Platform Strategy
Platform Strategy
Platform Strategy
During the last decade, platform businesses such as Uber, Airbnb, Amazon
and eBay have been taking over the world. In almost every sector, traditional
businesses are under attack from digital disrupters that are effectively harnes-
sing the power of communities. But what exactly is a platform business and
why is it different?
In Platform Strategy, Laure Claire Reillier and Benoit Reillier provide a
practical guide for digital entrepreneurs and executives to understand what
platforms are, how they work and how you can build one successfully.
Using their own “rocket model” and original case studies (including Google,
Apple, Amazon), they explain how designing, igniting and scaling a plat-
form business requires learning a whole new set of management rules. Platform
Strategy also offers many fascinating insights into the future of platforms,
their regulation and governance, as well as how they can be combined with
other business models.
Laure Claire Reillier and Benoit Reillier are co-founders of Launchworks,
a leading advisory firm focused on helping organizations develop and scale
innovative business models.
Laure Claire Reillier has worked for a number of high-growth start-ups
and established tech firms. Before co-founding Launchworks, Laure Claire was
a senior executive at eBay Europe. She studied computer sciences and tele-
communications at Telecom SudParis (France) and holds an MBA from
the London Business School.
Benoit Reillier has been advising the management teams of platforms and
digital and technology companies for the past 20 years. He studied informa-
tion systems, management and telecommunications at Telecom Management
and economics and competition law at King’s College, London. He holds
MBAs from both Columbia University in New York City and London Business
School.
Platform Strategy
(products and services) was no longer able to explain how these particular
firms were operating. A case study of Ford, which would have provided
powerful management insights into how firms operated only 15 years ago,
no longer provides the insights it once did. Firms such as Apple, Amazon,
Google, Airbnb and Uber have grown at an unprecedented pace while
operating in ways that have very little to do with traditional firms such as
Ford.
We also noticed that many of these disruptive platforms were in fact
cleverly combined with traditional business models to create powerful self-
reinforcing ecosystems. Amazon, for example, used eBay’s open marketplace
model and combined it with its own digital retail model. Apple is focused
on manufacturing and selling beautifully designed products – and this generates
more than 80% of its revenues – but these devices are often bought because
of the unique apps provided by the community of external developers and
available on its App Store platform. Google’s advertising and search platforms
are also supplemented by a range of other products and services developed
by Google as part of its fast-growing ecosystem.
Our fascination and interest for these new business models, whose power
we experienced first-hand, led us to set up Launchworks, a new breed of
advisory company dedicated to helping firms unlock value by leveraging
these new platform-based business models. At the time, books on platforms
simply didn’t exist beyond a few, often quite narrow, academic publications.1
As we developed our thinking and frameworks to help platform businesses,
we realized that many firms could benefit from our experience and insights.
executives, academics, students and clients who taught us so much over the
past few years. We acknowledge the contribution of all those who shared
their views with us, sent us their research, invited us to seminars and work-
shops, participated in some of our lectures or simply retained our firm,
Launchworks, to advise them.
Note
1 The possible exception is an early book on multisided markets by D. Evans and
R. Schmalensee, The Catalyst Code: The Strategies Behind the World’s Most Dynamic
Companies, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 2007.
Acknowledgements
While all errors and omissions are our own, we would like in particular to
thank the following individuals for sharing their insights with us as we worked
on the book.
In alphabetical order, we would like to thank: Ken Ardali, Jean-Jacques
Arnal, Andrin Bachmann, Nicolas Bailleux, Charles Baron, Matthew Bennett,
David Brackin, Verena Butt d’Espous, Sangeet Choudary, Jean-Marc Codsi,
Richard Davies, Carlos Eduardo Espinal, Richard Feasey, Jean-Marc Frangos,
Anshu Goel, Barbara Gray, Jonathan Hall, Tim Hilpert, Rob Hull, Stéphane
Kasriel, Spyros Katageorgis, Monroe Labouisse, Terence Lim, Elisabeth
Ling, Claude Lixi, Rodrigo Madanes, Frédéric Mazzella, Antonio Nieto-
Rodriguez, Keyvan Nilforoushan, Natasha Osborne-Geurts, Nilan Peris,
Didier Rappaport, Fred Reillier, Annemie Ress, Paul Ress, Ramsey R. F.
Sargent, Joe Schorge, Marie Taillard, Aude Thibaut de Maisières, Mike
Walker, Chris Webster, Taylor Wescoatt, Caspar Wolley, André Haddad,
Pascal Isbell and Albin Serviant.
Please note that while many of the people mentioned above work for,
advise or regulate some of the platform businesses we talk about in this book,
many spoke to us in a personal capacity rather than as representatives of their
employer. A small number of individuals asked to remain anonymous, and
we thank them as well.
We would also like to thank all the academics, including in particular
Marshall Van Alstyne, Annabelle Gawer, Thomas Eisenmann, Ray Fisman,
Geoff Parker, David Evans and Peter Evans, who have done much to improve
our understanding of platforms over the years. Many of them also kindly
provided feedback and/or shared their thoughts with us at a number of research
symposia and conferences.
Special thanks also go to Jonathan Norman, our publisher at Routledge,
as well as Emma Redley and Alex Atkinson, his assistants, for believing in
the project and providing ongoing support, to Philip Stirrup, our production
xviii Acknowledgements
Introduction to platform
businesses
Uber, the world’s largest taxi company, owns no vehicles. Facebook, the
world’s most popular media owner, creates no content. Alibaba, the most
valuable retailer, has no inventory. And Airbnb, the world’s largest
accommodation provider, owns no real estate. Something interesting is
happening.
Tom Goodwin
In 2007, designers Brian Chesky and Joe Gebbia struggled to pay their rent
in San Francisco when they noticed that the city’s hotels were fully booked
for an upcoming design conference. They came up with the idea of renting
out three airbeds in their loft and cooking breakfast for their guests. The next
day, they designed a website, originally called airbedandbreakfast.com. In less
than a week, they had three guests, paying $80 each a night. When the guests
left, thinking this could become a big idea, they asked a former roommate
of Joe’s, engineer Nathan Blecharczyk, to help them develop the site that we
know today as Airbnb.
For the first few years, the team failed to raise money. The vision of a
trusted community marketplace for people to list, discover and share private
accommodation around the world did not appeal to venture capitalists (VCs),
who couldn’t see a big enough market. But Brian, Joe and Nathan persisted
and found ingenious ways to keep going. In 2008, the company ran out of
cash, so they had to find creative ways to make money quickly. As the
presidential campaign was in full swing and both sides were keen to show
support for their favourite candidates, the Airbnb team decided to sell special
edition Cheerios cereal boxes for both presidential candidates called ‘Obama
O’s’ and ‘Cap’n McCains’ for $40 each. They made $30,000 in a few weeks.
By early 2009, they were invited to join the Y Combinator, one of the
leading incubator programmes in San Francisco, and got $20,000 of funding
from well-known angel investor Paul Graham. A seed round of $600,000 led
2 Introduction to platform businesses
by Sequoia Capital followed shortly afterwards.1 Even so, the business did
not take off. The Airbnb team realized that the photos of places advertised
on their website were not appealing. According to Brian Chesky, ‘A web
startup would say, “Let’s send emails, teach [users] professional photography,
and test them.” We said, “Screw that.”’2 They rented a $5,000 camera and
went door to door, taking professional pictures of as many New York listings
as possible. Revenues doubled quickly to $400/week and the site started
to grow. Brian knew at this point that it was not just about pretty pictures,
but that Airbnb first had to ‘create the perfect experience [. . .] and then scale
that experience.’ In April 2012, the team started monetizing the service by
charging up to 15% on the bookings. More funding rounds followed,3 which
enabled Airbnb to hire more staff to focus on the customer experience and
market the platform in order to scale the business.
Their success came down to three things: ease of joining for host and
guest; effective matching of hosts and guests; and safe and easy transactions
for all.
Since then, Airbnb has grown exponentially (see Figure 1.1), from 50,000
listings in 2011 to more than 2 million in April 2016.4 And this is not just
inventory. It is estimated that roughly half a million people around the world
sleep in an Airbnb rented accommodation at peak time.
Airbnb is currently active in 34,000 cities in 190 countries, and has had 35
million nights booked.5 Airbnb raised $1.5 billion in June 2015, which is one
of the largest private funding rounds ever. The company is estimated to be
worth $30 billion,6 which means that in less than 10 years, the travel accom-
modation platform has become one of the most valuable privately owned
start-ups, worth more than the largest hotel chains Wyndham, Intercontinental
and Hyatt, who own extensive portfolios of prime real estate globally.
And Airbnb owns no property.
While there’s been an overwhelming response from customers, Airbnb’s
high-growth success story has not been without resistance from hoteliers,
who claim that individuals renting their rooms or entire homes to visitors
represents an ‘unfair competition’ to their trade. There is emerging evidence7
that Airbnb is not only growing the market, but also increasingly competing
against hotels, who have to respond with new services and lower prices.
Interestingly, these lower prices benefit all consumers, and not just Airbnb
clients. Yet Airbnb has also been under growing pressure from city authorities
regarding housing regulations and tax laws. We’ll come back to these issues
in Chapter 13 on platforms and regulation.
Since many platform businesses are digital in nature, we use the term digital
platform for businesses digitally connecting members of communities to enable
them to transact.
Platform business models can be tailored to meet a wide range of needs.
They include:
• Chapter 2 explores the meteoric rise of platform business models over the
past decade.
• Chapter 3 reviews platform definitions in the academic literature, looks
at the various types of platforms and proposes basic characteristics common
to most platforms.
• Chapter 4 reviews the key economic characteristics of platforms, including
network effects, externalities, critical mass and tipping point.
8 Introduction to platform businesses
Notes
1 Telegraph, 7 September 2012, www.telegraph.co.uk/technology/news/9525267/Airbnb-
The-story-behind-the-1.3bn-room-letting-website.html.
2 Fast Company, www.fastcompany.com/3017358/most-innovative-companies-2012/
19airbnb.
Introduction to platform businesses 9
3 Following the Sequoia round, Airbnb went on to raise a series A round of $7.2 million
in 2010. Wall Street Journal, 25 July 2011, http://blogs.wsj.com/venturecapital/2011/
07/25/airbnb-from-y-combinator-to-112m-funding-in-three-years/.
4 VentureBeat, 19 June 2014, http://venturebeat.com/2014/06/19/uber-and-airbnbs-
incredible-growth-in-4-charts/ and Airbnb website at www.airbnb.co.uk/about/
about-us.
5 www.airbnb.co.uk/about/about-us.
6 CB Insights, 1 August 2016, www.wired.com/2015/12/airbnb-confirms-1-5-billion-
funding-round-now-valued-at-25-5-billion/. By the end of 2014, Airbnb had raised over
$800 million. ‘Airbnb Is Raising a Monster Round at a $20B Valuation’, TechCrunch,
27 February 2015, http://techcrunch.com/2015/02/27/airbnb-2/.
7 G. Zervas and D. Proserpio, ‘The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating the Impact
of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry’, Boston University, 27 January 2016.
8 As of 23 September 2016.
9 http://news.hiltonworldwide.com/assets/HWW/docs/brandFactSheets/HWW_
Corporate_Fact_Sheet.pdf.
10 www.marriott.com/marriott/aboutmarriott.mi.
11 As of 30 June 2016, www.accorhotels-group.com/en/brands/key-figures.html.
12 www.ihgplc.com/files/pdf/factsheets/factsheet_worldstats.pdf, 31 March 2015.
13 www.wyndhamworldwide.com/category/wyndham-hotel-group, June 2015.
14 Hyatt Hotels Q3 2016 earnings, available at http://investors.hyatt.com/files/doc_
financials/q3_2016/Q3-2016-Earnings-Release.pdf
15 See J. Rochet and J. Tirole, ‘Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, Journal of
the European Economic Association, 1(4), 2003, 990–1029. While Rochet and Tirole’s
contribution formalised the economics of two-sided markets, academics before them
also made significant contributions to the field. See for example G. Parker and M. Van
Alstyne, Internetwork Externalities and Free Information Goods, New York, NY, Proceedings
of the 2nd ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, 2000, pp. 107–16. See also M. Katz
and C. Shapiro, ‘Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility’, The American
Economic Review, Volume 75, Issue 3, June 1985, pp. 424–40. And J. Farrell and G.
Saloner (1988), ‘Coordination through Committees and Markets’, RAND Journal of
Economics, 19, issue 2, pp. 235–52.
16 http://business.lesechos.fr/directions-generales/strategie/business-plan/0203024730098-
guillaume-pepy-imagine-la-sncf-de-demain-9282.php, September 2013.
Chapter 2
new industries are now being disrupted by these digital platforms (for example,
healthcare, recruitment, professional services and energy).
Of course, some traditional businesses have realized that the digital transition
(arrow 1) was not enough and have started to develop platform capabilities
to compete (arrow 2). For example, retail giants are now going beyond their
initial e-commerce offerings and are trying to harness the power of platforms
(top arrow), where merchants can directly sell to customers. The recent
acquisition of digital marketplace Jet.com by Walmart for $3.3 billion can be
seen in that light. An increasing number of retailers who had only made limited
digital investments early on are now investigating digital platforms as add-on
businesses (arrow 3).
Amazon is also an interesting example, as while it started as a pure e-
commerce reseller with a curated but limited range of goods for sale, it quickly
added a marketplace platform to complement its reseller model. The latter
now represents well over 50% of its total e-commerce revenues.1 Zalando,
the successful e-commerce fashion company, is also turning itself into a fully
fledged platform business.2
The meteoric rise of platform businesses 13
Figure 2.4 The top 10 most valuable brands in the world (US$ millions)10
Source: Milliward Brown 2016, Launchworks analysis
like Uber, and both have raised significant private investments. Snapchat is a
well-known and fast-growing communications platform that famously turned
down a multibillion-dollar offer from Facebook in 2014. Stripe is a fast-
growing payment platform for e-commerce merchants.
Notes
1 ChannelAdvisor blog, www.channeladvisor.com/blog/?pn=scot/amazons-q4-results-
marketplace-surges-proves-it-is-the-amazon-profit-cow.
2 See, for example, blog post of Marcel Weiß dated 19 November 2015, https://
earlymoves.com/2015/11/19/zalando-we-want-to-become-an-open-fashion-platform/.
3 Financial Times Global 500 rankings, 30 September 2016.
4 FT Global 500 list of largest companies, 31 March 2006 and 31 March 2016, and
Launchworks analysis.
5 See B. Libert, M. Beck, J. Wind, The Network Imperative, Boston: Harvard Business
Review press, 2016.
6 BrandZ(tm) Top 100 Most Valuable Global Brands 2016, Millward Brown, http://
wppbaz.com/admin/uploads/files/BZ_Global_2016_Report.pdf.
7 We recognize that telecommunications operators, such as Verizon and AT&T, operate
somewhat differently than other platform-powered ecosystems. In fact, some may argue
they operate more like traditional businesses than digital platforms. Yet we believe
operators were an early wave of platforms that attracted users, matched them first using
switchboards, then with directories and yellow pages, to connect them and allow them
to transact. They also originally benefited from network effects, yet were not able to
innovate as fast as the new ‘Internet players’. Telecoms operators are, however,
increasingly investing in digital platform capabilities to avoid commoditization (such as
the acquisition of Yahoo by Verizon). We note that their exclusion from this list would
still result in more than 75% of the combined value of the top 10 brands in the world
coming from platform-powered businesses.
8 IBM is often seen as a platform in the technical sense of the term, and associated with
both hardware standards and operating system capabilities. Yet today’s business is largely
run as a technology advisory company rather than a digital platform. We note, however,
that the firm is investing in new capabilities that may allow it to transition to a platform-
powered ecosystem model.
9 Alibaba raised $25 billion on the NYSE in September 2014.
10 This is the value of the intangible asset of the brand itself.
11 At the time of writing, neither Airbnb nor Uber are quoted on the stock market, so
market valuations for these firms are based on the implied value of their last private
round of financing.
12 A unicorn, a legendary animal that has been described since antiquity as a beast with a
pointed horn on its forehead, is notoriously difficult to find. Private companies reaching
a $1 billion mark valuation were so rare until 2010 that they were coined unicorns.
13 http://techcrunch.com/2013/11/02/welcome-to-the-unicorn-club/, 2 November 2013.
14. Data from CB Insights, 28 September 2016, www.cbinsights.com/research-unicorn-
companies.
15 As we will see later on in this book, sky-high valuation at a given point in time is in
no way a guarantee of success, and even firms exhibiting strong platform characteristics
are not immune to failure. In fact, ‘unicorpses’, defined as ‘dead companies once valued
at more than $1 billion’, are likely to be observed soon. In the meantime, and irrespective
of market volatility, it is interesting to see overall patterns of value creation around
platform businesses.
The meteoric rise of platform businesses 19
16 See early definitions of the sharing economy in R. Botsman and R. Rogers, What’s
Mine Is Yours: The Rise of Collaborative Consumption, New York: Harper Business, 2010.
More recently, A. Stephany, The Business of Sharing, London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2015.
17 www.justpark.com/creative/sharing-economy-index/, February 2016.
Chapter 3
PLATFORM
A business creating significant value through the acquisition, matching
and connection of two or more customer groups to enable them to
transact.
Examples: eBay, Airbnb, Uber
While there is some overlap in terms of usage across these different defin-
itions, we believe it is very important to be clear about what we mean by
the word ‘platform’ from the outset. We propose to define platform businesses
as ‘businesses creating significant value through the acquisition and/or match-
ing, interaction and connection of two or more customer groups to enable
them to transact’.6
Since much of the academic work on platforms has been done in the context
of competition economics or antitrust,7 we will review some of this work
and discuss its implications for management. We will then review more recent
definitions against our own definition based on the activities of platform
businesses, as well as the characteristics of the underlying markets they serve.
We will also see that platforms are not all equal, but come in a range of
shapes, colours and sizes. They may allow you to buy, rent, swap and borrow
products, services or currencies. They may be open to third parties or closed,
have direct distribution to consumers and producers or indirect ones and they
may have a broad selection of differentiated goods or a narrow one with
homogeneous products and services. All these differences call for different
types of governance and business architecture within the overall platform
framework. Lastly, we will see that many companies are not pure platforms,
but ‘platform-powered ecosystems’ mixing different business models.
What is a platform business? 23
Platforms as ‘catalysts’
Evans also proposed a broad classification of ‘catalysts’ consistent with his
original definition. The three main business types identified were: (i) market
makers; (ii) audience builders; and (iii) demand coordinators.
Although Evans considers all of these businesses as platforms, the distinctions
between them are important:
(i) Market makers: eBay has created a unique global marketplace where sellers
and buyers of an incredibly wide range of goods meet. eBay is valued at
more than $35 billion17 and generated in excess of $83 billion of Gross
Merchandise Value (GMV)18 in 2016 without offering any product
whatsoever, but simply by connecting buyers and sellers through its online
platform and being paid a small percentage of the transaction19 for this
facilitation. Uber and Airbnb are in the same category.
(ii) Audience builders: Some platforms focus on allowing users to share and/or
consume content. This in turn attracts advertisers who need ‘eyeballs’ for
their campaigns. Evans argues that media firms, and many publications,
operate in such ‘audience building’ multisided markets.
(iii) Demand coordinators: A third type of platform business focuses on coord-
inating demand within a given ecosystem. Unlike market makers, demand
coordinators often have a broader group of stakeholders and ecosystem
What is a platform business? 25
participants. Operating systems (OS) fall into this category since they are
designed for users, licensed by hardware manufacturers and used by
application developers. The more applications available for a given OS, the
higher its utility or value. At the same time, app developers are only able
to invest in the development required if there are either currently or
prospectively enough users of the OS to cover their costs and eventually
make a profit.
Economists also showed that since platforms were connecting two markets,
they had a unique ability to price differently from traditional businesses.
In fact, they noticed that platform businesses were able to offer free services
not simply on a temporary basis or during promotions, but on a sustainable
basis.20 This has far-reaching implications, since it means that the very basis
of competition can be dramatically changed by platforms and that non-
platform businesses may find themselves ‘priced out’ of the market. This
phenomenon will be discussed in more detail in Chapter 14, where we will
examine why existing firms struggle to compete against platform businesses
and what options are available to them.
Hagiu and Wright also proposed a focused definition of ‘multisided
platforms’ (MSP). Their proposed definition is:
Platform-powered ecosystems
As we have seen, companies such as Apple, Google, Amazon, Microsoft and
Facebook are among the largest in the world. Yet very few are pure platform
businesses. Instead, these successful companies are underpinned by a mix of
business models, including platforms, and are therefore ‘platform-powered’.
The term ‘ecosystem’ is often defined in a business context as a group of
interdependent organizations collectively providing goods and services to their
customers.30 A platform-powered ecosystem can then be defined as a group
of organizations – under the same ownership or strategically linked – that
derives significant value from at least one platform business.
These platform ecosystems leverage the interplay between the various
business models that are part of the ecosystem to reinforce customer
propositions and create stickiness, often with spectacular success. These ideas
will be further explored in Chapter 6.
With the definitions out of the way, we can examine management principles
in more detail and look under the hood of platforms.
PLATFORM-POWERED ECOSYSTEM
A business comprising of a mix of business models, including platforms.
Examples: Amazon, Apple, Google, Alibaba, Microsoft
Notes
1 The Oxford English Dictionary states that a platform is ‘a raised level surface on which
people or things can stand, usually a discrete structure intended for a particular activity
or operation’.
2 See A. Gawer, Platforms, Markets and Innovation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2009, p.
45, as well as Y. Baldwin and J. Woodard, The Architecture of Platforms: A Unified View,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School, 2009, for a discussion of the architecture of
platforms across disciplines.
3 S. Wheelwright and K. Clark, Revolutionizing Product Development: Quantum Leaps in
Speed, Efficiency and Quality, New York: Free Press, 1992.
4 T. Bresnahan and S. Greenstein, ‘Technological Competition and the Structure of the
Computer Industry’, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 47, 1999, 1–40.
5 J. Rochet and J. Tirole, ‘Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, Journal of the
European Economic Association, 1(4), 2003, 990–1029.
6 Strictly speaking, businesses need not be Internet-enabled to have a platform business
model (e.g. shopping malls or estate agents), but many of the platform businesses we
What is a platform business? 29
will review in this book are digital platforms that have harnessed the power of the Internet
and big data to develop their offerings, often globally.
7 Also called antitrust, competition economics is concerned with competition between
firms and potential abuse of market power justifying market intervention.
8 See, for example, W. Baxter, ‘Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and
Economic Perspectives’, Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 1983, 541–88, for an early
discussion of pricing considerations in card markets (interchange fees).
9 Geoffrey Parker and Marshall van Alstyne, ‘Information Complements, Substitutes,
and Strategic Product Design’, ICIS 2000 Proceedings, Paper 2, 2000.
10 We will see in Chapter 11 how important these new ‘platform equations’ are for pricing
strategies.
11 This meets the definition of Rochet and Tirole: ‘A market is two sided if the platf-
orm can affect the volume of transactions by charging more to one side of the market
and reducing the price paid by the other side by an equal amount; in other words, the
price structure matters, and the platform must design it so as to bring both sides on
board’.
12 See B. Caillaud and B. Jullien, ‘Chicken and Egg: Competition among Intermediation
Service Providers’, RAND Journal of Economics, 34(2), 2003, 309–28, who departed from
the payment cards industry to explore and model in more details the expected market
equilibrium of competing platforms (including estate agents, dating agencies and
marketplaces) under a range of scenarios. G. Parker and W. Van Alstyne, ‘Two-Sided
Network Effects: A Theory of Information Product Design’, Management Science, 51(10),
2005, 1494–504, subsequently developed a model of ‘two sided network externality’
capturing network effects, price discrimination and product differentiation. Mark
Armstrong, ‘Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3),
September 2006, 668–91, also proposed a model of multisided markets built upon similar
theoretical foundations (but focused on membership externalities, as opposed to usage
ones, as originally modelled by Rochet and Tirole) and offered a generic definition based
primarily on the scale of the benefits derived by one side of the market depending upon
the size of the other side.
