306 Ibe Notes
306 Ibe Notes
306 Ibe Notes
Introduction
International trade theories are simply different theories to explain international trade. Trade is the
concept of exchanging goods and services between two people or entities. International trade is
then the concept of this exchange between people or entities in two different countries.
People or entities trade because they believe that they benefit from the exchange. They may need
or want the goods or services. While at the surface, this many sound very simple, there is a great
deal of theory, policy, and business strategy that constitutes international trade.
Different theories for international trade have been given by the economist to understand that why
international trade takes place
Comparative advantage is when a country produces a good or service for a lower opportunity cost
than other countries. Opportunity cost measures a trade-off. A nation with a comparative
advantage makes the trade-off worth it. The benefits of buying its good or service outweigh the
disadvantages. The country may not be the best at producing something. But the good or service
has a low opportunity cost for other countries to import.
For example, oil-producing nations have a comparative advantage in chemicals. Their locally-
produced oil provides a cheap source of material for the chemicals when compared to countries
without it. A lot of the raw ingredients are produced in the oil distillery process. As a result, Saudi
Arabia, Kuwait, and Mexico are competitive with U.S. chemical production firms. Their chemicals
are inexpensive, making their opportunity cost low.
Another example is India's call centres. U.S. companies buy this service because it is cheaper than
locating the call centre in America. Indian call centres aren't better than U.S. call centres. Their
workers don't always speak English very clearly. But they provide the service cheaply enough to
make the trade-off worth it.
For example, England was able to manufacture cheap cloth. Portugal had the right conditions to
make cheap wine. Ricardo predicted that England would stop making wine and Portugal stop
making cloth. He was right. England made more money by trading its cloth for Portugal's wine,
and vice versa. It would have cost England a lot to make all the wine it needed because it lacked
the climate. Portugal didn't have the manufacturing ability to make cheap cloth. So, they both
benefited by trading what they produced the most efficiently.
Textiles Books
UK 1 4
India 2 3
Total
3 7
Textiles Books
UK 0 8
India 4 0
TOTAL
4 8
Therefore, the total output of both goods has increased – illustrating the potential gains
from exploiting comparative advantage.
By trading the surplus books and textiles, India and UK can enjoy higher quantities of the
goods.
The following are the assumptions of the Ricardian doctrine of comparative advantage:
11. Factors of production are perfectly mobile within each country. However, they are
immobile between the two countries.
12. Free trade is undertaken between the two countries. Trade barriers and restrictions in the
movement of commodities are absent.
13. Transport costs are not incurred in carrying trade between the two countries.
14. Factors of production are fully employed in both the countries.
15. The exchange ratio for the two commodities is the same
Criticisms of Comparative advantage
Cost of trade. To export goods to India imposes transport costs.
External costs of trade. Exporting goods leads to increased pollution from ‘air-freight’ and can
contribute to environmental costs not included in models which only include private costs and
benefits.
Diminishing returns/diseconomies of scale. Specialisation means a country will increase the
output of one particular good. However, for some industries increasing output may lead to
diminishing returns. For example, if Portugal has a comparative advantage in wine, it may run
out of suitable land for growing grapes. A contemporary example is Mongolia. Mongolia was
believed to have a comparative advantage in cattle farming. However, according to Erik
Reinert opening of markets to international competition in 1991 led to an increased size of
animal herds, but this led to over-grazing and loss of grazing land.
Static comparative advantage. A developing economy, in sub-Saharan-Africa, may have a
comparative advantage in producing primary products (metals, agriculture), but these products
have a low-income elasticity of demand, and it can hold back an economy from diversifying
into more profitable industries, such as manufacturing.
Dutch disease. Dutch disease is a phenomenon where countries specialise in producing
primary products (oil/natural gas) but doing this can harm the long-term performance of the
economy. In the 1970s, the Netherlands specialised in producing natural gas, but this led to the
neglect of manufacturing and when the gas industry declined, the economy was left behind its
near neighbours.
Trade – not a Pareto improvement. Trade can lead to an increase in net economic welfare.
However, it doesn’t mean that everyone will become better off. Some workers in
uncompetitive industries may lose out and struggle to gain employment in new industries.
Gravity theory. Proposed by Jan Tinbergen, in 1962, this states that international trade is
influenced by two factors – the relative size of economies and economic distance. The model
suggests that countries of similar size will be attracted to trade with each other. Economic
distance depends on geographical distance and trade barriers. The implication is that countries
economically close and of similar size will engage in similar levels of bilateral trade. It also
suggests trade is more likely between countries which are geographically close.
Complexity of global trade. Models of comparative advantage usually focus on two countries
and two goods, but in the real world, there are multiple goods and countries. Increasingly there
is growing demand for a variety of goods and choice – rather than competing on simple price.
1. It is assumed that there are only two nations (1 and 2) with two goods for trade (X and Y)
and two factors of production (capital and labour).
2. For producing the goods, both nations use the same technology and they use uniform
factors of production.
4. The tastes and preferences of both nations are the same (both countries can be represented
in the same indifference curve).
5. In both nations, the assumption of constant returns to scale is applicable for the production
of goods X and Y.
8. There exists perfect mobility of factors of production within each country though
international mobility is not possible.
9. There are no restrictions or limitations to the free flow of international trade. That is, there
exist no transportation costs, tariffs, or like other obstructions either to control or to restrict
the exports or imports.
10. It is assumed that there exists full employment of all resources in both nations. That is,
there will not be any under employed resource in either nation.
11. The exports and imports between the nations are balanced. It means that the total value of
the exports will be equal to the total value of imports in both nations.
Heckscher-Ohlin model is generally described as two countries, two goods and two factors model
(2x2x2 model). This formulation of HO model was mathematically developed by Paul Samuelson.
The goal of the model is to predict the pattern of international trade in commodities between the
two countries on the basis of differences in factor endowments in both the countries.
Definition: A nation exports the commodities which are produced out of its relatively abundant
and cheap factors or resources and imports the commodity which is produced out of relatively
scarce factors or resources. In another words, relatively labour abundant country exports relatively
labour-intensive commodity and imports the relatively capital-intensive commodity. Country 1
exports commodity X because X is the Labor (L) intensive commodity and L is relatively cheap
and abundant factor in country 1. Country 2 exports commodity Y because Y is the Capital (K)
intensive commodity and K is relatively cheap and abundant factor in country 2.
The theory implicates two things: first, different supply conditions in terms of resource
endowments explain comparative advantage and second, countries export goods that use abundant
and cheap factors of production and import goods that use scarce and expensive factors.
According to Heckscher-Ohlin theory, international and interregional differences in production
costs occur due to the differences in the supply of factors of production. Under free trade, countries
export the commodities whose production requires intensive use of abundant factors and import
the commodities whose production requires the scarce factors. Hence, international trade
compensates for the uneven geographic distribution of factors of production. The theory gives
insight to the fact that commodities are the bundles of factors (land, labour and capital). Thus, the
exchange of commodities is indirect arbitrage of factors of production and the transfer of services
of otherwise immobile factors from regions where factors are abundant to regions where they are
scarce.
The H-O theorem identifies the basic reason for comparative advantage and international trade as
the different factor abundance or factor endowments among nations. Because of this particular
reason, the theory is known as factor proportions or factor endowment theory. The theory
postulates that the difference in relative factor endowment and prices is the main reason for the
difference in relative commodity prices between two countries.
Factor Endowments
Factor endowment can be defined as the ratio of capital to labour (K/L). If the capital – labour ratio
in country 1 is greater than in country 2, then country 1 is said to be relatively capital-abundant
(and labour-scarce) while country 2 is labour abundant (and capital scarce). Symbolically, this can
be represented as:
For two countries with same demand patterns, relative factor prices lead to relative factor
scarcities. Country 2 will have relatively inexpensive labour and country 1 is in a position to
provide relatively inexpensive (abundant) capital.
Criticism
1. Poor prediction and performance.
2. The unfair assumption that all labour is employed. This model assumes that all labor in the
country is employed thus ignoring the concept of unemployment.
3. The unrealistic assumption that identical production exits. This model assumes that nations
have the same technology being used for production undermining the effects and ignoring
the technological gaps.
4. Logical Flaws – Capital is assumed as being homogeneous and transferrable between
countries.
This post is an attempt to communicate the core of Krugman’s theory, for the layman. I will rely
mainly on three of Krugman’s original articles on the subject: Krugman (1979), Krugman (1980),
and Krugman (1981). There is also Krugman (1985), but the three earlier papers are shorter and go
straight to the point, so I recommend interested readers to read those.1 I am also using my favorite
textbook, Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz, International Economics.
Prior to the 1980s, most trade theorists thought about international trade within the Ricardian
framework of comparative advantage. The theory states that, assuming heterogeneous agents and
opportunity costs, a person can specialize in producing the good of lowest opportunity cost to them
and trade for other products (produced by other people) and be better off than if there were no
trade at all, and each person manufactured everything they want on their own. If someone else can
make you t-shirts at a lesser opportunity cost than you, you can buy the t-shirt at that cost, and use
your own time towards something more productive. You specialize in products others’ demand,
which you can sell to them at at least the cost of production — and your relative costs are the
lowest, so that is where your competitive advantage is.2
Ricardian trade theory continued to be developed throughout the 19th and 20th centuries, and one
of the directions later economists took Ricardian trade theory in is worth mentioning. In the early
20th century, trade theorists began working towards what is now known as the Heckscher–Ohlin
theory. Ohlin would go on to win the Nobel Memorial Prize, in 1977. The main insight the model
gives is that countries will tend to specialize in goods that are relatively intensive in the inputs
(factors of production) that country is relatively abundant in. Thus, the model looks at differences
in factor endowments as a cause of international trade. If the U.S. is relatively abundant in capital
and Mexico is relatively abundant in labor, it means that the ratio of labor to capital is lower in the
U.S. than it is in Mexico. If labor is cheaper in Mexico, Mexican industry is likely to use a greater
labor to capital ratio in their production than U.S. industry. Mexico will also tend to produce more
of their labor-intensive goods, because labor is relatively inexpensive (to capital). The U.S. will
export capital-intensive goods to Mexico, and Mexico labor-intensive goods to the U.S.
Against the predictions of the Heckscher–Ohlin theory, Wassily Leontief, in a 1953 article,
published data showing that U.S. exports are less capital-intensive than its imports.
Other evidence shows that the degree to which countries specialize is exaggerated in the models,
and that intra-trade industry makes up a significant chunk of international exchange that is not
accounted for by standard, Ricardian, trade theory.
After the Second World War, and before the 1990s, it was found that growth in international trade
was not leading to the distributional changes that Ricardian theory predicts. In fact, trade was
found to be, in large part, neutral to income distribution.
Economists had been toying around with the relationship between economies of scale and trade,
but it wasn’t until Krugman that we had a simple formal model. Krugman also took the original
insights and developed them further. He did all this by focusing on internal returns to scale, and by
adopting a recent modelling innovation in Dixit and Stiglitz (1977), making it easier to model
monopolistic competition.
