Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Corporate Governance of The Football Industry (PDFDrive) PDF

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 327

ORBIT - Online Repository of Birkbeck Institutional Theses

Enabling Open Access to Birkbecks Research Degree output

Corporate governance of the football industry - the stake-


holder approach towards the games marketisation and
professionalisation in China

http://bbktheses.da.ulcc.ac.uk/90/

Version: Full Version

Citation: Liang, Yiyong (2014) Corporate governance of the football industry -


the stakeholder approach towards the games marketisation and professionalisation
in China. PhD thesis, Birkbeck, University of London.

2014
c The Author(s)

All material available through ORBIT is protected by intellectual property law, including copyright law.
Any use made of the contents should comply with the relevant law.

Deposit guide
Contact: email
Corporate Governance of the Football Industry - the
stakeholder approach towards the game’s
marketisation and professionalisation in China

Yiyong Liang
Birkbeck College, University of London

This thesis is submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements of the degree of


Doctor of Philosophy

1
Declaration

I hereby declare that this thesis represent my own work. All sources of information have been
acknowledged by means of references including web resources.

December 2013
Yiyong Liang

2
Abstract

Sports governance has been given greater consideration over the course of the last 30 years
due primarily to the global trend of the increasing levels of sports commercialisation, and
professionalisation. Despite this, there are varieties of sport governing models existing in
different countries built against the difficult backgrounds of their own historical, cultural and
economical development. The stakeholder approach has become a trend for improving not
only corporate governance standards in many industries but also in sports worldwide. The
application of stakeholder theory to sports governance ensures sports are developed within a
necessarily transparent system and a balanced power structure. More importantly, it ensures
that decisions are made based on the interest of the majority of stakeholders and for the best
interest of sports. When this approach is applied to sport management, it helps a sports
organisation increase commercial awareness in terms of addressing the needs of different
stakeholders and thus benefits the organisation’s overall goal development and its long-term
success.

Alongside the rapid growth of the Chinese economy, sports development in China has also
gradually attracted interest from the West. With regard to Chinese football - the most popular
sport in the country, and the first sport to go the professional route under the market
economy, the Chinese football market has been seen as an untapped territory with big
business potential. It is not only attracting domestic investors but also global firms. This
thesis explores the impact of transitional changes within China’s football modernisation
process and the governance structure, by looking at the Chinese response to the football
development trend of professionalisation and commercialisation. It is a novel explorative
study on Chinese football, employing the framework of stakeholder theory to illustrate the
transitional process. The data collected from interviews with other sources available in both
Chinese and English, was qualitatively analysed and the findings provide evidence of
stakeholder relationships between the Chinese Football Association (CFA) and local football
associations (FAs), between the CFA and clubs, and between clubs and fans, which identify
modern conflicts, occurring within the current Chinese football industry during this
development phase. The discussion, based on evidence, is also able to suggest appropriate
governance responses for the Chinese game at different levels in order to face challenges
ahead.
3
Acknowledgement

Completing the thesis would not have been possible without the support of many different
people. My special thanks go to Professor John Kelly, Professor Klaus Nielsen and Mr Sean
Hamil. Their guidance and encouragement brought me through the tough journey.

I own adept of grateful to every member of my family. Their continuous supports,


encouragement and love over the course of the past years and deserves special praise for
always being there regardless how tough the process was. I always have their infinite support
to rely on.

I am also grateful to the Management Department of Birkbeck College and its members of
staff who provided professional support and personal encouragements that helped in
facilitating the completing of my thesis.

4
Content

Abbreviations ................................................................................................................ 8
Lists of figures, graphs and tables .............................................................................. 10
Chapter One: Introduction ......................................................................................... 12
1.1 Research context...................................................................................................... 15
1.1.1 Corporate governance in the football industry ............................................... 17
1.2 Theoretical context .................................................................................................. 21
1.2.1 More than a business ..................................................................................... 24
1.3 Thesis structure ....................................................................................................... 28
1.4 Concluding remarks ................................................................................................. 31
Chapter Two: Literature Review................................................................................ 32
2.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................. 32
2.2 Corporate governance theory ................................................................................... 32
2.2.1 Agency theory............................................................................................... 37
2.2.2 Stakeholder theory ........................................................................................ 45
2.3 Stakeholder theory and the football industry ............................................................ 62
2.4 Football governance and Europeanisation ................................................................ 67
2.5 The peculiarity of the football industry requires the stakeholder approach ............... 71
2.6 Summary ................................................................................................................. 74
Chapter Three: Chinese Economy and Sports Development .................................... 76
3.1 Brief history of the Chinese economy and sport development since 1949 ................. 76
3.1.1 The pre-reform era ........................................................................................ 76
3.1.2 Deng’s economy reform ................................................................................ 79
3.1.3 Summary ...................................................................................................... 81
3.2 Corporate governance in China ................................................................................ 82
3.2.1 The law and regulation framework ................................................................ 83
3.2.2 Corporate governance implementation .......................................................... 85
3.3 Brief history of Chinese sports development since 1949 .......................................... 88
3.3.1 The top-down administrative structure .......................................................... 89
3.3.2 Sports policies ............................................................................................... 91
3.3.3 Mass Participation ......................................................................................... 93
3.3.4 Elite sports .................................................................................................... 95
3.3.5 Why Chinese sports were re-constructed ....................................................... 97
3.4 Corporate governance in Chinese sports ................................................................ 105
3.4.1 The legislative framework of Chinese sport governance .............................. 106
3.5 Summary ............................................................................................................... 110
Chapter Four: Research Methodology ..................................................................... 111
4.1 Methodology and epistemology ............................................................................. 111
4.1.1 Research paradigm ...................................................................................... 114
4.1.2 Theory and research .................................................................................... 116
4.1.3 Inductive approach ...................................................................................... 117
4.1.4 Deductive approach .................................................................................... 119

5
4.2 Research strategy ................................................................................................... 120
4.2.1 Quantitative approach ................................................................................. 120
4.2.2 Qualitative approach ................................................................................... 121
4.2.3 Comparison between the quantitative and qualitative approach ................... 124
4.3 Methodology implementation ................................................................................ 126
4.4 Data analysis ......................................................................................................... 133
4.5 Summary ............................................................................................................... 137
Chapter Five: From State Amateur to Professional ................................................ 138
5.1 The background and basic infrastructure of Chinese football ................................. 138
5.1.1 The administrative structure ........................................................................ 138
5.1.2 The elite system .......................................................................................... 139
5.1.3 The league structure .................................................................................... 141
5.2 The policy shifting and the emergence of football professionalisation .................... 142
5.2.1 Political influence, sport policy and the development pattern before 1994 ... 142
5.2.2 Professionalisation ...................................................................................... 147
5.3 Modern development and current issues of the CFA .............................................. 153
5.3.1 The NPESC and the CFA ............................................................................ 153
5.3.2 Stakeholders in the Chinese football industry .............................................. 156
5.3.3 The mission of the CFA .............................................................................. 160
5.3.4 The structure of the CFA ............................................................................. 162
5.4 Development and current issues of league governance ........................................... 174
5.4.1 The governance structure ............................................................................ 174
5.4.2 The more inclusive managerial approach..................................................... 175
5.4.3 Commercial development of the League ..................................................... 176
5.5 Summary ............................................................................................................... 180
Chapter Six: Clubs’ Perspective on Football Governance ....................................... 183
6.1 Clubs’ status .......................................................................................................... 183
6.1.1 Clubs before professionalisation .................................................................. 183
6.1.2 Clubs after professionalisation .................................................................... 184
6.2 Clubs’ view on the current governance issues ........................................................ 190
6.2.1 The governing mechanisms ......................................................................... 191
6.2.2 The impact of professionalisation on clubs .................................................. 196
6.3 Summary ............................................................................................................... 218
Chapter Seven: The Players’ Perspective ................................................................. 221
7.1 The players’ status ................................................................................................. 221
7.1.1 The status before professionalisation ........................................................... 221
7.1.2 The status after professionalisation .............................................................. 224
7.2 Impact of professionalisation on players ................................................................ 225
7.2.1 Players’ wages ............................................................................................ 225
7.2.2 The transfer system and foreign players ...................................................... 227
7.2.3 The fitness test and the lifestyle................................................................... 231
7.3 Relationships with other stakeholders .................................................................... 234
7.3.1 The relationship with clubs ......................................................................... 235
7.3.2 The relationship with fans ........................................................................... 240
7.4 The players’ perspective on the game’s development ............................................. 243

6
7.4.1 The positive impression .............................................................................. 243
7.4.2 The negative impact of professionalisation .................................................. 245
7.5 The way forwards .................................................................................................. 247
7.6 Summary ............................................................................................................... 248
Chapter Eight: The Fans’ Perspective...................................................................... 250
8.1 Fandom development ............................................................................................ 250
8.2 Football fans in China ............................................................................................ 252
8.2.1 Fans in the pre-communist era..................................................................... 252
8.2.2 Fan development in the New China ............................................................. 254
8.3 Fan culture............................................................................................................. 257
8.3.1 Fans’ attachment to clubs ............................................................................ 258
8.4 The Fan/club relationship ...................................................................................... 261
8.4.1 The dependent position ............................................................................... 263
8.4.2 The independent position ............................................................................ 266
8.5 The fans’ perception of the football industry .......................................................... 273
8.5.1 The governance structure ............................................................................ 274
8.5.2 Fans’ impression of players ......................................................................... 277
8.5.3 Fans’ concern about the current development problems............................... 280
8.6 Summary ............................................................................................................... 282
Chapter Nine: Conclusion ......................................................................................... 283
9.1 Discussion ............................................................................................................. 283
9.2 The way forward ................................................................................................... 289
9.3 Summary ............................................................................................................... 292
Bibliography: ............................................................................................................. 296
List of Interviews ....................................................................................................... 325

7
Abbreviations
AFC – Asian Football Confederation
CCP – the Chinese Communist Party
CCTV – the Chinese Central Television
CFA – the Chinese Football Association
CFIDC – China Football Industry Development Company
CFMC – Chinese Football Management Centre
COSCO – China Ocean Shipping Company
CSL – Chinese Super League
CSLC – the Chinese Super League Company
CSR - Corporate Social Responsibility
CSRC – the China Securities Regulatory Commission
DFL – German Football League
DRC – Dispute and Resolution Chamber
ECA – the European Club Association
ECF – the European Club Forum
ECJ – the European Court of Justice
EII – Earth Island Institute
EPL – English Premier League
EU – the European Union
FIFA - Fédération Internationale de Football Association
FIFPro - the Fédération Internationale des Associations de Footballeurs Professionnels
GANEFO – Games of Newly Emerging Forces
GFL – the Great Leap Forward
IFRS – International Financial Reporting Standards
IMG - International Management Group
IOC – the International Olympic Committee
LC - the League Committee
NBA – the National Basketball Association
NPESC – National Physical Education and Sports Commission

8
OECD – Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
NGO – None Governmental Organisation
PCC – the Professional Cycling Council
PFA - the Professional Footballers’ Association
PLC - Public Limited Company
PRC – People’s Republic of China
PRP - Performance-Related Pay
SB - Sports Bureau
SEM – the Socialist Education Movement
SETC – the State Economic and Trade Commission
SGSA – the State General Sports Administration
SLC – the Super League Committee
SOE – State Owned Enterprise
UCL – the International Cycling Union
UEFA – the Union of European Football Associations

9
Lists of figures, graphs and tables
Figures
2-1 Stakeholders’ relationship model................................................................................ .......54
2-2 Stakeholder influences model......................................................................................56
2-3 Stakeholders’ & firms’ managerial strategies……………………………………………...58
3-1 Chronological chart – Economic & political policy…………………………………………….81
3-2 Chronological chart – Chinese sports’ policy development ………………………………………97
5-1 The elite training & selection system……………………….........................................................................140
5-2 Chronological chart – Key football policy development ………………………………………...153
5-3 Chronological chart – key AFC & FIFA events that had a major impact on Chinese
football development ..........................................................................................................................................154
5-4 Stakeholder map of the Chinese football industry………………………………….160
5-5 The structure of the CFA……………………………………………………………………………...............163
5-6 Development trends of the CFA /local FA relationship and the CFA/Club relationship …....167
5-7 The CFA governance transition and stakeholder influence……………………………………172
5-8 The league governance transition and stakeholder influence …………………………..………179
6-1 The clubs-CFA network configuration and firm response ……………………………………...202
6-2 Club/the CFA resource dependence relationship and club influence strategies…......204
6-3 The development pattern of the clubs/country relationship ……………………………….........207
6-4 The development pattern of the Club/player relationship ……………………………………...208
6-5 The club/player relationship development pattern…………………………………………………...211
6-6 The development pattern of club/ fan relationship………………………..……………………213
7-1 The pyramid structure of elite development ………………………………………………..…………..222
7-2 Players’ influences over clubs………………………………………………………………………………….236
7-3 The player/club relationship………………………………………………………...............................237
7-4 The player/fan relationship…………………………………………………………………………………...241
8-1 The fan associations/clubs relationship …………………………………………………………………264
8-2 The fan association/club relationships………………………………………………………………….265
8-3 Fan associations’ influences towards clubs……………………………………………………………..270

