This Content Downloaded From 13.239.75.78 On Thu, 19 Jan 2023 07:00:16 UTC
This Content Downloaded From 13.239.75.78 On Thu, 19 Jan 2023 07:00:16 UTC
This Content Downloaded From 13.239.75.78 On Thu, 19 Jan 2023 07:00:16 UTC
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Cambridge University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to Journal of Public Policy
In Whose Interest?
Pressure Group Politics, Econommic Competition
and Environmental Regulation
ABSTRACT
Basic arguments
Empirical relevance
All of the above explanations involve assumptions about 'bottom up' forces
in regulatory policy. For example, theories of competition in regulatory
laxity and public choice theory assume that industry interests tend to
dominate over consumer (or public) interests. In the former theories,
industry is assumed to favour laxer regulation because laxer regulation
increases firms' international competitiveness. In the latter theory, industry
is assumed to favour stricter regulation because such regulation offers rents.
Trading-up arguments, for their part, assume 'green' public preferences
in large importing jurisdictions and their transmission to firms (and
governments) abroad via international trade and multinational corporations.
We propose to refine these rather simplistic assumptions about consumer
and producer preferences and their effects on regulation and environmental
or public health outcomes along two lines. First, we develop an interest
group politics argument that endogenises public perceptions, regulators'
preferences and other factors largely ignored in theories of this nature. The
empirical relevance of this argument is illustrated with a case study on
growth hormones. Second, in the subsequent section we disentangle the
aforesaid contradictions between public choice and regulatory laxity argu-
ments with regard to producer preferences by exploring why and how firms
may seek stricter regulation to enhance their competitiveness. We also assess
the effects on regulatory policy. The empirical relevance of this argument is
illustrated with case studies on electronic waste and HACCP (a system for
controlling food safety).
The starting point for an answer to why the producer dominance hypothesis
appears to be inconsistent with the empirical evidence in many cases of
environmental and consumer regulation can be found in Mancur Olson's
'Logic of Collective Action'.4
Olson observed that some groups are more likely to organize collectively
because they are more adept at overcoming free-rider problems than others.
Specifically, he hypothesized that large (latent) groups are difficult to
mobilize. The underlying logic is as follows. Consumer and environmental
organizations are pressure groups that offer a 'collective good', that is,
consumer or environmental protection. The production of collective goods
is usually plagued by a free-rider problem.
We pick up at this point and assume that NGOs are aware of their
collective action problem, and that they follow a rational strategy (such as to
try and maximize their budget or other utility). NGOs will, therefore, tend
to focus on issues that allow for maximum mobilization of membership,
fundraising, and public support more generally. Public concerns or risk
perceptions are likely to be decisive in determining the 'winability' of an
issue from an NGO perspective (Meins 2003; Gormley I986).
The extent to which public concerns become politically relevant is largely
a matter of public risk perceptions5 and the problem solving capacity of
regulators, particularly as expressed by the effectiveness of previous risk
management policies (Caduff 2003). If the public in a given country is more
critical or fearful of a particular technology (or risk more generally), in ways
and for reasons to be identified, NGOs are likely to be more successful in
mobilizing their memberships if they decide to campaign for more regu-
latory restrictions. Furthermore, if particular risk regimes are characterized
by weak institutional rules for addressing public distrust, low transparency in
decision making, delayed action in the face of critical events, and severe
implementation failures, public trust in regulatory institutions and the
creators of risk, that is, industry, will erode, whereas NGOs' credibility with
the public will increase (see also Jacobsen 2002). In other words, we expect
that NGOs will organize around a particular policy issue and campaign for
regulatory restrictions more extensively and successfully if public concerns or
fears about a given technology or consumer or environmental risk are strong
competitive position. For example, some large firms may lobby for stricter
environmental or consumer regulation that would be too costly for smaller
firms to implement, whereas smaller firms within the same industry and the
same country oppose such regulation.'0
We now connect these arguments to the above proposition on the political
power of NGOs. An issue of high concern to the average voter and
associated campaigns by environmental and consumer groups can exert
'pull' and 'push' effects on producers (industry). Public concerns and NGO
campaigns can act as facilitators for rent-seeking by producers. 'Strange
bedfellow' coalitions of environmental/consumer and producer interests that
lobby for the same stricter regulation, but for different reasons, are
expressions of this possibility. Such pull effects can weaken producer
coalitions that oppose stricter regulation to the extent that incentives to
'piggy-back' on public concerns and NGO campaigns differ across firms or
types of producers in a given industry. Public concerns and NGO campaigns
can also exert 'push' effects by coercing producers that do not expect to
benefit from stricter regulation into supporting or tolerating such regulation.