13 Richard Schmalensee and David S. Evans, ‘Industrial Organization of Markets with Two-
Sided Platforms’, Competition Policy International, 3(1), Spring 2007.
14 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, Paying with Plastic: The Digital Revolution in Buying and
Borrowing, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2005, for a review of the economics of card
payments.
15 D. Evans, R. Schmalensee, M. Noel, H. Chang and D. Garcia-Swartz, ‘Platform
Economics: Essays on Multi-Sided Businesses’, Competition Policy International, 2011, for
competition issues arising in multisided businesses.
16 Also referred to as ‘matchmakers’. See D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, Matchmakers: The
New Economics of Multisided Platforms, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press,
2016.
17 As of 26 September 2016.
18 GMV stands for gross merchandise value and is used in online platforms to indicate a
total sales value for merchandise sold through a particular marketplace over a certain
time frame.
19 Typically final value fees are between 5% and 11% on eBay.
30 What is a platform business?
20 In fact, prices could even be negative on one side of the business on a sustainable basis.
See David S. Evans and Richard Schmalensee, ‘The Antitrust Analysis of Multi-Sided
Platform Businesses’ (Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics Working Paper
No. 623, 2012).
21 Andrei Hagiu and Julian Wright, ‘Multi-Sided Platforms’, Harvard Business School
Working Paper 12-024, October 2011.
22 P. Evans and A. Gawer, ‘The Rise of the Platform Enterprise’, Center for Global
Enterprise, January 2016.
23 G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York: W. W.
Norton & Company, 2016.
24 What marketers call B2B (business to business), B2C (business to consumer) and C2C
(consumer to consumer).
25 By targeting communities that are both buyers and sellers, such as stamps or rare coin
collectors in the early days of eBay, some platforms have been able to ignite their platform
more quickly and overcome some of the friction caused by the ‘chicken-and-egg’
problem, discussed in Chapter 8.
26 Card companies connect merchants and card users indirectly through merchant acquirers
and card issuers (usually banks).
27 While many platforms let their producers and users set the price themselves, some try
to internalize supply and demand to set uniform prices (e.g. Uber).
28 Many ecommerce sites today operate under a retailer/reseller model.
29 Please note that we are of course simplifying business typologies in order to illustrate
the differences between business models. For example, while Honda’s core business is
manufacturing ‘input’ and ‘output’ business for cars and engines, it also has significant
R&D activities in artificial intelligence and robotics.
30 ‘Business Ecosystem’, Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, London: Palgrave
Macmillan (2014).
Chapter 4
Economic characteristics
of platforms
Externalities
We can all benefit from and be harmed by things that are not within our
control. When people join networks (be it social networks or telecoms
networks), all the other network users benefit since the network’s reach –
and therefore overall value – is increased. This is a positive externality since
all network users are better off as a result.
If a company were to dump toxic waste in the water next to a village, the
villagers would suffer a strong negative externality. Villagers are not responsible
for the behaviour of the firm, yet their lives are impacted by it. This is a
negative externality, and the company is not incurring the real cost of its
actions (unless it is caught).
An externality occurs when individuals or firms are impacted, positively
or negatively, by an economic transaction that is independent of them. Many
examples of externalities can be found in everyday life. Things as simple as
the pleasant scent of a perfume worn by a stranger in the underground can
be seen as a positive externality. A negative externality has the same properties,
but with a negative impact imposed by somebody else’s actions. A smoker
would be imposing a negative externality on people around him.
Clearly, externalities go far beyond personal inconvenience, and the toxic
waste of our factory in our previous example is a strong negative externality
on the people living nearby.
32 Economic characteristics of platforms
Externalities can also change over time. The rather disturbing noises made
by the builders next door excavating a basement as these lines are being written
are not helping with concentration in the short term. However, once com-
pleted, an extended and renovated house next door will have a positive impact
on the valuation of the street and therefore represent a positive externality
for nearby homeowners.
One reason why such negative externalities occur is that economic agents
may not be able (or willing) to internalize the effect they have on third parties.
If a factory were economically responsible for the well-being of the nearby
population, it would have strong incentives not to pollute as much.
Positive externalities are important for platforms, since when a platform
grows, both in terms of number of transactions and participants, it becomes
more valuable to all. For example, the more applications available on an app
store, the more attractive it becomes for users. Of course, the more users join
and interact on the platform, the more attractive the platform becomes for
app developers trying to reach users.1
As in the Apple App Store example, when positive externalities exist on
both sides of a platform, positive feedback loops appear and amplify growth.
Enabling and enhancing these loops with a frictionless customer experience
and the right features for users is a key objective of platform businesses.
The term ‘internalizing the externalities’ is sometimes used, and sounds
more complicated than it is. It simply means that some firms and organizations
may need or want to take into account these externalities in their businesses.
So a pollution tax can help firms internalize the negative externalities associated
with pollution because it gives them an incentive to pollute less.
Economies of scale
Economies of scale are said to exist when the unit cost of production goes
down with the volume of production. Many businesses requiring significant
upfront investments benefit from economies of scale since the more units are
produced by a factory or plant, the lower the unit costs. The cost of production
of cars is highly dependent upon how many cars can be manufactured by a
given factory/car plant. If the production is very small, say 10 cars, the total
cost of the factory will have to be covered by these very few cars and result
in a very high unit cost. Car production is therefore said to benefit from
economies of scale, as more cars produced will allow for the shared cost of
production (including R&D) to be spread across more cars and will therefore
be lower on a per car basis. The logical strategic implication of industries
with economies of scale is that you need to become the largest company in
the sector in order to enjoy the lowest cost base per unit.
Economic characteristics of platforms 33
These economies of scale affect the supply side, that is to say the company
producing the goods. Recently, however, the concept of ‘demand-side’
economies of scale has become quite widespread. In networks, the value of
the service provided increases with the number of users because of the positive
externalities we discussed above. Economists therefore describe these network
businesses as benefiting from ‘demand-side’ economies of scale. Strictly
speaking, this is no longer about the cost of production (supply) going down
with volume, but about the value created for users (demand) going up with
the number of users.
The concept of ‘demand-side economies of scale’ is also referred to as
network effects. It is so central to the economics of platforms that we develop
it further below.
Critical mass
A critical mass in a network is defined as the point at which the growth of
the network becomes ‘self-sustaining’.
In the context of platform businesses, critical mass may be required on both
sides of the market and is driven by a number of variables, including the type
and strength of network effects, customer behaviours and the distribution of
customer tastes.10 While scaling a nascent platform is particularly difficult,
because it often has limited network effects due to its small size, reaching
critical mass makes growth and participant matching much easier.
Platforms that do not reach critical mass often unravel. In the case of direct
network effects, the level of participation on the platform affects the value it
36 Economic characteristics of platforms
Tipping point
Closely related to the notion of critical mass, the tipping point is defined as
the point at which a network ‘shifts’ from one state (e.g. competition, or
normal trading activities) to another one (e.g. monopoly, or market unravel-
ling) due to cumulative network effects. Numerous examples of markets
exhibiting such effects have been widely documented in Malcolm Gladwell’s
book Tipping Point.12 The definition offered by Gladwell is broader, but
overlaps with the critical mass concept discussed above: ‘the moment of critical
mass, the threshold, the boiling point’.
The tipping point is therefore an inflection point that, in the case of plat-
forms, is often synonymous with reaching critical mass. Early social networking
sites SixDegrees and Friendster never found the elusive tipping point in their
growth trajectory that would have allowed them to reach a critical mass. The
customer experience was lacking and there was not enough for users to do,
mainly because there were not enough users! Caught in a negative feedback
loop, these platforms unravelled fairly quickly.
easy it will be for the platform to reach a critical mass and gain market power.
For example, while it may be more difficult to ignite a platform when users
single home, if successful the platform then becomes more valuable since
a critical mass of users are committed. Of course, the platform itself can
shape the decisions of its participants by trying to seek exclusivity (e.g. for
game developers to single home), reducing switching costs from other
established platforms (e.g. by offering a ‘converter’ or compatibility with
other platform features) or trying to appear as the ‘winning’ platform, through
advertising and endorsements, to make sure users don’t feel the need to
look elsewhere. We will also see in Chapter 13 that the extent to which
multihoming is possible has implications for regulators and competition
authorities.
Price elasticity
We all know that the demand for products and services changes depending
on their price. If the price of baked beans goes up, people will buy fewer
cans – and vice versa, if the price goes down, more baked beans are sold.
The price elasticity of demand reflects this by giving the percentage change
in quantity demanded for a 1% change in price. It is the quantitative arti-
culation of the question ‘How many more cans of baked beans will I sell if
I decrease the price by 1%?’
A small change in price of some goods sometimes results in a large change
in demand. Traditional baked beans or chocolate bars would be in this cate-
gory and are therefore said to have a high price elasticity.
The demand for other types of goods doesn’t change much when prices
change. This is the case for cigarettes or petrol, where customers are either
addicted or really need to buy in order to go from A to B. These goods have
a low price elasticity.
Often, the decision to not buy something because the price has increased
is driven by the fact that other, cheaper alternatives may exist. So if you are
no longer buying baked beans because their prices have increased, you may
be buying black-eyed beans instead. When that is the case, the products are
said to be substitutes (see section below) and the relationship between the
increase of price of one product and the increase of demand of the other one
is called ‘cross-price elasticity’. The relationships between the interplay of prices
on two sides of a platform are discussed in more details in Chapter 11. This
concept of cross-price elasticity is also central to understanding substitute and
complement products.
38 Economic characteristics of platforms
Substitutes vs complements
Two products are deemed substitutes when the demand for one increases as
the price of the other increases. The concept is rather intuitive, and we all
review daily the characteristics of dozens of substitute products when shopping.
If the price of our favourite brand of butter has increased significantly, we
may want to switch to another – substitute – brand. The more substitutable
the products, the more they exert competitive pressure on one another.
Complements are the opposite. Products are said to be complements if the
increase in price of one leads to a decrease of demand for the other. While
this may sound slightly less intuitive, complementary products abound. Printers
and their cartridges (or razors and their blades) are typical complements. If
the price of a printer increases (everything else being equal), it is likely to sell
less, and the subsequent demand (in the aftermarket) for its ink cartridges will
decrease. These products are complements.13 In the same way, apps available
on Apple’s App Store are complements of its iPhone product.
This distinction between substitutes and complements is useful to better
understand the disruptions brought about by platform businesses. While
their operations are often very different from those of traditional busi-
nesses, the products and services they offer are often close substitutes to existing
ones.
Notes
1 In the context of platform businesses, Jean-Charles Rochet and Jean Tirole, ‘Two-Sided
Markets: A Progress Report’, The RAND Journal of Economics, 35(3), 2006, 645–67, made
an interesting observation about the different types of externalities that exist. They
distinguish between usage externalities and membership externalities. Usage external-
ities occur (as their name indicates) when the platform adds value through interactions
and transactions (e.g. usage) by existing members. Membership externalities exist when
the value received by users of the platform on one side of the market increases with the
number of users on the other side of the market.
2 The total number of relationships (T) in a network of n participants is given by the
formula: T = n(n – 1) / 2.
3 Metcalfe’s law states that the value of a network is proportional to the square of its users
(e.g. Facebook). Reed’s law states that the increase in value is not only proportional,
but exponential, due to the number of subgroups joining the network (e.g. Slack).
Beckstrom’s law states that the value is the net value to participants of all the transactions
carried over the network. Lastly, Sarnoff’s law states that the value of some networks is
proportional to the number of viewers (e.g. Yahoo).
4 Alibaba.com, March 2016 numbers for Taobao and Tmall marketplaces, www.alibaba-
group.com/en/ir/financial_fullyear
5 Fortune, 23 September 2016, http://fortune.com/2015/09/23/alibaba-says-numbers-
real-not-fake/. Each package could contain more than one item.
Economic characteristics of platforms 39
6 eBay.com, https://static.ebayinc.com/static/assets/Uploads/PressRoom/eBay-Factsheet-
Q2-2015.pdf
7 eBay.com, Q2 2016 numbers, https://investors.ebayinc.com/releasedetail.cfm?Release
ID=980435
8 Craigslist website, www.craigslist.org/about/factsheet
9 Well-known venture capital firm Andreessen Horowitz, one of the early financial
backers of Airbnb, knows a thing or two about network effects. See the excellent pre-
sentation and companion article of Anu Harianna et al. on their site: http://a16z.
com/2016/03/07/all-about-network-effects/
10 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, ‘Failure to Launch: Critical Mass in Platform Businesses’,
Review of Network Economics, 9(4), 2010, for a discussion on platforms failing to reach
critical mass.
11 Using the dating analogy, it is interesting to note that since female dating site members
appear to be more difficult to attract on platforms, these have to work extra hard to
ensure that they manage to reach a critical mass. This may include incentives (e.g. free
service), or even in some extreme cases the creation of false profiles to ‘appear’ to have
a critical mass! See the FTC ruling on online dating services using fake profiles, www.
ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2014/10/online-dating-service-agrees-stop-
deceptive-use-fake-profiles, or even ‘female chatbots’, which Ashley Madison claimed
in its defence were ‘widespread’ in this area.
12 See M. Gladwell, The Tipping Point: How Little Things Can Make a Big Difference, Boston,
MA: Little Brown, 2000, for a discussion on markets subject to tipping points.
13 We note, however, that platforms differ from products with an aftermarket in that, while
demand is also interlinked, platform businesses involve two distinct groups of customers,
as opposed to a single buyer of a product and its ‘after-products’. See S. Bishop and
M. Walker, ‘The Economics of EC Competition Law’, European Competition Journal,
6(1), 2010, p. 93, for examples of markets with after-products.
Chapter 5
The business model canvas is less linear than the value chain model and
can be applied to map out the key activities of a wide range of business models,
including platforms. Let’s take the example of Airbnb:
While a very useful framework when trying to quickly map a new business
model in creative sessions, this framework does not explicitly capture key
success factors of platforms, but rather makes it easier to overlay traditional
businesses operations onto a platform business model.6
46 Platforms as business models
Attract
This building block encompasses the characteristics, features and processes by
which a platform is able to attract producers and users. In management
literature, it is also referred to as the ‘magnet’7 or the ‘catalyst’.8 The functions
performed at the attraction stage evolve over the life cycle of a platform and
need to be reviewed on a regular basis. At launch, the attract function is pri-
marily focused on acquiring and hooking new customers, but as the platform
matures, retention starts to play a bigger part. While ultimately what will attract
users and producers on the platform are opportunities to transact with one
another, the design of the value proposition for each side is a critical driver of
attraction. Since platform businesses are subject to network effects, attracting
a critical mass of platform participants, on both sides of the platform, is key to
its long-term success. We will review a number of attraction strategies available
at ignition in Chapter 8.
The attraction – and subsequent management – of a community of users
and producers on a platform (or buyers and sellers in the case of a marketplace)
is quite different from the acquisition of clients in a traditional business. In
fact, some of the thinking that traditional firms apply to the recruitment,
management and motivation of their own employees is relevant to plat-
form participants since they also contribute to the value delivered by the
platform. Consumers will provide valuable feedback and ratings while
producers will ultimately be key to the experience enabled by the platform
since they will be providing their flat, their car, their content, etc. through
the platform. Therefore, identifying high-potential users and producers,
training them, incentivizing them and retaining them, or even ‘terminating
them’ – terms typically used more for employees than clients – is a key part
of the platform attract function. We discuss the different priorities for the
attract function across the various stages of platform development, from design
to maturity, in Chapters 7–9.
Match
In order for both sides to interact, they need to be introduced first. For Airbnb,
that involves presenting guests with the right properties in the right locations
at the right time; for Upwork, a global talent platform, it’s matching com-
panies with a specific assignment with available freelancers who have the right
skill set.
The quality of the matching is critical to the success of the platform. While
early adopters may be more interested by the concept and availability of
relevant platform participants, matching becomes increasingly important as
the platform scales. In a world of abundance, the ability to filter and present
48 Platforms as business models
customers with the right choices creates value. For matching to be effective
for participants, results must meet participant needs (relevance), be timely and
present the right amount of information or depth. The latter means that the
matching function should be optimized to return enough search results for
the user to find a relevant match but not so many as to overwhelm the user
with too much information.
The matching function can also play a key role in helping the platform
maximize positive network effects. For example, Amazon Marketplace
prioritizes product search results on best price but the search algorithm
de-prioritizes merchants with poor feedback. This ensures that consumers are
less likely to buy from merchants that provide bad customer experiences, and
ultimately leave the platform.
There are different ways to match participants. Matching can be done
through a search function with selected parameters for product marketplaces,
such as eBay or Amazon. For service platforms, a specific graphic interface
tailored to the focus of the platform (e.g. geo-localized maps for Airbnb)
is often used. Sometimes, the matching function uses the information that
both sides of the market have provided to the platform, such as pictures and
description on a dating site.
The complexity of the matching function depends on a number of factors.
Horizontal platforms, with a wide range of products and services, usually
require stronger search or matching functions than vertical ones that are more
specialized. In some cases, however, the matching function is almost implied
rather than explicit. This is often the case with payment networks (i.e.
merchants are not actively matched with cardholders, although ‘Amex accepted
here’ signs may help).9 The matching function can also be a mix of search
and self-selection.
Ideally, the matching function is configured to provide the optimal level of
choice required for a successful transaction. Some economists assume that
maximizing choices is always a good thing, yet we find that this is not always
the case and can in fact result in reduced transactions.10 Finding the right
balance between too many choices, which would confuse buyers, and not
enough options, which would drive buyers away, is not an easy task. A curated,
prioritized, relevant and timely selection maximizing the likelihood of
transactions occurring is therefore the nirvana of platforms. This ideal matching
will differ from one user to another, and therefore needs to be personalized.
Connect
Often, platform participants need to exchange additional information with
their counterparty before moving on to the transaction stage. With dating
Platforms as business models 49
Transact
Platforms enable a wide range of interactions among their ecosystem partici-
pants. In many cases, it is information, rather than money, that is exchanged
with the platform and its participants. Think, for example, of a like on
Facebook, a vote on Reddit, a rating on eBay or a comment on TripAdvisor.
The fact that no money changes hands during these interactions doesn’t mean
that they are not very valuable for the platform.12
Out of all the interactions participants have with the platform, some really
crystallize the raison d’être of the platform. We call these core transactions.
Examples include a sale on eBay, a successful hire with LinkedIn, a date with
Match.com or a click on a Google sponsored ad. These core transactions are
supported by other interactions that enable the overall value proposition.
The platform should be optimized to maximize the number of core
transactions and supporting interactions. It is important to note that both
50 Platforms as business models
interactions and core transactions need to be considered from the point of view
of each platform participant since they may be different for users, producers,
the platform owner, the advertisers, etc. Ultimately, the value of a platform
business will be driven by its ability to both maximize the total number of value-
adding interactions and core transactions and to capture a share of this value
through direct or indirect monetization. The platform design phase taking place
before launch should be approached with this objective in mind.
Value capture at the platform level may not be directly aligned with
interactions creating the most value between participants. There is direct
alignment for eBay, which takes a commission on the value of each success-
ful sale (a core transaction). However, dating sites rarely charge you when
you go on a date, as the core transaction for participants is difficult for the
platform to monitor. So dating platforms find ways to charge for other
interactions that lead to dates (including membership fee, a fee per message
for communicating with your matches or a fee to appear on top of searches).
While pricing is often discussed as part of the transact stage,13 it is a broad
topic closely related to the overall governance of the platform and is covered
in Chapter 11.
Optimize
This last optimization stage is iterative and represents an absolutely critical
process for continuous enhancement of the platform. Given the dynamic
nature of platform businesses, this data-driven function allows platform busi-
nesses to find the right balance between the two sides of the market and to
optimize all the matching, connecting and transacting functions of the
platform. Google’s search algorithm is constantly optimized with several A/B
tests14 a day to ensure the best and most relevant search results are provided.
In fact, many platforms see their early development as a portfolio of experi-
ments and hypotheses that need to be tested.
When a bottleneck forms at one of the stages of value creation, manage-
ment’s attention can almost immediately focus on the issue. While traditio-
nal marketplaces such as estate agents are types of platforms that have existed
offline for centuries, we note the technology that enables advanced use of
near real-time analytics on customer data has only been available relatively
recently.
Online platforms almost always capture, store and analyse vast amounts of
data so hypotheses can be formed and tested. As such, data can be considered
an ‘input of production’, as well as a ‘strategic asset’ and even a tradable good.
Platforms increasingly use unique performance indicators and dashboards to
track their progress. Selected platform success metrics can be mapped onto
the rocket framework to provide a holistic way of monitoring performance
Platforms as business models 51
and identifying bottlenecks. These metrics can apply to stages of the rocket,
but also to the wider ecosystem of producers, users and partners.
The concept of ‘big data’ is part of the organizational DNA of most online
platforms, and continuous monitoring of potential bottlenecks can unlock
growth in near real time. Many platforms are so adept at these types of analytics
that they are now applying these tools across their businesses to generate new
management insights. Google regularly generates insights into questions such
as ‘What makes a successful team?’ or ‘What is the most efficient recruitment
process?’ through the use of analytics. We discuss the implication of data usage
by platforms across their life stages in more detail in Chapters 7–10.
Platform enablers
A platform is supported by key enablers across all the stages of the rocket
model. We typically refer to governance, trust and brand as strategic enablers,
and to IT infrastructure, user interface and payment systems as key enablers.
Strategic enablers
Governance is the set of rules, norms and policies that the platform adheres to
in order to build its ecosystem. Platform governance principles deal with
questions such as: Who is allowed on the platform? What behaviours are
rewarded? How are disputes between platform participants handled?
Trust is what makes people believe that the platform participants they engage
with are reliable, credible and honest. It’s a set of principles, rules, filters,
processes and tools enabling participants to interact and transact in a safe envi-
ronment. High trust encourages interactions and core transactions by reducing
the asymmetry of information between participants. Without trust, many
platforms would struggle to gain any scale. It is thanks to the trust-building
features of social media that many people started to be comfortable with the
idea of having a ‘stranger’ rent their flat (Airbnb) or use their car (Turo) while
they are away.
Brand is also a key enabler that works in tandem with trust. The brand building
for platforms is a slightly trickier exercise than for other business models, since
much of the experience is directly influenced by other platform participants.
Platforms therefore need to internalize the needs and wants of their
communities and capture this in key brand attributes. Platforms such as
Airbnb are taking this brand management process, in which platform
participants co-create the overall experience, very seriously and use it as a
way of differentiating themselves.15
52 Platforms as business models
In fact, governance, trust and brand are strategic enablers so important for
platforms that they deserve their own chapter (Chapter 12).
Payments are often key to the platform function and a critical step to enabling its
core transactions. The design of a ‘frictionless’ payment experience is therefore
critical to the overall success of many platform businesses. Increasingly, solutions
tailored to the needs of platforms, such as Mangopay or Stripe Connect, offer
convenient ways of enabling global and secure payment capabilities.
Together, these enabling activities play a critical role in the success of the
platform.
Platforms as business models 53
Notes
1 See, for example, the ‘Pipes vs Platform’ article in the October 2013 Wired magazine
penned by Sangeet Paul Choudary, www.wired.com/insights/2013/10/why-business-
models-fail-pipes-vs-platforms/
2 M. E. Porter, Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors, New
York: Free Press, 1980.
3 M. E. Porter, Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, New
York: Free Press, 1985.
4 See A. Osterwalder and Y. Pigneur, Business Model Generation: A Handbook for Visionaries,
Game Changers, and Challengers, self-published, 2010.
5 Airbnb website, www.airbnb.com/help/article/384/what-are-the-service-fees.
6 It is worth noting that variants of the business canvas have been proposed to better
match the requirements of different types of businesses, including multisided ones. See,
for example, the Platform Design Toolkit (www.platformdesigntoolkit.com) from Simone
Cicero.
7 Sangeet Choudary, Platform Power, 2013, http://platformed.info
8 D. Evans and R. Schmalensee, The Catalyst Code, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School
Press, 2007.
