore overall value – is increased. This is a positive externality since
all network users are better off as a result.
If a company were to dump toxic waste in the water next to a village, the
villagers would suffer a strong negative externality. Villagers are not responsible
for the behaviour of the firm, yet their lives are impacted by it. This is a
negative externality, and the company is not incurring the real cost of its
actions (unless it is caught).
An externality occurs when individuals or firms are impacted, positively
or negatively, by an economic transaction that is independent of them. Many
examples of externalities can be found in everyday life. Things as simple as
the pleasant scent of a perfume worn by a stranger in the underground can
be seen as a positive externality. A negative externality has the same properties,
but with a negative impact imposed by somebody else’s actions. A smoker
would be imposing a negative externality on people around him.
Clearly, externalities go far beyond personal inconvenience, and the toxic
waste of our factory in our previous example is a strong negative externality
on the people living nearby.
32 Economic characteristics of platforms

Externalities can also change over time. The rather disturbing noises made
by the builders next door excavating a basement as these lines are being written
are not helping with concentration in the short term. However, once com-
pleted, an extended and renovated house next door will have a positive impact
on the valuation of the street and therefore represent a positive externality
for nearby homeowners.
One reason why such negative externalities occur is that economic agents
may not be able (or willing) to internalize the effect they have on third parties.
If a factory were economically responsible for the well-being of the nearby
population, it would have strong incentives not to pollute as much.
Positive externalities are important for platforms, since when a platform
grows, both in terms of number of transactions and participants, it becomes
more valuable to all. For example, the more applications available on an app
store, the more attractive it becomes for users. Of course, the more users join
and interact on the platform, the more attractive the platform becomes for
app developers trying to reach users.1
As in the Apple App Store example, when positive externalities exist on
both sides of a platform, positive feedback loops appear and amplify growth.
Enabling and enhancing these loops with a frictionless customer experience
and the right features for users is a key objective of platform businesses.
The term ‘internalizing the externalities’ is sometimes used, and sounds
more complicated than it is. It simply means that some firms and organizations
may need or want to take into account these externalities in their businesses.
So a pollution tax can help firms internalize the negative externalities associated
with pollution because it gives them an incentive to pollute less.

Economies of scale
Economies of scale are said to exist when the unit cost of production goes
down with the volume of production. Many businesses requiring significant
upfront investments benefit from economies of scale since the more units are
produced by a factory or plant, the lower the unit costs. The cost of production
of cars is highly dependent upon how many cars can be manufactured by a
given factory/car plant. If the production is very small, say 10 cars, the total
cost of the factory will have to be covered by these very few cars and result
in a very high unit cost. Car production is therefore said to benefit from
economies of scale, as more cars produced will allow for the shared cost of
production (including R&D) to be spread across more cars and will therefore
be lower on a per car basis. The logical strategic implication of industries
with economies of scale is that you need to become the largest company in
the sector in order to enjoy the lowest cost base per unit.
Economic characteristics of platforms 33

These economies of scale affect the supply side, that is to say the company
producing the goods. Recently, however, the concept of ‘demand-side’
economies of scale has become quite widespread. In networks, the value of
the service provided increases with the number of users because of the positive
externalities we discussed above. Economists therefore describe these network
businesses as benefiting from ‘demand-side’ economies of scale. Strictly
speaking, this is no longer about the cost of production (supply) going down
with volume, but about the value created for users (demand) going up with
the number of users.
The concept of ‘demand-side economies of scale’ is also referred to as
network effects. It is so central to the economics of platforms that we develop
it further below.

Networks and network effects


Networks are characterized by nodes interconnected by links. Networks can
be physical, such as telecommunications networks where copper pairs are
physically connected to premises, or logical – where the connection exists as
a piece of information – such as when you are connected to friends on social
media. Networks have a range of properties and topologies. They can connect
different types of nodes (heterogeneous), the links can be unidirectional or
bidirectional, the nodes can be more or less meshed, etc.
These distinctions are important when we discuss features of platform busi-
nesses. For example, does the platform allow two-way communication
between participants (e.g. friends on Facebook) or one-way communica-
tion (e.g. celebrities followed on Twitter), and what are the implications
of these network rules? For our purpose, platform businesses are powered by
these communities of producers and users that can be helpfully modelled and
explained using network concepts.
Network effects occur when a product or service becomes more valuable
as more people use it. This can be counter-intuitive, since with traditional
business models the opposite can be true, and the value of an exclusive
luxury car does not increase – and may actually decrease – if another one is
produced (or bought by a neighbour). However, having more collectors
(buyers and sellers) on eBay clearly increases the value of the overall platform
since the sellers will add inventory and the buyers will provide liquidity to
the platform and increase the number of transactions. Unlike traditional
businesses, platforms often exhibit network effects, and these have profound
competitive implications.
Figure 4.1 illustrates the number of relationships in a network with two,
five and 12 connected parties. The number of links in the network increases
34 Economic characteristics of platforms

Figure 4.1 Network effects

‘exponentially’, with one, 10 and 66 relationships (and therefore possible


connections), respectively.2
The relationship between the value of a network and its size, or between
its utility and the numbers of transactions, has been modelled in a number of
different contexts to help quantify network effects.3
Network effects can be:

(i) Direct: as in telecommunications, where the value of the network increases


directly with the numbers of users connected to it. This is also what
happens with ‘peer-to-peer’ or social networks, where more users tend
to benefit the entire platform.
(ii) Indirect: as in operating systems or app stores where the value of the
network increases not only with the number of users (direct), but with
the number of application developers attracted by the growing user base
(indirect effect). Indirect network effects result in positive feedback loops
across the platform as more developers creating more apps then attract
more users, and more users make the platform more attractive to
developers. Games consoles, operating systems and app stores are typical
platforms exhibiting strong indirect network effects.

Mature platforms such as Alibaba, eBay or Craigslist benefit from huge


indirect network effects. More than 423 million active buyers4 make an average
of 58 purchases a year5 on Alibaba; 25 million sellers6 with 1 billion listings
attract 164 million active buyers on eBay;7 and Craigslist8 users post well over
80 million classified ads each month.
It is worth noting that network effects can also be induced by platforms
and maximized or internalized through platform design and governance
decisions. For example, features that allow users to provide feedback on their
Economic characteristics of platforms 35

experiences add value to the platform. It increases direct network effects, as


the more users participate by giving feedback on books on Amazon or flats
on Airbnb, the better the information to other users. By the same token,
gaming platforms provide software development kits and a range of incentives
for developers to select their platform over other competing ones. They do
this to maximize indirect network effects since more and better games will
attract more buyers of the game console itself.
Network effects are very important since they can represent a significant
barrier to entry for competitors and therefore contribute to protecting a
business. In certain circumstances, network effects may lead a platform to reach
a ‘critical mass’, and even in some markets ‘tip’ to a ‘winner takes all’ natural
equilibrium, where a single business ends up serving the entire market.
Network effects are not just about the number of platform participants,
but about their propensity to interact on the platform as well. Inactive users
contribute less to network effects on a platform than active ones that participate
frequently. In real life, platforms often benefit from – and have to manage –
a combination of different types of network effects. For example, Facebook
started with direct network effects since Harvard students found it easier to
connect to one another once their entire class had joined. These effects were
later combined with indirect network effects with the addition of developers
on the platform offering games and applications (e.g. Farmville, horoscopes,
etc.). After proving that it could scale its free services, Facebook started
monetizing its business by inviting advertisers to the platform and allowing
them to target very specific segments of platform participants.9 It is worth
noting that while network effects may lead to viral growth, the two concepts
are distinct. A new book can become very successful and be bought/
downloaded by lots of people very quickly (viral growth) but have no network
effect (since new readers do not add value to previous ones).

Critical mass
A critical mass in a network is defined as the point at which the growth of
the network becomes ‘self-sustaining’.
In the context of platform businesses, critical mass may be required on both
sides of the market and is driven by a number of variables, including the type
and strength of network effects, customer behaviours and the distribution of
customer tastes.10 While scaling a nascent platform is particularly difficult,
because it often has limited network effects due to its small size, reaching
critical mass makes growth and participant matching much easier.
Platforms that do not reach critical mass often unravel. In the case of direct
network effects, the level of participation on the platform affects the value it
36 Economic characteristics of platforms

offers to users. Platforms without critical mass often struggle to match


participants. For example, if a new dating site launches but does not have
female participants on day one, male participants are unlikely to find a suitable
match. If the platform is not able to match people – which is its raison d’être
– then it unravels as early adopters leave.11 We will see in Chapter 7 how to
overcome these issues.

Tipping point
Closely related to the notion of critical mass, the tipping point is defined as
the point at which a network ‘shifts’ from one state (e.g. competition, or
normal trading activities) to another one (e.g. monopoly, or market unravel-
ling) due to cumulative network effects. Numerous examples of markets
exhibiting such effects have been widely documented in Malcolm Gladwell’s
book Tipping Point.12 The definition offered by Gladwell is broader, but
overlaps with the critical mass concept discussed above: ‘the moment of critical
mass, the threshold, the boiling point’.
The tipping point is therefore an inflection point that, in the case of plat-
forms, is often synonymous with reaching critical mass. Early social networking
sites SixDegrees and Friendster never found the elusive tipping point in their
growth trajectory that would have allowed them to reach a critical mass. The
customer experience was lacking and there was not enough for users to do,
mainly because there were not enough users! Caught in a negative feedback
loop, these platforms unravelled fairly quickly.

Single homing vs multihoming


Multihoming essentially means being connected to more than one network,
usually for increased reliability, resilience or performance. In the context of
platforms, it simply means participating in more than one platform.
For example, an application developer may decide to offer its app on both
iOS and Android platforms (multihoming on the producer side), while many
individuals only use one mobile phone and therefore need to commit to
a given platform or ‘single home’ with, say, either iOS or Android. The
decision to single home or multihome is typically driven by a cost–benefit
analysis that will need to answer the following questions: How expensive is
it to affiliate to more than one platform? What are the added benefits of doing
so? How easy is it to switch between platforms?
This is an important concept since the decision between single homing
and multihoming by users and producers will determine to a large extent how
Economic characteristics of platforms 37

easy it will be for the platform to reach a critical mass and gain market power.
For example, while it may be more difficult to ignite a platform when users
single home, if successful the platform then becomes more valuable since
a critical mass of users are committed. Of course, the platform itself can
shape the decisions of its participants by trying to seek exclusivity (e.g. for
game developers to single home), reducing switching costs from other
established platforms (e.g. by offering a ‘converter’ or compatibility with
other platform features) or trying to appear as the ‘winning’ platform, through
advertising and endorsements, to make sure users don’t feel the need to
look elsewhere. We will also see in Chapter 13 that the extent to which
multihoming is possible has implications for regulators and competition
authorities.

Price elasticity
We all know that the demand for products and services changes depending
on their price. If the price of baked beans goes up, people will buy fewer
cans – and vice versa, if the price goes down, more baked beans are sold.
The price elasticity of demand reflects this by giving the percentage change
in quantity demanded for a 1% change in price. It is the quantitative arti-
culation of the question ‘How many more cans of baked beans will I sell if
I decrease the price by 1%?’
A small change in price of some goods sometimes results in a large change
in demand. Traditional baked beans or chocolate bars would be in this cate-
gory and are therefore said to have a high price elasticity.
The demand for other types of goods doesn’t change much when prices
change. This is the case for cigarettes or petrol, where customers are either
addicted or really need to buy in order to go from A to B. These goods have
a low price elasticity.
Often, the decision to not buy something because the price has increased
is driven by the fact that other, cheaper alternatives may exist. So if you are
no longer buying baked beans because their prices have increased, you may
be buying black-eyed beans instead. When that is the case, the products are
said to be substitutes (see section below) and the relationship between the
increase of price of one product and the increase of demand of the other one
is called ‘cross-price elasticity’. The relationships between the interplay of prices
on two sides of a platform are discussed in more details in Chapter 11. This
concept of cross-price elasticity is also central to understanding substitute and
complement products.
38 Economic characteristics of platforms

Substitutes vs complements
Two products are deemed substitutes when the demand for one increases as
the price of the other increases. The concept is rather intuitive, and we all
review daily the characteristics of dozens of substitute products when shopping.
If the price of our favourite brand of butter has increased significantly, we
may want to switch to another – substitute – brand. The more substitutable
the products, the more they exert competitive pressure on one another.
Complements are the opposite. Products are said to be complements if the
increase in price of one leads to a decrease of demand for the other. While
this may sound slightly less intuitive, complementary products abound. Printers
and their cartridges (or razors and their blades) are typical complements. If
the price of a printer increases (everything else being equal), it is likely to sell
less, and the subsequent demand (in the aftermarket) for its ink cartridges will
decrease. These products are complements.13 In the same way, apps available
on Apple’s App Store are complements of its iPhone product.
This distinction between substitutes and complements is useful to better
understand the disruptions brought about by platform businesses. While
their operations are often very different from those of traditional busi-
nesses, the products and services they offer are often close substitutes to existing
ones.

Notes
1 In the context of platform businesses, Jean-Charles Rochet and Jean Tirole, ‘Two-Sided
Markets: A Progress Report’, The RAND Journal of Economics, 35(3), 2006, 645–67, made
an interesting observation about the different types of externalities that exist. They
distinguish between usage externalities and membership externalities. Usage external-
ities occur (as their name indicates) when the platform adds value through interactions
and transactions (e.g. usage) by existing members. Membership externalities exist when
the value received by users of the platform on one side of the market increases with the
number of users on the other side of the market.
2 The total number of relationships (T) in a network of n participants is given by the
formula: T = n(n – 1) / 2.
3 Metcalfe’s law states that the value of a network is proportional to the square of its users
(e.g. Facebook). Reed’s law states that the increase in value is not only proportional,
but exponential, due to the number of subgroups joining the network (e.g. Slack).
Beckstrom’s law states that the value is the net value to participants of all the transactions
carried over the network. Lastly, Sarnoff’s law states that the value of some networks is
proportional to the number of viewers (e.g. Yahoo).
4 Alibaba.com, March 2016 numbers for Taobao and Tmall marketplaces, www.alibaba-
group.com/en/ir/financial_fullyear
5 Fortune, 23 September 2016, http://fortune.com/2015/09/23/alibaba-says-numbers-
real-not-fake/. Each package could contain more than one item.
Economic characteristics of platforms 39

6 eBay.com, https://static.ebayinc.com/static/assets/Uploads/PressRoom/eBay-Factsheet-
Q2-2015.pdf
7 eBay.com, Q2 2016 numbers, https://investors.ebayinc.com/releasedetail.cfm?Release
ID=980435
8 Craigslist website, www.craigslist.org/about/factsheet
9 Well-known venture capital firm Andreessen Horowitz, one of the early financial
backers of Airbnb, knows a thing or two about network effects. See the excellent pre-
sentation and companion article of Anu Harianna et al. on their site: http://a16z.
com/2016/03/07/all-about-network-effects/
10 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, ‘Failure to Launch: Critical Mass in Platform Businesses’,
Review of Network Economics, 9(4), 2010, for a discussion on platforms failing to reach
critical mass.
11 Using the dating analogy, it is interesting to note that since female dating site members
appear to be more difficult to attract on platforms, these have to work extra hard to
ensure that they manage to reach a critical mass. This may include incentives (e.g. free
service), or even in some extreme cases the creation of false profiles to ‘appear’ to have
a critical mass! See the FTC ruling on online dating services using fake profiles, www.
ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2014/10/online-dating-service-agrees-stop-
deceptive-use-fake-profiles, or even ‘female chatbots’, which Ashley Madison claimed
in its defence were ‘widespread’ in this area.
12 See M. Gladwell, The Tipping Point: How Little Things Can Make a Big Difference, Boston,
MA: Little Brown, 2000, for a discussion on markets subject to tipping points.
13 We note, however, that platforms differ from products with an aftermarket in that, while
demand is also interlinked, platform businesses involve two distinct groups of customers,
as opposed to a single buyer of a product and its ‘after-products’. See S. Bishop and
M. Walker, ‘The Economics of EC Competition Law’, European Competition Journal,
6(1), 2010, p. 93, for examples of markets with after-products.
Chapter 5

Platforms as business models

Representation of firm activities

The linear firm


Traditional firms really took off following the Industrial Revolution around
the 1800s, and thus are a relatively recent construct in historical terms. Since
then, they have often been analysed by strategists, business consultants and
economists in a very linear way. It is interesting to start there before comparing
and contrasting traditional business models with platform ones. The overrid-
ing model of the firm historically used is predicated upon companies buying
raw material (inputs) and transforming them into outputs before selling to
downstream customers at a profit (hopefully). The success of these businesses
is typically driven by their ability to buy efficiently (low input costs), add
value (through design, efficient manufacturing, etc.) and sell resulting pro-
ducts and services with a high margin (through distribution networks, retail
shops, etc.).
Car manufacturers take raw materials such as steel and plastic, then design
and assemble parts to create vehicles. Coca-Cola combines sugar, water and
other well-guarded ingredients to produce one of the world’s most popu-
lar beverages. While the model is rooted in manufacturing, it also applies
to services. British Airways manages its fleet of airplanes, crew, logistics, in-
flight services, etc. to offer short- and long-haul flight services. In the case of
British Airways, its inputs are planes, oil and personnel, and the output is the
transport service provided to customers.
These firms have been described in the business literature as input/output
businesses or as ‘pipes’ because of their linear nature.1 We also refer to them
as ‘traditional’ businesses in this book.
42 Platforms as business models

Figure 5.1 The linear firm

Porter’s value chain


In the 1980s, Michael Porter was one of the first academic to codify and
formalize how firms create value.2 The concept of the ‘value chain’ was
introduced and popularized in his 1985 bestseller, Competitive Advantage:
Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. Today, the traditional value chain
is still the dominant frame of reference in business. It describes how a linear
set of activities and processes are organized by a firm to maximize the value
added to inputs of production.
Porter presented the concept of the value chain as the basic tool for
examining the activities a company performs and their interactions to identify
the sources of sustainable competitive advantage. It separates the activities of
a firm into a sequential stream of activities, as illustrated in Figure 5.2. It
describes the importance of the different activities in delivering the final
product/service, thereby facilitating the identification of core and non-core
activities:

• Core or primary activities are involved with a product’s physical creation,


sale and distribution to buyers, and service after sale. They include inbound
logistics, operations, outbound logistics, marketing and sales, and service.
These activities are termed ‘primary’ because they add value to the product
or those involved in either producing or selling the product.
• Non-core or support activities are generic processes supporting the core
activities of the firm. Procurement, technology development, human
resource management and infrastructure are typical examples of non-core
activities.

In this environment, a business gains ‘competitive advantage’ by performing


these activities either more cheaply than its competitors (low cost strategy)
or in a unique way that creates superior customer value and commands a
price premium (differentiation).
Platforms as business models 43

Figure 5.2 Michael Porter’s value chain (1985)


Source: Adapted from M. E. Porter’s Competitive Advantage

If we take the example of a car manufacturing business, the primary acti-


vities can be described as follows:

• Inbound logistics: receiving, storing and distributing inputs (e.g. handling


of raw materials, warehousing, inventory control).
• Operations: transformation of the inputs into the final product form (e.g.
car production, assembly, packaging).
• Outbound logistics: collecting, storing and distributing cars to the buyers
(e.g. processing of orders, warehousing of cars, delivery).
• Marketing and sales: identification of customer needs and generation of
sales (e.g. advertising, promotion, distribution).
• Service: maintain value after purchase (e.g. installation, repair, maintenance,
training).

Each function can in turn be broken down into smaller components or


processes for optimization. This representation of the firm goes hand in hand
with Porter’s five forces framework, which states that the competitive position
of the firm is driven by the negotiating power of clients, the negotiating
power of suppliers, the threat of substitutes, the threat of new entrants and
lastly the rivalry in the sector. Within Porter’s framework, a strong competitive
advantage for your own value chain is predicated upon fragmented markets
44 Platforms as business models

with lots of buyers and suppliers (unable to negotiate), as well as barriers to


entry to avoid new competitors and a product with no or limited substitutes,
as well as few direct competitors.3
The traditional linear model is under strain, though. Modern innovation-
driven firms are less linear and more open as the process of adding value may
be shared between the firm, partners, stakeholders and customers. It is in this
context that the business model canvas was collaboratively developed a few
years ago under the leadership of Alex Osterwalder.4

The business model canvas


Looking at existing frameworks, the business model canvas provides a good
strategic management tool. It is generic enough to work with different types
of business models, linear and non-linear, and can be applied to start-ups or
corporate environments.
The framework is made of nine basic building blocks that are mapped in
a pre-structured canvas:

1 customer segments or communities for which value is created;


2 the value proposition for each segment;

Figure 5.3 The business model canvas


Source: The Business Model Canvas, Creative Commons license, https://strategyzer.com/
Platforms as business models 45

3 channels needed to reach customers;


4 customer relationships;
5 the revenue streams generated by the business;
6 key resources used by the firm;
7 key activities required to create value;
8 key partners; and
9 the cost structure of the business model.

The business model canvas is less linear than the value chain model and
can be applied to map out the key activities of a wide range of business models,
including platforms. Let’s take the example of Airbnb:

1 Customer segments: Airbnb serves two interdependent customer segments:


the guests (personal and business travellers) and the hosts (residential asset
owners).
2 Value proposition: A trusted community marketplace for people to list,
discover and book unique accommodation around the world. For hosts,
it enables them to monetize their house in a safe environment.
3 Channels: Mainly through online marketing with: (i) referrals; and (ii) paid
advertising.
4 Customer relationships: hosts and guests.
5 Revenue streams: Airbnb’s model is commission-based. Hosts are charged
about 3% and guests between 6% and 12%.5
6 Key resources: Airbnb’s digital and mobile infrastructure, access to capital,
physical (staff and offices).
7 Key activities: Maintain and develop the online platform including key
product features for hosts and guests – to match hosts and guests, connect
them, enable safe payments, develop and maintain a trusted environment,
manage communities and market the service.
8 Key partners: Technical partners (hosting, database and payment services),
insurance companies, management service companies supporting hosts
(Guesty in the US, Hostmaker in Europe), venture capital firms (VCs).
9 Cost structure: Main costs are related to marketing and sales (advertising,
recruiting and opening new offices abroad), technology (platform
development and maintenance) and legal.

While a very useful framework when trying to quickly map a new business
model in creative sessions, this framework does not explicitly capture key
success factors of platforms, but rather makes it easier to overlay traditional
businesses operations onto a platform business model.6
46 Platforms as business models

The rocket model


As we worked with platforms, it became increasingly clear that the traditional
management frameworks were not suitable. And that’s why we developed
the rocket model: a high-level functional model of platform businesses based
on the core activities of firms serving multisided markets. Typically, we find
that platforms need to:
• attract a critical mass of customers on each side of the market;
• match them;
• allow them to connect;
• enable them to transact; and
• optimize their own operations and ecosystem iteratively.
Launching a multisided platform requires a lot of energy in the same way
as launching a rocket into space does. You need to recruit at least two sides
of the market, and run development and marketing for each side. In a way,
igniting a platform is not different from launching two companies at the same
time. You also need to scale your user base in order to reach a critical mass
on both sides of your platform, a challenging hurdle that doesn’t exist for
traditional businesses. On the plus side, once the rocket has reached a critical
mass, it requires less ‘power’ to propel itself. It has reached ‘escape velocity’
and is subject to less ‘gravity’ thanks to network effects.
Figure 5.4 presents the rocket model and associated functional stages.

Figure 5.4 The rocket model


Source: Launchworks
Platforms as business models 47

Attract
This building block encompasses the characteristics, features and processes by
which a platform is able to attract producers and users. In management
literature, it is also referred to as the ‘magnet’7 or the ‘catalyst’.8 The functions
performed at the attraction stage evolve over the life cycle of a platform and
need to be reviewed on a regular basis. At launch, the attract function is pri-
marily focused on acquiring and hooking new customers, but as the platform
matures, retention starts to play a bigger part. While ultimately what will attract
users and producers on the platform are opportunities to transact with one
another, the design of the value proposition for each side is a critical driver of
attraction. Since platform businesses are subject to network effects, attracting
a critical mass of platform participants, on both sides of the platform, is key to
its long-term success. We will review a number of attraction strategies available
at ignition in Chapter 8.
The attraction – and subsequent management – of a community of users
and producers on a platform (or buyers and sellers in the case of a marketplace)
is quite different from the acquisition of clients in a traditional business. In
fact, some of the thinking that traditional firms apply to the recruitment,
management and motivation of their own employees is relevant to plat-
form participants since they also contribute to the value delivered by the
platform. Consumers will provide valuable feedback and ratings while
producers will ultimately be key to the experience enabled by the platform
since they will be providing their flat, their car, their content, etc. through
the platform. Therefore, identifying high-potential users and producers,
training them, incentivizing them and retaining them, or even ‘terminating
them’ – terms typically used more for employees than clients – is a key part
of the platform attract function. We discuss the different priorities for the
attract function across the various stages of platform development, from design
to maturity, in Chapters 7–9.

Match
In order for both sides to interact, they need to be introduced first. For Airbnb,
that involves presenting guests with the right properties in the right locations
at the right time; for Upwork, a global talent platform, it’s matching com-
panies with a specific assignment with available freelancers who have the right
skill set.
The quality of the matching is critical to the success of the platform. While
early adopters may be more interested by the concept and availability of
relevant platform participants, matching becomes increasingly important as
the platform scales. In a world of abundance, the ability to filter and present
48 Platforms as business models

customers with the right choices creates value. For matching to be effective
for participants, results must meet participant needs (relevance), be timely and
present the right amount of information or depth. The latter means that the
matching function should be optimized to return enough search results for
the user to find a relevant match but not so many as to overwhelm the user
with too much information.
The matching function can also play a key role in helping the platform
maximize positive network effects. For example, Amazon Marketplace
prioritizes product search results on best price but the search algorithm
de-prioritizes merchants with poor feedback. This ensures that consumers are
less likely to buy from merchants that provide bad customer experiences, and
ultimately leave the platform.
There are different ways to match participants. Matching can be done
through a search function with selected parameters for product marketplaces,
such as eBay or Amazon. For service platforms, a specific graphic interface
tailored to the focus of the platform (e.g. geo-localized maps for Airbnb)
is often used. Sometimes, the matching function uses the information that
both sides of the market have provided to the platform, such as pictures and
description on a dating site.
The complexity of the matching function depends on a number of factors.
Horizontal platforms, with a wide range of products and services, usually
require stronger search or matching functions than vertical ones that are more
specialized. In some cases, however, the matching function is almost implied
rather than explicit. This is often the case with payment networks (i.e.
merchants are not actively matched with cardholders, although ‘Amex accepted
here’ signs may help).9 The matching function can also be a mix of search
and self-selection.
Ideally, the matching function is configured to provide the optimal level of
choice required for a successful transaction. Some economists assume that
maximizing choices is always a good thing, yet we find that this is not always
the case and can in fact result in reduced transactions.10 Finding the right
balance between too many choices, which would confuse buyers, and not
enough options, which would drive buyers away, is not an easy task. A curated,
prioritized, relevant and timely selection maximizing the likelihood of
transactions occurring is therefore the nirvana of platforms. This ideal matching
will differ from one user to another, and therefore needs to be personalized.

Connect
Often, platform participants need to exchange additional information with
their counterparty before moving on to the transaction stage. With dating
Platforms as business models 49

platforms, the matching function may be based on a range of criteria provided


by the platform, such as age, gender and location, but additional information
about occupation, tastes, interests, where to meet up, etc. is also helpful to
the dating process. It is the same with eBay when buyers ask specific questions
to sellers before making an acquisition (Has the car been involved in any
accidents?). This platform function also increases the trust of the parties and
reduces the ‘asymmetry of information’11 that may get in the way of the
transaction.
The connect stage will also depend upon how much information has been
shared with the participants prior to the matching stage. If all the relevant
information is already available and the nature of the transaction is such that
there is little uncertainty as to the outcome (e.g. a basic undifferentiated
product or service), then the connect stage can even be skipped altogether
(although the platform may want to ensure it has the capabilities to enable it
should participants need it for other types of transactions).
Platforms have to make sure their connect function minimizes the risk of
‘leakages’, that is to say of clients deciding to transact outside the platform
after having been connected through the platform. In a way, many platforms
face a self-imposed competitive constraint: if they do not add enough value,
they will be bypassed and unable to recapture the value they created in
matching and connecting people. In some unusually high-value/one-off
purchase categories (e.g. cars, floorboards, etc.), marketplaces often suffer from
significant ‘leakage’, with a very high percentage of transactions initiated but
not completed on the platform. We will look at price-based mitigation
strategies in Chapter 11.

Transact
Platforms enable a wide range of interactions among their ecosystem partici-
pants. In many cases, it is information, rather than money, that is exchanged
with the platform and its participants. Think, for example, of a like on
Facebook, a vote on Reddit, a rating on eBay or a comment on TripAdvisor.
The fact that no money changes hands during these interactions doesn’t mean
that they are not very valuable for the platform.12
Out of all the interactions participants have with the platform, some really
crystallize the raison d’être of the platform. We call these core transactions.
Examples include a sale on eBay, a successful hire with LinkedIn, a date with
Match.com or a click on a Google sponsored ad. These core transactions are
supported by other interactions that enable the overall value proposition.
The platform should be optimized to maximize the number of core
transactions and supporting interactions. It is important to note that both
50 Platforms as business models

interactions and core transactions need to be considered from the point of view
of each platform participant since they may be different for users, producers,
the platform owner, the advertisers, etc. Ultimately, the value of a platform
business will be driven by its ability to both maximize the total number of value-
adding interactions and core transactions and to capture a share of this value
through direct or indirect monetization. The platform design phase taking place
before launch should be approached with this objective in mind.
Value capture at the platform level may not be directly aligned with
interactions creating the most value between participants. There is direct
alignment for eBay, which takes a commission on the value of each success-
ful sale (a core transaction). However, dating sites rarely charge you when
you go on a date, as the core transaction for participants is difficult for the
platform to monitor. So dating platforms find ways to charge for other
interactions that lead to dates (including membership fee, a fee per message
for communicating with your matches or a fee to appear on top of searches).
While pricing is often discussed as part of the transact stage,13 it is a broad
topic closely related to the overall governance of the platform and is covered
in Chapter 11.

Optimize
This last optimization stage is iterative and represents an absolutely critical
process for continuous enhancement of the platform. Given the dynamic
nature of platform businesses, this data-driven function allows platform busi-
nesses to find the right balance between the two sides of the market and to
optimize all the matching, connecting and transacting functions of the
platform. Google’s search algorithm is constantly optimized with several A/B
tests14 a day to ensure the best and most relevant search results are provided.
In fact, many platforms see their early development as a portfolio of experi-
ments and hypotheses that need to be tested.
When a bottleneck forms at one of the stages of value creation, manage-
ment’s attention can almost immediately focus on the issue. While traditio-
nal marketplaces such as estate agents are types of platforms that have existed
offline for centuries, we note the technology that enables advanced use of
near real-time analytics on customer data has only been available relatively
recently.
Online platforms almost always capture, store and analyse vast amounts of
data so hypotheses can be formed and tested. As such, data can be considered
an ‘input of production’, as well as a ‘strategic asset’ and even a tradable good.
Platforms increasingly use unique performance indicators and dashboards to
track their progress. Selected platform success metrics can be mapped onto
the rocket framework to provide a holistic way of monitoring performance
Platforms as business models 51

and identifying bottlenecks. These metrics can apply to stages of the rocket,
but also to the wider ecosystem of producers, users and partners.
The concept of ‘big data’ is part of the organizational DNA of most online
platforms, and continuous monitoring of potential bottlenecks can unlock
growth in near real time. Many platforms are so adept at these types of analytics
that they are now applying these tools across their businesses to generate new
management insights. Google regularly generates insights into questions such
as ‘What makes a successful team?’ or ‘What is the most efficient recruitment
process?’ through the use of analytics. We discuss the implication of data usage
by platforms across their life stages in more detail in Chapters 7–10.

Platform enablers
A platform is supported by key enablers across all the stages of the rocket
model. We typically refer to governance, trust and brand as strategic enablers,
and to IT infrastructure, user interface and payment systems as key enablers.

Strategic enablers
Governance is the set of rules, norms and policies that the platform adheres to
in order to build its ecosystem. Platform governance principles deal with
questions such as: Who is allowed on the platform? What behaviours are
rewarded? How are disputes between platform participants handled?

Trust is what makes people believe that the platform participants they engage
with are reliable, credible and honest. It’s a set of principles, rules, filters,
processes and tools enabling participants to interact and transact in a safe envi-
ronment. High trust encourages interactions and core transactions by reducing
the asymmetry of information between participants. Without trust, many
platforms would struggle to gain any scale. It is thanks to the trust-building
features of social media that many people started to be comfortable with the
idea of having a ‘stranger’ rent their flat (Airbnb) or use their car (Turo) while
they are away.

Brand is also a key enabler that works in tandem with trust. The brand building
for platforms is a slightly trickier exercise than for other business models, since
much of the experience is directly influenced by other platform participants.
Platforms therefore need to internalize the needs and wants of their
communities and capture this in key brand attributes. Platforms such as
Airbnb are taking this brand management process, in which platform
participants co-create the overall experience, very seriously and use it as a
way of differentiating themselves.15
52 Platforms as business models

In fact, governance, trust and brand are strategic enablers so important for
platforms that they deserve their own chapter (Chapter 12).

Other key enablers


IT infrastructure is a key component of successful platform businesses. We use
the term generically to capture the systems and software resources required
to power platform businesses. This includes software stacks, databases, servers,
apps, code, application programming interfaces (APIs), cloud access etc. These
IT capabilities end up powering the platform and supporting key functions
of the rocket. IT capabilities can also be leveraged for platforms to excel at
some key functions such as matching. As Mike Curtis, Airbnb VP of engin-
eering, recently declared, ‘Everything that we do in engineering is about
creating great matches between people’. In fact, more than 70% of Airbnb
IT resources are reported to be focused on analytics and machine learning,
compared to only 30% for the Web-facing part of the business.16

User experience. Some platforms, such as Facebook, have an online-only user


experience (including mobile), while others have a mix of online and offline
experience, such as Airbnb or Uber. Online, the user experience is made of
user journeys and touchpoints with the platform and participants. But unlike
linear businesses, which have control on the user experience end to end, a big
part of the platform user experience, online and/or offline, is in fact delivered
by participants themselves. Platforms have little control but can nonetheless
influence positive outcomes over negative ones. Anyone can list their home
on Airbnb, but Airbnb has the capacity to prioritize hosts with the highest
feedback in search results. This way of operating is a significant departure from
the ‘value chain’ model of traditional firms, where end-to-end control of the
product is often taken for granted. A good way for platforms to improve the
user experience is often to increase their scale to benefit from network effects
and offer choice and liquidity to both users and producers.

Payments are often key to the platform function and a critical step to enabling its
core transactions. The design of a ‘frictionless’ payment experience is therefore
critical to the overall success of many platform businesses. Increasingly, solutions
tailored to the needs of platforms, such as Mangopay or Stripe Connect, offer
convenient ways of enabling global and secure payment capabilities.

Together, these enabling activities play a critical role in the success of the
platform.
Platforms as business models 53

Strengths and weaknesses of platform business models


We have talked a lot so far about the success of platforms and described some
of their unique features, but it would be wrong to think that platforms are
superior business models in their own right. In fact, it is very important to
recognize that each business model has strengths and weaknesses. Traditional
business models are often better suited to serving specific groups of consumers
thanks to an enhanced control of the value chain, as well as the ability to
curate a product selection (or even bundle complementary products) in ways
that platform businesses can’t manage as efficiently. Traditional business models
also enable complete control of the customer experience from end to end,
something platform models cannot deliver.
Conversely, platform businesses provide a unique opportunity to manage
cost effectively and provide a long tail of products or services. They enable
market discovery of successful producers. They can also scale rapidly once
critical mass has been reached by connecting large groups and commun-
ities of ‘platform participants’. This is, however, often achieved at the cost of
relatively complex management and governance decisions, trade-offs and
arbitrages compared to other more traditional business models.17
eBay did not tightly control the various product categories that initially
developed on its platform,18 although it did orient its investments towards
specific categories over time19 to stimulate and shape its growth trajectory.
This was largely based on trial and error at the beginning, but eBay learned
how to kick off the development of some categories, raise awareness in relevant

Table 5.1 Economic strengths and weaknesses of selected business models

Platform Retailer/ Input/Output


Reseller Business
Connects several groups of customers
Market discovery
Control of value chain
Control of customer experience
Supports long tail inventory
Potential for Hyper growth
Management complexity
Examples eBay Tesco Honda
Note: In this illustrative table, a full circle means that the business has the stated characteristic, while an
empty circle means the opposite.
Source: Adapted from Hagiu, A and Wright, J (2013) Marketplace or Reseller?, Launchworks analysis
54 Platforms as business models

communities, create a critical mass of platform participants and then move


on to another relevant and complementary category for the platform. In some
ways, eBay followed the ‘bowling pin’ strategy that we will develop further
when focusing on platform ignition in Chapter 8.
Table 5.1 illustrates the strengths and weaknesses of the generic business
models we previously discussed. As you can see, the different business models
we discussed appear to be complementary on a number of dimensions, rather
than substitutes. This is one of the powerful insights of companies such as
Apple, Google or Amazon, who have been able to mix business models to
develop their platform-powered ecosystems. This is the topic of the next
chapter.

Notes
1 See, for example, the ‘Pipes vs Platform’ article in the October 2013 Wired magazine
penned by Sangeet Paul Choudary, www.wired.com/insights/2013/10/why-business-
models-fail-pipes-vs-platforms/
2 M. E. Porter, Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors, New
York: Free Press, 1980.
3 M. E. Porter, Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, New
York: Free Press, 1985.
4 See A. Osterwalder and Y. Pigneur, Business Model Generation: A Handbook for Visionaries,
Game Changers, and Challengers, self-published, 2010.
5 Airbnb website, www.airbnb.com/help/article/384/what-are-the-service-fees.
6 It is worth noting that variants of the business canvas have been proposed to better
match the requirements of different types of businesses, including multisided ones. See,
for example, the Platform Design Toolkit (www.platformdesigntoolkit.com) from Simone
Cicero.
7 Sangeet Choudary, Platform Power, 2013, http://platformed.info
8 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, The Catalyst Code, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School
Press, 2007.
9 Even this may change as card companies develop new advertising capabilities allowing
card users to be notified of merchant promotions of interest based on their previous
purchases, physical location, etc.
10 There is emerging evidence that consumers can indeed be overwhelmed by choice. See
B. Schwartz, The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less, New York: Harper Perennial,
2004.
11 One side, the seller, knows everything about their products, while the buyer knows
little. For the transaction to occur, the platform needs to facilitate this exchange of
information by enabling both parties to communicate. Rating and reputation systems
such as eBay’s star system have been designed to increase the trust of potential buyers
by enhancing the information to the buyer (previous buyer reviews). Trust building is
discussed in more detail in Chapter 12.
12 A like on a Facebook company page was reported as being worth $173, for example.
While the exact number is likely to be highly dependent upon one’s own business, it
Platforms as business models 55

is clear that platform interactions have value not only for the community, but also
advertisers. See, for example, www.wired.com/insights/2013/07/is-a-facebook-like-
worth-174-probably-not/.
13 Charging sellers a sales commission fee (eBay) or members a subscription fee (Match.com)
can be seen as core transactions. This is because significant value is exchanged between
eBay and sellers in the first example, and Match.com and members in the second one.
14 A/B testing is jargon for a randomized experiment with two variants, A and B, which
are the control and treatment in the controlled experiment, for example by sending two
slightly different promotional emails while tracking responses in order to quickly select
the best of the two before iterating further. See R. Kohavi and R. Longbotham, ‘Online
Controlled Experiments and A/B Tests’, Encyclopedia of Machine Learning and Data Mining.
pp. 1–8, 13 May 2016, for a discussion on best practices.
15 See the Airbnb rebranding exercise case study at www.wearedesignstudio.com/works/
airbnb-process/.
16 Timothy Prickett Morgan, ‘Airbnb Shares the Keys to Its Infrastructure’, Next Platform,
10 September 2015, www.nextplatform.com/2015/09/10/airbnb-shares-the-keys-to-
its-infrastructure/.
17 See A. Hagiu and J. Wright, ‘Marketplace or Reseller’, Harvard Business School Working
Paper 13-092, 2013, for a discussion about the strengths and weaknesses of platforms.
18 Pierre Omidyar, founder of eBay, reported that the very first item that sold on the
platform was a broken laser pointer priced at $14.83. Astonished, he contacted the
winning bidder to check, just to be told by the buyer that he was ‘a collector of broken
laser pointers’. If evidence were needed, this strongly suggests that platforms do not
tightly control their value chain.
19 eBay started with collectibles in 1995, before moving on to computers, books, movies
and consumer electronics in 1997, and to cars, clothing and motors in 1999. These
waves were both driven by users trying to list new products and by eBay’s management
trying to make it easier for people to deal with various product categories.
Chapter 6

Platform-powered ecosystems

As mentioned earlier, platform business models can be associated and combined


with other business models. The aim is to ensure that the ‘whole’ is worth
more than the ‘sum of its parts’, and that the resulting platform-powered
ecosystem becomes stronger. In this chapter, we explore how business models
can complement each other to reinforce value propositions by presenting high-
level case studies on Amazon, Apple and Google.