Again, differences in industrial structure and competitive position of firms
are likely to determine the extent to which particular producers in a given
industry are more or less susceptible to push effects. For example, some
producers may be more vulnerable to public pressure and NGO campaigns
than others because they have valuable brands to protect, or simply because
they are bigger, which makes them a more attractive target for NGOs. In
addition, organizational and economic rigidities in particular economic
sectors may also shape the extent to which push effects translate into changes
in industry behaviour. For example, low economic concentration and poor
political organization may (paradoxically, at first glance) make certain
industrial sectors less vulnerable to NGO campaigns.
In summary, the argument outlined here holds that public concerns and
NGO campaigns generate pull and push effects on producers. Contingent on
differences in industrial structure, the extent to which these effects weaken
producers' political power will vary across issues and countries.
(Cohen I980: 2). Sales of meat dropped by 50 per cent in France and West
Germany during the boycott (Der Spiegel I982/3:76). Since the agricultural
policy of the EU at that time provided for guaranteed fixed purchases, the
unsold veal of that year resulted in a loss of io million ECU to the EU's
budget (Europe Daily Bulletin I985/4042:8).
European producers of growth hormones, organized in the Federation of
Animal Health (FEDESA),12 tried to convince the public and policy-makers
not to prohibit growth hormones, but to begin more systematic scientific
investigation of their public health effects (Economist I984, Feb 25). FEDESA
even tried, unsuccessfully, to shape public opinion by warning regulators and
the public that banning growth hormones could lead to more illegal and
dangerous growth hormone use: 'Remember the US alcohol prohibition
laws? Contraband was rife and the black market flourished!' (FEDESA
campaign, quoted in Brand and Ellerton I989: 4,5).
Producers were clearly disadvantaged in competing for influence on
public opinion, mainly for two reasons. First, highly publicised hormone
scandals and associated NGOs campaigns had led to an erosion of public
trust in producers and regulatory institutions, whereas NGOs' credibility
with the public increased. FEDESA's large investments in public relations
campaigns failed in turning this trend around (Brand and Ellerton I989).
Moreover, government authorities failed to fully inform the public on the
issue, which added substantially to escalating public fears of growth
hormones (European ParliamentWI2/I995:8). Second, FEDESA's position
on the issue was weakened by the fact that some producer groups joined
hands with NGOs. Through boycotts and lobbying activity, consumer
groups exerted 'pull' and 'push' effects on producers. On the one hand,
public concerns and NGO campaigns facilitated rent-seeking by some
producer groups, notably, import-competing, family-owned farmers in Italy,
France, and some other countries, which did not use growth hormones.
These producers tried to capture protectionist rents vis-'a-vis foreign com-
petitors as well as domestic economic benefits vis-'a-vis more efficient,
large-scale EU meat producers. On the other hand, market developments
made clear that consumers demanded 'natural' products. This had evident
implications for farmers using growth hormones, wholesalers, and retailers.
Fearing further losses, these producers decided to provide higher beef
quality, that is, hormone free beef. To avoid competitive disadvantages
(hormone use lowers production costs), however, they demanded strict
implementation of the ban in all EU member states, as well as an
internationalization of EU policy, i.e., an import ban on hormone-treated
meat from third countries. These demands were met in I989.
When, in I989, the EU's hormone ban was extended to imports from
third countries, US meat producers began to experience annual losses in
the order of $I30 million per year. Though this loss has amounted to only
o.I per cent of the EU-US annual trade volume, the EU's hormone ban has
led to one of the longest and most acrimonious transatlantic trade disputes.
By I999, the dispute had moved through the WTO's dispute settlement
mechanism. The final verdict supported the US claim that the European ban
on hormone' treated meat was not based on sufficient scientific evidence. The
US and Canada have since been retaliating against the EU's restrictions.