10
8-4 The development pattern of the clubs/country relationship ……………………….…………...276
8-5 The average match attendance per match……………………………………..….279

Graphs
Graph 6.1Percentage of clubs focal performance………………………………................................187
Graph 6.2 Percentage of clubs’ ownership structure in professional leagues ……….….188
Graph 6.3 Percentage of clubs with proper business plans in place …………………………...190
Graph 6.4 Percentage of clubs who believe in benefits through a wider range of revenue
redistribution…………………………………………………………………………..............................................................195
Graph 6.5 Percentage of clubs communicate with new media interaction………………….…215

Tables

3-1 All sports management centres under the SGSA……………………………………………………….90


3-2 The New Deli 1982 Asian Games Medal Table..................................................................................102
3-3 The LA 1984 Olympic Games Medal Table ……………………………………………………………102
3-4 The Beijing 1990 Asian Games Medal Table ………………………………………………………….103
3-5 The Barcelona 1992 Olympic Games Medal Table…………………………………………………103
4-1 Fundamental differences between quantitative and qualitative research strategies...124
4-2 Characteristics of quantitative and qualitative research.............................................125
5-1 League sponsors…………………………………………………………………………………………………….…178
7-1 The transfer figures from 1995-1997………………………………...……………….…………………….227
7-2 The 1999 season transfer list of mismatches…………………………………………….……………...228

11
Chapter One: Introduction
Corporate governance can be conveniently understood as the set of processes, customs,
policies, laws, and institutions that affect how a corporation or company is directed,
administered, and controlled (Leusse et al 2009). Such consideration also takes into
account the relationships existing among the many stakeholders involved and the
objectives for which the corporation is governed. Corporate governance and its associated
concerns had no bearing on Chinese industry management before its national economic
reform. The subject was only discussed when the Chinese stock market was established.
In China, corporate governance has emerged as a popular topic and is the subject of both
political and economic debate.

This thesis examines the concept of corporate governance in the context of Chinese
football, with regard to how the sport is governed in China for the purpose of gaining a
clearer understanding than previously existed on the governance of Chinese sports and its
football industry. This study seeks to contribute to the development of stakeholder theory
as an important analytical framework in social science studies, especially in relation to
countries with emerging economies. The wider background to football reform in China
has been the “Open Door” policy and the economic reform that was introduced from the
early 1980s. The government’s intention has been to make all state-owned enterprises
more effective and efficient than they previously were by gradually introducing Western
enterprise methods with a capitalist market approach (Chen 2003). Since football
possesses the greatest potential for market value of all sports, it was chosen as the first to
undergo Western style reform. The top league was made professional in 19941. Unlike
other Chinese sports, football became subject to new and different sets of rules, enjoying
more relaxed state control and marketing-orientated flexibility. In 1999, professional

1
The market elements have been introduced into the Chinese game in the early 1980s when the
marketisation process started. However, fundamental changes happened in 1994 when the top league teams
started to play the Western-style home-away formation and the teams’ state ownership gradually
transferred to non-state ownership. The state amateur model of the game became a Western-style
professional model. This study uses the term “professionalisation” to refer to the development period of
marketisation from 1994 onwards in order to keep the consistency with Chinese literature and existing
Chinese football literature in English.

12
clubs were required to adopt a business model and to become independent companies
with clear indications of their ownership structures. Clubs as companies are subject to
both the Company Law and the regulations set down by the football governing bodies.
Such ‘professionalisation’, combining the marketing approach and commercial activities,
led to the further development of the football industry.

Traditionally, corporate governance places emphasis on two aspects: management and


control. Studies have generally focused on interest alignment between primary
participants of the corporate structure, such as shareholders, management and boards of
directors. More recently, corporate governance concerns have shifted from being
shareholder-centric towards a more balanced approach (Donaldson & Preston, 1995).
Since other stakeholders can in many ways exert a significant influence on a corporation,
their interests are afforded greater consideration during decision-making. Furthermore, in
modern business management, corporate governance goes beyond merely complying
with the appropriate rules; it is also about establishing mechanisms and supporting
institutions to ensure the healthy development and long-term sustainability of firms
(Harrison & Freeman, 1999). The concept has undoubtedly entered the philosophy of the
modern football industry worldwide.

In Europe, there are already serious concerns over the governance of the European
football industry, especially towards the apex of the football pyramid, which has
“developed into a ‘business’ that has increased the tendency towards legal disputes and
cultural clashes, as a result, football now exists in an environment of legal
uncertainty”(Arnaut, 2006, p.iv). In China, the model for Chinese football
professionalisation has followed that of Europe - especially at the top level, where elite
teams have developed into club companies. This transformation has also led the Chinese
football industry into similar development uncertainty. This environment, together with
increasing commercialism, represents a threat to football’s long-term stability and
success; it is therefore necessary that proper governance of the Chinese football industry
be established in order to achieve legal certainty and financial sustainability. Moreover,
such good governance can only be achieved through the joint efforts and strong

13
commitments of all stakeholders. The major contribution of this study stands as the fresh
analytical insights have been generated by the application of stakeholder theory into the
changing behaviour of different stakeholders and development of their relationships
during the process of Chinese football professionalisation. Understanding the different
needs of different stakeholders is essential for both governing bodies and clubs to
maintain accountability and healthy development, and now it is time for these to be acted
upon.

The overall aim of this study is to provide an insight into the corporate governance of the
Chinese football industry after its transformation from the state amateur model to a
Western-style professional model; to identify some problems within the current Chinese
football industry through research; and consequently to make constructive suggestions for
the improvement of its governance. This mainly qualitative interview-based study is
designed to gain a better understanding of the Chinese football industry through different
stakeholders’ perspectives. It focuses upon the process of football professionalisation,
with particular emphasis upon the overriding research question: “How has
professionalisation impacted on the governance and development of the football
industry in China?” This overriding question has been divided into six sub-questions,
which have been discussed with different stakeholder groups separately during the
research process, in an attempt to explain some perplexing features of Chinese football:
1. What are the organisational structures of the Chinese FA and the Super League, and
how have they facilitated the development of an increasingly professional football
industry?
2. How does the Chinese FA balance the needs of the professional football industry and
grassroots development?
3. How do professional football clubs manage relationships with multiple stakeholders?
4. How has professionalism impacted the relationship between supporters and football
clubs?
5. How has increasing professionalism affected players?
6. What are the key governance challenges facing the Chinese football industry?

14
In order to answer the above questions, a number of practical principles provide useful
benchmarks, which are set as different themes for data analysis. Such as: managerial
approach, conflict of interest, financial dependency, stakeholder relationships, and
systematic sustainability. Moreover, the stakeholder framework serves as the theoretical
guide to analysing the legitimacy of key stakeholders, their relationships with, and
influences on, each other, and how these relationships have been managed by different
stakeholders from their own perspective. With the unique accessibility the researcher
gained, coupled with the stakeholder framework, this research offers an original
contribution and insights to the empirical studies of corporate governance in the Chinese
football industry in which very little research has been done in either China or the West.

1.1 Research context


There has been renewed interest in corporate governance in both the theory and the
practice of modern corporations since mismanagement and poor practice caused the
bankruptcies of a series of high-profile firms in the US, most notably, the collapse of the
Enron Corporation in 2001. Similar corporate failures have also happened in the UK,
such as the bankruptcy of Barings Bank, leading the US Government to pass the
Sarbanes-Oxley Act in 20022, and the UK Government to produce a series of reports in
order to counter mismanagement and financial fraud and to improve governance
standards. Despite legislative efforts, governance problems have been highlighted once
more by the recent global credit crunch, triggered by the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers
in September 2008 and the Madoff scandal of the same year, which showed the
importance of and real need for appropriate governance in today’s modern industries and
financial services. Corporate governance mechanisms are designed to reduce business
risk, to counter managerial inefficiency and to provide systems that are transparent to all
stakeholders in order to establish public confidence. The principles of corporate
governance good-practice include trust, integrity, responsibility, accountability, mutual
respect, effectiveness, and efficiency.

2
It is a US federal law set new standards for all US public company boards, management and public
accounting firms after a number of major corporate and accounting scandals, enacted on July 30, 2002.

15
Corporate governance is an important aspect of modern industrial management where
most research has been focused on conventional industries and stock-listed corporations.
The sports industry has thrived on commercial development. However, there is a danger
of over-commercialisation which can undermine the integrity and social value of sport.
The lengthy debate over the peculiarity of the sport industry, especially in league sports,
coupled with heavy discussions on the way sport has been commercialised globally over
the last two or three decades, has shown up particular concerns on the corporate
governance issues in the sport industry (Walters 2007). For instance, baseball, basketball
and ice hockey in the US, and football in Europe. Good governance practices in modern
sports management have been recognised as the necessary mechanism to ensure what is
needed for financial sustainability and the sport’s integrity (Hamil 1999, Hamil et al
2000). Notably, the Union of European Football Associations (UEFA)’s financial fair
play rules kick in at the 2011/2 season, and address clubs’ unbalanced spending power
and restrains some clubs’ irresponsible behavior. It is promoting greater financial
responsibility amongst clubs, and the health development of the football industry.
Currently, there are some different governance models of professional sport available in
North America and Europe, each model having been developed over a period of time
with its own characteristics.

Because of the high profile of sport in people’s social life and what appears to be a
successful adoption of sports commercialisation in both America and Europe, sports
governance has become a subject of wide concern, especially the concerns of authorities
and sports governing bodies. Football is so significant in terms of its worldwide
popularity, with huge amounts of money involved at professional level, that the
commercialisation seen during the last 20 years has changed the game to reach an even
more significant level not only in Europe but also in the rest of the World. The game has
been run very differently compared to 20 years ago, with too much money at stake, and
with many stakeholders holding serious doubts over the appropriateness of the current
governing structure and its ability to protect the game from losing touch with its
traditional roots.

16
Professional sports leagues consist of several individual teams or clubs. At the top level
clubs not only operate as individual firms, but also collectively act as cartels within their
industries (Sloane 1971). Especially in Europe, a sports club is often operated as both a
commercial entity and a local community hub simultaneously. Modern sports governance
creates a number of questions: Do sports need to be treated differently compared to other
conventional industries? Is commercialisation a good thing for sports’ development in
terms of its healthy development and long-term financial sustainability? Corporate
governance in sports is about to set up mechanisms in order to balance its social and
sports roles to protect its integrity from the inevitable trend of commercial development.
Joes Luis Arnaunt (2006 p.iv), Chair of Independent Europe Sport Review stated: “Sport
governing bodies must understand and accept the requests of political institutions towards
sport governing bodies regarding the need for proper governance”. In reality, European
Union (EU), UEFA and Fédération Internationale de Football Association (FIFA) are
working together for better governance in football, at not only international level, but also
national and club levels, which indicates the need to protect football’s sporting nature and
social functions from increasing business orientation.

1.1.1 Corporate governance in the football industry


The contemporary literature on corporate governance in professional football draws
attention to many areas - political interference, game regulators, revenue generation and
distribution, competitive balance, investors’ behaviour, management structure, fan
involvement and so on. In the last two decades, development trend of professional game
particular at the top level, it has become more of a business and less of a social institution.
Therefore, corporate governance on the subject of football development has raised
serious concerns from some economists, government officers and industry professionals.
In particular, the issues of commercial approach, protecting the game’s integrity,
financial sustainability, traditional value, and long-term healthy development. As a highly
commercialised entertainment industry with enormous amounts of money involved in
today’s professional game on a global scale, amongst the top European competitions and
clubs, establishing a transparent system and better business practice within the football

17
industry is required, as The State of the Games (Football Governance Research Centre
2005, p.X) explained: “Good governance is particularly important for football clubs
given the opaque world in which they operate, with football agents and others often
trying to avoid openness and accountability”.

On a macro level, corporate governance is a key element in enhancing investor


confidence, promoting competitiveness, and improving economic growth. On a micro
level, corporate governance is important promoting football not only as a high profile
social institution but also as an exciting entertainment industry. A transparent governing
system with a balanced approach towards all stakeholders enhances the game’s sport
value and social credibility at the same time as fulfilling the game’s ‘fair play’ spirit.

The prevalent view of football commercialisation and the establishment of the English
Premier League has been the greediness of top clubs exploiting the game and driving its
spirit away from the traditional values. The real danger is the ever-expanding financial
gap between the rich Premier League clubs and the rest of the Football League clubs. As
this continues, football starts to lose its cohesion, causing serious damage to the integrity
of the game as a whole (Hamil et al 2000; Lago et al 2006).

Despite football being described as the “the people’s game”, under today’s business
approach, “the people” are considered ‘customers’, the game more as the ‘product’ and
the club a ‘brand’. The over-development of football commercialisation has led to the
over-exploitation of its “customers”. Traditional fans are priced out, undermining the
values of football clubs as a community based social institution. Hamil (1999) recognises
the danger with the current commercial approach as it can erode the fans’ loyalty and
football’s social value therefore putting the game at risk.