Amazon’s ecosystem
Today, Amazon is the largest e-commerce retailer in the US, as well as the
world’s largest provider of cloud computing services.1 For the past 10 years,
Amazon’s growth rate has exceeded 20%2 year after year, recently surpassing
Walmart in market capitalization.3 Somebody who bought $1,000 of Amazon
stocks when it floated in May 1997 would now have approximately $552,700,
equivalent to a yearly return of 38.6%.4

A bit of history
Jeff Bezos founded Amazon in 1994 as an online bookstore. So Amazon started
as a traditional business model but online. The business expanded rapidly from
books to new categories such as CDs, DVDs, electronics, etc. and floated
three years later. In 1999, Amazon launched a separate Web auctions site to
compete with eBay’s fast-growing marketplace. It failed to ignite because
Amazon customers were buyers who were mainly convenience-motivated.
A second attempt, zShops, was based on fixed-price immediate buying but
third-party sellers were in separate parts of the store, which gave buyers a
disjointed customer experience. In 2000, Amazon was a third time lucky when
zShops was merged with the Amazon site and repositioned as Amazon
Marketplace. Deciding to let third-party sellers compete with the retail
business was a very controversial decision internally. Jeff Bezos recalls:
58 Platform-powered ecosystems

So our buyers were extremely concerned – and rightly. They were saying,
‘Let me just make sure I understand this. I might get stuck with inventory
of 10,000 units of this camera that I just loaded up on, and you’re going
to let just anybody come in and take Amazon traffic on what is our primary
retail real estate, which is the detail page, and I’m going to lose the buy
box to this other person because they have a lower price than me?’ And
we said, ‘Yeah, we are.’5

After difficult discussions, Jeff Bezos eventually took the bet to focus on what
was best for customers, and opened its original distribution business on the
producer side. As a result, a single search now returns results from both Amazon
itself and the marketplace merchants. Since then, the e-commerce business has
continued to expand to 15 countries in categories from clothes, furniture, toys
and jewellery to fresh groceries (Amazon Fresh) and daily deal products and
services (Amazon Local). Goods worth over $225 billion were sold in 2015
alone, with Amazon Marketplace representing in excess of 50% of sales.6
Since 2005, online merchants trading on Amazon have benefited from
Fulfilment by Amazon (FBA), a service where Amazon stores, picks, packs
and ships products on behalf of sellers. Amazon also launched Amazon Prime
the same year, a membership service offering buyers free and fast delivery.
Both FBA and Prime are traditional product lines leveraging Amazon’s
excellent logistics capabilities. They have been instrumental in supporting the
e-commerce business.
Amazon also branched out early on into services supporting digital busi-
nesses with Amazon Web Services (AWS), a cloud computing service launched
in 2006. AWS is now the largest cloud service in the world and generated
$12.2 billion in 2016.
Amazon’s first foray into consumer electronics started with the Kindle in
2007, supported by Fire OS, an Android based operating system. Building
on the success of Kindle e-book readers, Amazon later launched the Fire
Tablet, Fire Phone, Fire TV Stick, and more recently Amazon Echo. Amazon
also launched the Amazon Appstore for Android devices, as well as a Mac
download store with games and software for Apple computers.
In 2010, Amazon entered the entertainment and content industry with
Amazon Studios, a studio that develops television shows, movies and comics
from online submissions and crowdsourced feedback, and Amazon Instant
Video, an Internet video on-demand service. Amazon also purchased Twitch.tv
in 2014, a live streaming video platform and community for gamers. Twitch
attracts more than 100 million visitors per month and 1.5 million broadcasters.7
The Amazon timeline (see Figure 6.1) summarizes some of the key
milestones in the development of Amazon’s main lines of business. Over the
Platform-powered ecosystems 59

Figure 6.1 Amazon’s main business lines


Source: Amazon website, Wikipedia, Launchworks analysis

last 20 years, Amazon has acquired dozens of companies and launched many
services. Our purpose here is not to be exhaustive, but rather to illustrate at
a strategic level how the combination of several business models has allowed
Amazon to successfully develop its platform-powered ecosystem.

Amazon’s business models


Mapping Amazon’s key line of businesses against the three main families of
business models (see Table 6.1) shows that Amazon relies on all of them.

E-commerce
Although Amazon started as a pure e-commerce reseller with a curated but
limited range of goods at competitive prices, the integration of a third-party
marketplace platform has been complementary to the reseller model and now
represents over 50% of Amazon’s e-commerce business.8 The platform model
provides many benefits, including diversity and selection of goods offered by
millions of sellers. Outsourcing the risk of holding stock of new product
categories has proven a cost-effective method to manage millions of different
products – the so-called long tail – and scale quickly. This is one of the reasons
marketplaces have the potential to grow at a faster rate than traditional retail
businesses (see Figure 6.2).
60 Platform-powered ecosystems

Table 6.1 Amazon’s ecosystem

AMAZON Platform Retailer/ Input/Output


Reseller Business
Amazon Retail 3
Amazon Marketplace 3
Fulfilment, warehousing (FBA), Delivery 3
(Prime), Cloud services (AWS)
Amazon Android software (OS, appstores) 3
Consumer electronics (Kindle, Echo, 3
Fire Phone, Tablet & TV)
Content production (Amazon Studios) 3
On-demand video (Amazon Instant Video) 3
Gaming (Twitch.tv) 3
Source: Launchworks analysis

Figure 6.2 Relative growth of Amazon retail vs Amazon marketplace


(estimated split)
Source: ChannelAdvisor and Tamebay estimates, Launchworks analysis

Amazon constantly learns from sellers and competes with them as a retailer
on popular items. This hybrid model feeds the flywheel of traffic: consumers
are attracted to the site because of the combination of great selection, com-
petitive prices and customer experience. More buyers attract more sellers,
which in turn add to economies of scale that can be passed along by lowering
prices and reducing shipping fees.
Platform-powered ecosystems 61

Looking more closely at Amazon’s Marketplace, the breadth of selection


is a direct result of its horizontal focus and openness, as anybody, from humble
one-off consumer-sellers to established merchants, can join the platform to
sell. However, the right to sell on Amazon comes with the obligation to meet
strict customer service standards when dealing with buyers. Indeed, merchants
are responsible for a large portion of the customer experience, including
shipping. Over the years, Amazon has deployed seller coaching programmes
to help sellers better manage their stocks and price competitively. A number
of tools and services are also available to mitigate the risk of bad customer
experiences, including communications support between merchants and
buyers and a dispute resolutions centre. While merchants and buyers can
interact directly, communications and disputes are intermediated by Amazon
for greater control of the customer experience, as well as limitation of revenue
leakage.
Amazon’s marketplace is a great example of a platform with many value-
adding features, on the merchant side – as discussed above – but also on the
buyer side. Buyers benefit from value-added services, including payment inter-
mediation, independent customer reviews, a range of delivery options –
including the superfast Prime delivery subscription service – a ‘no questions
asked’ returns policy, etc. Prime subscribers can also get faster delivery of
items sold by merchants using FBA.
Amazon’s traffic is critically reinforced by Amazon Prime. Unlimited fast
and free delivery makes Prime customers more engaged. They spend between
two and four times more than non-Prime customers,9 which has encouraged
Amazon to make Prime more attractive by bundling additional services into
the subscription. They include free access to over half a million e-books, ad-
free music, photo storage and on-demand video, including exclusive content
from Amazon Studios. The recently launched Prime Now offers Prime
subscribers free two-hour delivery on tens of thousands of items or one-hour
delivery for a small fee.
Finally, FBA, a service for marketplace sellers, provides the link between
Amazon Marketplace and Prime. FBA leverages Amazon’s own infrastruc-
ture and gives Amazon greater control over the entire value chain, hence
reducing the risk of bad buyer experiences. When a seller joins FBA, their
goods can become Prime eligible. The Amazon fulfilment centre handles
logistics, customer service, product returns and, of course, delivery in record
time, alongside goods sold by Amazon. This represents a huge gain of
efficiency when customers order items from both FBA sellers and Amazon.
The flywheel of traffic is at play again: FBA leads to more sales for sellers,10
more FBA sellers lead to more value for Prime customers, who then spend
more, to the benefit of both Marketplace sellers and Amazon.
62 Platform-powered ecosystems

Amazon is getting the best of both worlds by combining the reach of


platforms with the control of simple distribution models in order to be a
‘one-stop shop’. The combination of the long tail marketplace with the highly
efficient high-volume reseller model attracts one of the biggest audiences across
the world and makes it one of the most successful e-commerce sites.

Amazon’s ecosystem
When more control over the product proposition is required, Amazon uses
more traditional business models. This is the case of Prime for shoppers, FBA
for merchants or cloud services for website owners.
When connecting large numbers of buyers and sellers, as happens with game
developers and gamers, or writers with readers, Amazon uses a platform model
with its Fire OS operating system and its Appstore.11 The launch of the Kindle
(joint hardware and operating system) was instrumental to the development
of the e-book market, resulting in Amazon becoming one of the largest e-
book retailers.
The addition of the Echo product line and Alexa’s always-on voice
recognition interface is a good illustration of this self-reinforcing ecosystem
strategy. Echo/Alexa gives customers access to a multitude of applications
– called ‘skills’ – from third-party developers (a platform), as well as access to
the Amazon site, Amazon Music and other services. Such an ecosystem is not
only more efficient overall, but it is also ‘stickier’ (e.g. it is more difficult for
a consumer to leave the ecosystem due to ‘lock-ins’ and associated ‘switching
costs’ of having to learn a new interface and transfer all their content).12
Leveraging platform business models with more traditional ones was initially
an organic process for Amazon. It was not designed from scratch and there
were trials and errors along the way. It took a couple of years for Amazon
to find the right marketplace model for its e-commerce offering.13 And it
took nearly a decade for Amazon’s platform operating system Fire OS and
associated hardware (Kindle, Fire Phone, Fire Tablet, Fire TV, Echo) to
develop into an integrated offering. The current model is not without its
challenges. Merchants on the marketplace effectively compete with Amazon’s
own retail activities, which creates tension, and the Fire Phone take-up has
been disappointing. But Amazon is now undeniably a sophisticated global
operator that manages a self-reinforcing ecosystem that uses and leverages both
traditional and platform business models wherever they make sense. Amazon
has recently moved into bricks and mortar retail, reinventing the shopping
experience with its Amazon Books stores. Amazon Go, a new ‘Just Walk
Out’ shopping experiment, where customers can shop with no checkout
required, has also launched in early 2017.14
Platform-powered ecosystems 63

Apple’s ecosystem
Apple is one of the largest companies in the world. In 40 years, it has become
a leader in manufacturing computer devices and mobile phones, developing
operating systems and software, and distributing music and digital apps. $1,000
of Apple stock purchased when it floated would now be worth approximately
$220,287, equivalent to a yearly return of 16.3%.15

A bit of history
In 1976, Steve Jobs, Steve Wozniak and Ronald Wayne invented the first
Apple personal computer. Sales grew exponentially and Apple publicly traded
on the stock market in 1980. Over the course of 20 years, Apple released
new and improved versions of its personal computer product line (Apple series,
Macintosh series, PowerBook series), operating systems (System 7, Mac OS)
and a suite of software applications. However, its closed approach and lack
of interoperability with PCs and Microsoft software, which had by then
become the market leader, almost led to its demise.
In 1997, Steve Jobs announced that Microsoft would release new versions
of Microsoft Office for the Macintosh following a historic partnership. Bill
Gates even appeared over a live video feed during that year’s keynote speech
in front of a bewildered audience to announce the new partnership. After a
much-needed $150 million cash investment from arch-enemy Microsoft,
Apple started a new lease of life. In 2001, the first retail store opened, and
the iPod and iTunes launched, as well as Mac OS, a new operating system.
In 2007, Apple’s future took a new course by extending its offering from
computers to mobile electronic devices with the iPhone and its App Store,
a platform selling third-party digital applications. Success was unprecedented,
and by October 2008 Apple was the third-largest mobile handset manufacturer
in the world.16
Since then, more product lines have been successfully introduced, from
the iPad and iCloud, an online storage and syncing service for music, photos,
files and software, to the Apple Watch.
The Apple timeline (see Figure 6.3) summarizes some of the key milestones
in the development of Apple’s key product lines. It is not exhaustive, but is
intended to illustrate how the combination of several underpinning business
models can complement and strengthen Apple’s value propositions.

Apple’s business models


Like Amazon, Apple manufactures its own hardware products17 (see Table 6.2).
The main benefit is higher control on design and quality of products. Through
64 Platform-powered ecosystems

Figure 6.3 Apple’s main business lines


Source: Apple website, Wikipedia, Launchworks analysis

Table 6.2 Apple’s ecosystem

APPLE Platform Retailer/ Input/Output


Reseller business
Apple hardware 3
(iPhone, MacBook, iPad, Apple
Watch)
Apple Operating Systems 3
(iOS, macOS, Watch OS)
Digital Stores (iTunes, Apple Music) 3
App stores (iOS, Mac) 3
Cloud services (iCloud) 3
Apple software (iMovie, iPhoto) 3
Source: Launchworks analysis

its operating systems and app stores for computers, mobile phones, tablets and
wearables, Apple manages a two-sided platform between consumers and
software providers. This model fosters a diverse range of software applications.
As of June 2016, Apple’s App Store had more than 2 million applications.18
It is interesting to note that Apple, unlike other marketplaces, remains very
keen to control the experience of its products end-to-end, and has therefore
maintained strong governance around its businesses. Apple’s experience is
heavily mediated and curated; its App Store platform is ‘regulated’, with its
applications selected, controlled and promoted by Apple, who reserve the
Platform-powered ecosystems 65

right to remove apps for any reason.19 Apple’s App Store is far less open than
Google’s or Microsoft’s in that regard.
For iTunes and Apple Music, Apple has chosen a reseller model. Apple
aggregates music from a few major music labels and distributes directly to
consumers. This is a very different model from SoundCloud, which enables
individual artists to upload audio files and share them with friends and wider
communities.
The resulting Apple ecosystem is significantly more powerful than the sum
of its parts. An excellent mobile phone with features far superior to the iPhone
but let down by a sub-par supporting ecosystem (with few apps, etc.) doesn’t
stand a chance in today’s market. In order to take on the iPhone, competitors
need to develop a similarly strong ecosystem of reinforcing business capabilities.
Samsung has been trying to do just that. Nokia, once a mobile leader, failed to
maintain its platform ecosystem and ended up selling its mobile division to
Microsoft, who had been struggling to make significant inroads into the mobile
market despite the strong desktop platform position of Windows.
It is also worth noting that the platform-powered parts of Apple’s business
are the ones growing at the fastest rate, although the positive externalities
created also support the other activities, as would be expected from a self-
reinforcing ecosystem. Apple’s services20 represented 11% of revenues for

Figure 6.4 Split of Apple’s hardware vs services revenues (2016)


Source: Apple website, Launchworks analysis
66 Platform-powered ecosystems

2016,21 as shown in Figure 6.4, with a growth rate of 19% year over year for
the first half of 2016.
A closer review of revenues generated by Apple’s non-hardware activities
since 2005 shows how apps, which were responsible for only a fraction of
Apple’s revenues in 2008, are now a multibillion-dollar business. In fact, Tim
Cook expects that it will be ‘the size of a Fortune 100 company by the end
of 2017’.22 And this, of course, excludes the amount of money that was paid
to the developers of these apps (Apple keeps 30% of the price paid for the
apps sold on its App Store).23 When looking at total App Store billings (what
customers actually spend), Figure 6.5 shows that they are now larger than
Hollywood’s US box office revenues and are likely to overtake Hollywood’s
global box office revenues in 2016.24
Apple has been able to match different business models to different activ-
ities in order to design a self-reinforcing business architecture. Apple is still
committed to a unique user experience on each of its device, but it is building
cross-device and cross-service experiences to offer a more unified experience
to both users and developers.25 Apple’s App Stores wouldn’t do as well with-
out Apple’s unique hardware offering, and vice versa.

Figure 6.5 Apple App Store billings vs Hollywood US box office revenues
Source: Apple website, Horace Dediu Asymco, www.asymco.com, Launchworks analysis

Google’s ecosystem
Google is one of the largest and best-known companies in the world. While
the company rebranded itself at the group level as Alphabet, Inc. on 2 October
Platform-powered ecosystems 67

2015, with Google operating as the search engine subsidiary, we use the term
Google to talk about all the group’s activities in this book. A $1,000 investment
in Google stock when it floated in 2004 would now be worth approximately
$15,665, equivalent to a yearly return of 25.6%.26

A bit of history
Founded by Larry Page and Sergey Brin in 1998, Google designed its original
search business around its superior ability to index what content producers
were putting online, mainly in the form of websites, in order to deliver it
to content seekers. Two years later, Google managed to monetize this
capability by selling key search terms in order to improve the visibility of
merchant sites. Advertising revenues are now at the heart of its monetization
strategy,27 with almost 90% of its $90 billion 2016 revenues derived from
AdWords, an online advertising service that places advertising near the list of
search results.
Google also developed a range of complementary products in key verticals
as part of its ecosystem (email, maps, flight information, etc.).
YouTube, the video sharing service that Google acquired in 2007, initially
launched as a two-sided platform connecting viewers and content producers.
Its unique proposition at the time was to allow anyone in the world to get
access to a long tail of amateur home videos, something that was not possible
through traditional TV. Over time, as viewer adoption strengthened,
YouTube started to attract professional and mainstream content producers,28
improving content quality and in turn customer traction. As it reached critical
mass – it’s now the third most visited website in the world29 – YouTube
added advertisers as a third side to monetize the site.
Google is also behind the Android operating system, a suite of software
products including the Chrome browser, associated Chrome laptop pro-
ducts and Android smartphones, as well as fibre access networks in the
US.30 The company also acquired the mobile division of Motorola and its
extensive patent portfolio in 2013. More recently, Google has entered the
‘Internet of things’ (IoT) market with the acquisition of Nest (temperature
control) and Dropcam (video surveillance) as well as the launch of Google
Home (voice activated assistant). Google is also very active in self-driving car
technology, artificial intelligence and, through its ventures arm, an investor
in some of the most promising start-ups in Silicon Valley (including Uber).
Although these different activities may look disparate, they actually create a
powerful ecosystem with complex linkages, as well as unique antitrust
challenges.
Google’s main business lines are presented in Figure 6.6.
68 Platform-powered ecosystems

Figure 6.6 Google’s main business lines


Source: Google website, Wikipedia, Launchworks analysis

Google’s business models


Google’s search platform is still at the core of the ecosystem (see Table 6.3).
It connects consumers and businesses relying on Google’s advertising products
to achieve visibility. The search engine is constantly optimized to improve
relevance, performance and efficiency for all participants. The search ecosystem
is reinforced by Google’s extensive range of integrated software services (also
called productivity tools), such as Gmail, Calendar, Google Maps, etc., to
encourage both consumers and businesses to interact within the ecosystem.
YouTube is now a platform with strong network effects. It’s an open
platform where unregistered users can watch videos and registered users can
upload videos to their channels. Videos considered to contain potentially
offensive content are available only to registered users over 18 years old. In
the spirit of openness, users can make any comment they like, which can
attract spammers and trolls. This has forced some superstar YouTubers such
as PewDiePie, who generated more than $15 million in 2016 advertising
revenues alone, to disable comments on their videos.31 Despite cutting off
Platform-powered ecosystems 69

Table 6.3 Google’s ecosystem

GOOGLE Platform Retailer/ Input/Output


Reseller Business
Search services 3
Software tools for enterprise 3
(AdWords, G Suite, etc.)
Software consumer tools 3
(Gmail, Google Maps, etc.)
Android OS and app stores 3
Video sharing and social networking 3
(YouTube, Google+)
Google hardware (glasses, 3
chromecast, driverless cars, etc.)
Source: Launchworks analysis

his ability to interact with fans, his decision has had no impact on his 50+
million subscriber base. YouTube has since introduced better moderation tools,
but the issue of moderation is still lingering, including with YouTube Gaming,
its newly launched live streaming platform for video gaming enthusiasts.32
In this category, real-time conversations are integral to the gaming experience.
YouTube rebuilt the live-streaming platform with a comment system giving
more control to game owners, such as chat moderation, the ability to ban
users, time-out users and ban filtered words.33
YouTube cannot be mentioned without Google+, Google’s fledgling social
network. In an attempt to offer a seamless experience into the Google eco-
system, Google+ was integrated directly with YouTube and the Chrome Web
browser, allowing YouTube videos to be viewed from within the Google+
interface. This meant that users were forced to sign up for accounts if they
wanted to use YouTube channels or accounts. We suspect this move was
mainly designed to ignite and scale Google+ to critical mass and compete
with already established social platforms such as Facebook and Twitter.
Although Google+ claims 2.2 billion accounts, only 9% of its users are active
and post public content.34 Google announced in July 2015 that Google was
scaling back the reach of its social network.35 Services such as YouTube
channels and accounts will be accessible without a Google+ account to
remove unnecessary friction for customers. This decision reflects the difficulty
of scaling a platform to critical mass in an already saturated market . . . even
for Google!
70 Platform-powered ecosystems

Other platform-powered ecosystems


While we have looked in some detail at how Amazon, Google and Apple
have been able to leverage platforms and combine business models to succeed,
the same framework can be applied to other companies. Microsoft and
Facebook deserve similar case studies. Both have made their investors healthy
returns: somebody who bought $1,000 of Facebook stock when it IPO’d on
12 March 2012 would have had $4,327 four years later, equivalent to a yearly
return of 40.2%, while somebody who bought $1,000 of Microsoft when it
IPO’d in 1986 would have $879,343 thirty years later, equivalent to a yearly
return of 24.9%.36
Like Apple, Google and Amazon, Microsoft and Facebook achieved these
performances by adding and combining platforms with other business models
to further strengthen their respective platform-powered ecosystems.
The acquisitions of Nokia’s mobile phone unit in September 2013 (for
$7.2 billion),37 collaborative communications platform Yammer in June 2012
(for $1.2 billion), peer-to-peer IP-based telecoms platform Skype in May
2011 (for $8.5 billion) and LinkedIn in June 2016 (for $26 billion) were driven
by Microsoft’s willingness to become the leading business platform-powered
ecosystem and ‘recreate the connective tissue of enterprises’.38
The acquisitions by Facebook of messaging app WhatsApp in February 2014
(for $19 billion),39 photo sharing platform Instagram in April 2012 (for $1
billion)40 and virtual reality hardware company Occulus in March 2014 (for
$2 billion)41 are also key moves aimed at consolidating its platform ecosystem
and gaining control of a new physical interface. Indeed, unlike Apple, Google,
Amazon and Microsoft, Facebook hasn’t yet got its own ‘operating system’,
and is therefore seen by some as ‘just an app’ dependent upon other people’s
hardware and OS.

Notes
1 Synergy Group, October 2014, www.srgresearch.com/articles/microsoft-cloud-revenues-
leap-amazon-still-way-out-front.
2 Amazon.com website and Statista, www.statista.com/statistics/233761/year-on-year-
revenue-of-amazon-and-ebay-since-2006/.
3 Amazon’s market capitalization is $354 billion and Walmart’s market capitalization is
$217 billion, 12 September 2016.
4 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (15 May 1997 for
Amazon until 29 September 2016) using the online stock return calculator available at
www.buyupside.com/.
5 Julia Kirby and Thomas A. Stewart, ‘The Institutional Yes’, Harvard Business Review,
October 2007.
Platform-powered ecosystems 71

6 www.channeladvisor.com/blog/?pn=scot/deep-dive-into-amazons-q4-results-for-sellers-
whats-cool-100b-and-200b.
7 Wall Street Journal, 29 January 2015, http://blogs.wsj.com/digits/2015/01/29/twitchs-
viewers-reach-100-million-a-month/
8 ChannelAdvisor blog, Scott Wingo, 1 February 2006, www.channeladvisor.com/blog/
?pn=scot/deep-dive-into-amazons-q4-results-for-sellers-whats-cool-100b-and-200b.
9 http://recode.net/2015/01/28/this-could-be-the-year-amazon-finally-reveals-its-most-
important-number/.
10 In a 2014 survey of US sellers, 71% of FBA merchants reported more than a 20% increase
in unit sales after joining FBA, Amazon 2014 Annual Report.
11 It is worth noting that Amazon reused a lot of the open-source Android code that Google
originally developed. FireOS is therefore very close to, but different from, Google
Android OS. For more information, see: www.howtogeek.com/232973/amazons-fire-
os-vs.-googles-android-whats-the-difference/.
12 It is worth noting at this stage that while such tying strategies may be perfectly legitimate
for start-ups, competition authorities and regulators often get concerned when large
established companies – with ‘market power’ – use these tricks. We will discuss regulatory
implications of platform businesses in Chapter 13.
13 In 1999, the company launched Amazon.com Auctions, a Web auctions service that
failed to make a dent in eBay’s large market share. Later that year, Amazon launched
zShops, a fixed-price marketplace and a now defunct partnership with Sotheby’s. In
late 2000, Auctions and zShops morphed into the Amazon Marketplace that we know
today.
14 http://fortune.com/2016/12/05/amazon-go-store/
15 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (12 December 1980
for Apple until 29 September 2016) using the online stock return calculator available at
www.buyupside.com/.
16 Wired, 21 October 2008, www.wired.com/2008/10/with-iphone-app/.
17 Apple is, of course, free to select partners and suppliers, such as Foxconn in China, for
the manufacturing of its products. These outsourcing decisions do not fundamentally
alter the business model of the company, however, since it keeps tight control over the
end-to-end production process of its devices.
18 Statista, June 2016, www.statista.com/statistics/276623/number-of-apps-available-in-
leading-app-stores/.
19 If you want to better understand the nature of this ‘governance’, you may want to have
a look at the App Store guidelines for app developers: https://developer.apple.com/app-
store/review/guidelines/.
20 Apple’s services include the various app stores, as well as iTunes, iCloud, Apple Music,
Apple Pay, Apple Care, licensing and other services.
21 Fiscal data from Apple’s website, www.apple.com/pr/library/2016/.
22 http://uk.businessinsider.com/apple-ceo-tim-cook-services-q3-2016-7.
23 Apple announced in June 2016 that this 30% figure could go down to 15% (with 85%
going to developers) in some circumstances. See www.theverge.com/2016/6/8/
11880730/apple-app-store-subscription-update-phil-schiller-interview.
24 Horace Dediu, Asymco (2014), www.asymco.com/, www.asymco.com/2015/08/26/much-
bigger-than-hollywood/ and www.asymco.com/2015/01/22/bigger-than-hollywood/.
72 Platform-powered ecosystems

25 At the developer level, Apple now allows third-party developers to plug into Siri across
multiple operating systems (iOS, tvOS and macOS). At the user level, the new macOS
version allows users to copy something on the Mac or iPhone and paste it on the other
device. And if users buy an app for the iPad, iOS’s automatic app download to tvOS
means that it will automatically show up on the Apple TV.
26 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (19 August 2004
for Google until 29 September 2016) using the online stock return calculator available
at www.buyupside.com/.
27 Google Investor Relations, 2016 Financial Tables, http://investor.google.com/financial/
tables.html.
28 Which YouTube supported with its Partner Program, making it possible to earn a
substantial living as a video producer.
29 As of June 2015, according to third-party Web analytics providers Alexa and SimilarWeb.
30 Although this may have more to do with its bargaining power with operators arguing
against net neutrality than with Google’s core strategy of organizing the world’s
information.
31 See Guardian, 3 September 2014, www.theguardian.com/technology/2014/sep/03/
pewdiepie-switches-off-youtube-comments-its-mainly-spam.
32 YouTube Gaming launched on 26 August 2015 in response to Twitch.tv, the leading
video streaming platform purchased by Amazon. YouTube Gaming is available as a
website globally and has iOS and Android apps in the US and UK. Announced in June,
the new portal includes a directory of more than 25,000 games, each with their own
profile page collecting related YouTube videos.
33 Ryan Wyatt interview, YouTube’s head of gaming, 26 August 2015, www.the
guardian.com/technology/2015/aug/26/youtube-gaming-live-website-apps.
34 Business Insider, ‘Nobody Is Using Google+’, 20 January 2015, http://uk.business
insider.com/google-active-users-2015-1
35 Google Blog, 27 July 2015, http://googleblog.blogspot.co.uk/2015/07/everything-in-
its-right-place.html.
36 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (respectively 18
May 2012 for Facebook and 13 March 1986 for Microsoft until 29 September 2016)
using the online stock return calculator available at www.buyupside.com/.
37 Microsoft’s intent when acquiring Nokia’s mobile phone division in 2014 for $7.2 billion
was to create added value by combining Microsoft’s software and services with Nokia’s
hardware assets. It was a failure, with Microsoft writing off $7.6 billion two years later.
38 According to Benedict Evans.
39 http://newsroom.fb.com/news/2014/02/facebook-to-acquire-whatsapp/
40 www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052702303815404577333840377381670
41 www.facebook.com/zuck/posts/10101319050523971?stream_ref=1
Chapter 7

Life stages of platforms


Design

In the previous chapters, we covered some definitions and underlying


economic principles of digital platforms. We then reviewed how they can
usefully be combined with traditional business models to form platform-
powered ecosystems. Finally, we reviewed a range of frameworks, including
our own rocket model, to better design platform businesses.

The rocket life stages at a glance


Let’s now examine in greater detail the inner workings of digital platforms
across their life stages. As a platform business develops and matures, growth
bottlenecks are likely to appear along the way. These bottlenecks will be
different from one market to another, and the sequence we propose is by no
means scientific or exhaustive since every platform is different. We have, how-
ever, seen some patterns emerge, since the same issues and bottlenecks tend
to appear at similar stages of development.
We therefore propose to review the key bottlenecks and illustrate the man-
agement challenges that could present themselves for each building block of
the rocket model (attract, match, connect, transact and optimize) across four
main life stages of a platform, as shown in Figure 7.1:

• Pre-launch, when the platform is designed and built prior to its launch.
• Ignition, when the platform is tested and launched. The recruitment of
participants may happen sequentially, on the producer side first (path A
in Figure 7.1), or the user side (path B).
• Scaling-up, when building a critical mass of participants on all sides of the
platform becomes key. The ratio of producers and users will need to be
kept within an equilibrium (path C).
• Maturity, or how to continue to grow the business while defending against
new entrants and existing competitors.
74 Life stages of platforms: design

Figure 7.1 The main life stages of a platform


Source: Launchworks

The four life stages are presented in the next four chapters and summarized
in Table 7.1. You can either read these four chapters sequentially or simply
go to the section most relevant to you given the life stage of your plat-
form. If you’re not interested in life stage deep dives, you can go straight to
Chapter 11 on pricing.

Pre-launch: designing the platform business


architecture
The importance of this stage cannot be overstated since all the aspects of the
business need to be broadly developed or hypothesized during this design
phase. Having clarity over the definition of platforms and a broad under-
standing of how the business model is going to operate are obvious pre-
requisites to ignition and central to the pre-launch phase. Starting with
technology questions is the wrong approach, yet we find that many would-
be platforms make this initial mistake.
Questions to be addressed at this stage include the identification of the key
stakeholders, the value proposition offered to them and a broad sizing of the
market opportunity. Note that these relatively generic questions will also allow
you to validate your critical business assumption that a platform business model
really is the best way to address the opportunity in question.
Using our proposed definition, this means the opportunity would be best
addressed by a business able to attract producers and consumers of a good or
service, to efficiently match and connect them in order for a transaction to occur
and for data to be captured so that the business can be further optimized.
Table 7.1 Rocket life stages

Pre-launch Ignition Scale-up Maturity

Key priorities Platform Design Platform Fit Customer /Transaction Business growth
Market Sizing Build liquidity growth Profitability
Prototyping Raise capital Balanced and relevant Platform Power
liquidity Brand
Trust and loyalty
Team culture and
recruitment
Attract Define value propositions Build liquidity Strengthen liquidity New markets and
sustainable growth
Who are the key participants? Experiment/decide market side Build liquidity whilst keeping Extend value propositions to
What is the value proposition focus and ignition sequence i.e. growth balanced and within meet participants’ needs and
for each side of the platform? which side should be recruited equilibrium limits compete against other offers
What tools/services should first Get insights into tipping point/ Focus on retention in existing
the platform provide to Users, Attract identifiable target critical mass, network value and markets and acquisition in
Producers? communities level of network effects new markets
Iterate value propositions based Focus on participant acquisition
on market feedback to find first then retention
platform fit
Match Define matching/filter Build matching effectiveness Improve matching Strengthen matching
criteria effectiveness effectiveness
How will the matching be Review matching criteria and Automate and optimize matching Optimize matching at mass
done? filters to improve relevance, depth of scale
What are the key matching results and timeliness Blend AI to matching/search
criteria to capture? algorithms
Connect Define interactions Remove friction between Improve Connection Strengthen Connection
between participants participants effectiveness effectiveness
What is the nature/type of Clear interaction bottlenecks Encourage positive interactions Review/simplify interactions
interactions? Review rules and norms to at scale and discourage as value propositions
How will Users/Producers encourage positive interactions negative ones mature and network effects
interact? and limit negative ones are at scale
Directly/indirectly?
Transact Define core transactions Remove friction between Scale core transactions Maximize core
between participants participants transactions
What is the nature/type of Clear core interaction Continue to clear core Continue to clear core
core transactions? bottlenecks interaction bottlenecks interaction bottlenecks
Table 7.1 continued

Pre-launch Ignition Scale-up Maturity

Which side adds the most Elements needed post-transaction Deploy monetization when/if Monetize for profitable
value? How is it enabled? (delivery, cancellation, etc.) relevant growth
How to monetize? Which Consider the range of possible
side(s) to charge? price options to quickly attract
most valuable customers
(including freemium)
Optimize Define North Star and Monitor North Star and Monitor North Star and Monitor North Star and
key KPIs ignition KPIs scaling KPIs maturity KPIs
What are the North Star KPIs to track North Star, platform KPIs to track North Star, KPIs to track North Star,
and key KPIs? fit, liquidity, matching effectiveness, participant acquisition/retention, new markets and on-going
core interaction bottlenecks and liquidity and balance, matching/ growth, matching
raising capital connection effectiveness, trust and optimization, monetization/
customer experience, brand profitability, customer
awareness success and innovation
Enablers
UX What is the desired level of Optimize UX to remove Continue to optimize UX to Simplify UX as more
control from the platform? bottlenecks reduce friction functionality gets
What are main flows? introduced
Payments What are the key payment Implement payment solution Scale payment solution Investigate upside of
flows? (if needed) (if needed) optimizing payments/
generating other revenue
streams
Infrastructure Make or buy platform Infrastructure to support Scale IT infrastructure Keep infrastructure
infrastructure? platform fit up to date
Governance What are the rules of access Adjust governance principles as Adjust governance principles for Consolidate governance
and engagement for Producers and Users join the mass scale principles
Producers, Users? platform and engage Automate conflict resolution
Will pricing be centralized/ Set the rules for conflict Community management and tools
decentralized? resolution
How to capture/distribute value
Trust What framework to establish Map key trust interactions Deploy solid Trust and Safety Consolidate Trust and
trust? framework and scale customer Safety framework
service teams
Brand What does the brand stand for Ensure brand identity/design is Consolidate brand to appeal to Consolidate brand to
and how does this translate aligned with platform fit mass market audience appeal to new and
into visual identity/design? existing audiences

Source: Launchworks
Life stages of platforms: design 77

There is no skipping a platform design phase, since it would be impossible


to design a platform without having at least first hypothesized the key
principles of its operations. However, staying in the platform design phase
too long can result in diminishing returns, since the best type of feedback is
market feedback and the cost of experimentation keeps going down.
One possible exception to this is when established businesses are keen to
develop and launch a platform as an add-on to their existing operations
to create a ‘platform-powered ecosystem’. In such cases, a longer pre-launch
phase may be considered because of the perceived sensitivity and risk of the
operation and its interplay with existing business activities. Managers may be
concerned about protecting a brand and an existing market position, minim-
izing disruption to the existing business, and leveraging current assets while
acquiring new skills and capabilities.
Many business planning1 and start-up2 books highlight the key issues that
need to be addressed at the outset when launching a new business venture.
Summarizing the entire start-up literature would be difficult, so we are

Figure 7.2 Pre-launch rocket questions


Source: Launchworks
78 Life stages of platforms: design

focusing on the things that are really different for platform businesses. We will
focus on business-related issues rather than technical questions. This is because
a successful platform is first and foremost a business construct later supported
by the right technical infrastructure.
The key pre-launch questions summarized in Figure 7.2 are developed
below.
Before attracting anybody to a platform, it is critically important to under-
stand who the key platform participants will be, and what kind of value
proposition will be offered to them. As we will see, the concept of value pro-
position is an interesting one in this context since some of the platform
participants are also co-creating value on the platform. While their expected
contribution needs to be defined and incentivized by the platform, it cannot,
by definition, be entirely controlled, but merely influenced.3
A good way to think about value creation is to map participants’
contributions out using a simple matrix, presented in Table 7.3, to describe
the value proposition to and from each stakeholder.

Identify participants
It is useful, as a preliminary step, to identify key participants involved with
the platform.

Platform owner: typically the organization (business, not-for-profit or network)


responsible for the development and management of the platform itself
and its ecosystem. For example, eBay Inc. (commercial organization), Kiva
(not-for-profit organization), Kickstarter (public-benefit corporation), Reddit
(community).

Sides: the distinct and diverse groups of customers or entities being connected
by the platform. For two-sided platforms, they are typically segmented into
two groups: one on the supply side (often called producers) and the other on
the demand side (often called users or consumers). They are jointly called
‘platform participants’.
• Producers: individuals, communities, businesses or entities delivering value
created on and/or through the platform. For example, eBay sellers, Kiva
borrowers, Kickstarter creators, Reddit content contributors. The producers
side can be further segmented if it is made of different customer groups.
For example, eBay sellers can be segmented into consumer sellers and
business sellers, and even broken down even further by product categories
(e.g. professional fashion sellers, non-professional coin collectors, etc.).
Life stages of platforms: design 79

• Users (or consumers): individuals, communities, businesses or entities that


access, consume and utilize the value provided by producers. For example,
eBay buyers, Kiva lenders, Kickstarter backers, Reddit readers.

Partners: individuals, communities, businesses or entities that collaborate with


platform owners and add value for the platform participants. For example,
the Airbnb management companies Guesty in the US or Hostmakers in the
UK, who manage listings, bookings, etc. on behalf of the hosts. In a first
analysis, partners may be left blank, especially in new markets where their
identity may not be obvious. But these providers of complementary products
can play a key role as the ecosystem expands.

Other stakeholders: typically actors who have a specific interest in the


development of platforms, and their impact on public welfare, competition,
etc. Examples include governments and regulators. They are often less relevant
in the early days, but their importance increases over time, so it is useful to
identify them early if possible. If your platform is very disruptive to established
market participants, it will be particularly important to engage with these
stakeholders early to ensure a balanced debate.

Market sizing
A necessary second step is to ‘quantify’ the number of possible platform
participants in order to get a sense for the market potential. Typically, this
requires a high-level, top-down estimate of classic marketing metrics such as
the total addressable market (TAM), the serviced addressable market (SAM)
and the target market (TM).
Using Airbnb as an illustration, the TAM would be all days/nights where
properties are empty, the SAM would be restricted to areas where it is pos-
sible to rent from a regulatory perspective, and the TM would be the
segment of people who would be open to renting their home. The TM can
of course be sub-segmented further by age group, geographies, risk aversion,
etc.
Market sizing is a traditional step for all start-up businesses, but with
platform businesses this requires some specific considerations, since:

• You need to get a sense of who in your market will be a platform participant.
Some people will never share their flat when they go on holiday. Some
people only want to go to hotels. Some platforms will require ownership
of a smartphone.
80 Life stages of platforms: design

• Your market sizing needs to ensure that there is a critical mass of participants
on both sides of the platform as quickly as possible so that your proposition
is ‘liquid’ and transactions are maximized.
• It is important to be careful when using existing market information and
statistics, since, more often than not, these have been framed in the context
of traditional businesses rather than platforms. For example, had Uber based
its business on the size of the taxi market, it would have significantly
underestimated the opportunity. In fact, 3 years after entry Uber managed
to grow the San Francisco taxi market by a factor of 3.5.4

Business architecture drivers


In addition to market sizing, there are several drivers to consider when
designing the business architecture of the platform. Some of the main ones
are listed below.