Assuming a situation where are all agents have identical comparative costs, technologies, and
tastes, and there is only one factor, there are none of the standard reasons for trade. But, we assume
that there are internal economies of scale. Internal economies of scale occur as long as the average
cost per unit of output falls as total output increases. The easiest reasons to cite for internal
economies are high fixed costs, where more output allows the firm to spread this fixed cost. If
there are internal economies of scale, markets are not perfectly competitive. Instead, there will be
less firms, and each firm will produce more. Each firm will also have an incentive to differentiate
their product from those of their competitors — if they are close/imperfect substitutes —, to
compete for profits. The total number of firms can be said to be determined by average cost and
price. As long as price is higher than average cost, it might pay for new firms to enter the market to
compete; but, when price equals average cost, profits won’t be high enough for new firms to
recover their fixed cost investment.
The size of an economy matters for its well-being. All else equal, larger economies — economies
with more people — are wealthier. This is because larger economies will have higher demand, will
have more inputs, and therefore more output. More output allows firms to exploit greater internal
economies of scale, which in turn lowers average cost. Prices fall, real wages increase, the number
of firms will increase, and therefore product diversity will increase (the italicized consequences are
welfare-enhancing).
International trade creates similar benefits as population growth. If trade between, say, the U.S.
and China suddenly emerged, the market each firm face would grow. There will be fewer total
firms (if the two countries were isolated, the sum of their firms would be greater than the total
number of firms in an integrated market), and each surviving firm would produce more, but all
consumers in both countries would be able to buy from a greater range of firms. That is, the
diversity of the products offer would increase. The price per unit would also fall, because of the
exploitation of further internal economies of scale. Thus, even if none of the standard reasons for
trade (comparative advantage) existed, trade would still occur, to exploit the benefits of internal
economies of scale.
One implication is that if there are barriers to trade, factors of production will tend to move to
countries where there are economies of scale in industries relatively intensive in a given factor
(input). For example, if we assume that the only factor is labor, barriers to trade would induce
foreign labor to move to the country with the largest market. Remember, larger markets mean
more product diversity and higher real wages, both of which are incentives to immigrants. As
immigrants arrive, the market grows further, and real wages and product diversity will increase.
Sending states, in turn, become poorer, as product diversity and real wages fall.
Countries will, all else equal, export the goods where domestic demand is highest. It will behove
firms to localize production in markets where demand for that type of product is highest. This is
because these firms will be able to exploit greater internal economies of scale than anywhere else.
Thus, under conditions of internal economies, countries will tend to export the good they produce
more of. In a world of no transaction costs, differences in local demand for a product will induce
the country with the greatest internal economies to specialize in that product. In a world of
transaction costs — where there are added costs to trade —, specialization will be more limited,
because these costs reduce the profitability of exporting. Also, the extent of internal economies
will also decide the extent of specialization; the less the opportunities for internal economies, the
less a country will specialize in a type of good. Thus, with costs to trade and limits to economies of
scale, what we expect is intra-industry trade, as each country produces multiple types of good and
trade these between each other, even goods of the same type. But, generally speaking, the country
with the larger home market for a given good will be a net exporter of that good, because of
economies of scale (and out of interest in minimizing transaction costs).
Finally, the type of trade between two nations has much to do with differences in factor
endowments (the type of inputs which are relatively abundant). If two countries are similarly
endowed, then trade will tend to be of the intra-industry type. As factor endowments become more
unique, the type of trade predicted by the Heckscher–Ohlin model will prevail. The implications
for changes in the distribution of income as a result of trade is that if endowments are the same,
trade is Pareto optimal. If factor endowments differ, how much they differ will decide relative
gains from trade and changes in income distribution. Namely, the more unique a country’s factor
endowment, the more the relatively scarce factor will lose from trade and the relatively abundant
factor will gain. The scarce factor loses, because with international trade, the price of that product
in that country falls (as it faces competition from foreign producers, who have lower costs, because
they are in countries that have a relative abundance in that factor). Whether trade is Pareto optimal
depends on whether the welfare increase from product differentiation is large enough to make up
for the relative loss of income for the scarce factor.
The internal economies of scale argument Krugman formalized allows economists to explain
aspects of international trade that were previously not explainable by Ricardian comparative
advantage. If there are internal economies of scale — firms are monopolistically competitive —,
markets will be supplied by a certain quantity of firms (less than the number in perfectly
competitive markets), each producing a greater amount of output than its perfectly competitive
analogue. In these cases, even if there are no differences in relative costs, tastes, or technology,
there will be gains from trade in the form of lower prices and greater product diversity. Whereas
standard Ricardian theory applies when there are differences between agents, economies of scale
explain trade when agents are similar. It is an alternative approach to the theories of the division of
labor and trade.
All economists borrow from their predecessors and their peers, so Krugman’s theory is by no
means entirely original to him. In fact, he cites a number of trade theorists who dabbled with
economies of scale prior to him: Herbert Grubel, Bertil Ohlin, Irving Kravis, Bela Balassa, et
cetera. But, Krugman was able to formalize the theory in a relatively simple model (more simple
than alternative approaches to trade with economies of scale). This allowed him to explore the
implications of internal economies in greater detail, and with much more precision. This allowed
him to persuade the majority of his peers, whereas previously Ricardian theory had continued to
dominate alternatives. This is what rightfully earned Krugman his Nobel Memorial Prize.
Unit -2
Unilateral Trade Practices
A unilateral trade agreement is a commerce treaty that a nation imposes without regard to others. It
benefits that one country only. It is unilateral because other nations have no choice in the matter. It
is not open to negotiation. The World Trade Organization defines a unilateral trade preference
similarly.1 It occurs when one nation adopts a trade policy that isn't reciprocated. For example, it
happens when a country imposes a trade restriction, such as a tariff, on all imports.
It also applies to a state that lifts a tariff on its partner's imports even that's not reciprocated. A
large country might do that to help out a small one.
A unilateral agreement is one type of free trade agreement. Another type is a bilateral
agreement between two countries. It is the most common because it's easy to negotiate. The third
type is a multilateral agreement. It's the most powerful but takes a long time to negotiate.
Some conservatives define unilateral trade policies as the absence of any trade agreement
whatsoever.2 In that definition, the United States would lift all tariffs, regulations, and other
restrictions on trade. It's unilateral because it doesn't require other nations to do the same. The
argument is that the government should not restrict the rights of its citizens to trade anywhere in
the world.
In that scenario, other countries would keep their tariffs on U.S. exports. That would give them a
unilateral advantage. They could ship cheap goods into the United States, but U.S. exports would
be priced higher in their countries.
Emerging market nations are afraid of any trade agreements with developed nations. They worry
that the imbalance of power would create a unilateral benefit to the developed nation.
Salient features:
Unilateral agreements are one-sided trade arrangements that benefit only one country.
Unilateral agreements are often options or offers giving a poorer nation more trade
benefits.
U.S. GSP offers duty-free status to 43 least developed countries. This allows the United
States to access low cost imports while furthering American foreign policies.
Unilateral trade policies such as tariffs work great in the short term. Tariffs raise the price
of imports. As a result, the prices of locally made products seem lower in comparison. This boosts
economic growth and creates jobs.
Over time, these advantages disappear. That's when other countries retaliate and add their own
tariffs. Now the domestic companies' exports drop. As businesses suffer, they lay off recently hired
workers. Global trade drops and everyone suffers.
This occurred during the Great Depression. Countries protected domestic jobs by raising import
prices through tariffs. This trade protectionism soon lowered global trade overall as country after
country followed suit. As a result, global trade plummeted 65%. Discover other effects of the
Great Depression.
After World War II, the United States started negotiating lower tariffs with 15 countries. They
were Australia, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, China, Cuba, Czechoslovakia, France, India,
Luxembourg, the Netherlands, New Zealand, South Africa, and the United Kingdom.
On January 1, 1948, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade went into effect with 23
countries. These were the original 15, plus Myanmar, Sri Lanka, Chile, Lebanon, Norway,
Pakistan, South Rhodesia, and Syria. This lifted all unilateral trade restrictions and the global
economy recovered.
Example:
The United States has unilateral trade policies under the Generalized System of
Preferences.3 That's where developed countries grant preferential tariffs to imports from
developing countries. It was instituted on January 1, 1976, by the Trade Act of 1974.
The U.S. GSP offers duty-free status for 5,000 imports from 120 countries.4 That includes 43 of
the Least Developed Beneficiary Developing Countries.5 These include Afghanistan, Bangladesh,
Bhutan, Cambodia, Nepal, and Yemen. It also includes 38 African countries that are under
the African Growth and Opportunity Act.
In 2015, total duty-free imports under the GSP was $18.7 billion.
The GSP has three goals. The first is to lower the prices of imports for Americans. That's one
reason why inflation has subsided. The success of Wal-Mart and other low-cost retailers depends
on tariff-free production in these countries.
The second goal is to help the countries become a more affluent market for U.S. exports. Since the
countries are small, the volume of these goods doesn't offer significant competition to U.S.
companies. But they do provide more customers.
The third goal is to further U.S. foreign policy goals. Countries must abide by U.S. worker rights
and intellectual property rights. That helps protect American companies' software, patents, and
proprietary manufacturing processes. Worker rights raise the standards of living in those countries.
That makes them less competitive against U.S. workers and protects American jobs.
The World Trade Organization (WTO) is the only global international organization dealing with
the rules of trade between nations. At its heart are the WTO agreements, negotiated and signed by
the bulk of the world’s trading nations and ratified in their parliaments. The goal is to ensure that
trade flows as smoothly, predictably and freely as possible.
The Uruguay round of GATT (1986-93) gave birth to World Trade Organization. The members of
GATT singed on an agreement of Uruguay round in April 1994 in Morocco for establishing a new
organization named WTO.
It was officially constituted on January 1, 1995 which took the place of GATT as an effective
formal, organization. GATT was an informal organization which regulated world trade since 1948.
Contrary to the temporary nature of GATT, WTO is a permanent organization which has been
established on the basis of an international treaty approved by participating countries. It achieved
the international status like IMF and IBRD, but it is not an agency of the United Nations
Organization (UNO).
Structure:
The WTO has nearly 153 members accounting for over 97% of world trade. Around 30 others are
negotiating membership. Decisions are made by the entire membership. This is typically by
consensus.
A majority vote is also possible but it has never been used in the WTO and was extremely rare
under the WTO’s predecessor, GATT. The WTO’s agreements have been ratified in all members’
parliaments.
The WTO’s top level decision-making body is the Ministerial Conferences which meets at least
once in every two years. Below this is the General Council (normally ambassadors and heads of
delegation in Geneva, but sometimes officials sent from members’ capitals) which meets several
times a year in the Geneva headquarters. The General Council also meets as the Trade Policy
Review Body and the Disputes Settlement Body.