Another element which is shaping the modern day view of the commercial football
industry is learning from crises which to offer its cultural readjustment (Elliott & Smith,
2006). Obviously, any physical unexpected disaster can be seen as a potential crisis for
the club or even the industry (e.g. the Hillsborough disaster in 1989), and similarly, a

18
firm’s underachievement and financial mismanagement can also be viewed as a crisis for
the organisation. Ultimately, it affects its stability and sustainability. However, by the
same token, a ‘crisis’ also provides opportunities for regulators to adjust or change
regulations in order to protect the game’s healthy status and to prevent incidents in the
future. Crises such as Bradford in 1985 and Hillsborough in 1989 forced public inquiries
and brought in government intervention. For instance, the Taylor Report resulted in
millions of pounds being spent on modernising grounds in England and Scotland. As a
result, stadiums became safer and football related crimes were reduced. Coupled with the
introduction of the Football Spectators Act (1989), all such efforts made a positive impact
to bring the game back from decline.

With this in mind, if stadium disasters, hooligans and the Taylor Report were the
triggering events for the modern commercialisation on the English game, in the Chinese
case, the triggering event was a long period of underachievement by the national team
which precipitated a management crisis within the CFA, and eventually led to football
reform, in other words, the advent of professionalisation.

China being one of the new emerging economic powers, not only its economic transition
but also its sports development experience radical changes, largely due to the increasing
influences of commercialisation. In terms of a research context, this thesis serves the
purpose not only of revealing the corporate governance structure of Chinese football and
of filling the research gap between corporate governance and the Chinese football
industry, but also of applying the stakeholder approach as the analytical framework to
bring fresh analytical insights to contribute to the field of Chinese corporate governance
study.

The concept of corporate governance was not introduced in China until the 1980s, when
its economic reform really took off. Clarke (2003) suggests Chinese corporate
governance tends to cover systematical relationships amongst all parties by its Chinese
definition, usually seeing shareholders as a particular important group and focusing
almost exclusively on agency problems. Although Chinese government adopted the

19
Western style of governance framework for state owned enterprises, its agency problems
are quite different in contrast to firms in other developed market economies. The real
goal of Chinese corporate governance was never solely concentrated on maximising
profits for shareholders; its initial aim was to make state owned enterprises more efficient
and effective. In other words, by using a market approach whilst at the same time trying
to keep state control over important industries.

China’s Company Law (1994) was certainly set to promote non-state sectors and
enterprise, nonetheless, corporatisation did not necessarily mean privatization. The state
needs firms to run more effectively, and at the same time it also needs firms’ help to keep
employment levels at an acceptable standard. Generally speaking, the state withdraws
some of its ownership from certain industries, but is committed to maintain control over
important sectors. Therefore, in many respects, the Chinese style of corporatisation is
very likely to conflict with shareholders’ interests.

Against a background of general economic reform, football reform in China was


influenced in a similar fashion. However, the football industry has its own specificity
compared to other conventional businesses, and thereby a narrow sense of agency
approach would not have been appropriate to define the complexity of the industry’s
development. Even though the marketing approach has been applied since the early
1980s, and was followed by the further creation of Club Companies in 2003, the ultimate
governing framework of the industry has been kept largely unchanged. There are a few
articles on Chinese football in English, such as, Five case studies – Algeria, China,
England, France and Japan by Amara et al (2005); Football in new China by Dong &
Mangan (2001). Both of them are quite chronologically descriptive of the development of
football professionalisation, even though they outline some sports management
frameworks, most of their data is nonetheless secondary and mainly comes from other
articles published in Chinese or in newspapers, providing a rather shallow perceptions
with managerial and governance issues give less cause for concern.

20
There remains a lack of analytical literature on China’s football governance, possibly for
a variety of reasons. Firstly, the weakness of Chinese football on the World stage results
in less perceived interest in the West. Secondly, corporate governance has not, until
recently, been addressed in China. Corporate governance issues are related predominately
to state owned enterprises and listed companies, and there is rarely any research looking
at the Chinese sport and the football industry from a view of point of the concept of
corporate governance. Thirdly, articles about Chinese football both in the West and China
are mainly descriptive, few of them going beyond the phenomenal surface. Despite
football professionalisation having been introduced for over a decade, football
governance lacks progress. As a result, there is a real need for having more research done
on the subject of corporate governance in the Chinese football industry from various
angles, especially as the current Chinese football market is getting more attractive for
many global businesses. This research employs a corporate governance concept and
stakeholder theory framework, looking at different perspectives from different
stakeholder groups in order to unveil the complexity of the corporate governance of the
Chinese football industry. It is not only to fill the research gap on the subject
aforementioned but also to provide a better understanding and an in-depth exploration of
Chinese football.

1.2 Theoretical context


Blair (1998) sees the shareholder-management nexus as important, however, corporate
governance should not solely focus on the power relationships between shareholders and
management, since it is not the only relationship within the corporation that is important
to wealth creation. As a social institution, club management do not solely concentrate on
shareholders’ profit maximisation like some other corporate management models do,
football clubs maximise their utility, coupled with the fact that the football industry has
its own peculiarities, means that, agency theory is relatively narrowly applied to explain
the complexity of the football phenomenon. By contrast, stakeholder theory addresses the
principle of who or what really counts, and the stakeholder approach also explains the
complexity of relationships amongst different stakeholders. It explains the state of the

21
game in China better. Moreover, the football industry has to reconcile its sporting nature
and business performance, which requires stakeholder management and stakeholder
management strategy.

Steurer (2006) argues that stakeholder theory has most commonly been used from a
corporate-centric perspective in the research field, and in the case of Chinese corporate
governance, most of the studies concentrate on state owned enterprises and listed big
companies with a predominate agency theory approach (Clarke, 2003). In the matter of
Chinese sport, there are some English articles and books available, however, few of them
place an emphasis on the concept of corporate governance and management, never mind
a stakeholder theory approach towards its football industry. As mentioned before, this
research is not only can fill the void of corporate governance in the Chinese football
industry, but also to adopt a different approach – a stakeholder approach towards the
corporate governance in China, each element itself being able to demonstrate a major
contribution to the research field, and a combination of the two plus further developed
stakeholder analytical models making this study an even more sound research project.

The agency approach focuses on aligning the interests of principals and agents, reducing
agency costs through mechanisms being the priority for a firm, with a strong focus on a
single target – shareholders’ profit maximisation. In the field of sports and the football
industry, clubs not only have commercial targets but also have sport and social roles to
fill. For example, even given that clubs are limited companies, the FA still took an
initiative to protect the sport’s heart of the game to ensure that the clubs did not become
solely profit-oriented vehicles3. Due to the fact that they often operate as both business
entities and local community hubs simultaneously, clubs are working on utility
maximisation rather than shareholder profit maximisation. A stakeholder approach
provides more comprehensive analysis than just a single target of profit maximisation, as
it fits the overall profile of the football industry making it even more important for
football clubs. The stakeholder approach helps the management of clubs to think of the

3
FA’s rule 34 regulated the game until the late 1990s, it restricted the payment of club directors and the
dividends of shareholders.

22
full range of communities from whom they need support and loyalty. Obviously, the need
for loyalty from across the range of stakeholders, does not mean just from shareholders.

Steurer (2006) states a corporate perspective emphasis on how corporations deal with
other stakeholders within its networks; a stakeholder perspective focuses on how
individual stakeholders or stakeholder groups try to influence corporations. In terms of
the football industry, corporations are clubs. With the high social profile the industry now
enjoys, football is certainly more influential in a social context for the common good and
social responsibility, an influence which stakeholder theory also recognises and reflects.
Furthermore, a stakeholder approach offers a broader set of relationships rather than the
narrow set of economic relationships which an agency approach does (Harrison &
Freeman 1999). Therefore, stakeholder theory has the potential of being as an integrating
theme in terms of how the business and social worlds interact, making it an appropriate
framework for conducting research in the football industry.

In the commercial environment, an ideal position for a conventional firm is to be a


monopoly in its industry in order to dominate the market. On the contrary, football clubs
rely on each other heavily to be able to function well; clubs operate as cartels within a
league framework to produce their joint product – football matches, a monopoly position
is impossible for a football club to achieve (Quirk & Fort 1992, Mason 1999, Neale
1964). The interdependent relationship amongst participants in league sports is an
important characteristic of the football industry, and a stakeholder approach offers better
positions and multiple angles to look at the interdependent relationships amongst clubs,
from both the competitive side and the co-operative side, in order to highlight the
peculiarity of the industry. Although a monopoly position is impossible for a club to
achieve, league competitions can be dominated by the few big clubs. A high level of
dominance produces unbalanced league competition; unbalanced league competition
reduces the outcome of uncertainty, which can arguably deterring supporters attending
matches (Football Governance Research Centre, 2003, 2004, 2005). In order to protect
competitive balance and to maintain a certain degree of outcome uncertainty, various
mechanisms have been employed in both American and European league sports. For

23
example, the draft system in the National Basketball Association (NBA) and the revenue
redistribution scheme in the English Premiership4.

More arguments have been raised recently about sport commercialisation and
globalisation, there is a need for a better understanding of how professional sports are
organised. Football has become a multi-million pound business; however, as a social
institution, football clubs have significant social roles which go beyond sports
performance, business profitability and organisational efficiency. Clubs are regarded as
representationally symbolic of geographical locations. Relationship between clubs and
their local communities demonstrate social bonds, and clubs can play important roles in
the development of local identity, culture and a shared memory of living (Morrow, 2003).
Therefore, the overall integrity of the game and stakeholder values should be valued even
more. Morrow (2000) argues that the stakeholder concept has greater relevance for the
football industry than for more conventional businesses because of the particular features
of certain football club stakeholders, especially their demands for accountability.

Does the modern game run to accommodate and be held accountable for meeting the
goals of multiple stakeholders? As Campbell (1997) argues stakeholder thinking should
not be assessed by what value has passed amongst stakeholders; management should
always make the company’s purpose clear to both shareholders and other stakeholders
before they commit themselves to the company. In the case of this study, to adopt a
stakeholder approach shows the researcher recognises the multi objectives of the football
clubs and the peculiarity of the football industry.

1.2.1 More than a business


In order to understand professional football, it is necessary to understand the relationship
between a club and its various stakeholders. Due to clubs do not pursue a solely sports
goal, they also pursue social goals which should be reflected in their governance process

4
The draft system gives teams with the worst record in the pervious season a better chance of picking order
for rookie players.

24
and business practices. As a result, stakeholder thinking is an essential element for a
modern club to function as both a commercial firm and a social institution simultaneously.

In England, most football clubs are private owned limited companies, and commonly
owned by local businessmen. Owners and their clubs tend to have shared the same roots
and culture, and originate from the same community. In the past, a club’s profitability
also came second to its traditional values. Both fan and club owner alike pledged their
support to the club above all else.

However, in 1983 Tottenham Hotspur, with the FA’s consent, became a public owned
company. The FA was accused of being irresponsible and shortsighted by some observers
after giving the green light. Tottenham’s floatation transformed football clubs in England
and the Public Limited Company (PLC) ownership emerged.

Football has changed beyond recognition since the 1990s when TV money poured in.
Critics (Conn, 2007, Wheel, 2011) believe the commercialisation of football development
has gone too far - clubs have lost touch with their communities, priced out ordinary fans
and damaged the traditional value of social cohesion and inclusion which football sought
to uphold.

In Spain, many clubs are owned by members. Real Madrid and Barcelona are the most
well-know of the clubs where members democratically elect their presidents. Smaller
clubs like Athletic Bilbao, are also owned by their members. In addition, in the case of
Barcelona, the club represents a traditional Catalan value of intolerance of dictators
throughout history. Barcelona’s famous slogan “more than a club” clearly indicates the
centrality of higher social values.

In Germany, the German FA maintains a policy that members of every Bundesliga club
own at least 51 percent of their club. This ensures a connection between clubs and their
local communities. Recently, league administrators voted to continue their ban on foreign
ownership of clubs, therefore, the German league will continually remain a domestic

25
affair. German Football League (DFL) president Dr Reinhard Rauball stated “The
Bundesliga thrives on its stability and balance, the protection of the competitions must be
maintained” (The Independent, 2008).

In Italy, clubs are owned by businessmen who see clubs as prestigious assets reflecting
their business images and representing their own personalities. Clubs have a far greater
sense of materialism. Clubs such as Juventus and Milan are owned by corporations
controlled by the Agnelli and Berlusconi families respectively. From their points of view
football clubs are part of their lives and social images – making the clubs too valuable to
sell.