Market focus
Which parts of the market do you intend to focus on first? Should you tar-
get a well-defined vertical first and then expand to other ones, and if so
which ones?

Type of interactions between users and producers


Will interactions between participants be one-to-one? One-to-many? Or
many-to-many?

Nature of interactions between users and producers


Will interactions be transactional or relationship-based? Will connections be
asymmetric (a participant can follow another one) or bidirectional (opt-in
from both sides)?

Level of intermediation
Will platform participants connect directly or indirectly? Direct platforms allow
for direct connection between customers, while indirect platforms connect
two or more customer groups indirectly. For example, card companies, such
as Visa or Mastercard, go through banks to issue their cards and acquire the
merchants that will accept cards. These intermediaries – so-called card issuers
and merchant acquirers – are effectively the ones in contact with the end
Life stages of platforms: design 81

Figure 7.3 Direct vs indirect platforms


Source: Launchworks

clients, while Visa manages the business-to-business platform in the centre


(interbank switch). As shown in Figure 7.3, platforms can be indirect on both
sides (e.g. Visa), on one side or direct on both sides (e.g. eBay). When a
platform is indirect, it needs to think about its value proposition to its
intermediaries, as well as its end users.

Governance
What are the main rules governing the platform?

• Users and producers joining rules: Who should be allowed to join the
platform? Everyone (open) or a curated few (closed)? How can the
positioning of your platform encourage your target users to join (and keeps
others at bay)?
• Centralized/decentralized governance: Will you keep control of manage-
ment decisions? For example, will the pricing of products and services
on the platform be delegated to the ecosystem stakeholders (i.e. eBay
sellers setting product prices) or will it be under the platform’s control
(i.e. Uber setting car ride tariffs).
• User experience control: How much of the user experience should you
control vs platform producers/users?
• Users and producers operating rules: What should be the rules for users
and producers to keep the right to interact and transact on the platform?
82 Life stages of platforms: design

The rocket model for platform design

Attract
Using the platform stakeholders identified above, it is helpful to go through
the value they bring to the platform – as well as the value that the platform
brings to them – to ensure that the overall architecture is consistent with the
type of self-reinforcing community model that powers most platforms.
For traditional businesses, this is a fairly straightforward exercise, as shown
in Table 7.2 for the Hilton Group.

Table 7.2 Hilton’s value proposition

Hilton Value proposition to hosts How


Value proposition ‘Leading brands serving virtually Identify prime locations, build/
any lodging need anywhere’5 acquire hotels, manage hospitality
logistics, sell rooms and invest in
Hilton brands
Source: Launchworks

The exercise is, however, a bit more complex for a multisided business
because: (i) there is more than one value proposition to define; and (ii) several
stakeholders can contribute, which is a significant difference from traditional
businesses. A good way to do this methodically is to use the matrix in
Table 7.3 and map each value proposition, and associated contributions from

Table 7.3 Deconstructing value propositions for multisided businesses

User (or US for Producer (or PS Partner (P) Platform (PO)


user side) for producer side)
Motivation ‘motivations of ‘motivations of ‘objectives and ‘objectives and
users for producers for vision of the vision of the
transacting on transacting on the partners in the platform owner’
the platform’ platform’ context of the
platform’
Value Contribution Contribution Contribution Contribution
proposition from from from from
(target) PO: PO: PO: US:
PS: US: US: PS:
P: P: PS: P:
US: PS: P: PO:
Source: Adapted from Simone Cicero, Platform Design Toolkit
Life stages of platforms: design 83

key stakeholders. This framework was used at eBay to identify value


proposition gaps and compare against competitive offers. It has been formalized
by Simone Cicero in the Platform Design Toolkit.6
Let’s use the above framework to map Airbnb’s value propositions in
Table 7.4.

Table 7.4 Airbnb’s value propositions

User (US) Producer (PS) Partner (P) Platform (PO)


Guests Hosts Hospitality service Airbnb
companies
Motivation Experience a Monetize my Solve admin, Attract, match
new place like place when I’m hospitality and and connect
locals do away cleaning pain guests and hosts
points for and generate a
Airbnb hosts/ margin
Provide experi-
ences to guests
Value PO: mobile and PO: listing tools, PO: access to a PS: publish and
proposition Web access, calendar, efficient market of hosts in manage listing(s),
efficient search, matching, safe need of hospitality host guests, pay
safe transaction transaction and services and host service fee,
and payment payment services, guests looking for write guest
services, cus- insurance, cus- experiences reviews
tomer care tomer care
PS: detailed listings, US: guest reviews US: search and
home hosting, book listing(s),
guest reviews pay guest service
fee, write host
P: unique local
reviews
experiences
US: reviews from P: listing and key PO: raise funds to
other guests management, meet support growth
and greet, cleaning
services
PS: reviews from P: assist hosts,
other hosts provide experi-
ences for guests
Source: Launchworks

Users, producers and partners will need tools and services to encourage
contributions. We therefore recommend mapping the likely tools and services
required for each customer group to facilitate them joining and operating on
the platform.
84 Life stages of platforms: design

The design of tools and associated features will largely be driven by how
platform owners plan to structure content from producers and users. This
question is particularly important for product marketplaces, such as Amazon
Marketplace or Etsy, for example. While Amazon manages a predefined
catalogue template against which sellers can create listings, craft marketplace
Etsy allows each listing to contain product information that is completely
custom. Etsy, however, prescribes a template with required fixed attributes,
such as the listing title, description, price, delivery cost and availability, in
order to control the front-end experience, while allowing the seller to be
relatively free-form with their supplied content. By contrast, social platforms
such as community forum Reddit or Facebook allow users to post largely
unstructured content in a free-form format. These considerations impact how
much control the platform owner applies to producer content, and this has
a direct impact on the matching, connect, trust and brand dimensions.

Match
Matching is a platform-specific activity, and key questions need to be addressed
at this platform design stage:

• What will be the matching criteria that need to be captured by the plat-
form?
• Will the matching rely on structured and formatted content or free-flow
content? Will the function be automated or manual and done by the
platform owner (in the early days)?
• To what extent will people self-select? For example, are people expected
to apply filters themselves to access relevant content?

The more information from platform participants is captured manually at


the outset, the greater the friction is. However, capturing relevant information
can enable efficient matching. For example, dating platform eHarmony asks
members to fill in a detailed questionnaire, and the results feed into their
compatibility-matching algorithm. While the length of the questionnaire can
be seen as an obstacle to joining the platform, the granularity of results allows
for optimal matching and successful ‘transactions’ (defined here as successful
dates). Dating platform Happn has a very different approach to matching,
which, according to CEO Didier Rappaport, reflects how people meet in
real life. Initial matching is done on where participants have been and who
else has passed within an 800-foot radius, gender orientation and age. No
need to fill in a questionnaire to join Happn. A simple Facebook log in is
enough to populate one’s profile. Over time, the matching algorithm learns
Life stages of platforms: design 85

form participant activity – who they’ve liked, sent charms to or had a con-
versation with.

Connect
Many platforms need to also enable peer-to-peer connection between platform
participants post-matching because the combination of these enabling
interactions drives the overall core transactions. Key questions at this stage
include:

• What will be the type and nature of interactions between users and
producers?
• How will users and producers interact on- and off-platform?
• How much structure should be applied to participants’ interactions?
• How can interactions be captured in a way that will enhance the platform’s
matching and support core transactions?

Transactional platforms such as marketplaces typically require advanced


connection capabilities between participants when one or several of the
following apply:

(i) the asymmetry of information between market participants is high;


(ii) the transaction is more a ‘one-off’ than a ‘recurring’ purchase; and
(iii) the value of the transaction is relatively high.

For example, the probability of using the messaging function of eBay to


ask questions to an individual car seller before making the transaction is high
(the three conditions above are met), while asking many questions to a
marketplace seller about napkins, notepads or pens (recurring and relatively
low-value purchases of products you already know) is less likely.

Transact
The ultimate goal of platforms is to maximize the number of value-adding
core transactions. Beyond defining what the core transaction actually is, clarity
on the following questions will be useful:

• What is the nature/type of core transactions?


• Will core transactions be on and off the platform?
• How will supporting interactions (covered in the connect section) enable
core transactions?
86 Life stages of platforms: design

• Which elements will be needed to complete core transactions (payment,


delivery aspects, other)? If the platform involves the physical delivery of
goods, should the delivery be outsourced to producers or should it be
intermediated by the platform?

While the main purpose of platforms is to enable value exchange between


participants, value capture should also be discussed early on. It is critical to
minimize friction in the earlier days of the platform, but it is equally important
to understand monetization options:

• Which side adds the most value? How is it enabled?


• How to monetize? Which side(s) to charge?

Even platforms that ended up monetizing late in their development often


experimented with revenue models very early in order to understand the
implications of the various growth models available to them.

Optimize
Although there is no data available at pre-launch to optimize the platform,
it is appropriate to think about the type of data that the platform could usefully
capture without increasing friction too much.
Key questions at this stage include:

• What information will the platform need to gather in order to test the
main hypotheses behind the business case?
• Which interactions between platform participants can be captured in a
small set of key performance indicators (KPIs) to track platform
developments and help identify bottlenecks as it scales?
• Which metrics can best measure platform success?

While the selection of KPIs is not an exact science, we found that the
following principles were often helpful in the context of platform design.
The definition of a generic overriding growth metric, that we call a ‘North
Star’, can be helpful to track the overall health of the platform community.
Beyond encapsulating a key growth dimension, it also represents the key
engagement/core transaction of the platform. The North Star metric should
be fully endorsed and championed by the CEO, and remains the same
through growth stages to guide all employees.
Selecting the right North Star metric depends on the type of platform you
are running. It is important to note that the core transaction may take place
Life stages of platforms: design 87

off the platform (e.g. dates or restaurant meals), and so a proxy metric may
be needed. The types of key engagement metrics include value exchanged
(e.g. gross merchandise value for marketplaces such as eBay or Etsy), transaction
numbers (e.g. nights booked at Airbnb,7 messages sent for WhatsApp), activity
or participation metrics (e.g. posts or monthly active users for social media8),
expressions of interest or connections that lead to off-platform transactions
(e.g. restaurant bookings on OpenTable).
Tracking of user behaviours through the various rocket stages gives a help-
ful picture of the platform’s overall health. As we will see in the next three
chapters, the key for each stage is to find relevant metrics that capture the
main enabling interaction as well as core transactions.

Enablers
Like any business, it is important to sketch the type of user experience the
platform will deliver, the interface it will need, how payments (if any) will
be made and what type of technical architecture it may have, as well as the
company’s key brand attributes and culture. Pre-launch, most of the above
topics are similar to traditional firms, but the following are platform-specific.

Governance and trust


Defining the rules of access and engagement for both producers and users
will determine who can join the platform, how they interact and transact.
This groundwork is essential to building the foundations of trust between
participants. Platform governance and trust are broad subjects that will be
covered more extensively in Chapter 12.

To make or to buy a technical platform solution?


As your platform concept gets defined, how should you build the technical
infrastructure underlying your platform? Should you build it yourself or use
an off-the-shelf solution?
There is currently a limited selection of software solutions able to support
platform-based business models out of the box, although choice is improving.
This means that the make-buy decision will depend upon the availability of
a solution catering for the vertical market being concerned, as well as specific
circumstances.
For existing businesses that may not have the right in-house development
capabilities but wish to add a marketplace to their existing ecommerce offering,
buying off-the-shelf software and plugging it into an existing infrastructure
88 Life stages of platforms: design

is likely to be the fastest and least risky solution – at least in the short term.
For well-defined verticals such as marketplaces for products, some well-
developed software solutions9 do exist. Solutions are usually Software as a
Service (SaaS)-based and priced on a revenue sharing model, which may be
fine initially but can become fairly costly for the platform owner as the platform
scales.
If you’re starting from scratch, or are addressing a specific vertical that is
not covered by existing software solutions, you may need to build the platform
infrastructure yourself. Bespoke development will give more control and the
ability to iterate quickly and customize the experience from a producer, user
and owner perspective. More investment will be required up front for
technical design and development. So it may be the preferred solution for
founders who know how to code, or for established firms with access to quality
developers.
The answer also depends upon the strategy planned to overcome the
chicken-and-egg problem described in the next chapter. If the initial focus
is on recruiting one side of the market first, the early technology selection
needs to consider this. Many successful start-ups launched basic concept
validation using off-the-shelf ‘pipe’ software designed for one side of the
market (usually the user side), such as Shopify or Magento, while manually
dealing with the back-end supply side.10 However, this may not always be
feasible if building liquidity on both sides is a really important driver early
on. When possible, though, this path enables market validation on a reduced
budget until you can demonstrate traction. Migration to a more scalable
infrastructure later on may be painful, but this transition may be the price to
pay for de-risking development costs up front.
The market for off-the-shelf platform software is changing rapidly, though.
Mirakl, Izberg, Near-me, Sharetribe and Marketplace Lab offer off-the-shelf
marketplace solutions for retailers, while Upwork offers white-label freelancer
marketplace solutions to large corporates. As the platform market matures,
we anticipate enterprise software vendors to develop platform solutions tailored
to specific verticals (telecoms, health, professional services, etc.) and offer
platform as a service – or PaaS – solutions.

Design a platform as an add-on to an existing business


Many established businesses now understand the impact of platforms and are
keen to add or replicate platform capabilities to their own activities. In such
cases, the platform design stage needs to take into account a range of additional
considerations that are related to the overall strategy of the company. Lever-
ageable assets, brand equity, resources and existing client relationships can be
Life stages of platforms: design 89

both a help and a hindrance in the context of a platform play. Some of the
difficulties for existing firms considering a transition to a platform model or
add-on will be discussed in Chapter 14.

Notes
1 Business model generation, with its previously mentioned business model canvas tool,
is a good start.
2 Eric Ries’s The Lean Startup has become a de rigueur read for any would-be entrepreneur
keen to change the world on a limited budget. See E. Ries, The Lean Startup, New
York: Crown Publishing, 2011.
3 While Hilton can manage and tightly control the experience of its guests, Airbnb can
only influence the experience provided by the hosts.
4 Henry Blodget, 19 January 2015, Business Insider, http://uk.businessinsider.com/uber-
revenue-san-francisco-2015-1.
5 Hilton Investor Presentation, November 2015.
6 The Platform Design Toolkit 2.0, the ecosystem’s motivation matrix, by Simone Cicero,
www.meedabyte.com.
7 Airbnb CEO Brian Chesky routinely tweets their nights booked milestones.
8 Alex Schultz, How to Start a Start-up, Lecture 6: Growth, Sam Altman.
9 We have seen a number of interesting implementations of Mirakl at Galeries Lafayette,
Darty, Halfords and l’Equipe.
10 LoveKnitting, the marketplace for knitting yarn, patterns and needles, was initially built
on Magento. Truly, a marketplace for unique experiences, was initially built on an even
tighter budget, using WordPress and WooCommerce, before migrating to Magento.
Chapter 8

Platform ignition
Proving the concept

The business architecture of the platform has been designed and a technical
solution has been built for ignition. The platform now needs to be launched
and platform participants recruited in order to test the platform’s concept.
The key challenge at this stage is typically to develop a minimum viable
product (MVP) of the platform that allows you to attract enough producers
and users in order to test your business hypothesis. You need to decide which
side to attract first and how to go about it. Since the platform hasn’t yet got
many users, there will be opportunities for iterating on the proposition, testing
additional features, different market channels, etc.
The main objective of this ignition stage is for your platform to pass the
product/market fit test that we also call ‘platform fit’, since it tests whether
the platform is able to attract, match, connect and enable transactions among
its participants. It would be very difficult for anybody to attract significant
capital to scale before showing a genuinely strong engagement from customers,
at least in a given market niche/community.
Finding this ‘platform fit’ is not straightforward and may require many
iterations of the original concept. It is, however, critical that the platform
manages to find its ‘fit’ relatively quickly since, unlike other more traditional
business models, platforms are only viable after they reach a critical mass
of participants.1 If it takes too much time for the platform to attract enough
participants, the platform is in danger of losing momentum and ‘unravelling’.
This is what happens when users are not finding what they are looking
for because the platform is subscale (e.g. imagine a dating site with only a
few profiles). If the platform is free, then its perceived value may still be positive
without much scale. But if the platform is already charging for its services,
participants are likely to be less forgiving.
Conversely, moving to the scaling phase should only take place once the
‘platform fit’ is validated. Understanding any technical or product obstacles
for platform participants to experience their ‘magic moment’ on the platform
92 Platform ignition: proving the concept

(i.e. the moment where they experience real value) is also a prerequisite. It
is much easier to make changes to the value proposition with few customers
than at scale.
The ignition stage is also the stage at which contracts need to be drafted
and signed by platform participants. These are very important and need to
clarify the responsibilities and liabilities of the parties (platform owner,
producers and users). Platform contracts also need to make it clear that
platform participants are not employees of the firm.
Getting the ‘cookie cutter’ right before scaling is therefore one of the key
objectives of the ignition phase.
The key ignition questions of Figure 8.1 are developed below. There are
two distinct scenarios. The first one is launching a platform from scratch. It
creates a unique chicken-and-egg problem: Which side of the platform should
be attracted first? The second scenario is when the platform is launched as an
add-on to an existing business.

Figure 8.1 Ignition rocket questions to achieve platform fit


Source: Launchworks
Platform ignition: proving the concept 93

Launching from scratch: the chicken-and-egg problem


Attract
The platform needs to attract the target participants identified during the pre-
launch phase. The attraction and acquisition of customers online is a topic
worthy of a book in itself and the key issues are not unique to platform
businesses so we will be very brief on the ‘dark arts of customer acquisition’
and focus on platform-specific aspects. While customer acquisition strategies
change with each wave of Internet marketing techniques, developing a value
proposition for each side of the platform that resonates with targeted audiences
remains a major driver of attracting and retaining customers.
At the outset, a platform is faced with a conundrum: the value it creates
is predicated upon one side of the market seeking to transact with another
one. Since there is nobody on board at the beginning, it is, of course, parti-
cularly difficult to attract users and producers for the purpose of transacting.
This is a platform-specific problem. In terms of execution, the key tactics
that have been shown to help break the chicken-and-egg conundrum fall into
the following categories.

Focus on one side first


This is one way of breaking the deadlock of ‘no producers and no consumers’.
Simply focus on one side first – as a traditional company would do – and
then once you’ve developed a value proposition that makes sense for your
customers, pivot to start your platform play by opening the other side. Before
launching its taxi booking app in London, Hailo, now MyTaxi, developed a
deep understanding of a taxi driver’s life by talking to many black cab drivers.
Hailo addressed their main ‘pain points’ by offering a free mobile app to help
them manage their money more effectively and get real-time traffic and speed
camera information. Casper Woolley, one of Hailo’s founders, acknowledges
that it would have been extremely difficult to recruit taxi drivers without
this.
Similarly OpenTable first focused on the needs of restaurants by offering
them the tools to easily manage bookings online before opening up its listing
of restaurants to customers once it had reached a critical mass.2 The
combination of deep understanding of the economics and booking dynamics
of the restaurants they sold their software to, combined with a critical mass,
allowed OpenTable to negotiate booking fees and in turn invest in advertising
and loyalty points to attract many more customers.
Marketplaces often need to attract the supply side first. La Belle Asiette, a
marketplace matching chefs with diners at home, initially focused on attracting
94 Platform ignition: proving the concept

chefs. Helping chefs to create innovative menus, coupled with financial


incentives to secure availability on the platform, ensured that new diners had
a wide range of options available to them from day one.

Use your producers or users to attract the other side


By enabling one side to transact, your platform may give incentives to its
producers to bring in participants through their own networks. If a start-up
uses a crowdfunding platform for raising money, they will tell all their
potential investors about the campaign. Some may join the platform as
members and invest in other start-ups, and some may even decide to use the
platform to raise money for their own venture at a later stage. In the early
days, Etsy courted established crafters and leveraged word of mouth through
the ‘Stitch ’n Bitch’ movement by attending local art and craft fairs across the
US and Canada. These influential artisans had established substantial followings.
They had no e-commerce presence prior to Etsy and were therefore motivated
to recommend potential buyers to the site. We’ll see in Chapter 9 (scaling-
up) that identifying and recruiting early adopters who can recommend the
platform to a large following can significantly boost growth.

Seed one side to ignite traction


Sometimes the best way to get a platform going is to do what platform
participants would do if they knew the platform existed . . . but by yourself.
Hiring great contributors helped Medium kick-start its curated content
platform and established an image of quality contributions that subsequently
attracted both readers and contributors. Reddit initially submitted large amount
of content using fake profiles. It gave the impression that that site was alive and
in turn attracted people interested in the content.3 Online dating sites are
notoriously difficult to kick-start given the importance of having a critical mass
for traction in this area (e.g. how would you feel if a site was unable to match
you with anybody?). This has led to persistent rumours of fake profiles being
created – often of attractive single women who play the role of producers on
many dating platforms – at launch in order to seed that particular side.4

Focusing on meshed communities


Attracting both sides at the same time can be challenging, so it helps when
early producers also happen to be users. eBay initially launched collectables
categories, targeting existing offline communities of passionate collectors
(coins, stamps, etc.). eBay’s early focus on collectibles allowed the platform
Platform ignition: proving the concept 95

to grow a vibrant online community of people who were very often both
buyers and sellers. This overlap of roles is very useful in terms of entry point
for platforms, since a new platform participant will be adding value to the
platform both as a buyer/user and seller/producer. Meshed communities with
significant overlap are often prioritized as entry points for this reason.

The bowling pin strategy


One tested way to overcome the chicken-and-egg conundrum is what
Geoffrey Moore calls the bowling pin strategy:5 find a niche where the
chicken-and-egg problem is more easily overcome and then find ways to hop
from that niche to other niches, and eventually to the broader market. Typical
examples are Facebook, which was first ignited as a platform at Harvard,
and then slowly expanded to other Ivy League universities in the US before
crossing the pond and reaching some elite universities in the UK, then
spreading to all universities, and ultimately reaching almost everybody.6
The bowling pin strategy is also highly relevant for hyperlocal services where
platform owners need to create local matching within limited geographic areas.
This can be done with focused geographic targeting of relevant communities.
Deliveroo, the restaurant delivery platform, initially launched in Chelsea, a
relatively well-off area of London with lots of time-poor executives. It started
by recruiting restaurants and diners in the neighbourhood, before successfully
scaling to other parts of London and other cities in the UK and across the world.

Piggybacking on existing networks


There are many tales of platforms igniting by piggybacking on existing
networks. The most famous one is Airbnb. Craigslist had many users who
looked for listings other than the standard hotel experience, which was
precisely Airbnb’s target market. To attract guests, Airbnb developed an
integration with the Craigslist platform as early as 2010.7 It offered hosts who
listed properties on Airbnb the opportunity to automatically publish them on
Craigslist. To attract hosts, Airbnb also developed a hack that spammed
people posting listings on Craigslist, offering them to list on Airbnb.8 Both
hacks allowed Airbnb to grow their guest and host base at almost no cost.
PayPal initially ignited (when still independent from eBay) by targeting
eBay power-buyers and power-sellers, which were high growth segments at
the time. Cash incentives for people to join and refer others,9 combined with
a high velocity of buying and selling, generated viral growth, and PayPal
expanded rapidly to become the de facto payment solution on eBay,10
squeezing out eBay’s own in-house payment solution.
96 Platform ignition: proving the concept

The event strategy


A variant of the bowling pin strategy is what we call the ‘event’ strategy
(sometimes also called ‘big bang launch strategy’),11 in which the platform
chooses a particular event where a critical mass of an identified target
community is present in order to kick-start the platform in the hope that
other communities will follow. Typical examples of such a strategy include
the launch of Twitter (and then later Foursquare) at the South by Southwest
(SXSW) festival, which gave the company a captive audience for exchanging
short messages that were displayed in real time on stage. It also allowed Twitter
to recruit a critical mass of ‘opinion formers’ who were subsequently instru-
mental in spreading the app. Similarly, Tinder, the famous dating app recently
valued at more than $3 billion, was launched in 2012 at ‘exclusive’ University
of Southern California (USC) campus student parties, where downloading
the app was a condition of entry. This allowed them to sign up a significant
number of young singles, and they replicated the model at other universities,
using the college-by-college growth technique used by Facebook, in order
to get a critical mass in each relevant campus.12 After the parties, Tinder users
told their friends, and this led to a viral growth effect, reaching over 1 million
monthly active users (MAUs) within the first year.

The VIP strategy


The VIP strategy (also called the ‘marquee strategy’)13 consists of attracting
‘star’ producers or users on the platform, who in turn attract more producers
and/or users. Game console platforms often try to sign exclusive partnerships
with developers to attract players with ‘must-have’ games only available on
their console.
Tinder’s successful ‘hyperlocal saturation campaigns’ also targeted the most
popular organizations within colleges to seed the app with key influencers.
Whitney Wolfe, then VP of marketing, explains: ‘You need to identify social
influencers in small areas, see who the influencers are, and target them . . .
That’s how we spread throughout college campuses and other social scenes.’14
In more extreme examples, some platforms sign up powerful clients who
are then able to literally ‘coerce’ the other side into joining. A number of
large corporations who use Ariba’s supply management platform require sup-
pliers to onboard Ariba’s platform and answer a raft of questions before
becoming an accredited supplier. The Ariba platform then uses the information
provided to match the supplier with other possible work opportunities in
their field across other companies.
Platform ignition: proving the concept 97

The cultural meme


Embedding an existing cultural meme as part of the value proposition on one
side can also accelerate acquisition. To grow the adoption of its peer-to-peer
payment service, WeChat launched a feature called Lucky Money, later
renamed Red Packets, during the Chinese New Year Holiday in 2014. Red
Packets is modelled after red envelopes, a cultural tradition in China and parts
of South East Asia, where a monetary gift is given during holidays such as
the Chinese New Year or special occasions such as weddings, graduation
ceremonies or the birth of a baby. WeChat injected lottery-like features into
its digital version of red envelopes, which encouraged senders to share red
envelopes with large groups of friends to win goodwill. Viral effects started
to build with little acquisition costs.15 These were further compounded by
paid partnerships and advertising campaigns.16 Red Packets has today become
a new form of communication in China, with over 60 million WeChat users
sending Red Packets every day.17 Pokémon Go, which connects players with
advertisers through augmented reality (AR) gaming, also experienced
phenomenal growth at launch.18 The app game concept is based on the original
Game Boy and physical trading card game developed by Nintendo, which
has inspired millions of children worldwide – now young adults – over the
last 20 years. Pokémon Go’s growth was not sustained, but the Pokémon cultural
meme has played a key role in igniting the platform.

Match
Since the platform is now live, the objective is to make sure the matching works
on a small scale. Even if aspects of the matching still require manual inter-
ventions, it becomes important to start thinking about ways to automate this.
Key matching questions include:

• Is the basic matching concept working?


• What would need to be done for it to scale?
• How could the matching be improved?
• Is more data from platform participants required to improve matching
relevance?
• Are matching rules improved with more participants?

Depth of results
At launch, the platform may suffer from a lack of selection/choice for both
sides. As a result, the matching criteria need to be defined to maximize
liquidity.
98 Platform ignition: proving the concept

Relevance or matching quality


Relevance or matching quality is a function of matching information from
both users and producers against the right set of criteria. For platforms
such as product or service marketplaces, poor quality of structured informa-
tion on products or services may lead to suboptimal matching. For social
networks, though, it will be more about understanding users’ actions so that
they can be served with posts/content/ads and people they’re likely to engage
with.
At launch, ranking results against one criterion only may make sense until
you learn more about user preferences. Stootie, the French geo-localized service
marketplace initially ranked producers on their location. But as the plat-
form grew and the choice for producers increased, Stootie started to rank on
producer availability and feedback score. Producers with low feedback score
were also de-prioritized from the search results. The mix of search parameters
will likely evolve over time as the number of users and producers scales.

Timeliness
Many platforms try to display matching results instantly to meet participants’
needs. At the ignition stage, though, matching may still be done manually
for a range of platforms – say, a marketplace matching an expert consultant
with a complex technical assignment.
However, when participant behaviour is well understood, timely does not
always mean immediately. Carwow, the marketplace matching car buyers
and dealers, discovered that conversion rates were higher when search results
were not sent immediately to potential buyers, but a few hours later, as if the
platform was effectively taking time to negotiate on their behalf.

Connect
At ignition, the connect function may be quite basic, but the key questions
include:

• How do platform participants really interact?


• Is the connect function working? Is it currently a bottleneck for core
transactions or is it likely to become one in the future?
• What new interactions, communication features, rules or norms would
be most relevant to deal with such bottlenecks?
• What are the emerging patterns of communications between platform
participants, and what do they reveal about customer engagement?
Platform ignition: proving the concept 99

• Is there a need to add filters to the platform connection function (e.g.


prevent email addresses from being exchanged, etc.) in order to prevent
leakage or other unwanted behaviours emerging on the platform?

In its early days, the dog-sharing marketplace BorrowMyDoggy had lots


of activity, but few people made the jump of transacting on the platform.
BorrowMyDoggy introduced local meetups where dog owners and dog-sitters
could meet locally. This new type of off-platform interaction increased trust
between participants and unlocked further core transactions on the platform.
Since the platform is still adding significant value to the community – in terms
of access to veterinary help, insurance for both dog owners and borrowers,
information sheets on different breeds, etc. – the incentives to transact off
platform remain minimized.

Transact
At this stage, the main focus should be testing the proof of concept of the
prototype platform. The key questions are whether or not the interactions
previously identified are indeed leading to core transactions and under which
conditions:

• Is the platform managing to enable core transactions between participants?


• What are the bottlenecks to successful core interactions? Which ones are
on or off the platform?

Poor matching effectiveness (discussed previously) or lack of liquidity are


often bottlenecks during ignition. Platform liquidity is a proxy for activity on
the platform and how network effects are building. In finance, a market is
said to be liquid when assets can be quickly bought or sold without their
price being affected.19 The concept applies to platforms as well since they
need to ensure that transactions are as seamless as possible. For fashion
marketplaces such as Depop, Vinted or notonthehighstreet, ‘liquidity is the
reasonable expectation of selling something you list or finding what you’re
looking for’.20 For advertisers on Instagram, it will be the reasonable
expectation of eyeballs from the right demographics. Defining a minimum
liquidity target might be useful at this stage. For example, La Belle Asiette
aims for new chefs to get their first booking within two weeks.
A freemium model can be used at launch in order to minimize friction
while the platform is ‘subscale.’ But if participants are charged, is this creating
friction or solving a commitment problem on the platform?
100 Platform ignition: proving the concept

Building liquidity and network effects are often more important priorities
than monetization at this stage. However, while the priority should be
growing network effects, monetization experiments can be useful to develop
organizational expertise on revenue systems and operations, and to answer
monetization questions of investors in follow-up rounds. Facebook had small
advertising revenues from its very beginnings. LinkedIn also started to generate
revenues 18 months after launch.21 The interplay between pricing and revenue
generation is developed further in Chapter 11.

Optimize
The optimization process is quite critical during the ignition stage. In fact,
the platform is likely to change quite dramatically in the early days based on
participants’ direct and indirect feedback. One of the unique features of
platforms is that development can be shaped at least as much by participants
as by platform owners. This endows the platform with some strategic flexibility
that traditional businesses would only dream of, since participants can start
using the platforms for a range of activities that may not have been even
identified as opportunities at the outset.22 Some key optimization questions
at ignition are:

• Are the metrics giving a good sense of bottleneck formation that prevents
core transactions?
• Is feedback from platform participants taken on board?
• Are the key datapoints/insights needed to demonstrate traction captured?
• Does the optimization process enable convergence towards platform fit?

In addition to the North Star metric, which was introduced in the


previous chapter, several focus areas should be closely monitored during
the ignition phase. They are related to achieving platform fit, creating liquidity,
clearing interaction and core transaction bottlenecks and raising capital. While
KPIs are likely to be industry-specific, a few generic examples are proposed
in Table 8.1.

Enablers
Typically, many of the platform-enabling capabilities, from governance, trust,
brand and customer experience, to infrastructure support, are in their infancy
at launch. They are there to support the MVP and make sure that early traction
can be demonstrated. Platform owners should be thinking about the following
questions:
Platform ignition: proving the concept 101

• What are the basic enabling capabilities needed at ignition?


• Which enabling capability is most likely to become a bottleneck in the
near future and how much investment will be required to fix it?

This doesn’t mean that enabling capabilities are not important, but rather
that they are unlikely to be immediate bottlenecks at ignition. If early parti-
cipants are tech-savvy early adopters who like the platform concept, they won’t
mind the imperfections and will willingly provide feedback to improve the
user experience. As the number of participants is still small, the launch team
should be able to be right on top of any participant issue that comes up,
and update governance rules on an ongoing basis. Participants should feel

Table 8.1 Examples of performance metrics at platform ignition

Platform fit
• Engagement: % of sign-ups that search, connect, transact
• Customer feedback: particularly qualitative
• Customer retention: % of users that remain active, ‘retention curves’
Clearing core interaction bottlenecks
Liquidity:
• Ratio of active users (producers) to total users (producers) and ratio of active users to
active producers
• Number of active users/producers vs minimum liquidity target
• On-boarding completion rates
• Fulfilment completion rates and time (e.g. suppliers delivering goods on time), waiting times
for users (e.g. Uber car waiting times)
• Utilization rate of any seeded liquidity (e.g. utilization rates of Uber drivers directly
employed vs the minimum utilization to be viable)
• Ratio of nil return search queries to total search queries
Matching effectiveness:
• Ratio of searches to core transactions
• Ratio of matches to core transactions
• Quality of supplier presentation (e.g. Airbnb listings and professional photography bookings)
Metrics to raise capital
• Growth rate of active users and producers (above some defined activity level, e.g. Instagram
daily active users)
• Viral coefficient and breakdown of paid vs organic viral growth
• Speed to saturation in targeted niche markets (e.g. Facebook penetration in college
campuses)
• Super user segments (e.g. % of users above higher engagement level thresholds)
• Revenue proxies: metrics correlated with revenue
Source: Launchworks
102 Platform ignition: proving the concept

comfortable interacting and transacting on the platform. Basic checks should


take place, even if they are done manually at the ignition stage.
What is more important at ignition is to minimize friction for users and
producers to easily join, on-board the platform, and start interacting.

Launch an add-on to an existing business


Established companies interested in harnessing the power of platforms – to
become a platform-powered ecosystem – may find that they already have
possible sides of platform businesses. Retailers such as Amazon or Zalando
were already successful online retailers when they decided to open their busi-
ness model further to merchants, stylists, designers or manufacturers. French
retailer Darty had an established online and physical presence with thousands
of shops before opening its online marketplace. Cloud-based team collabor-
ation Slack built a strong user base before launching a platform and an app
directory, connecting users with apps through its API.23
Launching a platform on the back of an existing linear business to create
a ‘platform-powered ecosystem’ may appear easier than launching from
scratch. After all, if there is an existing customer base, adding another side
must be easier than launching two sides from scratch. While this may be the
case, adding a platform to an existing business comes with a number of
challenges, including risks of disruption, need for coordination of different
business models, alignment of incentives, skills and culture. These issues are
discussed further in Chapter 14.

Notes
1 www.launchworksventures.com/insights/scaling-up-a-necessity-for-platform-businesses/.
2 OpenTable was able to reach a critical mass of restaurants and diners in some cities first
where it launched its platform. It still sold its online booking tools to restaurants in other
markets where it was building its presence.
3 See http://venturebeat.com/2012/06/22/reddit-fake-users/.
4 There are many examples of allegations of fake profile schemes. In 2014, the Federal
Trade Commission reached a settlement that prohibits JDI Dating Ltd., the British
company that owns 18 dating sites, from using fake, computer-generated profiles to trick
users into upgrading to paid memberships and charging these members a recurring
monthly fee without their consent: www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2014/10/
online-dating-service-agrees-stop-deceptive-use-fake-profiles.
5 See Chris Dixon’s blog post on the topic, www.businessinsider.com/the-bowling-pin-
strategy-2010-8?IR=T.
6 Facebook has in excess of 1 billion users logging in daily and monthly active users in
excess of 1.7 billion at the time of writing.
Platform ignition: proving the concept 103

7 Rishi Shah, 24 November 2010, www.gettingmoreawesome.com/2010/11/24/airbnb-


leverages-craigslist-in-a-really-cool-way/.
8 Dave Gooden, 31 March 2011, http://davegooden.com/2011/05/how-airbnb-became-
a-billion-dollar-company/.
9 4 May 2012, Peter Thiel’s CS183: Startup – Class 9 Notes Essay, http://blakemasters.
com/post/22405055017/peter-thiels-cs183-startup-class-9-notes-essay.
10 By the time PayPal was acquired by eBay, 70% of all eBay auctions accepted PayPal
payments, and roughly one in four closed auction listings were transacted using the
payment service. VentureBeat, 27 October 2012, http://venturebeat.com/2012/10/27/
how-ebays-purchase-of-paypal-changed-silicon-valley/#8cV8y19jcBArQLfE.99.
11 G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York: W. W.
Norton & Company, 2016, p. 97.
12 Bryan Hackett, ‘Tinder’s First Year User Growth Strategy’, 3 March 2015, https://
parantap.com/tinders-first-year-growth-strategy/.
13 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, Matchmakers: The New Economics of Multisided Platforms,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 2016.
14 Bryan Hackett, ‘Tinder’s First Year User Growth Strategy’, 3 March 2015, https://
parantap.com/tinders-first-year-growth-strategy/.
15 Connie Chan, http://a16z.com/2016/07/24/money-as-message/.
16 The first prominent campaign was the Festival Gala TV show on CCTV during the
annual Spring Festival. It is the largest TV show on earth, with seven times the number
of viewers of the Super Bowl in the US. WeChat advertisers distributed $81 million of
digital money to 36 million WeChat users.
17 Stephen Wang, WeChat senior product manager, Siyu Xiao, WeChat product manager,
https://soundcloud.com/wechatpodcast/red-packets-wechats-secret-weapon-in-
payments.
18 Pokémon Go was launched in July 2016. It is one of the most used mobile apps in 2016,
having been downloaded more than 500 million times worldwide in less than two months
since launch.
19 High price dispersion is often the sign of an inefficient and illiquid market.
20 Simon Rothman, 19 August 2012, https://techcrunch.com/2012/08/19/how-to-
structure-a-marketplace/.
21 Matt Colher, Quora, 16 March 2016, www.quora.com/In-the-early-days-of-LinkedIn-
how-much-of-a-focus-was-there-on-monetization-and-who-was-their-target-customer.
22 eBay’s founder, Pierre Omidyar, was the first to be surprised when eBay’s first auction
revealed a buyer interested in purchasing broken laser pointers.
23 16 December 2015, Slack API, https://medium.com/slack-developer-blog/launch-
platform-114754258b91#.1yrakzpuk.
Chapter 9

Platform scaling
Reaching critical mass

Congratulations, the platform has been ignited and the business concept pro-
ven. Now that you have clearly demonstrated a valid platform concept and
early traction, more funding will be required to support the scaling-up phase
and really take the ‘rocket’ into orbit. Since this growth stage can take several
years and a number of funding rounds, it covers a wide range of business
situations, but the key questions remain the same.
Platform fit is a prerequisite for successful scaling. Otherwise, the money
spent on marketing to acquire lots of customers is unlikely to generate
customer engagement and value creation. We agree with Sean Ellis, CEO of
GrowthHackers, who says that ‘you should survey your user base before doing
growth work. At least 40% of your users should say they would be very
disappointed if your service or product went away overnight’.1 If the platform
is part of an add-on to an existing business, or part of a transformation, it is also
important to ensure that scaling investment is not available ‘too early’. While
this may sound counterintuitive, the danger for large firms keen to push their
new platforms is to invest in scaling before the platform fit is achieved.
This stage is critical for the platform since it is likely to have to go through
the usual ‘growth pains’ associated with scaling-up. This includes preserving
the winning culture, introducing new scalable processes, attracting talents,
looking beyond domestic boundaries, attracting significant growth investments,
navigating regulatory hurdles and attracting growth capital,2 to name a few.
This critical growth phase is also a unique period of transition between the
well-documented and supported start-up stage and the more traditional
challenges associated with the management of large firms. There are now
excellent resources3 and tips on scaling-up that, while not always uniquely
tailored to platforms, are highly relevant to inform and guide the platform
owners during this important phase.
From a platform point of view, the main challenge is to grow each side to
critical mass in a balanced way. The monetization question may also become
106 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

important during the scaling-up stages, although in some cases this question
is only relevant after a critical mass has been reached. Lastly, the existence of
imitators in other countries may provide an added stimulus for some platforms
to scale globally as quickly as possible.4
During the scaling phase, the following activities should be in focus:

• Use of marketing levers to keep growth balanced between the two sides.
• Reduce friction (improve customer experience) to increase velocity.
• Get insights into tipping point/critical mass, network value and level of
network effects.
• Foster trust and safety, and scale customer service team.
• Deploy and optimize pricing model.
• Develop a distinctive brand that resonates with customers on both sides
of the platform.