9 Even this may change as card companies develop new advertising capabilities allowing
card users to be notified of merchant promotions of interest based on their previous
purchases, physical location, etc.
10 There is emerging evidence that consumers can indeed be overwhelmed by choice. See
B. Schwartz, The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less, New York: Harper Perennial,
2004.
11 One side, the seller, knows everything about their products, while the buyer knows
little. For the transaction to occur, the platform needs to facilitate this exchange of
information by enabling both parties to communicate. Rating and reputation systems
such as eBay’s star system have been designed to increase the trust of potential buyers
by enhancing the information to the buyer (previous buyer reviews). Trust building is
discussed in more detail in Chapter 12.
12 A like on a Facebook company page was reported as being worth $173, for example.
While the exact number is likely to be highly dependent upon one’s own business, it
Platforms as business models 55
is clear that platform interactions have value not only for the community, but also
advertisers. See, for example, www.wired.com/insights/2013/07/is-a-facebook-like-
worth-174-probably-not/.
13 Charging sellers a sales commission fee (eBay) or members a subscription fee (Match.com)
can be seen as core transactions. This is because significant value is exchanged between
eBay and sellers in the first example, and Match.com and members in the second one.
14 A/B testing is jargon for a randomized experiment with two variants, A and B, which
are the control and treatment in the controlled experiment, for example by sending two
slightly different promotional emails while tracking responses in order to quickly select
the best of the two before iterating further. See R. Kohavi and R. Longbotham, ‘Online
Controlled Experiments and A/B Tests’, Encyclopedia of Machine Learning and Data Mining.
pp. 1–8, 13 May 2016, for a discussion on best practices.
15 See the Airbnb rebranding exercise case study at www.wearedesignstudio.com/works/
airbnb-process/.
16 Timothy Prickett Morgan, ‘Airbnb Shares the Keys to Its Infrastructure’, Next Platform,
10 September 2015, www.nextplatform.com/2015/09/10/airbnb-shares-the-keys-to-
its-infrastructure/.
17 See A. Hagiu and J. Wright, ‘Marketplace or Reseller’, Harvard Business School Working
Paper 13-092, 2013, for a discussion about the strengths and weaknesses of platforms.
18 Pierre Omidyar, founder of eBay, reported that the very first item that sold on the
platform was a broken laser pointer priced at $14.83. Astonished, he contacted the
winning bidder to check, just to be told by the buyer that he was ‘a collector of broken
laser pointers’. If evidence were needed, this strongly suggests that platforms do not
tightly control their value chain.
19 eBay started with collectibles in 1995, before moving on to computers, books, movies
and consumer electronics in 1997, and to cars, clothing and motors in 1999. These
waves were both driven by users trying to list new products and by eBay’s management
trying to make it easier for people to deal with various product categories.
Chapter 6
Platform-powered ecosystems
Amazon’s ecosystem
Today, Amazon is the largest e-commerce retailer in the US, as well as the
world’s largest provider of cloud computing services.1 For the past 10 years,
Amazon’s growth rate has exceeded 20%2 year after year, recently surpassing
Walmart in market capitalization.3 Somebody who bought $1,000 of Amazon
stocks when it floated in May 1997 would now have approximately $552,700,
equivalent to a yearly return of 38.6%.4
A bit of history
Jeff Bezos founded Amazon in 1994 as an online bookstore. So Amazon started
as a traditional business model but online. The business expanded rapidly from
books to new categories such as CDs, DVDs, electronics, etc. and floated
three years later. In 1999, Amazon launched a separate Web auctions site to
compete with eBay’s fast-growing marketplace. It failed to ignite because
Amazon customers were buyers who were mainly convenience-motivated.
A second attempt, zShops, was based on fixed-price immediate buying but
third-party sellers were in separate parts of the store, which gave buyers a
disjointed customer experience. In 2000, Amazon was a third time lucky when
zShops was merged with the Amazon site and repositioned as Amazon
Marketplace. Deciding to let third-party sellers compete with the retail
business was a very controversial decision internally. Jeff Bezos recalls:
58 Platform-powered ecosystems
So our buyers were extremely concerned – and rightly. They were saying,
‘Let me just make sure I understand this. I might get stuck with inventory
of 10,000 units of this camera that I just loaded up on, and you’re going
to let just anybody come in and take Amazon traffic on what is our primary
retail real estate, which is the detail page, and I’m going to lose the buy
box to this other person because they have a lower price than me?’ And
we said, ‘Yeah, we are.’5
After difficult discussions, Jeff Bezos eventually took the bet to focus on what
was best for customers, and opened its original distribution business on the
producer side. As a result, a single search now returns results from both Amazon
itself and the marketplace merchants. Since then, the e-commerce business has
continued to expand to 15 countries in categories from clothes, furniture, toys
and jewellery to fresh groceries (Amazon Fresh) and daily deal products and
services (Amazon Local). Goods worth over $225 billion were sold in 2015
alone, with Amazon Marketplace representing in excess of 50% of sales.6
Since 2005, online merchants trading on Amazon have benefited from
Fulfilment by Amazon (FBA), a service where Amazon stores, picks, packs
and ships products on behalf of sellers. Amazon also launched Amazon Prime
the same year, a membership service offering buyers free and fast delivery.
Both FBA and Prime are traditional product lines leveraging Amazon’s
excellent logistics capabilities. They have been instrumental in supporting the
e-commerce business.
Amazon also branched out early on into services supporting digital busi-
nesses with Amazon Web Services (AWS), a cloud computing service launched
in 2006. AWS is now the largest cloud service in the world and generated
$12.2 billion in 2016.
Amazon’s first foray into consumer electronics started with the Kindle in
2007, supported by Fire OS, an Android based operating system. Building
on the success of Kindle e-book readers, Amazon later launched the Fire
Tablet, Fire Phone, Fire TV Stick, and more recently Amazon Echo. Amazon
also launched the Amazon Appstore for Android devices, as well as a Mac
download store with games and software for Apple computers.
In 2010, Amazon entered the entertainment and content industry with
Amazon Studios, a studio that develops television shows, movies and comics
from online submissions and crowdsourced feedback, and Amazon Instant
Video, an Internet video on-demand service. Amazon also purchased Twitch.tv
in 2014, a live streaming video platform and community for gamers. Twitch
attracts more than 100 million visitors per month and 1.5 million broadcasters.7
The Amazon timeline (see Figure 6.1) summarizes some of the key
milestones in the development of Amazon’s main lines of business. Over the
Platform-powered ecosystems 59
last 20 years, Amazon has acquired dozens of companies and launched many
services. Our purpose here is not to be exhaustive, but rather to illustrate at
a strategic level how the combination of several business models has allowed
Amazon to successfully develop its platform-powered ecosystem.
E-commerce
Although Amazon started as a pure e-commerce reseller with a curated but
limited range of goods at competitive prices, the integration of a third-party
marketplace platform has been complementary to the reseller model and now
represents over 50% of Amazon’s e-commerce business.8 The platform model
provides many benefits, including diversity and selection of goods offered by
millions of sellers. Outsourcing the risk of holding stock of new product
categories has proven a cost-effective method to manage millions of different
products – the so-called long tail – and scale quickly. This is one of the reasons
marketplaces have the potential to grow at a faster rate than traditional retail
businesses (see Figure 6.2).
60 Platform-powered ecosystems
Amazon constantly learns from sellers and competes with them as a retailer
on popular items. This hybrid model feeds the flywheel of traffic: consumers
are attracted to the site because of the combination of great selection, com-
petitive prices and customer experience. More buyers attract more sellers,
which in turn add to economies of scale that can be passed along by lowering
prices and reducing shipping fees.
Platform-powered ecosystems 61
Amazon’s ecosystem
When more control over the product proposition is required, Amazon uses
more traditional business models. This is the case of Prime for shoppers, FBA
for merchants or cloud services for website owners.
When connecting large numbers of buyers and sellers, as happens with game
developers and gamers, or writers with readers, Amazon uses a platform model
with its Fire OS operating system and its Appstore.11 The launch of the Kindle
(joint hardware and operating system) was instrumental to the development
of the e-book market, resulting in Amazon becoming one of the largest e-
book retailers.
The addition of the Echo product line and Alexa’s always-on voice
recognition interface is a good illustration of this self-reinforcing ecosystem
strategy. Echo/Alexa gives customers access to a multitude of applications
– called ‘skills’ – from third-party developers (a platform), as well as access to
the Amazon site, Amazon Music and other services. Such an ecosystem is not
only more efficient overall, but it is also ‘stickier’ (e.g. it is more difficult for
a consumer to leave the ecosystem due to ‘lock-ins’ and associated ‘switching
costs’ of having to learn a new interface and transfer all their content).12
Leveraging platform business models with more traditional ones was initially
an organic process for Amazon. It was not designed from scratch and there
were trials and errors along the way. It took a couple of years for Amazon
to find the right marketplace model for its e-commerce offering.13 And it
took nearly a decade for Amazon’s platform operating system Fire OS and
associated hardware (Kindle, Fire Phone, Fire Tablet, Fire TV, Echo) to
develop into an integrated offering. The current model is not without its
challenges. Merchants on the marketplace effectively compete with Amazon’s
own retail activities, which creates tension, and the Fire Phone take-up has
been disappointing. But Amazon is now undeniably a sophisticated global
operator that manages a self-reinforcing ecosystem that uses and leverages both
traditional and platform business models wherever they make sense. Amazon
has recently moved into bricks and mortar retail, reinventing the shopping
experience with its Amazon Books stores. Amazon Go, a new ‘Just Walk
Out’ shopping experiment, where customers can shop with no checkout
required, has also launched in early 2017.14
Platform-powered ecosystems 63
Apple’s ecosystem
Apple is one of the largest companies in the world. In 40 years, it has become
a leader in manufacturing computer devices and mobile phones, developing
operating systems and software, and distributing music and digital apps. $1,000
of Apple stock purchased when it floated would now be worth approximately
$220,287, equivalent to a yearly return of 16.3%.15
A bit of history
In 1976, Steve Jobs, Steve Wozniak and Ronald Wayne invented the first
Apple personal computer. Sales grew exponentially and Apple publicly traded
on the stock market in 1980. Over the course of 20 years, Apple released
new and improved versions of its personal computer product line (Apple series,
Macintosh series, PowerBook series), operating systems (System 7, Mac OS)
and a suite of software applications. However, its closed approach and lack
of interoperability with PCs and Microsoft software, which had by then
become the market leader, almost led to its demise.
In 1997, Steve Jobs announced that Microsoft would release new versions
of Microsoft Office for the Macintosh following a historic partnership. Bill
Gates even appeared over a live video feed during that year’s keynote speech
in front of a bewildered audience to announce the new partnership. After a
much-needed $150 million cash investment from arch-enemy Microsoft,
Apple started a new lease of life. In 2001, the first retail store opened, and
the iPod and iTunes launched, as well as Mac OS, a new operating system.
In 2007, Apple’s future took a new course by extending its offering from
computers to mobile electronic devices with the iPhone and its App Store,
a platform selling third-party digital applications. Success was unprecedented,
and by October 2008 Apple was the third-largest mobile handset manufacturer
in the world.16
Since then, more product lines have been successfully introduced, from
the iPad and iCloud, an online storage and syncing service for music, photos,
files and software, to the Apple Watch.
The Apple timeline (see Figure 6.3) summarizes some of the key milestones
in the development of Apple’s key product lines. It is not exhaustive, but is
intended to illustrate how the combination of several underpinning business
models can complement and strengthen Apple’s value propositions.
its operating systems and app stores for computers, mobile phones, tablets and
wearables, Apple manages a two-sided platform between consumers and
software providers. This model fosters a diverse range of software applications.
As of June 2016, Apple’s App Store had more than 2 million applications.18
It is interesting to note that Apple, unlike other marketplaces, remains very
keen to control the experience of its products end-to-end, and has therefore
maintained strong governance around its businesses. Apple’s experience is
heavily mediated and curated; its App Store platform is ‘regulated’, with its
applications selected, controlled and promoted by Apple, who reserve the
Platform-powered ecosystems 65
right to remove apps for any reason.19 Apple’s App Store is far less open than
Google’s or Microsoft’s in that regard.
For iTunes and Apple Music, Apple has chosen a reseller model. Apple
aggregates music from a few major music labels and distributes directly to
consumers. This is a very different model from SoundCloud, which enables
individual artists to upload audio files and share them with friends and wider
communities.
The resulting Apple ecosystem is significantly more powerful than the sum
of its parts. An excellent mobile phone with features far superior to the iPhone
but let down by a sub-par supporting ecosystem (with few apps, etc.) doesn’t
stand a chance in today’s market. In order to take on the iPhone, competitors
need to develop a similarly strong ecosystem of reinforcing business capabilities.
Samsung has been trying to do just that. Nokia, once a mobile leader, failed to
maintain its platform ecosystem and ended up selling its mobile division to
Microsoft, who had been struggling to make significant inroads into the mobile
market despite the strong desktop platform position of Windows.
It is also worth noting that the platform-powered parts of Apple’s business
are the ones growing at the fastest rate, although the positive externalities
created also support the other activities, as would be expected from a self-
reinforcing ecosystem. Apple’s services20 represented 11% of revenues for
2016,21 as shown in Figure 6.4, with a growth rate of 19% year over year for
the first half of 2016.
A closer review of revenues generated by Apple’s non-hardware activities
since 2005 shows how apps, which were responsible for only a fraction of
Apple’s revenues in 2008, are now a multibillion-dollar business. In fact, Tim
Cook expects that it will be ‘the size of a Fortune 100 company by the end
of 2017’.22 And this, of course, excludes the amount of money that was paid
to the developers of these apps (Apple keeps 30% of the price paid for the
apps sold on its App Store).23 When looking at total App Store billings (what
customers actually spend), Figure 6.5 shows that they are now larger than
Hollywood’s US box office revenues and are likely to overtake Hollywood’s
global box office revenues in 2016.24
Apple has been able to match different business models to different activ-
ities in order to design a self-reinforcing business architecture. Apple is still
committed to a unique user experience on each of its device, but it is building
cross-device and cross-service experiences to offer a more unified experience
to both users and developers.25 Apple’s App Stores wouldn’t do as well with-
out Apple’s unique hardware offering, and vice versa.
Figure 6.5 Apple App Store billings vs Hollywood US box office revenues
Source: Apple website, Horace Dediu Asymco, www.asymco.com, Launchworks analysis
Google’s ecosystem
Google is one of the largest and best-known companies in the world. While
the company rebranded itself at the group level as Alphabet, Inc. on 2 October
Platform-powered ecosystems 67
2015, with Google operating as the search engine subsidiary, we use the term
Google to talk about all the group’s activities in this book. A $1,000 investment
in Google stock when it floated in 2004 would now be worth approximately
$15,665, equivalent to a yearly return of 25.6%.26
A bit of history
Founded by Larry Page and Sergey Brin in 1998, Google designed its original
search business around its superior ability to index what content producers
were putting online, mainly in the form of websites, in order to deliver it
to content seekers. Two years later, Google managed to monetize this
capability by selling key search terms in order to improve the visibility of
merchant sites. Advertising revenues are now at the heart of its monetization
strategy,27 with almost 90% of its $90 billion 2016 revenues derived from
AdWords, an online advertising service that places advertising near the list of
search results.
Google also developed a range of complementary products in key verticals
as part of its ecosystem (email, maps, flight information, etc.).
YouTube, the video sharing service that Google acquired in 2007, initially
launched as a two-sided platform connecting viewers and content producers.
Its unique proposition at the time was to allow anyone in the world to get
access to a long tail of amateur home videos, something that was not possible
through traditional TV. Over time, as viewer adoption strengthened,
YouTube started to attract professional and mainstream content producers,28
improving content quality and in turn customer traction. As it reached critical
mass – it’s now the third most visited website in the world29 – YouTube
added advertisers as a third side to monetize the site.
Google is also behind the Android operating system, a suite of software
products including the Chrome browser, associated Chrome laptop pro-
ducts and Android smartphones, as well as fibre access networks in the
US.30 The company also acquired the mobile division of Motorola and its
extensive patent portfolio in 2013. More recently, Google has entered the
‘Internet of things’ (IoT) market with the acquisition of Nest (temperature
control) and Dropcam (video surveillance) as well as the launch of Google
Home (voice activated assistant). Google is also very active in self-driving car
technology, artificial intelligence and, through its ventures arm, an investor
in some of the most promising start-ups in Silicon Valley (including Uber).
Although these different activities may look disparate, they actually create a
powerful ecosystem with complex linkages, as well as unique antitrust
challenges.
Google’s main business lines are presented in Figure 6.6.
68 Platform-powered ecosystems
his ability to interact with fans, his decision has had no impact on his 50+
million subscriber base. YouTube has since introduced better moderation tools,
but the issue of moderation is still lingering, including with YouTube Gaming,
its newly launched live streaming platform for video gaming enthusiasts.32
In this category, real-time conversations are integral to the gaming experience.
YouTube rebuilt the live-streaming platform with a comment system giving
more control to game owners, such as chat moderation, the ability to ban
users, time-out users and ban filtered words.33
YouTube cannot be mentioned without Google+, Google’s fledgling social
network. In an attempt to offer a seamless experience into the Google eco-
system, Google+ was integrated directly with YouTube and the Chrome Web
browser, allowing YouTube videos to be viewed from within the Google+
interface. This meant that users were forced to sign up for accounts if they
wanted to use YouTube channels or accounts. We suspect this move was
mainly designed to ignite and scale Google+ to critical mass and compete
with already established social platforms such as Facebook and Twitter.
Although Google+ claims 2.2 billion accounts, only 9% of its users are active
and post public content.34 Google announced in July 2015 that Google was
scaling back the reach of its social network.35 Services such as YouTube
channels and accounts will be accessible without a Google+ account to
remove unnecessary friction for customers. This decision reflects the difficulty
of scaling a platform to critical mass in an already saturated market . . . even
for Google!
70 Platform-powered ecosystems
Notes
1 Synergy Group, October 2014, www.srgresearch.com/articles/microsoft-cloud-revenues-
leap-amazon-still-way-out-front.
2 Amazon.com website and Statista, www.statista.com/statistics/233761/year-on-year-
revenue-of-amazon-and-ebay-since-2006/.
3 Amazon’s market capitalization is $354 billion and Walmart’s market capitalization is
$217 billion, 12 September 2016.
4 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (15 May 1997 for
Amazon until 29 September 2016) using the online stock return calculator available at
www.buyupside.com/.
5 Julia Kirby and Thomas A. Stewart, ‘The Institutional Yes’, Harvard Business Review,
October 2007.
Platform-powered ecosystems 71
6 www.channeladvisor.com/blog/?pn=scot/deep-dive-into-amazons-q4-results-for-sellers-
whats-cool-100b-and-200b.
7 Wall Street Journal, 29 January 2015, http://blogs.wsj.com/digits/2015/01/29/twitchs-
viewers-reach-100-million-a-month/
8 ChannelAdvisor blog, Scott Wingo, 1 February 2006, www.channeladvisor.com/blog/
?pn=scot/deep-dive-into-amazons-q4-results-for-sellers-whats-cool-100b-and-200b.
9 http://recode.net/2015/01/28/this-could-be-the-year-amazon-finally-reveals-its-most-
important-number/.
10 In a 2014 survey of US sellers, 71% of FBA merchants reported more than a 20% increase
in unit sales after joining FBA, Amazon 2014 Annual Report.
11 It is worth noting that Amazon reused a lot of the open-source Android code that Google
originally developed. FireOS is therefore very close to, but different from, Google
Android OS. For more information, see: www.howtogeek.com/232973/amazons-fire-
os-vs.-googles-android-whats-the-difference/.
12 It is worth noting at this stage that while such tying strategies may be perfectly legitimate
for start-ups, competition authorities and regulators often get concerned when large
established companies – with ‘market power’ – use these tricks. We will discuss regulatory
implications of platform businesses in Chapter 13.
13 In 1999, the company launched Amazon.com Auctions, a Web auctions service that
failed to make a dent in eBay’s large market share. Later that year, Amazon launched
zShops, a fixed-price marketplace and a now defunct partnership with Sotheby’s. In
late 2000, Auctions and zShops morphed into the Amazon Marketplace that we know
today.
14 http://fortune.com/2016/12/05/amazon-go-store/
15 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (12 December 1980
for Apple until 29 September 2016) using the online stock return calculator available at
www.buyupside.com/.
16 Wired, 21 October 2008, www.wired.com/2008/10/with-iphone-app/.
17 Apple is, of course, free to select partners and suppliers, such as Foxconn in China, for
the manufacturing of its products. These outsourcing decisions do not fundamentally
alter the business model of the company, however, since it keeps tight control over the
end-to-end production process of its devices.
18 Statista, June 2016, www.statista.com/statistics/276623/number-of-apps-available-in-
leading-app-stores/.
19 If you want to better understand the nature of this ‘governance’, you may want to have
a look at the App Store guidelines for app developers: https://developer.apple.com/app-
store/review/guidelines/.
20 Apple’s services include the various app stores, as well as iTunes, iCloud, Apple Music,
Apple Pay, Apple Care, licensing and other services.
21 Fiscal data from Apple’s website, www.apple.com/pr/library/2016/.
22 http://uk.businessinsider.com/apple-ceo-tim-cook-services-q3-2016-7.
23 Apple announced in June 2016 that this 30% figure could go down to 15% (with 85%
going to developers) in some circumstances. See www.theverge.com/2016/6/8/
11880730/apple-app-store-subscription-update-phil-schiller-interview.
24 Horace Dediu, Asymco (2014), www.asymco.com/, www.asymco.com/2015/08/26/much-
bigger-than-hollywood/ and www.asymco.com/2015/01/22/bigger-than-hollywood/.
72 Platform-powered ecosystems
25 At the developer level, Apple now allows third-party developers to plug into Siri across
multiple operating systems (iOS, tvOS and macOS). At the user level, the new macOS
version allows users to copy something on the Mac or iPhone and paste it on the other
device. And if users buy an app for the iPad, iOS’s automatic app download to tvOS
means that it will automatically show up on the Apple TV.
26 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (19 August 2004
for Google until 29 September 2016) using the online stock return calculator available
at www.buyupside.com/.
27 Google Investor Relations, 2016 Financial Tables, http://investor.google.com/financial/
tables.html.
28 Which YouTube supported with its Partner Program, making it possible to earn a
substantial living as a video producer.
29 As of June 2015, according to third-party Web analytics providers Alexa and SimilarWeb.
30 Although this may have more to do with its bargaining power with operators arguing
against net neutrality than with Google’s core strategy of organizing the world’s
information.
31 See Guardian, 3 September 2014, www.theguardian.com/technology/2014/sep/03/
pewdiepie-switches-off-youtube-comments-its-mainly-spam.
32 YouTube Gaming launched on 26 August 2015 in response to Twitch.tv, the leading
video streaming platform purchased by Amazon. YouTube Gaming is available as a
website globally and has iOS and Android apps in the US and UK. Announced in June,
the new portal includes a directory of more than 25,000 games, each with their own
profile page collecting related YouTube videos.
33 Ryan Wyatt interview, YouTube’s head of gaming, 26 August 2015, www.the
guardian.com/technology/2015/aug/26/youtube-gaming-live-website-apps.
34 Business Insider, ‘Nobody Is Using Google+’, 20 January 2015, http://uk.business
insider.com/google-active-users-2015-1
35 Google Blog, 27 July 2015, http://googleblog.blogspot.co.uk/2015/07/everything-in-
its-right-place.html.
36 Stock returns computed using monthly price services from IPO date (respectively 18
May 2012 for Facebook and 13 March 1986 for Microsoft until 29 September 2016)
using the online stock return calculator available at www.buyupside.com/.
37 Microsoft’s intent when acquiring Nokia’s mobile phone division in 2014 for $7.2 billion
was to create added value by combining Microsoft’s software and services with Nokia’s
hardware assets. It was a failure, with Microsoft writing off $7.6 billion two years later.