The ownership structures of football clubs in Spain, Germany and Italy would make any
acquisition difficult. By contrast, ownership models of English football clubs make
English clubs easy targets, especially with big TV money ‘sweetening the deal’. The
recent arrival of foreign businessmen in the Premiership shows a clear indication of this.
The UEFA President Michel Platini has been aware of the phenomena and has said: “We
are the guardians of European football. Our role is to protect the game from business”.
“The US businessmen, buying your clubs today. They want to make money. I say, ‘take
care’” (Conn, 2007). Platitni’s warning signaled the need to protect the true value of
English football and its clubs as a social institution.

When the Glazer family bought Manchester United in 2005, the blatant business-like
approach caused a rather hostile reception from the fans. Many fans believe that
Manchester United, whilst under the Glazer family, cannot represent the club’s traditional
values, and, as a result, the club will never be same again. Many who felt disillusioned
and betrayed by the loss of the club walked out Old Trafford and formed a new club (FC
United of Manchester) in order to represent the true value of their own culture. In many
respects this goes to show that the clubs embody stronger social values and relationships
than they do big business structures.

26
In the end it appears that football is not only to do with the actual game, but its social
value as well. When Randy Lerner took over Aston Villa, he adopted a different approach,
and by showing a respect for the club’s heritage and community value, the fans shared a
common platform with him. As a result, he had a much smoother start at Villa Park.

In terms of modern industry management, agency theory and stakeholder theory are the
most popular approaches under the corporate governance framework. Agency theory
concentrates on management and control, as well as interest alignment between owners
and agents; stakeholder theory concentrates on relationships amongst a corporation and
its stakeholders, which has broader concerns covering the wider interests of all
stakeholders rather than the narrow interest alignment between owners and management.
Campbell (1997) argues that purpose being something independent of shareholder value
thinking or stakeholder value thinking, business purpose defines business model, and has
implications for each stakeholder. Football is a modern industry, possessing its own
peculiarities, whereby clubs are corporate entities with multiple objectives. A narrow
agency approach would not explain well either the complexity of the club company
model nor the relationships amongst stakeholders within the industry.

A football club is more than a club, a football business is more than a business. As Platini
said:

“That is my philosophy, to protect the identity of the clubs. I like the system where Real
Madrid and Barcelona belong to the members, the socios. The fans are the identity and
history of the club and in England you have great clubs, great fans. If the money ever
goes the new owners will leave while the fans will stay. It is for the FA and the
government to do what they can to protect the clubs” (Conn, 2007).

The uniqueness of the football industry defines the way football management is different
when compared to other conventional businesses. Stakeholder theory not only addresses
the multiple objectives of football clubs, but also takes a modest approach towards a
better understanding of complex relationships amongst different stakeholders within the

27
industry. In this case, a meaningful insight into the Chinese football industry and
complexity of relationships amongst stakeholders can only be achieved through the
stakeholder analysis framework. The research looks at the Chinese football industry from
the perspectives of different stakeholder groups namely: the CFA, clubs, players and
supporters, taking the research to address the complex relationship amongst them, as seen
from their own points of view, to avoid a simple corporate-centric approach. Moreover, it
provides analysis and fresh insights beyond narrow management issues such as
organisational efficiency and effectiveness.

1.3 Thesis structure


This thesis consists of nine chapters. Chapter One sets out the main aim, introduces the
overriding question, and presents an overviews of the structure of the whole project as
well as to define its major contribution. The research context gives a general sense of the
topic by gradually introducing the research subject - what exactly this research is working
on, and why it is important. This chapter also unveils the theoretical context of the
research by illustrating the peculiarity of professional sports, especially the peculiarity in
league sports and the football industry. Then it justifies the question: why is stakeholder
theory an appropriate approach to conduct research into the football industry generally as
well as into the Chinese football industry?

Chapter Two starts to review corporate governance literature in general by looking at its
two popular theories, namely agency theory and stakeholder theory. The starting point
aims to introduce the modern management concept of corporate governance, providing
general ideas on the question: What do corporate governance theories mean to
conventional industries? The chapter places an emphasis on the stakeholder theory in
order to lay down a foundation for later actual implementation. The review also tries to
link the research questions to literature, it then narrows down to further justify why
stakeholder theory is an appropriate framework for conducting research within the
football industry, which shows how research questions flow from the account of
stakeholder theory.

28
Chapter Three outlines the general background of Chinese economy development, and
then it narrows down to focus on the areas of corporate governance in China and its sport
governance in order to illustrate the research gap between corporate governance and the
Chinese football industry. The purpose of this approach is to review corporate
governance from a broad general concept to a particular Chinese concept as well as to a
specific field of Chinese sport and Chinese football. Through a top down review, readers
are not only helped to see a gradually more specific research field of literature
systematically, but also provided with an easy way of identifying the research gap
between corporate governance and the Chinese football industry. Ultimately, the aim is to
highlight the need for conducting research on the topic of corporate governance in the
Chinese football industry.

Chapter Four is the methodology chapter, it starts from epistemology - a branch of


philosophy and its direct Greek meaning is the theory of knowledge. Epistemology is
devoted to use a scientific way to find knowledge through research, which has to be
guided by theory. It primarily addresses such questions: What is knowledge? How has
knowledge been acquired? And also addresses what we know and how we know what we
know? The chapter starts reviewing research philosophy from three dominant views in
literature: positivism, interpretivism and realism, to outline the subject of any research
approach that flows from the research philosophy (Saunders et al 2003). In terms of a
theoretical approach towards research, within a theoretical framework, this chapter
compares and contrasts the inductive and deductive research approaches in order to
demonstrate a clear understanding. Then it steps on to the next layer - research strategy,
quantitative and qualitative approaches within the strategy framework. The researcher
gives a brief overview of both approaches, describing their advantages and disadvantages
as well as the reasons for using them during research. The discussion of research strategy
is a presentation of the researcher’s acquired knowledge of the research process at the
same time as showing the credentials of the researcher to undertake this project. Data
validity, reliability, and limitation is the section that characterises the process of data
collection and illustrates the importance of obtaining unbiased research. Moreover, this

29
chapter also explains the details of the researcher’s own methods and the whole process
of data collection and analysis. Finally, it demonstrates how the research is underpinned
by philosophical, theoretical, and methodological consideration when it employing its
particular methods, in other words, how this research is supported by the application of
scientific methods.

Chapter Five reviews the Chinese sports system and its structure as well as its football
development before professionalisation. It gives a general background on Chinese sports
management and control since the communist takeover, and within this structure, the
football system and its development model are emphasised. This background is a very
important part for understanding the trend of later professional development in the
Chinese football industry, providing historical information on Chinese sports and the
football infrastructure as well as giving useful context for discovering answers to the
main research question itself. In this chapter, studies are also carried out into the top
hierarchy of football governance, mainly the CFA, and local FAs by analysing the CFA’s
dual governing status, development strategies, decision-making process and showing the
governing insights. From a stakeholder’s point of view, it reflects the governing bodies’
perspective of the game’s development.

Chapter Six provides a club’s perspective of corporate governance in the Chinese football
industry and works on the detailed questions derived from the overriding question.
Analysis is based on data that is mainly taken from interviews with the senior club
managers, supplemented by other sources to illustrate club governance and management
strategies. The analytical focus includes operational practices, understood through
looking at the operational design of clubs and goals; the decision-making process by
looking at their ownership structures; conflicts of interest and accountability by looking
at other stakeholders’ involvement. From a stakeholder’s point of view, it represents the
view from the clubs.

Chapter Seven is angled from the perspective of players to look at governance and the
football industry. Analysis is based on interviews with current and former professional

30
players to show analytical insights of the game from the players’ perspective. It delves
into the players’ relationship with other stakeholders and how players manage their
relationships with different stakeholders given the current structure of the industry.

Chapter Eight is from the supporters’ perspective to explore the industry and its
governance. Analysis is based on interviews with leaders from different fan associations.
This chapter explains the insights how fans are organised differently and how they
manage their relationships with other stakeholders according to their own circumstances.

Finally, Chapter Nine concludes research findings and provides discussion of how the
stakeholder theory approach and research findings help to answer the research question.
It offers some predictions and some suggestions based on findings.

1.4 Concluding remarks


The stakeholder theory approach argues that an ideal corporate structure should deliver
value to its stakeholders in order to be in a healthy, sustainable condition. Recent studies
on the subject of corporate social responsibility have paid more attention to the
stakeholder approach, nonetheless, much more theoretical and empirical works still
remains to be done, especially in new emerging market countries. Corporate governance
in a Chinese context has been studied only recently, and these studies have concentrated
mainly on agency theory and listed companies operating in conventional businesses, with
the arguments focussing only on the appropriate structure of corporate governance.
Despite the fact that the researcher spotted the absence of corporate governance studies
into Chinese sport and the stakeholder approach to the football industry, we still need to
bear in mind that China is a new emerging market economy and its marketing orientated
economic status has not yet been fully developed nor recognised. There are institutional
differences between the Chinese legal system and those of developed countries, so
therefore, both theoretical and practical applicability need to be argued from the
perspective of the Chinese context.

31
Chapter Two: Literature Review

2.1 Introduction
This part of the literature review focuses exclusively on corporate governance theories –
in particular stakeholder theory and agency theory. It then justifies further why
stakeholder theory can be used as an appropriate framework to apply to the football
industry. By doing so, it not only provides for a broader understanding and background to
the study of corporate governance but also points out that the stakeholder focus
introduces a theoretical framework with which one can further develop the empirical
research for this thesis.

In discussing the connections between corporate governance and sport, the review
identifies a research gap, and the need for empirical investigation into corporate
governance within the Chinese football industry. With this in mind, it tries to link the
literature review to the research questions. The literature review demonstrates how the
corporate governance theory, and particularly stakeholder theory, can be used as the
theoretical framework for investigation into the Chinese football industry. The following
sections will review corporate governance and its major theories in order to provide a
broader conceptual understanding that will underpin the practical research within this
thesis.

2.2 Corporate governance theory


Despite a long history dating back to the influential work of Berle and Means (1932),
corporate governance has developed dramatically in the last 20 years and embraces many
different academic disciplines. Berle and Means (1932) argue that the separation of
ownership and control had major consequences for a modern corporation, compared to a
traditionally-owned business, where, as the number of shareholders increases, and
directors and management are prone to serve their own interests without effective
scrutiny instead of profit maximisation for shareholders. Alongside the development of
economic globalisation and industrial capitalism, corporate governance has become one

32
of the central topics in not only developed economies but also newly emerging ones. The
concept of corporate governance is widely used in economics, management studies, law
and finance. At a theoretical level, the two dominant corporate governance theories are
agency theory and stakeholder theory. The two theories affecting the development of
corporate governance should be viewed within their relevant contexts. For example, in
different corporate governance systems and political environments, there are different
legal safeguards to ensure investors get a return on their investment (Mallin 2004, Clark
2007, Shleifer & Vishny, 1997).

Studies of corporate governance have increased significantly in number since the


emerging markets crisis in 1997(Campos et al 2002). Discussions of corporate
governance feature mostly in British and American academic literature, supported by
practical application and written commentary in Anglo-American corporate experiences
(Sheridan & Kendall, 1992). The Cadbury Report (1992) is considered the most
influential guideline in the development of corporate governance codes throughout the
world (Mallin, 2004). It emphasised company structure, board-level structures, reporting
and control of corporations, and, when introduced in 1992, applied to all listed companies
in the UK on a ‘comply or explain’ basis. The Cadbury Report was replaced by the
Combined Code in 1998. A series of additional reports provide best practice guidelines
on which a firm’s performance should be benchmarked (e.g. OECD, 1999). The
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD, 1999) Principles,
although non-binding, nevertheless, provided common characteristics for good
governance which included shareholders’ rights, stakeholders’ roles, and managerial
transparency. The Cadbury Report (1992) and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act 2002, are direct
government responses that aims to enhance corporate governance standards following
financial scandals and big corporate collapses in the UK and US respectively. Corporate
governance has been seen as one of the basic objectives and needs for governing a
modern organisation or industry. The application of good corporate governance provides
more credible operational systems and managerial accountability. Ultimately, good
corporate governance can prevent financial collapses occurring and provides the stability
and credibility within a financial system to maintain investors’ confidence.

33
The development of corporate governance relates to different political systems, as well as
social and economic developments. Corporate governance can vary due to different legal,
regulatory and institutional environments. However it is commonly referred to as a
system with the objective of delivering credibility and accountability to modern
organisations and industries. It concerns itself with the relationships and responsibilities
amongst management, shareholders and other stakeholders within a regulated framework,
dealing with issues such as ownership and control, as well as any potential conflict of
interests between different parties.

Corporate governance is the relationship among various participants. It can be defined


narrowly as the relationship between a company and its shareholders or, more broadly, in
its relationship to society, as the system by which businesses and corporations are
directed and controlled (Cadbury, 1992). The former President of the World Bank –
James Wolfensohn states “Corporate governance is about promoting corporate fairness,
transparency and accountability” (Financial Times, 1999).