To summarize, by means of their various informational and lobbying
activities, NGOs offered an effective avenue for translating widespread
consumer concerns into political and market initiatives. Taking advantage of
pre-existing public concerns, they were largely successful in amplifying these
concerns. As market developments made clear, many consumers in Europe
perceived hormone-free beef as offering a health benefit to the individual
consumer. And policy makers and producers in Europe had to acknowledge
that fact. As noted by the EU's Council of Ministers: 'Because of campaigns
by consumer organizations, the consumption of meat had, in the past, at
various times, noticeably declined. These campaigns are not just based on
concerns as regards the health hazards of hormones, but express a general
tendency in public opinion, namely the aversion to the use of chemicals in
agriculture. A legalization of hormones would, therefore, lead to an even
more extensive wave of protest and an even greater decline in meat
consumption' (quoted in European Court ofJustice I988: 4045).
rent seeking harder (see also above) firms are increasingly using environ-
mental performance strategies to enhance their competitive position in
domestic and international markets (Hoffman 2000).
As a starting point we submit that firms are increasingly engaging in
environmental performance strategies and are pushing for stricter govern-
ment regulation to back these strategies. We also submit that these processes
have, under conditions to be specified, positive effects on environmental and
public health outcomes. Analysis of this hypothesis requires answers to two
questions. First, what is motivating firms to pursue environmental perform-
ance (or, 'beyond compliance') strategies, and when and why are firms
pushing for stricter public regulation to back these strategies? Second, when
and why do corporate environmental performance strategies and stricter
public regulation improve corporate competitiveness and/or environmental
(or public health) outcomes. In this article we concentrate on the first
question because we are interested in the driving forces of increasing
regulatory stringency.'6
Our research to date suggests that firms engage in corporate environ-
mental performance strategies (which may involve over-compliance with
public regulation) for several reasons, including the following:
to cut production costs and thereby improve competitiveness on the supply side: strategies to that
end focus on reducing materials and energy use and waste, on more efficient
product and production process design, on developing environmentally friendly
product substitutes, and on reducing business risks and their financial implications
(e.g., reducing exposure to product liability or compensation claims, shielding
against non-insurable risks, reducing insurance costs);
to improve competitiveness on the demand side: measures to that end focus on product
development programmes intended to meet consumer demand for green and/or
healthier products, and on corporate marketing and public education programmes
designed to meet existing or create new demand for green and/or healthier
products. They also focus on promoting industry standards that require green
and/or healthier products and/or create or enhance beneficial market segmenta-
tion for particular products - e.g., through labelling standards and/or product
quality standards that define niche segments offering price premiums (e.g., sustain-
ably produced timber, organic food). They also focus on creating good will and
increasing the value of brands.
Moreover, and crucial from the viewpoint of public interests and regula-
tion, firms may push for public regulation that supports supply- and demand-side
environmental perfornance strategies. Such regulatory strategies may permit par-
ticular firms to capitalize on proprietary technologies, product qualities,
or advantages in marketing and distribution, for example, by requiring
specific products (e.g., substitutes for pollutants, as in the CFC case). Also,
they may help firms in defining market segments for products, in creating
The first of the following two case studies, which are used to illustrate the
above arguments, adopts a firm-level perspective, focusing on Electrolux.
Electronic waste
Food safety: hazard analysis and critical control point (HA CCP) systems
research by the authors of this article is trying to establish why many firms
are exceeding government set standards, what the effect of these corporate
strategies is on public health, and how these measures are affecting
regulatory processes. Our research thus far has produced four arguments
explaining why firms may engage in over-compliance.
First, in many advanced industrialized countries the industrialization of
food production, longer supply chains, and periodic occurrences of food
safety problems have led to a consumer trust deficit. Food firms have sought
to address this deficit by adopting business strategies that enhance trust-
worthiness and enable firms to allocate blame and costs efficiently should one
of their products turn out to be unsafe or experience declining consumer
acceptance for other reasons. Many firms have addressed trust deficits
through branding, which involves a privatization of consumer trust. How-
ever, branding also involves a privatization of risk, particularly if firms move
from individual brand products to turning the entire firm into a brand. In
other words, branding shields food firms at least to some extent from food
safety problems caused by other firms - in the best case, brand producers
may even increase their market share as food safety problems with
non-brand products grow. On the downside, firms experiencing safety
problems with one of their own brand products cannot externalize the costs
involved to the entire food market. And they cannot free ride on positive
externalities generated by a generally safe food supply in the respective
market. This is why food firms relying on brand products are more interested
in tougher corporate food safety systems than non-brand firms and are more
willing to adopt strict HACCP and other food safety control measures. These
systems allow firms to partition, allocate, control and reduce risks throughout
the value chain. Surveys on the beef, poultry and dairy sectors in the United
States and other countries support the proposition that brand-product food
firms are the leaders in over-compliance.35
Firm size appears to play an important role in this context. Large firms,
particularly those in concentrated markets, have much more influence on
their suppliers than small firms. Thus they can impose quality standards
quicker, more effectively and at lower cost throughout their supply chain.