38 According to Benedict Evans.
39 http://newsroom.fb.com/news/2014/02/facebook-to-acquire-whatsapp/
40 www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052702303815404577333840377381670
41 www.facebook.com/zuck/posts/10101319050523971?stream_ref=1
Chapter 7
• Pre-launch, when the platform is designed and built prior to its launch.
• Ignition, when the platform is tested and launched. The recruitment of
participants may happen sequentially, on the producer side first (path A
in Figure 7.1), or the user side (path B).
• Scaling-up, when building a critical mass of participants on all sides of the
platform becomes key. The ratio of producers and users will need to be
kept within an equilibrium (path C).
• Maturity, or how to continue to grow the business while defending against
new entrants and existing competitors.
74 Life stages of platforms: design
The four life stages are presented in the next four chapters and summarized
in Table 7.1. You can either read these four chapters sequentially or simply
go to the section most relevant to you given the life stage of your plat-
form. If you’re not interested in life stage deep dives, you can go straight to
Chapter 11 on pricing.
Key priorities Platform Design Platform Fit Customer /Transaction Business growth
Market Sizing Build liquidity growth Profitability
Prototyping Raise capital Balanced and relevant Platform Power
liquidity Brand
Trust and loyalty
Team culture and
recruitment
Attract Define value propositions Build liquidity Strengthen liquidity New markets and
sustainable growth
Who are the key participants? Experiment/decide market side Build liquidity whilst keeping Extend value propositions to
What is the value proposition focus and ignition sequence i.e. growth balanced and within meet participants’ needs and
for each side of the platform? which side should be recruited equilibrium limits compete against other offers
What tools/services should first Get insights into tipping point/ Focus on retention in existing
the platform provide to Users, Attract identifiable target critical mass, network value and markets and acquisition in
Producers? communities level of network effects new markets
Iterate value propositions based Focus on participant acquisition
on market feedback to find first then retention
platform fit
Match Define matching/filter Build matching effectiveness Improve matching Strengthen matching
criteria effectiveness effectiveness
How will the matching be Review matching criteria and Automate and optimize matching Optimize matching at mass
done? filters to improve relevance, depth of scale
What are the key matching results and timeliness Blend AI to matching/search
criteria to capture? algorithms
Connect Define interactions Remove friction between Improve Connection Strengthen Connection
between participants participants effectiveness effectiveness
What is the nature/type of Clear interaction bottlenecks Encourage positive interactions Review/simplify interactions
interactions? Review rules and norms to at scale and discourage as value propositions
How will Users/Producers encourage positive interactions negative ones mature and network effects
interact? and limit negative ones are at scale
Directly/indirectly?
Transact Define core transactions Remove friction between Scale core transactions Maximize core
between participants participants transactions
What is the nature/type of Clear core interaction Continue to clear core Continue to clear core
core transactions? bottlenecks interaction bottlenecks interaction bottlenecks
Table 7.1 continued
Which side adds the most Elements needed post-transaction Deploy monetization when/if Monetize for profitable
value? How is it enabled? (delivery, cancellation, etc.) relevant growth
How to monetize? Which Consider the range of possible
side(s) to charge? price options to quickly attract
most valuable customers
(including freemium)
Optimize Define North Star and Monitor North Star and Monitor North Star and Monitor North Star and
key KPIs ignition KPIs scaling KPIs maturity KPIs
What are the North Star KPIs to track North Star, platform KPIs to track North Star, KPIs to track North Star,
and key KPIs? fit, liquidity, matching effectiveness, participant acquisition/retention, new markets and on-going
core interaction bottlenecks and liquidity and balance, matching/ growth, matching
raising capital connection effectiveness, trust and optimization, monetization/
customer experience, brand profitability, customer
awareness success and innovation
Enablers
UX What is the desired level of Optimize UX to remove Continue to optimize UX to Simplify UX as more
control from the platform? bottlenecks reduce friction functionality gets
What are main flows? introduced
Payments What are the key payment Implement payment solution Scale payment solution Investigate upside of
flows? (if needed) (if needed) optimizing payments/
generating other revenue
streams
Infrastructure Make or buy platform Infrastructure to support Scale IT infrastructure Keep infrastructure
infrastructure? platform fit up to date
Governance What are the rules of access Adjust governance principles as Adjust governance principles for Consolidate governance
and engagement for Producers and Users join the mass scale principles
Producers, Users? platform and engage Automate conflict resolution
Will pricing be centralized/ Set the rules for conflict Community management and tools
decentralized? resolution
How to capture/distribute value
Trust What framework to establish Map key trust interactions Deploy solid Trust and Safety Consolidate Trust and
trust? framework and scale customer Safety framework
service teams
Brand What does the brand stand for Ensure brand identity/design is Consolidate brand to appeal to Consolidate brand to
and how does this translate aligned with platform fit mass market audience appeal to new and
into visual identity/design? existing audiences
Source: Launchworks
Life stages of platforms: design 77
focusing on the things that are really different for platform businesses. We will
focus on business-related issues rather than technical questions. This is because
a successful platform is first and foremost a business construct later supported
by the right technical infrastructure.
The key pre-launch questions summarized in Figure 7.2 are developed
below.
Before attracting anybody to a platform, it is critically important to under-
stand who the key platform participants will be, and what kind of value
proposition will be offered to them. As we will see, the concept of value pro-
position is an interesting one in this context since some of the platform
participants are also co-creating value on the platform. While their expected
contribution needs to be defined and incentivized by the platform, it cannot,
by definition, be entirely controlled, but merely influenced.3
A good way to think about value creation is to map participants’
contributions out using a simple matrix, presented in Table 7.3, to describe
the value proposition to and from each stakeholder.
Identify participants
It is useful, as a preliminary step, to identify key participants involved with
the platform.
Sides: the distinct and diverse groups of customers or entities being connected
by the platform. For two-sided platforms, they are typically segmented into
two groups: one on the supply side (often called producers) and the other on
the demand side (often called users or consumers). They are jointly called
‘platform participants’.
• Producers: individuals, communities, businesses or entities delivering value
created on and/or through the platform. For example, eBay sellers, Kiva
borrowers, Kickstarter creators, Reddit content contributors. The producers
side can be further segmented if it is made of different customer groups.
For example, eBay sellers can be segmented into consumer sellers and
business sellers, and even broken down even further by product categories
(e.g. professional fashion sellers, non-professional coin collectors, etc.).
Life stages of platforms: design 79
Market sizing
A necessary second step is to ‘quantify’ the number of possible platform
participants in order to get a sense for the market potential. Typically, this
requires a high-level, top-down estimate of classic marketing metrics such as
the total addressable market (TAM), the serviced addressable market (SAM)
and the target market (TM).
Using Airbnb as an illustration, the TAM would be all days/nights where
properties are empty, the SAM would be restricted to areas where it is pos-
sible to rent from a regulatory perspective, and the TM would be the
segment of people who would be open to renting their home. The TM can
of course be sub-segmented further by age group, geographies, risk aversion,
etc.
Market sizing is a traditional step for all start-up businesses, but with
platform businesses this requires some specific considerations, since:
• You need to get a sense of who in your market will be a platform participant.
Some people will never share their flat when they go on holiday. Some
people only want to go to hotels. Some platforms will require ownership
of a smartphone.
80 Life stages of platforms: design
• Your market sizing needs to ensure that there is a critical mass of participants
on both sides of the platform as quickly as possible so that your proposition
is ‘liquid’ and transactions are maximized.
• It is important to be careful when using existing market information and
statistics, since, more often than not, these have been framed in the context
of traditional businesses rather than platforms. For example, had Uber based
its business on the size of the taxi market, it would have significantly
underestimated the opportunity. In fact, 3 years after entry Uber managed
to grow the San Francisco taxi market by a factor of 3.5.4
Market focus
Which parts of the market do you intend to focus on first? Should you tar-
get a well-defined vertical first and then expand to other ones, and if so
which ones?
Level of intermediation
Will platform participants connect directly or indirectly? Direct platforms allow
for direct connection between customers, while indirect platforms connect
two or more customer groups indirectly. For example, card companies, such
as Visa or Mastercard, go through banks to issue their cards and acquire the
merchants that will accept cards. These intermediaries – so-called card issuers
and merchant acquirers – are effectively the ones in contact with the end
Life stages of platforms: design 81
Governance
What are the main rules governing the platform?
• Users and producers joining rules: Who should be allowed to join the
platform? Everyone (open) or a curated few (closed)? How can the
positioning of your platform encourage your target users to join (and keeps
others at bay)?
• Centralized/decentralized governance: Will you keep control of manage-
ment decisions? For example, will the pricing of products and services
on the platform be delegated to the ecosystem stakeholders (i.e. eBay
sellers setting product prices) or will it be under the platform’s control
(i.e. Uber setting car ride tariffs).
• User experience control: How much of the user experience should you
control vs platform producers/users?
• Users and producers operating rules: What should be the rules for users
and producers to keep the right to interact and transact on the platform?
82 Life stages of platforms: design
Attract
Using the platform stakeholders identified above, it is helpful to go through
the value they bring to the platform – as well as the value that the platform
brings to them – to ensure that the overall architecture is consistent with the
type of self-reinforcing community model that powers most platforms.
For traditional businesses, this is a fairly straightforward exercise, as shown
in Table 7.2 for the Hilton Group.
The exercise is, however, a bit more complex for a multisided business
because: (i) there is more than one value proposition to define; and (ii) several
stakeholders can contribute, which is a significant difference from traditional
businesses. A good way to do this methodically is to use the matrix in
Table 7.3 and map each value proposition, and associated contributions from
Users, producers and partners will need tools and services to encourage
contributions. We therefore recommend mapping the likely tools and services
required for each customer group to facilitate them joining and operating on
the platform.
84 Life stages of platforms: design
The design of tools and associated features will largely be driven by how
platform owners plan to structure content from producers and users. This
question is particularly important for product marketplaces, such as Amazon
Marketplace or Etsy, for example. While Amazon manages a predefined
catalogue template against which sellers can create listings, craft marketplace
Etsy allows each listing to contain product information that is completely
custom. Etsy, however, prescribes a template with required fixed attributes,
such as the listing title, description, price, delivery cost and availability, in
order to control the front-end experience, while allowing the seller to be
relatively free-form with their supplied content. By contrast, social platforms
such as community forum Reddit or Facebook allow users to post largely
unstructured content in a free-form format. These considerations impact how
much control the platform owner applies to producer content, and this has
a direct impact on the matching, connect, trust and brand dimensions.
Match
Matching is a platform-specific activity, and key questions need to be addressed
at this platform design stage:
• What will be the matching criteria that need to be captured by the plat-
form?
• Will the matching rely on structured and formatted content or free-flow
content? Will the function be automated or manual and done by the
platform owner (in the early days)?
• To what extent will people self-select? For example, are people expected
to apply filters themselves to access relevant content?
form participant activity – who they’ve liked, sent charms to or had a con-
versation with.
Connect
Many platforms need to also enable peer-to-peer connection between platform
participants post-matching because the combination of these enabling
interactions drives the overall core transactions. Key questions at this stage
include:
• What will be the type and nature of interactions between users and
producers?
• How will users and producers interact on- and off-platform?
• How much structure should be applied to participants’ interactions?
• How can interactions be captured in a way that will enhance the platform’s
matching and support core transactions?
Transact
The ultimate goal of platforms is to maximize the number of value-adding
core transactions. Beyond defining what the core transaction actually is, clarity
on the following questions will be useful:
Optimize
Although there is no data available at pre-launch to optimize the platform,
it is appropriate to think about the type of data that the platform could usefully
capture without increasing friction too much.
Key questions at this stage include:
• What information will the platform need to gather in order to test the
main hypotheses behind the business case?
• Which interactions between platform participants can be captured in a
small set of key performance indicators (KPIs) to track platform
developments and help identify bottlenecks as it scales?
• Which metrics can best measure platform success?
While the selection of KPIs is not an exact science, we found that the
following principles were often helpful in the context of platform design.
The definition of a generic overriding growth metric, that we call a ‘North
Star’, can be helpful to track the overall health of the platform community.
Beyond encapsulating a key growth dimension, it also represents the key
engagement/core transaction of the platform. The North Star metric should
be fully endorsed and championed by the CEO, and remains the same
through growth stages to guide all employees.
Selecting the right North Star metric depends on the type of platform you
are running. It is important to note that the core transaction may take place
Life stages of platforms: design 87
off the platform (e.g. dates or restaurant meals), and so a proxy metric may
be needed. The types of key engagement metrics include value exchanged
(e.g. gross merchandise value for marketplaces such as eBay or Etsy), transaction
numbers (e.g. nights booked at Airbnb,7 messages sent for WhatsApp), activity
or participation metrics (e.g. posts or monthly active users for social media8),
expressions of interest or connections that lead to off-platform transactions
(e.g. restaurant bookings on OpenTable).
Tracking of user behaviours through the various rocket stages gives a help-
ful picture of the platform’s overall health. As we will see in the next three
chapters, the key for each stage is to find relevant metrics that capture the
main enabling interaction as well as core transactions.
Enablers
Like any business, it is important to sketch the type of user experience the
platform will deliver, the interface it will need, how payments (if any) will
be made and what type of technical architecture it may have, as well as the
company’s key brand attributes and culture. Pre-launch, most of the above
topics are similar to traditional firms, but the following are platform-specific.
is likely to be the fastest and least risky solution – at least in the short term.
For well-defined verticals such as marketplaces for products, some well-
developed software solutions9 do exist. Solutions are usually Software as a
Service (SaaS)-based and priced on a revenue sharing model, which may be
fine initially but can become fairly costly for the platform owner as the platform
scales.
If you’re starting from scratch, or are addressing a specific vertical that is
not covered by existing software solutions, you may need to build the platform
infrastructure yourself. Bespoke development will give more control and the
ability to iterate quickly and customize the experience from a producer, user
and owner perspective. More investment will be required up front for
technical design and development. So it may be the preferred solution for
founders who know how to code, or for established firms with access to quality
developers.
The answer also depends upon the strategy planned to overcome the
chicken-and-egg problem described in the next chapter. If the initial focus
is on recruiting one side of the market first, the early technology selection
needs to consider this. Many successful start-ups launched basic concept
validation using off-the-shelf ‘pipe’ software designed for one side of the
market (usually the user side), such as Shopify or Magento, while manually
dealing with the back-end supply side.10 However, this may not always be
feasible if building liquidity on both sides is a really important driver early
on. When possible, though, this path enables market validation on a reduced
budget until you can demonstrate traction. Migration to a more scalable
infrastructure later on may be painful, but this transition may be the price to
pay for de-risking development costs up front.
The market for off-the-shelf platform software is changing rapidly, though.
Mirakl, Izberg, Near-me, Sharetribe and Marketplace Lab offer off-the-shelf
marketplace solutions for retailers, while Upwork offers white-label freelancer
marketplace solutions to large corporates. As the platform market matures,
we anticipate enterprise software vendors to develop platform solutions tailored
to specific verticals (telecoms, health, professional services, etc.) and offer
platform as a service – or PaaS – solutions.
both a help and a hindrance in the context of a platform play. Some of the
difficulties for existing firms considering a transition to a platform model or
add-on will be discussed in Chapter 14.
Notes
1 Business model generation, with its previously mentioned business model canvas tool,
is a good start.
2 Eric Ries’s The Lean Startup has become a de rigueur read for any would-be entrepreneur
keen to change the world on a limited budget. See E. Ries, The Lean Startup, New
York: Crown Publishing, 2011.
3 While Hilton can manage and tightly control the experience of its guests, Airbnb can
only influence the experience provided by the hosts.
4 Henry Blodget, 19 January 2015, Business Insider, http://uk.businessinsider.com/uber-
revenue-san-francisco-2015-1.
5 Hilton Investor Presentation, November 2015.
6 The Platform Design Toolkit 2.0, the ecosystem’s motivation matrix, by Simone Cicero,
www.meedabyte.com.
7 Airbnb CEO Brian Chesky routinely tweets their nights booked milestones.
8 Alex Schultz, How to Start a Start-up, Lecture 6: Growth, Sam Altman.
9 We have seen a number of interesting implementations of Mirakl at Galeries Lafayette,
Darty, Halfords and l’Equipe.
10 LoveKnitting, the marketplace for knitting yarn, patterns and needles, was initially built
on Magento. Truly, a marketplace for unique experiences, was initially built on an even
tighter budget, using WordPress and WooCommerce, before migrating to Magento.
Chapter 8
Platform ignition
Proving the concept
The business architecture of the platform has been designed and a technical
solution has been built for ignition. The platform now needs to be launched
and platform participants recruited in order to test the platform’s concept.
The key challenge at this stage is typically to develop a minimum viable
product (MVP) of the platform that allows you to attract enough producers
and users in order to test your business hypothesis. You need to decide which
side to attract first and how to go about it. Since the platform hasn’t yet got
many users, there will be opportunities for iterating on the proposition, testing
additional features, different market channels, etc.
The main objective of this ignition stage is for your platform to pass the
product/market fit test that we also call ‘platform fit’, since it tests whether
the platform is able to attract, match, connect and enable transactions among
its participants. It would be very difficult for anybody to attract significant
capital to scale before showing a genuinely strong engagement from customers,
at least in a given market niche/community.
Finding this ‘platform fit’ is not straightforward and may require many
iterations of the original concept. It is, however, critical that the platform
manages to find its ‘fit’ relatively quickly since, unlike other more traditional
business models, platforms are only viable after they reach a critical mass
of participants.1 If it takes too much time for the platform to attract enough
participants, the platform is in danger of losing momentum and ‘unravelling’.
This is what happens when users are not finding what they are looking
for because the platform is subscale (e.g. imagine a dating site with only a
few profiles). If the platform is free, then its perceived value may still be positive
without much scale. But if the platform is already charging for its services,
participants are likely to be less forgiving.
Conversely, moving to the scaling phase should only take place once the
‘platform fit’ is validated. Understanding any technical or product obstacles
for platform participants to experience their ‘magic moment’ on the platform
92 Platform ignition: proving the concept
(i.e. the moment where they experience real value) is also a prerequisite. It
is much easier to make changes to the value proposition with few customers
than at scale.
The ignition stage is also the stage at which contracts need to be drafted
and signed by platform participants. These are very important and need to
clarify the responsibilities and liabilities of the parties (platform owner,
producers and users). Platform contracts also need to make it clear that
platform participants are not employees of the firm.
Getting the ‘cookie cutter’ right before scaling is therefore one of the key
objectives of the ignition phase.
The key ignition questions of Figure 8.1 are developed below. There are
two distinct scenarios. The first one is launching a platform from scratch. It
creates a unique chicken-and-egg problem: Which side of the platform should
be attracted first? The second scenario is when the platform is launched as an
add-on to an existing business.
to grow a vibrant online community of people who were very often both
buyers and sellers. This overlap of roles is very useful in terms of entry point
for platforms, since a new platform participant will be adding value to the
platform both as a buyer/user and seller/producer. Meshed communities with
significant overlap are often prioritized as entry points for this reason.
Match
Since the platform is now live, the objective is to make sure the matching works
on a small scale. Even if aspects of the matching still require manual inter-
ventions, it becomes important to start thinking about ways to automate this.
Key matching questions include:
Depth of results
At launch, the platform may suffer from a lack of selection/choice for both
sides. As a result, the matching criteria need to be defined to maximize
liquidity.
98 Platform ignition: proving the concept
Timeliness
Many platforms try to display matching results instantly to meet participants’
needs. At the ignition stage, though, matching may still be done manually
for a range of platforms – say, a marketplace matching an expert consultant
with a complex technical assignment.
However, when participant behaviour is well understood, timely does not
always mean immediately. Carwow, the marketplace matching car buyers
and dealers, discovered that conversion rates were higher when search results
were not sent immediately to potential buyers, but a few hours later, as if the
platform was effectively taking time to negotiate on their behalf.
Connect
At ignition, the connect function may be quite basic, but the key questions
include:
Transact
At this stage, the main focus should be testing the proof of concept of the
prototype platform. The key questions are whether or not the interactions
previously identified are indeed leading to core transactions and under which
conditions:
Building liquidity and network effects are often more important priorities
than monetization at this stage. However, while the priority should be
growing network effects, monetization experiments can be useful to develop
organizational expertise on revenue systems and operations, and to answer
monetization questions of investors in follow-up rounds. Facebook had small
advertising revenues from its very beginnings. LinkedIn also started to generate
revenues 18 months after launch.21 The interplay between pricing and revenue
generation is developed further in Chapter 11.
Optimize
The optimization process is quite critical during the ignition stage. In fact,
the platform is likely to change quite dramatically in the early days based on
participants’ direct and indirect feedback. One of the unique features of
platforms is that development can be shaped at least as much by participants
as by platform owners. This endows the platform with some strategic flexibility
that traditional businesses would only dream of, since participants can start
using the platforms for a range of activities that may not have been even
identified as opportunities at the outset.22 Some key optimization questions
at ignition are:
• Are the metrics giving a good sense of bottleneck formation that prevents
core transactions?
• Is feedback from platform participants taken on board?
• Are the key datapoints/insights needed to demonstrate traction captured?
• Does the optimization process enable convergence towards platform fit?
Enablers
Typically, many of the platform-enabling capabilities, from governance, trust,
brand and customer experience, to infrastructure support, are in their infancy
at launch. They are there to support the MVP and make sure that early traction
can be demonstrated. Platform owners should be thinking about the following
questions:
Platform ignition: proving the concept 101
This doesn’t mean that enabling capabilities are not important, but rather
that they are unlikely to be immediate bottlenecks at ignition. If early parti-
cipants are tech-savvy early adopters who like the platform concept, they won’t
mind the imperfections and will willingly provide feedback to improve the
user experience. As the number of participants is still small, the launch team
should be able to be right on top of any participant issue that comes up,
and update governance rules on an ongoing basis. Participants should feel
Platform fit
• Engagement: % of sign-ups that search, connect, transact
• Customer feedback: particularly qualitative
• Customer retention: % of users that remain active, ‘retention curves’
Clearing core interaction bottlenecks
Liquidity:
• Ratio of active users (producers) to total users (producers) and ratio of active users to
active producers
• Number of active users/producers vs minimum liquidity target
• On-boarding completion rates
• Fulfilment completion rates and time (e.g. suppliers delivering goods on time), waiting times
for users (e.g. Uber car waiting times)
• Utilization rate of any seeded liquidity (e.g. utilization rates of Uber drivers directly
employed vs the minimum utilization to be viable)
• Ratio of nil return search queries to total search queries
Matching effectiveness:
• Ratio of searches to core transactions
• Ratio of matches to core transactions
• Quality of supplier presentation (e.g. Airbnb listings and professional photography bookings)
Metrics to raise capital
• Growth rate of active users and producers (above some defined activity level, e.g. Instagram
daily active users)
• Viral coefficient and breakdown of paid vs organic viral growth
• Speed to saturation in targeted niche markets (e.g. Facebook penetration in college
campuses)
• Super user segments (e.g. % of users above higher engagement level thresholds)
• Revenue proxies: metrics correlated with revenue
Source: Launchworks
102 Platform ignition: proving the concept
Notes
1 www.launchworksventures.com/insights/scaling-up-a-necessity-for-platform-businesses/.
2 OpenTable was able to reach a critical mass of restaurants and diners in some cities first
where it launched its platform. It still sold its online booking tools to restaurants in other
markets where it was building its presence.
3 See http://venturebeat.com/2012/06/22/reddit-fake-users/.
4 There are many examples of allegations of fake profile schemes. In 2014, the Federal
Trade Commission reached a settlement that prohibits JDI Dating Ltd., the British
company that owns 18 dating sites, from using fake, computer-generated profiles to trick
users into upgrading to paid memberships and charging these members a recurring
monthly fee without their consent: www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2014/10/
online-dating-service-agrees-stop-deceptive-use-fake-profiles.
5 See Chris Dixon’s blog post on the topic, www.businessinsider.com/the-bowling-pin-
strategy-2010-8?IR=T.
6 Facebook has in excess of 1 billion users logging in daily and monthly active users in
excess of 1.7 billion at the time of writing.