Blair (1995, p3) sees the definition of corporate governance has been broadened from just
questioning the structure and function of the board of directors and the rights and
prerogatives of shareholders in boardroom decision-making to refer to “the whole set of
legal, cultural and institutional arrangements, which determines what publicly traded
corporations can do, who controls them, how that control is exercised and how the risks
and returns from the activities they undertake are allocated”.

By contrast, other scholars define it differently, and in a narrower way: Corporate


governance can also be seen as an institutional arrangement by which suppliers of finance
to corporations assure themselves of getting a proper return on their investment (Shleifer
& Vishny, 1997, p737). However, the definition of corporate governance is poorly
defined because it potentially covers a large number of distinct economic phenomena. As
a result, different people have come up with different definitions that essentially reflect
their own special interest in the field. All definitions are concerned with the objectives of

34
corporations; stakeholders’ interest and whose interest has priority to be looked after and
how. How should stakeholders be taken into consideration and what are the corporation’s
priorities?

The broader definition of the concept offered by the World Bank is 5 : “Corporate
governance is concerned with holding the balance between economic and social goals
and between individual and communal goals. The governance framework is there to
encourage the efficient use of professional resources and equally to require accountability
for the stewardship of those resources. The aim is to align as nearly as possible the
interests of individuals, corporations and society”. Despite the lack of an all-
encompassing definition in the literature, corporate governance does have real-world
practical benefits.

The original purpose of corporate governance was to protect shareholder interest,


enhance systematic transparency, facilitate effective board management and provide an
efficient regulatory framework. Good governance provides not only performance
measurement to balance the differing interests of various participants in order to achieve
business success, but also to enhance industry accountability and transparency and to
ensure the fairness of the resulting wealth. Clarke (2004, p153) sums it up nicely
“corporate governance is about wealth generation and risk management, these duties
require continuous and simultaneous performance”.

Monks and Minow (2001) defined three primary participants in the corporate system
which they invest in, work for and direct, namely the shareholders, the management and
the board of directors. Good governance can improve corporate performance by
minimising the total cost of aligning managers’ and shareholders’ incentives and of self-
interested managerial behaviour (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).

In the Anglo-American economy, it is very common for a corporation to have widely


dispersed ownership, therefore, this raises concern about the board of directors who may

5
Sir Adrian Cadbury in “Global Corporate Governance Forum” World Bank (2000).

35
place self-interest over company interests during the decision-making process. In many
European and developing countries, corporations are mostly dominated by concentrated
ownership and the major shareholders have effectively got the controlling position on the
board, therefore, the possibility exists for them to abuse their positions for their own
benefit to make decisions at the expense of the small shareholders’ interests. In
management studies, corporate governance is seen as focusing on balancing differing
interests between owners and the people who manage the corporation - building better
practice within their organizations for improving corporate performance.

Cadbury identifies three levels of company responsibility. At the primary level,


companies must meet their basic material obligations to their stakeholders. In other words,
companies are required to maintain a certain degree of economic profit in order to carry
out normal operations. The second level of concern is making the correct use of a
community’s human resources and avoiding environmental damage. The third level is a
blurred one, in which companies’ responsibility concerns the relationship between
business and society in a wider sense (Monks & Minow 2001, p44).

A corporation is created for a specific purpose, and a good corporation allows different
participants to contribute capital, labour and expertise in a transparent system for the
maximum benefit of all. Therefore, a corporate system should promote a structure of
fairness, transparency and accountability for the good of not only primary participants,
but also all stakeholders.

Clarke (2004) states a single analytical lens offered by most existing theories of corporate
governance cannot fully explain the complexity of the changing phenomena. The lack of
a common definition of corporate governance leaves room for multiple approaches in this
field of research. The next sub-section will review academic literature on both agency
theory and stakeholder theory to understand how businesses are governed.

36
2.2.1 Agency theory
Agency theory concerns the relationship between a principal (resource holders or
shareholders) and an agent of the principal (company’s managers). The principal
delegates the decision-making authority to agents and the agents act on behalf of the
principals (Mallin 2004). Agency theory is a common topic within the field of
management studies as it deals with a variety of issues, such as agent opportunism, and
self-interested agent behaviour. From an agency theory standpoint “the central issue of
corporate governance is how shareholders (as principals) ensure that self-seeking
executives (as agents) act in the shareholders’ interests rather than their own” (Hendry
2005, Ps55).

Although agency theory was first formalised as an academic theory in the 1970s, the
concepts adopted and refined already have a long established history. Berle & Means
(1932) stated that as markets developed and countries industrialised, family ownership
made way for the rise of ‘salaried managers’. As a result, a separation between ownership
and control started to emerge. With this in mind, a modern shareholder can be seen as
possessing a direct property right in the firm (Aglietta 2000), whereas the managerial
control of the firm, as ascribed under agency theory, is a means of protecting the
shareholders’ interests (Jensen & Meckling 1976). Furthermore, where a director of a
firm makes decisions based on a delegated authority, one cannot assume that they would
act in a same way if they were the owners of the company.

Jensen (1983) discusses the development of agency theory along two lines: positivist and
principal-agent. The positivist line concentrates on the relationship between owners and
managers of large corporations. It is particularly concerned with the governing
mechanisms that can reduce agency problems. Positivist writers almost exclusively
focused on the owner/CEO relationship in the large corporation (Eisenhardt 1989). By
contrast, the principal-agent line concentrates on the theoretical implications behind
agency theory. It has a broader focus and greater interests in general, as Eisenhardt (1989)
argues, the principals-agent relationship can be applied to a wider range of commercial
relationships: employer-employee, lawyer-client, and buyer-supplier.

37
A key issue within agency theory is the potential for conflicts of interest between agents
and principals. It is based on the assumption that principals and agents are self-interested
groups. This self-interested behaviour has been raised as a significant problem within
commercial organisations. Generally, directors and managers can operate with their own
self-interest in mind, rather than in the best interests of shareholders. It is a common view
that all cooperating parties will have different goals and visions, this is especially true if
one party delegates work to another (Eisenhardt, 1989). In large corporations, agency
conflicts can be quite significant because managers generally own little, or no, company
stock.

Agency theory also emphasises the risk-reward trade-offs. It has raised issues of risk
sharing between principals and agents, as well as their attitudes towards risk (Lawler
1981). If a firm is fully owned and managed by the owner, then evidently the owner-
manager will seek to maximise his own interest and make the business as profitable as
possible. Jensen & Meckling (1976) call this a zero agency-cost firm. If the manager
owns less than 100% of the firm, there will be an agency conflict. A salaried manager, by
contrast to the shareholder, has a greater incentive to shirk and not perform in the best
interest of the business (Fama 1980, Ang et al 2000).

The principal-agent model assumes not only different goals exist between the principals
and agents, but that agents always possess more information than their principals
(Waterman & Meier 1998,Eisenhardt 1989).This is known as information asymmetry.
Under the condition of incomplete information and uncertainty, two agency problems
arise in management - adverse selection and moral hazard. Adverse selection is where
principals cannot be certain that agents are competent to do the job for which they are
being paid, while moral hazard is where principals are not sure whether agents have put
their maximum efforts into completing a task or job (Eisenhardt 1989). This relates to
another issue in agency theory – agent behaviour can be difficult and expensive to
monitor (Carr & Brower, 1996).

38
Eisenhardt (1988 p489) states, “agency theory focuses on the need for measurability of
performance and for performance criteria that employees can influence”. There are two
options available for principals to control these agency problems. Firstly, by investing in
information systems to determine an agent’s productivity. Eisenhardt (1989) determines
that a work based information system can be regarded as a commodity which can be
invested in by a business to act as a deterrent to agent opportunism. Secondly, agents can
be tied into performance-based contracts (Eisenhardt 1988). In the context of corporate
control, agency theory views corporate governance as the mechanisms essential to
monitor agent behaviour and to reduce agency costs of the firm (Mallin 2004).

2.2.1a Interest alignment


Blair (1995) argues managers must be monitored in order to make sure they do not abuse
their power. Because of self-interested behaviour, institutional arrangements must be put
in place in order to prevent agency problems. Various mechanisms have been used to
align the interests of the principals and agents to encourage agents to act with their
principals’ best interest in mind.

1. The board of directors


The board of directors is the link between managers and investors. The structure and
function of the board is an essential mechanism for overseeing management and holding
them accountable (Hendry 2005). The accountability of managers to company
shareholders is clearly outlined in the Combined Code on Corporate Governance (2003)
and the late refined UK Corporate Governance Code (2010). The Code further states that
the roles of chairman and CEO are preferably separated to ensure no one individual is too
powerful. It also suggests that the board should consist of a wide range of executive and
non-executive directors – thereby enabling independent advice and additional expertise.

Furthermore, a mixed boardroom will allow for a more balanced structure, allow for the
monitoring of individual directors and ensure that the board make decisions that are in the
interests of the shareholders (Mallin 2004, Hendry 2005). In addition, Fama (1980)
argues that at the senior level, if there is competition among the top managers themselves,

39
their individual ambition, reputation and personal interest, make them the best ones to
control the board of directors as they are the most informed and responsive critics of the
firm’s performance. Hendry (2005) argues that the occasional limited competence of
certain agents will no doubt cause problems for the company. An inefficient agent is not
necessarily immediately noticeable, and the board itself is by no means a perfect
governance mechanism either - it can only overcome the problem by learning with time.

2. Performance-based incentive plans


When shareholders hire top executives, fixed wages are not the optimal way of rewarding
them. A fixed wage creates an incentive for agents to shirk. Agents are likely to take
fixed salaries for granted since even a lacklustre performance can be met with a reward
(Eisenhardt 1985). Therefore, performance based incentive plans are used to reduce
shirking and effectively curb agent opportunism. For example, commissions and profit-
sharing schemes have been adopted in order to align the interests of both principal and
agent. A performance-based contract also reduces the difficulties for principals to
monitor agents, and ensure that they are performing to the best of their abilities. Since a
principal may lack the necessary knowledge to ensure that the agent is performing his/her
job efficiently, performance based pay will entitle the agent to a bonus for good
performance, rather than requiring the principal to police the agent. Furthermore, the
incentive of performance-based pay will encourage agents to endeavour to benefit
shareholders returns at the same time.

However, one problem with a performance-based scheme is simply the fact that the
external managerial labour market will continually exert pressures on the firm, therefore,
in order to avoid a manager being head-hunted by another company, the firm’s reward
system and performance-based pay scheme will have to be attractive and reflect the
managerial performance of the director (Fama 1980). Therefore, a pivotal issue of agency
theory lies in determining the ‘optimal contract’ that governs the relationship between
principals and agents (Eisenhardt 1988).

3. Shareholders’ direct intervention

40
Major shareholders, or institutional investors, can meet the firm’s managers to offer their
opinions regarding the company’s operation. Moreover, they can also raise issues at
annual shareholders’ meetings and use their voting power to enforce policies.

4. Job threat
It is difficult to remove the top layer of management in big corporations as the ownership
is widely spread between shareholders. However, there are means by which shareholders
may act to remove top management. Furthermore, there is always the risk that poor
performance and inadequate management can lead to hostile takeovers, in which top
management are normally dismissed. The constant threat of losing one’s job aligns
agents’ interests with principals’.

5. Employee share ownership


Barney (1988) argues that employee ownership of a company aligns the interests between
principals and agents. When an employee owns shares in a firm, he effectively becomes a
shareholder. According to Jensen & Meckling’s (1976) study of agency theory, they
conclusion was that that agency-cost is negatively related to the managers’ share
ownership. Therefore, the higher the percentage of the managers’ share ownership, the
lower the agency-cost. Ang et al (2000) analysis of 1,249 companies confirms that
companies with high turnover are less likely to be managed by non-managing
shareholders.

Employee share ownership can be viewed as an outcome-based contract - it aligns the


interest of shareholders and agents. Eisenhardt (1989, p68) make another point,
“Managers who have substantial equity positions within their firms were less likely to
resist takeover bids”. This is due to the fact that the new company is expected to be more
efficient, and it can therefore align the interest between the principals and agents more
effectively. Moreover, it is also the case that when a company is taken over, managers are
likely to get a premium for their shareholding.

2.2.1b Risk shifting

41
Eisenhardt (1989, p61) argues, “The heart of the principal-agent theory is the trade-off
between the cost of measuring agent behaviour and the cost of measuring outcomes and
transferring the risk from principals to agents”. Agency theory uses the metaphor of a
contract to describe the principal-agent relationship (Jensen & Meckling 1976, Keeley
1980). As an outcome-based contract would curb agent opportunism and shift business
risks from the principals to the agents. Therefore, it favours the principal rather than the
agent – much like performance-based pay schemes. For example, top managers of big
corporations are typically on outcome-based contracts. They are heavily incentivised, and
an easily measured outcome enables the principal to shift the investment risk onto agents.
By contrast, a behaviour-based contract with a fixed salary is more favourable to agents
rather than principals.