The key scaling questions summarized in Figure 9.1 are developed below.

Figure 9.1 Scaling-up the rocket to reach critical mass


Source: Launchworks
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 107

Attract
Scaling effectively will probably require significant investment in customer
acquisition not only to gain traction, but also to create a viral acquisition
effect. For some platforms, often those with a social network component such
as Facebook, Instagram or LinkedIn, the all-important ‘viral coefficient’ (also
sometimes called K-factor or contagion coefficient)5 will become critical
since it will contribute significantly to the traction of the platform and the
efficiency of marketing.

Perfect the on-boarding process on both sides


As more users and producers join the platform, the on-boarding process needs
to be as smooth as possible for both sides. It might be acceptable to on-board
producers and/or users manually at ignition to test a platform concept, but
automation becomes critical prior to the scaling phase to accelerate growth
and keep costs down. While many traditional businesses need to add significant
resources in line with their growth (i.e. buy more raw materials, get more
employees), platforms should be able to rely on significant automation of the
key platform functions to scale at a minimal incremental cost.
Special attention to on-boarding can pay off not only in terms of customer
acquisition numbers, but, most importantly, it can make a big difference to
customer engagement and customer retention. As Facebook opened up
beyond the Ivy League schools, the social network realized that the on-
boarding experience for users was more than just joining the platform.
Analysing cohorts of new joiners showed that users who connected to 10
friends in the first 14 days were far more engaged and were way more likely
to become lifelong users. On the other hand, users making fewer friends in
the first few days tended to lose interest and become inactive. This could be
easily explained: no or few friends meant that customers’ newsfeeds were
empty, and no one would see their posts, hence limiting the number of
potential interactions. So VP of growth, Alex Schultz, and his team focused
on making it easy for new joiners to quickly find friends. This included
collecting the most appropriate data during the on-boarding journey – such
as age, school, university attended, company, etc. – so the matching function
could automatically suggest the best results in terms of potential friends.
Facebook found the right balance after many iterations and is now able to
collect key information required to find enough relevant ‘friends’ quickly and
without making the sign-up process too cumbersome. Alex talks about the
‘magical moment’ when users see their friends on Facebook. ‘It is just as simple
as when you see the first picture of one of your friends on Facebook, you
go “Oh my God, this is what this site is about!”.’6 Concentrating on getting
108 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

that magical moment right has had a profound impact on both user retention
and engagement. The on-boarding process should be designed to enable these
‘magical moments’.
On-boarding can often be more complex on the producer side for two
reasons. First, the platform may try to apply quality filters on the producers it
accepts. For example, TaskRabbit helpers go through a screening process,
including interviews, before being able to offer their services on the platform.
There is a trade-off between the selectivity level of the platform towards
producers and achieving critical mass as soon as possible. The dynamics
between the level of openness for producers joining the platform and the joining
customer experience can, however, be flexed over time as the platform scales.
When Uber launched in the UK in 2012, drivers had to go through a com-
prehensive training before being able to register on the platform. Three years
later, the on-boarding process still includes driver screening but is now much
simpler and faster. The Uber ‘ignite’ programme offers a step-by-step process
for securing the required licence and, depending on the country, get specific
training, tests, medical exams, access to a car and insurance marketplace, visit
of Uber offices and financial incentive to start as an Uber driver.7 It is designed
to minimize the friction and assist would-be Uber drivers with the entire process
of joining the platform. It benefited from the feedback of many Uber drivers
who helped identify bottlenecks on the driver recruitment side.
Second, new producers may need to familiarize themselves with tools to
engage and ultimately transact on the platform. Depending on the complexity
of the on-boarding process, email, phone, training or even dedicated account
management resources should be allocated. The level of support should be
proportionate to the effort required for producers to interact and therefore may
vary across customer segments. eBay provides email support for consumer sellers
registering a listing on the marketplace, a five-step process that is designed to
take no more than a few minutes. For large merchants and brands, a dedicated
team of account managers is on call to help with listing catalogues and
integrating eBay as part of their multichannel strategy. The on-boarding process
is also a unique opportunity to convey key messages about the ethos, govern-
ance principles and norms of good behaviours to new platform participants.

Acquire users and producers


There is no one-size-fits-all approach when it comes to scaling the number
of producers and users to critical mass. While acquisition should be the first
priority when starting the scaling process, retention should become a close
second as soon as producers and users have been engaged for long enough
on the platform.
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 109

Figure 9.2 User and producer acquisition sources


Source: Adapted from T. Eisenmann, G. Parker and M. van Alstyne ‘Strategies for Two-Sided Markets’,
Harvard Business Review, 84(10), October 2006

While initially designed to solve the chicken-and-egg problem, some


ignition techniques that we have already discussed, such as the bowling pin
strategy, can still be very useful to unlock pockets of supply and demand during
scaling stages. By mapping adjacent target segments and communities, which
can themselves be leveraged to win other segments, the platform may better
inform the allocation of its marketing spend. Acquiring users and producers
can be achieved by using resources from the platform itself but also by
leveraging marketing capabilities from users and producers themselves. There
are six growth dynamics at play,8 as shown in Figure 9.2, which can all be
modelled to forecast growth and funding requirements:

1 Direct acquisition of new producers and new users by the platform. The platform
markets directly and acquires producers and users, through organic (press,
SEO, email, social media, direct mail, etc.) and paid acquisition channels.
2 Acquisition of new users through existing producers. The producers themselves
market the benefits of joining and using the platform to their customers
and people in their network. This can be through word of mouth, social
media or platform tools aimed at helping producers advertise. Indiegogo,
Kickstarter and other crowdfunding platforms have viral invite loops
enabling project owners to invite people in their network to join in and
110 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

fund their project. Eventbrite acquires new users by relying on event


organizers to invite attendees to their events.
3 Acquisition of new producers through existing users. This is the reverse, with
users themselves inviting producers to join the platform, using similar
channels and/or features. We mentioned above Eventbrite’s viral loop of
event organizers inviting attendees to their events. After attendees buy
tickets, they discover that they can also use the platform to organize their
own events.
4 Acquisition of new users through existing users. Product features such as viral
invite loops are a great way to tap into existing users’ networks to acquire
new users. For example, Snapchat and WhatsApp ask users to invite their
friends by importing their contact books.
5 Acquisition of new producers through existing producers. Finally, existing
producers can help acquire new ones. In addition to the techniques
mentioned above, new content generated by producers can help acquire
new producers and users. Knowledge platform Quora uses fresh con-
tent produced by its contributors to continually improve its search
rankings. This makes Quora more visible to readers and contributors, and
helps attract new readers and contributors, creating a positive feedback
loop.

The above-mentioned viral loops can be very useful to maintain low


acquisition costs. Instagram spent very little marketing in the first couple of
years, relying instead on viral loops, brand ambassadors and great app store
ratings, which all contributed to securing a top place in the app stores. Etsy
also has a low cost of acquisition thanks to viral effects, with the majority of
gross market sales generated from organic marketing channels (i.e. from users
and sellers themselves). In 2015, 91% of Etsy’s site traffic came from direct,
organic and email traffic sources, with only 9% from paid traffic. The under-
lying strength of a large organic channel is also illustrated by Etsy’s repeat
purchase rate, with 81% of purchases from repeat customers in 2015.9
Many of the growth techniques listed above rely on several levers and
not just marketing. Brian Rothenberg, VP of growth and acquisition
marketing at event booking platform Eventbrite, emphasizes how growth is
a cross-functional effort: ‘Growth is best driven through tight alignment and
coordination between marketing, product, engineering and analytics’.10

Retain users and producers


Once users and producers have been interacting long enough on the platform,
it’s time to look for those who don’t come back or churn. It can be difficult
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 111

to measure initially because the numbers may not be significant enough. This
is especially true for transactional platforms where the frequency of interaction
and transaction is low – for example, legal services platforms where a client
may hire a lawyer for a one-off case. It is, however, essential to have a sense
of how many users and producers are no longer engaged and why, and
customer feedback is a good way to do this (Net Promoter Score11 surveys,
for example). For these reasons, retention efforts at the beginning of the scaling
stage tend to focus on product and customer experience improvements, and
reviews of user and producer funnels.
As the platform scales and more users and producers join, get matched,
connect and transact on the platform, network effects start to kick in and the
value proposition becomes richer for all participants. Such positive feedback
loops may translate into more selection for users, more reviews for producers
and more overall traffic, which in turn attract more users and producers.
A review of the value proposition might be useful at this stage to understand
what users and producers value most in the platform, and what features/
attributes are currently missing. Tools and services can make a significant
contribution to producer engagement. Beyond traffic, Amazon Marketplace
offers bulk listing, editing and management tools to enable merchants to list
and update listings as efficiently as possible. Sometimes important aspects of
the value proposition are outside of the direct control of the platform. For
example, Deliveroo, the food delivery platform, discovered that many of its
drivers were joining while learning English before trying to become Uber
drivers. This became an unexpected part of Deliveroo’s value proposition to
its drivers.

Aiming for ‘balance’


Keeping the platform ‘balanced’ is critical to successful scaling. This requires
keeping tabs on the ratio of active producers to users in order to understand
where the sweet spot is, and when one side starts to become a bottleneck for
growth.
Once a bottleneck has been identified – say, not enough producers – the
platform needs to take action to get back into its ‘sweet spot’ ratio that
maximizes good interactions and transactions on the platform.
This sounds simple, but many platforms are not homogeneous, meaning
they have to manage different equilibria across different product/service
categories, at different points in time and in different geographies. In fact,
international platforms are often better represented as portfolios of platform
positions, each characterized by a given level of maturity and equilibrium in
a given country at a given point in time.
112 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

In some cases, platforms develop a ‘centralized’ or ‘regional’ function


whose goal it is to overcome the bottlenecks that appear during the scaling-up
phase. BlaBlaCar has a dedicated team focused on launching and scaling in
international markets. No less than 60 people from headquarters were allocated
to the project team who launched BlaBlaCar in India.12 eBay Europe set up
a centralized, dedicated team focused on optimizing search and stimulating
seller growth in countries and categories where buyer demand was strongest
– and sellers were becoming a bottleneck. Through targeted seller acquisition
and coaching, eBay was able to nudge its platform in the right direction by
improving both the quality and depth of its inventory, as well as search
relevance for buyers.
In our experience working with high-growth platforms, modelling the
growth of both user and producer communities is not straightforward,
but can provide valuable insights into how the balance between the two sides
is likely to shift over time. It also provides essential visibility on funding
requirements until the platform becomes profitable.

Developing value propositions for new customer segments


While the core offering to users and producers is unlikely to have dramatically
changed since ignition, the needs of early customers may evolve over time,
while new types of customers may also join the platform. As a result, the value
propositions will require changes to meet new and existing customer needs.
For example, while eBay started as a C2C auction marketplace, many of
its most successful consumer sellers, who initially started selling as a hobby
on eBay, became professional sellers with carefully managed inventories and
sometimes full-time staff to deal with the logistics. As buyers also expressed
the need to be able to buy new items immediately at a fixed price in many
categories (fashion, electronics, home & garden, etc.), eBay saw an opportunity
to update its value proposition. It gave its increasingly professional sellers the
tools to list and sell in bulk new items at a fixed price. The Powerseller
programme, launched in 2005, offered fee discounts proportional to sales
volume, and resulted in the number of business sellers, their associated
inventory and sales scaling dramatically. By 2010, the majority of items sold
on eBay were offered by professional sellers. Today, eBay manages three
distinct seller segments: merchants, entrepreneurs and consumers. eBay offers
each of the three segments a distinct value proposition that meets their
different motivations and needs. Each segment brings a different kind of
inventory (unique, long tail and affordable inventory from consumer sellers
and entrepreneurs, as well as popular new products from merchants), as
illustrated in Table 9.1.
Table 9.1 Illustrative value proposition for a scaling product marketplace

Merchants Entrepreneur sellers Consumer seller


Motivation • Pragmatic, rational, profit driven • Highly engaged, passionate • Active buyers (‘think’ buyer)
• Sales strategy: multichannel • Sales strategy: mostly mono-channel • Sales strategy: mono-channel
• Motivation: What can I do to get • Motivation: What can the market- • Motivation: I want a secure and easy
the most out of the marketplace? place do more to help me? way to sell stuff for a great price

Key needs • Sales velocity • Sales velocity • Reliable way to sell an item
• Profitability • Make money • Easy to list/sell and ship
• Reliability/predictability • Support from the community and • Make some money (often to
marketplace fund buying activity)
• Safety

What each • Scalability offers growth potential • Bring unique long tail inventory • Extremely active buyers
segment brings in fashion and collectibles • Provides wide range of unique
• High concentration
to the table inventory: 50% of used items,
• Offer unique, personable
• 90% new inventory C2C auction inventory provides
e-commerce experience
• Offer trusted, e-commerce-like best value vs competition
experience
• Selling drives engagement and
loyalty/word of mouth
Source: Launchworks
114 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

At the end of the scaling phase, it is common for platforms to cater for the
needs of several consumer and producer segments. A C2C, B2C and B2B13
skill set is often required to understand the motivations of these diverse
customer segments, and how to best attract them.

Match
At this stage of development, the matching function can quickly become a
real bottleneck if it does not efficiently match users with relevant producers.

Balance of supply and demand


Close monitoring of matching results allows the platform to identify pockets
of missing supply (or demand) in particular verticals, locations, times of day,
etc., depending on the nature of the business. This information should be fed
back to the team members looking after attract and optimize activities in order
to improve the targeting and recruitment of platform participants and unlock
pockets of transactions. Hyperlocal marketplaces – which often require a
geographically located critical mass to fully benefit from network effects –
need to closely monitor the spatial distribution of their recruitment. As more
producers join the platform and supply increases, the depth of the results can
be controlled through the introduction of search filters. They can be search
engine driven – for geo-localized services, only local producers can be shown
by default – or can be user-configurable – especially when users express the
need to search for a particular location or type of service/product.

Relevant and timely results


While scaling platforms often benefit from a long tail inventory generating
unmatched levels of choice in selected categories, the key to maximizing
transactions is to ensure that this selection is displayed in the most meaningful
way to the users and that the most relevant results are listed first.
At this stage of development, the matching rules should have now been
captured and automated as part of a matching algorithm. As soon as there are
enough participants and interactions on the platform for meaningful A/B tests,
the search or matching team can start to run experiments. Many things can
be tested iteratively, from the blend of criteria used in the matching algorithm
to how search results should be displayed, in order to improve relevance and
ultimately conversion.
Lastly, matching results must be timely. This is often a technology design
issue, and many platforms need to re-engineer their original code in order to
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 115

cope with the level of activity generated at scale. BlaBlaCar started to grow
rapidly in 2012, and by January 2013 the number of rides booked on the
platform had hit 50 million.14 The in-house search engine became a bottleneck.
It was not scalable enough to consistently return search results in less than
200 milliseconds, and could not support more complex queries and new
features beyond a basic geographical search. BlaBlaCar completely redesigned
and migrated its search engine in 2013 with limited customer disruption and
has been scaling aggressively ever since.

The secrets of matching algorithms


At ignition, the volume of transactions is still small so changes to the matching
algorithm criteria are unlikely to have much impact on producers. However,
as the platform scales, some of its producers become larger and more dependent
on it. A change to the matching algorithm may have a profound impact on
search results rankings and therefore producers’ revenues. Platform managers
need to provide enough transparency and notice for the producers to success-
fully adapt to the new changes. On the other hand, providing too much
detailed information on the inner workings of the platform’s matching engine
may encourage some producers to game the system. Platform managers need
to communicate the changes in a way that will truly encourage positive
interactions on the platform. We’ll come back to managing this delicate balance
for mature platforms in Chapter 10.

Connect
As we have seen, facilitating positive interactions – and preventing negative
ones – between participants on the platform is a way to enhance positive net-
work effects.
Using eBay as an illustrative example in Table 9.2, mapping the core inter-
actions between the different sides of a platform can be a valuable scaling tool
to identify inefficiencies, governance or trust issues that may not have surfaced
during the ignition phase.
As eBay scaled to categories with fixed-priced, high-volume and low-
margin items, a review of interactions between eBay sellers and buyers
revealed new inefficiencies. Being able to ask questions to sellers prior to
purchase made sense in categories with unique, high-value inventory such as
cars and collectables. However, high-volume, low-margin items also generated
a high level of questions, often making the sales process inefficient for
merchants. eBay subsequently introduced new features such as product listing
FAQs and product catalogues to reduce most buyers’ generic queries.
116 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

Table 9.2 Mapping interactions between participants – eBay illustration


Interactions between Buyer Seller eBay
Buyer eBay forum Pre-sale questions Customer support
discussions requests
Community support After-sale Report seller’s bad
communications behaviour
Seller ratings and
reviews
Seller Answers to pre-sale eBay forum Customer support
questions discussions requests
After-sale Community support Report seller or
communications buyer’s bad behaviour
Buyer feedback Off-site meetings
eBay Buyer customer Seller customer N/A
support support
Conflict resolution Conflict resolution
Source: Launchworks

Transact
Enabling transactions is the raison d’être of platforms, so the scaling phase must
ensure that transactions occur as smoothly as possible.
Since the platform is now fully operational, it is often useful to use
transaction metrics in marketing and communication briefs as social proof to
further increase trust. In some cases, the platform enables ‘ultimate’ transac-
tions, such as weddings for dating sites. eHarmony reports being responsible
for more than 2 million marriages.
The scaling phase is often the phase when monetization needs to be intro-
duced to ensure that the platform generates enough revenues going forward.15
The various pricing levers available in the context of monetization, and their
respective strengths and weaknesses, are discussed in Chapter 11 on pricing.

Optimize
The optimization function should focus on the development of metrics that
can help monitor and adjust the growth trajectory of the platform. During
the scaling-up phase, the platform needs to maximize its viral impact and
ensure it is focused on the needs of the marginal user so that growth continues.
The optimization function should monitor individual building blocks of
the rocket model and look for bottlenecks. It should also develop a more
holistic view of its ecosystem and its alignment with the platform itself. Some
of the key questions at this stage are:
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 117

• Is the platform growing in a way that maximizes positive network effects?


• Are both sides of the platform growing in a balanced way?
• How much capital is required to support growth over the next few
months? (See Chapter 8 on ignition for a list of metrics.)

A few generic metric examples are given in Table 9.3. Note that the ‘North
Star’, introduced in Chapter 7, should ideally continue to act as the overarching
growth metric for the business.16

Table 9.3 Examples of performance metrics at platform scaling

Attracting participants
• Growth rate of interactions
• Growth rate of active users and producers
• Cohort analysis of growth, % of interactions from ‘new’ users
•‘ New/marginal’ user feedback
• Viral coefficient, breakdown of paid vs organic viral growth
• Retention curves, frequency/number of interactions per user
Liquidity and balance
• Number of/ratio of active producers/users above some activity threshold (e.g. Upwork
sets targets for the number of workers per posting)
• Liquidity failures (i.e. opening Uber app and finding no cars)
• Growth in listings per supplier
• % of listings that receive no interaction (e.g. eBay listings with no bids)
• Value received by each platform side to determine balance (i.e. pricing, marketing and
feature development)
Matching/connection effectiveness
• Interactions: impressions, purchases per week, sales conversion rate
• Consumer side: time to book, listings viewed before booking, average time to choose
listing, average number of clicks/searches for each booking, first page search result
connections
• Producer side: % of listings with no views/matches
• Connect: ratio causation analysis of connections driving interactions. Frequency of
connections (e.g. connections on WeChat monitored to understand user/producer
relationships)
Trust, customer experience
• Ratio of reviews to core transactions
• Ratio of positive to negative reviews
• Average ratings
• Ratio of complaints or fraud to core transactions
• % of disputes successfully resolved
• % of transactions preceded by review viewings
• Net Promoter Score (NPS)
Source: Launchworks
118 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass

Beyond the platform dashboard that will be focused on key functions, the
platform will need to develop modelling and forecasting capabilities. This will
be particularly important during the scaling phase to be able to understand
the impact of growth on funding requirements and infrastructure needs.

Enablers
The supporting capabilities and infrastructure of the platform need to be able
to grow and evolve to support the scaling process.
In many cases, the customer service team balloons in size to support
platform operations at scale. As the customer experience keeps being optimized
to remove friction, the ratio of the number of complaints over the number
of new participants should ideally decrease. That is to say the platforms should
have relatively less negative interactions as it scales. It’s important to establish
a feedback loop between the product and customer support teams for customer
feedback to be embedded back into the value proposition.
The platform’s brand may also need to morph into a more mainstream,
and often more international, proposition. Finally, as the communities now
constituting the platform are shaping its success and offering unparalleled
feedback, their contributions need to be reflected in the brand attributes of
the scaling platform. We will discuss some of these trust and brand aspects in
Chapter 12.

Notes
1 First Round article, ‘Answers to Your Tough Questions About Growth – Learned While
Scaling Eventbrite’s $5B+ Growth Engine’, http://firstround.com/review/answers-to-
your-tough-questions-about-growth-learned-while-scaling-eventbrites-5b-growth-
engine/?ct=t(How_Does_Your_Leadership_Team_Rate_12_3_2015).
2 See, for example, the scale-up report, Sherry Coutu et al., November 2014,
www.scaleupreport.org/, for a well-documented articulation of the scale-up challenges.
3 Reid Hoffman is now teaching his own version of fast scaling strategies at Stanford:
‘Blitzscaling’, http://techcrunch.com/2015/09/14/reid-hoffman-to-teach-blitzscaling-
at-stanford-this-fall/.
4 Rocket Internet is a VC firm well known for launching and selling copycat business
models in markets when the leading player is not yet established. See, for example,
‘Rocket Internet: What It’s Like to Work at a Startup Clone Factory’, http://thehustle.
co/rocket-internet-oliver-samwer.
5 The K-factor simply represents the number of new customers an existing customer
brings to the platform on average. It is often driven by social media promotions and
online acknowledgement of your platform. If i is the number of invites sent by your
existing platform participants and c the percentage of conversion to your platform, then
K = i × c.
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 119

6 Alex Schultz, http://startupclass.samaltman.com/courses/lec06/.


7 See, for example, Uber ignite programme in the UK: www.driveuberuki.com/private-
hire-booking/.
8 See, T. Eisenmann, G. Parker and M. van Alstyne, ‘Strategies for Two-Sided Markets’,
Harvard Business Review, 84(10), October 2006.
9 Distribution of visitor traffic to Etsy from 2011 to 2015, by channel and Etsy’s repeat
and first-time purchase sales 2011–2015, Statista.
10 First Round, Brian Rothenberg interview, http://firstround.com/review/answers-
to-your-tough-questions-about-growth-learned-while-scaling-eventbrites-5b-growth-
engine/?ct=t(How_Does_Your_Leadership_Team_Rate_12_3_2015).
11 Net Promoter Scores (NPSs) are computed using the following question: Using a 0–10
scale: How likely is it that you would recommend [COMPANY] to a friend or colleague?
Respondents are grouped as promoters (score 9–10), passives (score 7–8) or detractors
(score 0–6). Subtracting the percentage of detractors from the percentage of promoters
yields the Net Promoter Score, which can range from a low of –100 (if every customer
is a detractor) to a high of 100 (if every customer is a promoter). See www.netpromoter.
com for more information.
12 Conversation with Frédéric Mazzella, 14 January 2016.
13 C2C: consumer to consumer; B2C: business to consumer; B2B: business to business.
14 ‘How Elasticsearch Was Deployed at BlaBlaCar’, 19 June 2013, www.slideshare.net/
sinfomicien/presentation-elastic-searchfeedback.
15 In some cases, this question is only relevant after a critical mass has been reached.
16 Unless, of course, the platform has pivoted since then and a new North Star metric is
more appropriate for the new business.
Chapter 10

Platform maturity
Defending profitable growth

Once critical mass is reached, the energy required to sustain platform growth
is proportionally smaller than the energy required at ignition due to network
effects. With an established market position, barriers to entry are likely to be
high for new entrants. However, competitive threats will come from numer-
ous fronts and will need to be dealt with appropriately. Scale also comes
with drawbacks. It may take longer to adjust to new market dynamics and
make changes to the value proposition – at least without alienating existing
platform participants. Product/market fit was a prerequisite for successful
ignition and scaling, and remains essential for all subsequent growth phases.
Like a rocket, the platform has some velocity and momentum, but its trajectory
is now more difficult to change. If the platform is really successful, it is also
likely to attract the attention of competition authorities.
As the platform matures and continues to grow (see Figure 9.2 in the
previous chapter), focus is usually given to the following activities:

• Respond to competitive threats.


• Increase engagement, repeat visits, stickiness and retention.
• Enhance feature set for both producers and users.
• Extract value by lowering acquisition costs and monetizing platform
services.
• Scale trust and customer service teams.
• Consolidate brand.

In this chapter, we first review aspects of defensive growth with the rocket
model framework (Figure 10.1), as well as managing change in a mature plat-
form environment. We then discuss the strategic management of mature
platforms.
122 Platform maturity: profitable growth

Figure 10.1 Defending platform position and growing profitably


Source: Launchworks

The rocket model for platform maturity

Attract

Retention is key
While acquisition is the main focus of the platform during the scaling phase,
retention and engagement maximization become increasingly important as
the platform matures. Acquisition remains key to the growth of the platform,
but its established market position makes it much easier to attract new
customers, at least until its market is saturated.

Innovation
Enhancing the platform’s value proposition with new features/tools to meet
platform participants’ needs is an important lever for retention and to keep
Platform maturity: profitable growth 123

engagement levels high. To avoid the threat of new entrants, the platform
needs to keep learning from its customers. Alibaba’s proposition to mer-
chants, ‘to help small businesses grow by solving their problems’,1 has kept
expanding from its basic marketplace features to an extended range of ser-
vices, including analytics tools showing data trends to assist sellers’
decision-making, logistical services and financing solutions. To help hosts set
a price for their listings, Airbnb offers a free smart pricing tool, which
automatically adjusts daily price listings based on a minimum and maximum
price range and willingness to host.2 Price listing adjustments are based on
supply and demand, and the listing’s features, location, amenities, booking
history and availability.
Monitoring the success of platform participants is a good way to gain insights
into what works on the platform and how to further enhance the value
proposition for all users. Which users and producers could become more
valuable with better support, tools or advice from the platform?
In some cases, platform participants themselves develop new functionalities
that are so successful that they should in fact become part of the platform. In
such cases, the platform needs to consider carefully how to secure strategic
control of these features. When a new application on an app store becomes a
‘must-have’ app, the platform owner has a strong incentive to either duplicate
or acquire it. If it fails to do so, the platform will be at the mercy of platform
participants with a strong bargaining power and an increased ability to monetize
their offering. In some extreme cases, these new great features may even end
up being controlled by a competitor whose objectives are not aligned with the
interest of the platform (and may want to degrade, rather than enhance, the
features of an app, for example). At the same time, the platform ideally needs
to ensure that it remains fair to its ecosystem participants and does not
‘expropriate’ them on a whim. Of course, platforms can play games but it may
undermine the trust of participants. For example, Spotify, the music streaming
service with over 30 million paying subscribers – twice as many as Apple Music
has – recently claimed that Apple was intentionally making it difficult to update
its iPhone app and was holding back new features.3
Paying a fair price in the context of an acquisition or giving fair warning
that a feature is so strategic4 that it will be replicated by the platform within
a given timescale are two ways of ensuring that strategic control is gained
without alienating platform participants. SAP gives developers visibility of its
roadmap over an 18–24 month period so that they build new products
without the risk of competing with SAP – for at least two years. SAP also
has a policy of partnering with developers to help them financially or buy
them out at a fair price.5
124 Platform maturity: profitable growth

Personalization
Managing the balance between simplicity and new features is key to
strengthening the platform’s overall market position. One way to achieve this
is through contextualization and personalization. By only showing features/
choices that may be relevant for a given customer at a given moment in time,
platforms can leverage their feature-rich architecture without complicating
the user experience. Many Facebook features are only made visible when
particular events are triggered (e.g. the option to post an album just after a
user takes a series of photos).

Match
The same logic applies to marketplaces’ long tail inventories. Being able to
personalize a search result allows platforms to leverage their wide selection
without confusing buyers with too much choice. This has allowed Alibaba to
push the concept of the long tail to the limit with in excess of a billion products
listed. To make the most of this unique inventory, the same search engine
powers a number of consumer marketplaces owned by the group, such as Tmall
and Taobao. This means that a search on one consumer site can also return
search results across all other Alibaba consumer sites. This guarantees customers
complete inventory discovery and access to the long tail across all marketplaces.
For example, a search on Taobao for the latest Burberry tote bag may come
back with few results on Taobao, but with a relevant selection on Tmall. The
mix of search results displayed across marketplaces is decided at group level,
based on priorities, relevance, supply gaps and merchant performance.

Optimize matching at mass scale


Search optimization should continue to be a priority, with iterative improve-
ments of the search algorithm relying on A/B testing. Because the algorithm
rules are rarely perfect, the best way to validate improvements to the matching
algorithm is often to combine A/B testing with qualitative human feedback.
Hugh Williams,6 who used to run search at eBay, said:

One of the most important ways we understand if we’ve improved our


search engine is by asking people what they think. We do this at a large-
scale: we’ve asked human judges questions about our search results over
two million times in the past year.

This process of collecting human observations about the relevance of search


results is also used by Facebook to improve what people should see first in
their newsfeed.7 It started as a feed quality panel experiment in 2014, asking
Platform maturity: profitable growth 125

people to provide detailed feedback on what they saw in their newsfeeds,


which posts they liked and why, and what posts they would have liked to
see instead. This qualitative human feedback exposed blind spots that data
scientists, who work on improving the newsfeed algorithm, could not identify
with machine learning. Facebook now runs feed quality panels across the US
and international markets, and combines both quantitative and qualitative
approaches to optimize its newsfeed algorithm.

Search innovation
Search is an area that is constantly evolving. In the past, the matching func-
tion relied mostly on algorithms that followed a set of rules written by
software engineers. But artificial intelligence is starting to redefine how search
works. Search neural networks can learn from analysing large amounts of
data and build their own rules to match users and producers better and faster.
RankBrain, Google’s deep neural network, which helps generate responses
to search queries, now handles about 15% of Google’s daily search queries.8
All major platforms, from Facebook to Microsoft, have invested in deep
learning, with Amazon even having released deep learning open-source soft-
ware for search and product recommendations.9 Search technology, increas-
ingly powered by deep neural networks, is evolving fast beyond text and geo-
localized data to include voice and images. No doubt the integration of new
technology such as messaging bots (automated search) and augmented reality
(visual search) will redefine existing platforms’ user search experience.

Connect
What defines positive interactions may change over time so it’s worth revisiting
these definitions on a regular basis. Mature platforms can also leverage their
communities to increase the quality and quantity of relevant content available
on the platform. To drive higher customer engagement, Taobao’s mobile app
offers new social commerce features to meet the evolving needs of how people
shop. Taobao hosts over 1,000 quanzi (circles) where shopping enthusiasts talk
about their hobbies and favourite products. Taobao also hosts crowdsourced
Q&As. When a buyer submits a question, Taobao’s algorithms identify buyers
who are best qualified to answer and send them a message. 25% of all questions
are answered within one minute and 60% of questions within 10 minutes.10
Two million buyers help answer 1 million questions every day.

Transact
Maximizing the number of core transactions should remain a key objective
through improvements to the customer experience to reduce friction during
126 Platform maturity: profitable growth

and after the transaction. The services added to enhance the transaction experi-
ence – from loan products to users, conflict resolution support, insurances, etc.
– should be well integrated to the existing customer experience.
Now that the platform has reached critical mass and that network effects
are in full swing, the platform can optimize how much of the excess value
delivered to customers can be captured during the core transaction. This may
translate into more refined pricing structures and levels. The key things to
watch out for at this stage are disintermediation and leakage. For example,
Upwork changed its pricing structure in June 2016 to reduce leakage from
its most profitable freelancers. Based on their choice of payment method,
clients now either pay a processing fee of 2.75% when paying by credit cards,
or no processing fee if they choose a low cost payment method like an
Automated Clearing House (ACH). This change enabled Upwork to rebalance
their pricing and charge a fee inversely proportional to total billings, as shown
in Table 10.1.11

Table 10.1 Upwork’s new sliding fee structure


Fees paid by Before After
Clients • No fees Choice of payment options
• 2.75% per transaction (if the client pays by credit
card)
• 0% (if using a low cost payment method like an
Automated Clearing House)
Freelancers • 10% service fee Sliding service fee per client
• 20% for first $500 billed
• 10% for billings greater than $500 and smaller than
$10,000
• 5% for billings greater or equal to $10,000

Platforms also need to ensure that revenues do not encourage negative


network effects. A number of marketplaces have allowed sellers to purchase
increased listing visibility. So-called ‘promoted listings’, although not always
clearly labelled as such to buyers, typically appear at the top of the search result
page. While this generates sizeable revenues for the marketplace, this feature
also potentially weakens the relevance of items shown to buyers, which in turn
impacts the number of purchases, as well as positive network effects. Many
marketplaces, including eBay, eventually chose to remove this ‘bad revenue’
to preserve the platform. While in some cases the lost revenues in the short term
were significant – and not always offset by increased sales – the long-term health
of the platform ecosystem was deemed to be more important.
Platform maturity: profitable growth 127

In order to allocate resources efficiently, mature platforms need to under-


stand the relative price responses of platform participants on both sides of the
market they serve. For example, credit card companies need to understand
the extent to which lowering the price they charge to merchants (merchant
fee) will result in increased coverage (more merchants will join the card net-
work). This, in turn, needs to be contrasted against the impact of a resulting
increase in card fees on users’ propensity to get and use their cards.

Optimize
By now, the platform should have developed strong analytical capabilities and
the challenge is the opposite of the one faced during the ignition phase. There

Table 10.2 Examples of performance metrics at platform maturity


New markets and ongoing growth
• Product/geographic market coverage (e.g. Airbnb: cities served as % of total universe)
• Growth of users switching sides
• Effectiveness of notifications for prompting transactions
• % of existing users total business (e.g. How much are users multihoming? How much do
producers sell through other channels?)
• Disintermediation metrics (e.g. measures of repeat business between the same user and
producer)
Search/match optimization
• Proactive and predictive search/match analytics
• Individual customization of offers, marketing, etc.
Monetization/profitability
• Revenue/profit per core transaction, customer lifetime value
• Customer acquisition costs
• Organic vs paid growth (e.g. Etsy tracks merchandise volumes from paid vs organic to
understand profitability)
• Ancillary revenue growth (e.g. from premium services such as enhanced curation, premium
listings, insights products)
Metrics for customer success
• Metrics to assist users/producers optimize their contribution (e.g. eBay improved pricing by
providing metrics such as number of items that failed to receive a bid, those bought with
buy now button, and the duration and outcome of auctions)
• % of transactions preceded by review viewings
• Net Promoter Score (NPS)
Innovation
• Understanding how users are creating new value on the platform
• Developer activity, high-growth user-created apps
• Growth in new transaction categories
Source: Launchworks
128 Platform maturity: profitable growth

is so much data available that identifying which key metrics are really relevant
for sustainable and profitable growth requires focus and discipline. We recom-
mend continuing to develop the strategic ecosystem dashboard, including
profitability and monetization metrics, as well as operational dashboards for
both user and producer sides, focusing on detailed success metrics.
Financial metrics will become increasingly important, as the platform’s ability
to monetize becomes the critical issue for its sustainability. Finally, the self-
marketing and innovation potential of the community will now outstrip that
of the platform business, and so it will be critical to empower and measure
the community’s performance in these areas. A few examples of metrics at
platform maturity are shown in Table 10.2.

Enablers

Customer experience
Improving and simplifying the experience of platform participants on both
sides may not be as straightforward now that many users and producers are
familiar with the platform services. But perfecting the customer experience
for all participants should remain a goal.

Managing change
Traditional companies make management decisions about the development
of their value proposition – such as price changes, new product introductions,
new features, etc. – unilaterally and sometimes adjust them if customers do
not respond well. Platforms are different. They have to take into account
the impact of changes on different sides of their platforms. Some changes
can be perceived as positive for one side, but not the other. They could
also be positive for both, or negative for both. A mature platform will need
to carefully consider the interests of its stakeholders, including producers and
users, as well as employees and partners, as changes to its rules may have
far-reaching consequences for its participants. A new pricing model or match-
ing algorithm may fundamentally impact the economics of a wide range of
platform participants.
Mature platforms therefore need to track the changes in their roadmap
and understand which side(s) will be impacted and how. If many changes
are planned at the same time – which is often the case when a new release
is prepared – it is important to understand their cumulative effects and try to
ensure that the overall balance of the platform is not undermined.
Platform maturity: profitable growth 129

Figure 10.2 Assessing platform changes on users and producers


Source: Launchworks

Figure 10.2 illustrates some changes that are negative for both producers
and users12 (A and B), some important changes that are neutral for produ-
cers and very positives for users (C), as well as small changes that are slightly
positive for users and very positive for producers (D) and very negative for
users but positive for producers (E). The size of the ‘bubble’ can illustrate the
value at risk for stakeholders.
Processes need to be put in place in order to both assess and mitigate the
impact of changes. Advanced notice should be given and reactions carefully
monitored. Ideally, a rollback plan should be available in case something goes
wrong. A large platform considering changes that are both difficult to rollback
and have a significant customer impact need to invest significant time and
resources in ensuring these are successful, and/or develop mitigating strategies
that will reduce the customer impact. Mandating free postage for media
products (CDs, DVDs) generated a revolt from eBay sellers,13 although it was
a buyer need that Amazon and other competing e-commerce websites had
already met. eBay had to roll the policy back, but interestingly sellers didn’t
revert to charging postage fees, and arguably the entire eBay ecosystem
benefited as a result.
130 Platform maturity: profitable growth

Trust and safety


The set of governance, trust and safety rules encouraging positive interactions
and limiting negative ones evolve organically during scaling, as more and
more new use cases are encountered. Some of these rules are embedded into
automated scripts, while community or customer service managers enforce
others manually. Often both methods are combined and employees act on
filtered content or events brought to their attention by algorithms. After years
of scaling, the resulting rules and policies defining the difference between a
positive interaction vs a negative one are often so complex that they become
a challenge for the customer service team to apply efficiently. A restructuring
and simplification of rules and policies is often required for mature platforms.
Mature marketplaces often need to rationalize and simplify their trust and
safety policies. Beyond the customer benefits, this simplification of rules is
often combined with increased autonomy given to first line service advisors
in order to reduce customer service costs.

Optimizing the strategic management of mature


platforms
One of the important long-term aspects of the optimization function is the
development of a sustainable market position over time. This goes beyond
metrics used to manage the actual business, but includes the analysis of inter-
nal data and market trends to identify new opportunities, seize them either
directly or through partnership, and embed them into the organization. In
this section, we discuss some of the strategic challenges that mature platforms
may encounter and possible courses of action.
Platforms typically face three types of competitive pressures: internal ones,
external ones from other platforms, and external ones from traditional players.

Competition from ‘within’ the ecosystem


Once mature, a platform may give rise to very successful producers who may
end up having significant negotiating power and influence over the entire
ecosystem. In some situations, these companies may even be in a position to
establish rival platforms and take significant business away. In such cases, the
platform may want to follow an envelopment strategy14 to secure strategic
control of such ‘must-have’ complements.
Microsoft followed such an approach when it realized that RealPlayer was
becoming an important streaming app with the potential to become a platform
in its own right. Microsoft famously added its Media Player to Windows to
replace RealPlayer (and subsequently added the Explorer browser to replace
Platform maturity: profitable growth 131

Netscape). While this strategy can be a very effective attack (or defence), it
may also attract the wrath of the competition authorities since it involves
bundling and may lead to foreclosure. If used too often, it may also deter
complements from investing in the platform (and result in less apps developed
for your app store, less inventory in your marketplace, etc.).
In some other cases, the complement service being developed ends up being
acquired by the ‘complemented’ platform. For example PayPal managed to
attract lots of eBay sellers (and buyers) onto its own platform, which led
to its acquisition by eBay. By the same token, YouTube ended up becoming
a search platform for video in its own right and this led to its acquisition by
Google.
In some cases, however, the acquisition or imitation of the complement is
not required. When faced with the formidable success of some of its game
producers (such as Zynga when it launched the game Farmville), Facebook
thought about its options. While buying Zynga was a possibility, the price
was already high and the risks associated with follow-up games deemed
significant – despite incredible early successes. Facebook decided instead to
manage more closely the gaming category of its app store in order to ensure
that barriers to launching apps were minimal and that whoever ended up
providing the best entertainment would succeed on the platform. Other
providers launched equally successful games and Facebook didn’t have to face
too strong a producer in follow-up negotiations.