Platform ignition: proving the concept 103
Platform scaling
Reaching critical mass
Congratulations, the platform has been ignited and the business concept pro-
ven. Now that you have clearly demonstrated a valid platform concept and
early traction, more funding will be required to support the scaling-up phase
and really take the ‘rocket’ into orbit. Since this growth stage can take several
years and a number of funding rounds, it covers a wide range of business
situations, but the key questions remain the same.
Platform fit is a prerequisite for successful scaling. Otherwise, the money
spent on marketing to acquire lots of customers is unlikely to generate
customer engagement and value creation. We agree with Sean Ellis, CEO of
GrowthHackers, who says that ‘you should survey your user base before doing
growth work. At least 40% of your users should say they would be very
disappointed if your service or product went away overnight’.1 If the platform
is part of an add-on to an existing business, or part of a transformation, it is also
important to ensure that scaling investment is not available ‘too early’. While
this may sound counterintuitive, the danger for large firms keen to push their
new platforms is to invest in scaling before the platform fit is achieved.
This stage is critical for the platform since it is likely to have to go through
the usual ‘growth pains’ associated with scaling-up. This includes preserving
the winning culture, introducing new scalable processes, attracting talents,
looking beyond domestic boundaries, attracting significant growth investments,
navigating regulatory hurdles and attracting growth capital,2 to name a few.
This critical growth phase is also a unique period of transition between the
well-documented and supported start-up stage and the more traditional
challenges associated with the management of large firms. There are now
excellent resources3 and tips on scaling-up that, while not always uniquely
tailored to platforms, are highly relevant to inform and guide the platform
owners during this important phase.
From a platform point of view, the main challenge is to grow each side to
critical mass in a balanced way. The monetization question may also become
106 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass
important during the scaling-up stages, although in some cases this question
is only relevant after a critical mass has been reached. Lastly, the existence of
imitators in other countries may provide an added stimulus for some platforms
to scale globally as quickly as possible.4
During the scaling phase, the following activities should be in focus:
• Use of marketing levers to keep growth balanced between the two sides.
• Reduce friction (improve customer experience) to increase velocity.
• Get insights into tipping point/critical mass, network value and level of
network effects.
• Foster trust and safety, and scale customer service team.
• Deploy and optimize pricing model.
• Develop a distinctive brand that resonates with customers on both sides
of the platform.
The key scaling questions summarized in Figure 9.1 are developed below.
Attract
Scaling effectively will probably require significant investment in customer
acquisition not only to gain traction, but also to create a viral acquisition
effect. For some platforms, often those with a social network component such
as Facebook, Instagram or LinkedIn, the all-important ‘viral coefficient’ (also
sometimes called K-factor or contagion coefficient)5 will become critical
since it will contribute significantly to the traction of the platform and the
efficiency of marketing.
that magical moment right has had a profound impact on both user retention
and engagement. The on-boarding process should be designed to enable these
‘magical moments’.
On-boarding can often be more complex on the producer side for two
reasons. First, the platform may try to apply quality filters on the producers it
accepts. For example, TaskRabbit helpers go through a screening process,
including interviews, before being able to offer their services on the platform.
There is a trade-off between the selectivity level of the platform towards
producers and achieving critical mass as soon as possible. The dynamics
between the level of openness for producers joining the platform and the joining
customer experience can, however, be flexed over time as the platform scales.
When Uber launched in the UK in 2012, drivers had to go through a com-
prehensive training before being able to register on the platform. Three years
later, the on-boarding process still includes driver screening but is now much
simpler and faster. The Uber ‘ignite’ programme offers a step-by-step process
for securing the required licence and, depending on the country, get specific
training, tests, medical exams, access to a car and insurance marketplace, visit
of Uber offices and financial incentive to start as an Uber driver.7 It is designed
to minimize the friction and assist would-be Uber drivers with the entire process
of joining the platform. It benefited from the feedback of many Uber drivers
who helped identify bottlenecks on the driver recruitment side.
Second, new producers may need to familiarize themselves with tools to
engage and ultimately transact on the platform. Depending on the complexity
of the on-boarding process, email, phone, training or even dedicated account
management resources should be allocated. The level of support should be
proportionate to the effort required for producers to interact and therefore may
vary across customer segments. eBay provides email support for consumer sellers
registering a listing on the marketplace, a five-step process that is designed to
take no more than a few minutes. For large merchants and brands, a dedicated
team of account managers is on call to help with listing catalogues and
integrating eBay as part of their multichannel strategy. The on-boarding process
is also a unique opportunity to convey key messages about the ethos, govern-
ance principles and norms of good behaviours to new platform participants.
1 Direct acquisition of new producers and new users by the platform. The platform
markets directly and acquires producers and users, through organic (press,
SEO, email, social media, direct mail, etc.) and paid acquisition channels.
2 Acquisition of new users through existing producers. The producers themselves
market the benefits of joining and using the platform to their customers
and people in their network. This can be through word of mouth, social
media or platform tools aimed at helping producers advertise. Indiegogo,
Kickstarter and other crowdfunding platforms have viral invite loops
enabling project owners to invite people in their network to join in and
110 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass
to measure initially because the numbers may not be significant enough. This
is especially true for transactional platforms where the frequency of interaction
and transaction is low – for example, legal services platforms where a client
may hire a lawyer for a one-off case. It is, however, essential to have a sense
of how many users and producers are no longer engaged and why, and
customer feedback is a good way to do this (Net Promoter Score11 surveys,
for example). For these reasons, retention efforts at the beginning of the scaling
stage tend to focus on product and customer experience improvements, and
reviews of user and producer funnels.
As the platform scales and more users and producers join, get matched,
connect and transact on the platform, network effects start to kick in and the
value proposition becomes richer for all participants. Such positive feedback
loops may translate into more selection for users, more reviews for producers
and more overall traffic, which in turn attract more users and producers.
A review of the value proposition might be useful at this stage to understand
what users and producers value most in the platform, and what features/
attributes are currently missing. Tools and services can make a significant
contribution to producer engagement. Beyond traffic, Amazon Marketplace
offers bulk listing, editing and management tools to enable merchants to list
and update listings as efficiently as possible. Sometimes important aspects of
the value proposition are outside of the direct control of the platform. For
example, Deliveroo, the food delivery platform, discovered that many of its
drivers were joining while learning English before trying to become Uber
drivers. This became an unexpected part of Deliveroo’s value proposition to
its drivers.
Key needs • Sales velocity • Sales velocity • Reliable way to sell an item
• Profitability • Make money • Easy to list/sell and ship
• Reliability/predictability • Support from the community and • Make some money (often to
marketplace fund buying activity)
• Safety
What each • Scalability offers growth potential • Bring unique long tail inventory • Extremely active buyers
segment brings in fashion and collectibles • Provides wide range of unique
• High concentration
to the table inventory: 50% of used items,
• Offer unique, personable
• 90% new inventory C2C auction inventory provides
e-commerce experience
• Offer trusted, e-commerce-like best value vs competition
experience
• Selling drives engagement and
loyalty/word of mouth
Source: Launchworks
114 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass
At the end of the scaling phase, it is common for platforms to cater for the
needs of several consumer and producer segments. A C2C, B2C and B2B13
skill set is often required to understand the motivations of these diverse
customer segments, and how to best attract them.
Match
At this stage of development, the matching function can quickly become a
real bottleneck if it does not efficiently match users with relevant producers.
cope with the level of activity generated at scale. BlaBlaCar started to grow
rapidly in 2012, and by January 2013 the number of rides booked on the
platform had hit 50 million.14 The in-house search engine became a bottleneck.
It was not scalable enough to consistently return search results in less than
200 milliseconds, and could not support more complex queries and new
features beyond a basic geographical search. BlaBlaCar completely redesigned
and migrated its search engine in 2013 with limited customer disruption and
has been scaling aggressively ever since.
Connect
As we have seen, facilitating positive interactions – and preventing negative
ones – between participants on the platform is a way to enhance positive net-
work effects.
Using eBay as an illustrative example in Table 9.2, mapping the core inter-
actions between the different sides of a platform can be a valuable scaling tool
to identify inefficiencies, governance or trust issues that may not have surfaced
during the ignition phase.
As eBay scaled to categories with fixed-priced, high-volume and low-
margin items, a review of interactions between eBay sellers and buyers
revealed new inefficiencies. Being able to ask questions to sellers prior to
purchase made sense in categories with unique, high-value inventory such as
cars and collectables. However, high-volume, low-margin items also generated
a high level of questions, often making the sales process inefficient for
merchants. eBay subsequently introduced new features such as product listing
FAQs and product catalogues to reduce most buyers’ generic queries.
116 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass
Transact
Enabling transactions is the raison d’être of platforms, so the scaling phase must
ensure that transactions occur as smoothly as possible.
Since the platform is now fully operational, it is often useful to use
transaction metrics in marketing and communication briefs as social proof to
further increase trust. In some cases, the platform enables ‘ultimate’ transac-
tions, such as weddings for dating sites. eHarmony reports being responsible
for more than 2 million marriages.
The scaling phase is often the phase when monetization needs to be intro-
duced to ensure that the platform generates enough revenues going forward.15
The various pricing levers available in the context of monetization, and their
respective strengths and weaknesses, are discussed in Chapter 11 on pricing.
Optimize
The optimization function should focus on the development of metrics that
can help monitor and adjust the growth trajectory of the platform. During
the scaling-up phase, the platform needs to maximize its viral impact and
ensure it is focused on the needs of the marginal user so that growth continues.
The optimization function should monitor individual building blocks of
the rocket model and look for bottlenecks. It should also develop a more
holistic view of its ecosystem and its alignment with the platform itself. Some
of the key questions at this stage are:
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 117
A few generic metric examples are given in Table 9.3. Note that the ‘North
Star’, introduced in Chapter 7, should ideally continue to act as the overarching
growth metric for the business.16
Attracting participants
• Growth rate of interactions
• Growth rate of active users and producers
• Cohort analysis of growth, % of interactions from ‘new’ users
•‘ New/marginal’ user feedback
• Viral coefficient, breakdown of paid vs organic viral growth
• Retention curves, frequency/number of interactions per user
Liquidity and balance
• Number of/ratio of active producers/users above some activity threshold (e.g. Upwork
sets targets for the number of workers per posting)
• Liquidity failures (i.e. opening Uber app and finding no cars)
• Growth in listings per supplier
• % of listings that receive no interaction (e.g. eBay listings with no bids)
• Value received by each platform side to determine balance (i.e. pricing, marketing and
feature development)
Matching/connection effectiveness
• Interactions: impressions, purchases per week, sales conversion rate
• Consumer side: time to book, listings viewed before booking, average time to choose
listing, average number of clicks/searches for each booking, first page search result
connections
• Producer side: % of listings with no views/matches
• Connect: ratio causation analysis of connections driving interactions. Frequency of
connections (e.g. connections on WeChat monitored to understand user/producer
relationships)
Trust, customer experience
• Ratio of reviews to core transactions
• Ratio of positive to negative reviews
• Average ratings
• Ratio of complaints or fraud to core transactions
• % of disputes successfully resolved
• % of transactions preceded by review viewings
• Net Promoter Score (NPS)
Source: Launchworks
118 Platform scaling: reaching critical mass
Beyond the platform dashboard that will be focused on key functions, the
platform will need to develop modelling and forecasting capabilities. This will
be particularly important during the scaling phase to be able to understand
the impact of growth on funding requirements and infrastructure needs.
Enablers
The supporting capabilities and infrastructure of the platform need to be able
to grow and evolve to support the scaling process.
In many cases, the customer service team balloons in size to support
platform operations at scale. As the customer experience keeps being optimized
to remove friction, the ratio of the number of complaints over the number
of new participants should ideally decrease. That is to say the platforms should
have relatively less negative interactions as it scales. It’s important to establish
a feedback loop between the product and customer support teams for customer
feedback to be embedded back into the value proposition.
The platform’s brand may also need to morph into a more mainstream,
and often more international, proposition. Finally, as the communities now
constituting the platform are shaping its success and offering unparalleled
feedback, their contributions need to be reflected in the brand attributes of
the scaling platform. We will discuss some of these trust and brand aspects in
Chapter 12.
Notes
1 First Round article, ‘Answers to Your Tough Questions About Growth – Learned While
Scaling Eventbrite’s $5B+ Growth Engine’, http://firstround.com/review/answers-to-
your-tough-questions-about-growth-learned-while-scaling-eventbrites-5b-growth-
engine/?ct=t(How_Does_Your_Leadership_Team_Rate_12_3_2015).
2 See, for example, the scale-up report, Sherry Coutu et al., November 2014,
www.scaleupreport.org/, for a well-documented articulation of the scale-up challenges.
3 Reid Hoffman is now teaching his own version of fast scaling strategies at Stanford:
‘Blitzscaling’, http://techcrunch.com/2015/09/14/reid-hoffman-to-teach-blitzscaling-
at-stanford-this-fall/.
4 Rocket Internet is a VC firm well known for launching and selling copycat business
models in markets when the leading player is not yet established. See, for example,
‘Rocket Internet: What It’s Like to Work at a Startup Clone Factory’, http://thehustle.
co/rocket-internet-oliver-samwer.
5 The K-factor simply represents the number of new customers an existing customer
brings to the platform on average. It is often driven by social media promotions and
online acknowledgement of your platform. If i is the number of invites sent by your
existing platform participants and c the percentage of conversion to your platform, then
K = i × c.
Platform scaling: reaching critical mass 119
Platform maturity
Defending profitable growth
Once critical mass is reached, the energy required to sustain platform growth
is proportionally smaller than the energy required at ignition due to network
effects. With an established market position, barriers to entry are likely to be
high for new entrants. However, competitive threats will come from numer-
ous fronts and will need to be dealt with appropriately. Scale also comes
with drawbacks. It may take longer to adjust to new market dynamics and
make changes to the value proposition – at least without alienating existing
platform participants. Product/market fit was a prerequisite for successful
ignition and scaling, and remains essential for all subsequent growth phases.
Like a rocket, the platform has some velocity and momentum, but its trajectory
is now more difficult to change. If the platform is really successful, it is also
likely to attract the attention of competition authorities.
As the platform matures and continues to grow (see Figure 9.2 in the
previous chapter), focus is usually given to the following activities:
In this chapter, we first review aspects of defensive growth with the rocket
model framework (Figure 10.1), as well as managing change in a mature plat-
form environment. We then discuss the strategic management of mature
platforms.
122 Platform maturity: profitable growth
Attract
Retention is key
While acquisition is the main focus of the platform during the scaling phase,
retention and engagement maximization become increasingly important as
the platform matures. Acquisition remains key to the growth of the platform,
but its established market position makes it much easier to attract new
customers, at least until its market is saturated.
Innovation
Enhancing the platform’s value proposition with new features/tools to meet
platform participants’ needs is an important lever for retention and to keep
Platform maturity: profitable growth 123
engagement levels high. To avoid the threat of new entrants, the platform
needs to keep learning from its customers. Alibaba’s proposition to mer-
chants, ‘to help small businesses grow by solving their problems’,1 has kept
expanding from its basic marketplace features to an extended range of ser-
vices, including analytics tools showing data trends to assist sellers’
decision-making, logistical services and financing solutions. To help hosts set
a price for their listings, Airbnb offers a free smart pricing tool, which
automatically adjusts daily price listings based on a minimum and maximum
price range and willingness to host.2 Price listing adjustments are based on
supply and demand, and the listing’s features, location, amenities, booking
history and availability.
Monitoring the success of platform participants is a good way to gain insights
into what works on the platform and how to further enhance the value
proposition for all users. Which users and producers could become more
valuable with better support, tools or advice from the platform?
In some cases, platform participants themselves develop new functionalities
that are so successful that they should in fact become part of the platform. In
such cases, the platform needs to consider carefully how to secure strategic
control of these features. When a new application on an app store becomes a
‘must-have’ app, the platform owner has a strong incentive to either duplicate
or acquire it. If it fails to do so, the platform will be at the mercy of platform
participants with a strong bargaining power and an increased ability to monetize
their offering. In some extreme cases, these new great features may even end
up being controlled by a competitor whose objectives are not aligned with the
interest of the platform (and may want to degrade, rather than enhance, the
features of an app, for example). At the same time, the platform ideally needs
to ensure that it remains fair to its ecosystem participants and does not
‘expropriate’ them on a whim. Of course, platforms can play games but it may
undermine the trust of participants. For example, Spotify, the music streaming
service with over 30 million paying subscribers – twice as many as Apple Music
has – recently claimed that Apple was intentionally making it difficult to update
its iPhone app and was holding back new features.3
Paying a fair price in the context of an acquisition or giving fair warning
that a feature is so strategic4 that it will be replicated by the platform within
a given timescale are two ways of ensuring that strategic control is gained
without alienating platform participants. SAP gives developers visibility of its
roadmap over an 18–24 month period so that they build new products
without the risk of competing with SAP – for at least two years. SAP also
has a policy of partnering with developers to help them financially or buy
them out at a fair price.5
124 Platform maturity: profitable growth
Personalization
Managing the balance between simplicity and new features is key to
strengthening the platform’s overall market position. One way to achieve this
is through contextualization and personalization. By only showing features/
choices that may be relevant for a given customer at a given moment in time,
platforms can leverage their feature-rich architecture without complicating
the user experience. Many Facebook features are only made visible when
particular events are triggered (e.g. the option to post an album just after a
user takes a series of photos).
Match
The same logic applies to marketplaces’ long tail inventories. Being able to
personalize a search result allows platforms to leverage their wide selection
without confusing buyers with too much choice. This has allowed Alibaba to
push the concept of the long tail to the limit with in excess of a billion products
listed. To make the most of this unique inventory, the same search engine
powers a number of consumer marketplaces owned by the group, such as Tmall
and Taobao. This means that a search on one consumer site can also return
search results across all other Alibaba consumer sites. This guarantees customers
complete inventory discovery and access to the long tail across all marketplaces.
For example, a search on Taobao for the latest Burberry tote bag may come
back with few results on Taobao, but with a relevant selection on Tmall. The
mix of search results displayed across marketplaces is decided at group level,
based on priorities, relevance, supply gaps and merchant performance.
Search innovation
Search is an area that is constantly evolving. In the past, the matching func-
tion relied mostly on algorithms that followed a set of rules written by
software engineers. But artificial intelligence is starting to redefine how search
works. Search neural networks can learn from analysing large amounts of
data and build their own rules to match users and producers better and faster.
RankBrain, Google’s deep neural network, which helps generate responses
to search queries, now handles about 15% of Google’s daily search queries.8
All major platforms, from Facebook to Microsoft, have invested in deep
learning, with Amazon even having released deep learning open-source soft-
ware for search and product recommendations.9 Search technology, increas-
ingly powered by deep neural networks, is evolving fast beyond text and geo-
localized data to include voice and images. No doubt the integration of new
technology such as messaging bots (automated search) and augmented reality
(visual search) will redefine existing platforms’ user search experience.
Connect
What defines positive interactions may change over time so it’s worth revisiting
these definitions on a regular basis. Mature platforms can also leverage their
communities to increase the quality and quantity of relevant content available
on the platform. To drive higher customer engagement, Taobao’s mobile app
offers new social commerce features to meet the evolving needs of how people
shop. Taobao hosts over 1,000 quanzi (circles) where shopping enthusiasts talk
about their hobbies and favourite products. Taobao also hosts crowdsourced
Q&As. When a buyer submits a question, Taobao’s algorithms identify buyers
who are best qualified to answer and send them a message. 25% of all questions
are answered within one minute and 60% of questions within 10 minutes.10
Two million buyers help answer 1 million questions every day.
Transact
Maximizing the number of core transactions should remain a key objective
through improvements to the customer experience to reduce friction during
126 Platform maturity: profitable growth
and after the transaction. The services added to enhance the transaction experi-
ence – from loan products to users, conflict resolution support, insurances, etc.
– should be well integrated to the existing customer experience.
Now that the platform has reached critical mass and that network effects
are in full swing, the platform can optimize how much of the excess value
delivered to customers can be captured during the core transaction. This may
translate into more refined pricing structures and levels. The key things to
watch out for at this stage are disintermediation and leakage. For example,
Upwork changed its pricing structure in June 2016 to reduce leakage from
its most profitable freelancers. Based on their choice of payment method,
clients now either pay a processing fee of 2.75% when paying by credit cards,
or no processing fee if they choose a low cost payment method like an
Automated Clearing House (ACH). This change enabled Upwork to rebalance
their pricing and charge a fee inversely proportional to total billings, as shown
in Table 10.1.11
Optimize
By now, the platform should have developed strong analytical capabilities and
the challenge is the opposite of the one faced during the ignition phase. There
is so much data available that identifying which key metrics are really relevant
for sustainable and profitable growth requires focus and discipline. We recom-
mend continuing to develop the strategic ecosystem dashboard, including
profitability and monetization metrics, as well as operational dashboards for
both user and producer sides, focusing on detailed success metrics.
Financial metrics will become increasingly important, as the platform’s ability
to monetize becomes the critical issue for its sustainability. Finally, the self-
marketing and innovation potential of the community will now outstrip that
of the platform business, and so it will be critical to empower and measure
the community’s performance in these areas. A few examples of metrics at
platform maturity are shown in Table 10.2.
Enablers
Customer experience
Improving and simplifying the experience of platform participants on both
sides may not be as straightforward now that many users and producers are
familiar with the platform services. But perfecting the customer experience
for all participants should remain a goal.
Managing change
Traditional companies make management decisions about the development
of their value proposition – such as price changes, new product introductions,
new features, etc. – unilaterally and sometimes adjust them if customers do
not respond well. Platforms are different. They have to take into account
the impact of changes on different sides of their platforms. Some changes
can be perceived as positive for one side, but not the other. They could
also be positive for both, or negative for both. A mature platform will need
to carefully consider the interests of its stakeholders, including producers and
users, as well as employees and partners, as changes to its rules may have
far-reaching consequences for its participants. A new pricing model or match-
ing algorithm may fundamentally impact the economics of a wide range of
platform participants.
Mature platforms therefore need to track the changes in their roadmap
and understand which side(s) will be impacted and how. If many changes
are planned at the same time – which is often the case when a new release
is prepared – it is important to understand their cumulative effects and try to
ensure that the overall balance of the platform is not undermined.
Platform maturity: profitable growth 129
Figure 10.2 illustrates some changes that are negative for both producers
and users12 (A and B), some important changes that are neutral for produ-
cers and very positives for users (C), as well as small changes that are slightly
positive for users and very positive for producers (D) and very negative for
users but positive for producers (E). The size of the ‘bubble’ can illustrate the
value at risk for stakeholders.
Processes need to be put in place in order to both assess and mitigate the
impact of changes. Advanced notice should be given and reactions carefully
monitored. Ideally, a rollback plan should be available in case something goes
wrong. A large platform considering changes that are both difficult to rollback
and have a significant customer impact need to invest significant time and
resources in ensuring these are successful, and/or develop mitigating strategies
that will reduce the customer impact. Mandating free postage for media
products (CDs, DVDs) generated a revolt from eBay sellers,13 although it was
a buyer need that Amazon and other competing e-commerce websites had
already met. eBay had to roll the policy back, but interestingly sellers didn’t
revert to charging postage fees, and arguably the entire eBay ecosystem
benefited as a result.
130 Platform maturity: profitable growth
Netscape). While this strategy can be a very effective attack (or defence), it
may also attract the wrath of the competition authorities since it involves
bundling and may lead to foreclosure. If used too often, it may also deter
complements from investing in the platform (and result in less apps developed
for your app store, less inventory in your marketplace, etc.).
In some other cases, the complement service being developed ends up being
acquired by the ‘complemented’ platform. For example PayPal managed to
attract lots of eBay sellers (and buyers) onto its own platform, which led
to its acquisition by eBay. By the same token, YouTube ended up becoming
a search platform for video in its own right and this led to its acquisition by
Google.