From an organisational viewpoint, agency theory concerns itself with a system based on
risk and reward trade-offs between the principal and the agent. Despite being engaged in
cooperative behaviour, they have different goals and different attitudes towards risk
(Eisenhardt 1989). Principals and agents will prefer different actions and make different
decisions because of their misaligned risk preference. Agents will always be more risk
averse, particularly so if there is no accountability put in place (e.g. performance
monitoring). The uncertainty associated with commercial outcomes and the willingness
to accept this uncertainty from both principals and agents determines the relationship
between the two sides. An agent is considered more risk averse than the principal,
particularly because the success or failure of the business is more of an investment loss
than for the principal. Agents are focused on fulfilling their employment contracts,
whereas principals are merely focused on expanding the business and diversifying the
company’s investments. Ultimately, the agent stands to lose his job, whereas the principal
stands to lose an equity share if the business is unsuccessful (Fama, 1980, Carr & Brower
1996, Eisenhardt 1989).

2.2.1c Effective monitoring


Effective monitoring is a good mechanism for reducing the adverse agent selection and
moral hazard. It has always been difficult for principals to monitor agents’ behaviour and

42
to verify exactly what the agents are doing. Therefore information and information
technology is considered an important element in controlling and monitoring managers’
behaviour. The more information available to principals, the better aligned the interests of
both principals and agents (Fama 1980, Fama & Jensen 1983). In a sense, the agent is
essentially forced to align with the principal’s interest.

Effective monitoring and good flow of information can be pursued through different
methods, such as adding extra layers of management, or building a more appropriate
board structure. Fama (1980) argues that each manager naturally monitors other
managers directly above and below him as he has a stake in their performance. Fama &
Jensen (1983) see the board as one of the devices through which the agent can be
monitored, and argue that when the board is provided with better information, agents are
more likely to engage in shareholders’ interest. Furthermore, the inclusion of outside
directors stimulates that competition amongst the company’s top managers (Fama 1980).
In addition, Ang et al (2000) argue that the vigilance of the non-managing shareholders
and related third parties can monitor managers’ expenditure on personal consumption and
pre-requisites. For example, banks require a firm’s manager to report results honestly and
monitor the firm’s business performance, to safeguard their investment.

Generally speaking, lower-skilled repetitive jobs cost less to monitor, as the agent’s
behaviour is predictable, and can be observed and evaluated easily. The principal knows
exactly what an agent has done and the outcome of the job can be easily assessed. In the
same way, if an agent engages in complex work with an uncertain outcome, the
monitoring cost for the principal will be much higher. Monitoring is a controlling
mechanism, which derives from a goal conflict between the principal and the agent (Carr
and Brower, 1996). Through monitoring, the principal is trying to reduce investment risk,
and control agent opportunism and other lacklustre behaviour that will affect the
company. If there is no goal conflict, agents will act in the principals’ interest regardless
of whether they have been monitored or not. The less goal conflict, the more interest
alignment exists between the principal and the agent. From this, the choice between
employing an agent on a performance based contract or a behaviour based contract will

43
depend on the trade-off between the cost of monitoring and the cost of transferring the
risk (Eisenhardt 1988). Indeed, in a competitive environment, a firm with low-cost
monitoring mechanisms is likely to survive.

2.2.1d Theory implication and limitation


Carr & Brower (1996) argue that principal-agent theory has evolved from the issue of
why organisations form and the purpose of an organisation. Furthermore, principal-agent
theory has narrow assumptions regarding principal and agent motivations. Agency theory
is more relevant in situations in which the principal and the agent create a contract that
involves goal conflict, outcome uncertainty and risk shifting. It provides the framework
for a better understanding of principal-agent relationships in organisations as well as an
understanding of self-interested behaviour. An ideal scenario is to study organisational
behaviour of both principals and agents through contractual engagements between the
two parties. These types of arrangements between principals and agents confirm the
firm’s organisational behaviour and managerial mechanisms are in place.

Carr & Brower (1996) argue that apart from self-interested actions, agency theory
provides little information about principals’ behaviour and motivation. For example, it
presumes that agents always take advantage of principals, but it was never considered
from the position of a principal itself. Principal-agent theory is limited to answering
questions about what organisations do, and how they do it. Proponents of this theory
argue that agency theory is a bilateral activity and should therefore be analysed
accordingly. At present, in any agency theory analysis, self-interested behaviour seems to
be the only motivation binding the principal-agent relationship. However, in any one
organisation you are likely to have a coalition of members pursuing certain interests with
multiple goals. At present, agency theory is limited to analysing unitary organisational
goals. For instance, the reality of many organisations is that it is difficult to identify a
single principal who is totally in control, and it is common for multiple principal-
executives, and multiple legislative bodies to pursue different directions and different
priorities when they execute policies. Therefore, the organisation’s short-term operational
goal could conflict with its long-term development goal. However, “The agency model

44
treats all non-sanctioned behaviour as shirking and does not differentiate between acts
that breach organisational goals and those that challenge organisational procedure but
support the goals” (Carr & Brower 1996).

Waterman & Meier (1998) argue that the two assumptions (1. that a goal conflict exists
between principals and agents; 2. that agents have more information than principals) of
agency theory do not always hold. The principal-agent relationship is viewed as dynamic,
and not static. With this in mind, agency theory is not a catch-all for determining the
relationships in all particular social environments (whether commercial or not). There are
various kinds of relationships that exist in the political sphere which differ to the
commercial one. The relationship between principals (politicians) and agents (bureaucrats)
in a political context does not always present goal conflicts to the two actors, nor do the
bureaucrats always possess more information than politicians. Indeed, agency theory, as
Eisenhardt (1989) stated, is unable to account for the process of negotiation and
bargaining when resolving certain goal conflicts in a political model. Ultimately there is
a limitation with agency theory in that it cannot be successfully applied to all situations.

Finally, agency theory has further limitations in determining certain principal-agent


relationships. For example, in complex organisations, managers will play a dual role,
both as principals to their subordinates and as agents to their supervisors. Therefore, there
tends to be a more complex array of goal conflict at the managerial level. In fact,
managerial decisions and the actions of both principals and agents are based on a
business reality rather than purely self-interested motivation.

2.2.2 Stakeholder theory


Stakeholder theory provides a different understanding of the objective of the corporation
compared to agency theory. Indeed, it was designed as an alternative to shareholder-
orientated theories of organisations (Freeman 1994). The term “stakeholder” was used in
contrast to the dominant economic logic of the stockholder notion, which emphasises the
stockholder’s priority. Agency theory is based on shareholders (as owners) interests first.

45
Stakeholder theory promotes the idea of the common good and considers the corporation
within a broader environment, consisting of a range of stakeholders in addition to
sharehodlers. It suggests other stakeholders’ interests can be easily overlooked if the
corporation only concentrates on maximising shareholders’ values. Therefore, all
stakeholders’ interests should be recognised in order to achieve superior performance
(Freeman 1984, Friedman & Miles 2002, Laplume, et al 2008).

A stakeholder was defined in the seminal text by Freeman (1984: p46) as “any group or
individual who can affect or is affected by the achievement of the organisation’s
objectives”. This definition is broad – it assumes that any group or individual can be a
stakeholder of an organisation as long as they can affect or are affected by the
achievement of the organisation’s objectives. More recently, stakeholders have been
defined as “those groups without whose support the organisation would cease to exist”
(Freeman, cited by Sternberg, 1997, p3) and as those groups “on which the organisation
is dependent for its continued survival” (Freeman & Reed 1983, p91 cited by Mitchell et
al, 1997 p856). Since then, the stakeholder concept has gained wide recognition in
multiple subjects and has developed in the fields of strategic management, corporate
governance and corporate social responsibility (CSR) since (Laplume et al 2008,
Turnbull 1997).

Traditional capitalist firms are profit driven organisations representing the value of true
capitalism, such as greed and aggression. Neo-capitalist firms are managed with a new
approach and new desire to be accountable not only to shareholders but also to all the
stakeholders involved (Clarkson 1995). The new approach does not disregard a firm’s
profit as an important element, on the contrary, it takes a new perception to conceive that
a firm’s profit should be generated in a long term sustainable healthy process, and every
stakeholder involved should benefit from the firm’s sustainable development (Freeman
1984, Hillman & Keim 2001). Moreover, social issues and ethical concerns have
gradually became a part of mainstream management literature, in practice the stakeholder
approach has certainly become a trend for a firm’s management to pay attention to, and

46
investors have begun to make investment decisions on the basis of both economic and
social responsibility (Harrison & Freeman, 1999).

Stakeholder theory is closely linked to the concept of CSR, both of them having the same
‘normative core value’, something which is widely recognised in current mainstream
legal thinking. The American Law Institute report, Principle of Corporate Governance
(1992) states that the central corporate objective is to enhance corporate profit and
shareholder gain, however, it also indicates “Even if corporate profit and shareholder gain
are not thereby enhanced, the corporation must abide by law and may take into account
ethical consideration and engage in philanthropy” (cited by Donaldson & Preston, 1995,
p82). This stakeholder-thinking concept has also been adopted in many other countries,
the so-called codetermination laws of Germany require employee representation on
second-tier boards of directors; the Companies Act (1980, 2006) in the UK requires
corporate decisions made by board directors to include the interests of employees, and to
act in the interest of stakeholders. Even in an emerging economy like China, the Chinese
Communist Party (CCP) issued a doctrine at the 6th plenum of its 16th Central Committee
in 2006, indicating that social cohesion should not be sacrificed in the pursuit of
economic development, so facilitating social harmony in order to enhance the ability to
counter risks and better cope with international challenges (Central Committee, CCP,
2006). The development of legal systems in favour of stakeholders emphasises the
legitimate interests of stakeholders rather than simply taking a corporation’s or
shareholders’ interests for granted. A stakeholder approach became the way of thinking
for value creation, due to its analytical power offers a broad set of stakeholder
relationships rather than a pure economic relationship, and it is able to address the
interest of the full range of communities as a whole (Harrison & Freeman, 1999). The
stakeholder model is becoming a common characteristic of the contemporary managerial
approach for many organisations (Post et al 2002, Rowley 1997). Donaldson & Preston
(1995) argue that stakeholder theory is first and foremost a managerial concept. However
there is an overlap into organisational theory including business ethics. Furthermore,
stakeholder management constitutes a combination of attitudes, structure and practices.
Donalson & Preston review the theory from descriptive, normative and instrumental

47
aspects, ultimately relying on the normative base and moral philosophy to provide the
ultimate justification for the theory.

Laplume et al (2008) review the theory from five themes: stakeholder definition and
salience; stakeholder actions and responses; corporation actions and response;
corporation performance; theory debate, the five themes cover multiple research fields.
From a managerial point of view, the section below focuses on stakeholders’
identification, stakeholder relationships and managerial implication, elaborating on why
it is important to distinguish different stakeholders and their diverse interests; what
strategy the firm can adopt to respond to stakeholders’ influences according to the
relationships the firm has with its stakeholders.

2.2.2a Stakeholders’ identification and legitimacy


Critics argue that stakeholder theory is weak in identifying who could be considered
stakeholders and in which capacity they are to be included. Furthermore, it has been
argued that stakeholder theory provides no guidance on how to balance different interests
amongst stakeholders (Argenti, 1997; Sternberg, 1997). Freeman’s definition about
stakeholders is considered too broad in practice regarding stakeholder management, as it
virtually includes everything, everyone and everywhere. On a practical level therefore, it
becomes an impossible task for an organisation to be run for the benefit of all its
stakeholders.

Clarkson (cited by Mitchell et al 1997) treats stakeholders as voluntary and involuntary


risk bearers. Voluntary stakeholders invest some form of capital and bear a certain degree
of business risk; “involuntary stakeholders are placed at risk as a result of a firm’s
activities. But without the element of risk there is no stake” (ibid p857). In his terms, a
stake is interpreted as something which can be lost, consisting only in the form of a
legitimate claim and omitting any power element or urgency claim. Donaldson & Preston
(1995, p85) see it as following: “stakeholders are identified through the actual or
potential harms and benefits that they experience or anticipate experiencing as a result of
the firm’s action or inaction”.

48
Clarkson (1995) introduces concepts of primary stakeholder groups, which the
corporation depends on to survive, and secondary stakeholder groups, which the
corporation is less engaged with, the latter being groups that are not essential for the
corporation to survive. He argues that the interests of primary stakeholder groups have
priorities which need to be met by the corporation, a consideration which does not apply
to secondary stakeholder groups, while failure to satisfy primary stakeholder groups
results in the failure of the whole stakeholder system. He sees the corporation as a system
of primary stakeholder groups, which, including employees, customers, investors and
suppliers, governments and communities are identified as primary stakeholders as they
provide the legislative framework, the location and possess the executive power to shape
the infrastructure of the corporation.