Competition from other platforms


As we have seen, platforms increasingly compete against one another, and
this gives rise to some new strategic challenges. It is useful to review some
of the strategic moves that competing platforms may be considering:

• Side differentiation: Other platforms in the same space may decide to focus
on the needs of the side that is ‘the least looked after’ by the established
platform. For example, new platform entrants in the taxi market may focus
more on the needs of drivers (Hailo, Juno) than Uber, which arguably
was more focused on its clients.
• Challengers’ mergers: Established platforms are also exposed to the merger
of smaller followers, which may result in a challenger suddenly with critical
mass. This may drive the acquisition of smaller competitors.
• Niche/vertical focus: Niche players may try to cherry-pick the most
profitable segments that are big enough to support a critical mass on their
own (e.g. fashion marketplaces such as Farfetch, Videdressing, Vestiaire
Collective and Vinted compete against eBay’s fashion vertical).
132 Platform maturity: profitable growth

• Subsidized cost competitors: Platforms may copy your basic functionality


but seek alternative monetization methods in order to offer low transaction
costs to address the price-sensitive segments of the market. Classified sites
such as Gumtree, leboncoin or OfferUp have been challenging incumbent
marketplaces.
• ‘Me too’ imitators: Some firms may try to replicate your business model
in other geographies before you can establish a footprint. You may then
have to acquire them, decide not to enter in these international markets,
or invest more to catch up at a later stage. Companies such as Rocket
Internet are famous for such strategies.
• Creating barriers to growth: Some competitors prevent access to new
markets. Tencent has repeatedly blocked the Uber app on WeChat in
2015,15 with a ban in December 2015 days after Tencent-backed Didi
Chuxing announced a global partnership with Lyft, GrabTaxi and Ola.16
Competitive pressure was too hard for Uber, and it led Uber China to
merge with Didi.17
Mature platforms have a range of strategic options available to deal with
increased competitive pressures, but we’ll focus here on two generic responses:
(i) creating a platform-powered ecosystem; (ii) adding sides to their existing
business models.

Creating a platform-powered ecosystem


Successful mature platforms often end up developing adjacent activities with
traditional business models in order to strengthen their ecosystem. The same
is true for businesses that started as linear ones (e.g. Amazon started as a digital
book retailer) and then added platform elements. As we have seen in Chapter
6, the most successful platforms seem to have developed complementary
activities and combined business models in ways that enhanced their value
propositions. Microsoft did not shy away from entering the hardware business
with its surface tablet to compete against Apple’s platform ecosystem, Google
is investing in fibre to reduce its dependence on telecommunications operators,
Facebook and Microsoft are laying transatlantic cables for the same reason, and
Alibaba ended up developing one of the largest delivery infrastructures in the
world (Cainiao)18 to deliver to any city in China in 24 hours.19 Facebook has
also realized that the next bottleneck for connecting everybody on the planet
to its services is . . . Internet access. That’s why it set up Internet.org20 to provide
broadband connectivity using high-altitude aircraft and satellites to the 4.5
billion people not currently connected to the Internet. All these moves result
in the development of a platform-powered ecosystem where the various business
models constituting the entire ecosystem are more or less integrated.21
Platform maturity: profitable growth 133

Opening another or multiple sides


Opening another side is likely to require significant funding and resources,
but it may provide multiple benefits from value proposition improvements,
superior monetization opportunities, accelerated growth and/or stronger
competitive position against new entrants and existing firms. In 2015, Etsy
opened Etsy Manufacturing in the US first to match Etsy sellers with small
manufacturers. In another bid to help its sellers expand their businesses, Etsy
also launched Etsy Wholesale,22 a service that allows independent retailers to
buy items wholesale from Etsy sellers to sell in their bricks-and-mortar stores.
Many of the pre-launch and launch principles discussed in Chapters 7 and
8 still apply. There are, however, additional concerns to address, the main
one being how network effects will change. Will opening a third side poten-
tially strengthen positive network effects (e.g. Facebook opening to developers)
or weaken them (e.g. opening to advertisers)? A negative impact on the
customer experience may impact positive network effects, and this could
weaken all sides as a result. When Instagram opened to businesses with its
Ads API in 2015, great care was taken for ads to be as unobtrusive as possible.
The ‘swipe to view’ posts require the user to swipe left or right on an image
to see any additional content or calls to action.23 Key to success also requires
Instagram’s matching algorithm and content mix to be aligned.
Opening of a new side might also impact the delicate balance between
existing sides. UberEATS, the on-demand meal delivery service powered
by Uber, allows users to order from local restaurants and get delivered through
Uber’s network of drivers and riders. Ordering a ride or a meal are different
experiences, which impact logistics. Drivers cannot arrive late at the restaurant
or the food might be served cold. Peak times for food delivery are also
different. This will have an impact on driver supply and incentives, which
Uber has solved by managing two distinct driver bases.24 With UberEATS’s
launch, and its most recent UberRUSH, an online delivery service to
merchants, Uber is not only competing head to head with Seamless, Postmates,
Delivery.com, Deliveroo and Amazon, but also strengthening its foothold in
the on-demand transport market.

Competition from traditional players outside


Established platforms have often been able to redefine the reference offer in
a given market and to establish a more effective and efficient platform powered
business model. Yet, traditional companies that have been outmanoeuvred
can also fight back.
Established companies may decide to launch their own platforms to counter
any perceived threat to their businesses. Merchants in the US have tried to
134 Platform maturity: profitable growth

set up payment alternatives to Visa and Mastercard in order to reduce their


influence. For traditional players, the temptation to respond to platform
disruption without fundamentally changing existing capabilities, processes and
mental models often makes successful execution difficult. We discuss how
traditional firms compete against platforms in Chapter 14.

Notes
1 Alibaba founder Jack Ma’s open letter to the company’s investors after Alibaba’s IPO,
September 2014.
2 Airbnb’s smart pricing was launched in November 2015. There are other pricing tools
on the market, such as Beyond Pricing, which charge 1% of booking earnings.
3 Peter Kafka, Recode, 30 June 2016, www.recode.net/2016/6/30/12067578/spotify-
apple-app-store-rejection.
4 Platforms providing a new core features roadmap over the next 18–24 months, such as
SAP, come to mind.
5 G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York: W. W.
Norton & Company, 2016, pp. 174–5.
6 Hugh Williams, ‘Measuring Search Relevance’, eBay Tech Blog, 10 November 2010,
www.ebaytechblog.com/2010/11/10/measuring-search-relevance/.
7 Will Oremus, Slate, 3 January 2016, www.slate.com/articles/technology/cover_story/
2016/01/how_facebook_s_news_feed_algorithm_works.html.
8 Cade Metz, ‘AI Is Transforming Google Search. The Rest of the Web Is Next’, Wired,
4 February 2016, www.wired.com/2016/02/ai-is-changing-the-technology-behind-
google-searches/.
9 Klint Finley, ‘Amazon’s Giving Away the AI Behind Its Product Recommenda-
tions’, Wired, 16 May 2016, www.wired.com/2016/05/amazons-giving-away-ai-behind-
product-recommendations/.
10 See Alibaba.com, 26 July 2016, www.alibabagroup.com/en/ir/article?news=p160726.
11 In the old pricing (where the fee was entirely paid by the freelancer), the client had no
incentive to switch to a low cost payment method and often had reasons not to, e.g.
because credit cards offer points and float. Conversely in the old pricing, the freelancers
were always paying for the cost of payment, i.e. they were burdened with a cost that
only the client could change. The idea was to charge clients for this because they can
make the decision to pay by credit card despite the 2.75% fee, if they see value in doing
this, or else to switch to a low cost payment method. This rebalancing enabled reducing
Upwork fees to 5% for cumulative billings over $10K for a given client.
12 Of course, changes that have a negative impact on both sides would need to be justified
on the basis that they benefit the platform even more than they hurt its participants. For
example, this could be the case if the platform needs additional income to reinvest in
new services, or wants to reposition its proposition and is prepared to ‘cull’ some of its
existing producers and users as a result.
13 The policy was rolled out in 2009 in the UK and Germany.
14 T. Eisenmann, G. Parker and M. Van Alstyne, Platform Envelopment, Harvard Business
School Working Paper, 2010.
Platform maturity: profitable growth 135

15 http://venturebeat.com/2015/12/06/uber-is-still-blocked-on-wechat-in-china-and-the-
situation-is-getting-worse/
16 http://venturebeat.com/2015/12/03/lyft-adds-grabtaxi-and-ola-to-its-faction-of-allies-
against-uber/.
17 www.wsj.com/articles/china-s-didi-chuxing-to-acquire-rival-uber-s-chinese-operations-
1470024403.
18 Cainiao was formed by a consortium of existing logistics companies to give the project
a running start. Alibaba itself took a 48% stake.
19 See https://techcrunch.com/2016/03/14/alibaba-backed-logistics-firm-cainiao-lands-
funding-at-a-reported-7-7b-valuation/.
20 Internet.org is a partnership between Facebook and six companies (Samsung, Ericsson,
MediaTek, Opera Software, Nokia and Qualcomm). In February 2016, regulators banned
its Free Basics service in India based on ‘Prohibition of Discriminatory Tariffs for Data
Services Regulations’.
21 Benjamin Gomes-Casseres, 15 June 2016, Harvard Business Review, https://hbr.org/2016/
06/is-the-linkedin-acquisition-microsofts-attempt-to-build-its-own-alphabet.
22 See https://techcrunch.com/2015/09/14/etsy-opens-to-manufacturing/.
23 At the time of writing, there are no page takeover ads, no advertising video content
forced viewing, and no autoplay of videos from paid posts yet.
24 See www.wired.com/2016/03/ubereats-standalone-app-launches-us/. Drivers can choose
to switch between modes freely, by logging into and out of the app.
Chapter 11

Platform pricing

Pricing in traditional businesses


How much are we going to charge for our product or service? This is a
fundamental question that most firms have to address early on if they want
to generate revenue. For traditional businesses, pricing can be set in a num-
ber of ways. A simple approach is to set the price of a product or service on
a ‘cost plus’ basis in order to ensure that a margin is generated on every sale.
In such a model, all the relevant costs are captured before a mark-up is applied
to the total. Many retail stores and small businesses use such an approach as
their basic pricing strategy.
More advanced pricing methods allow firms to differentiate their pricing
based on the ‘willingness to pay’ of various customer segments (or price elas-
ticity, as discussed in Chapter 4). Being able to ‘price discriminate’, that is to
say to set a price that is different from one customer group to another, often
allows firms to increase revenues. This is because the propensity of one
customer to pay can be higher than that of another. For example, if there is
a unique market price for a product (say $10 for a game), then customers that
would have been prepared to pay more (say $15) end up paying the lower
market price and the difference ($5 in this case) is not captured by the seller.
Price discrimination can be created at the customer level with unique prices
(e.g. bespoke price for a given contract), at the segment level with prices for
certain customer groups (e.g. student discounts) or even at the product level
where slightly different versions of the product are priced very differently and
marketed at different customer groups (e.g. economy vs business class airfares).
Such approaches need to be adapted depending on the market environment,
the propensity of clients to compare price information, and regulatory
constraints, among other things.
Because many firms compete on price in many sectors, price benchmarking
is often a key input to the pricing strategy of the firm. If all your competitors
138 Platform pricing

– that is to say firms offering substitute products or services – are pricing a


given product between X and Y, then this is a powerful source of information
for your own pricing.
So while much more sophisticated pricing approaches do exist (e.g. airline
dynamic pricing, etc.), it is fair to say that most traditional businesses typically
use a mixture of cost-plus, value-based and competitive benchmarked pricing
approaches in the context of their pricing strategy. This pricing strategy process
can end up being quite complicated for traditional businesses, yet it is often
much simpler than pricing for platform businesses.

Unique challenges of platform pricing


While platform-powered businesses must consider all of the above, they also
need to deal with unique features linked to their business models, including:

1 their customers create value for each other when using the platform due
to network effects;
2 pricing on one side of the platform often impacts the other side of the
platform due to cross-elasticity of demand across the platform;
3 a critical mass of customers may be required to make the platform valuable
to other customers; and
4 pricing in platforms truly shapes the behaviours of platform participants and
therefore needs to be set to enhance the overall value proposition.

It is important to reflect on how different platforms are from traditional busi-


nesses in terms of pricing decisions. Pricing strategies for platforms need to not
only capture some of the value created – to generate revenue for the platform
owner – but also to enhance the platform’s overall value proposition. This is
achieved by using pricing as a lever to encourage positive interactions on the
platform – and incidentally discourage bad interactions. Given that any change
in price will have both direct effects for those paying and indirect effects for
other platform participants, platform pricing can only be approached holistic-
ally. For example, a decision to increase the price for sellers may lead to a
reduction in inventory, which may result in less choice for buyers who may
then be tempted to leave, which in turn may make the platform less attractive
to sellers (or even advertisers, in the case of a three-sided platform). Pricing
decisions therefore need to consider these – positive and negative – feedback
loops. Lastly, platform pricing decisions stack up, that is to say a pricing decision
made in the past (say, free transactions) may have attracted producers on the
platform that will remain there even if the price changes again.
Platform pricing 139

To develop a suitable pricing strategy, it is important to consider the distinct


characteristics of the platform itself along with the following pricing design
questions:

• What is the pricing governance framework? (e.g. are the end prices set by the
platform owner or by the platform participants?).
• Which pricing model to follow? (e.g. charging platform users, advertising
model, freemium/selling of value-added services).
• Who to charge? (e.g. all users, one side, third parties, specific customer sub-
segments on each platform side).
• Which pricing structures to use? (e.g. one-off joining fees, annual membership
fees, transaction fees – fixed amounts or proportional to transaction value
– donations, as well as discounts and rewards).

The answers to these questions lie in the type of platform and ecosystem
that need to be developed, and the extent to which pricing is a strategic enabler
and lever for the platform to succeed. In this context, it is important to keep
in mind that since the interactions and behaviours of a critical mass of cus-
tomers are the key to platform value creation, pricing strategies need to support
these objectives first and foremost. Generating revenue will (almost) always
be the ultimate goal, but successful pricing architecture will also contribute
to addressing broader questions, such as:

• How do platforms ensure that ‘end user pricing’ is efficient and creates a
good customer experience for ‘users’ (even if producers are the ones setting
the price)?
• How can platforms both support rapid user growth and generate revenues
with minimum friction to maximize network effects?
• How can platforms use pricing to ensure the communities are balanced
in terms of supply and demand?
• How do platforms maximize the quality of customer interactions and
experiences?
• How can platforms use pricing models that minimize the risk of ‘disinter-
mediation’ and ‘leakages’ (i.e. transactions moving ‘off-platform’)?
• How to best transition from one pricing model to another (in particular,
transition from free to a paying model)?

We’ll review these questions in turn. Let’s start by looking at key pricing
governance questions.
140 Platform pricing

How to ensure ‘producers’ pricing creates a good


customer experience for ‘users’
A platform architect must consider not only the impact of the platform’s own
pricing strategies on interactions, but also the impact of producers’ pricing
structures. Two key aspects to consider are the nature of the good/service
and the differentiation strategy of the platform.

Nature of the good/service


It is often argued that simple, standardized, low-cost and high-frequency ser-
vices benefit from standardized pricing across all producers. This is to make
the customer buying experience efficient and reassuringly predictable, while
also giving suppliers greater certainty around revenues. For example, Uber
does not ask each driver to set prices but standardizes its pricing, based on
supply and demand conditions, to ensure a consistent experience for users.
Conversely, where the goods and services on the platform are more dif-
ferentiated and consumers are more price-sensitive, it may be preferable to
allow producers to signal quality and compete by setting their own price.
In addition, if the platform supports a large portfolio of different goods/service
categories, it may be impractical for the platform to set prices.

Platform strategy
Strategic platform design choices also need to be considered. In particular, the
overall differentiation strategy of the platform and the customers it is targeting.
For many of the platforms that standardize producer pricing, there are often
competing platforms offering greater pricing flexibility. The competing
platform may seek to provide superior pricing innovation or competition
among producers, greater flexibility for producers to differentiate their
product/level of service, or improved customization and negotiation options
for users. It is therefore important to ensure that the level of control over
producer pricing is aligned with the overall strategy of the platform, not just
the nature of its products. For example, eBay had to introduce its ‘Buy It
Now’ option in order to compete with other platforms and e-commerce sites
offering a fixed price, while also keeping its auction model to allow more
price-sensitive customers a chance to secure lower prices.

Implications of open or controlled pricing governance


Where producers’ prices are highly standardized, the platform architect
must consider tools to help balance supply in the platform (for example, Uber’s
Platform pricing 141

‘surge pricing’ approach to demand management). Users can, however,


see these dynamic pricing tools in a very negative light. As a result, platforms
should ensure that users see the link between the premium price and the service
while retaining control over their purchase (for example, while Uber will
increase its prices during a ‘surge’, users can wait or upgrade/downgrade ride
categories – moving between ‘uber pool’, ‘uber X’, ‘uber XL’ and ‘EXEC’ –
to avoid paying a premium). It is also important to show that the surge price
is not ‘made up’, but represents the required incentive for the platform to be
able to attract producers at this particular time. In that context, behavioural
economists at Uber have established that users were more likely to accept at
2.1× price multiplier (which sounds ‘computed’ by the platform) rather than
a 2× price multiplier (which sounds ‘made up’).1
Where pricing governance is relatively open, information and rating tools
take on added importance. For example, to ensure that a producer’s lower
prices are not being achieved through a misrepresentation of product or service
quality. This can be illustrated by the importance of eBay’s multi-criteria rating
system in influencing purchaser behaviour vs the Uber rating system, which
probably has a lesser impact on which Uber driver you use. It is also worth
noting that a platform-controlled end user pricing regime may raise some
regulatory concerns, which we discuss in Chapter 13.

How to support rapid user growth by avoiding


‘pricing friction’
This is one of the key questions that platforms need to address, since there
is often a perceived trade-off between charging for services (and running the
risk of never reaching a critical mass) and offering core platform services for
free (and running the risk of not generating sufficient revenues to finance
the platform itself).
A range of pricing models is usually considered, each with unique strengths
and weaknesses. We review the main ones below and the extent to which
they may support the strategic objectives of the platform.

Not charging for services


Due to network effects, platform businesses want to encourage membership
growth and maximize the number of valuable interactions occurring on their
platform. The more users and the more active they are on the platform, the
better. In that context, monetizing customers’ participation can be difficult
because charging for access or use may introduce friction and hamper the
142 Platform pricing

positive growth dynamics. In fact, a number of platforms decided that they


would try to reach critical mass first and monetize later. Such a strategy
minimizes friction, and may have some economic rationale since the value of
the platform with critical mass is much higher than before, but financing that
growth requires deep pockets. Once a critical mass is reached, the platform may
be able to justify introducing a fee or monetize its interactions by bringing on
board other participants, such as advertisers.

Not charging temporarily for services (trial period)


Another traditional method of attracting users with minimal friction while
monetizing afterwards is the simple ‘free trial’ model, although platform users
may decide not to invest too much time in joining and participating in the
platform if they believe they will end up having to pay for the privilege. This
can be mitigated if the trial period is long enough (WhatsApp used to offer
one year of free service), but even then it may still create a barrier to adoption
(WhatsApp made its app free in January 2016 and introduced some degree
of advertising instead).

Charging others for financing free platform services


Monetization needs not be seen as mutually exclusive with exponential
growth. In fact, pricing can also be designed in a way that strengthens – rather
than weakens – the effects of positive network effects. It is possible to
monetize a platform by opening it to another side (for example, like Facebook
did with advertisers) rather than to charge existing platform participants.
Such a model may be used to scale with minimum friction in order to reach
a critical mass of participants. Advertising can still act as a ‘cost’ on users
(e.g. a type of ‘friction’) by detracting from the user experience. Therefore,
these free, advertising sponsored models are not necessarily the panacea, and
the relevance of the ads served is key to minimizing the negative effects of
this source of financing.

Charging a subset of platform participants using ‘premium’


services
Another way to minimize friction is to only charge a small set of customers
for advanced features while offering basic access for free. These so-called
freemium models are, however, highly dependent upon the balance between
free features and premium ones. If the platform withholds too many features
in order to incentivize premium membership, it may see its growth stall. That’s
Platform pricing 143

why the design of both free and premium value propositions require care-
ful thinking about the trade-off between the free features (usually conducive
to scaling) and the take-up of the premium version (usually conducive to
revenues). While a difficult balance to strike, this model has been used
by a number of fast-growing platforms such as SoundCloud. Platforms
such as LinkedIn, now owned by Microsoft, also have a freemium model
that is targeted at various segments of users. For example, jobseekers can join
the premium subscription model in order to have increased visibility of job
offers, while established professionals can join a premium networking option
where they will be able to see the identity of the people who viewed their
profile.
It is worth noting that a number of classified websites also use some form
of price discrimination, depending on whether or not you are a business user
and/or which section you want to place your adverts in. Gumtree, owned
by eBay, offers free posts to private individuals in most second-hand goods
sections, while businesses have to pay. In some sections of the site, such as
property, all posters have to pay. In some cases, more visibility can be gained
within a category (‘featured ad’) for a small fee as well.

Charging only when a transaction occurs on the platform


Transaction fee models have been used to encourage participants to join
platforms as they are only charged when the participants receive some
significant value from the platform (e.g. eBay charges transaction fees to sellers
when items are sold). This approach works best when the platform seeks to
offer a wide selection of ‘inventory’ with minimal friction. It may, however,
increase ‘search costs’ for users if the platform is then inundated with low-
quality listings. This search cost can be reduced through enhanced matching,
searching and curation activities by the platform (to make sure most relevant
results are displayed first).

Charging a membership fee irrespective of transactions on


the platform
Where platforms seek reliable participants who will conduct a high volume
of interactions, they may charge joining or membership fees. This can help
with ‘liquidity’ on the platform as there is an incentive to use it frequently
once membership has been paid. This is the case at Artfire, a marketplace
for handmade products, which offers a monthly fee in exchange for a reduced
transaction fee of 3% (instead of 9% for non-members).2 Ruby Lane, an
antique marketplace, also uses membership fees rather than transaction fees.
144 Platform pricing

In addition, some platforms have used joining fees on the merchant side to fund
a strong referral program (e.g. Alibaba). This method can drive growth when
the joining fees are relatively small compared to the potential savings on trans-
actions.

Charging a listing fee


In some cases, platforms decide to charge for listing a product or service. Such
a fee is quite common, and well-known platforms – such as Amazon and
eBay – use them. These fees generate revenue, but they also allow the
platforms to use the friction generated (e.g. payment of the listing fee) as a
filter in order to enhance the quality of its listing inventory. In some cases,
the listing fee is deployed for specific categories of listings where the bottleneck
is not the supply, but the ‘quality of supply’. It is, however, rare to find
platforms that only charge a listing fee. Listing fees are generally used in
combination with other charging mechanisms. In the case of classified sites
such as leboncoin in France, listings are often free but visibility can be
enhanced by paying extra. These sites, however, tend to generate the bulk
of their revenues through advertising.

Charging for a number of different things


The above-mentioned pricing models are not mutually exclusive, and many
mature platforms have combined several pricing levers to achieve their objec-
tives. eBay charges both listing fees and transaction fees to deal with inventory
quality concerns while minimizing friction. Some platforms have a member-
ship fee and a transaction fee (e.g. Artfire) to both encourage recurrent
purchases and get some volume-related revenues. The interplay between the
various pricing levers needs to be carefully considered by the platform owner
as it represents an opportunity to balance supply and demand, as discussed
below.

How to balance supply and demand on the platform


through pricing?

Why balance is important


Balancing supply and demand ensures that both sides benefit from sufficient
cross-network effects. A marketplace seller who receives few bids will be
concerned that they’re not achieving the best price. Likewise, a marketplace
Platform pricing 145

buyer who finds goods that are constantly sold out will be frustrated. Since
the two sides of the platform are interdependent, price signals on one side
will have an impact on the value of the platform for the other side (for
example, the introduction of a listing fee may reduce the inventory of a
platform and undermine buyers’ ability to find what they are looking for).
Platform balancing is therefore key to maximizing the number of relevant
transactions and ensuring that the platform can find an equilibrium in matching
supply and demand.
Imbalance can occur for a number of reasons. Often it’s easier to sign up
members on one side of the platform than the other(s) because the benefit
of transactions is higher for one side. Sometimes the ancillary and time costs
of joining a platform make one set of customers more likely to align with a
single platform while members on the other side join many different platforms
(e.g. they ‘multihome’). This is important since one side ends up with fewer
options than the other side. In gaming, many households decide to commit
to a single platform (be it an Xbox, PlayStation or Nintendo), while few
developers commit to a single platform (or if they do, they ask for additional
fees for exclusive games).

Pricing strategies to achieve balance


Platform pricing should seek to balance the value received by participants
in a way that optimizes the cross-platform network effects. This is generally
done by setting higher prices for the side that receives the most value from
the transaction (for example, if men are finding it more difficult to find
girlfriends than the opposite, then they may be willing to pay more to join
a dating platform). One side of the platform may be provided free (or even
be sponsored if women get a free drink). This occurs if the value of their
involvement and the elasticity of their demand are high enough that cross-
subsidizing their participation becomes worthwhile (e.g. the cost of attracting
women on the platform is more than made up by the revenues generated
by men joining the platform). Nightclubs didn’t wait for economists to realize
that they could effectively sometimes operate on a platform model and
make more money by offering free drinks and free entry to women . . . while
men have to pay a hefty sum to get in and buy drinks.3
Early-stage platforms may be eager to offer a free service to all customers
in order to scale quickly. They may, however, grow faster – and in a more
balanced way – by charging one side and investing in extra services and
incentives for the customers that provide the most value to the network or
where there is a significant gap in the network.
146 Platform pricing

Conversely, some platforms’ business models may rely so much on scale


that pricing either side of the platform (e.g. producers and consumers, or
women and men in our previous example) may be difficult unless extra value
is created. In addition, just because one side gains significant value from
the platform does not mean that value can be readily captured (for example,
if a platform competes on the basis of its exhaustive selection, having sellers
leave as a result of a price increase would undermine the promise at the heart
of its value proposition). In these cases, revenue may need to be generated
from complementary value-added services (see below).
Many platforms use a range of charging techniques in order to balance
supply and demand. By selecting the right pricing models, platforms are able
to deal with different objectives and priorities at the cost of some increased
complexity. Etsy charges a small listing fee as well as a reasonable transaction
fee (3.5%), while eBay only charges its US customers for listing after 50 listings
per month but takes a 10% transaction fee in most categories. The mix of
fees applied by platforms tends to be dynamic and changes over time and
across geographies. Table 11.1 illustrates the various fees applied by a number
of marketplaces in the US.
While comparing the US pricing policies of a number of platforms to illustrate
supply and demand management, we note that the same platform may be at
different stages of development (and face different competitors) in different
geographic markets. This means that many platforms will need to adapt their

Table 11.1 Seller fee examples

Listing Final Membership Fees if Total sale Amount


fee value no sale fees seller
fee keeps
Bonanza – $1.05 – – $1.05 $28.95
Etsy $0.20 $1.05 – $0.20 $1.25 $28.75
Ruby Lane $0.19 – $69 per $1.35 $1.54 $28.46
month
eBay $0.30 $3.00 – $0.30 $3.30 $26.70
Amazon $0.99 $4.50 – $0.99 $5.49 $24.51
Note: Fees have been calculated for an item selling at $30. The seller has sold 50 other items in the month.
Etsy: Basic fees for selling on Etsy (no pattern site).
Ruby Lane: There is a $100 one-time setup fee, inclusive of free listings for the first 10 items. The monthly
maintenance fee of $69 is for the first 80 items, with a corresponding charge per item in excess of 80
listings.
eBay: Basic fees for auction style and fixed priced listing. Insertion fees are free for the first 50 listings per
month, $0.30 thereafter.
Amazon: Individual seller pricing, with 15% final value fee (most categories).
Source: Bonanza, Etsy, Ruby Lane, eBay and Amazon websites, Launchworks analysis, September 2016
Platform pricing 147

pricing strategy to their local market environment – to ensure sides are


balanced – ideally while staying within an overall global pricing framework.

How to enhance the quality of customer interactions


and experiences
Sophisticated pricing strategies can enhance the overall value proposition of
the platform by improving the quality of customer interactions, without adding
too much friction. For example, by helping to solve a commitment or
signalling problem between platform participants (e.g. if payment is made on
the platform, it shows parties are committed and price is final). This is the
approach that car-sharing start-up BlaBlaCar adopted with great success, by
introducing upfront online prepayment of rides, after having tried a number
of other models. The number of drivers not showing up for pickups was
significantly reduced (from about 35% down to 3%!) almost overnight.
BlaBlaCar was simultaneously able to monetize its service and capture real
data about ride-sharing. This critical enabler, to help arbitrate potential dis-
putes, was not possible when the financial transaction happened off-platform.
Platforms can also use such pricing strategies to differentiate their customer
community vs other platforms based on the ‘average value’ of users. Apple
promotes its users as higher-value customers to app developers, and Amex its
cardholders as high-value diners to restaurants.
The monetization of value-added features of the platform can also enhance
the quality of platform interactions when they help participants improve their
offering. For example, offering (and charging for) data insights and service-
enhancement tools can help platform participants improve the marketing and
quality of their product offering on the platform.
Ensuring that the additional services monetized on the platform are having
a positive impact on the overall customer experience is critical for a successful
value-added pricing strategy. Some platforms have damaged trust in their
communities by, for example, allowing sellers to buy their way to the top of
listings. While evidence suggests that some well-known platforms have been
able to recover from those pricing mistakes, it is always important for the
platform owner to consider the impact of pricing on the platform as a whole,
as opposed to just the segment being charged.

How to avoid disintermediation


Leakage is a risk for many platforms. Customers make initial contact using
the platform but then form an ongoing transactional relationship outside of
the platform. This makes it difficult for the platform to capture and share the
148 Platform pricing

value created by these interactions. Many platforms suffer from some level of
leakage,4 so it needs to be managed carefully, especially if the value capture
is done at the transaction stage. This is why some platforms have tried different
pricing for first and subsequent transactions between participants. TaskRabbit,
a service platform, takes 30% on the first transaction with a producer, and
15% subsequently. Other service platforms, such as Thumbtack, simply
monetize the lead/introduction to avoid leakage when participants connect.
The more direct the connection between participants, the greater the risk
of disintermediation. Transactions requiring face-to-face meetings, for exam-
ple, may lead to off-platform transactions, while anonymous mediated
communication is likely to be more conducive to on-platform transactions.
Pricing structures such as one-off joining fees can negate this risk, but they
may conflict too heavily with the goals of rapid growth and frictionless
pricing. In these cases, a strategy of monetizing value-added and comple-
mentary products and services may be appropriate.
The key is to understand the most valuable additional services provided by
the platform, in addition to searching/matching, and offer them as stand-alone
products. For example, additional services could include insurance, reference
checking, dispute and remediation services, simple safe payment systems and
emergency on-demand services (e.g. a nanny platform may offer and monetize
fully accredited and endorsed emergency nannies in addition to providing a
free ‘regular’ nanny marketplace).

How to transition from one pricing model


to another
A common platform strategy is to offer services for free and then seek to
introduce new pricing structures once a critical mass of customers is reached.
Many successful or promising platforms have failed in part because they
managed this transition poorly (e.g. Myspace). While platform managers may
not want to charge fees early on, they should have a coherent transition strategy
in mind from the beginning.
Pricing transitions are particularly challenging for platforms because:

• cross-platform network effects can compound any negative impacts from


the price change;
• platforms are often moving from a ‘price of zero’, which is the most
difficult pricing transition to make; and
• customers may invest significant time into a platform community and may
view the initial pricing as a type of ‘social contract’ promising a long-
term return on their investment.
Platform pricing 149

Of course, these challenges also provide opportunities. Positive network


effects will amplify the benefits of effective price changes (e.g. improvements
in average user ‘quality’). Finally, users’ investment of time into the platform
makes them ‘stickier’ customers who are prepared to pay so as not to lose
that investment.
While the lessons on these transitions are still being learned, some patterns
are emerging:

• Customers can be highly sensitive to unexpected price changes (especially


when free platforms start charging). For example, Meetup lost 95% of
its listings after introducing fees (although this was not necessarily detri-
mental).5 Customers may only invest time into a platform community
because they expect the current fee structures to continue. Clarity on
whether a platform’s initial pricing is an ‘introductory offer’ or a long-
term strategy is important to ensure that user growth and the monetization
model are sustainable.
• Where new fees are introduced, the platform should seek to provide
new value to its customers as well. This will help balance out the ‘long-
term equation’ for the customer and avoid the feeling that they’ve been
‘duped’.
• Offering highly relevant but optional fee-based services can enhance the
value of the platform and provide revenue without upsetting the ‘social
contract’ linked to the core interaction.
• Platform switching costs must be understood clearly, specifically how much
investment users have made in the platform. Does this investment provide
permanent value or must additional time/energy be spent to maintain it?
And are users multihoming?
• Pricing transitions can be focused on one side of the platform or one cus-
tomer segment at a time to avoid large shocks to the platform. For example,
Facebook has placed constraints on commercial pages to assist its paid
advertising business, but personal users remain free from direct fees.

In general, it is risky to unexpectedly alter the pricing or scope of the core


interaction of a platform. Only platforms with extremely high value compared
to competitors are able to suddenly change the price of the core interaction
with limited impact, and even then they may choose to limit the change to
specific customer segments. It is, however, possible for a platform to pivot
and change its business model by starting to charge, especially once it reaches
critical mass. The new resulting equilibrium can however be significantly
different from the previous one (e.g. Meetup).
150 Platform pricing

Transitional pricing strategies can be designed to leverage the core value


proposition of the platform and build complementary businesses. Such
approaches also open the door to the monetization of the wider platform-
powered ecosystem. For example, LinkedIn introduced a number of premium
subscriptions giving access to enhanced functionalities for people with specific
requirements (e.g. looking for a job, keen to be able to reach out beyond their
direct network, etc.), but still doesn’t charge 80% of its users for its basic services.

Conclusion
Platform pricing has unique challenges. Many platform pioneers who have
learned through trial and error have provided us with useful insights into the
effects of various pricing models. This has allowed us to identify patterns
and infer high-level pricing principles for new platform businesses. When
poorly designed, pricing may stifle positive network effects and slow growth.
However, the right pricing strategy can generate tremendous value while
supporting the strategic objectives of the platform. BlaBlaCar is an excellent
illustration of the growth that can be unlocked once the right platform pricing
model is found. Platform pricing can sometimes be more an art than a science,
and experimentations to test high-level hypotheses remain key. As illustrated
in Table 11.2, it is important for pricing levels and structure to support the
objectives of the platform at a given point in time.

Table 11.2 Matching platform objectives with pricing levers and examples
Objective Possible levers and examples
Rapidly grow platform membership Freemium (SoundCloud)
Transaction fees (Airbnb)
Encourage members to transact Membership fees with unlimited use (Match.com)
frequently Subscription for reduced fees (Ruby Lane)
Balance growth on each side of the Credit card rewards (Amex issuing)
platform Surge pricing (Uber)
Generate revenue for profit and Credit card merchant fee premium
cross-subsidization (Amex acquirer)
Value-added features for reduced fees
(OpenTable)
Embed loyalty and discourage Discounts for ongoing use (TaskRabbit)
disintermediation Lead generation fee only (Thumbtack)
Differentiate/attract the most valuable Ecosystem strategy (iPhone premium customers
customers drive App Store spending)
Improve inventory quality Listing fees (SpareRoom)
Super seller discounts (eBay top-rated sellers)
Source: Launchworks
Platform pricing 151

Notes
1 See http://qz.com/687231/people-are-more-likely-to-take-uber-at-2-1x-surge-pricing-
than-2x/.
2 See www.artfire.com/ext/sell/join_now for terms and conditions. Also, we note that
the membership fee gives access to added ‘premium’ services, such as higher caps on
number of listings or enhanced tools to sell on the marketplace.
3 Interestingly, such a pricing approach has been banned on the basis of gender dis-
crimination in a number of US states. The California Supreme Court, for example, ruled
that it violated California’s Unruh Civil Rights Act. See, for example, Angelucci v. Century
Supper Club (2007). Attempts to circumvent the law by having ‘free drinks for people
wearing skirts’ have apparently been tried as a result.
4 Typical examples include platforms introducing cleaning ladies to clients or even some
product categories sold on marketplaces such as eBay where some sellers clearly try to
get the connection with the buyer before selling the full service direct. This may explain
why some firms are selling single planks of wood in the ‘wood flooring’ section as opposed
to square metres . . .
5 See G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York:
W. W. Norton & Company, 2016, Chapter 6, for a discussion on how price increases
at Meetup actually strengthened the platform.
Chapter 12

Trust, governance and brand

Why trust matters


Trust is the glue of life. It’s the most essential ingredient in effective
communication. It’s the foundational principle that holds all relationships.
Stephen Covey

What made people suddenly comfortable with the idea of sharing their flats
with strangers (Airbnb), buying second-hand goods from people on the other
side of the planet (eBay) or renting their cars while they are away (Turo)?
The answer is trust. Understanding how platforms have been able to build
trust between participants of their ecosystem is key to understanding their
success. Unlike traditional businesses – where trust must be established between
the firm and its customers – platforms need a more holistic approach where
trust has to be built between the platform and its participants as well as between
the participants themselves. You not only need to trust the Airbnb brand,
but also the person you are going to rent your flat to. Without a sufficient
level of trust, perceived risks may outweigh the possible financial gains of
using the platform. In fact, one of the key issues for platforms is that the
producer has more information about what is being exchanged, sold or traded
than the users. Using the example of cars, famous economic Nobel Prize
winner George Akerlof wrote a very insightful paper titled ‘The Market for
Lemons’. In it, he explains that if some sellers are selling cars in working
order while others are selling broken cars (so-called ‘lemons’, presumably
because they leave a bitter taste in the mouth of buyers) and that buyers have
no way of knowing which is which, then the price of all the cars will converge
towards the price of the worst possible car. Without a well-thought-out trust
framework and relevant information exchange between participants, a platform
offering second-hand cars would therefore simply fail.1
So how do platforms build trust?
154 Trust, governance and brand

Figure 12.1 Trust survey: responses to the question, ‘On a scale of 0–5, how much
do you trust . . . ?’
Source: BlaBlaCar, Chronos

A fascinating study commissioned by BlaBlaCar2 gives us some insights into


the new unique tools available to platforms to help build enough trust for
people to be comfortable transacting. In this study, the participants are asked
to which extent they trust friends and family, strangers in the street, and a
number of different online profiles.
As expected (see Figure 12.1), close friends and family are the most trusted
(4.7/5), while online strangers are the least trusted (1/5). What is fascinating
is the extent to which adding a picture and having a validated identity, as
well as positive reviews on a platform, can make a total stranger almost as
trusted as a family member (4.2/5). BlaBlaCar and NYU Stern Professor Arun
Sundararajan also carried out an extensive study in 2016 over 18,000 BlaBlaCar
members in 11 European countries. It validated earlier survey results across
all countries, showing the universality of new online trust tools.3
The ability to create a trusted online profile is a very recent phenomenon
that is partly linked to the ubiquitous availability of social networks and the
unique ability for platforms to collect and display relevant data that increase
trust between participants.4
Establishing trust between participants is therefore one of the foundational
pillars of platforms and critical to their successful scaling. But as trust expert
Trust, governance and brand 155

Rachel Botsman explains, before participants trust each other, they need to
trust the idea. It can be a challenge when this idea is new, couch-surfing
for example. Then they need to trust the platform.5 For someone to list their
car on Turo, they need to know they’re insured in case something bad
happens. Finally, participants need to trust each other. While this applies to
all platforms, the required threshold of trust for transactions to occur will vary
depending on the type of transaction enabled by the platform. Marketplaces
enabling simple transactions such as product purchases will need a basic level
of trust between buyers and sellers. But the minimum trust threshold required
also depends upon the type of platform. Service platforms with high-stakes
transactions, such as Sittercity.com, which matches babysitters with parents,
or medical sites, such as Doctolib, that match you with health practitioners,
will require a high trust threshold. More mundane services, and more
standardized lower-value items, typically have a lower trust threshold.

