A Farewell To Alms Clark en 9377.simple
A Farewell To Alms Clark en 9377.simple
A Farewell To Alms Clark en 9377.simple
Princeton UP © 2007
getAbstract © 2013
1/10
Take-Aways
Neolithic and 18th-century living standards were comparable.
European living standards rose only after the Industrial Revolution.
Before that time, all societies were stuck in a “Malthusian trap.”
In this Malthusian world, technological change was extremely slow.
Perversely, anything that increased mortality also increased living
standards.
The Industrial Revolution, when it came, was not a sharp break with the
past.
Nineteenth century economic growth was due mostly to the reproductive
success of the rich.
“Middle class” cultural traits consequently spread throughout society.
Because of this, the West has triumphed in terms of living standards.
But material prosperity does not bring happiness.
2/10
Recommendation
The topic of this thrilling book, 20 years in the making, is nothing less than the
history of civilization, from the Neolithic Revolution to the Industrial
Revolution to today. Rather than relating history as a story of kings, Caesars,
popes, prelates and presidents, Gregory Clark tells the story through economic
data, much of which is the result of his own analysis of documentary evidence.
Almost every other page contains a beautiful graph, table or chart illuminating
some dimly lit bit of history. And Clark’s detours are almost as wonderful as
his main argument. His writing is elegant and clear, his sense of humor present
but not annoying. While this book has outraged some commentators, it’s hard
to see why, given the caution with which Clark presents his conclusions. Most
likely, the flash point is his stress on culture as enabling and retarding
economic growth – views that sometimes get wrongly equated with racism.
getAbstract recommends this book to anyone who wants to quantitatively
enhance his or her conception of human history.
3/10
Summary
5/10
Rather, it was an acceleration of a long-term trend. The march of technological
progress was already under way well before 1800. Progress was gradual and
varied a great deal over time. In fact, even finding a date for the Industrial
Revolution is hard. It could be 1800, but dividing lines could also be drawn at
1860, 1600 or even 1200. Moreover, the rise in income per person since 1800,
which truly is dramatic, was the result not only of technological advances but
also of declining fertility. Starting with the upper classes and then cascading
downward, couples had fewer children.
Traditional explanations of the Industrial Revolution don’t fit the data. Some
economic historians claim the Industrial Revolution resulted from shocks
outside the economic system. Typically, these shocks would have included
occurrences such as changes in political institutions and the rise of democratic
forms of government. But, in societies like England’s, most of the institutions
necessary for economic growth existed by 1200. The incentives to work hard
and invest were actually better at that time than during the modern age. Other
historians claim that preindustrial human societies remained caught in a stable
equilibrium and that something moved preindustrial economies out of this
stasis to a dynamic equilibrium. For years, economists have examined the
period just before 1800 for the agent of such a change. Coal? Colonies? Sadly,
this approach has failed to find convincing supporting data.
One of the more puzzling questions about the Industrial Revolution is why it
occurred in Europe, and not in China, Japan or India. The answer is that the
Industrial Revolution in Europe was an accident of history, largely the result of
European social customs. For example, England was a stable society and had
been since around 1200. Its population growth started to slow around 1300.
Stable economies and lower birth rates were both necessary for economic
growth. But China and Japan had stable societies that exemplified the
middle-class values of thrift, hard work, honesty and education, just like
English society. China and Japan were on their way to accelerating economic
growth, but they lacked one factor: an increasingly fecund upper class and the
consequent distribution of middle-class values (or habits) down the social
hierarchy. In Japan during the Tokugawa era, for instance, the rich had so few
children that those offspring could remain in jobs appropriate to their “station.”
Good for them, but not for the economy as a whole.
6/10
But that’s not the way things worked out. Instead, a few countries became
spectacularly rich while many countries stayed poor or, like some African
nations, became poorer. Living standards in England circa 1800 may have been
as much as two-and-a-half times better than living standards in Malawi today.
This great divergence between the rich and the poor countries is evident in
wage differentials. An hour of an Indian apparel worker’s time is now worth 38
cents; an hour of a United States apparel worker’s time is worth $9.
You can find part of the answer to this puzzle by looking at data from the
cotton textile industry. It is indicative, mostly because cotton textile
manufacturing provided a good natural experiment: It appeared in the early
years of the Industrial Revolution in both rich and poor countries. Workers in
England and India used the same machines and the same material. The result?
Output in India was far lower than output in England. Indian textile workers at
the dawn of the Industrial Revolution supplied very little labor compared to
English workers. (Even today, Indian textile workers actually work for as little
as 15 minutes an hour.) The same pattern emerges from 19th-century data on
the railway industry in rich and poor countries. Poor countries had the same
machinery – the same locomotives and tracks. But productivity was shockingly
low and economic growth suffered.
Was this because of poor government institutions or geography? Possibly both
played a role, but a more plausible answer lies in the social environment.
English cultural traits had not yet become widespread in many poor countries.
English workers were simply more conscientious and disciplined than Indian
workers, and the great divergence followed. Unfortunately, the great
divergence remains. Today’s world contains people richer than any in history.
It also contains human beings who are poorer than people have been for
millennia.
The even worse news is that contemporary manufacturing requires ever more
conscientiousness and discipline, since an error in the production chain can
often entirely destroy a day’s products. Crucially, though, all this emphatically
does not mean that the poor world is “destined” to stay poor. Human societies
are remarkably adaptive. Historically, northern Germany was economically
dominant over the south, but that situation is now reversed. Shortly after World
War I, the north of England traded places with the south in terms of economic
energy. And Ireland, which was desperately poor for more than 200 years, has
recently become as rich as England, its traditional economic superior. After all,
who standing in the England of, say, 300 A.D. would have predicted that a
small island nation centered there would extend its empire around the world?
And recall those “middle class” values that could have allowed the Industrial
Revolution to occur in China. These seeds have lately bloomed. Not even some
7/10
30 years of communism could destroy the cultural basis for economic growth
in China. Japan, though obviously never communist, has recovered remarkably
from its own calamity, World War II.
8/10
About the Author
Gregory Clark, an economic historian, is chair of the economics department at
the University of California, Davis.
9/10
Quotes
“As long as technology improved slowly, material conditions could not
permanently improve.”
“Since the Industrial Revolution...we have entered a strange new world in
which economic theory is of little use in understanding differences in income
across societies.”
“Primitive man ate well compared with one of the richest societies in the world
in 1800.”
“Foraging and shifting cultivation societies had a form of ‘primitive
affluence’...measured in the abundance of leisure as opposed to goods.”
“The plague was not the harsh judgment of a vengeful Old Testament God on a
sinful Europe, but merely a mild reproof by a beneficent New Age-style deity.”
“Given the static nature of the economy and of the opportunities it afforded, the
abundant children of the rich had to, on average, move down the social
hierarchy.”
“There is, in fact, nothing inherently industrial about the Industrial
Revolution.”
“The increased rate of innovation in Industrial Revolution England was the
result not of unusual rewards but of a greater supply of innovation, still
modestly rewarded.”
“Poor countries used the same technology as rich ones. They achieved the
same levels of output per unit of capital. But in doing so they employed so
much more labor per machine that they lost most of the labor cost advantages
with which they began.”
“Societies subject to Malthusian constraints were not necessarily particularly
poor, even by the standards of today.”
“High incomes profoundly shape lifestyles in the modern developed world. But
wealth has not brought happiness. Another foundational assumption of
economics is incorrect.”
“People in contemporary countries as poor as those of the world before 1800
on average report little difference in happiness from those in very rich
countries, such as the United States.”
“Modern man might not be designed for contentment. The envious have
inherited the earth.”
10/10