In some cases, however, the acquisition or imitation of the complement is
not required. When faced with the formidable success of some of its game
producers (such as Zynga when it launched the game Farmville), Facebook
thought about its options. While buying Zynga was a possibility, the price
was already high and the risks associated with follow-up games deemed
significant – despite incredible early successes. Facebook decided instead to
manage more closely the gaming category of its app store in order to ensure
that barriers to launching apps were minimal and that whoever ended up
providing the best entertainment would succeed on the platform. Other
providers launched equally successful games and Facebook didn’t have to face
too strong a producer in follow-up negotiations.
• Side differentiation: Other platforms in the same space may decide to focus
on the needs of the side that is ‘the least looked after’ by the established
platform. For example, new platform entrants in the taxi market may focus
more on the needs of drivers (Hailo, Juno) than Uber, which arguably
was more focused on its clients.
• Challengers’ mergers: Established platforms are also exposed to the merger
of smaller followers, which may result in a challenger suddenly with critical
mass. This may drive the acquisition of smaller competitors.
• Niche/vertical focus: Niche players may try to cherry-pick the most
profitable segments that are big enough to support a critical mass on their
own (e.g. fashion marketplaces such as Farfetch, Videdressing, Vestiaire
Collective and Vinted compete against eBay’s fashion vertical).
132 Platform maturity: profitable growth
Notes
1 Alibaba founder Jack Ma’s open letter to the company’s investors after Alibaba’s IPO,
September 2014.
2 Airbnb’s smart pricing was launched in November 2015. There are other pricing tools
on the market, such as Beyond Pricing, which charge 1% of booking earnings.
3 Peter Kafka, Recode, 30 June 2016, www.recode.net/2016/6/30/12067578/spotify-
apple-app-store-rejection.
4 Platforms providing a new core features roadmap over the next 18–24 months, such as
SAP, come to mind.
5 G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York: W. W.
Norton & Company, 2016, pp. 174–5.
6 Hugh Williams, ‘Measuring Search Relevance’, eBay Tech Blog, 10 November 2010,
www.ebaytechblog.com/2010/11/10/measuring-search-relevance/.
7 Will Oremus, Slate, 3 January 2016, www.slate.com/articles/technology/cover_story/
2016/01/how_facebook_s_news_feed_algorithm_works.html.
8 Cade Metz, ‘AI Is Transforming Google Search. The Rest of the Web Is Next’, Wired,
4 February 2016, www.wired.com/2016/02/ai-is-changing-the-technology-behind-
google-searches/.
9 Klint Finley, ‘Amazon’s Giving Away the AI Behind Its Product Recommenda-
tions’, Wired, 16 May 2016, www.wired.com/2016/05/amazons-giving-away-ai-behind-
product-recommendations/.
10 See Alibaba.com, 26 July 2016, www.alibabagroup.com/en/ir/article?news=p160726.
11 In the old pricing (where the fee was entirely paid by the freelancer), the client had no
incentive to switch to a low cost payment method and often had reasons not to, e.g.
because credit cards offer points and float. Conversely in the old pricing, the freelancers
were always paying for the cost of payment, i.e. they were burdened with a cost that
only the client could change. The idea was to charge clients for this because they can
make the decision to pay by credit card despite the 2.75% fee, if they see value in doing
this, or else to switch to a low cost payment method. This rebalancing enabled reducing
Upwork fees to 5% for cumulative billings over $10K for a given client.
12 Of course, changes that have a negative impact on both sides would need to be justified
on the basis that they benefit the platform even more than they hurt its participants. For
example, this could be the case if the platform needs additional income to reinvest in
new services, or wants to reposition its proposition and is prepared to ‘cull’ some of its
existing producers and users as a result.
13 The policy was rolled out in 2009 in the UK and Germany.
14 T. Eisenmann, G. Parker and M. Van Alstyne, Platform Envelopment, Harvard Business
School Working Paper, 2010.
Platform maturity: profitable growth 135
15 http://venturebeat.com/2015/12/06/uber-is-still-blocked-on-wechat-in-china-and-the-
situation-is-getting-worse/
16 http://venturebeat.com/2015/12/03/lyft-adds-grabtaxi-and-ola-to-its-faction-of-allies-
against-uber/.
17 www.wsj.com/articles/china-s-didi-chuxing-to-acquire-rival-uber-s-chinese-operations-
1470024403.
18 Cainiao was formed by a consortium of existing logistics companies to give the project
a running start. Alibaba itself took a 48% stake.
19 See https://techcrunch.com/2016/03/14/alibaba-backed-logistics-firm-cainiao-lands-
funding-at-a-reported-7-7b-valuation/.
20 Internet.org is a partnership between Facebook and six companies (Samsung, Ericsson,
MediaTek, Opera Software, Nokia and Qualcomm). In February 2016, regulators banned
its Free Basics service in India based on ‘Prohibition of Discriminatory Tariffs for Data
Services Regulations’.
21 Benjamin Gomes-Casseres, 15 June 2016, Harvard Business Review, https://hbr.org/2016/
06/is-the-linkedin-acquisition-microsofts-attempt-to-build-its-own-alphabet.
22 See https://techcrunch.com/2015/09/14/etsy-opens-to-manufacturing/.
23 At the time of writing, there are no page takeover ads, no advertising video content
forced viewing, and no autoplay of videos from paid posts yet.
24 See www.wired.com/2016/03/ubereats-standalone-app-launches-us/. Drivers can choose
to switch between modes freely, by logging into and out of the app.
Chapter 11
Platform pricing
1 their customers create value for each other when using the platform due
to network effects;
2 pricing on one side of the platform often impacts the other side of the
platform due to cross-elasticity of demand across the platform;
3 a critical mass of customers may be required to make the platform valuable
to other customers; and
4 pricing in platforms truly shapes the behaviours of platform participants and
therefore needs to be set to enhance the overall value proposition.
• What is the pricing governance framework? (e.g. are the end prices set by the
platform owner or by the platform participants?).
• Which pricing model to follow? (e.g. charging platform users, advertising
model, freemium/selling of value-added services).
• Who to charge? (e.g. all users, one side, third parties, specific customer sub-
segments on each platform side).
• Which pricing structures to use? (e.g. one-off joining fees, annual membership
fees, transaction fees – fixed amounts or proportional to transaction value
– donations, as well as discounts and rewards).
The answers to these questions lie in the type of platform and ecosystem
that need to be developed, and the extent to which pricing is a strategic enabler
and lever for the platform to succeed. In this context, it is important to keep
in mind that since the interactions and behaviours of a critical mass of cus-
tomers are the key to platform value creation, pricing strategies need to support
these objectives first and foremost. Generating revenue will (almost) always
be the ultimate goal, but successful pricing architecture will also contribute
to addressing broader questions, such as:
• How do platforms ensure that ‘end user pricing’ is efficient and creates a
good customer experience for ‘users’ (even if producers are the ones setting
the price)?
• How can platforms both support rapid user growth and generate revenues
with minimum friction to maximize network effects?
• How can platforms use pricing to ensure the communities are balanced
in terms of supply and demand?
• How do platforms maximize the quality of customer interactions and
experiences?
• How can platforms use pricing models that minimize the risk of ‘disinter-
mediation’ and ‘leakages’ (i.e. transactions moving ‘off-platform’)?
• How to best transition from one pricing model to another (in particular,
transition from free to a paying model)?
We’ll review these questions in turn. Let’s start by looking at key pricing
governance questions.
140 Platform pricing
Platform strategy
Strategic platform design choices also need to be considered. In particular, the
overall differentiation strategy of the platform and the customers it is targeting.
For many of the platforms that standardize producer pricing, there are often
competing platforms offering greater pricing flexibility. The competing
platform may seek to provide superior pricing innovation or competition
among producers, greater flexibility for producers to differentiate their
product/level of service, or improved customization and negotiation options
for users. It is therefore important to ensure that the level of control over
producer pricing is aligned with the overall strategy of the platform, not just
the nature of its products. For example, eBay had to introduce its ‘Buy It
Now’ option in order to compete with other platforms and e-commerce sites
offering a fixed price, while also keeping its auction model to allow more
price-sensitive customers a chance to secure lower prices.
why the design of both free and premium value propositions require care-
ful thinking about the trade-off between the free features (usually conducive
to scaling) and the take-up of the premium version (usually conducive to
revenues). While a difficult balance to strike, this model has been used
by a number of fast-growing platforms such as SoundCloud. Platforms
such as LinkedIn, now owned by Microsoft, also have a freemium model
that is targeted at various segments of users. For example, jobseekers can join
the premium subscription model in order to have increased visibility of job
offers, while established professionals can join a premium networking option
where they will be able to see the identity of the people who viewed their
profile.
It is worth noting that a number of classified websites also use some form
of price discrimination, depending on whether or not you are a business user
and/or which section you want to place your adverts in. Gumtree, owned
by eBay, offers free posts to private individuals in most second-hand goods
sections, while businesses have to pay. In some sections of the site, such as
property, all posters have to pay. In some cases, more visibility can be gained
within a category (‘featured ad’) for a small fee as well.
In addition, some platforms have used joining fees on the merchant side to fund
a strong referral program (e.g. Alibaba). This method can drive growth when
the joining fees are relatively small compared to the potential savings on trans-
actions.
buyer who finds goods that are constantly sold out will be frustrated. Since
the two sides of the platform are interdependent, price signals on one side
will have an impact on the value of the platform for the other side (for
example, the introduction of a listing fee may reduce the inventory of a
platform and undermine buyers’ ability to find what they are looking for).
Platform balancing is therefore key to maximizing the number of relevant
transactions and ensuring that the platform can find an equilibrium in matching
supply and demand.
Imbalance can occur for a number of reasons. Often it’s easier to sign up
members on one side of the platform than the other(s) because the benefit
of transactions is higher for one side. Sometimes the ancillary and time costs
of joining a platform make one set of customers more likely to align with a
single platform while members on the other side join many different platforms
(e.g. they ‘multihome’). This is important since one side ends up with fewer
options than the other side. In gaming, many households decide to commit
to a single platform (be it an Xbox, PlayStation or Nintendo), while few
developers commit to a single platform (or if they do, they ask for additional
fees for exclusive games).
value created by these interactions. Many platforms suffer from some level of
leakage,4 so it needs to be managed carefully, especially if the value capture
is done at the transaction stage. This is why some platforms have tried different
pricing for first and subsequent transactions between participants. TaskRabbit,
a service platform, takes 30% on the first transaction with a producer, and
15% subsequently. Other service platforms, such as Thumbtack, simply
monetize the lead/introduction to avoid leakage when participants connect.
The more direct the connection between participants, the greater the risk
of disintermediation. Transactions requiring face-to-face meetings, for exam-
ple, may lead to off-platform transactions, while anonymous mediated
communication is likely to be more conducive to on-platform transactions.
Pricing structures such as one-off joining fees can negate this risk, but they
may conflict too heavily with the goals of rapid growth and frictionless
pricing. In these cases, a strategy of monetizing value-added and comple-
mentary products and services may be appropriate.
The key is to understand the most valuable additional services provided by
the platform, in addition to searching/matching, and offer them as stand-alone
products. For example, additional services could include insurance, reference
checking, dispute and remediation services, simple safe payment systems and
emergency on-demand services (e.g. a nanny platform may offer and monetize
fully accredited and endorsed emergency nannies in addition to providing a
free ‘regular’ nanny marketplace).
Conclusion
Platform pricing has unique challenges. Many platform pioneers who have
learned through trial and error have provided us with useful insights into the
effects of various pricing models. This has allowed us to identify patterns
and infer high-level pricing principles for new platform businesses. When
poorly designed, pricing may stifle positive network effects and slow growth.
However, the right pricing strategy can generate tremendous value while
supporting the strategic objectives of the platform. BlaBlaCar is an excellent
illustration of the growth that can be unlocked once the right platform pricing
model is found. Platform pricing can sometimes be more an art than a science,
and experimentations to test high-level hypotheses remain key. As illustrated
in Table 11.2, it is important for pricing levels and structure to support the
objectives of the platform at a given point in time.
Table 11.2 Matching platform objectives with pricing levers and examples
Objective Possible levers and examples
Rapidly grow platform membership Freemium (SoundCloud)
Transaction fees (Airbnb)
Encourage members to transact Membership fees with unlimited use (Match.com)
frequently Subscription for reduced fees (Ruby Lane)
Balance growth on each side of the Credit card rewards (Amex issuing)
platform Surge pricing (Uber)
Generate revenue for profit and Credit card merchant fee premium
cross-subsidization (Amex acquirer)
Value-added features for reduced fees
(OpenTable)
Embed loyalty and discourage Discounts for ongoing use (TaskRabbit)
disintermediation Lead generation fee only (Thumbtack)
Differentiate/attract the most valuable Ecosystem strategy (iPhone premium customers
customers drive App Store spending)
Improve inventory quality Listing fees (SpareRoom)
Super seller discounts (eBay top-rated sellers)
Source: Launchworks
Platform pricing 151
Notes
1 See http://qz.com/687231/people-are-more-likely-to-take-uber-at-2-1x-surge-pricing-
than-2x/.
2 See www.artfire.com/ext/sell/join_now for terms and conditions. Also, we note that
the membership fee gives access to added ‘premium’ services, such as higher caps on
number of listings or enhanced tools to sell on the marketplace.
3 Interestingly, such a pricing approach has been banned on the basis of gender dis-
crimination in a number of US states. The California Supreme Court, for example, ruled
that it violated California’s Unruh Civil Rights Act. See, for example, Angelucci v. Century
Supper Club (2007). Attempts to circumvent the law by having ‘free drinks for people
wearing skirts’ have apparently been tried as a result.
4 Typical examples include platforms introducing cleaning ladies to clients or even some
product categories sold on marketplaces such as eBay where some sellers clearly try to
get the connection with the buyer before selling the full service direct. This may explain
why some firms are selling single planks of wood in the ‘wood flooring’ section as opposed
to square metres . . .
5 See G. Parker, M. Van Alstyne and S. Choudary, Platform Revolution, New York:
W. W. Norton & Company, 2016, Chapter 6, for a discussion on how price increases
at Meetup actually strengthened the platform.
Chapter 12
What made people suddenly comfortable with the idea of sharing their flats
with strangers (Airbnb), buying second-hand goods from people on the other
side of the planet (eBay) or renting their cars while they are away (Turo)?
The answer is trust. Understanding how platforms have been able to build
trust between participants of their ecosystem is key to understanding their
success. Unlike traditional businesses – where trust must be established between
the firm and its customers – platforms need a more holistic approach where
trust has to be built between the platform and its participants as well as between
the participants themselves. You not only need to trust the Airbnb brand,
but also the person you are going to rent your flat to. Without a sufficient
level of trust, perceived risks may outweigh the possible financial gains of
using the platform. In fact, one of the key issues for platforms is that the
producer has more information about what is being exchanged, sold or traded
than the users. Using the example of cars, famous economic Nobel Prize
winner George Akerlof wrote a very insightful paper titled ‘The Market for
Lemons’. In it, he explains that if some sellers are selling cars in working
order while others are selling broken cars (so-called ‘lemons’, presumably
because they leave a bitter taste in the mouth of buyers) and that buyers have
no way of knowing which is which, then the price of all the cars will converge
towards the price of the worst possible car. Without a well-thought-out trust
framework and relevant information exchange between participants, a platform
offering second-hand cars would therefore simply fail.1
So how do platforms build trust?
154 Trust, governance and brand
Figure 12.1 Trust survey: responses to the question, ‘On a scale of 0–5, how much
do you trust . . . ?’
Source: BlaBlaCar, Chronos
Rachel Botsman explains, before participants trust each other, they need to
trust the idea. It can be a challenge when this idea is new, couch-surfing
for example. Then they need to trust the platform.5 For someone to list their
car on Turo, they need to know they’re insured in case something bad
happens. Finally, participants need to trust each other. While this applies to
all platforms, the required threshold of trust for transactions to occur will vary
depending on the type of transaction enabled by the platform. Marketplaces
enabling simple transactions such as product purchases will need a basic level
of trust between buyers and sellers. But the minimum trust threshold required
also depends upon the type of platform. Service platforms with high-stakes
transactions, such as Sittercity.com, which matches babysitters with parents,
or medical sites, such as Doctolib, that match you with health practitioners,
will require a high trust threshold. More mundane services, and more
standardized lower-value items, typically have a lower trust threshold.
actions. The trust framework can be used as a high-level guide to assess platform
governance principles to ensure that new rules do not drain the trust bank.
Some academics have tried to unpack the key underlying drivers of trust
to derive a simple formula for a trust quotient.6
C+R+I
The formula for the trust quotient is: TQ =
S
With the following definitions for the fundamental building blocks:
• Credibility (C), or the perceived capabilities of a person or an organization.
• Reliability (R), or how consistently experiences of kept promises have
been repeated.
• Intimacy (I ), or how enjoyable to interact with.
• The inverse of self-orientation (1/S ). It can also be described as bene-
volence, empathy and the ability to hold the other party’s interest over
one’s own.
The formula states that the sum of credibility, reliability and intimacy are
key positive drivers of trust and that the effect of these three building blocks
is magnified when combined with high empathy or, conversely, diminished
when exhibited by a ‘selfish’ individual or organization.
This generic trust formula is said to be applicable to a range of situations,
from professional relationships to social interactions.
We know that trust can be enhanced or eroded based on experiences
and interactions, so platforms need to design a user experience that encourages
interactions and activities that enable trust rather than limit it.
Many surveys and studies show the type of behaviours that are conducive
to trust and those that undermine it. A World Economic Forum survey on
trust in 2014 showed that the characteristics or behaviours most damaging
to people’s trust were when people were: ‘not doing what they say’ (45% of
respondents), ‘self-interested’ (28%), ‘secretive’ (11%) and ‘arrogant’ (8%).
A platform could look at the interactions it enables and seek to develop govern-
ance principles to ensure that the above issues are addressed. For example,
when BlaBlaCar introduced its online pre-payment feature, as described in
the previous chapter, it started to monetize its ride-sharing platform, but more
importantly it solved a key trust issue that had been undermining the growth
of the platform. When the service was free, the cost of not showing up for
a ride (either to pick up or to be picked up) was very low. Since money had
not changed hands, people were not always fully committed. This was
consistent with the very high ‘no-show’ rate prior to the online payment
feature being introduced. Enabling online payment on the BlaBlaCar platform
was therefore a key trust-enhancing move that directly contributed to the
subsequent exponential growth of the platform.
Trust, governance and brand 157
Credibility
Credentials of participants and/or products/services provided should include
the relevant information needed for trust to be built. As we saw from the
trust survey, a picture, a verified email and mobile phone number, and posi-
tive feedback scores are all critical components of platform participants’ online
trust profiles.
Companies such as eBay, Airbnb and BlaBlaCar all offer useful information
on the profiles of their members. In many cases, the information is
supplemented by some form of platform ranking (Ambassador in Figure 12.4),
as well as relevant preferences (e.g. likes to talk during trips, non-smoker,
etc.) to maximize the chances of positive interactions on – and off – platform.
In our experience, the link between the quality of the profile and likelihood
to transact is very strong. There is ample evidence that, with all other things
being equal, sellers with complete profiles and verified information sell
significantly more than others. Big high-resolution product pictures and clear
detailed descriptions also have a higher conversion rate. To come back to our
opening example of Airbnb, the poor quality of pictures for homes being
advertised in the early days was indeed a limiting factor, and dealing with this
proved to be a key contributor to the exponential growth that ensued.
While we have been focusing on trust aspects on the producer side of the
platform, it is worth remembering that the credibility principle also applies
to the user side. On Airbnb, hosts can check potential guests before accepting
a rental.
Higher-credential participants not only do better, but they also benefit the
entire community and the platform itself. This is why Upwork, the talent
platform, has developed hundreds of proprietary skill tests for freelancers to
assure clients that the freelance contractors are certified. Upwork also recently
launched its ‘Pro’ status, which requires that freelancers go through a rigorous
vetting process, including technical skill evaluations and behavioural interviews.
LinkedIn’s acquisition of online certification company Lynda for $1.5 billion
in April 2015 can also be seen in that light.
Contribution
Showing participants’ activity on the platform can be a good indication of their
level of contribution, engagement and proficiency in using the platform.
BlaBlaCar displays an activity box on driver profiles showing the day they
joined the platform, the number of rides given, how long ago they were active
on the platform, when they last logged on, and how responsive they are. Quora
provides the number of questions and answers a user has contributed to. Twitter
shows how many tweets people have posted and liked. Upwork displays the
number of hours freelancers have worked for clients through the platform.
Consistency
As we’ve seen from the trust equation, trust results from the accumulation
of positive interactions and experiences. So it’s not just the activity or
contribution that counts, but also the consistency of experiences over time.
Many marketplaces use rating and review systems to capture the quality of
past experiences delivered by participants.
eBay was one of the first companies that managed to scale its review and
rating system globally, and this has been instrumental in creating trust between
buyers and sellers. Buyers can rate and review sellers on their overall experience
(positive, negative or neutral), which results in a feedback score (percent-
age in parentheses next to a member’s user ID in Figure 12.5).8 Detailed seller
ratings (item as described, communication, dispatch time, postage) are also
160 Trust, governance and brand
rated on a score of 1 to 5. eBay reports these ratings over time with one-,
six- and 12-month averages in order to show consistency trends. Amazon has
a similar reporting system for merchants on its platform.
eBay started with a reciprocal reputation system in the early years, where
sellers could leave visible ratings for buyers. eBay, however, found that sellers
with poor ratings often retaliated against buyers by also giving them bad ratings.
Clearly, this ‘tit for tat’ approach gave the wrong incentives to platform
participants and amplified issues instead of strengthening positive network
effects. eBay therefore decided to carry on collecting ratings from sellers, in
order to identify and weed out bad buyers, but that data is no longer visible
to platform participants.
Platform rating and review systems are not perfect and can suffer from biases
as Andrei Hagiu and Simon Rothman point out.9 Some customers never leave
ratings, and those who do so tend to be either very happy or very unhappy
with the product or service. Rating and review systems therefore need to be
calibrated to lessen the impact of biases. Airbnb has an advanced feedback
system with the possibility of leaving confidential feedback directly to the
host as well as the platform, in addition to public feedback. This is very useful
to track changes, spot emerging issues or even capture suggestions that do
not deserve a public mention but could help the host/platform adjust its
offering. Airbnb, like many other platforms, also captures NPS scores for both
Trust, governance and brand 161
guests and hosts, which provides better insights into the experiences of plat-
form participants.
Community
Community building is at the heart of many platforms and plays a key part
in encouraging positive interactions – leading to positive network effects –
and reducing negative interactions. A moderation policy should be instituted
early, especially for social platforms. It helps shape the community’s culture
and set the tone for the first 1,000 people. Once this early culture is set, it
is harder to change later on.
Control
Platforms have significant power and responsibilities associated with their
operations. To quote law professor Jeffrey Rosen, platforms such as Facebook
have ‘more power in determining who can speak and who can be heard
around the globe than any Supreme Court justice, any king or any president’.
It is certainly true that the monitoring of content contribution and sharing
(automated or not) is a key activity for many platforms. While the exact
numbers are not reported, some social platforms are thought to have up to
a third of their entire staff involved in content monitoring.11 When participant
activity happens off-platform, monitoring tools may also be required to
control the experience. In some places, Uber asks a driver to take and send
a selfie when starting work. Uber then compares the image with the biometric
data on record for an ID check. If it does not match, Uber suspends the
account until an investigation takes place.12
As a platform scales, monitoring often needs to be extended beyond the
platform itself. A more holistic type of ‘client service’ monitoring involving
social platforms, corporate blogs, review sites, etc. can be instrumental in
surfacing bad – or good – customer experiences. It can also help recognize
VIP customers and influencers and monitor so called ‘trolls’, that are only
there to provoke the community. This holistic monitoring function, sometimes
called ‘social listening’, is often part of the customer service team and benefits
greatly from strong analytics support (optimize function of the Launchworks
rocket model) and feedback loops with most teams (trust, product, engineering,
growth, marketing, pricing and legal) to drive meaningful calls to action.