The building blocks of trust


First, it is important to understand the nature of trust. Trust is not a static
concept, but grows over time as a result of accumulated experiences and
interactions with the platform. Trust requires constant nurturing. It works
like the reservoir shown in Figure 12.2: actions that build trust accumulate,
but trust can be also be eroded. Finally, trust is more effectively built by
repeatedly demonstrating, rather than asserting, one’s strengths and values.
But what are the actions that can build trust, and what can erode it?
To answer these questions, it is useful to have an overall trust framework in
place to identify, at least directionally, trust-enhancing and trust-eroding inter-

Figure 12.2 The trust bank


Source: Adapted from Hitendra Wadhwa, Driving Strategic Impact, Columbia Business School Teaching
Material
156 Trust, governance and brand

actions. The trust framework can be used as a high-level guide to assess platform
governance principles to ensure that new rules do not drain the trust bank.
Some academics have tried to unpack the key underlying drivers of trust
to derive a simple formula for a trust quotient.6
C+R+I
The formula for the trust quotient is: TQ =
S
With the following definitions for the fundamental building blocks:
• Credibility (C), or the perceived capabilities of a person or an organization.
• Reliability (R), or how consistently experiences of kept promises have
been repeated.
• Intimacy (I ), or how enjoyable to interact with.
• The inverse of self-orientation (1/S ). It can also be described as bene-
volence, empathy and the ability to hold the other party’s interest over
one’s own.
The formula states that the sum of credibility, reliability and intimacy are
key positive drivers of trust and that the effect of these three building blocks
is magnified when combined with high empathy or, conversely, diminished
when exhibited by a ‘selfish’ individual or organization.
This generic trust formula is said to be applicable to a range of situations,
from professional relationships to social interactions.
We know that trust can be enhanced or eroded based on experiences
and interactions, so platforms need to design a user experience that encourages
interactions and activities that enable trust rather than limit it.
Many surveys and studies show the type of behaviours that are conducive
to trust and those that undermine it. A World Economic Forum survey on
trust in 2014 showed that the characteristics or behaviours most damaging
to people’s trust were when people were: ‘not doing what they say’ (45% of
respondents), ‘self-interested’ (28%), ‘secretive’ (11%) and ‘arrogant’ (8%).
A platform could look at the interactions it enables and seek to develop govern-
ance principles to ensure that the above issues are addressed. For example,
when BlaBlaCar introduced its online pre-payment feature, as described in
the previous chapter, it started to monetize its ride-sharing platform, but more
importantly it solved a key trust issue that had been undermining the growth
of the platform. When the service was free, the cost of not showing up for
a ride (either to pick up or to be picked up) was very low. Since money had
not changed hands, people were not always fully committed. This was
consistent with the very high ‘no-show’ rate prior to the online payment
feature being introduced. Enabling online payment on the BlaBlaCar platform
was therefore a key trust-enhancing move that directly contributed to the
subsequent exponential growth of the platform.
Trust, governance and brand 157

The trust framework and the 7Cs of trust in a platform


environment
Digital platforms can incorporate the general principles presented earlier by
developing online tools and processes that create the foundation and
environment for communities to develop high levels of trust.
While the trust quotient equation is a helpful starting point, we find that
platforms often benefit from a more granular approach of the key levers
available to enhance trust. BlaBlaCar’s co-founder Frédéric Mazzella believes
trust is fundamental to the company success. His excellent DREAMS frame-
work (declared, rated, engaged, activity-based, moderated, social)7 has facili-
tated the mapping and enhancement of key trust levers for peer-to-peer
ride-sharing. From our experience, we have found that a more generic
framework, as illustrated by the 7Cs in Figure 12.3, can be applied to and
adapted for most types of platforms, from marketplaces, social networks,
payment platforms, operating systems and app stores. Let’s have a look at each
part in more detail.

Figure 12.3 The 7Cs of trust


Source: Launchworks
158 Trust, governance and brand

Credibility
Credentials of participants and/or products/services provided should include
the relevant information needed for trust to be built. As we saw from the
trust survey, a picture, a verified email and mobile phone number, and posi-
tive feedback scores are all critical components of platform participants’ online
trust profiles.
Companies such as eBay, Airbnb and BlaBlaCar all offer useful information
on the profiles of their members. In many cases, the information is
supplemented by some form of platform ranking (Ambassador in Figure 12.4),
as well as relevant preferences (e.g. likes to talk during trips, non-smoker,
etc.) to maximize the chances of positive interactions on – and off – platform.
In our experience, the link between the quality of the profile and likelihood
to transact is very strong. There is ample evidence that, with all other things
being equal, sellers with complete profiles and verified information sell
significantly more than others. Big high-resolution product pictures and clear

Figure 12.4 BlaBlaCar driver profile


Source: BlaBlaCar
Trust, governance and brand 159

detailed descriptions also have a higher conversion rate. To come back to our
opening example of Airbnb, the poor quality of pictures for homes being
advertised in the early days was indeed a limiting factor, and dealing with this
proved to be a key contributor to the exponential growth that ensued.
While we have been focusing on trust aspects on the producer side of the
platform, it is worth remembering that the credibility principle also applies
to the user side. On Airbnb, hosts can check potential guests before accepting
a rental.
Higher-credential participants not only do better, but they also benefit the
entire community and the platform itself. This is why Upwork, the talent
platform, has developed hundreds of proprietary skill tests for freelancers to
assure clients that the freelance contractors are certified. Upwork also recently
launched its ‘Pro’ status, which requires that freelancers go through a rigorous
vetting process, including technical skill evaluations and behavioural interviews.
LinkedIn’s acquisition of online certification company Lynda for $1.5 billion
in April 2015 can also be seen in that light.

Contribution
Showing participants’ activity on the platform can be a good indication of their
level of contribution, engagement and proficiency in using the platform.
BlaBlaCar displays an activity box on driver profiles showing the day they
joined the platform, the number of rides given, how long ago they were active
on the platform, when they last logged on, and how responsive they are. Quora
provides the number of questions and answers a user has contributed to. Twitter
shows how many tweets people have posted and liked. Upwork displays the
number of hours freelancers have worked for clients through the platform.

Consistency
As we’ve seen from the trust equation, trust results from the accumulation
of positive interactions and experiences. So it’s not just the activity or
contribution that counts, but also the consistency of experiences over time.
Many marketplaces use rating and review systems to capture the quality of
past experiences delivered by participants.
eBay was one of the first companies that managed to scale its review and
rating system globally, and this has been instrumental in creating trust between
buyers and sellers. Buyers can rate and review sellers on their overall experience
(positive, negative or neutral), which results in a feedback score (percent-
age in parentheses next to a member’s user ID in Figure 12.5).8 Detailed seller
ratings (item as described, communication, dispatch time, postage) are also
160 Trust, governance and brand

Figure 12.5 eBay star system


Source: eBay/Stuff U Sell

rated on a score of 1 to 5. eBay reports these ratings over time with one-,
six- and 12-month averages in order to show consistency trends. Amazon has
a similar reporting system for merchants on its platform.
eBay started with a reciprocal reputation system in the early years, where
sellers could leave visible ratings for buyers. eBay, however, found that sellers
with poor ratings often retaliated against buyers by also giving them bad ratings.
Clearly, this ‘tit for tat’ approach gave the wrong incentives to platform
participants and amplified issues instead of strengthening positive network
effects. eBay therefore decided to carry on collecting ratings from sellers, in
order to identify and weed out bad buyers, but that data is no longer visible
to platform participants.
Platform rating and review systems are not perfect and can suffer from biases
as Andrei Hagiu and Simon Rothman point out.9 Some customers never leave
ratings, and those who do so tend to be either very happy or very unhappy
with the product or service. Rating and review systems therefore need to be
calibrated to lessen the impact of biases. Airbnb has an advanced feedback
system with the possibility of leaving confidential feedback directly to the
host as well as the platform, in addition to public feedback. This is very useful
to track changes, spot emerging issues or even capture suggestions that do
not deserve a public mention but could help the host/platform adjust its
offering. Airbnb, like many other platforms, also captures NPS scores for both
Trust, governance and brand 161

guests and hosts, which provides better insights into the experiences of plat-
form participants.

Community
Community building is at the heart of many platforms and plays a key part
in encouraging positive interactions – leading to positive network effects –
and reducing negative interactions. A moderation policy should be instituted
early, especially for social platforms. It helps shape the community’s culture
and set the tone for the first 1,000 people. Once this early culture is set, it
is harder to change later on.

Providing the right tools to platform participants


Tools for participants to interact are key, and can take many forms depending
on the nature of the platform (upvotes, likes, posts, intermediated email
systems, etc.). Tools to help participants understand how they relate to each
other within the community (how they’re connected/related, etc.) are also
important to enhance trust.
The platform should supplement its own internal controls by harnessing
the power of its communities to detect negative interactions and offensive
content. The ability for participants to flag and report inappropriate content
or behaviour and to file complaints is key to this process. Participants are
usually happy to help ‘police’ the platform and recognize the role the platform
plays in regulating the community.10

Platform community management


Many companies are using community managers to establish and maintain
relationships with clients online. The role of community managers is even
more critical for platform businesses since communities are the very source
of value of the platform. Community management needs to support the scaling
stage of the platform by securing user and producer engagement, identifying
star customers and producers – as well as troublemakers – moderating content,
and shaping the norms and behaviours that support a platform’s ethos and
brand. The influence of platform community managers shouldn’t be under-
estimated since they play some of the roles that managers used to play in
traditional companies (reward, praise, nudge, coach, etc.) with the community
members who are effectively co-creating value with the platform. They can
also ensure that they engage with their communities on issues of strategic
interest to the platform itself. Airbnb community managers are very active in
mobilizing its hosts and guests on the topic of rental regulations, for example.
162 Trust, governance and brand

Control
Platforms have significant power and responsibilities associated with their
operations. To quote law professor Jeffrey Rosen, platforms such as Facebook
have ‘more power in determining who can speak and who can be heard
around the globe than any Supreme Court justice, any king or any president’.
It is certainly true that the monitoring of content contribution and sharing
(automated or not) is a key activity for many platforms. While the exact
numbers are not reported, some social platforms are thought to have up to
a third of their entire staff involved in content monitoring.11 When participant
activity happens off-platform, monitoring tools may also be required to
control the experience. In some places, Uber asks a driver to take and send
a selfie when starting work. Uber then compares the image with the biometric
data on record for an ID check. If it does not match, Uber suspends the
account until an investigation takes place.12
As a platform scales, monitoring often needs to be extended beyond the
platform itself. A more holistic type of ‘client service’ monitoring involving
social platforms, corporate blogs, review sites, etc. can be instrumental in
surfacing bad – or good – customer experiences. It can also help recognize
VIP customers and influencers and monitor so called ‘trolls’, that are only
there to provoke the community. This holistic monitoring function, sometimes
called ‘social listening’, is often part of the customer service team and benefits
greatly from strong analytics support (optimize function of the Launchworks
rocket model) and feedback loops with most teams (trust, product, engineering,
growth, marketing, pricing and legal) to drive meaningful calls to action.

Correction
Control and correct activities are closely linked. When platforms detect that
some interactions or transactions are not carried out in a trust-enhancing way,
or contravene governance principles, they have an opportunity to correct the
outcome directly. As a platform matures, corrections may be automated by
algorithms, with exceptions managed manually by employees from the trust
and safety team.

Punish bad behaviour and incentivize good behaviour


Correction can go from taking down illicit content (YouTube) and banning
a participant who displayed inappropriate behaviour (Twitter), to de-
prioritizing a seller with low ratings in search results (eBay). The trust and
safety team will need to constantly review and update rules and policies against
governance principles, as new use cases and behaviours reveal themselves.
Trust, governance and brand 163

Following the 2016 US presidential election, Facebook and Twitter have been
heavily criticized about their role in allowing ‘bots’ to spread misleading or
fake information to voters.13 Since then, Facebook has vowed to tackle
hoaxes. Google has also blocked fake news from its ad network. Twitter,
which by design is a more open platform, still faces challenging governance
issues in this area.

Make it right
Inherently, platforms do not completely control the end-to-end customer
experience. When something goes wrong, great customer service can help
minimize the reputational damage. Airbnb has been known to book hotel
rooms directly to make sure a guest who was let down by a host could have
a place to sleep.

Conflict resolution and risk management


As mentioned earlier, many participants expect a platform to regulate its
community. This includes resolving three different types of conflicts that may
arise on the platform: between producers (for example, if a producer tries to
undermine a competitor by giving bad reviews), between producers and users
(say, if orders are not delivered) and between users (who may disagree about
reviews of a product, etc.). To that end, the platform needs to understand
how to mitigate the risks associated with producers or users not fulfilling their
obligation. The platform should also decide who should bear the cost of failures
from users and producers. Poor risk management led to the demise of peer-
to-peer luxury car-sharing service HiGear. A criminal ring used stolen
identities and stolen credit cards to bypass HiGear’s security checks and stole
several high-end cars. HiGear’s insurance covered the thefts, but it made the
economic equation unsustainable and HiGear had to shut down shortly after
the incident.14
While conflict resolution should be fast, clear and fair, some platforms apply
a correction bias on one side. Amazon will generally side with buyers if they
have a dispute with a merchant on the platform. A refund is almost always
given. Since both buyers and sellers are platform participants, it is important
to make sure that the correction bias does not undermine one side of the
platform too much. For example, very lenient policies biased towards buyers
may result in legitimate sellers not being paid. In the long term, this may
harm trust on the platform. Bad buyers therefore also need to be monitored
and managed, even if a positive bias towards buyers is part of the platform
governance framework.
164 Trust, governance and brand

Coverage: insurances as a trust device


At a basic level, trust is about making sure that things go as expected. If they
don’t, insurance is a helpful device to bring the final outcome closer to what
was expected, even when something goes wrong. In that sense, insurance can
be used as a trust-enhancing mechanism for platforms.
Platforms are often reluctant to secure insurance early on for a number of
reasons, including price, the difficulty of finding suitable products and the
perceived brand impact of signalling that the platform offering could fail. Yet
offering insurance often results in enhanced trust and increased platform
transactions.
An often-cited example is the one of credit card companies that were forced
to offer insurances by regulators in the US in the 1970s.15 While they reluc-
tantly complied with the $50 consumer liability limit, this move ended up
benefiting them commercially as increased consumer trust in cards led to
significantly more transactions.
Similarly, despite an initial reluctance to cover its hosts and guests, Airbnb’s
introduction of its $1 million liability insurance was instrumental in growing
its market share beyond the early adopters segments.16
BlaBlaCar’s sharing model is largely covered by the existing insurance poli-
cies of drivers. This is because BlaBlaCar drivers are only able to recoup part
of the costs associated with the ride and are not therefore offering a com-
mercial service. The BlaBlaCar passengers are therefore covered under the
driver’s insurance policy, as if they were friends or family members of the driver.
Yet Blablacar added an insurance provided by Axa to cover some other, very
rare, use cases. The marketing impact of the insurance on trust, however,
made the deal worthwhile irrespective of the real value of the additional
coverage.
Insurance companies, historically organized domestically even when part
of large international groups, are waking up to these developments and
designing new insurance products for platform businesses. New insurance start-
up companies such as Kasko have also entered the market with innovative
products tailored to platform businesses and the sharing economy. Going
forward, we have no doubt that new insurance products suited to platform
needs will emerge.

Trust as a new currency


It is trust, more than money, that makes the world go round.
Joseph Stiglitz, professor of economics at Columbia
University, Economics Nobel Prize winner (2001)
Trust, governance and brand 165

As participants get more familiar with one platform, research shows that they
also become more willing to use other platforms. A recent study from
Professor Arun Sundararajan showed that existing BlaBlaCar ride-sharers were
more likely to use a peer-to-peer marketplace than non-ride-sharers.17
As interpersonal trust is being transformed from a ‘scarce to an abundant
resource’,18 a new digital trust ecosystem is emerging. Companies such as eRated
or Traity are now aggregating ratings and reviews from various marketplaces,
social networks and government sites in order to create a unified online trusted
identity. This can be extremely valuable to new platforms since they may be
able to leverage some of the trust that users have acquired somewhere else
instead of only relying on feedback on the platform itself (often scant at
ignition!). The need for a ‘trusted online identity’ is likely to increase in
tomorrow’s platform economy, and today’s solutions are just the beginning.

Governance principles
Platform governance principles must enhance trust between the platform and
its participants, as well as among participants. The trust framework principles
should therefore be part of the overall governance framework of the platform.
Once the key features of a platform have been designed, the focus should
be on the governance framework. This framework needs to set out the key
principles that will drive the way the platform:

• allows participants to join and interact with the platform and other
participants;
• shares economic and non-economic rewards among the platform itself
and its participants; and
• deals with exceptions, conflicts and outside stakeholders.

We have to keep in mind that these governance principles have far-reach-


ing consequences for platform participants. Some businesses may be excluded
overnight and go bankrupt, while some participants may lose a needed source
of income due to sudden rule changes. The economic importance of good
platform governance can’t be overemphasized, especially since some platforms
are now larger than countries.19

Filtering platform participants


In order to maximize trust, a platform needs to ensure that its participants
are trustworthy, and that those engaging in trust-eroding interactions and
behaviour are marginalized or excluded.
166 Trust, governance and brand

The first step for building a platform is attracting relevant participants.


This will partly be a function of the positioning of the platform in terms of
brand and acquisition channels used to recruit participants. In some cases, the
platform is designed in such a way that unsuitable participants are simply
discouraged to join. Before a seller or a shop can get started selling items,
vintage marketplace Ruby Lane conducts a prescreening to see if they meet
predetermined standards. There is also a $100 one-off setup fee to be paid
to discourage uncommitted sellers.20 Dating platforms such as Tinder seem
to be doing all they can to keep their user bases ‘young’ and ‘cool’. Tinder
markets predominantly to teens and young adults, and offers users the option
to use age filters to exclude older singles. Tinder even decided to charge more
– up to four times more in the UK – when users are above 30.21
Checking that participants are who they say they are is also a key trust-
enhancing feature of many platforms. This can be done in a number of
ways, from checking email addresses at a very basic level (date of account
creation, account activity) to full ID checks on individuals. For example,
companies like Onfido, Sift Science or Checker provide these types of
services. Facebook has had a major impact on the scaling of new plat-
forms and marketplaces thanks to the Facebook Connect API,22 which
helps reduce friction at user registration and login but also enables trust build-
ing as people register/log in using their real identity. Prior to social media,
the main way to register on eBay was to create a new user ID, which was a
real impediment to increasing trust since it said very little about who was
behind the account.
Finally, the continuous monitoring of participants’ behaviour and the
identification of trust-eroding actions as they emerge will be key to trust-
enhancing governance of the platform. Based on feedback, complaints and
pattern analysis, platforms should be able to marginalize participants that are
not following the rules or even exclude them from the platform.

Fairly rewarding participants


To be trusted, the platform also needs to ensure that the right kind of
behaviour is encouraged and rewarded. Rewards can be monetary and act as
an incentive to participate in the platform. But more subtle recognition cues,
or privileges, can be bestowed upon its ‘good citizens’.
Many platforms have a super user programme whereby the platform
itself can award special status, points or karma, to its most active/best
participants. In some communities, such as Wikipedia, these super users are
even entrusted with curating privileges and controls over the platform content
and operations.
Trust, governance and brand 167

Dealing with exceptions and conflicts


The extent to which a platform is involved in dispute resolution depends on
how it is designed. For example, some ‘thin’ platforms with limited func-
tionalities, such as Craigslist, have minimal conflict resolution capabilities since
they simply provide a canvas for platform participants to transact directly
among themselves.
However, platforms such as eBay, Airbnb or Uber need to carefully monitor
the behaviour of their participants, drivers and clients alike to ensure they
offer a safe and trusted environment for them to transact.

Platform governance through laws, norms and architecture


Unlike countries, which are built upon layers and layers of history, legal
practices, memberships to various supranational bodies and deep cultural ties,
digital platforms emerge from a blank slate. They have to comply with local
laws and regulations and operate in various cultural contexts, but they are
free to set their own internal governance principles. This is an opportunity
to design fair and transparent models that will attract participants and ensure
their success but also an immense challenge to ensure that the platform mini-
mizes ‘collateral damages’ that changes in governance may trigger.
The starting point of many platforms is simply to rely on market mecha-
nisms. As we have seen, the platform has to create the basic conditions for
participants to join (attract), find what they are looking for (match), and
exchange relevant information (connect) before they are able to make a deal
(transact). In some cases, platforms are able to succeed with a very light govern-
ance structure, but markets are not always efficient and governance principles
need to deal with market failures.
The platform owner is, however, not neutral in the platform market in
which it operates and may be tempted to design governance principles that
capture disproportionate value for itself.
Platform architects need to ensure that good behaviours are encouraged
while negative behaviours are minimized. In order to achieve this, platforms
have a number of levers available to them, including23 sets of governance
rules, which – in a similar way as countries use laws – are aimed at streng-
thening incentives for good behaviours, such as rewards for loyalty, increased
status for participation, monetary incentive for good referrals, etc. The same
applies for rules that undermine bad behaviours and prevent fraud, misrepre-
sentation, bullying, etc. This should be done as overtly as possible. While it
is important to clearly set out generic policies and objectives, it is often useful
to keep their detailed implementation hidden so that participants punished
for bad behaviour cannot easily bypass the exact rule that was invoked.
168 Trust, governance and brand

Sometimes the softer rules of platforms are conveyed through the behaviour
of existing platform participants, community leaders or even through coaching
examples chosen to explain the on-boarding process to new participants. A
‘like’ on a Facebook post from Mark Zuckerberg will do wonders to your
online credentials and shows other platform participants that whatever you
are doing is consistent with what Facebook expects from its users. The
behavioural norms that emerge over time in many platforms help shape the
future behaviour of new joiners and the platform ecosystem as it scales.
Lastly, the platform itself should embed some of the intelligence required
to enforce governance principles. Many automated algorithms and rules help
ensure that the right information is captured, that it is internally consistent,
and that the parties are who they say they are (if anonymous participation is
forbidden). Going forward, new technologies, such as distributed database
models like blockchain, will open the door to ‘self-enforcing smart contracts’
between platform participants and further strengthen the legal certainty of
core transactions. This will be a formidable enabler for platform businesses
since it will further lower friction between transacting parties.

Platform branding
The other side of trust is brand recognition. Brands still play a very important
part in the buying decision, and this is likely to hold true for many years.
This is because we still draw trust from familiar and recognizable names.
The development and management of a relevant platform brand is therefore
a key strategic enabler of reaching mass-market position and long-term success.
Typical branding strategies, however, need to be adapted to the fact that the
platform has unique relationships with its users and producers, and that they
themselves will interact with one another. That’s why the brand strategy needs
to not only ensure that the brand conveys trust in the idea and the platform
itself, but also that the brand is conducive to enabling transactions between
users and producers.

Getting participants over the fear barrier


Dealing with the potential fears of platform participants head-on should be
one of the brand-building missions of platform marketing executives. In the
case of Airbnb, there are three fear barriers. First, peer-to-peer home sharing
is safe. Second, people using Airbnb can be trusted. And third, Airbnb will
look after both hosts and guests if something goes wrong. The chief marketing
officer of Airbnb and former senior Coca-Cola executive Jonathan Mildenhall
identified the fear barrier early on and deliberately cast a single white female
Trust, governance and brand 169

who wanted to travel the world alone as the lead protagonist in the company’s
global TV campaign, ‘Never a Stranger’.24

Serving both sides


While branding efforts are often focused on building trust on the user side –
especially in B2C markets – success is also dependent on acquiring and
retaining producers. Platforms should therefore champion a set of clear and
powerful values and a design identity that resonate with both user and pro-
ducer communities. Sub brands can be used to more effectively target specific
segments on one side of the platform. eBay recognized this earlier as it rolled
out its ‘Powerseller Programme’. Not only did it reassure buyers that some
sellers had a seal of approval from eBay and could be trusted more, but it also
provided an evolution path and status recognition that sellers could strive for.
Many platforms have followed suit: Upwork has Upwork Pro freelancers,
Airbnb has Superhosts, Google has Android Certified developers, etc.

Brand co-evolution
At the launch stage, there is so much to do, from achieving platform fit,
acquiring and retaining users and producers, to building technical capabilities,
etc. that branding can be treated as a secondary concern. Airbnb co-founder
Joe Gebbia talks about the first airbed and breakfast logo, and explains:
‘Those brand identities were created in a matter of hours, for a short deadline,
and only for temporary use’. Brian Chesky echoes that sentiment and
continues: ‘We were growing so fast, it became one of those things where
you say you’ll figure it out later, but then you never end up doing it because
you’re too busy.’25
Platforms introducing a new concept such as Airbnb may initially focus
on describing simply and convincingly to both users and producers how
interacting and transacting on the platform can help them create and capture
value. But as the platform scales and its communities grow, a utility-driven
and descriptive brand is unlikely to reach, inspire and reassure late adopters.
Airbnb relaunched its website and mobile apps with a new brand identity in
July 2014, with the new focus of expanding internationally and becoming a
more inclusive hospitality brand. The year-long brand study included user
research as well as interviews from guests and hosts in more than a dozen
countries to capture the essence of the brand. It boiled down to one powerful
concept: belonging. Brian Chesky explains: ‘Airbnb is about belonging
anywhere. The brand shouldn’t say we’re about community, or our inter-
national [reach], or renting homes – it’s about belonging.’
170 Trust, governance and brand

It will be interesting to see how brands such as Airbnb will evolve over
time and how their communities will influence this process. We believe that
platform brands co-evolve with their communities and that participants
contribute to shaping brand values through their interactions with the platform
and other participants.
In the case of food delivery platform Deliveroo, the rebranding that took
place in September 2016 resulted in significant changes to the brand identity.
These changes were driven by the need to be more attuned to the expectations
of not only users, but also producers of the platform. For example, the new
identity now includes colourful jackets and jerseys for Deliveroo riders so that
they can be better seen at night.
When platforms change their strategies, like eBay did when it introduced
its ‘Buy It Now’ option, a brand refresh is often required. By the mid-2000s,
eBay had attained nearly universal brand recognition in Western countries
as the go-to marketplace for second-hand auctions, with vibrant seller and
buyer communities. eBay was well known for auction-style listings, second-
hand, quirky and unique items. It was so ingrained in the popular psyche,
and existing buyers and sellers were so passionate about the old eBay, that
the transition to being known as the destination for buying brand-new items –
as well as second-hand ones in auctions – took many years. A new branding
redesign in 2012 encapsulated this evolution of continued innovation,
combining eBay’s history of the unique, the vintage and its vibrant com-
munities with the new.

Notes
1 For an accessible summary of the argument and its implications for platforms, see
R. Fisman and T. Sullivan, The Inner Lives of Markets: How People Shape Them – and
They Shape Us, London: Public Affairs/John Murray Learning, 2016.
2 Betrustman Report, Chronos & BlaBlaCar, December 2012.
3 See BlaBlaCar, NYU Stern, Entering the Trust Age, 2016. In this study, respondents
were asked to rank on a scale from 0 to 5 the level of trust they gave to different types
of relationships, from a social network contact through to friends or family. A BlaBlaCar
member with a full online profile was then included in the mix. Looking at the
percentage of respondents that gave a high level of trust (4 or 5 out of 5), the results
revealed that 88% of respondents had high trust in a BlaBlaCar member. This percentage
is largely above the percentage of people who highly trust their colleagues (58%) or
neighbors (42%), and close to the percentage of people who highly trust their friends
(92%), revealing that trust built by online platforms can supersede offline relationships.
4 Arun Sundararajan, The Sharing Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2016, p. 61.
5 Rachel Bostman, the Trust Stack, www.rachelbotsman.com.
6 D. H. Maister, R. Galford and C. Green, The Trusted Advisor, London: Simon & Schuster,
2 January 2002.
Trust, governance and brand 171

7 BlaBlaCar, NYU Stern, Entering the Trust Age, 2016.


8 This feedback profile example is from StuffUSell, the UK’s leading trading assistant. This
popular merchant helps people who don’t have the time or don’t have enough positive
feedback to efficiently sell on eBay.
9 H. Hagiu and S. Rothman, ‘Network Effects Aren’t Enough’, Harvard Business Review,
94(4), 2016, https://hbr.org/2016/04/network-effects-arent-enough.
10 Survey from BlaBlaCar showed that 75% of participants believed in the importance of
the platform in regulating the community. Betrustman Report, Chronos & BlaBlaCar,
December 2012.
11 See www.theverge.com/2016/4/13/11387934/internet-moderator-history-youtube-
facebook-reddit-censorship-free-speech.
12 See http://venturebeat.com/2016/09/23/uber-selfies-security-photos-drivers/.
13 See www.thedailybeast.com/articles/2016/11/17/how-pro-trump-twitter-bots-spread-
fake-news.html. By election day, automated pro-Trump activity outnumbered pro-
Clinton activity by a 5:1 ratio.
14 See https://techcrunch.com/2012/01/01/luxury-car-sharing-service-higear-shuts-down-
due-to-theft/.
15 G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York: W. W.
Norton & Company, 2016, p. 175.
16 www.airbnb.co.uk/host-protection-insurance
17 BlaBlaCar, NYU Stern, Entering the Trust Age, 2016. Interestingly, the results were
even higher for millennials.
18 Frédéric Mazzella, Ouishare magazine interview, 14 January 2013.
19 Apple itself is roughly the size of Slovakia. See http://ftalphaville.ft.com/2015/01/28/
2103622/if-apple-were-a-country/.
20 Ruby Lane fees effective 1 May 2016, www.rubylane.com/kb/question.php?ID=36.
21 See www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-03-03/how-tinder-gets-away-with-
charging-people-over-30-twice-as-much.
22 Facebook Connect was launched in 2009.
23 These governance principles are borrowed from Lawrence Lessig, who formulated them
in the context of governments. See G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform
Revolution, New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2016, p. 164.
24 See www.adweek.com/news/advertising-branding/how-airbnbs-cmo-transformed-
company-super-brand-just-18-months-167620.
25 See www.fastcompany.com/3033130/most-innovative-companies/airbnb-unveils-a-
major-rebranding-effort-that-paves-the-way-for-sh#8.
Chapter 13

Platforms, regulation
and competition

Why should firms be regulated in the first place?


Governments are typically concerned about firms becoming ‘dominant’
because they can then abuse their market power to drive competitors away,
before increasing their prices. Typically, such issues can be dealt with in two
ways. The first one is to pre-emptively set rules for market participants. This
approach is often called ex ante regulation – because it sets the rules at the
outset – and is the domain of sector-specific regulators.1 The second way to
avoid abuse of market power is to intervene if evidence of anticompetitive
behaviour emerges after the facts (ex post). These types of interventions are
usually triggered by a complaint or an investigation and are the responsibility
of competition agencies and the commercial courts.
Similar principles are applied in many jurisdictions around the world, includ-
ing the US and Europe, where antitrust concerns are taken very seriously. As
seen in Chapter 6, platform-powered companies such as Apple, Google and
Amazon have been extraordinarily successful over the past decade and are now
among the largest in the world. This has in turn attracted the attention of those
in charge of policing markets to prevent firms from abusing dominant positions.
Much has been written on the various competition cases and regulatory
challenges that have been launched against platforms. This chapter will
summarize some of the main regulatory and competition arguments that have
been made in favour of, or against, platforms. This will help us answer some
of the key questions surrounding platform regulations:

• When is intervention warranted and what does good regulation look like?
• What are the characteristics of platforms that may cause economic harm?
• What should those in charge of policing markets, including governments,
regulators and competition authorities, do?
• How should platforms deal with regulation and regulators?
174 Platforms, regulation and competition

When and how to regulate platforms


Platforms such as Uber or Airbnb are often accused of ‘unfair competition’
and of being in breach of a raft of regulations. Such accusations, which are
often brought about by established firms disrupted by platforms such as taxi
companies or hotel chains, have not been taken lightly by governments
and regulators. Many cases against platforms have resulted in total or partial
bans.
One of the central questions is whether or not successful global platform
businesses are now able to behave in ways that reduce competition and
innovation to the detriment of customers.
In this section, we will look at the two main dangers facing regulatory and
competition interventions:

• Platforms end up being regulated when they shouldn’t have been.


• Platforms end up not being regulated when they should have been.

It’s worth remembering that both over-regulation and under-regulation


result in bad market outcomes, including reduced choice, reduced innovation
and higher prices. It is therefore important to understand what good regulation
would look like and whether the biggest risk is to over-regulate or to under-
regulate.
If it becomes apparent that over-regulation seems to be happening, it
may be because the regulations are not fit for purpose, or the wrong tools
are being applied. If it also appears that the value creation potential of
platforms is very significant, then over-regulation runs the risk of prevent-
ing the benefits brought about by platforms from being realized. To take the
example of the taxi market, forcing the status quo and preventing plat-
forms such as Uber or Lyft from operating, as advocated by many, may
result in enshrining the position of existing taxi firms, reducing choice and
convenience, and keeping prices high while discouraging future inno-
vation.
If, however, platforms end up being under-regulated, then they may be
able to drive out competition and abuse their market power in the longer
term, ultimately to the detriment of consumers.
One way to avoid this trade-off is to ensure that the right tools are
available to minimize both under- and over-regulation. In the absence of
perfect regulation, however, it is useful to understand how ‘less harm’ could
be done.
Platforms, regulation and competition 175

First do no harm: intervention and market failure


While markets have shown how efficient they are at allocating resources under
a wide range of conditions, they can also fail to promote efficient outcomes.
This does not mean that markets do not work at all, but that they do not
always work properly.
These market failures are the basis of intervention for many governments
and regulators, since without external intervention and ‘remedies’ to correct
these failures, some markets may result in suboptimal outcomes for society.2
Typically, economists associate the source of market failures to one of the
following three categories:

• The market consolidates and only a small number of firms (or even one)
are left with significant market power (or monopoly).
• The market under consideration has strong externalities (such as pollution),
and those are by definition not factored in the decisions of the firm.
• The good being traded is a ‘public good’ (such as street lighting) where
consumption cannot be denied and people can’t be excluded.

One of the first issues platforms are facing is that it is unclear how some
of the ‘historic’ regulations would pass the current market failure tests. This
suggests that these regulations, which often date back decades, sometimes
centuries, may in fact prevent the market from functioning rather than cor-
recting market failures. Many of the regulations that create barriers to entry
in markets where there is no market failure fall into this category. The
question for regulators and policymakers is then how to change these regu-
lations to ensure that the market is not artificially distorted. In some cases,
regulators seem to have been ‘captured’ by the firms they are meant to regulate.
Competition authorities tend to be more independent and therefore often
argue that many regulations need to be updated and shouldn’t be used to
prevent innovation. They also remind us of a very important principle: ‘the
purpose of competition law is to ensure that consumers are not harmed, not
to ensure that inferior competitors are protected from disruption’.
To be clear, that doesn’t mean that new entrants should be allowed to do
anything they want, including not carrying out checks on their drivers, not
providing insurance and not paying taxes. But it means that shielding specific
interest groups from competition should only be done after careful con-
siderations have been given as to why this should be the case and why society
would be better off as a result. Granting regulatory protection without tangible
welfare benefits would simply represent a tax on consumers in the form of
increased prices and reduced innovation.
176 Platforms, regulation and competition

This is a case where platforms risk being ‘over-regulated’ and prevented


from operating efficiently, and the regulations being applied to a sector are
aimed more at protecting corporations than enabling fair competition. It is
worth noting that in such cases, platforms are simply the catalyst for the
disruption and any other innovative entrant would create similar tensions.
We will illustrate how the above dynamics play out in the taxi industry later
in this chapter.

Big platforms are not necessarily dominant


As we have seen, platforms benefit from network effects, which means that
they are often more valuable the more people use them3 (e.g. imagine Airbnb
with one flat, or Tinder with only your profile!). When successful, these
platforms gain scale and achieve critical mass to become market leaders – this
is the ‘winner takes all’ principle. This is why securing the capital to acquire
more users and scale-up quickly is often the name of the game for platform
businesses.
This is not an abuse of market power, but simply a feature of the economics
of platform businesses. Yet scale can still create some market issues, and any
market with few competitors is bound to attract scrutiny. If competition is
really only a click away, the platforms are unlikely to be able to exploit their
market power. But in some circumstances, if switching is particularly difficult,
or if ‘multihoming’ (using similar platforms such as Uber and Lyft at the same
time) is for some reason not possible, it could become a concern.

Platforms have far more flexible pricing options


By virtue of the fact that platforms attract and market to different customer
groups in order to enable them to transact, they benefit from enhanced pricing
flexibility that is not available to traditional businesses. If you sell to only one
customer group, you need to price above the costs associated with this
product for the company to be sustainable in the long term.4 If you are a
platform, you may be able to offer the platform service for free to one side
of the platform (say, the producers) and charge the other side (say, the clients).
We illustrated the complexity and range of pricing models available to
platforms in Chapter 11, and showed that offering free entry to women in
night clubs – or dating platforms – in order to attract paying men is a rational
pricing strategy.
Some judges and lawyers seem to still be assuming that platforms offering
services for free are necessarily behaving in a predatory manner. Since it is
perfectly legitimate for platforms to price below cost on one side of the market
Platforms, regulation and competition 177

for profit motives, rather than anticompetitive ones, traditional predation tests
are not fit for purpose in the context of platforms.

Who do platform participants work for?


While this chapter focuses on competition issues, it is also important to
mention the tension between labour laws in many countries and many
platforms’ use of self-employed or independent contractors.
When the California Labor Commission suggested that an Uber driver could
in fact be considered an employee, rather than an independent contractor, it
sent shockwaves throughout the industry. Similar judgments have been
reached in UK courts,5 where the self-employed status of Uber drivers has
been called into question. Such findings, under appeal by Uber at the time
of writing, would have far-reaching consequences since they would undermine
many platform business models that are predicated on the participation of
self-employed workers. It is clear that platforms shouldn’t be allowed to
circumvent labour laws, yet we find the argument that platform participants
should be considered full employees of the platform quite difficult. Unlike
traditional employees, platform participants have the flexibility of working
only when suitable, can switch off at any time, are able to work for other
platforms (multihoming) at the same time, and have no notice to serve if they
decide to leave the platform. Yet we understand that the current labour laws,
designed primarily for the business models of the Industrial Revolution, are
struggling to cater for the new fluid reality of the platform economy. One
of Uber’s arguments is that is it a technology platform company offering a
service to both drivers and passengers, but some judges believe that Uber is
a transport company instead. Many legal practitioners believe that new types
of contracts, and agreements, will emerge as a result of this tension. In the
meantime, the legal uncertainty resulting from these labour regulations are
seen as a major risk by platform businesses and investors alike.

Are platforms ignoring regulations?


Platform-powered businesses such as Uber have been forced to change their
business model in several countries in order to comply with domestic
regulations and laws.6 In some cases, platforms have been fined7 or even
banned.8 In the UK and France, regulatory authorities even proposed that
their service be degraded in order to ‘level the playing field’ with traditional
taxi companies. For example, Transport for London (TfL) proposed that a
five-minute delay be added as a regulatory requirement before a trip can be
accepted by the Uber platform, while the French Government passed a law
178 Platforms, regulation and competition

adding 15 minutes to online bookings of taxis in 2013. The real-time display


of cars on a map, a valuable and innovative feature of Uber and other digital
entrants, was also in the cross hairs of taxi companies that were seeking a ban
on such disruptive new technologies. On both occasions, it is interesting to
see that the domestic competition authorities, in charge of enforcing
competition law, have strongly criticized these proposals. The Competition
and Market Authority (CMA) made its point known in no uncertain terms:

A number of TfL’s (Transport for London) proposals will harm


competition and, by extension, consumers. This will take the form of
harm to competition between Private Hire Vehicles (PHVs), through
regulations which is disproportionate and/or reduces incentives for entry,
expansion or innovation.9

It further added:

The CMA is concerned that some of TfL’s proposals will create barriers
to innovation in particular. Hampering innovation results in inefficient
business models, services of a lower quality than could otherwise be the
case, and dissatisfied consumers.