Stakeholder identification and legitimacy literature argues the principle of who or what
really counts. Scholars such as Freeman, Mitchell, Clarkson, Donaldson and Preston
believe a stakeholder-firm relationship should be built on the basis of a ‘moral core’.
Philips (1997, 2003) considers stakeholders should be identified under the principle of
fairness. This provides an explanation of the obligations due to stakeholders. Philips’
approach is similar to the normative approach espoused by Donaldson and Preston (1995);
they also believe that a normative component of stakeholder theory is the foundation for
the concept of stakeholder legitimacy, therefore it seems to present a stronger platform
for identifying legitimate stakeholders. Stakeholders can be limited to those individuals
or individual groups who have a more legitimate claim and appeal to a normative core for
stakeholder theory (Philips 2003; Donaldson & Preston 1995, Suchman 1995).

Phillips (1997, 2003) first widened the debate on stakeholder legitimacy into a concept of
broad vs narrow, ultimately favouring the narrow concept. A broad definition such as that
given by Freeman (1984) can be argued to be a meaningless term to identify stakeholders.
However, the moral principle sets the tone for stakeholder legitimacy (Phillips, 2003).
For Phillips, stakeholders are only those groups or individuals to whom a moral
obligation is owed. Still, this narrow version of stakeholder legitimacy has been criticised,

49
as it omits groups that could have an impact on an organisation but do not have a
legitimate claim, such as terrorists (Schweickart, 2006). Under Phillips’s (1997) principle
of fairness framework, stakeholders are voluntary members of a co-operative scheme for
mutual benefit, therefore terrorists are not included as stakeholders.

Phillips (1997) categorises stakeholders as normative stakeholders, derivative


stakeholders and non-stakeholders. Normative stakeholders are those groups to which an
organisation has a moral obligation. Derivative stakeholders are those groups that their
interests an organisation must consider due to their actions may have a major impact
upon the organisation itself. The organization can ignore non-stakeholders in a process of
managerial decision-making. Despite the differences between stakeholders, he sees all
stakeholders within the context of the fairness framework; they are rather partners than
competitors in achieving mutual goals, and one’s success is integrated with the success of
all others (ibid). According to Freeman (1984) and Phillips (2003), stakeholder status and
an organisation’s obligations can change across both time and issues; non-stakeholders
can become derivative or normative stakeholders, thereby affecting the organisation.

In business practice, legitimate stakeholders are identified by the existence of contracts,


explicit or implicit between stakeholders and the firm (Donaldson & Preston, 1995).
Mitchell et al (1997) introduced another narrow concept of stakeholder, based on
legitimate links, such as contract, legal right, and moral interest, which not only identifies
stakeholder status, but can also explain to whom the management of an organisation pay
attention to. They argue the stakeholder-firm relationship can be addressed by three key
attributes: power; legitimacy and urgency. A stakeholder can impose its will in the
stakeholder-firm relationship through its power; legitimacy gives a stakeholder a
legitimate status. Mitchell et al (1997) use the term ‘stakeholder salience’ to describe the
attitude with which management treat the firm’s stakeholders. Managers give different
priorities to competing stakeholder claims and pay different attention to each claim
according to its power of enforcement. The more attributes a stakeholder possesses, the
more managerial attention it gets (Mitchell et al, 1997). Agle et al (1999) study
Mitchell’s stakeholder salience from a CEOs’ perception and point out that a stakeholder

50
who possesses more attributes of power, legitimacy and urgency is likely to have higher
salience compared to a stakeholder with less attributes. Parent & Deephouse (2007, p3)
argue “a greater understanding of stakeholder salience can be gained by focusing on
individual managers”. Agle et al (1999) explain managers’ attention towards stakeholders
as depending on two elements:

1. The control power of a stakeholder over critical resources. Stakeholders who control
more critical resources gain more attention from CEOs;
2. A manager’s own perception and values. CEOs’ own values influence their decision-
making and attention given to the stakeholder.

What is clear within the litertuare on stakeholder identification is that different


stakeholders possess different attributes which can determine stakeholder salience and
managers’ level of attention. Nevertheless, their importance for the firm is not static,
because a stakeholder’s access to means (information or power) is not in a steady state
(Parent & Deephouse 2007). Freeman (1984) recognises environmental ‘shifts’ for
stakeholders both internally and externally, and that there is a need to categorise different
stakeholders in order to understand more about their interests and behavior. However,
stakeholder groups are not homogenous - there can be several sub-group stakeholders
within one stakeholder group (Low & Cowton 2004), and each of them has their set of
interests. A good manager needs to be aware of the priorities of the organisation as the
status of different stakeholders can change under different circumstances, and despite the
fact that, at some point one stakeholder may be more important than another, a balanced
consideration of various stakeholders is required during the decision-making process
(Phillips 2003, Clarkson 1995).

2.2.2b Stakeholder Management


Stakeholder management is one of the central themes of recent business and social
studies (Carroll & Bucholtz 1989). Donaldson and Preston (1995) point out that
stakeholder theory has been advanced and justified on three grounds: descriptive
accuracy, instrumental power and normative validity. They argue the stakeholder model

51
is descriptive and serves as a framework to test empirical claims; it is also instrumental in
setting up a framework to examine the connections between stakeholder management and
the firm’s performance goals; normative aspect is the fundamental base for stakeholder
theory and stakeholder management. All stakeholders’ interests have intrinsic value,
therefore stakeholder management requires simultaneous attention being given to
legitimise the interests of all stakeholders.

Should stakeholders be taken care of equally by a corporation? Clarkson (1995) argues


managers should pay more attention to primary stakeholders, place their interests above
interests of secondary stakeholders. Beaver (1999) and Argenti (1997) argue different
stakeholders possess different positions and have different relationships with the
corporation, therefore they should not be treated equally. Moreover, shareholders are the
owners of corporations, they expect a financial return on their investment and demand
their voices be heard first, therefore they are the superior ones amongst stakeholders and
they deserve priority. Sundaram and Inkpen (2004) see more than one objective as
causing confusion for management during the decision-making process. Practically, in
order to reduce agency problems, many corporations align interests of management and
firm by issuing shares to top management to create stronger connections between
management and the firm in order to forge a special relationship which other stakeholders
or shareholders do not have.

In contrast, Campbell (1997), Freeman et al (2004), believe the stakeholder approach is


the attitude corporations should have towards stakeholders and their surrounding
environments. Even though each stakeholder has a different relationship with the
corporation, a corporation should treat all stakeholders equally. Firms need to win loyalty
from stakeholders to survive, therefore it is necessary for a firm to build good
relationships and trust with stakeholders. It is hard to gain the loyalty of other
stakeholders if a firm’s only purpose is to maximise the wealth of shareholders. Campbell
(1997) argues managers should think about the full range of communities from whom
they need loyalty instead of only thinking about shareholder value and it is a vital point
for thinking about business. As an alternative to the shareholder approach, the

52
stakeholder approach values the full range of stakeholder relationships as well as those
stakeholders’ interests, providing managers with more resources and a greater scope to
deal with business challenges (Freeman et al 2004). Freeman argues that the reality is
complicated; to have a single objective ignores the complexity of the environment in
which the firm operates, by solely emphasising shareholders’ interest the moral high-
ground can be easily lost and it is more likely to foster unethical behavior as well as
tunnel vision. A good management approach is to not make a decision to distribute
surplus spoils without due regard to a firm’s long term ability of generating profit, benefit
distribution, concentrated solely on shareholders, is unwise behaviour for a firm’s future
development (Campbell 1997).

In terms of stakeholder practice, Low and Cowton (2004) suggest two steps of practice
towards proactive stakeholder management: engagement and participation. Engagement
is the technique used by a corporation whereby regular contact with its stakeholders is
made in order to keep them well informed but distanced from decision-making;
participation is the technique which allows stakeholders to have a more active
involvement in a corporation’s decision-making process and governance structure,
therefore to offer more transparency and greater accountability. Despite these
mechanisms of stakeholder management, there are also various problems which are
recognised during practice, including the explicit identification of stakeholders, their
capability and how representative they are in the governance structure. More importantly,
a major problem lies in how to get the right balance and an appropriate approach for
managing stakeholder relationships. The subsection below looks at three different
stakeholder relationship models, and each one provides a useful tool for understanding
why a specific managerial approach ought to be employed by firms (according to a
specific stakeholder relationship). These models are implemented within this study,
therefore guiding and underpinning the data analysis of the research.

Understanding Stakeholder Relationships


The relationships between different stakeholders of a firm have been seen as a nexus of
contract under stakeholder theory framework. Friedman & Miles (2002) recognise two

53
types of contract amongst stakeholders, explicit and implicit contracts, which provide
different degrees of freedom to different stakeholders. “Implicit contracts fill the gap
between social relations which are not characterised by explicit contracts (ibid p7)”. As
figure 2-1 shows, they distinguish four types of stakeholder relationships based on two
distinctions:

1. The compatibility of stakeholders’ own values and interests associated with social
structure. In other words, a compatible relationship indicates stakeholders have common
values and similar interests and an incompatible relationship means the opposite.

2. The necessity of stakeholders’ business connections and ideas. In other words,


stakeholders with connected ideas or internal organisations within the same framework
are considered to have a necessary relationship, if they are different external
organisations or disconnected, which means a contingent relationship.

Contingent Necessary
(High level common value)
Compatible Contingent Compatible Necessary Compatible
(Low) (Highly connected)
Incompatible Contingent Incompatible Necessary Incompatible

(Low)
Figure 2-1 Stakeholders’ relationship model (based on: Friedman & Miles, 2002, p8)

Friedman & Miles (2002) illustrate that relationships between organisations and
stakeholders can be viewed as Necessary Compatible, Necessary Incompatible,
Contingent Compatible and Contingent Incompatible, each particular combination
representing different relationships between stakeholders which require a certain type of
approach to manage.

In a Necessary Compatible stakeholder relationship, all parties have an interest to


strengthen the existing structure in order to benefit from the relationship, therefore

54
explicit contracts are expected to be in place between stakeholders, as for instance, in the
relationships between a firm and shareholders. Although different values and interests
between stakeholders exist within a Necessary Incompatible relationship, organisations
are expected to answer the claims of stakeholders, since stakeholders and organizations
may have incompatible ideas but compatible interests or vice versa. For example, a
relationship between a firm and its customers. Implicit contracts are recognised amongst
stakeholders under the Contingent Compatible structure, where there are potential
opportunities for stakeholders to develop further relations, for example, a relationship
between a firm and its local community. Divergences of interests exist between
organisations and stakeholders within a Contingent Incompatible structure, in which the
relationships amongst stakeholders are often intense.

These four types of structures explain stakeholder relationships with different dimensions
and also demonstrate that stakeholder relationships can change over time. This model
helps organisations predict a developing trend of a particular stakeholder relationship
according to changes in values of the stakeholder and the overall business approach,
thereby enabling organisations to effectively manage the relationship between the
company and the stakeholder. Furthermore, this model also allows us to develop a better
understanding of stakeholder theory beyond an exclusive organisational perspective.

Understanding Stakeholder Environments


Network theory sees stakeholders interact, cooperate or form an alliance (Neville &
Menguc 2006, Rowley 1997). Rowley argues that organisations do not often respond to
each stakeholder individually. He analyses relationships between different stakeholder
groups, looking especially at stakeholder interactions and the focal organisation’s
position, in order to explain how an organisation responds to stakeholders’ influence
within a network environment. A model is developed on two distinctions; the density of
the stakeholder network and centrality of the focal organisation. Stakeholder density
characterises the number of ties linking all stakeholders, which allows information to
flow amongst all members. Density is a mechanism that can represent the effectiveness
and efficiency of communication between stakeholders within the network. Centrality

55
refers to the power of a focal organisation and its ability to control information flows
amongst stakeholders. In a high density network, stakeholders who have more connected
ties between them are able to communicate efficiently allowing them more power to push
their claims forward. It can also be explained by Mitchell et al’s (1997) ‘stakeholder
salience term’. Through efficient communication linkages, sufficient stakeholder power
can be accumulated by forming an alliance amongst different stakeholders; the combined
stakeholder salience can increase pressures on a focal organisation (Neville & Menguc
2006, Frooman 1999). A centrally located position provides a focal organisation with the
strength to resist stakeholders’ influence and pressure. Therefore the focal organisation
can play a more commanding role in the network.

Stakeholder Density
(High)

Firm’s High Density/Low Centrality High Density/High Centrality


(Low) (High)
Centrality Low Density/Low Centrality Low Density/High Centrality
(Low)
Figure 2-2 Stakeholder influences model (based on Rowley 1997, p901)

Figure 2-2 demonstrates such a model. In a High Density/High Centrality stakeholder


environment, on the one hand, stakeholders possess efficient linkages to influence an
organization; on the other hand the firm has a centralised position and therefore has the
power to ignore certain stakeholder demands. As a result, a compromise approach is
likely to be adopted by both parties and a position of mutual satisfaction is likely to be
negotiated. In a High Density/Low Centrality environment, stakeholders are able to speak
collectively from a superior position; a focal organisation is likely to comply with
stakeholders’ demands. In a Low Density/High Centrality environment, without an
efficient communication system, stakeholders are peripheral to the focal organisation and
a focal organisation is able to dictate the relationship and is more resistant to
stakeholders’ influence. In a Low Density/Low Centrality environment, even though the
focal firm is not in the central position, it does not face intensified claims from the poorly

56
connected stakeholders either. The focal firm is likely to pursue its interests without
significant scrutiny from stakeholders.