One indication for this is that HACCP has proven much harder to
implement in the seafood industry, which is less concentrated and more
disaggregated, than for example in the red meat and poultry sector. At the
same time, studies on the US meat and poultry sector show that only small
plants may at times benefit from skimping on food safety efforts. Larger
plants with poor quality controls have a higher probability of exiting the
market.36 Moreover, several studies have shown that marginal HACCP
implementation costs are lower for larger than for smaller firms. A I998
USDA study, for example, suggests that HACCP cost ratios for US
producers were 3:1 in the beef sector and io:i in pork production. At the
Conclusion
NOTES
i. The authors would like to thank Kenneth Oye, James Foster, Niclas Adler and Christos Pitelis for
letting us use some ideas on corporate environmental performance strategies developed in a joint
project. They are also grateful to Claudio Radaelli, Richard Rose, Thomas Plumper, Frank Vibert and
anonymous reviewers for valuable comments.
2. See Tullock I967 on the concept of rent-seeking.
3. E.g. Rehbinder and Stewart I985; Scharpf I996, 1997; Murphy 1995; Vogel 1995; Oye and Maxwell
I996; Kelemen 200O, 200I; Bernauer 2000; Genschel 2000; Hix I999; Esty and Geradin 2ooi.
4. See in particular Olson (I965: 48-65).
5. Most authors argue that public concerns will grow with the extent to which a given risk is perceived
to be involuntary, uncontrollable, or invisible, has a delayed or catastrophic effect, is memorable, very
uncertain, poorly understood, unfamiliar, unfairly distributed, and a technological hazard. Public
concerns over risks with these properties tends to be even stronger in cases where less risky alternatives
exist (see Slovic 1987, 200I; Groth 1994; Wohl I998; Gaskell and Bauer 200i).
6. Friedman (i99i), Putnam (I993), and Friese (2000). For the theoretical background see Hall and
Taylor (X996) and Kitschelt (I986). See also Baron (2002). In Private Politics and Private Policy: A
Theory of Boycotts, he argues that boycotts are the result of private and not collective action, taken by
citizens in their role as customers. Thus, there is no free rider problem present in launching boycotts.
7. An early example of the use of consumer pressure to influence the behaviour of companies is Friends
of the Earth's action against Schweppes in 197I, when it returned thousands of non-returnable bottles
to the soft drinks manufacturer (Rawcliffe I998).
8. Several authors have proposed a further differentiation of this argument by distinguishing between
regulations focusing on the quality of products and regulations focusing on production processes. They
claim that product regulations are easier to instrumentalize for protectionist purposes than process
regulations. Consequendy, product regulations, on average, tend to be more stringent than process
regulations and also vary more across countries. In many empirical cases, e.g. food biotechnology and
growth hormones, a straightforward distinction of product and process regulations is difficult. Thus we
stick to a simpler argument about protectionist benefits (see Murphy I995; Scharpf I996, I998;
Bernauer 2000).
9. See Stigler (197I) and Baron (2000).
Io. See Foster (2002).
ii. The five hormone types most widely used in meat production include three natural hormones,
oestradiol 1743, testosterone, and progesterone, and two synthetic substances, trenbolone and zeranol.
12. FEDESA represented 23 European and eight American pharmaceutical companies.
I3. The theoretical argument in this section builds on joint work with Ken Oye,Jim Foster, Niclas Adler
and Christos Pitelis.
I4. E.g., Porter 1995; Porter/van der Linde I998.
I5. E.g., Jaffe/Palmer 1997;Jaffe 1997.
i6. A larger project in which the authors are involved is also examining the second question. See also
Reinhardt 2000.
17. Examples of rent-producing regulation without apparent environmental and public health benefits
include US oxygenate ethanol and MTBE standards, Australian restrictions on salmon imports,
Japanese rules on fumigant certification of imported vegetables, and US fuel refining standards.