At the next level, the Goods Council, Services Council and Intellectual Property (TRIPs) Council
report to the General Council. Numerous specialized committees, working groups and working
parties deal with the individual agreements and other areas such as, the environment, development,
membership applications and regional trade agreements.
Secretariat:
The WTO secretariat, based in Geneva, has around 600 staff and is headed by a Director-General.
Its annual budget is roughly 160 million Swiss Francs. It does not have branch offices outside
Geneva. Since decisions are taken by the members themselves, the secretariat does not have the
decision making the role that other international bureaucracies are given.
The secretariat s main duties to supply technical support for the various councils and committees
and the ministerial conferences, to provide technical assistance for developing countries, to analyse
world trade and to explain WTO affairs to the public and media. The secretariat also provides
some forms of legal assistance in the dispute settlement process and advises governments wishing
to become members of the WTO.
Objectives:
The important objectives of WTO are:
1. To improve the standard of living of people in the member countries.
Functions:
The main functions of WTO are discussed below:
1. To implement rules and provisions related to trade policy review mechanism.
2. To provide a platform to member countries to decide future strategies related to trade and tariff.
6. To assist international organizations such as, IMF and IBRD for establishing coherence in
Universal Economic Policy determination.
Anti-dumping duty
In the U.S., the International Trade Commission (ITC)–an independent government agency–is
tasked with imposing anti-dumping duties. Their actions are based on the investigations and
recommendations they receive from the U.S. Department of Commerce.
In many cases, the duties imposed on these goods exceeds the value of the goods. Anti-dumping
duties are typically levied when a foreign company is selling an item significantly below the price
at which it is being produced.
While the intention of anti-dumping duties is to save domestic jobs, these tariffs can also lead to
higher prices for domestic consumers. And, in the long-term, anti-dumping duties can reduce the
international competition of domestic companies producing similar goods.
The World Trade Organization (WTO) is an international organization that deals with the rules
of trade between nations. The WTO also operates a set of international trade rules, including the
international regulation of anti-dumping measures. The WTO does not intervene in the activities of
companies engaged in dumping. Instead, it focuses on how governments can—or cannot—react to
the practice of dumping. In general, the WTO agreement permits governments to "act against
dumping where there is a genuine (or material) injury to the competing domestic industry."
This intervention must be justified in order to uphold the WTO's commitment to free-market
principles. Anti-dumping duties have the potential to distort the market. In a free market,
governments cannot normally determine what constitutes a fair market price for any good or
service.
After conducting a review, one year later the U.S. announced that it would be imposing a 500%
import duty on certain steel imported from China. In 2018, China filed a complaint with the WTO
challenging the tariffs imposed by the Trump administration. Since then, the Trump administration
has continued to use the WTO to challenge what it claims are unfair trading practices by the
Chinese government and other trading partners.
nowadays, among WTO members, agricultural products are protected only by tariffs.1 All non-
tariff barriers had to be eliminated or converted to tariffs as a result of the Uruguay Round (the
conversion was known as “tariffication”). In some cases, the calculated equivalent tariffs — like
the original measures that were tariffed — were too high to allow any real opportunity for imports.
So a system of tariff-rate quotas was created to maintain existing import access levels, and to
provide minimum access opportunities. This means lower tariffs within the quotas, and higher
rates for quantities outside the quotas.
Customs duties on merchandise imports are called tariffs. Tariffs give a price advantage to locally-
produced goods over similar goods which are imported, and they raise revenues for governments.
One result of the Uruguay Round was countries’ commitments to cut tariffs and to “bind” their
customs duty rates to levels which are difficult to raise. The current negotiations under the Doha
Agenda continue efforts in that direction in agriculture and non-agricultural market access.
The WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures disciplines the use of subsidies,
and it regulates the actions countries can take to counter the effects of subsidies. Under the
agreement, a country can use the WTO’s dispute-settlement procedure to seek the withdrawal of
the subsidy or the removal of its adverse effects. Or the country can launch its own investigation
and ultimately charge extra duty (“countervailing duty”) on subsidized imports that are found to be
hurting domestic producers.
his agreement does two things: it disciplines the use of subsidies, and it regulates the actions
countries can take to counter the effects of subsidies. It says a country can use the WTO’s dispute
settlement procedure to seek the withdrawal of the subsidy or the removal of its adverse effects. Or
the country can launch its own investigation and ultimately charge extra duty (known as
“countervailing duty”) on subsidized imports that are found to be hurting domestic producers.
The agreement contains a definition of subsidy. It also introduces the concept of a “specific”
subsidy — i.e. a subsidy available only to an enterprise, industry, group of enterprises, or group of
industries in the country (or state, etc) that gives the subsidy. The disciplines set out in the
agreement only apply to specific subsidies. They can be domestic or export subsidies.
The agreement defines two categories of subsidies: prohibited and actionable. It originally
contained a third category: non-actionable subsidies. This category existed for five years, ending
on 31 December 1999, and was not extended. The agreement applies to agricultural goods as well
as industrial products, except when the subsidies are exempt under the Agriculture Agreement’s
“peace clause”, due to expire at the end of 2003.
Prohibited subsidies: subsidies that require recipients to meet certain export targets, or to use
domestic goods instead of imported goods. They are prohibited because they are specifically
designed to distort international trade, and are therefore likely to hurt other countries’ trade. They
can be challenged in the WTO dispute settlement procedure where they are handled under an
accelerated timetable. If the dispute settlement procedure confirms that the subsidy is prohibited, it
must be withdrawn immediately. Otherwise, the complaining country can take counter measures. If
domestic producers are hurt by imports of subsidized products, countervailing duty can be
imposed.
Actionable subsidies: in this category the complaining country has to show that the subsidy has
an adverse effect on its interests. Otherwise the subsidy is permitted. The agreement defines three
types of damage they can cause. One country’s subsidies can hurt a domestic industry in an
importing country. They can hurt rival exporters from another country when the two compete in
third markets. And domestic subsidies in one country can hurt exporters trying to compete in the
subsidizing country’s domestic market. If the Dispute Settlement Body rules that the subsidy does
have an adverse effect, the subsidy must be withdrawn or its adverse effect must be removed.
Again, if domestic producers are hurt by imports of subsidized products, countervailing duty can
be imposed.
Some of the disciplines are similar to those of the Anti-Dumping Agreement. Countervailing duty
(the parallel of anti-dumping duty) can only be charged after the importing country has conducted
a detailed investigation similar to that required for anti-dumping action. There are detailed rules for
deciding whether a product is being subsidized (not always an easy calculation), criteria for
determining whether imports of subsidized products are hurting (“causing injury to”) domestic
industry, procedures for initiating and conducting investigations, and rules on the implementation
and duration (normally five years) of countervailing measures. The subsidized exporter can also
agree to raise its export prices as an alternative to its exports being charged countervailing duty.
Subsidies may play an important role in developing countries and in the transformation of
centrally-planned economies to market economies. Least-developed countries and developing
countries with less than $1,000 per capita GNP are exempted from disciplines on prohibited export
subsidies. Other developing countries are given until 2003 to get rid of their export subsidies.
Least-developed countries must eliminate import-substitution subsidies (i.e. subsidies designed to
help domestic production and avoid importing) by 2003 — for other developing countries the
deadline was 2000. Developing countries also receive preferential treatment if their exports are
subject to countervailing duty investigations. For transition economies, prohibited subsidies had to
be phased out by 2002.
necessary to prevent or remedy serious injury and to help the industry concerned to adjust. Where
quantitative restrictions (quotas) are imposed, they normally should not reduce the quantities of
imports below the annual average for the last three representative years for which statistics are
available, unless clear justification is given that a different level is necessary to prevent or remedy
serious injury.
In principle, safeguard measures cannot be targeted at imports from a particular country. However,
the agreement does describe how quotas can be allocated among supplying countries, including in
the exceptional circumstance where imports from certain countries have increased
disproportionately quickly. A safeguard measure should not last more than four years, although
this can be extended up to eight years, subject to a determination by competent national authorities
that the measure is needed and that there is evidence the industry is adjusting. Measures imposed
for more than a year must be progressively liberalized.
When a country restricts imports in order to safeguard its domestic producers, in principle it must
give something in return. The agreement says the exporting country (or exporting countries) can
seek compensation through consultations. If no agreement is reached the exporting country can
retaliate by taking equivalent action — for instance, it can raise tariffs on exports from the country
that is enforcing the safeguard measure. In some circumstances, the exporting country has to wait
for three years after the safeguard measure was introduced before it can retaliate in this way — i.e.
if the measure conforms with the provisions of the agreement and if it is taken as a result of an
increase in the quantity of imports from the exporting country.
To some extent developing countries’ exports are shielded from safeguard actions. An importing
country can only apply a safeguard measure to a product from a developing country if the
developing country is supplying more than 3% of the imports of that product, or if developing
country members with less than 3% import share collectively account for more than 9% of total
imports of the product concerned.
The WTO’s Safeguards Committee oversees the operation of the agreement and is responsible for
the surveillance of members’ commitments. Governments have to report each phase of a safeguard
investigation and related decision-making, and the committee reviews these reports.
Export taxes, Export subsidies, Economic Integration
One proposal involves a 50% reduction in export subsidies as an immediate down payment,
followed by eliminating subsidies completely in three years (for developed countries) or six years
(for developing countries).
The proposal from five developing countries is similar but with more emphasis on flexibilities for
developing countries. It includes expanding the types of export subsidies that developing countries
are currently allowed under Article 9.4 of the Agriculture Agreement. This group’s proposed
formula would continue reductions at the same pace as under the present agreement while
negotiations continue, followed by complete elimination within three years of the negotiations’ end
or 2006, whichever is earlier — with a longer deadline for developing countries.
These proposals received some support, and some opposition, particularly over the complete
elimination of export subsidies.
Most participants agree that some disciplines are needed to ensure supplies are available for
importing countries. Among the issues that have been raised:
Symmetry between imports and exports: Some countries argue that the disciplines in this subject
should be seen as part of balancing measures on the imports with those on exports. Others
disagree.
Supporting domestic processing: Several developing countries say taxes or restrictions on raw
materials exports are sometimes needed in order to promote domestic processing industries,
particularly when importing developed countries charge higher tariffs on processed products than
on raw materials (“tariff escalation”). Some countries argue that getting rid of tariff escalation is a
better solution.
Prohibited products and national security: Some countries say some restrictions are needed to
prevent exports of hazardous and other prohibited products, and for national security reasons.
Others disagree.
Single market
You can be in the EU's Single Market, but not the EU, this is what Norway, Iceland and
Liechtenstein do.
The European Union's single market is perhaps the most ambitious type of trade co-operation.
That's because as well as eliminating tariffs, quotas or taxes on trade, it also includes the free
movement of goods, services, capital and people.
That is why there has been no limit on the number of French people who can come to the UK, or
the number of British people who can live in Spain - but there are limits on Turks or Ukrainians,
for example.
Also, a single market strives to remove so-called "non-tariff barriers" - different rules on
packaging, safety and standards and many others are abolished and the same rules and regulations
apply across the area.