Ultimately, these proposed regulations were not retained by TfL. Following


a petition organized by Uber that attracted in excess of 200,000 signatures in
only a few days, it became clear that TFL’s proposals were not seen favourably
by consumers. Under pressure, the regulator decided to back down, although
black cabs are now seeking other legal options to block Uber. In France,
l’Autorité de la Concurrence (the French Competition Authority) argued that
the mandated delay was not necessary, that it would distort competition
between taxis and private hire vehicles, and that it should be removed. The
rule was subsequently struck down on technical grounds in December 2014.
Uber’s own lobbying efforts seem to be paying off in a number of US states
as well as other countries, and traditional taxi companies have not managed
to get the app banned (although court cases are still likely to be launched in
many jurisdictions).
Taxi companies have used regulations as a barrier to entry and have been
able to keep supply constrained for many years. That is to say by not allowing
more taxis on the streets – through so-called numerus clausus policies – they
have been able to increase their prices significantly above what happens
in other competitive markets. For example, the number of cab drivers in
NYC between 1937 and 1996 was exactly 11,787. Not one more and not
one less, despite a structural increase in demand over the 60-year period.
Platforms, regulation and competition 179

In fact, the value of such a monopoly model is directly enshrined in the value
of the ‘licence’ – a taxi medallion in this case. In other words, the economic
returns the taxi owners receive above what would be a fair return in a
competitive market is captured in the price of the medallion (which exceeded
$1 million in NYC in 2013). Incidentally, economists will tell you that this
value also represents the lifetime super profits or – in other words – money
taxis make by charging above market price that would otherwise be retained
by clients.
However, since new potential buyers are now anticipating more com-
petition from platforms such as Uber going forward, the price of medallions
is dropping, and quickly, as shown in Figure 13.1.10
Taxis are not the only sector to be impacted by the disruptive entry of
platforms. The hotel lobby has also mounted a global war on Airbnb, arguing
that taxes were not collected in the same way and that security regulations
that hotels are subject to didn’t apply. This resulted in a number of legal moves
against Airbnb,11 with partial or total bans in a number of cities (e.g. Barcelona).
In many cases, the legal position is not directly targeted at Airbnb, but clearly
aimed at reducing the number of people letting their property on the site.
While it is important for Airbnb and its hosts to pay the relevant taxes, it is
sometimes difficult to justify the proportionality of the regulations proposed

Figure 13.1 NYC taxi medallion prices (2004–2015)


Source: NYC Taxi and Limousine Commission
180 Platforms, regulation and competition

or passed in some countries. Clearly, it is important to prevent unscrupulous


businesspeople from circumventing legitimate hotel regulations by setting up
entire buildings as Airbnb rental properties rather than hotels, but should
private individuals be forced to implement hotel regulations when they rent
their own place?
Like Uber, Airbnb is now actively lobbying and its public policy teams
have been hard at work over the past couple of years to ensure consumers
can carry on participating in its platform.
It is, however, true that platforms often fail to prioritize these regulations
and requirements as they enter their international scale-up phase and tend to
negotiate ‘after the fact’.12 While the tension between compliance at a local
level and the need to gain scale for network effects to kick in is understandable
and may lead to a ‘bias towards action’ rather than compliance, it is clear that
this needs to be remedied quickly and that consumer protection regulations
shouldn’t be overlooked simply because services are provided by platforms.
In fact, it is clear that some platforms also impose negative externalities – such
as increased visits in formerly secure shared areas of buildings in the case of
Airbnb – that need to be factored in.
We also understand that it may be politically difficult for government to
suddenly remove previously granted exclusivity rights (especially if your entire
country can be locked down by angry taxi drivers as a result) and transition
measures may well be warranted. We, however, do not believe that seeking
to preserve the status quo by preventing innovation is either a practical or
desirable long-term option.

Could platform ecosystems abuse their market power?


Leaving behind the misguided ‘unfair competition’ argument we previously
discussed, it is important to ask whether or not some platforms, especially
very successful ones, are in a position to abuse their market power.
While we have seen that below-cost prices or even a large market share
are not enough to accuse platforms of abusing platform participants (users
and/or producers), it remains important to ensure that platforms are not in a
position to harm consumers in other ways.
When a platform becomes very successful, it gains significant market power
and may be tempted to use that power to colonize adjacent markets (e.g.
Google could bias search results in order to support its own music, finance,
etc. services to the detriment of competitors). While this presents clear
advantages for Google and allows the company to further develop its plat-
form-powered ecosystem, it may also undermine competition in a way that
is harmful to customers in the long term. As one of the largest companies in
Platforms, regulation and competition 181

the world in terms of market capitalization, Google is a prime candidate for


market power accusations. We’ll illustrate the type of competition issues that
platform-powered ecosystems can give rise to using Google as an example.

Google cases linked to ‘search favours’ for its own services


At the time of writing, Google is the second largest company in the world in
terms of market capitalization13 and its influence has not escaped competition
authorities and competitors alike.14 Google didn’t face much criticism as it grew
its superior search engine and displaced some of its early competitors such as
Alta Vista. However, things started to change once it became a market leader.
Its leadership position in search, combined with entry into new markets, were
often deemed to provide Google with the means and incentives to discriminate
against competitors, which in turn led to a wave of competition cases.
Indeed, Google has developed a number of vertical services over the years,
and has sometimes been accused of giving them favourable treatments,
especially in terms of search display (and without informing end users). Table
13.1 lists some of Google’s services and their direct competitors at time of
launch.

Table 13.1 Selected Google services and some competitors’ services by year of launch

Year Google service Competitors’ services


2002 Froogle (now Product Search) Amazon, eBay, Shopzilla
2005 Google Maps MapQuest, navX, Bing Maps
2006 Google Finance Yahoo Finance, MSN Money, AOL Money
YouTube Dailymotion, Veoh, Go Fish
2009 Google eHealth WebMD, Mayo Clinic
Google Compare Bankrate, LendingTree
Google Place (now Google Local) Yelp, TripAdvisor, Citysearch
2010 Google’s Boutiques.com eBay, Amazon
2011 Google Travel and Flights KAYAK, Expedia, TripAdvisor
Google+ (formerly G Wave) Facebook, LinkedIn
2013 Google Helpouts Duolingo, Hired, Fiverr
Source: Google, Inc., Fairsearch.org, Launchworks analysis

The first type of legal cases are linked to claims that Google discriminates
by favouring the rankings of its own services. Marissa Mayer, former Google
senior VP, commented in 2007 during a conference:
182 Platforms, regulation and competition

When we rolled out Google Finance, we did put the Google link first.
It seems only fair right, we do all the work for the search page and all
these other things, so we do put it first . . . That has actually been our
policy, since then, because of Finance. So for Google Maps again, it’s the
first link.

The above statement would suggest that Google’s search results may have
been biased in favour of the ranking of its own ecosystem properties vs those
of its competitors.15

Google cases linked to tying and bundling


Google also has an incentive to bundle the services it offers as part of
its ecosystem in order to increase overall penetration, and in turn the value
of its platform. In September 2013, Google started to require that users of
YouTube open a Google+ account in order to be able to post comments
(on YouTube). The strategic rationale for trying to boost Google’s new
social network was clear, but led some observers to highlight the possible
anticompetitive nature of such ties.16 The fact that users of Google search
services do not pay for the platform doesn’t mean that Google doesn’t have
incentives to extend its market power in some service markets (e.g. YouTube)
to other apparently free services (Google+) in order to later monetize these
through advertising contracts. But since bundling can also be useful to con-
sumers, such tying and bundling issues need to be approached on a case-by-case
basis. Conventional competition methods and bundling analysis guidelines17
are based on prices set by traditional firms and need to be adapted, since many
of these services are free and offered by platforms.
Google’s tying strategies are not only happening on the end user side (as
per Google+ and YouTube), but also on the content producer side.
The testimony of Jeremy Stoppelman,18 CEO of Yelp, in front of the US
Senate in 2011 provides some further insights into these allegations:

Websites typically allow search engines like Google to crawl and index
their sites so that links to their sites can appear in response to relevant
search engines queries . . . In 2010, Google began incorporating the
content it indexed from its competitors into Google Local without
permission. Although Google had previously acknowledged that it needed
a license to use Yelp’s content, it was now using it without permission
to prop up its own, less effective, product. In some instances, Google
even presented this content to its users as if it were its own . . . In response
to our objections, Google informed us that it would cease the practice
Platforms, regulation and competition 183

only if we agreed to be removed from Google’s Web search index, thereby


preventing Yelp from appearing anywhere in Google Web search results.
This of course was a false choice . . . it is a choice between allowing Google
to co-opt one’s content and not competing at all.
Google’s comments about delisting Yelp from its Web search results in a
retaliatory move if Yelp didn’t accept to license its content for free suggests
that Google may have been trying to abuse its market power. Other academics
have highlighted a number of potentially problematic linkages within Google’s
ecosystem.19

Google cases linked to exclusion and innovation deterrence


Google can also exclude competitors offering services overlapping with those
offered by its own ecosystem.
In 2011, Microsoft accused Google of preventing rival search engines,
including Microsoft’s Bing, from indexing YouTube and therefore voluntarily
degrading the quality of the service that other competitors could offer. This
is typically a case where some of Google’s own services were given a
preferential treatment compared to third parties, and the case would not have
arisen had Google not invested in its own video portal and associated
advertising offering.
The FTC also investigated allegations that Google was: (i) using proprietary
Application Programming Interfaces (APIs) in a way that hampered advertisers
willing to switch from AdWords (Google’s advertising service) to competing
providers; and (ii) stifling innovation by erecting barriers to entry through
unfair licensing of essential patents.20 Google agreed to legally binding com-
mitments in lieu of a full investigation. This directly led to a change in its
APIs so that transfer to other advertising platforms would be easier, and a
new fair licensing regime for any ‘essential’ Intellectual Property (IP) owned
by Google.21

Recent Google cases in Europe


In 2014, the Directorate of the European Commission in charge of com-
petition (DG Comp) expressed the following four concerns:
(a) Search results of Google services (hotel, restaurant, flight search, etc.)
are displayed more favourably than competing services and users are
unaware of this favourable treatment;
(b) Google uses content from competing search engines on its own site
against their express will and without payments;
184 Platforms, regulation and competition

(c) Publishers are asked to sign exclusive advertising agreements with


Google which risk reducing competition in the market for internet
ads; and
(d) Google is actively preventing the development of technology that
would facilitate the switching of ad campaigns from its own AdWords
service to competing ones (such as Microsoft’s AdCentre).

Instead of going to court, Google responded by proposing several legally


binding undertakings,22 including an agreement to inform its users about
sponsored shopping results and to provide links to competitors (as illustrated
in Figure 13.2). The Commission decided in fine to reject Google’s offer, and

Figure 13.2 Google’s proposed search page during negotiations


Source: EU Commission
Platforms, regulation and competition 185

Figure 13.3 Uber banner appearing in Google Maps mobile searches

the EU is reviewing the evidence, but still believes that Google may well be
favouring its own comparison shopping service.
Google also started showing the Uber option on the results of its mobile
mapping application in June 2014 (see Figure 13.3). This is an interesting
twist since Google is also a large shareholder of Uber,23 and may therefore
be in a position to offer favourable terms to Uber. However, in March 2016,
Google announced that new partners would be added to its service, including
99Taxis in Brazil, Ola Cabs in India, Hailo in the UK and Spain, mytaxi in
Germany and Spain, and Gett in the UK.
Google also came under scrutiny for its Android operating system and the
extent to which handset partners, such as Samsung and HTC, were forced
to pre-install Google apps24 – and whether or not such a practice distorts
competition. This again illustrates the extent to which Google can leverage
parts of its ecosystem (in this case, its operating system platform) to secure
prime ‘real estate display’ and default usage settings in order to favour its own
services. The US lawsuit was dismissed in early 2015, but EU antitrust
186 Platforms, regulation and competition

commissioner Margrethe Vestager also focused on Google’s Android, and


recently declared, ‘Google’s behaviour denies consumers a wider choice of
mobile apps and services and stands in the way of innovation’.
In fact, Google is now being accused by the European Commission of
using the Android operating system to tie together its own search engine,
maps, Gmail and YouTube video services (among others) in order to lever-
age its position and increase its advertising revenues. The Commission’s
concerns, communicated to Google in July 2016, are likely to be the begin-
ning of another protracted negotiation that may lead to a fully fledged
regulatory and legal battle. We are of course only focusing on antitrust
and competition matters, but Google, and other platforms, have also raised
concerns about their tax affairs and their management of data privacy
(and compliance with the ‘right to be forgotten’ principle) from the EU and
member states.

What should governments, regulators and competition


authorities do?
Our goal in the previous section was to distinguish between potentially
legitimate competition concerns levied against platforms and misguided
arguments rooted in bad regulations or due to a lack of understanding of
platforms as business models. While we have used Google as an example
to illustrate some of the potential ways in which platform-powered eco-
systems may behave strategically to maintain their market power, we are not
accusing Google – or indeed any other platforms – of systematically behav-
ing anticompetitively. Each case is different, but we have highlighted specific
areas where platforms may have the means and incentives to reduce
competition. The purpose of this chapter was to provide a balanced view as
to what may or may not constitute anticompetitive conduct in a platform
world, and dispel some of the more self-serving arguments sometimes
deployed by ‘protected firms’ while focusing on more relevant competition
concerns.
We would, in particular, like to attract the attention of governments and
competition authorities on the confusion around the notion of ‘unfair
competition’ and encourage them to distinguish between regulatory provi-
sions that platforms need to embrace in order to provide the quality of service
and security expected and regulations aimed at preventing entry and
innovation.
We, however, believe competition authorities should remain vigilant when
dealing with platform-powered ecosystems able to leverage their market
power across business models and product categories.
Platforms, regulation and competition 187

But most of the debates we’ve followed have been about trying to apply
traditional regulatory instruments and thinking to the new world of platforms.
This has often been a forced process, and few policymakers seem to have
been able to truly grasp what platforms really are and how a new type of
regulation could harness their power to flexibly embed regulatory requirements
into the platforms themselves.
We believe that a new type of regulatory approach is warranted, and that
public policy objectives should be reviewed in light of today’s innovations.
While the thinking around what some call Regulation 2.0 is only emerging,
it sketches a way forward to provide a sustainable answer to the challenges
brought about by platform-powered business models.25 Regulations based
on the need for pre-authorizations were often predicated on the fact that
information was scarce and therefore an independent body needed to check
and centralize it. Today, platforms could leverage their analytics to monitor
who is doing what in near real time. Companies such as PayPal have engaged
with regulators and encouraged such iterative approaches leveraging new
data analytics tools to deal with the regulators’ concerns. Platforms, since they
mediate markets, generate both new types of market failures (around con-
sumer safety, privacy and fraud, for example) and unique ways of addressing
them (through data capture, analytics and governance). Professor Abbey
Stemler even suggests setting out policy objectives, such as ‘user feedback on
platforms must be authentic’ or ‘services, spaces, and assets offered must be
provided by legitimate and trustworthy users’ to ensure that relevant data
are gathered and analysed by platforms and governance iteratively updated
until these objectives are met and good long-term regulatory outcomes
secured.26

How should platforms deal with regulation and


regulators?
It may be tempting for platforms to ignore regulations, and the ‘ask for
forgiveness rather than ask for permission’ approach has been a guiding
principle for many start-ups. The inherent iterative approach of new innovative
firms trying to find a product/market fit is arguably not well suited to
traditional regulations. However, we would strongly advise platform firms to
engage with regulators, government officials and policymakers at the earliest
opportunity in order to explain the value they bring to the market and what
regulations hamper their development, if any. Frank and early engagement,
with a cogent articulation of their value proposition and economic contribu-
tion, would allow them to shape the debate. Without engagement, disrupted
companies, who often already have the right contacts within the media and
188 Platforms, regulation and competition

government, are able to control the narrative. Being able to communicate


and explain what the company does and its economic contribution, in terms
of jobs, taxes generated and value added, is important for policymakers. It is
also worth articulating benefits that are often ignored because they are not
captured by traditional economic indicators such as gross domestic product.
These include time saved by platform participants and increased convenience
provided by the platform, enhanced choice and selection on the platform, as
well as lower cost of products.27
Simple case studies showing how the platform is used help regulators to
understand the benefits. For example, a traditional approach to planning
holidays often required numerous visits to a travel agent, significant research
to ensure that the destination will turn out as expected, that the hotel is
suitable, and the flights selected are the most convenient and cost-effective.
Using a platform such as TripAdvisor is easier, cheaper, less time-consuming,
offers more choice and minimizes the risk of disappointment through the
extensive use of real-time feedback on countries, hotels, restaurants and
flights. The articulation of these benefits should help frame the debate with
policymakers.
Platforms rely on both producers and users to market themselves. This co-
creation effort can extend to regulation aspects. Airbnb and Uber have
successfully encouraged their communities to engage with local authorities
to promote the benefits of their services.
Successful platforms should also provide regulators with data on their
activities in order to alleviate concerns. Existing regulations are often designed
for data-poor environments and therefore seek to enforce rules ex ante in
order to secure public policy objectives of reduced fraud, consumer protection,
etc. If platforms are able to demonstrate that they have both the means and
incentives to achieve the same objectives through their analytics, governance
rules and trust frameworks, this will significantly alleviate many regulatory
concerns.
Finally, platforms may be able to engage with policymakers to change and
improve regulations. When current regulations impede innovative practices,
it may be helpful to return to the original public policy objective that under-
pins these regulations. The very innovations that platforms bring to the
market could quite possibly be used to efficiently solve public policy concerns
that led to the need for regulation in the first place. By focusing on market
outcomes – rather than simply compliance and legacy regulations – regulators
may be able to harness the power of platforms in the pursuit of their public
policy objectives.
Government regulations for cars, when they were introduced in the 1910s,
stipulated that cars were not allowed to go faster than horse carts, at around
Platforms, regulation and competition 189

5 mph. This limit, which had been suggested by horse cart drivers, was not
very efficient. Incidentally, it also made it very difficult for cars not to stall.
In England, the law even required that the automobilist had to notify a village
constable of his arrival, so that officials could walk in front of the car waving
two red warning flags while the driver followed slowly behind. Road
regulations have moved on quite a bit since then. For platforms, however,
the regulatory challenges ahead are still very significant and, as with the early
days of cars, some regulations are likely to be more focused on the protection
of the status quo rather than aimed at improving the lives of consumers.

Notes
1 Such regulators typically exist in sectors where monopoly provision used to be the norm
before a transition towards a more competitive market structure was decided as part of
a liberalization programme, such as in telecoms, energy, water, transport, post, etc.
2 We note that some renowned economists, such as George Stigler, have argued that
regulators could be ‘captured’ by market participants and that regulation may in some
cases lead to a worse outcome than market failures. There is, however, a broad consensus
around the importance of regulation to deal with market failures.
3 Note that this is a significant departure from many traditional models driven by ‘scarcity’.
The more a traditional company sells its products, the less stock it has, and it needs to
spend money to manufacture new products, often at a significant marginal cost, while
with many platforms the more their services are used (often with a marginal cost close
to zero), the more valuable they become.
4 Temporary promotions resulting in some products being sold below costs are of course
possible, but cannot be systematic and across all product categories, since this would
generate cumulative losses, preventing the firm from being sustainable.
5 See Mr Y Aslam, Mr J Farrar and Others -V- Uber, UK Employment Tribunal, Case
Numbers: 2202551/2015, 28 October 2016, available at www.judiciary.gov.uk/
judgments/mr-y-aslam-mr-j-farrar-and-others-v-uber/.
6 ‘Uber Suspends UberPOP in France Following Turmoils and Arrests’, TechCrunch,
3 July 2015, http://techcrunch.com/2015/07/03/uber-stops-uberpop-in-france-
following-turmoils-and-arrests/.
7 ‘Tourist-Heavy Barcelona is Cracking Down on Airbnb’, Atlantic Citylab, 25 December
2015, www.citylab.com/housing/2015/12/barcelona-airbnb-tourism/421788/
8 ‘Here’s Everywhere Uber Is Banned Around the World’, April 2015, www.business
insider.com/heres-everywhere-uber-is-banned-around-the-world-2015-4?IR=T.
9 See Competition and Markets Authority response to Transport for London’s private hire
regulations proposals: www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_
data/file/481450/CMA_response_to_TfL.pdf.
10 This chart shows how Uber is devastating New York’s taxi business: www.goldman
sachs.com/our-thinking/pages/2015-10-favorite-charts.html.
11 See Zaw Thiha Tun, ‘Top Cities Where Airbnb Is Legal or Illegal’, Investopedia, updated
30 October 2015, www.investopedia.com/articles/investing/083115/top-cities-where-
airbnb-legal-or-illegal.asp.
190 Platforms, regulation and competition

12 See insightful piece from Richard Feasey, ‘Compliance Is for Winners’, Remarks at
Cullen BITS Seminar on Platforms, Brussels, 16 July 2015, www.fronfraithltd.com/
home/articles.
13 With a market capitalization of $529 billion as of 11 September 2016, just behind
Apple.
14 We note that Google’s search business is not always seen as a pure platform, since
advertisers, rather than users, are the main source of revenues. We consider that Google
directly connects information producers and information consumers. Irrespective of
the approach used for the search market, Google is undeniably an ecosystem combin-
ing different business models, including some with clear platform characteristics (such
as its app store and operating system).
15 See Measuring Bias in ‘Organic’ Web Search, by Benjamin Edelman and Benjamin
Lockwood from HBS: www.benedelman.org/searchbias/.
16 B. Edelman, Leveraging Market Power Through Tying and Bundling: Does Google Behave
Anti-Competitively?, self-published, 2014, for a discussion of potential tying and bundling
issues within Google’s ecosystem, www.benedelman.org/publications/google-tying-
2014-05-12.pdf.
17 See, for example, the European Commission’s 2009 Guidance Paper proposing the
following test: ‘If the incremental price that customers pay for each of the dominant
undertakings products in the bundle remains above the LRAIC of the dominant firm
from including this product in the bundle, the Commission will normally not intervene
since an equally efficient competitor with only one product should in principle be able
to compete profitably against the bundle.’ December 2008, OJ C45/7,§60.
18 The power of Google, Serving consumers or threatening competition? Hearing before
the Sub Committee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights of the Sub
Committee on the Judiciary, 112th cong. 247 (2011). Submission of Jeremy Stoppelman,
cofounder and CEO of Yelp! Inc and quoted by H. Shelanski, ‘Information, Innovation,
and Competition Policy for the Internet’, University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 161,
2013, 1664–705.
19 B. Edelman, Leveraging Market Power Through Tying and Bundling: Does Google Behave
Anti-Compettively?, self published, 2014, identified eight different families of products
and services that Google is linking to one another.
20 Including the 24,500 patents acquired as part of the Motorola Mobility acquisition in
May 2012.
21 The binding settlement (‘consent decree’) signed by Google and the FTC in February
2013 states that: ‘Google has agreed to remove restrictions on the use of its online search
advertising platform, AdWords, that may make it more difficult for advertisers to
coordinate online advertising campaigns across multiple platforms. [This decision was
taken] following concerns from some FTC Commissioners that Google’s contractual
conditions governing the use of its API made it more difficult for an advertiser to
simultaneously manage a campaign on AdWords and on competing ad platforms.’
22 See: Commission obtains from Google comparable display of specialized search rivals,
EU Memo/14/87, 5th February 2014.
23 Google Ventures invested $258 million in Uber’s August 2013 round. See http://
techcrunch.com/2013/08/22/google-ventures-puts-258m-into-uber-its-largest-deal-
ever/.
Platforms, regulation and competition 191

24 See https://uk.finance.yahoo.com/news/smartphone-suit-against-google-plays-101909548.
html, 18 July 2014.
25 White Paper: Regulation, the Internet Way: A Data-First Model for Establishing Trust,
Safety, and Security, Nick Grossman, 8 April 2015.
26 See A. Stemler, ‘Regulation 2.0: The Marriage of New Governance and Lex Informatica’,
Kelley School of Business Research Paper No. 16-25, March 2016.
27 See, for example, ‘The Sharing Economy in the UK’, report commissioned by Airbnb,
Diane Coyle, 18 January 2016.
Chapter 14

Competing against platforms

We have seen how platforms are designed, ignited, scaled-up and defended
once mature, but what about traditional businesses facing increased
competition and disruptions from platform entrants?
How to deal with platform disruption is a question often asked by leaders
of large established organizations. Traditional responses of established players
to disruptive market entry often follow what we call the ‘5Ds’ process (deny,
deter, denigrate, delay and dollar!). Our experience, however, suggests that
enlightened leadership may benefit from considering an alternative ‘5Es’
pattern about engaging, enabling, enhancing, embracing and earning, to
maximize value creation in an increasingly platform-powered economy. This
is a significant shift in terms of mindset, and no one should underestimate
the difficulty of the journey.
With this in mind, we note that since some of the most successful businesses
out there are platform-powered ones, traditional firms may wish to leverage
some of their key assets to add platform capabilities where relevant. As we
saw previously, Apple is still generating more than 80% of all its revenues
through the sale of hardware, but one of the key reasons why its hardware
is so sought after is to be found in the strength of its overall app-based
ecosystem.
In many cases, established firms looking to add platform capabilities already
have a client base, which can constitute one side of a platform. Their priority
should be to develop the other side – by inviting third-party producers – and
enabling matching, connecting and transacting between the two sides. Starting
from scratch is much more difficult since both sides need to be attracted at
the same time. Traditional business models have strengths that pure platforms
are unable to replicate. Therefore, markets where these strengths are key to
success can remain relatively protected. Irrespective of the response to platform
disruption, one thing is certain: the cultural shift required by many established
players is significant. Denying markets are being disrupted or trying to
194 Competing against platforms

undermine the innovation process brought about by platform entrants is a


very risky long-term strategy indeed.

Traditional response to market disruption: ‘the 5Ds’


The pattern of responses from firms in disrupted industries is quite consistent
across geographies, sectors and even periods. Clearly some firms do behave
differently and exceptions can be found, but the default response of established
firms to disruptive entry usually follows some combination of the ‘5Ds’
sequence described below.1

Deny: The first response of established market participants is to ignore that


emerging competitors represent any form of threat. This is akin to the ‘ostrich
strategy’, where individuals and firms decide to ‘bury their heads in the sand’
and ignore bad news rather than deal with the new information and adapt
their strategy. In the words of Richard Tedlow, denial is ‘the unconscious
calculus that if an unpleasant reality were true, it would be too terrible, so
therefore it cannot be true’. Sigmund Freud described denial as the
combination of ‘knowing with not knowing’, while George Orwell called it
bluntly ‘protective stupidity’.2 This response does not only apply to platforms,
but change and disruption in general. For many years, firms such as Polaroid,
IBM and Blockbuster were in denial. Today, many established companies
challenged by platforms behave simply as if this was a temporary phenomenon
that will go away, as illustrated in Figure 14.1.

Denigrate: Trying to downplay – or even undermine – what competitors are


doing is a traditional reflex for established firms and industries that are being
disrupted. Living in London, we often use black cabs3 and sometimes indulge
in discussions with their drivers. While we are big fans of black cab drivers
and are always amazed at their unparalleled knowledge of London, their kind
demeanour changes abruptly when competition is mentioned. In fact,
mentioning Uber is an invitation to a diatribe about ‘uninsured drivers’, ‘often
without a driving licence’, ‘criminals that were not ID checked’, ‘not paying
a cent in tax’, etc. We would, of course, expect Uber and its drivers to be
in serious legal trouble if all these accusations were true. Yet creating the
doubt in the minds of potential customers by denigrating the platform-based
competition is still seen by many as a worthwhile approach, at least in the
short term.

Deter: When disruptive entrants can no longer be ignored and it is self-evident


that markets are under threat, then traditional firms conclude that something
Competing against platforms 195

Figure 14.1 Denial


Source: Cartoonresource/Shutterstock.com

drastic has to be done. A strong signal needs to be sent to the enemy, a credible
threat, or even in some cases a physical one, as in the case of French taxi
drivers turning on Uber drivers and their passengers. The ultimate objective
of deterrence is to make entry costly (and bias the risk/reward equation
underpinning the opportunity). This phase is usually associated with a strong
lobbying strategy in order to mobilize government agencies and policymakers
who can prevent disruptive entry through regulatory means. Public relations
campaigns are also often used during this stage to highlight the benefits of
the current market model and undermine the credibility of disruptors or
potential disruptors. From an economic perspective, the more protected the
incumbant business, the higher its incentives to invest in deterrence.

Delay: Delaying tactics are almost always used by established firms in order
to postpone disruption. In many cases, established firms operate within a broad
regulatory environment, and one of the most potent ways of delaying
disruptive entry is to use regulatory and legal arguments to prevent entrants
from being allowed to establish themselves. It is, however, important to also
highlight the fact that a number of global platforms may have been happy to
enter markets without first being fully compliant, and that testing legal
boundaries also comes at a price.
196 Competing against platforms

Dollar: Ultimately established companies often try to get some form of


compensation, to make up for what they would have earned had their markets
not been disrupted, through the courts, from the government or even from
consumers (through raised prices). An example is taxi companies asking for
their ‘medallions’ or ‘licence’ to be repurchased by the government at full
price.4 This is predicated upon the belief that their income should be
guaranteed by somebody and that they should not bear any economic risk.
It is understandable that a driver would feel cheated after buying a licence at
peak price – on the understanding that she is buying monopoly protection –
and subsequently finding out that there is in fact increasing competition in
the market. Going forward, it is therefore important for buyers of such
licences to factor in the risk of disruption and to negotiate prices accordingly.
Governments and regulators should also come clean about the fact that they
are unlikely to be able to shield drivers from more efficient and innovative
competitors forever. This stage can be particularly difficult since disrupted
firms try to be compensated at the time when their value proposition is
seriously undermined by disruptive new entrants.

New response to market disruption: ‘the 5Es’


We have observed the pattern of the ‘5Ds’ in a number of sectors and
geographies. While we understand the temptation to fight for the status quo,
we believe that relying on such strategies is unlikely to be optimal in the long
term. Usually, platform disruption means that key elements of the value
proposition can be provided in much more efficient and innovative ways.5
Ultimately, we propose a range of alternative approaches, some more
difficult to implement than others, but all focused on the root causes of the
problem rather than its symptoms.

Embracing market disruption and trying to understand the nature of the


business models and value propositions that are emerging is a far more valuable
activity than denial. It is the key to having a baseline for action. Dispassionate
insights into the nature of the threat being faced, as well as the existing
capabilities and assets that can be leveraged, is a first essential step for a strategic
response. It is key to a culture of experimentation, either directly, through
partnerships or investments. It is also about the ability of established firms
to read weak market signals and capture them in market development
scenarios against which they can test their generic strategies and the (preferably
unique) value they can bring to the market going forward. These ‘sensing’
and ‘seizing’ skills are key dynamic capabilities required to fully embrace new
opportunities.
Competing against platforms 197

Enabling clients and relevant market participants is often a way of carving out
a sustainable market position. Instead of trying to protect existing equilibria
and market structures at all costs, it may be more effective to engage with
disruptors – while still from a position of strength – in order to find ways to
deliver superior market value. Platforms are very unique businesses that face
serious challenges before they reach a critical mass, and existing firms can
therefore find partnership opportunities. Of course, fear of cannibalization
has to be dealt with, and a simple strategy of enablement without value capture
is unlikely to be sustainable. However, it is important to recognize how the
formidable strengths of existing players in terms of brands, distribution channels
and access to finance can be combined with innovative platform entrants to
offer superior products and services. When Reed Hastings, founder of Netflix,
a new start-up at the time, approached Blockbuster’s CEO in 2000 to discuss
a potential partnership, he was apparently ‘laughed out of the office’.6 A few
years later, Blockbuster filed for bankruptcy. Both firms could have probably
benefited from a deal at the time, though apparently Blockbuster more so
than Netflix. Now partnerships and ecosystem management may involve
application programming interfaces (APIs) that firms can develop to give access
to some of their capabilities.7

Enhancing capabilities and value propositions rather than simply investing


large sums in deterrence strategies is likely to pay better dividends in the long
term. As we have seen, above-average economic value is only fundamentally
created in one of three ways: (a) by being more innovative than competitors;
(b) by being more efficient than competitors; and (c) by being able to abuse
a position of market power. Since (c) is not legal in most jurisdictions, and
assuming that ultimately competition authorities will be efficient at enforcing
competition law, investments in efficiency and innovation capabilities are key
to profit generation.
In the case of taxis, it is pretty obvious that offering a real-time app with
location information and accepting credit cards instead of cash would be an
obvious commercial response to reduce the competitive gap between taxis
and Uber. Being even more welcoming, knowledgeable about their city and
friendly with clients would also further enhance their value proposition and
help differentiate them from alternatives. Yet despite a number of announce-
ments, there is little evidence that all taxis are embracing this view at the
moment.

Encouraging those who are a force for change internally – and externally – in
order to develop new organizational capabilities rather than support the status
quo will, in most cases, be more effective than simply delaying the entry of
198 Competing against platforms

competitors. Plenty of individuals and groups within traditional businesses


are well aware of the competitive threats and understand the potential
for disruption of these new platform business models. Often these people
even have ideas and projects to respond and compete effectively against new
entrants, but they struggle to get their voices heard. Unable to get the
attention of top management in order to harness the resources required to
implement their recommendations, they become disillusioned and resent-
ful towards those who try to maintain the status quo at all cost. The most
adventurous ones may even leave and provide valuable knowledge and
expertise to the very start-ups that are taking on their former employers.
These departures are significant losses for established firms, and further
reduce their ability to respond to the threats in a timely manner.

Earning their keep instead of asking for compensation is the best way for firms
to develop a sustainable long-term position. This doesn’t mean that disrupted
companies should not invest in a robust regulatory defence, but the ultimate
objective should be to support a winning business strategy delivering a relevant
value proposition to the market rather than prevent competition from altering
the status quo. Betting the ranch on long-term regulatory protection from
innovation and more efficient entrants is a risky gamble.

Some practical options to manage platform


disruptions
Arguably, the ‘5Ds’ and ‘5Es’ above are highly simplified and very generic
descriptions of possible responses to platform disruption. In some cases, the
two lists are not mutually exclusive. Mounting legal challenges in order to
‘delay’ the entry of some new disruptive competitor that may not comply
with local legislation could be a legitimate course of action for established
companies keen to buy time to adapt their business. But our experi-
ence suggests that established firms often waste valuable time and resources
by going through their ‘Ds’ instead of strategically investing to address
the platform challenges ahead. With this in mind, we believe established
non-platform companies can deploy a range of strategies to deal with the
challenges of platform competition. Here are a few suggested areas:

Understand platform market dynamics


Benjamin Franklin once said that ‘an investment in knowledge pays the best
interest’. We agree with this maxim and believe that the single most danger-
ous pitfall for many established firms in the next decade would be a failure
Competing against platforms 199

to grasp the underlying economic models that are disrupting so many mar-
kets. The key to competing against platforms – or becoming one – is to
understand the way they operate and what it means for the industry and for
the business – both in terms of opportunities and threats. At a macro level,
industries characterized by relatively high transaction costs, asymmetry of
information and regulatory protection are now ripe for disruption by inno-
vative digital entrants. In many cases, these entrants have proven that customers
can be more efficiently served and transactions better coordinated through a
platform business model. Even if parts of an industry are not directly impacted
(for example, car production), the firms operating in this industry may see
that platforms are disrupting their market (for example, by undermining
car ownership and therefore depressing demand). Some traditional platforms,
such as lenders, estate agents or recruiters, also need to realize the threat for
them not to embrace a digital platform strategy. They operate in markets that
are particularly open to disruptive entry and cannot afford to rely on legacy
management systems, technology and processes.

If not a leader . . . develop real ‘fast follower’ capabilities


Innovation may be a rewarding game, but it is also a very difficult one, and
there is increasing evidence suggesting larger organization are finding it more
difficult to innovate.8 But not being the first out of the starting blocks doesn’t
mean that the race is lost. In fact, established companies often have valuable
assets and capabilities that can help new ideas scale faster. This opens a
strategic option sometimes called ‘fast follower’ that is predicated upon the
ability to scale an idea rather than come up with it. In the words of Reid
Hoffman, being the ‘first to scale’ rather than the first to launch a product is
now the name of the game.9 Many traditional firms talk about being ‘fast
followers’, and while this a laudable strategy (rooted in solid research),10 it
only works if the company focuses on developing the capabilities to be able
to identify market niches and business innovations, and quickly scale their
new value proposition. Such a fast follower strategy relies on a superior ability
to identify and seize opportunities before scaling them. This in turn requires
investments in dynamic capabilities, described below.

Develop dynamic capabilities to see, seize and harness


opportunities
It is worth noting that while traditional firms often develop ‘ordinary’
capabilities and focus on efficiency improvements, firms embracing platform-
200 Competing against platforms

powered business models tend to master higher-level capabilities, enabling


them to better ‘orchestrate’ resources, within and outside the firm. In fact,
harnessing the power of communities, such as users and producers, while
managing complementary business models as part of a platform-powered
ecosystem, requires strong ‘dynamic capabilities’. Using David Teece’s
framework, it can be said that the advent of platform firms makes the need
for dynamic capabilities more salient. Platform firms need the sensing skills
required to spot market changes, the seizing skills required to address new
opportunities and the transforming skills needed to ensure the overall
organization, and its ecosystem, remain relevant. We note that while it is
difficult to attribute precisely to what extent a given firm may display these
capabilities, all the platform-powered ecosystem companies in our case
studies have displayed inordinate sensing, seizing and transforming skills to
get where they are today. These skills are at the heart of the dynamic
capabilities framework.11

Develop your own platform-powered ecosystem


As we have seen, a platform-powered ecosystem is made up of a combination
of business models and has been an extremely successful organizational form
for companies such as Apple, Google, Microsoft, Facebook and Amazon.
Without necessarily trying to emulate the scale of these giants, it is possible
to introduce platform capabilities to an existing business model in order
to benefit from its characteristics. Ideally, this needs to be done on the back
of a strategic review of the markets the firms operate in, and based on the
identification of market niches where platform characteristics (e.g. long tail,
community involvement, etc.) are highly valued. The permutations and
synergies between existing business models and platforms can then be assessed
in light of these opportunities and experiments launched to validate the proof
of concept. Online retailer Zalando12 decided to proactively open its traditional
retail model further to create a fashion ecosystem. Today, shoppers can already
be matched with fashion stylists with Zalon, Zalando’s curated shopping
service, but Zalando’s co-founder Robert Gentz’s vision for the future is to
go far beyond: ‘to connect every stakeholder in the fashion world: retailers,
stationary stores, advertising agencies, logistic services, app developers and
many more’.13
It may also pay off to partner with – or invest in – young platforms before
they scale in order to benefit from their expertise while helping them to realize
their true potential. Established firms may not be as nimble as new entrants,
but they often benefit from valuable assets and capabilities that can be har-
nessed in the context of a competitive response. The recent acquisition
Competing against platforms 201

of Onefinestay – a UK-headquartered premium start-up offering access to


luxury accommodations in London, Los Angeles, New York City, Paris and
Rome – by the Accor Group can be seen in that light. Accor’s CEO Sébastien
Bazin told its investors they had missed an early opportunity to invest in
Airbnb, that Accor would have needed between two and three years to
develop a competing offer, and that it would have been a ‘terrible idea’ for
the group to do this internally.14 Accor Group will help Onefinestay scale its
offering to 40 new cities within the next five years. While details on how
Accor may provide access to its client base and loyalty reward programme
have not yet been announced, joint collaboration on these would be a
logical next step for the group. Accor also announced that it would open its
online booking service to independent hotels in order to counter the threat
of increasingly powerful holiday booking platforms such as Expedia,
Priceline.com or Booking.com. These initiatives may well help Accor become
a fully fledged platform-powered ecosystem.

Make sure incentives don’t get in the way


In some cases, the reward and incentive structure of top management doesn’t
help with decision-making in light of significant disruption. As a senior
executive of a large established business that is starting to be disrupted by
platform-powered entrants, would you rather:

(a) tell your board that all is fine – as your stock options vest quietly over
the next two years; carry on managing the existing business on a quarterly
basis and execute the current strategy – agreed by all – before moving on
to your next role/retiring; or
(b) go to your board and explain that the current strategy is under threat,
that the very basis of competition in your industry is changing, that you
need to reorganize globally and that this will be hard and risky work and
that dividends may need to be lowered over the next few years so that
you can invest to transform the business?