Correction
Control and correct activities are closely linked. When platforms detect that
some interactions or transactions are not carried out in a trust-enhancing way,
or contravene governance principles, they have an opportunity to correct the
outcome directly. As a platform matures, corrections may be automated by
algorithms, with exceptions managed manually by employees from the trust
and safety team.
Following the 2016 US presidential election, Facebook and Twitter have been
heavily criticized about their role in allowing ‘bots’ to spread misleading or
fake information to voters.13 Since then, Facebook has vowed to tackle
hoaxes. Google has also blocked fake news from its ad network. Twitter,
which by design is a more open platform, still faces challenging governance
issues in this area.
Make it right
Inherently, platforms do not completely control the end-to-end customer
experience. When something goes wrong, great customer service can help
minimize the reputational damage. Airbnb has been known to book hotel
rooms directly to make sure a guest who was let down by a host could have
a place to sleep.
As participants get more familiar with one platform, research shows that they
also become more willing to use other platforms. A recent study from
Professor Arun Sundararajan showed that existing BlaBlaCar ride-sharers were
more likely to use a peer-to-peer marketplace than non-ride-sharers.17
As interpersonal trust is being transformed from a ‘scarce to an abundant
resource’,18 a new digital trust ecosystem is emerging. Companies such as eRated
or Traity are now aggregating ratings and reviews from various marketplaces,
social networks and government sites in order to create a unified online trusted
identity. This can be extremely valuable to new platforms since they may be
able to leverage some of the trust that users have acquired somewhere else
instead of only relying on feedback on the platform itself (often scant at
ignition!). The need for a ‘trusted online identity’ is likely to increase in
tomorrow’s platform economy, and today’s solutions are just the beginning.
Governance principles
Platform governance principles must enhance trust between the platform and
its participants, as well as among participants. The trust framework principles
should therefore be part of the overall governance framework of the platform.
Once the key features of a platform have been designed, the focus should
be on the governance framework. This framework needs to set out the key
principles that will drive the way the platform:
• allows participants to join and interact with the platform and other
participants;
• shares economic and non-economic rewards among the platform itself
and its participants; and
• deals with exceptions, conflicts and outside stakeholders.
Sometimes the softer rules of platforms are conveyed through the behaviour
of existing platform participants, community leaders or even through coaching
examples chosen to explain the on-boarding process to new participants. A
‘like’ on a Facebook post from Mark Zuckerberg will do wonders to your
online credentials and shows other platform participants that whatever you
are doing is consistent with what Facebook expects from its users. The
behavioural norms that emerge over time in many platforms help shape the
future behaviour of new joiners and the platform ecosystem as it scales.
Lastly, the platform itself should embed some of the intelligence required
to enforce governance principles. Many automated algorithms and rules help
ensure that the right information is captured, that it is internally consistent,
and that the parties are who they say they are (if anonymous participation is
forbidden). Going forward, new technologies, such as distributed database
models like blockchain, will open the door to ‘self-enforcing smart contracts’
between platform participants and further strengthen the legal certainty of
core transactions. This will be a formidable enabler for platform businesses
since it will further lower friction between transacting parties.
Platform branding
The other side of trust is brand recognition. Brands still play a very important
part in the buying decision, and this is likely to hold true for many years.
This is because we still draw trust from familiar and recognizable names.
The development and management of a relevant platform brand is therefore
a key strategic enabler of reaching mass-market position and long-term success.
Typical branding strategies, however, need to be adapted to the fact that the
platform has unique relationships with its users and producers, and that they
themselves will interact with one another. That’s why the brand strategy needs
to not only ensure that the brand conveys trust in the idea and the platform
itself, but also that the brand is conducive to enabling transactions between
users and producers.
who wanted to travel the world alone as the lead protagonist in the company’s
global TV campaign, ‘Never a Stranger’.24
Brand co-evolution
At the launch stage, there is so much to do, from achieving platform fit,
acquiring and retaining users and producers, to building technical capabilities,
etc. that branding can be treated as a secondary concern. Airbnb co-founder
Joe Gebbia talks about the first airbed and breakfast logo, and explains:
‘Those brand identities were created in a matter of hours, for a short deadline,
and only for temporary use’. Brian Chesky echoes that sentiment and
continues: ‘We were growing so fast, it became one of those things where
you say you’ll figure it out later, but then you never end up doing it because
you’re too busy.’25
Platforms introducing a new concept such as Airbnb may initially focus
on describing simply and convincingly to both users and producers how
interacting and transacting on the platform can help them create and capture
value. But as the platform scales and its communities grow, a utility-driven
and descriptive brand is unlikely to reach, inspire and reassure late adopters.
Airbnb relaunched its website and mobile apps with a new brand identity in
July 2014, with the new focus of expanding internationally and becoming a
more inclusive hospitality brand. The year-long brand study included user
research as well as interviews from guests and hosts in more than a dozen
countries to capture the essence of the brand. It boiled down to one powerful
concept: belonging. Brian Chesky explains: ‘Airbnb is about belonging
anywhere. The brand shouldn’t say we’re about community, or our inter-
national [reach], or renting homes – it’s about belonging.’
170 Trust, governance and brand
It will be interesting to see how brands such as Airbnb will evolve over
time and how their communities will influence this process. We believe that
platform brands co-evolve with their communities and that participants
contribute to shaping brand values through their interactions with the platform
and other participants.
In the case of food delivery platform Deliveroo, the rebranding that took
place in September 2016 resulted in significant changes to the brand identity.
These changes were driven by the need to be more attuned to the expectations
of not only users, but also producers of the platform. For example, the new
identity now includes colourful jackets and jerseys for Deliveroo riders so that
they can be better seen at night.
When platforms change their strategies, like eBay did when it introduced
its ‘Buy It Now’ option, a brand refresh is often required. By the mid-2000s,
eBay had attained nearly universal brand recognition in Western countries
as the go-to marketplace for second-hand auctions, with vibrant seller and
buyer communities. eBay was well known for auction-style listings, second-
hand, quirky and unique items. It was so ingrained in the popular psyche,
and existing buyers and sellers were so passionate about the old eBay, that
the transition to being known as the destination for buying brand-new items –
as well as second-hand ones in auctions – took many years. A new branding
redesign in 2012 encapsulated this evolution of continued innovation,
combining eBay’s history of the unique, the vintage and its vibrant com-
munities with the new.
Notes
1 For an accessible summary of the argument and its implications for platforms, see
R. Fisman and T. Sullivan, The Inner Lives of Markets: How People Shape Them – and
They Shape Us, London: Public Affairs/John Murray Learning, 2016.
2 Betrustman Report, Chronos & BlaBlaCar, December 2012.
3 See BlaBlaCar, NYU Stern, Entering the Trust Age, 2016. In this study, respondents
were asked to rank on a scale from 0 to 5 the level of trust they gave to different types
of relationships, from a social network contact through to friends or family. A BlaBlaCar
member with a full online profile was then included in the mix. Looking at the
percentage of respondents that gave a high level of trust (4 or 5 out of 5), the results
revealed that 88% of respondents had high trust in a BlaBlaCar member. This percentage
is largely above the percentage of people who highly trust their colleagues (58%) or
neighbors (42%), and close to the percentage of people who highly trust their friends
(92%), revealing that trust built by online platforms can supersede offline relationships.
4 Arun Sundararajan, The Sharing Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2016, p. 61.
5 Rachel Bostman, the Trust Stack, www.rachelbotsman.com.
6 D. H. Maister, R. Galford and C. Green, The Trusted Advisor, London: Simon & Schuster,
2 January 2002.
Trust, governance and brand 171
Platforms, regulation
and competition
• When is intervention warranted and what does good regulation look like?
• What are the characteristics of platforms that may cause economic harm?
• What should those in charge of policing markets, including governments,
regulators and competition authorities, do?
• How should platforms deal with regulation and regulators?
174 Platforms, regulation and competition
• The market consolidates and only a small number of firms (or even one)
are left with significant market power (or monopoly).
• The market under consideration has strong externalities (such as pollution),
and those are by definition not factored in the decisions of the firm.
• The good being traded is a ‘public good’ (such as street lighting) where
consumption cannot be denied and people can’t be excluded.
One of the first issues platforms are facing is that it is unclear how some
of the ‘historic’ regulations would pass the current market failure tests. This
suggests that these regulations, which often date back decades, sometimes
centuries, may in fact prevent the market from functioning rather than cor-
recting market failures. Many of the regulations that create barriers to entry
in markets where there is no market failure fall into this category. The
question for regulators and policymakers is then how to change these regu-
lations to ensure that the market is not artificially distorted. In some cases,
regulators seem to have been ‘captured’ by the firms they are meant to regulate.
Competition authorities tend to be more independent and therefore often
argue that many regulations need to be updated and shouldn’t be used to
prevent innovation. They also remind us of a very important principle: ‘the
purpose of competition law is to ensure that consumers are not harmed, not
to ensure that inferior competitors are protected from disruption’.
To be clear, that doesn’t mean that new entrants should be allowed to do
anything they want, including not carrying out checks on their drivers, not
providing insurance and not paying taxes. But it means that shielding specific
interest groups from competition should only be done after careful con-
siderations have been given as to why this should be the case and why society
would be better off as a result. Granting regulatory protection without tangible
welfare benefits would simply represent a tax on consumers in the form of
increased prices and reduced innovation.
176 Platforms, regulation and competition
for profit motives, rather than anticompetitive ones, traditional predation tests
are not fit for purpose in the context of platforms.
It further added:
The CMA is concerned that some of TfL’s proposals will create barriers
to innovation in particular. Hampering innovation results in inefficient
business models, services of a lower quality than could otherwise be the
case, and dissatisfied consumers.
In fact, the value of such a monopoly model is directly enshrined in the value
of the ‘licence’ – a taxi medallion in this case. In other words, the economic
returns the taxi owners receive above what would be a fair return in a
competitive market is captured in the price of the medallion (which exceeded
$1 million in NYC in 2013). Incidentally, economists will tell you that this
value also represents the lifetime super profits or – in other words – money
taxis make by charging above market price that would otherwise be retained
by clients.
However, since new potential buyers are now anticipating more com-
petition from platforms such as Uber going forward, the price of medallions
is dropping, and quickly, as shown in Figure 13.1.10
Taxis are not the only sector to be impacted by the disruptive entry of
platforms. The hotel lobby has also mounted a global war on Airbnb, arguing
that taxes were not collected in the same way and that security regulations
that hotels are subject to didn’t apply. This resulted in a number of legal moves
against Airbnb,11 with partial or total bans in a number of cities (e.g. Barcelona).
In many cases, the legal position is not directly targeted at Airbnb, but clearly
aimed at reducing the number of people letting their property on the site.
While it is important for Airbnb and its hosts to pay the relevant taxes, it is
sometimes difficult to justify the proportionality of the regulations proposed
Table 13.1 Selected Google services and some competitors’ services by year of launch
The first type of legal cases are linked to claims that Google discriminates
by favouring the rankings of its own services. Marissa Mayer, former Google
senior VP, commented in 2007 during a conference:
182 Platforms, regulation and competition
When we rolled out Google Finance, we did put the Google link first.
It seems only fair right, we do all the work for the search page and all
these other things, so we do put it first . . . That has actually been our
policy, since then, because of Finance. So for Google Maps again, it’s the
first link.
The above statement would suggest that Google’s search results may have
been biased in favour of the ranking of its own ecosystem properties vs those
of its competitors.15
Websites typically allow search engines like Google to crawl and index
their sites so that links to their sites can appear in response to relevant
search engines queries . . . In 2010, Google began incorporating the
content it indexed from its competitors into Google Local without
permission. Although Google had previously acknowledged that it needed
a license to use Yelp’s content, it was now using it without permission
to prop up its own, less effective, product. In some instances, Google
even presented this content to its users as if it were its own . . . In response
to our objections, Google informed us that it would cease the practice
Platforms, regulation and competition 183
the EU is reviewing the evidence, but still believes that Google may well be
favouring its own comparison shopping service.
Google also started showing the Uber option on the results of its mobile
mapping application in June 2014 (see Figure 13.3). This is an interesting
twist since Google is also a large shareholder of Uber,23 and may therefore
be in a position to offer favourable terms to Uber. However, in March 2016,
Google announced that new partners would be added to its service, including
99Taxis in Brazil, Ola Cabs in India, Hailo in the UK and Spain, mytaxi in
Germany and Spain, and Gett in the UK.
Google also came under scrutiny for its Android operating system and the
extent to which handset partners, such as Samsung and HTC, were forced
to pre-install Google apps24 – and whether or not such a practice distorts
competition. This again illustrates the extent to which Google can leverage
parts of its ecosystem (in this case, its operating system platform) to secure
prime ‘real estate display’ and default usage settings in order to favour its own
services. The US lawsuit was dismissed in early 2015, but EU antitrust
186 Platforms, regulation and competition
But most of the debates we’ve followed have been about trying to apply
traditional regulatory instruments and thinking to the new world of platforms.
This has often been a forced process, and few policymakers seem to have
been able to truly grasp what platforms really are and how a new type of
regulation could harness their power to flexibly embed regulatory requirements
into the platforms themselves.
We believe that a new type of regulatory approach is warranted, and that
public policy objectives should be reviewed in light of today’s innovations.
While the thinking around what some call Regulation 2.0 is only emerging,
it sketches a way forward to provide a sustainable answer to the challenges
brought about by platform-powered business models.25 Regulations based
on the need for pre-authorizations were often predicated on the fact that
information was scarce and therefore an independent body needed to check
and centralize it. Today, platforms could leverage their analytics to monitor
who is doing what in near real time. Companies such as PayPal have engaged
with regulators and encouraged such iterative approaches leveraging new
data analytics tools to deal with the regulators’ concerns. Platforms, since they
mediate markets, generate both new types of market failures (around con-
sumer safety, privacy and fraud, for example) and unique ways of addressing
them (through data capture, analytics and governance). Professor Abbey
Stemler even suggests setting out policy objectives, such as ‘user feedback on
platforms must be authentic’ or ‘services, spaces, and assets offered must be
provided by legitimate and trustworthy users’ to ensure that relevant data
are gathered and analysed by platforms and governance iteratively updated
until these objectives are met and good long-term regulatory outcomes
secured.26
5 mph. This limit, which had been suggested by horse cart drivers, was not
very efficient. Incidentally, it also made it very difficult for cars not to stall.
In England, the law even required that the automobilist had to notify a village
constable of his arrival, so that officials could walk in front of the car waving
two red warning flags while the driver followed slowly behind. Road
regulations have moved on quite a bit since then. For platforms, however,
the regulatory challenges ahead are still very significant and, as with the early
days of cars, some regulations are likely to be more focused on the protection
of the status quo rather than aimed at improving the lives of consumers.
Notes
1 Such regulators typically exist in sectors where monopoly provision used to be the norm
before a transition towards a more competitive market structure was decided as part of
a liberalization programme, such as in telecoms, energy, water, transport, post, etc.
2 We note that some renowned economists, such as George Stigler, have argued that
regulators could be ‘captured’ by market participants and that regulation may in some
cases lead to a worse outcome than market failures. There is, however, a broad consensus
around the importance of regulation to deal with market failures.
3 Note that this is a significant departure from many traditional models driven by ‘scarcity’.
The more a traditional company sells its products, the less stock it has, and it needs to
spend money to manufacture new products, often at a significant marginal cost, while
with many platforms the more their services are used (often with a marginal cost close
to zero), the more valuable they become.
4 Temporary promotions resulting in some products being sold below costs are of course
possible, but cannot be systematic and across all product categories, since this would
generate cumulative losses, preventing the firm from being sustainable.
5 See Mr Y Aslam, Mr J Farrar and Others -V- Uber, UK Employment Tribunal, Case
Numbers: 2202551/2015, 28 October 2016, available at www.judiciary.gov.uk/
judgments/mr-y-aslam-mr-j-farrar-and-others-v-uber/.
6 ‘Uber Suspends UberPOP in France Following Turmoils and Arrests’, TechCrunch,
3 July 2015, http://techcrunch.com/2015/07/03/uber-stops-uberpop-in-france-
following-turmoils-and-arrests/.
7 ‘Tourist-Heavy Barcelona is Cracking Down on Airbnb’, Atlantic Citylab, 25 December
2015, www.citylab.com/housing/2015/12/barcelona-airbnb-tourism/421788/
8 ‘Here’s Everywhere Uber Is Banned Around the World’, April 2015, www.business
insider.com/heres-everywhere-uber-is-banned-around-the-world-2015-4?IR=T.
9 See Competition and Markets Authority response to Transport for London’s private hire
regulations proposals: www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_
data/file/481450/CMA_response_to_TfL.pdf.
10 This chart shows how Uber is devastating New York’s taxi business: www.goldman
sachs.com/our-thinking/pages/2015-10-favorite-charts.html.
11 See Zaw Thiha Tun, ‘Top Cities Where Airbnb Is Legal or Illegal’, Investopedia, updated
30 October 2015, www.investopedia.com/articles/investing/083115/top-cities-where-
airbnb-legal-or-illegal.asp.
190 Platforms, regulation and competition
12 See insightful piece from Richard Feasey, ‘Compliance Is for Winners’, Remarks at
Cullen BITS Seminar on Platforms, Brussels, 16 July 2015, www.fronfraithltd.com/
home/articles.
13 With a market capitalization of $529 billion as of 11 September 2016, just behind
Apple.
14 We note that Google’s search business is not always seen as a pure platform, since
advertisers, rather than users, are the main source of revenues. We consider that Google
directly connects information producers and information consumers. Irrespective of
the approach used for the search market, Google is undeniably an ecosystem combin-
ing different business models, including some with clear platform characteristics (such
as its app store and operating system).
15 See Measuring Bias in ‘Organic’ Web Search, by Benjamin Edelman and Benjamin
Lockwood from HBS: www.benedelman.org/searchbias/.
16 B. Edelman, Leveraging Market Power Through Tying and Bundling: Does Google Behave
Anti-Competitively?, self-published, 2014, for a discussion of potential tying and bundling
issues within Google’s ecosystem, www.benedelman.org/publications/google-tying-
2014-05-12.pdf.
17 See, for example, the European Commission’s 2009 Guidance Paper proposing the
following test: ‘If the incremental price that customers pay for each of the dominant
undertakings products in the bundle remains above the LRAIC of the dominant firm
from including this product in the bundle, the Commission will normally not intervene
since an equally efficient competitor with only one product should in principle be able
to compete profitably against the bundle.’ December 2008, OJ C45/7,§60.
18 The power of Google, Serving consumers or threatening competition? Hearing before
the Sub Committee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights of the Sub
Committee on the Judiciary, 112th cong. 247 (2011). Submission of Jeremy Stoppelman,
cofounder and CEO of Yelp! Inc and quoted by H. Shelanski, ‘Information, Innovation,
and Competition Policy for the Internet’, University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 161,
2013, 1664–705.
19 B. Edelman, Leveraging Market Power Through Tying and Bundling: Does Google Behave
Anti-Compettively?, self published, 2014, identified eight different families of products
and services that Google is linking to one another.
20 Including the 24,500 patents acquired as part of the Motorola Mobility acquisition in
May 2012.
21 The binding settlement (‘consent decree’) signed by Google and the FTC in February
2013 states that: ‘Google has agreed to remove restrictions on the use of its online search
advertising platform, AdWords, that may make it more difficult for advertisers to
coordinate online advertising campaigns across multiple platforms. [This decision was
taken] following concerns from some FTC Commissioners that Google’s contractual
conditions governing the use of its API made it more difficult for an advertiser to
simultaneously manage a campaign on AdWords and on competing ad platforms.’
22 See: Commission obtains from Google comparable display of specialized search rivals,
EU Memo/14/87, 5th February 2014.
23 Google Ventures invested $258 million in Uber’s August 2013 round. See http://
techcrunch.com/2013/08/22/google-ventures-puts-258m-into-uber-its-largest-deal-
ever/.
Platforms, regulation and competition 191
24 See https://uk.finance.yahoo.com/news/smartphone-suit-against-google-plays-101909548.
html, 18 July 2014.
25 White Paper: Regulation, the Internet Way: A Data-First Model for Establishing Trust,
Safety, and Security, Nick Grossman, 8 April 2015.
26 See A. Stemler, ‘Regulation 2.0: The Marriage of New Governance and Lex Informatica’,
Kelley School of Business Research Paper No. 16-25, March 2016.
27 See, for example, ‘The Sharing Economy in the UK’, report commissioned by Airbnb,
Diane Coyle, 18 January 2016.
Chapter 14
We have seen how platforms are designed, ignited, scaled-up and defended
once mature, but what about traditional businesses facing increased
competition and disruptions from platform entrants?
How to deal with platform disruption is a question often asked by leaders
of large established organizations. Traditional responses of established players
to disruptive market entry often follow what we call the ‘5Ds’ process (deny,
deter, denigrate, delay and dollar!). Our experience, however, suggests that
enlightened leadership may benefit from considering an alternative ‘5Es’
pattern about engaging, enabling, enhancing, embracing and earning, to
maximize value creation in an increasingly platform-powered economy. This
is a significant shift in terms of mindset, and no one should underestimate
the difficulty of the journey.
With this in mind, we note that since some of the most successful businesses
out there are platform-powered ones, traditional firms may wish to leverage
some of their key assets to add platform capabilities where relevant. As we
saw previously, Apple is still generating more than 80% of all its revenues
through the sale of hardware, but one of the key reasons why its hardware
is so sought after is to be found in the strength of its overall app-based
ecosystem.
In many cases, established firms looking to add platform capabilities already
have a client base, which can constitute one side of a platform. Their priority
should be to develop the other side – by inviting third-party producers – and
enabling matching, connecting and transacting between the two sides. Starting
from scratch is much more difficult since both sides need to be attracted at
the same time. Traditional business models have strengths that pure platforms
are unable to replicate. Therefore, markets where these strengths are key to
success can remain relatively protected. Irrespective of the response to platform
disruption, one thing is certain: the cultural shift required by many established
players is significant. Denying markets are being disrupted or trying to
194 Competing against platforms
drastic has to be done. A strong signal needs to be sent to the enemy, a credible
threat, or even in some cases a physical one, as in the case of French taxi
drivers turning on Uber drivers and their passengers. The ultimate objective
of deterrence is to make entry costly (and bias the risk/reward equation
underpinning the opportunity). This phase is usually associated with a strong
lobbying strategy in order to mobilize government agencies and policymakers
who can prevent disruptive entry through regulatory means. Public relations
campaigns are also often used during this stage to highlight the benefits of
the current market model and undermine the credibility of disruptors or
potential disruptors. From an economic perspective, the more protected the
incumbant business, the higher its incentives to invest in deterrence.
Delay: Delaying tactics are almost always used by established firms in order
to postpone disruption. In many cases, established firms operate within a broad
regulatory environment, and one of the most potent ways of delaying
disruptive entry is to use regulatory and legal arguments to prevent entrants
from being allowed to establish themselves. It is, however, important to also
highlight the fact that a number of global platforms may have been happy to
enter markets without first being fully compliant, and that testing legal
boundaries also comes at a price.