For goods, the single market was largely completed in 1992, but the market for services remains a
work in progress a quarter of a century later. The EU has promised to introduce it many times, but
several countries have dragged their feet and it is much more complicated than creating a single
market for say, cars or computers. Even so, the City of London dominates financial services in the
EU not least because it can do business in every member country.
But to stay in the single market, countries have to allow the free movement of goods, services,
capital and people. That last one means immigration is difficult if not impossible to control -
although the UK might get a special deal to allow some limits.
Membership of the single market also normally involves making annual payments towards the
EU's budget and accepting the jurisdiction of the European Court of Justice, which would cross
quite a few red lines for many Brexiteers.
CUSTOMS UNION
Turkey is part of a customs union with the EU but not in the single market. The deal does not
cover food or agriculture, services or government procurement.
The EU is not only a single market - it is also a customs union. The countries club together and
agree to apply the same tariffs to goods from outside the union.
Once goods have cleared customs in one country, they can be shipped to others in the union
without further tariffs being imposed.
If the UK left the Customs Union but stayed in the Single market, our exporters would have to
contend with what are called 'rules of origin'.
These rules are designed to demonstrate that goods that legally originated in the UK - and did not
contain more than the maximum permitted level of parts and components from elsewhere - qualify
for duty-free entry into the EU.
If we left both the single market and the customs union, we could negotiate a free trade deal with
the EU. A free trade area is one where there are no tariffs or taxes or quotas on goods and/or
services from one country entering another.
The negotiations to establish them can take years and there are normally exceptions.
So, agriculture and fisheries might be exempted, certain industries protected and some goods may
not be covered.
Regional trading agreements refer to a treaty that is signed by two or more countries to encourage
free movement of goods and services across the borders of its members. The agreement comes
with internal rules that member countries follow among themselves. When dealing with non-
member countries, there are external rules in place that the members adhere to.
Quotas, tariffs, and other forms of trade barriers restrict the transport of manufactured goods and
services. Regional trading agreements help reduce or remove the barriers to trade.
Regional trading agreements vary depending on the level of commitment and the arrangement
among the member countries.
The preferential trading agreement requires the lowest level of commitment to reducing trade
barriers, though member countries do not eliminate the barriers among themselves. Also,
preferential trade areas do not share common external trade barriers.
In a free trade agreement, all trade barriers among members are eliminated, which means that they
can freely move goods and services among themselves. When it comes to dealing with non-
members, the trade policies of each member still take effect.
3. Customs Union
Member countries of a customs union remove trade barriers among themselves and adopt common
external trade barriers.
4. Common Market
A common market is a type of trading agreement wherein members remove internal trade barriers,
adopt common policies when it comes to dealing with non-members, and allow members to move
resources among themselves freely.
5. Economic Union
An economic union is a trading agreement wherein members eliminate trade barriers among
themselves, adopt common external barriers, allow free import and export of resources, adopt a set
of economic policies, and use one currency.
6. Full Integration
The full integration of member countries is the final level of trading agreements.
Member countries benefit from trade agreements, particularly in the form of generation of more
job opportunities, lower unemployment rates, and market expansions. Also, since trade agreements
usually come with investment guarantees, investors who want to invest in developing countries are
protected against political risk
2. Volume of Trade
Businesses in member countries enjoy greater incentives to trade in new markets, thanks to
attractive trading conditions due to the policies included in the agreements.
Trade agreements open a lot of doors for businesses. As they gain access to new markets, the
competition becomes more intense. The increased competition compels businesses to produce
higher quality products. It also leads to more variety for consumers. When there is a wide variety
of high-quality products, businesses can improve customer satisfaction.
Unit-3
Foreign Exchange
Foreign Exchange refers to currencies and other instruments of payment denominated in other
countries’ currencies.
An Exchange rate can be defined as the number of units of one currency that must be given to
acquire one unit of a currency of another country. It is the price paid in the home currency to
purchase a certain quantity of funds in the currency of another country. It is therefore the link
between different national currencies that makes international price and cost comparisons possible.
If the rate is quoted for current foreign currency transactions, it is called the spot rate. The spot
rate applies to interbank transactions for delivery within two business days or immediate delivery
for over-the-counter transactions that usually involve non-bank customers.
If the rate is quoted for delivery of foreign currency in the future, it is called the forward rate. This
is a contractual rate between the foreign exchange trader and the trader's client.
The spread in the spot market is the difference between the bid (buy) and offer (sell) rates quoted
by the foreign exchange trader.
The forward spread is the difference between the spot and forward exchange rates.
The direct quote is the number of units of the domestic currency for one unit of the foreign
currency.
The indirect quote is the number of units of the foreign currency for one unit of the domestic
currency.
The cross rate is an exchange rate computed from two other exchange rates.
The demand for foreign currency is fixed by the supply and demand curve (just like any
other commodity in an open market). The demand for foreign currency arises from the traders
who have to make up payments for imported goods. The supply arises from those who have
exported goods and services abroad. This depends largely on how much foreigners are willing to
buy goods and services from a particular country.
1. Export/Imports
If a country exports more goods, the importing country will have a higher demand for the currency
of the exporting country so as to meet its obligation. The value of the currency of the exporting
country will therefore appreciate. The opposite is the case if a country imports more goods than
exports.
2. Political Stability
Unsuitable political climate will make the citizens lose confidence in their currency.
They would therefore wish to invest or just buy the currency of the other countries they deem to be
stable. In so doing, the demand for currency of more political stable countries will appreciate as
compared to those of politically unstable countries.
Parity between the purchasing powers of two currencies establishes the rate of
exchange between the two currencies. When inflation rate differential between two countries
changes, the exchange rate also adjusts to correspond to the relative purchasing powers of the
currencies.
5. Balance of Payment
The term balance of payment refers to a system of government accounts that catalogues the flow of
economic transactions between the residents of one country and the residents of other countries. It
is therefore the fund flow statement.
Continuous deficit in the balance of payments is expected to depress the value of a currency
because such deficit would increase the supply of that currency relative to its demand.
6. Government Policies
A national government may through its Central Bank intervene in the foreign
exchange market, buying and selling its currency as it sees fit to support its currency relative to
others. In order to promote cheap export, a country may maintain a policy of undervaluing its
currency.
A foreign exchange rate is the rate at which one currency is exchanged for another. Thus,
an exchange rate can be regarded as the price of one currency in terms of another.
on 01 Apr 2020.
$1 = Rs. 76.575
In India the free exchange rate regime is prevailed. Foreign exchange rate is determined on
the basis of Demand and Supply theory.
Foreign Exchange is a price of one country currency in relation to other country currency, which
like the price of any other commodity is determined by the demand and supply factors. The
demand and supply of the foreign exchange rate come from the residents of the respective
countries.
shares/bonds etc.
Purpose.
When the demand of the dollar will increase , dollar appreciates from Rs. 50 = $1 to Rs. 53
= $1, while rupee depreciates from $1 = Rs. 50 to $1 = Rs. 53.
When the supply of the dollar will increase, dollar depreciate from Rs. 50 = $1 to Rs. 48 =
$1, while rupee appreciate from $1 = Rs. 50 to $1 = Rs. 48.
Exchange Rate Management in India
Over the last six decades since independence the exchange rate system in India has transited from
fixed exchange rate regime to floating rate regime.
1. Par Value System (1974-1971): After Independence Indian followed the ‘Par Value
System’ whereby the rupee’s external par value was fixed with gold and UK pound
sterling.
2. Pegged Regime (1971-1991): India pegged its currency to the US dollar (1971-1991) and
to pound (1971-75). Following the breakdown of Breton Woods system, the value of pound
collapsed, and India witnessed misalignment of the rupee. To overcome the pressure of
devaluation India pegged its currency to a basket of currencies. During this period, the
exchange rate was officially determined by the RBI within a nominal band of +/- 5 percent
of the weighted average of a basket of currencies of India’s major trading partners.
3. The period since 1991 -1993: The transition to market-based exchange rate was in response
to the BOP crisis of 1991. As a first step towards transition, India introduces partial
convertibility of rupee in 1992-93 under LERMS.
Liberalized Exchange Rate Management System (LERMS): The LERMS involved partial
convertibility of rupee. Under this system, India followed a dual exchange rate policy,
where
40 converted at the official exchange rate and the remaining
60% converted at the market-based exchange rate
4. Market-Based Exchange rate Regime (1993- till present): The LERMS was a transitional
mechanism to provide stability during the crisis period. Once the stability is achieved, India
transited from LERMS to a full flash market exchange rate system. As a result, since 1993,
exchange rate fluctuations are marker determined. In the 1994 budget, 60:40 ratio was
removed, and 100 percent conversion at market-based rate was allowed for all goods and
capital movement
Exchange Rate Exposure
The extent to which a firm is exposed or vulnerable to fluctuations in exchange rate is referred to
as the exchange rate exposure and can be perceived in three different ways:
Transaction exposure
This defines the foreign exchange rate risk in terms of the impact of exchange rate movement on
the firm’s future cash flows. This type of exposure arises from an obligation to either accept or
deliver foreign currency at a future date. The most important transactions leading to transaction
exposure are accounts receivable and accounts payables denominated in foreign currency.
Translation Exposure
Translation exposure defines exchange rate risk in terms of the impact of exchange rate movement
on the financial statement of the firm. When a business is organized as several separate
corporations, then financial statements must be filed on a consolidated basis so as to give
shareholders concise and complete information as to the financial position and the operating
performance of the firm as a whole. When subsidiary operate in a foreign country then major
complications occur in consolidation process. This problem arises from the fact that financial
statements of the foreign subsidiary are usually in a currency which is different form that of the
parent company. The foreign currency must be converted into the home currency before accounts
can be consolidated. Translation exposure therefore is the extent to which multinational firms
consolidated financial statements are affected by the need to convert its foreign subsidiary
accounts to the home currency. As the value of the exchange rate fluctuates, so would be the value
of the foreign subsidiary.
Economic Exposure
Economic exposure defines exchange rate risk as the total impact on all the cash flow of the firm
(both contractual and non-contractual) It is broader than the other types of exposure and may be
considered to be the overall impact of the foreign exchange fluctuations on the shareholders
wealth. It affects both the companies that enter into foreign currency transactions and those that do
not.
Non-Contractual Techniques
Contractual techniques include forward exchange rates, money market hedge currency options,
currency futures and swaps. These techniques are explained below:
A forward exchange contract is an immediate, firm and binding contract between the bank and its
customer for the purchase or sale of a specified quantity of a stated foreign currency at a rate of
exchange fixed when the contract is made but requiring performance at a specified future date.
