Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

On Efficiency of Production Under Imperfect Competition

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 2

1

Annotated Bibliography

Ohta H. (1976). On Efficiency of Production under Conditions of Imperfect Competition.

Southern Economic Journal, 43(2), 1124-1135.https://doi.org/10.2307/1057337 In light

of the recent article that Greenhut M.L. that M.L. Greenhut has launched a new edition of

his theory of imperfect competition and presents a brief presentation, as well as the clear

reorganization of his same original proposition which states that imperfect competition

leads the market results isomorphic to perfectly competitive outcomes Demetz, on the

other hand, claims that this theory is incorrect and argues that “efficiency in production

can prevail if what he calls an average revenue (MAR) curve is bell-shaped.” Dewey on

the other hand also disagrees, he claimed that excess capacity would be “eliminated by

the rationalization process.” Contrary to Dewey, Greenhut proposes that “free entry, exit,

and relocation of firms, competition rather than a merger, will yield a stable, unique, and

efficient tangency equilibrium under oligopolistic condition.” This paper will provide an

articulate view of the new evidence of Greenhut's proposition regarding a certain

behavioral assumption and related theories of Demetz and Dewey that requires initial

examination to give us an understanding that imperfect competition firms will produce

efficiently in comparison to the perfect competitor. Demetz's theory recognized that

average revenue is the result of a firm's product profits determined by the cost of sales

promotion. And each level of selling costs produces a different average revenue; the

firm's revenue ultimately has become a function of its selling costs S along with the

quantity Q supplied. Dewey, on the other hand, suggested two alternative models for
imperfect competition that will demonstrate that

Chamberlinian tangency will not always lead to stable non-Chanbelinean equilibrium. In

his solution, he uses firm mergers rather than average revenue and average cost.

Greenhut's revised prior proposition focuses on the entry, exit, and relocation processes

required for the required movement to the unique-stable equilibrium tangency point. He

makes the following fundamental assumptions: (a) a homogeneous buyer community is

equitably spread across an economic space.; (b) homogeneous firms are concentrated in

the same particular region, and (c) these firms are also subject to intralocal and interlocal

competition.

Demsetz's objections are rather deceptive; after all, the shape of MAR is not required to

be bell-shaped in order to come to Demsetz's conclusion. Dewey's final proposition is

perplexing because it contradicts his fundamental assumption. Nonetheless, Dewey

claims that it reflects production efficiency, as one merged firm can produce any given

product more cheaply than two firms (or n firms) working independently. According to

Greenhut's model, free entry eliminates excess profits, whereas exit can be characterized

by changes in firm size and location.

The Robinson-Chamberlin claim that imperfect competition most likely leads to

inefficient production was overplayed, as we see Demestz, Dewey, and Greenhut refute

indicates that imperfect competition does not technically result in inefficient

production.

You might also like