Communication withJim Foster and Ken Oye.
i8. As noted by Foster (personal communication), conceptualizing corporate regulatory strategy in those
terms alone would only make sense if markets had fully degenerated into commodity markets and
factors other than price played no role.
I9. For example, product differentiation strategies are more likely to be successful if the following
conditions are given. Consumers must be willing to pay for environmental superior attributes of
products. 'Greener' goods must provide comparable (to conventional products) consumer benefits at a
comparable price (Hoffman 2000: 86). Firms must be able to communicate their product's environ-
mental benefits in an obvious and credible way. Firms must protect themselves against imitation by
competitors for long enough to obtain a significant return on investments (Reinhardt 2000: 40).
20. Ongoing work by the authors is examining a variety of constraints on the successful pursuit of
corporate environmental performance strategies, for example inflexibility of environmental regulation,
bounded rationality and incomplete information, internal firm characteristics, and market structures.
Note that the industrial ecology and environmental economics literature largely ignores interactive
effects between regulation, business strategy, and environmental and economic outcomes. Instead, it
concentrates on examining the effects of regulation (usually measured in terms of compliance costs) on
innovation (often measured in terms of R&D spending or patents) or the effects of firm size, voluntary
environmental certification, and other factors, on environmental and economic outcomes. See Jaffe
and Palmer I997 and http://www.environmental-performance.org/index.php.
21. See http://www.enviroireland.com/detail.asp?item=157-
22. This case study draws on joint work by Ladina Caduff and Jim Foster.
23. See http://www.snf.se/snf/seminarier/eusem3-dok.htm.
24. See Environmental Health News, March 7, 2002. Almost go per cent of e-waste produced in the
industrialized world is land-filled, incinerated or recovered without any pre-treatment. This results in
a huge loss of valuable resources. It also presents a growing problem in the form of air, soil, and water
pollution, since such waste is one of the largest known sources of heavy metals and organic pollutants
in the waste stream.
25. The WEEE directive also states that manufacturers are responsible for recycling 'historic' waste,
which adds to the advantages of firms that established recycling networks long before EU regulation.
26. According to the EU the cost implications of the WEEE directive will be rather small (I-3 per cent
of retail prices). The EU assumes that this cost increase will be temporary: producers will eventually
improve the efficiency of products with regard to reuse and recovery of components.
27. The Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, which became federal law in I999, makes businesses,
but not households, liable for improperly disposing hazardous waste.
28. In the absence of bilateral agreements, countries that have ratified the 'Ban Amendment of the Basel
Convention on the Control of Transboundary Movement of Hazardous Waste', such as China, would
have to prohibit e-waste trading.
29. As of 2003, California, Massachusetts and Minnesota had the most ambitious legislation. Weaker bills
were pending in New York, NewJersey and North Carolina. Altogether six to ten US states expected
legislative proposals on e-waste in 2003. See Toeffel 2002.
30. See Waste Age, March I, 200i, http://www.wasteage.com/ar/waste us_feels_effects/.
31. See http://www.appliancemagazine.com/article.cfm?articleindexid I2I6.
32. The AEA is supported by the American Plastics Council, the International Cadmium Association, the
Lead Industries Association and the Semiconductor Industry Association.
33. See http://www.chipcenter.com/eexpert/lgoldberg2/dbello2s.html.
34. See http://www.umass.edu/neI6s/; Ollinger and Ballenger 2003.
35. Ollinger and Mueller 2003. See also http://www.umass.edu/neI65/.
36. Ollinger and Ballenger 2003.
37. Communication withJim Foster and Ken Oye. See also Muth et al. 2003; http://www.umass.edu/
nei65/; Ollinger and Mueller 2003. Note that USDA/ERS has been publishing contradictory
assessments on whether HACCP implementation imposes a cost disadvantage on smaller businesses.
38. http://www.umass.edu/neI65/
39. See Jacobsen 2002.
40. See http://www.umass.edu/nei65/haccpi998/haccpig998.html.
REFERENCES
Aerni, P. (2002) 'Stakeholder Attitudes Toward the Risks and Benefits of Agricultural Biotechnology in
Developing Countries: A Comparison Between Mexico and the Philippines'. Risk Anaysis, 22, 6.