A forward exchange contract can either be fixed or option. A fixed forward exchange contract
requires performance to take place on a specified future date. While an option forward exchange
contract requires performance to take place at any date between two specified dates
Forward exchange rate might be higher or lower than the spot rate. If it is higher, then the quoted
currency would be cheaper forward than spot (using indirect quote)
When the time to carry out the transaction in a forward exchange contract is due but the party
buying or selling the foreign currency does not have the required currency, then the party may
organize a cross out of the contract. If the customer had contracted to sell foreign currency to the
bank but cannot perform his part of the contract, then the bank will sell the currency at the spot
rate to the customer and then buy it back at the agreed rate. If the difference in this transaction is a
loss (on the part of the customer), then the bank is compensated by the customer to offset the loss.
If there is a gain then the bank compensates the customer.
Money-Market Hedge
An exporter who invoices foreign customers in foreign currency can hedge against the exchange
risk by:
- Repaying the loan and interest out of the foreign currency received from the customer
Similarly, if a company has to make foreign currency payment in the future, it can buy the
currency now at the spot rate and put it in a foreign currency deposit account. Eventually the
company should use the principle and interest earned to make the payment when they fall due.
Currency Option
A major drawback of a forward exchange contract is that it’s a binding contract which must be
performed. Some investors may be uncertain about the earnings they will make in several months’
time and therefore would be unable to enter into a forward exchange contract without the risk of
contraction to sell more or less than they will receive.
The use of a currency option overcomes this problem. A currency option is an agreement that
gives the holder the right but not the obligation to buy or sell a certain quantity of foreign currency
at a specified exchange rate at a specified future time.
When there is uncertainty about foreign currency receipt or payment either in timing or amount. If
the foreign exchange transaction does not materialise then the currency option can be sold in the
market (if it has any value) or it can be exercised if it will make a profit
- It can be used to support a tender for an overseas contract priced in foreign currency.
Currency Futures
A financial future is a standard contract between a buyer and a seller in which a buyer has a
binding obligation to buy a fixed amount (i.e. the contract size) at a fixed price (the future price),
on a fixed date (delivery date or the expiration date) of some underlying assets. E.g. if we bought
sterling pound futures than we will have a binding obligation to buy a fixed amount of sterling
pound at a fixed rate at a fixed date. Similarly a seller would have a binding obligation to deliver a
sterling pound. This is similar to a forward exchange contract to buy sterling pound from a bank.
- Each currency future is traded in units of a fixed size such that fractions of contracts cannot
be bought or sold.
- Whereas forward exchange contract with banks can be drawn up for any date in future,
delivery date for currency futures occur only on 4 dates per year, (March, June, September and
December). This may appear to be a severe restriction but in practice most future contracts are
sold before they reach maturity.
- A financial future exchange offers a physical meeting place for buyers and sellers. Dealing
on floor between member firms is by open outcry.
- Buyers and sellers are required to deposit margins to ensure credit worthiness. Profit or
losses on contracts are also received and paid throughout the life of the future.
Hedging
It is the technique by which a person can minimize or reduce the risk which arises due to the
change in the foreign exchange rate. There are 2 techniques of Hedging
1. Internal Techniques
a. Invoice in home currency: in this technique company make the payment and receive
the payment in its home currency.
b. Leading and lagging: Importer can delay the payment
Theory suggests that, in the long run, gains and losses net off and leave a similar result to that if
hedged.
a. Forward contracts
The forward market is where you can buy and sell a currency, at a fixed future date for a
predetermined rate, i.e. the forward rate of exchange. This effectively fixes the future rate.
b. Futures contracts
The aim of a currency futures contract is to fix an exchange rate at some future date, subject to
basis risk.
Commercial banks are normally taking over the position to support the economy of the country by
carrying over the foreign currency from one period to another, for meeting the future need of the
country. They are also sometime making short sale (agree to sell or actually sell the foreign
currency without any real capacity to sell through or borrow the required currency from others) of
foreign currency to satisfy the need of firms to make payments.
Later on to bring the position in equilibrium, they quote the rates for buying and selling of foreign
currency accordingly. As they are buying the foreign currency from the customer, the rate they
quote for buying the foreign currency is technically named as Bid rate. When they sell the foreign
currency to customer, the rate they quote is technically known as Ask rate.
FE brokers do not buy or sell the foreign currency on their own account, as done by market
makers. They are working as an intermediary between two parties, to satisfy their respective needs.
As they are working as a bridge between buyers and sellers of the foreign currency, they are only
earning the fees in the form of brokerage charges.
To protect the financial strength and stability of the country’s balance of payments, internal money
supply, interest rates and inflation, RBI intervenes in the foreign exchange markets to protect the
disequilibrium in the prices of foreign exchange conversion.
Corporate are the players in the FE market, to satisfy their need of payment in foreign currency
towards imports of goods, commodities and services. On the opposite way, they need to convert
foreign currency in home currency on account of export of goods, commodities, and services. The
need of conversion also happens on account of transactions in financial markets across the globe,
for loan disbursement, repayment of loans, receipt and payment of annual charges, etc.
Arbitrage
Arbitrage is the process of a simultaneous sale and purchase of currencies in two or more foreign
exchange markets with an objective to make profits by capitalizing on the exchange-rate
differentials in various markets.
The arbitrage opportunities exist due to the inefficiencies of the market. While dealing in the
arbitrage trade, an individual can make profits only out of price differences of similar or identical
financial instruments traded on different exchange markets. Thus, the price differential is
captured as a trade’s net payoff. This payoff should be large enough to cover the expenses
incurred in executing the trade.
For example: Suppose the stock of company A is trading at Rs 2000 on BSE while the same stock
is trading on NSE at Rs 2500. A trader can earn a profit of Rs 500 by buying the stock on BSE and
immediately selling the same shares on NSE. This arbitrage opportunity can be availed until BSE
runs out of shares of company A or until BSE and NSE adjusts the price differences so as to wipe
out the arbitraging opportunity.
The importance of arbitrage lies in its ability to correspond foreign exchange rates in all the major
foreign exchange markets. The arbitraging involves the transfer of foreign exchange from the
market with a lower exchange rate to the market with a higher exchange rate. Hence, arbitraging
equates the demand for foreign exchange with its supply, thereby acting as a stabilizing factor in
the exchange markets.
The arbitrage opportunity can be availed only where the foreign exchange is free from controls,
and if any, controls should be of limited significance. If the sale and purchase of foreign exchange
are under severe control and regulation, then the arbitrage is not possible. Practically, the arbitrage
opportunity exists for a very brief period since in the mature markets the most of the trading has
been taken by the algorithm-based trading (a trading system that relies heavily on mathematical
formulas and computer programs to determine the trading strategies). These algorithm-based
trading are quick to spot and is quite easy for a trader to keep track.
Currency arbitrage involves the exploitation of the differences in quotes rather than movements in
the exchange rates of the currencies in the currency pair.
A cross-currency transaction is one that consists of a pair of currencies traded in forex that
does not include the U.S. dollar. Ordinary cross currency rates involve the Japanese yen.
Arbitrage seeks to exploit pricing between the currency pairs, or the cross rates of different
currency pairs.
In covered interest rate arbitrages the practice of using favourable interest rate differentials
to invest in a higher-yielding currency, and hedging the exchange risk through a forward
currency contract.
An uncovered interest rate arbitrage involves changing a domestic currency which carries a
lower interest rate to a foreign currency that offers a higher rate of interest on deposits.
Spot-future arbitrage involves taking positions in the same currency in the spot and futures
markets. For example, a trader would buy currency on the spot market and sell the same
currency in the futures market if there is a beneficial pricing discrepancy.
Forex arbitrage often requires lending or borrowing at near to risk-free rates, which generally are
available only at large financial institutions. The cost of funds may limit traders at smaller banks or
brokerages. Spreads, as well as trading and margin cost overhead, are additional risk factors.
Foreign exchange intervention is the process whereby a central bank buys or sells foreign currency
in an attempt to stabilize the exchange rate, or to correct misalignments in the forex market. This is
often accompanied by a subsequent adjustment, by the central bank, to the money supply to offset
any undesirable knock-on effects in the local economy.
The mechanism mentioned above, is referred to as “sterilized intervention” and will be discussed
later on, along with the other currency intervention methods.
Traders must keep in mind that when central banks intervene in the forex market, moves can be
extremely volatile. Therefore, it is essential to set an appropriate risk to reward ratio and make use
of prudent risk management.
Central banks intervene in the forex market when the current trend is in the opposite direction to
where the central bank desires the exchange rate to be. Therefore, trading around central bank
intervention is a lot like trading reversals.
Additionally, the forex market tends to anticipate central bank intervention meaning that it is not
uncommon to see movements against the long-term trend in the moments leading up to central
bank intervention. Since there is no guarantee that traders can look for the new trend to emerge
before placing a trade.
Central banks generally agree that intervention is necessary to stimulate the economy or maintain a
desired foreign exchange rate. Central banks will often buy foreign currency and sell local
currency if the local currency appreciates to a level that renders domestic exports more expensive
to foreign nations. Therefore, central banks purposely alter the exchange rate to benefit the local
economy.
Below is an example of successful central bank intervention in response to Japanese Yen strength
against the US dollar. The Bank of Japan was of the view that the exchange rate was unfavourable
and swiftly intervened to depreciate the Yen thus, resulting in a move higher for the USD/JPY
pair. The intervention took place in the timespan depicted by the blue circle and the effect was
realised shortly thereafter.
While most central bank intervention is successful, there are instances when this in not the case.
The chart below depicts a currency intervention example in the USD/BRL (Brazilian Real)
currency pair. The chart highlights both instances where the central bank intervened to stop the
decline in the Brazilian Real. It is clear to see that both scenarios failed to immediately strengthen
the Real against the US dollar as the dollar continued to rise higher and higher.
Central banks have a choice of different types of interventions to make use of. These can either be
direct or indirect. Direct intervention, as the name suggests, has an immediate effect on the forex
market, while indirect intervention achieves the objectives of the central bank via less invasive
means. Below are examples of direct and indirect intervention:
Jawboning Indirect
Sterilized InterventionDirect
Operational Intervention: This is usually what people mean when they refer to central bank
intervention. It involves the central bank buying and selling both foreign and local currency to
drive the exchange rate to a targeted level. It is the pure size of these transactions that move the
market.
Jawboning: this is an example of indirect FX intervention whereby a central bank mentions that it
may intervene in the market if the local currency reaches a certain undesirable level. This method,
as the name suggests, is more about talking than actual intervention. With the central bank ready to
intervene, traders take it upon themselves to collectively bring the currency back to more
acceptable levels.
Sterilized intervention: Sterilized intervention involves two actions from the central bank in order
to influence the exchange rate and at the same time, leave the monetary base unchanged. This
involves two steps: The sale or purchase of foreign currency, and an open market operation
(selling or buying government securities) of the same size as the first transaction.
The focus of attention in this approach was on international trade flows as primary determinants of
exchange. One reason for this was that up to 1960s, government’s maintained tight restrictions on
international flow of financial capital.
The role of exchange rate changes in dominating international trade imbalances suggests that
countries with current trade surpluses should have an appreciat•ing currency whereas countries
with trade deficits should have depreciating currencies. Such exchange rate changes would lead to
changes in international relative prices that would work to eliminate the trade imbalances like
surplus or deficit.