The established organizations able to incentivize choice (b) over choice (a)
have a significantly better chance to successfully deal with the kind of
disruption brought about by platforms. Launching your own platform is likely
to bring new challenges, such as potential cannibalization of the traditional
model itself. A new reward and incentive system may also be needed. This
is of course linked to the transformational aspects of the dynamic capabilities
that firms need to build to be able to remain relevant.
202 Competing against platforms

Become an experienced platform user


Many of the efficiencies brought about by platforms can be captured simply
by using them. Identifying the assets, processes and resources that are historically
kept in-house but could be replaced by the use of disruptive platforms may
generate significant savings while providing insights into the workings of
platform businesses in general. Offices could be shared, temporary expertise
could be hired, and new, efficient and cost-effective suppliers could be identi-
fied in ways that bypass and supplement traditional and (often cumbersome)
in-house processes. Traditional firms may still need to keep many activities ‘in-
house’ and tightly integrated – as they are at the heart of the unique value
proposition that is offered – but the use of platforms in a client capacity can
unlock significant value where the firm has no particular competitive advantage
– or arguably is at a competitive disadvantage. For example, crowdsourcing ideas
by using platforms such as Crowdicity or InnoCentive is an easy way for large
established firms to tap into a global and diverse network of innovators.

Analyse platform disruption holistically and focus on


‘non-Uberizable’ markets
Some businesses are unlikely to be directly impacted by platform models. This
is especially the case where end-to-end control of the value chain is a criti-
cal element of the production process. For example, a platform business is
unlikely to be optimal for the mass manufacturing of cars. The coordination
of the various production stages needs to be tightly controlled, and while car
manufacturers increasingly need to manage a complex ecosystem of suppliers
and technology, their core business model remains linear.
But does that mean new platform businesses are irrelevant in this industry
and will not have any impact on car companies? Of course not. The rise of
platforms enabling the sharing economy movement – both in terms of renting
other people’s cars or sharing rides with them – will no doubt have a profound
impact on future demand for cars. Some observers are predicting a future
where personal car ownership becomes a distant memory and an economic
aberration. Recent moves by General Motors (who invested $500 million in
Uber’s competitor Lyft and is forging strategic alliances with other platforms)
suggest that some companies are taking notice and trying to secure orders
from companies that will be tomorrow’s customers. Lyft is unlikely to become
a car manufacturer and compete against GM, yet it is one of the companies
disrupting the transportation market, which will definitely have an effect on
demand for cars. These ‘second order’ effects can be missed if the assessment
of possible platform disruption is too narrowly focused on the emergence of
direct competitors.
Competing against platforms 203

But while platforms are formidable business models in many respects, they
fail to deliver on a range of fronts. Many activities require tight control over
the value chain to ensure high quality and consistency, and platforms are not
good at enabling this. By focusing on markets where these characteristics are
prominent, it is possible to strengthen a competitive position that a platform
would struggle to undermine. It still leaves the business open to traditional
competitors, but at least fundamental disruption can be avoided. Some large
groups have just started to review their portfolio of activities in this light and
to consider disposing of assets in markets likely to be disrupted while
reinvesting in businesses less exposed to platform disruption.

Notes
1 We note a loose parallel between the organizational 5Ds we are using to describe firms’
responses to disruption and the Kubler-Ross model of grief that suggests a very personal
pattern starting with denial, anger, bargaining, depression and acceptance.
2 Richard S. Tedlow, Denial: Why Business Leaders Fail to Look Facts in the Face – and What
to Do About It, New York: Penguin Portfolio, 2010.
3 Black cabs in London are a good example of strong established market participants
who, while being among the best in the world in terms of market knowledge, security
and efficiency, are fighting hard to keep new entrants at bay. Their approach very
much matches the 5Ds described above, while we believe they would be a formidable
force if they were to embrace the 5Es instead.
4 It is worth noting that in France, taxi licences are given for free by the government but
subsequently traded by taxi drivers and taxi companies for substantial sums.
5 We agree with Peter Thiel when he says that markets where companies are able to gain
market power based on their innovations are a lot more attractive than markets where
undifferentiated companies compete on low margins to survive. See Peter Thiel,
‘Competition Is for Losers’, Wall Street Journal, 12 September 2014 (based on Zero to
One: Notes on Startups, or How to Build the Future).
6 Source: CNET, 9 December 2010, Greg Sandoval. https://www.cnet.com/uk/news/
blockbuster-laughed-out-at-netflix-partnership-offer/
7 Recent research by Seth Benzell, Guillermo Lagarda and Marshall Van Allstyne from Boston
University and MIT (12 July 2016) seems to suggest that firms adopting APIs become more
profitable than those who don’t. See http://questromworld.bu.edu/platformstrategy/
files/2016/07/S4-Seth-Benzell-Guillermo-Lagarda-role-apis-economy-7-12.pdf.
8 M. Wessel, ‘Why Big Companies Can’t Innovate’, Harvard Business Review, September
2012, https://hbr.org/2012/09/why-big-companies-cant-innovate.
9 See, for example, Wired article by Cade Metz dated 14 September 2015 titled ‘Silicon
Valley Success Goes to the Fastest, Not the First’.
10 P. Geroski and C. Markides, Fast Second: How Smart Companies Bypass Radical Innovation
to Enter and Dominate New Markets, San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass, 2005.
11 David Teece, ‘The Foundations of Enterprise Performance: Dynamic and Ordinary
Capabilities in an (Economic) Theory of Firms’, Academy of Management Perspectives, 8(4),
2014, 328–52.
204 Competing against platforms

12 Zalando generated €3.6 billion in 2016, with a growth rate of 23%, 17 January 2017,
Zalando’s corporate website.
13 ‘How Zalando Is Becoming the Online Fashion Platform for Europe’, 1 June 2016,
https://blog.zalando.com/en/blog/how-zalando-becoming-online-fashion-platform-
europe.
14 Murad Ahmed and Adam Thomson, ‘Accor to Acquire Online Home Rental Site
Onefinestay’, Financial Times, 5 April 2016.
Chapter 15

The future of platforms

As we have seen, platform-based business models are having a profound impact


on the business world. In the words of Ray Fisman and Tim Sullivan, in
their insightful book The Inner Lives of Markets:

Not even the market designers themselves have all the answers: economics
is an inexact science, and every time we participate in a market innovation
– each time we hail a ride via a smartphone or download a song via iTunes
– we’re part of a massive social experiment whose ultimate consequences
are unknown.

While, like them, we remain optimistic and see the potential for good, we
are acutely aware that the long-term consequences of the current platform
revolution are unclear. Society will need to apply judgement and common
sense to ensure that the potential negative side effects of these innovative
business models are minimized. Platforms are likely to change the way people
work, are managed, get paid, share and collaborate, interact with others –
humans and ‘robots’ – generate insights from data, and organize themselves
to deal with world issues. We discuss these changes in turn in this final chapter.

The future of work


The way people work and interact with one another in an increasingly
platform-based economy will be vastly different from the traditional work
relationships of the past. In fact, a recent study1 of all drivers of change affecting
our economies by the World Economic Forum singles out ‘the changing
nature of work and talent platforms’ as the most important trend.2
Platforms provide a unique degree of flexibility, transparency and trust to
their participants. They organize markets that would have otherwise been
very difficult for individuals to participate in. Being able to work specific time
206 The future of platforms

shifts around one’s own life constraints (picking up kids from school, looking
after elderly relatives, etc.) can in some cases make the difference between
being able to work and having to stay at home, possibly relying on state
benefits. While some will no doubt see this flexibility as another form of
alienation,3 we can’t help but see it as an opportunity to unlock job creation
and economic growth. And we’re not alone. A recent McKinsey report
on talent platforms4 suggests that $2.7 trillion of value could be created by
talent platforms alone by 2025. This is equivalent to the GDP of the UK.
That amount could be generated simply by increasing labour force parti-
cipation for existing workers, reducing unemployment through better job
matching and raising productivity through better coordination of work
through platforms. In fact, the countries currently struggling with the most
inefficient labour markets are the ones that would benefit the most from the
development of talent platforms.5 Upwork now has more than 12 million
freelancers globally who can help with coding duties, graphic design, financial
planning, etc. and over 10,000 sign-ups every day.
Firms can tap into these platforms in order to supplement their own
capabilities or develop their own internal platforms to flexibly secure the skills
and capabilities they need. Eden McCallum, a successful management
consulting firm headquartered in the UK, uses a hybrid model of full-time
analysts and partners supplemented by hundreds of part-time consultants who
are members of its platform. Launchworks, our own advisory business, uses
some of the same principles to develop its global network of platform experts.
And this is just the beginning. Existing platforms are still very much version
1.0 of talent platforms. While existing models focus on connecting companies
with individual contributors, new generations of platforms will allow entire
teams to coordinate projects and offer turnkey solutions. HoneyBook, for
example, is a platform connecting event managers, creative professionals and
clients. It provides tools to coordinate a team of producers (caterers, photo-
graphs, venue rental, make-up, event planning, etc.) to manage events
throughout their entire life cycle, from the proposal to invoicing stages.
However, the transition from a traditional labour market to a platform-
powered one is unlikely to go smoothly for all. As the physical location of
platform workers is increasingly irrelevant for some jobs, the cost of work
can be driven down significantly. This has been happening for years in the
manufacturing sector, with China becoming the world’s factory. Platforms
are now enabling this for services. Entire businesses now rely on externalized
flexible workforces for a range of activities. Amazon’s Mechanical Turk,6 for
example, provides ‘businesses and developers access to an on-demand scalable
workforce’, while ‘workers can select from thousands of tasks and work
whenever it’s convenient’. Tasks are called HITs (human intelligence tasks)
The future of platforms 207

and can be posted – and carried out – by anybody. Testing features of a web-
site, transcribing a recording, tagging content of pictures, answering questions
of a survey, and moderating content of a blog are some of the hundred of
thousands of tasks posted on the site at any point in time. In fact, some
companies outsource entire processes, such as the 24/7 monitoring of com-
ments on a blog or the tagging of images before their publication, to the
Mechanical Turk. Since these tasks can be carried out globally, unless a specific
expertise is required, such as language or coding skills, the pricing is quite
low by US or European standards. This means that many ‘low-level’ tasks
can now be efficiently and flexibly outsourced to a platform, and that therefore
‘high-cost’ workers are increasingly unlikely to be able to compete for these
activities. You don’t need to have offices everywhere to arbitrage labour
market rates anymore. Knowledge workers are now a click away, and this is
understandably one aspect of globalization that is increasingly worrying
employees and governments.

The future of management


Platform companies will change the way we work, and leading these new
organizations successfully will require very different management skills. As
we have seen, platform business models, and their cousins, platform-powered
ecosystems, have unique organizational models. All the key management
disciplines, as taught in business school and learned on the job, are impacted
by these changes. We have, for example, observed a number of differences
in areas such as strategy development, organizational design, finance and talent
management. We also believe that these differences will increase, as many
platforms that started off using the same tools as traditional firms are now
adapting these management principles to the new challenges they are facing.
Many of these approaches are new and therefore still in a state of flux, but
we highlight some of the patterns we see emerging.
We see the yearly strategic planning process of traditional firms superseded
by more organic and iterative models where portfolios of experiments and
hypothesis have to be tested over a short time frame before the strategy is
reviewed in light of new available data.
In terms of organizational design, while many platforms started off with
traditional hierarchical structures, we have witnessed an increasing drive to
create communication channels across business areas to avoid the silo mentality
and truly enable coordination across the various sides of the platforms. This
is important since having a structure where different sides of the platforms
are managed independently – with a distinct business unit leader in charge
of the performance of his ‘side’ – would almost always result in a suboptimal
208 The future of platforms

market outcome unless the CEO constantly arbitrates between ‘side owners’
in order to ensure that the platform is balanced. For example, rewarding the
head of one side of the business with additional resources based on his success,
something seen as natural in a traditional firm, may result in increased
imbalance on the platform and undermine its overall success. We are increas-
ingly seeing calls for more flexible organizational forms allowing iterative
resource allocation decisions between sides, depending upon which one is a
bottleneck for the growth of the platform at a given point in time. This
requires management able to internalize and orchestrate more holistic success
metrics. Platforms typically need employees and leaders who understand and
are able to harness dynamic network effects rather than staff who can optimize
static processes.
Financial management is also drastically different, with some platforms being
able to largely outsource some of the risks of trading physical stocks and
associated cash flow requirements onto platform participants. That’s why
marketplaces such as eBay or Alibaba have been able to scale-up quickly with
a huge inventory without incurring these costs. Alternatively, platforms are
able to reduce risk through data analytics to more effectively deploy their
own capital. Deliveroo, the restaurant delivery marketplace, knows so much
about areas lacking quality food, that it recently announced it would partner
with restaurants and invest in setting up dedicated kitchens – so-called
RooBoxes – in order to further stimulate the growth of the platform.
Lastly, platforms themselves increasingly require specific talents. The
necessity to manage an ecosystem often requires technology-savvy individuals,
comfortable with ambiguity and fluid networks, to help design and grow the
platform. Generally, we see talents with advanced degrees and more inter-
national outlooks attracted to, and successful at, the kinds of challenges that
potentially global platforms throw up. Lastly, we see significant transferable
skills from one platform to another, even across industries, and we are starting
to see talents able to build on their experiences with ‘platform careers’
spanning multiple firms. Our own corporate and consulting experience at
Launchworks strongly points to the importance of having senior individuals
able to build and deploy cross-industry platform knowledge.

The platform-powered ‘sharing economy’


Platforms powering sharing economy activities will undoubtedly continue their
expansion. Today, they can be classified into five broad categories:

• The sharing of goods, from recirculation of second-hand goods (eBay or


Craiglist) to shared usage (Drivy and Turo for peer-to-peer car rentals,
The future of platforms 209

BlaBlaCar for car-sharing trips, Airbnb for home rentals, Love Home Swap
for home exchanges).
• Knowledge sharing, such as massive open online course (MOOC)
platforms connecting students all over the world with universities (edX,
FUN, Coursera).
• Money sharing, where projects can be financed through crowdfunding
or crowd-lending platforms (Kiva, Kickstarter, Lending Club).
• Time/service sharing, where people can share their time and expertise,
on an ad hoc or regular basis with others in need (Stootie, TaskRabbit,
Thumbtack).
• Content sharing, from music platforms connecting amateur artists and
listeners (SoundCloud) to user-generated content platforms (Reddit).

Many of the platforms that we have talked about in this book are for-profit
private companies, often backed by sizeable VC investments. Their business
model is designed to maximize the value that they can capture and reward their
shareholders accordingly. When successful, platforms can indeed return very
significant sums to their backers, as early shareholders of the GAFAMs (Google,
Apple, Facebook, Amazon and Microsoft) will testify. Even when platform
participants are not allowed to make a profit themselves,7 the platform owner
can generate significant profits as a result of the service provided. While this
has enabled the development of successful large-scale transformative platform
companies, bringing much-needed efficiency to numerous markets, many now
believe that the promise of platforms powering the ‘sharing economy’ is flawed.
The initial dream of green ‘co-creation’ and ‘co-consumption’ enabled by
platforms and shared by many early platform enthusiasts seems to have been
replaced by a platform-powered capitalist market economy more able to extract
value from both its workers and its assets.
The arguments that have been raised against such platforms include:8 (i)
they are for-profit and therefore concentrate rather than redistribute wealth;
(ii) they aim at becoming dominant and driving out other market participants;
(iii) they are not really green as they stimulate consumption; (iv) they replicate
discrimination biases rather than solve them; (v) they exploit labour by
breaking/circumventing existing laws; (vi) they shift the risk of production
from the company to the participants; and (vii) they are managed privately
top-down rather than by their participants bottom-up.
Many of these arguments are not without merit, and privately owned
platforms do indeed seem to accumulate wealth for their shareholders – like
most successful businesses. Platforms also reflect some discriminatory biases
already present in society. Everything else being equal, a study showed that
210 The future of platforms

African-American hosts on average charge 12% less renting their homes on


Airbnb than white hosts.9 When platforms stimulate consumption (e.g. make
people travel more because Airbnb is cheaper than alternatives), they increase
the carbon footprint rather than lower it.
In many ways, platforms still reflect many of the issues affecting our society,
but the question is whether or not platforms can demonstrate that they
have a positive impact overall. Since platforms have both positive and negative
impacts, the question is really about the net effect of the disruption. On one
side of the argument, many established providers and associated jobs are at
risk, but on the other end, like other innovations, platforms create jobs and
result in lower prices, increased convenience and greater choice for millions
of users. And that’s probably why the views on platforms are so polarized;
some stakeholders are negatively impacted while others are winning out.
The increased productivity brought about by platforms – and other
innovative companies – may magnify some imbalances in our economies and
require government intervention. For example, the prospect of having to deal
with increased levels of unemployment is leading many policymakers and
economists – of all persuasions – to call for an unconditional basic income to
be put in place.10
Platforms themselves may be able to adopt more collective governance
models, such as modern forms of ‘cooperatives’. While the concept of sharing
value between contributing members is appealing, cooperatives may find it
more difficult to raise funds (since shares are often fixed at their nominal value)
and to reward stakeholders with different motivations. This makes it more
difficult for these models to scale.
We are also likely to see the emergence of hybrid models where the platform
is co-owned by the communities using it. Some platforms have toyed with
such models in the past and Reddit went as far as to announce its intention
of sharing 10% of new equity with members when raising $50 million in
September 2014.11 However, the lack of regulatory clarity, combined with
the legal and tax issues associated with shared ownership, have hampered
progress for the time being.
Given that these issues affect so many countries, we believe that govern-
ments and lawmakers have a significant role to play in shaping platform friendly
policies. This could enable the emergence of more flexible platform-based
organizations, where value and equity are shared in a simple and effective
way with their contributing participants and the wider ecosystem.
A few sharing economy platforms have recently taken a stance to address
the profit conundrum. Benefit Corporations include Etsy, Juno, and Kick-
starter, which reincorporated as a benefit corporation in 2015.12 Kickstarter’s
mission is driven first by how well they bring creative projects to life before
The future of platforms 211

the size of their profits. Kickstarter measures project success rates (typically
only 9% of projects fail to deliver results)13 as a key driver of added value.
It is also very possible that more open, decentralized platforms, with shared
governance models, as advocated by many within the sharing economy
movement, are able to scale and offer successful alternatives not controlled by
large corporations. Sites such as OpenBazaar, while in their infancy at the time
of writing, are proposing totally open, not-for-profit, peer-to-peer platform
functionalities to buy and sell a wide range of goods and services. Underground
platforms that have existed on the Dark Web for years, such as Silk Road, have
also shown that organic bottom-up platform models could succeed (and even
reach a critical mass of buyers and sellers of illegal goods and services!).

Platforms will increasingly power complex


ecosystems
Traditional business models have significant strengths that platforms are finding
difficult to match (and vice versa). Firms such as Amazon that have managed
to combine both business models have been able to create incredibly powerful
companies. We believe this trend will carry on, and that while many markets
will be successfully served – and disrupted – by pure platforms, the number
of firms effectively combining traditional and new business models will
increase. Firms will increasingly look at parts of their value creation processes
that could be replaced or supplemented by platform models (or new entrants
will show them). Many firms will then try to introduce these capabilities to
their operations while pure platforms will also develop non-platform business
models. Large retailers (including ‘digital ones’ such as Zalando) are now
realizing that being online is not enough and are looking at ways to supplement
their e-commerce operations with platform models. Hotel chains such as Accor
are adding new platform capabilities. Car manufacturers have started making
partnerships with ride-sharing companies. The answer of established firms is
still a bit chaotic, but the direction of travel is clear.

Platform of things

Automation
Platform ecosystems will increasingly include automated ‘sides’. If the future
that GM is preparing for materializes soon, we will have the option to hail
(or pre-book) a self-driving car from an app in just a few years’ time.14 This
is not as far-fetched as many people think, and since the disruptive entry of
Tesla, Uber and Google in the race for self-driving capabilities, the pressure
212 The future of platforms

has been mounting for traditional car manufacturers to get their act together.
It is relatively easy to imagine a platform model where one side is entirely
automated. There may still be a market for hand-driven rides (like handmade
suits) for many years to come, but self-driving cars certainly have the potential
to replace cab – and truck – drivers within a generation. In fact, parts of
platform business models are likely to become automated in the near future.
Home automation is now around the corner with a range of controllable
devices, from thermostat to audiovisual equipment, representing entry points
for companies keen on developing their ecosystems. Google acquired Nest
and Dropcam to extend the reach of its platform-powered ecosystem into
the home; Amazon has its innovative, always-on Alexa speaker; Microsoft is
trying to leverage the role of its Xbox and Windows 10, etc. Many of the
connected devices that will appear over the next few years will be able to
interact with various apps within, or even across, different platform-powered
ecosystems. The development of cross-platform IoT enabling Web services
such as If This Then That (IFTTT.com) or Yonomi – which allow users to
connect and control devices from different manufacturers – is testimony
to the growth potential of these applications.

Technology underpinning platform businesses is improving


everyday
Current platform business models are powered by technologies such as
relational databases, instant Internet-based communications and matching
algorithms. To start with, all of these technologies benefit from regular
hardware performance improvements.15
But more fundamental innovations in these areas, such as blockchains, which
are effectively distributed ledgers, also contribute to the development of key
building blocks able to further unlock the potential of platforms as business
models. By lowering the friction for securely registering time-stamped
transactions, blockchain technology can provide a global, scalable, low-cost
registrar for contracts and commitments between platform agents. This has
the potential to strengthen and broaden platforms’ transaction capabilities
globally.
The Internet provides connectivity, with quasi ubiquitous coverage, and
enabling platform business models in an increasing number of countries.
Emerging platforms of things even have dedicated operators such as Sigfox
vying for their attention.
Other software building blocks, such as matching algorithm – increasingly
powered by artificial intelligence models – and instant messaging solutions
are also evolving at an unprecedented pace, and enabling increasingly efficient
The future of platforms 213

and frictionless matching and connection of platform participants. Analytics and


big data provide unique ways of monitoring platforms in real time and opti-
mizing their architecture.
In fact, the availability of core software-powering platforms – often through
the software as a service model (SaaS) – is now making basic technical
development of a platform proposition very easy.16

Platforms to save the world


Lastly, we think platforms also have the potential to help us deal with some
of the global issues of our time, including inequalities, diseases, food and water
supply, and global warming. Governments have shown the limits of existing
domestic bureaucratic systems in dealing with many of these global challenges.
Non-governmental organizations have sought to fill this void with some
success, but the overall system remains woefully inadequate in light of the
challenges we face. The allocation of money and resources is often very
inefficient, their matching inadequate, and the connection between those who
can help and those who need help is often heavily mediated if not simply
absent from the altruistic process.
The best progress made in recent years may well have been achieved by
rich philanthropists who decided to apply business thinking to the world’s
largest problems. These donors are prepared to give vast sums of money.
However, they need to know that their capital is efficiently deployed accord-
ing to clear strategic objectives, with projects carefully selected, tracked
and closely monitored on the ground. Yet even the most sophisticated and
advanced programs, such as the ones run by the Bill and Melinda Gates
Foundation, recognize that there is much to do and that even good
management techniques and technology may not be sufficient.
There is still a huge imbalance between the issues that cause the most
suffering in the world and the ones that attract money because they are popular
with donors. In a recent ‘Ask Me Anything’ online session on well-known
social platform Reddit, Bill Gates’s answer to a question about what is yet to
be done was the following:

So far we have not been able to use technology to connect people to the
needs of the poorest in countries that are [too] far away to tap into their
empathy. I think this can be done but it needs some missing creativity.

Jeremy Rifkin also describes how important an emphatic civilization is


going to be to solve the world’s problems.17 Platforms have many of the
characteristics required to help with the issues mentioned above. It should be
214 The future of platforms

possible to find ways to create this empathic connection that Jeremy Rifkin
is so keen on. For example, an app – maybe a role-playing game – where
the character being played is randomly generated – using real-world statistics
– and has to overcome real-life challenges could help with this. Once the
character ‘dies’ in the virtual world, the money generated by the game (either
directly or through sponsorship) gets paid to the most relevant charity for
that particular cause of death. This simple example would provide a platform
business model with gamers on one side and charities on the other side, and
the money allocated would go to these while creating a strong empathic
experience between the virtual character and the player.
In fact, we believe such models are so worth exploring that we decided
that we would dedicate all the royalties generated by this book to support
such non-profit platform projects. There is no reason the power of commu-
nities that underpins the private platform businesses discussed in this book
cannot be replicated to deal with some of the world’s greatest challenges.
After all, everybody needs a platform strategy . . . what is yours?

Notes
1 World Economic Forum, Future of Jobs report, January 2016.
2 WEF Future of Jobs report, January 2016. With 44% of respondents, mainly human
resources representatives from organizations representing more than 13 million employees
in total, the topic of the changing nature of work was far ahead of all other strategic
considerations, including growth of the mobile Internet and cloud technologies (with
34%) or increased processing power and big data (with 26%).
3 For a full Marxist analysis of these developments, see Nick Dyer-Witheford, Cyber-
Proletariat: Global Labour in the Digital Vortex, 15 May 2015, or Ursula Huws, Labor in
the Global Digital Economy: The Cybertariat Comes of Age, 10 December 2014.
4 A Labor Market That Works: Connecting Talent with Opportunity in the Digital Age,
McKinsey Global Institute, June 2015.
5 The McKinsey report mentions that Spain, Greece, Portugal, Italy and France would
benefit the most in Europe, while South Africa, Colombia, the Philippines, Egypt and
Russia would be the emerging economies benefiting the most. The US would also benefit
significantly through increased participation and faster matching of jobs.
6 See www.mturk.com/mturk/welcome.
7 Such as in the case of BlaBlaCar where only a contribution to the costs of driving from
A to B can be levied by the driver, or charity-enabling platforms such as JustGiving that
connect givers and good causes.
8 See, for example, Juliet Schor, ‘Debating the Sharing Economy’, October 2014, for a
good summary of the debate: www.greattransition.org/publication/debating-the-sharing-
economy#sthash.wjx6WQ6c.dpuf.
9 11 December 2015, CNN, http://money.cnn.com/2015/12/11/technology/airbnb-
bias-harvard/. It is worth noting that Airbnb has since implemented robust anti-
discrimination provisions that are aimed at improving this.
The future of platforms 215

10 See, for example, Bloomberg article dated 2 May 2016 on universal basic income:
www.bloombergview.com/articles/2016-05-02/a-basic-income-should-be-the-next-
big-thing.
11 www.theverge.com/2014/9/30/6874353/reddit-50-million-funding-give-users-10-
percent-stock-equity and www.reddit.com/r/AskReddit/comments/2moyiz/serious_
how_should_reddit_inc_distribute_a/.
12 21 September 2015, Kickstarter blog, www.kickstarter.com/blog/kickstarter-is-now-a-
benefit-corporation?ref=charter.
13 Kickstarter fulfilment report, www.kickstarter.com/fulfillment.
14 At the time of writing, the Singapore Autonomous Vehicle Initiative (SAVI) is running
live trials of autonomous cars.
15 Moore’s law states that computer processing power doubles every two years.
16 Sharetribe promises to have your platform business running in a few minutes without
the need for a developer . . . give it a go at www.sharetribe.com/.
17 J. Rifkin, The Empathic Civilization, New York: Jeremy P. Tarcher, 2010.
A word from the authors

We hope you enjoyed reading Platform Strategy and learned a thing or two
about platforms along the way.
Platform business models are changing many areas of our lives at an unpre-
cedented pace. When we started writing this book, very little had been written
about the practical principles of platform management. Now we see new
platform businesses being launched every day and, increasingly, established
businesses launching or acquiring their own platforms. We also come across
a range of useful studies, conferences, reports and books touching upon plat-
form strategy and related topics.
If you’re interested in keeping track of these developments you may want
to check the book’s companion web site: www.platformstrategy.co, where
you will find additional resources on how to design, ignite and scale your
own platform.
Also we are always interested in hearing about platforms so feel free to
drop us a line at benoit@platformstrategy.co and laure@platformstrategy.co.
Index

Accor Group 3, 201, 211 application programming interfaces


add-on platforms 77, 88–9, 92, 102, 105 see APIs
advertising 37, 43, 45, 67–8, 93, 97, Ariba 96
99–100, 142, 144, 183 Artfire 143
AdWords (Google) 67, 69, 183, 184 attract 6, 15, 24, 47, 167; ignition 75, 91–6;
Airbnb 1–2, 3, 4, 15, 24, 168, 188; brand maturity 75, 121–2, 131; pre-launch 74;
51–2, 153, 169–70; business model 45; scaling-up 75, 105, 107, 110–14, 117
credibility 158–9, 163; feedback 35, 52, audience builders 24
160, 179–80; insurance 164; market sizing AWS see Amazon Web Services
79; match 47, 52, 83; value propositions
83, 95, 123 balance 48, 50, 106, 111–12, 114, 117, 124,
Alibaba 1, 15, 28, 34, 123, 124, 132, 208 144–7, 150
Amazon 8, 12, 13, 14, 15, 125; business Bezos, J. 57, 58
model 48, 59, 63; conflict resolution 163; big bang launch strategy see event strategy
ecosystem 28, 57–8, 59–61, 62, 70; BlaBlaCar 7, 154, 157, 158, 159; insurance
feedback 35, 160; home automation 212 164; pricing strategies 147, 150, 156;
Amazon FBA (Fulfilment by Amazon) 58, scaling-up 112, 115
61–2 BorrowMyDoggy 99
Amazon Marketplace 26–7, 48, 57, 58, 59, bottlenecks 51, 73, 75–6, 86, 98, 99, 100,
60, 61–2, 84, 111 101, 108, 112, 116
Amazon Prime 58, 61, 62 bowling pin strategy 54, 95, 109
Amazon Web Services (AWS) 58 brand 14–15, 51, 76, 118, 153–70
analytics 50–1, 52, 110, 123, 162, 187, 208, bundling strategies 61, 131, 182
213; see also data capture business architecture 22, 66, 74, 80, 91
Android operating system (Google) 58, 67, business models 6–7, 11, 22, 27, 59, 62, 63,
185–6 68, 132; platform businesses 6–7, 11, 22,
anticompetitive behaviour 173, 182, 186 23, 27–8, 41–54, 70, 87, 138, 146, 177,
APIs (application programming interfaces) 199, 200, 212; traditional businesses 62,
52, 183, 197 73, 91, 193, 211
Apple 5, 8, 13, 14, 28, 193; App Store 32,
38, 63, 64–6; business model 54, 63, 66; card platforms 6, 23, 80, 126
ecosystem 63–6, 70, 132; iPhone 63, 65, catalyst businesses 23–4
123; iTunes 63, 65 Chesky, B. 1, 2, 169
218 Index

Choudary, S. 25 disintermediation 126, 147–8


communications platforms see Snapchat; dispute resolution see conflict resolution
WeChat; WhatsApp dollar strategy 196
communities 44–5, 51, 78, 94, 112, 118, dynamic capabilities 196, 199, 200, 201
125, 170
compensation strategy see dollar strategy eBay 4, 15, 22, 48, 49, 53–4; brand 169,
competing platforms 131, 140, 149 170; business model 21, 27; connect 4,
competition 22, 25, 121, 130–2, 140, 173, 85; feedback 159, 160; ignition 54;
193 network effects 33, 34; pricing strategies
competition authorities 122, 131, 173-5, 129, 140, 144, 146; scaling-up 108, 112,
186, 197 115, 208; value propositions 83, 112
complements 31, 38, 130, 131 economic value 4, 14, 197
conflict resolution 126, 163, 167 economies of scale 31, 32–33
connect 4, 45–6, 62; ignition 98; ecosystems 6, 13, 17, 26–8, 180–1, 186,
maturity 97; pre-launch 85; scaling-up 207, 211; Amazon 26–7, 57–8, 59–61,
115, 117 62, 70; Apple 63–6, 70, 132; Facebook
consistency 159–60, 203 28, 70; Google 66–7, 68–9, 70, 132,
contributions 78, 82-3, 94, 118 180–1, 185–6; Microsoft 70, 130, 132
control 52, 53, 123, 140–1, 162 enablers 51, 52, 87; ignition 101; maturity
core transactions 49, 52, 85–6, 98–101, 128; pre-launch 87; scaling-up 118
125, 168 Etsy 84, 87, 94, 110, 132, 146, 210
correction activities 162 Evans, P. 14, 24, 25
Craigslist 34, 95, 167 event strategy 96
credibility 156, 158–9, 195 ex ante regulation 173, 188
critical mass 31, 35–6, 37, 46, 73, 80, ex post regulation 173
121 externalities 31–3, 65, 175, 180
cultural meme 97
customer acquisition 93, 107, 127; see also Facebook 8, 13, 14, 52, 124, 131, 163, 168;
platform participants ecosystem 28, 70; ignition 95, 96;
customer experience 36, 48, 53; maturity network effects 35; pricing strategies 149;
108, 111; pricing strategies 139, 140–1; scaling-up 107, 166; search results 124
scaling-up 162 fast follower strategy 199
fear barriers 168–9
data capture 187; see also analytics feedback 32, 34–6, 47, 77, 98, 100, 101,
dating platforms 13, 36, 48, 50, 95, 166, 108, 110, 111, 125, 160, 165, 188
176 Fulfilment by Amazon see Amazon FBA
delay strategy 195
Deliveroo 95, 111, 133, 170, 208 gaming platforms 35, 69, 97, 145
demand coordinators 24–5 Gawer, A. 14, 25
denial strategy 194 Gebbia, J. 1, 169
denigrate strategy 194 Google 7, 13, 14, 67, 163, 180–6; AdWords
deter strategy 194–5 67; Android operating system 67, 185;
Didi Chuxing 15, 132 brand 169; business model 50–1, 68;
digital platforms 4, 5, 12, 17, 73, 157, ecosystem 66–7, 68–9, 70, 132, 180–1,
167 186; home automation 212; search results
direct network effects 34–5 125; YouTube 67, 69, 131, 182
direct platforms 80 Google+ 69, 182
Index 219

governance 51, 76, 140, 165, 167; pre- market power 37, 173–6, 180–3, 186, 197
launch 87; trust framework 155, 157, 162, market sizing 79–80
164–70 Mastercard 5, 23, 26, 80, 134
Gumtree 132, 143 match 75; ignition 97–101, 115; maturity
124; platform participants 47–8, 52, 84–5,
Hailo (MyTaxi) 93, 185 95; pre-launch 86; scaling-up 114–15
HiGear 163 maturity 73, 75–6, 121–2, 127–8
home automation 212 media companies 25
Honda 27 membership fees 139, 143–4
hotels 1, 3, 7, 79, 179–80 meshed communities 94–5
Microsoft 13–14, 23, 28, 63, 65, 70, 125,
IBM 14, 26, 194 143; ecosystem 70, 130, 132; home
ignition 73, 74, 91–102; eBay 53–4; automation 212
Facebook 95, 96 minimum viable product see MVP
indirect network effects 34–5 monetization 50, 67, 86, 100, 116, 142,
indirect platforms 80–1 147
innovation 140, 170, 174; maturity 127, MSP (multisided platforms) 25, 46
128; regulation 174, 186, 199 multihoming 36–7, 149, 176, 177
Instagram 70, 99, 107, 110, 133 multisided markets 5, 23–4, 46
insurance 164 multisided platforms see MSP
intervention 175 MVP (minimum viable product) 91, 100–1
intimacy 156 MyTaxi 93
IT infrastructure 52
negative externalities 32, 180
key enablers 51, 52 Netflix 26, 197
Kickstarter 78, 109, 210 network effects 33–5, 35, 48, 52, 68, 99,
133, 176; positive 48, 115, 126, 133, 142,
La Belle Asiette 93–4, 99 149
labour laws 177 networks 31, 33–5
Launchworks 21, 157, 206, 208 North Star metric 86, 100, 119
leakage 49, 126, 147–8
leverage 61, 62, 70, 88, 124–5 on-boarding processes 107–8, 168
linear businesses 6, 12, 41–2, 44, 52 Onefinestay 200–1
LinkedIn 49, 70, 100, 107, 143, 150, online platforms 11, 50, 51, 162
159 OpenTable 93
liquidity 33, 52, 143; ignition 99, 101; operating systems 5, 6, 25, 34; Android 58,
scaling-up 117 67, 185–6
listing fees 144 optimize 50, 76; ignition 100, 101; maturity
Lyft 15, 132, 174, 176, 202 128, 130; pre-launch 74, 86; scaling-up
116
management principles 6, 7, 207 over-regulation 174
management rules 7, 17
market failures 167, 175–6, 187 Parker, G. 23, 25–6
market makers 24–5 partners 45, 79, 128
marketplace platforms 12, 15, 48, 26, 59, payment platforms 6, 24, 48
61, 85 PayPal 95, 131, 187
marketplaces 6, 26, 64, 49, 59, 84, 85, 208 performance metrics 100, 117, 127
220 Index

personalization 124 regulation 167, 173–9, 186–9


piggybacking 95 reliability 156
platform balance 111, 117, 128, 144–6 retention 47, 107–8, 111, 122
platform businesses 4, 5–7, 11–14, 205, 207, risk management 163
212, 214; definitions 21, 24–8 Rochet, J. 23–4
platform business models 4–7, 21–2, 27, rocket model 46, 51, 73, 82, 116; ignition
45–7, 146, 199, 205, 207, 212, 214 73, 74, 91; maturity 73, 122; pre-launch
platform development 73, 77, 88; ignition 73, 74; scaling-up 73, 162
73, 75–6, 91–101; maturity 73, 75–6, Ruby Lane 143, 166
122, 125, 126, 128, 130; pre-launch 50,
73, 74, 75–6, 77–8, 82–7, 87, 169; SAP 123
scaling-up 73, 75–6, 91, 105–18, 169, scaling-up 73, 105–6, 116
176 Schmalensee, R. 24
platform disruption 193–9, 201–3, 210–11; search results 48, 50, 52, 67, 98, 114, 124,
traditional businesses 132, 193–4, 206, 180–1
198–201 self-driving cars 67, 211–12
platform ecosystems see ecosystems sharing economy 8, 16, 164, 208–11
platform fit 75–6, 91, 92, 100, 105, 169 single homing 36–7
platform management 6–7, 17, 161, 168 Snapchat 16, 110
platform owners 79, 84, 95, 100, 105 Spotify 123
platform participants 35, 47, 48, 51, 78–80, stakeholders 74, 79, 82, 210
113, 142, 165; connect 98; ignition 91, start-ups 15
101; match 35, 84, 97; maturity 121–2; Stootie 98
pre-launch 78–9, 86; trust framework 51, strategic enablers 51, 101, 118
158, 160–1 substitutes 38
platforms 11–12
Pokémon Go 97 talent platforms 205–6
Porter, M. 6, 42–3 Taobao 124–5
positive externalities 31, 32, 65 TaskRabbit 108, 148
positive network effects: match 48; maturity taxi market 7, 24, 80, 93, 131, 174, 176,
111, 114; pricing strategies 126, 142, 149; 178, 196
scaling-up 117 Tesco 27
pre-launch 73, 74, 75–6, 77–8 Tinder 13, 96, 166
premium services 142–3 tipping point 36
price discrimination 137–8, 143 Tirole, J. 7, 23–4
price elasticity 37, 137 traditional businesses 4, 11, 13, 25, 41, 46,
pricing 50, 81, 116, 126–8, 137, 150 79, 82, 137, 176; platform disruption 38,
pricing friction 141–4 193, 198
pricing models 139, 141–4, 146 traditional business models 33 41, 53, 62,
pricing strategies 23, 138–9, 140, 145–50 132, 193, 211; ignition 91; maturity 132,
producer acquisition 108–9 193
producer retention 108, 121 transactional platforms 85, 111
producers 78, 107–8 transaction fees 139, 143–4, 146
transaction metrics 111, 115, 116
Quora 110, 159 Transport for London (TfL) 177–8
travel platforms 3, 11; see also Airbnb; Lyft;
Reddit 49, 78, 84, 94, 209, 210, 213 Uber
Index 221

trust 45, 49, 51, 84, 87, 99, 106, 115, 121, value chains 6, 42–3, 52–3, 202–3
130, 147, 153 value creation 11, 50, 78, 139, 174, 193,
trust framework 153, 155, 157, 165, 211
188 value propositions 57, 63, 82, 112, 196,
Twitter 69, 96, 159, 163 197; maturity 112; pre-launch 82;
tying strategies 182–3 scaling-up 112, 133, 142
Van Alstyne, M. 23, 25–6
Uber 11, 15, 22, 52, 108, 177; business VIP strategy 96
model 24, 79; price strategies 81, 140; viral loops 110
regulation 140, 162, 167, 174, 177 Visa 5, 14, 23, 26, 80–1, 134
UberEATS 133
under-regulation 174 WeChat 6, 97, 132
unfair competition 3, 174, 180–1, 186 WhatsApp 70, 110
unicorns 15–16
Upwork 47, 88, 126, 159, 169, 206 YouTube (Google) 67–9, 131, 182, 183,
user acquisition 93, 97, 107–10, 122; 186
see also platform participants
user retention 107–8, 111, 122 Zalando 12, 102, 200

You might also like