196 Competing against platforms
Enabling clients and relevant market participants is often a way of carving out
a sustainable market position. Instead of trying to protect existing equilibria
and market structures at all costs, it may be more effective to engage with
disruptors – while still from a position of strength – in order to find ways to
deliver superior market value. Platforms are very unique businesses that face
serious challenges before they reach a critical mass, and existing firms can
therefore find partnership opportunities. Of course, fear of cannibalization
has to be dealt with, and a simple strategy of enablement without value capture
is unlikely to be sustainable. However, it is important to recognize how the
formidable strengths of existing players in terms of brands, distribution channels
and access to finance can be combined with innovative platform entrants to
offer superior products and services. When Reed Hastings, founder of Netflix,
a new start-up at the time, approached Blockbuster’s CEO in 2000 to discuss
a potential partnership, he was apparently ‘laughed out of the office’.6 A few
years later, Blockbuster filed for bankruptcy. Both firms could have probably
benefited from a deal at the time, though apparently Blockbuster more so
than Netflix. Now partnerships and ecosystem management may involve
application programming interfaces (APIs) that firms can develop to give access
to some of their capabilities.7
Encouraging those who are a force for change internally – and externally – in
order to develop new organizational capabilities rather than support the status
quo will, in most cases, be more effective than simply delaying the entry of
198 Competing against platforms
Earning their keep instead of asking for compensation is the best way for firms
to develop a sustainable long-term position. This doesn’t mean that disrupted
companies should not invest in a robust regulatory defence, but the ultimate
objective should be to support a winning business strategy delivering a relevant
value proposition to the market rather than prevent competition from altering
the status quo. Betting the ranch on long-term regulatory protection from
innovation and more efficient entrants is a risky gamble.
to grasp the underlying economic models that are disrupting so many mar-
kets. The key to competing against platforms – or becoming one – is to
understand the way they operate and what it means for the industry and for
the business – both in terms of opportunities and threats. At a macro level,
industries characterized by relatively high transaction costs, asymmetry of
information and regulatory protection are now ripe for disruption by inno-
vative digital entrants. In many cases, these entrants have proven that customers
can be more efficiently served and transactions better coordinated through a
platform business model. Even if parts of an industry are not directly impacted
(for example, car production), the firms operating in this industry may see
that platforms are disrupting their market (for example, by undermining
car ownership and therefore depressing demand). Some traditional platforms,
such as lenders, estate agents or recruiters, also need to realize the threat for
them not to embrace a digital platform strategy. They operate in markets that
are particularly open to disruptive entry and cannot afford to rely on legacy
management systems, technology and processes.
(a) tell your board that all is fine – as your stock options vest quietly over
the next two years; carry on managing the existing business on a quarterly
basis and execute the current strategy – agreed by all – before moving on
to your next role/retiring; or
(b) go to your board and explain that the current strategy is under threat,
that the very basis of competition in your industry is changing, that you
need to reorganize globally and that this will be hard and risky work and
that dividends may need to be lowered over the next few years so that
you can invest to transform the business?
The established organizations able to incentivize choice (b) over choice (a)
have a significantly better chance to successfully deal with the kind of
disruption brought about by platforms. Launching your own platform is likely
to bring new challenges, such as potential cannibalization of the traditional
model itself. A new reward and incentive system may also be needed. This
is of course linked to the transformational aspects of the dynamic capabilities
that firms need to build to be able to remain relevant.
202 Competing against platforms
But while platforms are formidable business models in many respects, they
fail to deliver on a range of fronts. Many activities require tight control over
the value chain to ensure high quality and consistency, and platforms are not
good at enabling this. By focusing on markets where these characteristics are
prominent, it is possible to strengthen a competitive position that a platform
would struggle to undermine. It still leaves the business open to traditional
competitors, but at least fundamental disruption can be avoided. Some large
groups have just started to review their portfolio of activities in this light and
to consider disposing of assets in markets likely to be disrupted while
reinvesting in businesses less exposed to platform disruption.
Notes
1 We note a loose parallel between the organizational 5Ds we are using to describe firms’
responses to disruption and the Kubler-Ross model of grief that suggests a very personal
pattern starting with denial, anger, bargaining, depression and acceptance.
2 Richard S. Tedlow, Denial: Why Business Leaders Fail to Look Facts in the Face – and What
to Do About It, New York: Penguin Portfolio, 2010.
3 Black cabs in London are a good example of strong established market participants
who, while being among the best in the world in terms of market knowledge, security
and efficiency, are fighting hard to keep new entrants at bay. Their approach very
much matches the 5Ds described above, while we believe they would be a formidable
force if they were to embrace the 5Es instead.
4 It is worth noting that in France, taxi licences are given for free by the government but
subsequently traded by taxi drivers and taxi companies for substantial sums.
5 We agree with Peter Thiel when he says that markets where companies are able to gain
market power based on their innovations are a lot more attractive than markets where
undifferentiated companies compete on low margins to survive. See Peter Thiel,
‘Competition Is for Losers’, Wall Street Journal, 12 September 2014 (based on Zero to
One: Notes on Startups, or How to Build the Future).
6 Source: CNET, 9 December 2010, Greg Sandoval. https://www.cnet.com/uk/news/
blockbuster-laughed-out-at-netflix-partnership-offer/
7 Recent research by Seth Benzell, Guillermo Lagarda and Marshall Van Allstyne from Boston
University and MIT (12 July 2016) seems to suggest that firms adopting APIs become more
profitable than those who don’t. See http://questromworld.bu.edu/platformstrategy/
files/2016/07/S4-Seth-Benzell-Guillermo-Lagarda-role-apis-economy-7-12.pdf.
8 M. Wessel, ‘Why Big Companies Can’t Innovate’, Harvard Business Review, September
2012, https://hbr.org/2012/09/why-big-companies-cant-innovate.
9 See, for example, Wired article by Cade Metz dated 14 September 2015 titled ‘Silicon
Valley Success Goes to the Fastest, Not the First’.
10 P. Geroski and C. Markides, Fast Second: How Smart Companies Bypass Radical Innovation
to Enter and Dominate New Markets, San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass, 2005.
11 David Teece, ‘The Foundations of Enterprise Performance: Dynamic and Ordinary
Capabilities in an (Economic) Theory of Firms’, Academy of Management Perspectives, 8(4),
2014, 328–52.
204 Competing against platforms
12 Zalando generated €3.6 billion in 2016, with a growth rate of 23%, 17 January 2017,
Zalando’s corporate website.
13 ‘How Zalando Is Becoming the Online Fashion Platform for Europe’, 1 June 2016,
https://blog.zalando.com/en/blog/how-zalando-becoming-online-fashion-platform-
europe.
14 Murad Ahmed and Adam Thomson, ‘Accor to Acquire Online Home Rental Site
Onefinestay’, Financial Times, 5 April 2016.
Chapter 15
Not even the market designers themselves have all the answers: economics
is an inexact science, and every time we participate in a market innovation
– each time we hail a ride via a smartphone or download a song via iTunes
– we’re part of a massive social experiment whose ultimate consequences
are unknown.
While, like them, we remain optimistic and see the potential for good, we
are acutely aware that the long-term consequences of the current platform
revolution are unclear. Society will need to apply judgement and common
sense to ensure that the potential negative side effects of these innovative
business models are minimized. Platforms are likely to change the way people
work, are managed, get paid, share and collaborate, interact with others –
humans and ‘robots’ – generate insights from data, and organize themselves
to deal with world issues. We discuss these changes in turn in this final chapter.
shifts around one’s own life constraints (picking up kids from school, looking
after elderly relatives, etc.) can in some cases make the difference between
being able to work and having to stay at home, possibly relying on state
benefits. While some will no doubt see this flexibility as another form of
alienation,3 we can’t help but see it as an opportunity to unlock job creation
and economic growth. And we’re not alone. A recent McKinsey report
on talent platforms4 suggests that $2.7 trillion of value could be created by
talent platforms alone by 2025. This is equivalent to the GDP of the UK.
That amount could be generated simply by increasing labour force parti-
cipation for existing workers, reducing unemployment through better job
matching and raising productivity through better coordination of work
through platforms. In fact, the countries currently struggling with the most
inefficient labour markets are the ones that would benefit the most from the
development of talent platforms.5 Upwork now has more than 12 million
freelancers globally who can help with coding duties, graphic design, financial
planning, etc. and over 10,000 sign-ups every day.
Firms can tap into these platforms in order to supplement their own
capabilities or develop their own internal platforms to flexibly secure the skills
and capabilities they need. Eden McCallum, a successful management
consulting firm headquartered in the UK, uses a hybrid model of full-time
analysts and partners supplemented by hundreds of part-time consultants who
are members of its platform. Launchworks, our own advisory business, uses
some of the same principles to develop its global network of platform experts.
And this is just the beginning. Existing platforms are still very much version
1.0 of talent platforms. While existing models focus on connecting companies
with individual contributors, new generations of platforms will allow entire
teams to coordinate projects and offer turnkey solutions. HoneyBook, for
example, is a platform connecting event managers, creative professionals and
clients. It provides tools to coordinate a team of producers (caterers, photo-
graphs, venue rental, make-up, event planning, etc.) to manage events
throughout their entire life cycle, from the proposal to invoicing stages.
However, the transition from a traditional labour market to a platform-
powered one is unlikely to go smoothly for all. As the physical location of
platform workers is increasingly irrelevant for some jobs, the cost of work
can be driven down significantly. This has been happening for years in the
manufacturing sector, with China becoming the world’s factory. Platforms
are now enabling this for services. Entire businesses now rely on externalized
flexible workforces for a range of activities. Amazon’s Mechanical Turk,6 for
example, provides ‘businesses and developers access to an on-demand scalable
workforce’, while ‘workers can select from thousands of tasks and work
whenever it’s convenient’. Tasks are called HITs (human intelligence tasks)
The future of platforms 207
and can be posted – and carried out – by anybody. Testing features of a web-
site, transcribing a recording, tagging content of pictures, answering questions
of a survey, and moderating content of a blog are some of the hundred of
thousands of tasks posted on the site at any point in time. In fact, some
companies outsource entire processes, such as the 24/7 monitoring of com-
ments on a blog or the tagging of images before their publication, to the
Mechanical Turk. Since these tasks can be carried out globally, unless a specific
expertise is required, such as language or coding skills, the pricing is quite
low by US or European standards. This means that many ‘low-level’ tasks
can now be efficiently and flexibly outsourced to a platform, and that therefore
‘high-cost’ workers are increasingly unlikely to be able to compete for these
activities. You don’t need to have offices everywhere to arbitrage labour
market rates anymore. Knowledge workers are now a click away, and this is
understandably one aspect of globalization that is increasingly worrying
employees and governments.
market outcome unless the CEO constantly arbitrates between ‘side owners’
in order to ensure that the platform is balanced. For example, rewarding the
head of one side of the business with additional resources based on his success,
something seen as natural in a traditional firm, may result in increased
imbalance on the platform and undermine its overall success. We are increas-
ingly seeing calls for more flexible organizational forms allowing iterative
resource allocation decisions between sides, depending upon which one is a
bottleneck for the growth of the platform at a given point in time. This
requires management able to internalize and orchestrate more holistic success
metrics. Platforms typically need employees and leaders who understand and
are able to harness dynamic network effects rather than staff who can optimize
static processes.
Financial management is also drastically different, with some platforms being
able to largely outsource some of the risks of trading physical stocks and
associated cash flow requirements onto platform participants. That’s why
marketplaces such as eBay or Alibaba have been able to scale-up quickly with
a huge inventory without incurring these costs. Alternatively, platforms are
able to reduce risk through data analytics to more effectively deploy their
own capital. Deliveroo, the restaurant delivery marketplace, knows so much
about areas lacking quality food, that it recently announced it would partner
with restaurants and invest in setting up dedicated kitchens – so-called
RooBoxes – in order to further stimulate the growth of the platform.
Lastly, platforms themselves increasingly require specific talents. The
necessity to manage an ecosystem often requires technology-savvy individuals,
comfortable with ambiguity and fluid networks, to help design and grow the
platform. Generally, we see talents with advanced degrees and more inter-
national outlooks attracted to, and successful at, the kinds of challenges that
potentially global platforms throw up. Lastly, we see significant transferable
skills from one platform to another, even across industries, and we are starting
to see talents able to build on their experiences with ‘platform careers’
spanning multiple firms. Our own corporate and consulting experience at
Launchworks strongly points to the importance of having senior individuals
able to build and deploy cross-industry platform knowledge.
BlaBlaCar for car-sharing trips, Airbnb for home rentals, Love Home Swap
for home exchanges).
• Knowledge sharing, such as massive open online course (MOOC)
platforms connecting students all over the world with universities (edX,
FUN, Coursera).
• Money sharing, where projects can be financed through crowdfunding
or crowd-lending platforms (Kiva, Kickstarter, Lending Club).
• Time/service sharing, where people can share their time and expertise,
on an ad hoc or regular basis with others in need (Stootie, TaskRabbit,
Thumbtack).
• Content sharing, from music platforms connecting amateur artists and
listeners (SoundCloud) to user-generated content platforms (Reddit).
Many of the platforms that we have talked about in this book are for-profit
private companies, often backed by sizeable VC investments. Their business
model is designed to maximize the value that they can capture and reward their
shareholders accordingly. When successful, platforms can indeed return very
significant sums to their backers, as early shareholders of the GAFAMs (Google,
Apple, Facebook, Amazon and Microsoft) will testify. Even when platform
participants are not allowed to make a profit themselves,7 the platform owner
can generate significant profits as a result of the service provided. While this
has enabled the development of successful large-scale transformative platform
companies, bringing much-needed efficiency to numerous markets, many now
believe that the promise of platforms powering the ‘sharing economy’ is flawed.
The initial dream of green ‘co-creation’ and ‘co-consumption’ enabled by
platforms and shared by many early platform enthusiasts seems to have been
replaced by a platform-powered capitalist market economy more able to extract
value from both its workers and its assets.
The arguments that have been raised against such platforms include:8 (i)
they are for-profit and therefore concentrate rather than redistribute wealth;
(ii) they aim at becoming dominant and driving out other market participants;
(iii) they are not really green as they stimulate consumption; (iv) they replicate
discrimination biases rather than solve them; (v) they exploit labour by
breaking/circumventing existing laws; (vi) they shift the risk of production
from the company to the participants; and (vii) they are managed privately
top-down rather than by their participants bottom-up.
Many of these arguments are not without merit, and privately owned
platforms do indeed seem to accumulate wealth for their shareholders – like
most successful businesses. Platforms also reflect some discriminatory biases
already present in society. Everything else being equal, a study showed that
210 The future of platforms
the size of their profits. Kickstarter measures project success rates (typically
only 9% of projects fail to deliver results)13 as a key driver of added value.
It is also very possible that more open, decentralized platforms, with shared
governance models, as advocated by many within the sharing economy
movement, are able to scale and offer successful alternatives not controlled by
large corporations. Sites such as OpenBazaar, while in their infancy at the time
of writing, are proposing totally open, not-for-profit, peer-to-peer platform
functionalities to buy and sell a wide range of goods and services. Underground
platforms that have existed on the Dark Web for years, such as Silk Road, have
also shown that organic bottom-up platform models could succeed (and even
reach a critical mass of buyers and sellers of illegal goods and services!).
Platform of things
Automation
Platform ecosystems will increasingly include automated ‘sides’. If the future
that GM is preparing for materializes soon, we will have the option to hail
(or pre-book) a self-driving car from an app in just a few years’ time.14 This
is not as far-fetched as many people think, and since the disruptive entry of
Tesla, Uber and Google in the race for self-driving capabilities, the pressure
212 The future of platforms
has been mounting for traditional car manufacturers to get their act together.
It is relatively easy to imagine a platform model where one side is entirely
automated. There may still be a market for hand-driven rides (like handmade
suits) for many years to come, but self-driving cars certainly have the potential
to replace cab – and truck – drivers within a generation. In fact, parts of
platform business models are likely to become automated in the near future.
Home automation is now around the corner with a range of controllable
devices, from thermostat to audiovisual equipment, representing entry points
for companies keen on developing their ecosystems. Google acquired Nest
and Dropcam to extend the reach of its platform-powered ecosystem into
the home; Amazon has its innovative, always-on Alexa speaker; Microsoft is
trying to leverage the role of its Xbox and Windows 10, etc. Many of the
connected devices that will appear over the next few years will be able to
interact with various apps within, or even across, different platform-powered
ecosystems. The development of cross-platform IoT enabling Web services
such as If This Then That (IFTTT.com) or Yonomi – which allow users to
connect and control devices from different manufacturers – is testimony
to the growth potential of these applications.
So far we have not been able to use technology to connect people to the
needs of the poorest in countries that are [too] far away to tap into their
empathy. I think this can be done but it needs some missing creativity.
possible to find ways to create this empathic connection that Jeremy Rifkin
is so keen on. For example, an app – maybe a role-playing game – where
the character being played is randomly generated – using real-world statistics
– and has to overcome real-life challenges could help with this. Once the
character ‘dies’ in the virtual world, the money generated by the game (either
directly or through sponsorship) gets paid to the most relevant charity for
that particular cause of death. This simple example would provide a platform
business model with gamers on one side and charities on the other side, and
the money allocated would go to these while creating a strong empathic
experience between the virtual character and the player.
In fact, we believe such models are so worth exploring that we decided
that we would dedicate all the royalties generated by this book to support
such non-profit platform projects. There is no reason the power of commu-
nities that underpins the private platform businesses discussed in this book
cannot be replicated to deal with some of the world’s greatest challenges.
After all, everybody needs a platform strategy . . . what is yours?
Notes
1 World Economic Forum, Future of Jobs report, January 2016.
2 WEF Future of Jobs report, January 2016. With 44% of respondents, mainly human
resources representatives from organizations representing more than 13 million employees
in total, the topic of the changing nature of work was far ahead of all other strategic
considerations, including growth of the mobile Internet and cloud technologies (with
34%) or increased processing power and big data (with 26%).
3 For a full Marxist analysis of these developments, see Nick Dyer-Witheford, Cyber-
Proletariat: Global Labour in the Digital Vortex, 15 May 2015, or Ursula Huws, Labor in
the Global Digital Economy: The Cybertariat Comes of Age, 10 December 2014.
4 A Labor Market That Works: Connecting Talent with Opportunity in the Digital Age,
McKinsey Global Institute, June 2015.
5 The McKinsey report mentions that Spain, Greece, Portugal, Italy and France would
benefit the most in Europe, while South Africa, Colombia, the Philippines, Egypt and
Russia would be the emerging economies benefiting the most. The US would also benefit
significantly through increased participation and faster matching of jobs.
6 See www.mturk.com/mturk/welcome.
7 Such as in the case of BlaBlaCar where only a contribution to the costs of driving from
A to B can be levied by the driver, or charity-enabling platforms such as JustGiving that
connect givers and good causes.
8 See, for example, Juliet Schor, ‘Debating the Sharing Economy’, October 2014, for a
good summary of the debate: www.greattransition.org/publication/debating-the-sharing-
economy#sthash.wjx6WQ6c.dpuf.
9 11 December 2015, CNN, http://money.cnn.com/2015/12/11/technology/airbnb-
bias-harvard/. It is worth noting that Airbnb has since implemented robust anti-
discrimination provisions that are aimed at improving this.
The future of platforms 215
10 See, for example, Bloomberg article dated 2 May 2016 on universal basic income:
www.bloombergview.com/articles/2016-05-02/a-basic-income-should-be-the-next-
big-thing.
11 www.theverge.com/2014/9/30/6874353/reddit-50-million-funding-give-users-10-
percent-stock-equity and www.reddit.com/r/AskReddit/comments/2moyiz/serious_
how_should_reddit_inc_distribute_a/.
12 21 September 2015, Kickstarter blog, www.kickstarter.com/blog/kickstarter-is-now-a-
benefit-corporation?ref=charter.
13 Kickstarter fulfilment report, www.kickstarter.com/fulfillment.
14 At the time of writing, the Singapore Autonomous Vehicle Initiative (SAVI) is running
live trials of autonomous cars.
15 Moore’s law states that computer processing power doubles every two years.
16 Sharetribe promises to have your platform business running in a few minutes without
the need for a developer . . . give it a go at www.sharetribe.com/.
17 J. Rifkin, The Empathic Civilization, New York: Jeremy P. Tarcher, 2010.
A word from the authors
We hope you enjoyed reading Platform Strategy and learned a thing or two
about platforms along the way.
Platform business models are changing many areas of our lives at an unpre-
cedented pace. When we started writing this book, very little had been written
about the practical principles of platform management. Now we see new
platform businesses being launched every day and, increasingly, established
businesses launching or acquiring their own platforms. We also come across
a range of useful studies, conferences, reports and books touching upon plat-
form strategy and related topics.
If you’re interested in keeping track of these developments you may want
to check the book’s companion web site: www.platformstrategy.co, where
you will find additional resources on how to design, ignite and scale your
own platform.
Also we are always interested in hearing about platforms so feel free to
drop us a line at benoit@platformstrategy.co and laure@platformstrategy.co.
Index
governance 51, 76, 140, 165, 167; pre- market power 37, 173–6, 180–3, 186, 197
launch 87; trust framework 155, 157, 162, market sizing 79–80
164–70 Mastercard 5, 23, 26, 80, 134
Gumtree 132, 143 match 75; ignition 97–101, 115; maturity
124; platform participants 47–8, 52, 84–5,
Hailo (MyTaxi) 93, 185 95; pre-launch 86; scaling-up 114–15
HiGear 163 maturity 73, 75–6, 121–2, 127–8
home automation 212 media companies 25
Honda 27 membership fees 139, 143–4
hotels 1, 3, 7, 79, 179–80 meshed communities 94–5
Microsoft 13–14, 23, 28, 63, 65, 70, 125,
IBM 14, 26, 194 143; ecosystem 70, 130, 132; home
ignition 73, 74, 91–102; eBay 53–4; automation 212
Facebook 95, 96 minimum viable product see MVP
indirect network effects 34–5 monetization 50, 67, 86, 100, 116, 142,
indirect platforms 80–1 147
innovation 140, 170, 174; maturity 127, MSP (multisided platforms) 25, 46
128; regulation 174, 186, 199 multihoming 36–7, 149, 176, 177
Instagram 70, 99, 107, 110, 133 multisided markets 5, 23–4, 46
insurance 164 multisided platforms see MSP
intervention 175 MVP (minimum viable product) 91, 100–1
intimacy 156 MyTaxi 93
IT infrastructure 52
negative externalities 32, 180
key enablers 51, 52 Netflix 26, 197
Kickstarter 78, 109, 210 network effects 33–5, 35, 48, 52, 68, 99,
133, 176; positive 48, 115, 126, 133, 142,
La Belle Asiette 93–4, 99 149
labour laws 177 networks 31, 33–5
Launchworks 21, 157, 206, 208 North Star metric 86, 100, 119
leakage 49, 126, 147–8
leverage 61, 62, 70, 88, 124–5 on-boarding processes 107–8, 168
linear businesses 6, 12, 41–2, 44, 52 Onefinestay 200–1
LinkedIn 49, 70, 100, 107, 143, 150, online platforms 11, 50, 51, 162
159 OpenTable 93
liquidity 33, 52, 143; ignition 99, 101; operating systems 5, 6, 25, 34; Android 58,
scaling-up 117 67, 185–6
listing fees 144 optimize 50, 76; ignition 100, 101; maturity
Lyft 15, 132, 174, 176, 202 128, 130; pre-launch 74, 86; scaling-up
116
management principles 6, 7, 207 over-regulation 174
management rules 7, 17
market failures 167, 175–6, 187 Parker, G. 23, 25–6
market makers 24–5 partners 45, 79, 128
marketplace platforms 12, 15, 48, 26, 59, payment platforms 6, 24, 48
61, 85 PayPal 95, 131, 187
marketplaces 6, 26, 64, 49, 59, 84, 85, 208 performance metrics 100, 117, 127
220 Index
trust 45, 49, 51, 84, 87, 99, 106, 115, 121, value chains 6, 42–3, 52–3, 202–3
130, 147, 153 value creation 11, 50, 78, 139, 174, 193,
trust framework 153, 155, 157, 165, 211
188 value propositions 57, 63, 82, 112, 196,
Twitter 69, 96, 159, 163 197; maturity 112; pre-launch 82;
tying strategies 182–3 scaling-up 112, 133, 142
Van Alstyne, M. 23, 25–6
Uber 11, 15, 22, 52, 108, 177; business VIP strategy 96
model 24, 79; price strategies 81, 140; viral loops 110
regulation 140, 162, 167, 174, 177 Visa 5, 14, 23, 26, 80–1, 134
UberEATS 133
under-regulation 174 WeChat 6, 97, 132
unfair competition 3, 174, 180–1, 186 WhatsApp 70, 110
unicorns 15–16
Upwork 47, 88, 126, 159, 169, 206 YouTube (Google) 67–9, 131, 182, 183,
user acquisition 93, 97, 107–10, 122; 186
see also platform participants
user retention 107–8, 111, 122 Zalando 12, 102, 200