The interest parity condition can be used to develop a model of exchange rate determination. That
is, investor behaviour in asset markets which generates interest parity can also explain why the
exchange rate may rise and fall in response to market changes.
The first step is to reinterpret the rate of return calculation described above in more general
(aggregate) terms. Thus instead of using the interest rate on a one year CD, we will interpret the
interest rates in the two countries as the average interest rates currently prevailing. Similarly, we
will imagine that the expected exchange rate is the average expectation across many different
individual investors. The rates of return then are the average expected rates of return on a wide
variety of assets between the two countries.
Next we imagine that investors trade currencies in the foreign exchange market. Each day some
investors come to a market ready to supply a currency in exchange for another while others come
to demand currency in exchange for another.
Consider the market for British pounds (£) in New York depicted in the adjoining diagram. We
measure the supply and demand of £s along the horizontal axis and the price of £s (i.e. the
exchange rate E$/£) on the vertical axis. Let S£ represent the supply of £s in exchange for dollars
at all different exchange rates that might prevail. The supply is generally by British investors who
demand dollars to purchase dollar denominated assets. However, supply of £s might also come
from US investors who decide to convert previously acquired £ currency. Let D£ the demand for
£s in exchange for dollars at all different exchange rates that might prevail. The demand is
generally by US investors who supply dollars to purchase £ denominated assets. Of course,
demand might also come from British investors who decide to convert previously purchased
dollars. Recall that which implies that as E$/£ rises RoR£ falls. This means that British investors
would seek to supply more £s at higher £ values but US investors would demand fewer £s at
higher £ values. This explains why the supply curve slopes upward and the demand curve slopes
downward.
The intersection of supply and demand specifies the equilibrium exchange rate, E1, and the
quantity of £s, Q1, traded in the market.
Influencing exchange rates of currencies by the authorities which issue them is a common
phenomenon in the modern global economy. At its base, there is primarily a conviction of the need
for more stable environment for international economic flows. In the case of the European Union
member states, another reason for shaping the exchange rate emerges – its stability is one of the
convergence criteria, which determine the possibility of joining the euro zone. The objective of
this paper is the presentation of the results of an analysis how this criterion is met by the EU
countries which do not use the common currency yet and the indication of the elementary
conditions that affect their ability to fulfil it. In the first part of the article, several determinants
arising from the provisions of European law and from their implementation in practice are
signalled, and then a focus is made on a brief analysis of statistical data.
Influencing the exchange rate and the Maastricht Treaty Economic authorities influence the
exchange rate in order to achieve two main, direct goals – to adjust it in the desired direction and
to stabilise it. The former of these objectives is not the subject of this study, however, the
consequences of changes in the exchange rate are widely analysed in available literature. In turn,
stabilising the national currency’s relation against other means of payment also carries a number of
economic consequences. Moreover, their occurrence is very often the primary intention of shaping
the exchange rate. A basic effect of the stabilisation of the relation between the national means of
payment and other currencies is a higher level of certainty in international flows. A low degree of
national currency’s value fluctuations causes that entities maintaining economic relations with
foreign countries may take long-term decisions less burdened with the exchange rate risk. This
kind of risk often represents a barrier to entry by domestic companies on the path of
internationalisation1 . Choosing to enter new markets or to start up production in other countries is
certainly easier when the authorities conduct effective and responsible currency policy, focused on
the stabilisation of the exchange rate. A similar dependence also applies to investors on financial
markets. Admittedly, in practice, because of the enormous value of speculative capital pouring
between countries, in the face of significant tensions or crises, central banks have been – and
Unit -4
This is that rate at which the value of a currency remains stable vis-a-vis other currencies
for a long period of time. A fixed exchange rate, sometimes called a pegged exchange rate, is a
type of exchange rate regime where a currency's value is fixed against the value of another single
currency, to a basket of other currencies, or to another measure of value, such as gold. A fixed
exchange rate is usually used to stabilize the value of a currency against the currency it is pegged
to. This makes trade and investments between the two currency areas easier and more predictable,
and is especially useful for small economies in which external trade forms a large part of their
GDP. It can also be used as a means to control inflation. However, as the reference value rises and
falls, so does the currency pegged to it. These rates of exchange are fixed by the Central Bank
through the process of pegging the currency concerned e.g. if the currency is pegged to a Dollar,
then its value remains fixed to the value of the dollar and will move with movement in the value of
the dollar.
1. It stabilizes the export proceeds and therefore it may stimulate exports for the period in
which it is fixed.
2. Foreign investors gauge the return on their investments in local currency vis-a-vis their
own currencies. A fixed exchange rate will assure these investors of a stable return on their
investment which may induce foreign investors, thus increasing the inflow of foreign
exchange to the country.
3. It enables the government to meet its development plans whose budgets are set in local
currencies but may be financed by foreign loans and aid.
4. It may keep inflation under control because the prices of imported goods will remain stable
as long as the exchange rate is fixed. This is particularly true for imported inflation
(Inflation due to an increase in the price of imports. As the price of imports increase, prices
of domestic goods using imports as raw materials also increase, causing an increase in the
general prices of all goods and services. Imported inflation may be caused by foreign price
increases or depreciation of a country's exchange rate).
5. Long term investment plans can be worked out with substantial accuracy and may
minimize budget deficits with their negative effects.
1. Reduced risk in international trade - By maintaining a fixed rate, buyers and sellers of
goods internationally can agree a price and not be subject to the risk of later changes in
the exchange rate before contracts are settled. The greater certainty should help
encourage investment.
2. Introduces discipline in economic management - As the burden or pain of adjustment to
equilibrium is thrown onto the domestic economy then governments have a built-in
incentive not to follow inflationary policies. If they do, then unemployment and balance
of payments problems are certain to result as the economy becomes uncompetitive.
3. Fixed rates should eliminate destabilising speculation - Speculation flows can be very
destabilising for an economy and the incentive to speculate is very small when the
exchange rate is fixed.
Disadvantages of the Fixed Exchange Rate
• Large holdings of foreign exchange reserves required - Fixed exchange rates require a
government to hold large scale reserves of foreign currency to maintain the fixed rate - such
reserves have an opportunity cost.
• Loss of freedom in your internal policy - The needs of the exchange rate can dominate
policy and this may not be best for the economy at that point. Interest rates and other policies may
be set for the value of the exchange rate rather than the more important macro objectives of
inflation and unemployment.
• Fixed rates are inherently unstable - Countries within a fixed rate mechanism often
follow different economic policies, the result of which tends to be differing rates of inflation. What
this means is that some countries will have low inflation and be very competitive and others will
have high inflation and not be very competitive. The uncompetitive countries will be under severe
pressure continually and may, ultimately, have to devalue. Speculators will know this and thus
creates further pressure on that currency and, in turn, government.
currency that uses a floating exchange rate is known as a floating currency. A floating currency is
contrasted with a fixed currency.
When the rate of exchange of a currency is floating, it is left to move in response to different
forces (especially the balance of payments). It is left to be determined by the forces of demand and
supply of foreign currencies of a given currency.
This rate may discourage investment by foreign investors as they are uncertain about the return to
be earned on investment made under floating rates of exchange. It may also discourage export
trade and may increase inflation rates.
• Absence of crises - Fixed rates are often characterized by crises as pressure mounts on a
currency to devalue or revalue. The fact that, with a floating rate, such changes are automatic
should remove the element of crisis from international relations.
• Flexibility - Post-1973 there were great changes in the pattern of world trade as well as a
major change in world economics as a result of the OPEC oil shock. A fixed exchange rate would
have caused major problems at this time as some countries would be uncompetitive given their
inflation rate. The floating rate allows a country to re-adjust more flexibly to external shocks.
• Lower foreign exchange reserves - A country with a fixed rate usually has to hold large
amounts of foreign currency in order to prepare for a time when they have to defend that fixed rate.
These reserves have an opportunity cost.
• Uncertainty - The fact that a currency changes in value from day to day introduces
instability or uncertainty into trade. Sellers may be unsure of how much money they will receive
when they sell abroad or what their price actually is abroad. Of course, the rate changing will
affect price and thus sales. In a similar way importer never know how much it is going to cost
them to import a given amount of foreign goods. This uncertainty can be reduced by hedging the
foreign exchange risk on the forward market.
• Lack of investment - The uncertainty can lead to a lack of investment internally as well as
from abroad.
• Speculation - Speculation will tend to be an inherent part of a floating system and it can be
damaging and destabilising for the economy, as the speculative flows may often differ from the
underlying pattern of trade flows.
• Inflation - The floating exchange rate can be inflationary. Apart from not punishing
inflationary economies, which, in itself, encourages inflation, the float can cause inflation by
allowing import prices to rise as the exchange rate falls. This is, undoubtedly, the case for
countries such as UK where we are dependent on imports of food and raw materials.
For example, consider an electronic component priced at $10 in the U.S. that will be exported to
India. Assume the exchange rate is 50 rupees to the U.S. dollar. Neglecting shipping and
other transaction costs such as importing duties for now, the $10 electronic component would cost
the Indian importer 500 rupees.
If the dollar were to strengthen against the Indian rupee to a level of 55 rupees (to one U.S. dollar),
and assuming that the U.S. exporter does not increase the price of the component, its price would
increase to 550 rupees ($10 x 55) for the Indian importer. This may force the Indian importer to
look for cheaper components from other locations. The 10% appreciation in the dollar versus the
rupee has thus diminished the U.S. exporter’s competitiveness in the Indian market.
At the same time, assuming again an exchange rate of 50 rupees to one U.S. dollar, consider a
garment exporter in India whose primary market is in the U.S. A shirt that the exporter sells for
$10 in the U.S. market would result in them receiving 500 rupees when the export proceeds are
received (neglecting shipping and other costs).
If the rupee weakens to 55 rupees to one U.S. dollar, the exporter can now sell the shirt for $9.09
to receive the same amount of rupees (500). The 10% depreciation in the rupee versus the dollar
has therefore improved the Indian exporter’s competitiveness in the U.S. market.
The result of the 10% appreciation of the dollar versus the rupee has rendered U.S. exports of
electronic components uncompetitive, but it has made imported Indian shirts cheaper for U.S.
consumers. The flip side is that a 10% depreciation of the rupee has improved the competitiveness
of Indian garment exports, but has made imports of electronic components more expensive for
Indian buyers.
When this scenario is multiplied by millions of transactions, currency moves can have a drastic
impact on a country's imports and exports.
The Venezuelan Crisis is an ongoing socioeconomic and political crisis that began in Venezuela on
June 2, 2010 during the presidency of Hugo Chávez and has continued into the presidency of
Nicolás Maduro. It is marked by hyperinflation, escalating starvation, disease, crime and mortality
rates, resulting in massive emigration from the country. According to economists interviewed by
The New York Times, the situation is the worst economic crisis in Venezuela's history and the
worst facing a country that is not experiencing war since the mid-20th century, and is more severe
than that of the United States during the Great Depression, of Brazil's 1985–1994 economic crisis,
or of Zimbabwe's 2008–2009 hyperinflation crisis. Other American writers have also compared
aspects of the crisis, such as unemployment and GDP contraction, to Bosnia and Herzegovina after
the 1992-95 Bosnian War as well as Russia, Cuba and Albania following the collapse of the
Eastern Bloc in late 1989.