Aerni, P. (2003) The Private Management of Public Trust: The Changing Nature of Political Protest. Paper prepared
for ECPR conference in Marburg, Germany, September.
Baron, D. (2000) Business and its Environment. Upper Saddle River NJ: Prentice Hall.
Baron, D. (2002) Private Politics and Private Policy: A neo?y of Boycotts. Research Paper No. I766, Stanford
University.
Becker, G.S. (I983) 'A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence', Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 98, August, 371-400.
Berger, S. and Dore, R. (eds.) (I996) National Diversiy and Global Capitalism, Ithaca NY, Cornell University
Press.
Bernauer, T. and Koubi, V. (2003) Environmental Performance ofDemocracies. Zurich, ETH Zurich, Center for
Comparative and International Studies, manuscript.
Bernauer, T. (2000) Staaten im Weltmarkt. Opladen: Leske+Budrich.
Bernauer, T. (2003) Genes, Trade, and Regulation: The Seeds of Conflict in Food Biotechnologv, Princeton, Princeton
University Press.
Bernstein, M.H. (I955) Regulating Business By Independent Commission, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Berry, J.M. (2ooo) The New Liberalism: The Rising Power of Citizen Groups, Washington DC, Brookings
Institution.
Brand, A. and Ellerton, A. (i989) Report on Hormone Treated Meat, BruxeHes, Club de Bruxeles.
Caduff, L. (2003) ExplainingRegulatogy Diversit_: Environmental and Consumer Protection in the European Union and the
United States. Zurich, ETH Zurich, Center for Comparative and International Studies manuscript.
Cohen, R. (I980) 'Boycott Shows EEC's Consumer Power', The Globe and Mail, October i6.
Chang, H.-J. (1997) 'The Economics and Politics of Regulation', Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2I, 6,
703-28.
Daley, H. (1993) 'The Perils of Free Trade', Scientific American, November.
Donahue, T. (i994) International Labor Standards: The Perspectives of Labor. Paper presented at Symposium on
International Labor Standards and Global Economic Integration, Washington DC.
Drazen, A. (2000) Political Economy in Macroeconomics. Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Derthick, M. and Quirk, PJ. (i985) The Politics of Deregulation, Washington DC, Brookings Institution.
Eichener, V. (i996) 'Die Ruckwirkungen der Europaischen Integration auf nationale Politikmuster' in M.
Jachtenfuchs and B. Kohler-Koch (eds.) Europdische Integration, Opladen, Leske+Budrich, 249-280.
Esty, D.C. and Geradin, D. (eds.) (200i) Regulatory Competition and Economic Integration: Comparative Perspectives,
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
European Court ofJustice (I988) 'The Queen against The Minister of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food
and the Secretary of State for Health'. Ex parte: FEDESA u. a. Rechtssache, C-33I/88.
European Parliament (1995) 'Der illegale Einsatz von Hormonen zu Mastzwecken in Europa', Reihe
Umwelt, Volksgesundheit und Verbraucherschutz, W 12, Strasbourg, European Parliament.
Friedman, M. (I99I) 'Consumer Boycotts: A Conceptual Framework and Research Agenda', Journal of
Social Issues, 47, I49-68.
Gormley, W.T. (I983) The Politics of Public Utiliy Regulation, Pittsburgh, Uni
Gormley, W.T. (I986) 'Regulatory Issue Networks in a Federal System', Polity I8, 595-620.
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (2001) Special Interest Politics, Cambridge MA, MIT Press.
Groth, E. (I994) 'Consumer Perceptions of and Responses to Potentially Hazardous Technologies',
ICGFI, Document No. I8, Vienna, ICGFI: 4123-24.
Hall, P.A. and Taylor, R.C. (I996) 'Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms', Political Studies,
XLIV, 936-57.
Hix, S. (I999) The Political System of the European Union, Basingstoke, Macmillan Press.
Hoffman, AJ. (2000) Competitive Environmental Strategy: A Guide to the Changing Business Landscape. Washington
DC, Island Press.
Hood, C., Rothstein, H. and Baldwin, R. (200I) The Government of Risk: Understanding Risk Regulation Regimes,
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Jacobsen, E. (2002) The Rhetoric's on Food: Food aslNature, Commodity and Culture. Paper prepared for Workshop
in the ESA Network on the Sociology of Consumption, University of Bergen, Norway, 28-3I August.