On 2 June 2010, Chávez declared an "economic war" due to increasing shortages in Venezuela.
The crisis intensified under the Maduro government, growing more severe as a result of low oil
prices in early 2015, and a drop in Venezuela's oil production from lack of maintenance and
investment. The government failed to cut spending in the face of falling oil revenues, and has dealt
with the crisis by denying its existence and violently repressing opposition. Extrajudicial killings
by the Venezuelan government became common, with the U.N. reporting 5,287 killings by the
Special Action Forces in 2017, with at least another 1,569 killings recorded in the first six months
of 2019; the U.N. had "reasonable grounds to believe that many of these killings constitute
extrajudicial executions", and characterized the security operations as "aimed at neutralizing,
repressing and criminalizing political opponents and people critical of the government." The U.N.
also stated that the Special Action Forces "would plant arms and drugs and fire their weapons
against the walls or in the air to suggest a confrontation and to show the victim had resisted
authority" and that some of the killings were "done as a reprisal for [the victims'] participation in
anti-government demonstrations". Political corruption, chronic shortages of food and medicine,
closure of companies, unemployment, deterioration of productivity, authoritarianism, human rights
violations, gross economic mismanagement and high dependence on oil have also contributed to
the worsening crisis.
Supporters of Chávez and Maduro say that the problems result from an "economic war" on
Venezuela and "falling oil prices, international sanctions, and the country's business elite"; critics
of the government say the cause is "years of economic mismanagement, and corruption". Most
critics cite anti-democratic governance, corruption and mismanagement of the economy as causes
of the crisis. Others attribute the crisis to the "socialist", "populist" or "hyper-populist “nature of
the regime's policies and the use of these policies to maintain political power. In 2018, the United
Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights (OHCHR) documented that "information gathered
indicates that the socioeconomic crisis had been unfolding for several years" before international
sanctions, with Michelle Bachelet saying in 2019 that the social and economic crisis was
dramatically deteriorating, the government had not acknowledged or addressed the extent of the
crisis, and she expressed concern that although the "pervasive and devastating economic and social
crisis began before the imposition of the first economic sanctions", the sanctions could worsen the
situation. National and international analysts and economists stated that the crisis is not the result
of a conflict, natural disaster or sanctions but the consequences of populist policies and corrupt
practices that began under the Chávez administration's Bolivarian Revolution and continued under
the Maduro administration.
The crisis has affected the life of the average Venezuelan on all levels. By 2017, hunger had
escalated to the point where almost seventy-five percent of the population had lost an average of
over 8 kg (over 19 lbs) in weight, and more than half did not have enough income to meet their
basic food needs. Reuters reported that a UN report estimated in March 2019 that 94% of
Venezuelans live in poverty, and more than ten percent of Venezuelans (3.4 million) have left their
country. The UN analysis estimates in 2019 that 25% of Venezuelans need some form of
humanitarian assistance. Venezuela led the world in murder rates, with 81.4 per 100,000 people
killed in 2018, making it the third most violent country in the world
Following increased international sanctions throughout 2019, the Maduro government abandoned
policies established by Chávez such as price and currency controls, which resulted in the country
seeing a temporary rebound from economic decline before COVID-19 entered Venezuela the
following year. In an interview with José Vicente Rangel, President Maduro described
dollarization as an "escape valve" that helps the recovery of the country, the spread of productive
forces in the country and the economy. However, Maduro said that the Venezuelan bolívar remains
as the national currency.
In Venezuela, the government of President Nicolás Maduro and the opposition are engaged in a
bitter power struggle. Opposition lawmakers have been barred from standing for office, some have
been arrested and others have gone into exile. The United Nations has accused the government of
using a strategy of instilling fear in its population to retain power. The South American country has
been caught in a downward spiral for years with growing political discontent further fuelled by
skyrocketing hyperinflation, power cuts and shortages of food and medicine. Close to five million
Venezuelans have left the country in recent years. But what exactly is behind the crisis rocking
Venezuela.
1. Financial risk
In 2015, banks began tightening lending standards, borrowers became more delinquent
paying back loans and financial stress while still low, began to increase.
Financial stress indicators from the Federal Reserve are extremely valuable for compositing
various financial risks. They measure foreign exchange rates, real estate, interest rates,
yield spreads, volatility indexes, liquidity, yield curve, market indexes, and inflation.
In addition to the Financial Stress indexes, I use the Chicago Fed Adjusted National
Financial Conditions Index and Chicago Board Options Exchange Volatility
Index (VIX) to come up with my own Risk Indicator. Near 100% are the best investment
periods, negative indicators are the risky times to be long in the stock market. When the
Risk Indicator is declining toward zero, are times to be looking for opportunities to
rebalance to safety.
While the Yield Curve has not inverted, it has been flattening for the past two years as
shown below. Short term interest rates are rising and long term rates are falling. It is
normalizing of interest rates. This is typically a sign of lower expected growth rates from
bond investors.
I also estimate an Interest Indicator as shown below based on bond total return, corporate
bond spread, yield curve, TED spread and high yield rates.
2. Credit/monetary risk
Access to money for investment is a large factor in growth of the economy. The next chart
shows the high growth rate of credit over the past half century and the lower rate after the
financial crisis. This will likely contribute to slower growth.
3. RECESSION RISK
In the media, there are so many estimates of recession probabilities. The Philadelphia Fed's
survey of 42 economists puts the probability of recession at 12.5% in the second quarter of
2016 and 18.5% in the second quarter of 2017. "WSJ Survey: Recession Odds Remain
Elevated Despite Calmer Financial Markets" describes a Wall Street Journal survey of 70
economists with an average estimated probability of 20% for a recession to start in the next
12 months. Below is the smoothed recession probability (RECPROUSM156N, Feb 2016)
and the GDP-based recession indicator (JHGDPBRINDX, 2015 Q4).
INFLATION RISK
The St. Louis Fed Price Pressures are a good measure of the risk of inflation and deflation.
We are currently in a low inflation environment. Notice that in the past 20 years there have
only been two periods where there was much of a probability of deflation.
5. VALUATION RISK
Turning valuation metrics into an investment indicator was difficult because of the high
valuation during the Technology Bubble and because of the duration that the markets can
be highly valued before falling. The next chart shows how the Wilshire large cap index
performed in the year following the peak valuation for the Technology Bubble, Financial
Crisis and the current market. There is a risk that the stock market will fall more than 10%
in 2016 if the economy fails to improve.
The three highest weighted sub-indexes in my Valuation Indicator are Tobin Q, Cyclically
Adjusted Price to Earnings Ratio (NYSEARCA:CAPE) and trailing Price to Earnings Ratio. Also
used is the Market Capitalization to Gross Domestic Product. Finally, I shift the allocation index
forward 5 months to compensate for the long lead time.
6. GROWTH RISK
An economy that is not growing has inherent risks. I combine the Philadelphia Fed
(USSLIND), Conference Board, and Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) leading indicators into my US Leading Indicator. It shows a slowing
economy.
INTERNATIONAL RISK
The following indicator is based on a weighted average of Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development (OECD) leading indicators for China, Japan, Euro Zone and
United States. It reflects anticipated global slow growth. It is probably one of the higher
risks to the current investment environment, particularly China.
7. MOMENTUM RISK
I created the Market Turning Points Indicator based on over 20 indicators to help identify tops
and bottoms in the markets/economy. It is more of short term indicator based on percent of
positive or negative indicators, technical indicators and rates of change.
From a longer term perspective, the current market (red) as measured by the Wilshire 5000
appears to be returning to the trajectory that follows the bursting of the Technology Bubble
and the Financial Crisis as shown below.
8. CORPORATE RISK
Most measures of corporate health are worsening such as profits, sales, income, cash flow
and inventory to sales ratios. There is often a lag before stock prices reflect profits.
Stocks of small companies tend to fall before large cap companies at the end of business
cycles as shown in the chart below.
My Business Indicator is based on the Wilshire Micro Cap Index and the percentage of
banks tightening lending standards for small companies.
Below is a chart that I consolidated from " The Era Of Uncertainty" by Francois Trahan
and Katherine Krantz (2011) suggesting where to invest based on inflation and growth. I
put us in the boxes of low to neutral inflation and low growth. I am mostly invested in
bonds, cash and gold. It is great book and worth reading.
FII
Institutional Investor credit ratings are based on a survey of leading international bankers who are
asked to rate each country on a scale from zero to 100 (where 100 represents maximum
creditworthiness). Institutional Investor averages these ratings, providing greater weights to
respondents with greater worldwide exposure and more sophisticated country analysis systems.
In order to identify the factors that its survey participants have taken into consideration in the past,
Institutional Investor asks them to rank the factors that they take into account in preparing country
ratings. The bankers rank factors differently for different groups of countries and that rankings
have changed over time within country groups. The ranking of factors affecting OECD country
ratings appear to have been the most turbulent over the fifteen-year period.
Monetary approach and asset market approach to predict future exchange rate
The monetary approach has two key ingredients: exogeneity of the real exchange rate, and a
simple Classical model of price level determination.1 Exogeneity of the real exchange rate means
that inflation at home or abroad will not affect how much foreign goods cost in terms of domestic
goods. The Classical model of price determination says roughly that the price level is proportional
to the money supply, so that monetary policy is the key determinant of inflation rates. Eventually,
we will explore both of these constituents in some detail. Suffice it to say that as short-run
descriptions of real economies, both appear quite unrealistic. However as long-run descriptions,
they show somewhat more promise. So the monetary approach to flexible exchange rates is best
seen as a description of long-run outcomes. As a description of short-run outcomes, it serves as a
reference model that highlights some core concerns in our attempt to understand exchange rate
determination.
Exogenous Real Exchange Rates Let P be the domestic consumer price index and P ∗ be the
foreign consumer price index. For now, we will keep things simple by thinking of each price index
as the monetary cost of a fixed consumption basket. Equation (3.1) defines the real exchange rate,
Q.
We call Q the real exchange rate because it tells you the rate at which domestic goods must be
given up to obtain foreign goods. The monetary approach to flexible exchange rates assumes that
Q is exogenous. This exogeneity assumption fits naturally with the Classical model of price
determination, which generally treats real variables as exogenous. Given the real exchange rate,
the nominal exchange rate and the relative price level have a determinate relationship given by
(3.2). S = Q P P∗ (3.2) Here S is the exchange rate, P is the domestic price index, P ∗ is the foreign
price index, and Q is the exogenous real exchange rate. For any given Q, equation (3.2) requires
that exchange rate movements offset price level movements so that the rate at which goods
actually exchange for each other remains unchanged
Over the last six decades since independence the exchange rate system in India has transited from
fixed exchange rate regime to floating rate regime.
1. Par Value System (1974-1971): After Independence Indian followed the ‘Par Value
System’ whereby the rupee’s external par value was fixed with gold and UK pound
sterling.
2. Pegged Regime (1971-1991): India pegged its currency to the US dollar (1971-1991)
and to pound (1971-75). Following the breakdown of Breton Woods system, the value
of pound collapsed, and India witnessed misalignment of the rupee. To overcome the
pressure of devaluation India pegged its currency to a basket of currencies. During this
period, the exchange rate was officially determined by the RBI within a nominal band
of +/- 5 percent of the weighted average of a basket of currencies of India’s major
trading partners.
3. The period since 1991 -1993: The transition to market-based exchange rate was in
response to the BOP crisis of 1991. As a first step towards transition, India introduces
partial convertibility of rupee in 1992-93 under LERMS.
Liberalized Exchange Rate Management System (LERMS): The LERMS involved partial
convertibility of rupee. Under this system, India followed a dual exchange rate policy,
where
41 converted at the official exchange rate and the remaining
60% converted at the market-based exchange rate
4. Market-Based Exchange rate Regime (1993- till present): The LERMS was a
transitional mechanism to provide stability during the crisis period. Once the stability is
achieved, India transited from LERMS to a full flash market exchange rate system. As
a result, since 1993, exchange rate fluctuations are marker determined. In the 1994
budget, 60:40 ratio was removed, and 100 percent conversion at market-based rate was
allowed for all goods and capital movement
Open-Economy Macroeconomics:
Basic Concepts
•A closed economy is one that does not interact with other economies in the world.
•An open economy is one that interacts freely with other economies around the world.
•It buys and sells goods and services in world product markets.
•The United States is a very large and open economy—it imports and exports huge quantities of
goods and services.
• Over the past four decades, international trade and finance have become increasingly important.
• Exports are goods and services that are produced domestically and sold abroad.
• Imports are goods and services that are produced abroad and sold domestically.
• Net exports (NX) are the value of a nation’s exports minus the value of its imports.
Balanced trade refers to when net exports are zero—exports and imports are exactly equal.
•Factors That Affect Net Exports
•The exchange rates at which people can use domestic currency to buy foreign currencies. The
incomes of consumers at home and abroad.
•Net capital outflow refers to the purchase of foreign assets by domestic residents minus the
purchase of domestic assets by foreigners.
•A U.S. resident buys stock in the Toyota corporation and a Mexican buys stock in the Ford Motor
corporation.
•When a U.S. resident buys stock in Telmex, the Mexican phone company, the purchase raises
U.S. net capital outflow.
• When a Japanese resident buys a bond issued by the U.S. government, the purchase reduces the
U.S. net capital outflow.
• Net exports (NX) and net capital outflow (NCO) are closely linked.
•For an economy as a whole, NX and NCO must balance each other so that: NCO = NX •This
holds true because every transaction that affects one side must also affect the other side by the
same amount. Saving, Investment, and Their Relationship to the International Flows •Net exports
is a component of GDP: Y = C + I + G + NX
•National saving is the income of the nation that is left after paying for current consumption and
government purchases:
Y - C - G = I + NX
The prices for international transactions: real and nominal exchange rates
•The two most important international prices are the nominal exchange rate and the real exchange
rate. Nominal Exchange Rates
•The nominal exchange rate is the rate at which a person can trade the currency of one country for
the currency of another.
•The nominal exchange rate is expressed in two ways: •In units of foreign currency per one U.S.
dollar.
•And in units of U.S. dollars per one unit of the foreign currency.
•Assume the exchange rate between the Japanese yen and U.S. dollar is 80 yen to one dollar. •One
U.S. dollar trades for 80 yen.
•One yen trades for 1/80 (= 0.0125) of a dollar
. •Appreciation refers to an increase in the value of a currency as measured by the amount of
foreign currency it can buy.
•Depreciation refers to a decrease in the value of a currency as measured by the amount of foreign
currency it can buy.
•If a dollar buys more foreign currency, there is an appreciation of the dollar.
Unit-5
. International Banking: Reserves, Debt and Risk : Nature of International Reserves – Demand for
International Reserves – Supply of International Reserves – Gold Exchange Standard – Special
Drawing Rights – International Lending Risk – The Problem of International Debt – Financial
Crisis and the International Monetary Fund – Eurocurrency Market
monetary value of international transactions disequilibrium that can arise in balance of payment
positions speed and strength of balance of payments adjustment mechanisms institutional
framework of the world economy In theory there would be no need for international reserves with
freely floating exchange rates.
With Managed Float assume again an increase in imports increases the demand for pounds from
D0 to D1if the upper limit for float is $2.25 Fed must supply 40 pounds effect would be an
increase in supply restoring rate of $2.25
Foreign Currencies largest share of reserves consists of holdings of national currencies through
1900s two currencies commonly held to finance international transactions were UK pound and
U.S. dollar liquidity problem – result of payment deficits position for U.S. while on gold exchange
standard
Demonetization of Gold
1960s supply of foreign held dollars exceeded U.S. stock of gold1968 two-tier gold system official
tier at which central banks could buy and sell gold private market in which gold could be traded at
free market price1971 Nixon suspended commitment to buy and sell gold at $351975 official price
of gold abolished as unit of account for international monetary system
weights of the US dollar, euro, Chinese renminbi, Japanese yen, and British pound sterling are
percent, percent, percent, 8.33 percent, and 8.09 percent The basket composition is reviewed every
five years next review is currently scheduled to take place by September 30, 2021In the
most (concluded in November 2015), the Executive Board decided that, effective October 1, 2016,
the Chinese renminbi is determined to be freely usable and was included in the SDR basket.
Borrowed Reserves IMF Drawings – transactions by which the IMF makes foreign currency loans
to member nations with balance of payment deficits General Agreements to Borrow – ten leading
industrial nations agreement to temporarily supplement IMF reserves; once loans are repaid
reserves revert back to original levels Swap Agreements – bilateral agreements between central
banks for temporary exchange of currencies
Eurodollar Market Eurodollars – bank deposited liabilities denominated in U.S. dollars in banks
outside U.S. though not necessarily in Europe free from regulation by host country competitive
advantage relative to domestic deposits substantial growth since 1950 because of greater freedom
from regulation eliminate the risk associated with converting from one currency to another
Eurocurrencies are a form of bank money: an unsecured short-term bank debt denominated in a
currency (for instance, US dollars) but issued by banks operating offshore – that is, in a
geographical location or a legal space situated outside of the jurisdiction of the national
authorities presiding over that currency (for instance, the Federal Reserve) – in order to fund
short-term loans. Eurodollars were the first and more prominent example of Eurocurrency. The
term was coined in the late 1950s, when banks in London and other European financial centers
started bidding for dollar liquid balances in the hands of foreign wealth owners (other
commercial banks, central banks, official institutions, commercial companies) and used them to
fund short-term loans to other foreign banks and nonfinancial companies. At the same time,
smaller offshore markets for time deposits denominated in other international currencies
emerged; the most relevant examples were the Euro Deutschemark, Euro Swiss Franc and Euro
yen markets in London, and the Euro sterling market in Paris. In the 1970s, as banks operating in
extra-European financial centres expanded their Eurocurrency (mostly Eurodollar) activities, the
market acquired a global dimension, turning into “one of the fastest-growing as well as the most
vital and important capitalist institutions” of the twentieth century (Stigum and Crescenzi 2007,
p. 209). By the mid-1980s, London accounted for 25% of global Eurocurrency assets, followed
by Tokyo (10%), Paris (7%), and offshore financial centres in the Caribbean (Bahamas, Cayman
Islands) and the Far East (Singapore and Hong Kong), with a share between 4% and 6% each
(Lewis and Davis 1987, pp. 230–231). Since then, the prefix “Euro” survived more as a remnant
of the origins of the market, than as a characterization of its geographical scope. Given the
historical importance of Eurodollars, their impact on global monetary and credit conditions, and
the extensive literature on their origins, development, and implications, this chapter will often
make special reference to them.
As a financial product, a Eurocurrency is simply a time deposits (or a certificate of deposit, that
is, a negotiable receipt of a deposit) yielding a fixed rate and with maturities ranging from
overnight to 6 months. Time deposits are a form of near (or quasi) money: short-term stores of
value that cannot be used directly as a medium of exchange to settle debts but can be very easily
converted into cash. In spite of their simplicity, Eurocurrencies represented a financial
innovation with enormous consequences. Their “essential feature” (Niehans 1984) was the
separation between the location of the issuing bank and the currency in which transactions were
denominated. This resulted in the unbundling of currency risk from political risk and more
generally in the ability to circumvent regulations imposed by national authorities. For instance,
the most important advantage of booking dollar deposits offshore was to avoid interest rate
ceilings, reserve requirements, and deposit insurance fees imposed by US authorities on deposits
held with domestic banks. By significantly reducing the costs of bank intermediation, this
allowed depositors to yield higher interest rates and borrowers to have access to cheaper short-
term loans.
Eurodollars and the other Eurocurrencies were an innovative form of wholesale banking (i.e.,
transactions with large customers – including other banks – involving large sums), which led to
the development of an international money market with a specific microstructure and
autonomous sets of interest rates. Since the 1960s, therefore, Eurocurrency markets played a
critical role as a channel for the redistribution of international liquidity. Banks’ borrowing and
lending in the Eurocurrency wholesale market was also conducive to a major structural change in
banking business: the marketization of liabilities, pioneered by US commercial banks both
domestically and internationally in the 1960s, and subsequently adopted by banks in both
industrialized and developing economies. Liability management – the active management of short-
term debt instruments with different rates, maturities, and currency of denomination to match the
size and characteristics of asset portfolios – created unprecedented scope for leverage, thus
enhancing the fast expansion of banks’ balance sheets. However, it also made banks much more
vulnerable to currency, liquidity, interest rate, and counterparty risk and facilitated the
international transmission of financial shocks
By drawing on an extensive economic and historical literature, this chapter analyses different
aspects of the historical development of Eurocurrencies and their role in the international
monetary and financial system between the late 1950s and the Great Financial Crisis of 2007–
2009. The first section “Theory” discusses alternative interpretations based on different
approaches to monetary economics. The second section “Scale” presents estimates of the size of
Eurodollar and Eurocurrency markets in the long run. The third section “Structure” describes the
microstructure of the market and its interbank segment. The fourth section “Growth” discusses
the different phases of expansion of the market and their determinants. The fifth section
“Arbitrage” analyses the relationships between rates in the Eurodollar market and other US
money markets. The sixth section “Risk” explores how risk in the Eurocurrency markets evolved
over time and analyses historical episodes of severe stress in the interbank market. The seventh
section “Political Economy” focuses on the attitude of British authorities in the emergence of
Eurodollars and the international debates of the 1970s on the multilateral regulation of
Eurocurrencies. A brief summary and final considerations are offered in the last section.