Jaffe, A. et al. (I995) 'Environmental Regulation and the Competitiveness of US Manufacturing: What
Does the Evidence Tell Us?', Journal of Economic Literature 33.
Jaffe, A. and Palmer, K. (1997) 'Environmental Regulation and Innovation: Panel Data Study', Review of
Economics and Statistics, 79, 4, 6Io-6i9.
Kelemen, R.D. (2000) 'Regulatory Federalism: EU Environmental Regulation in Comparative Perspec-
tive', Journal of Public Poligy, 20, 2, 133-67.
Kelemen, R.D. (2001) 'The Limits of Judicial Power: Trade-Environmental Disputes in the GATT/
WTO and the EU', Comparative Political Studies, 34, 6, 622-50.
Kitschelt, H.P. (I986) 'Political Opportunity Structures and Political Protest: Anti-Nuclear Movements in
Four Democracies', British journal of Political Science, 16, i, 57-85.
Levinson, A. (I996) 'Environmental Regulations and Industry Location: International and Domestic
Evidence', in J. Bhagwati and R.E. Hudec (eds.) Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisitesfor Free Trade?,
Cambridge MA, MIT Press.
Majone, G. (I996) Regulating Europe, London, Routledge.
Meier, Kj. (I989) The Political Economy of Regulation: 7he Case of Insurance Regulation, Albany NY, University
of New York Press.
Meins, E. (2003) Politics and Public Outrage: Explaining Transatlantic and Intra-European Diversity of Regulations on
Food Irradiation and Genetically Modiied Food, Hamburg, Lit Verlag.
Moe, T.M. (I980) The Organization of Interests, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Murphy, D. D. (I995) Open Economics and Regulations: Convergence and Competition amongjurisdictions, Cambridge
MA, MIT, Department of Political Science, dissertation.
Muth, M.K., Wohlgenant, M.K., Karns, S.A. and Anderson, D.W. (2003) 'Explaining Plant Exit in the
U.S. Meat and Poultry Industries', journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization, I, I.
Ollinger, M. and Ballenger, N. (2003) Weighing Incentivesfor Food Safely in Meat and Poultgy, USDA, April.
Ollinger, M. and Mueller, V. (2003) Managingfor Safer Food: The Economics of Sanitation and Process Controls in
Meat and Poulty Plants, USDA/ERS, Agricultural Economic Report 817.
Olson, M. (I965) 7The Logic of Collective Action, Cambridge MA, Harvard University Press.
Oye, K. and Maxwell,J. (I995) 'Self-Interest and Environmental Management', in R. Keohane and E.
Ostrom (eds.) Local Commons and Global Interdependence, London, Sage, I9I-222.
Peltzman, S. (I976) 'Towards a More General Theory of Regulation', journal of Law and Economics, August,
21 -40.
Porter, M. (I998) On Competition, Boston MA, Harvard Business School Publishing.
Porter, M.E. and van der Linde, C. (1995) 'Green and Competitive: Ending the Stalemate', Haoard
Business Review, Sept/Oct, 120-34.
Posner, R. (I974) 'Theories of Economic Regulation', Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5, 337-52.
Putnam, T. (I993) 'Boycotts are Busting Out all Over'. Business and Society, Review, 85, 47-51.
Radcliffe, P. (I998). Environmental Pressure Groups in Transition. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Vogel, D. (I995) Trading Up: Consumer and Environmental Regulation in a Global Economy, Cambridge MA,
Harvard University Press.
Vogel, D. and Kagan, R. (2002) Dynamics of Regulatogy Change: How Globalization Affects National Regulatory
Policies. Berkeley, University of California, UCIAS.
Vogel, S.K. (I996) Freer Markets, More Rules: Regulatory Reform in Advanced Industrial Countries, Ithaca, Cornell
University Press.
Wheeler, D. (2000) Racing to the Bottom? Foreign Investment and Air Qualip in Developing Countries, Washington
DC, World Bank, Development Research Group.
Wilson, J.Q. (ed.) (I980) 7he Politics of Regulation, New York, Basic Books.
Wohl,J.B. (I998) 'Consumers' Decision-Making and Risk Perceptions Regarding Foods Produced with
Biotechnology', Journal of Consumer Policy, 21, 387-404.
WTO (World Trade Organization) (I999) Trade and Environment: Special Studies, WTO.
Zeit, die (various issues).