From the firm’s perspective, there are managerial strategies to gain support from
stakeholders. Building trust and giving fair treatment to stakeholders are valued as
effective ways to achieve stakeholder support (Jones 1995). Scott & Lane (2000) argue
for increasing organisational communications; enhancing stakeholders’ affiliations;
integrating stakeholders into the organisational community are the three tactics to win
stakeholders’ support. Stakeholders use a network formation to increase their influence
over the focal firm. The focal firm also employs the same strategy to increase its stability,
especially in an inter-organisational network, an efficient communication mechanism
provides a competitive advantage for the firm to overcome uncertainty and become
adoptable, flexible with a quick response to challenges (Gulati 1998, Hage & Alter 1997).
Since the 1990s network analysis has been seen as a powerful tool and a useful
framework to gain a better understanding of a firm’s behaviour and stakeholder
relationships (Grandori & Soda, 1995).

Understanding Corporation Responses


Frooman (1999) sees the stakeholder concept as crucial for strategic management.
Corporations and stakeholders may potentially head towards conflict because of their
different interests; stakeholder theory is the framework for managing these potential
conflicts. He analyses stakeholder relationships from a resource dependence concept and
argues that if organisation A is dependent on organisation B6, then B possesses power
over A. Yet simply controlling resources is not the only route to pursuing stakeholder
influence. Apart from the direct influence, the influence of one organisation over another
can be achieved indirectly via the third party. Stakeholders use direct strategies when the
firm depends on them and indirect strategies when it does not (Laplume et al 2008). In
order to influence the focal organisation, a stakeholder has two options to control

6
A’s resources are dependent on B, for instance, B supplies or consumes a large proportion of the input or
output that A needs, or both.

57
resources: withholding and usage 7 with direct or indirect managerial approaches at its
disposal according to its level of stakeholder interdependence with the firm. Figure 2-3
below indicates how stakeholders influence firms with appropriate managerial
approaches under the resource dependence framework.

Level of stakeholder dependence on a firm


(High)
Indirect/usage Direct/usage
Level of firm’s (Firm power) High interdependence)
dependence on (Low) (High)
stakeholders Indirect/withholding Direct/withholding
(Low interdependence) (Stakeholder power)
(Low)
Figure 2-3 Stakeholders’ & firms’ managerial strategies (based on Frooman 1999, table 1&2)

With a low level interdependence, the indirect approach is likely employed by


stakeholders to pursue their influences over a focal organisation while a direct approach
is used where there is a high level of interdependence. A stakeholder who has a high level
of controlling power over an organisation is likely to adopt the resource withholding
method to get its message across, therefore a usage method is used in a low resource
dependent relationship. Frooman’s model provides managerial options for stakeholders
who try to influence a focal organisation based on their interdependence status. Even
though the model focuses on stakeholders’ actions, it also illustrates firms’ managerial
responses under different stakeholder relationships and provides a better explanation of
how the interaction between stakeholders can influences a firm’s decision-making
process. Firms should be aware of changes in their stakeholder environments as there are
some stakeholders who are willing and capable of moblising to enhance their bargaining
position by combining their power and legitimacy (Rowley & Berman 2000, Laplume et
al 2008).

7
Keeping the original resource dependence relationship with attached conditions.

58
All three stakeholder relationship models can be represented in a similar configuration as
showed above. All of them are developed under stakeholder theory, and they are able to
explain and predict stakeholder relationships under different circumstances. Friedman
and Miles (2002) use Greenpeace as an example to analyse the relationship ‘shift’ within
corporations from a Contingent Incompatible position to a Necessary Compatible one
over the course of development. The argument is based on elements such as the material
interests and social values of different stakeholders.

Rowley’s (1997) argument is based on the concept of a stakeholder environment. It charts


the physical linkages between stakeholders and the controlling power of focal
organisations, so gaining a deep insight into how organisations are embedded within a
stakeholder network and how an organisation’s position affects it response to
stakeholders’ influences (Neville & Menguc 2006). The model is a combination of
stakeholder theory and social network analysis with two dimensions: stakeholder
influence and a firm’s resistance. The two elements interact in a stakeholder network and
explain how they restrain each other.

Frooman (1999) develops stakeholder theory from a resource dependence dimension; the
model identifies not only relationships between stakeholders but also states which
managerial strategy the stakeholder would choose to influence in a focal firm’s decision-
making. He uses an environmental group, Earth Island Institute (EII) campaigns against
StarKist as an example of analysing relationships between stakeholder power and a firm’s
managerial strategies. Stakeholder relationships and their status inside any model are not
static; for instance, in Figure 2-1, the goals of different stakeholders can change, therefore
their relationships with other stakeholders shift from compatible to incompatible, and
vice versa; in Figure 2-2, the centrality of a focal organisation in a network can change
from a central position to a less central position according to the number of linkages it
has with other stakeholders and its ability to control information flows, and vice versa.
Figure 2-3 explains how stakeholders can achieve their goals by adopting different
strategies according to their level of ability to control resources. More importantly,
stakeholder theory is applicable a wider range of business fields (Harrison & Freeman,

59
1999), and the three models mentioned above set a suitable foundation for analysing
stakeholder relationships, firms’ behaviour, and managerial strategies across different
industries, especially an industry with many highly interdependent stakeholders involved,
such as the football industry.

Steurer (2006) expands stakeholder theory further with a triple-perspective typology


approach. The three perspectives are: a corporate perspective, stakeholder perspective
and conceptual perspective. He argues business-society relationships should not be
considered from a corporate-centric perspective exclusively, as stakeholders have a view
towards more of a network base within relational and process-orientated circumstances
(Andriof & Waddock 2002 cited by Steurer 2006 p56). A corporate perspective provides
the managerial approach of the focal organisation; the stakeholder perspective analyses
various relationships between stakeholders and how stakeholders try to influence the
focal organisation; the conceptual perspective explores some particular incidents and
business-stakeholder interactive practices which are tested against principles of
‘sustainable development’ or ‘common good’. The triple-perspective provides a more
comprehensive way to approach research subjects when evaluating stakeholder
relationships, therefore setting the theoretical context for this thesis too. The triple-
perspective typological approach underpins not only the empirical work carried out in
relation to the Chinese football industry but also naturally has a triangulated function to
enhance the data’s validity, and coupled with the three stakeholder relationship models
aforementioned, together they provide a solid analytical framework and theoretical
guidance for this study in its answers to research questions.

As Laplume et al (2008, p1173) state: “It (stakeholder theory) has received reasonable
attention in management fields and specialty niches, such as sports and recreation and
urban affairs, where researchers have tested and extended some stakeholder arguments”.
In terms of sports management, stakeholder theory can be used to identify an
organisation’s legitimate stakeholders; to determine the “stakes” of selected stakeholders;
to evaluate stakeholders’ relationships and their importance to the organisation; to
formulating an organisation’s business strategies relative to different stakeholders as well

60
as in monitoring the implementation of those strategies. The section below will gradually
discuss stakeholder theory and the football industry as well as further justify why the
framework of stakeholder theory is the appropriate approach for analysing the football
industry.

2.2.2c Theory implication and limitation


Stakeholder theory was developed from the field of strategic management and grew into
organisation theory (Clarkson 1995; Freeman 1984; Frooman 1999). However, its
empirical validity has not been established, as the theory questions the conventional
assumption of the corporation’s objectives of profit maximisation, which contradicts
some deeply rooted values (Jones 1995).

On the one hand, stakeholder theory developed to the term of maturity around the late
1990 with a significant increase in attention, on the other hand, it has always been under
attack from advocates of shareholder primacy (Laplume et al 2008). Jensen (2002) sees
stakeholder theory not only as an affront to traditional economic theory and research but
also can be employed by special interest groups who wish to use the firms’ resources for
their own benefits. Others argue that stakeholder theory exacerbates agency problems and
at the same time attempts to develop a ‘special’ moral theory as an alternative in the
business environment, in which stakeholder management is considerably difficult to
implement. In fact, implementation of stakeholder management creates mismanagement
as it enables managers to have more power to distribute shareholder wealth in
questionable ways (Gioia 1999, Laplume et al 2008, Humber 2002, Sundaram & Inkpen
2004).

From the perspective of practice, Gioia (1999) questions practicability and the “just do
the right thing” approach of stakeholder theory and argues that its ethical ground is not
credible enough to adequately represent its complex social and economic reality.
Moreover, it is not practicable for managers to weight all stakeholders’ interests equally
(Sundaram & Inkpen 2004). Having more than one objective function can create
confusion during the organisations’ decision-making process. An analysis of Laplume et

61
al (2008)’s study based on 179 articles, suggesting a lack of substantiating evidence of
stakeholder management “works” shows that the theory is delivering something less than
the claims made. Margolis and Walsh (2001) concluded their research based on 95
empirical studies by pointing out that any positive relationship between firms’ social
performance and financial performance needs to be treated with caution. Also Griffin and
Mahon (1997) state that no consensus exists between such a relationship of firms’ social
performance and financial performance as the conclusion of 51 studies over 25 years.

2.3 Stakeholder theory and the football industry


Many debates within corporate governance literature have centered on the shareholder
model and the stakeholder model. The shareholder model advocates individual
shareholder interest over and above other stakeholders in contrast to the stakeholder
model which places an emphasis on broader concerns and wider interests from different
stakeholder groups. Over the course of the last 20 years, governance in sport has been
given greater consideration due primarily to the increasing levels of commercialisation
and professionalisation.

Henry and Lee (2004) explain sport governance using three key approaches – systemic
governance, corporate (or organisational) governance and political governance. Systemic
governance concerns the academic and policy related business environment and the legal
framework. Organisational governance is a sports term of corporate governance used for
sporting organisations by Henry and Lee. They see sports organisations as having a wider
set of goals than traditional business firms and are concerned more with ethically related
business practices. Political governance refers to governing bodies and governments who
use laws, regulations and policies to direct sports development into desired paths. The
three approaches to governance are interrelated, with the latter two included in the
framework of systemic governance (ibid).

The stakeholder approach has become a trend for corporate governance development in
many industries - including sport. The stakeholder approach ensures sports are developed

62
with a balanced power structure and with the necessary transparent systems in place.
More importantly, decisions are made based on the interest of the majority of
stakeholders and for the best interest of sport. For instance, the creation of the Athletes’
Commission in the International Olympic Committee (IOC) provides a link between
active athletes and the IOC body. Similarly, the introduction of the European Club Forum
(ECF)8 within the UEFA structure aims to strengthen the relationship between European
clubs and the European football governing body. The implementation of stakeholder
theory in sports management helps sport organisations increase awareness in addressing
the needs of different stakeholders and thereby benefits the organisation’s overall goals
and long-term success. Governing bodies are in a privileged position to oversee the
interests of stakeholders and to promote balance among them, as Ducrey et al (2003,
p100) point out: “sports need an internal regulator to accommodate the interests of all
stakeholders involved, and the best institution to assume the role of regulator is the
governing body”.

Research into sports management has focused primarily on organisational theory and
subsequent studies have placed more emphasis on the efficiency and effectiveness of
sports organisations. Frisby (2005) suggests a more critical sports management research
strategy is needed, to avoid a narrow academic approach. The research needs to be more
concerned with the organisational goals and the wider interests of workers, athletes, and
volunteers, rather than just profit maximisation and the organisation’s overall efficiency.
In short, “stakeholder theory does not necessarily presume that managers are the rightful
locus of corporate control and governance” (Donaldson & Preston 1995, p67). It is
therefore relevant for the study of sports management to embrace stakeholder theory and
stakeholder values in order to better understand a range of issues from a wide variety of
stakeholder perspectives (Steurer, 2006).

Stakeholder theory can be used in sport management to identify an organisation’s


legitimate stakeholders; to determine their “stakes”; to evaluate a stakeholder’s
relationship and its importance to the organisation; to formulate an organisation’s

8
The ECF became the European Club Association (ECA) on 21 January 2008.

63
business strategies towards different stakeholders; and to monitor the implementation of
those strategies. Finally, stakeholder theory can be used to analyse the governance of
sports organisations (Walters, 2007).

The direct result of sports commercialisation is that the significant amount of money at
stake within professional sports has caused significant conflicts of interest between
different stakeholder groups and an unbalanced governance structure. Therefore proactive
thinking and actions are needed to fix the situation before it is too late. At the
international level, The creation of the Athletes’ Commission by the IOC in 1981; the
Professional Cycling Council (PCC) by the International Cycling Union (UCI) in 1999
and the ECF by UEFA in 2002, are good examples of how stakeholder initiatives have
been implemented by sports governing bodies to tackle conflicts of interest and
unbalanced governance structures in modern sports management. In the Chinese case, the
overarching research question of this study focuses on the impact of professionalisation
(commercialisation) on the governance and development of the Chinese football industry,
and employs stakeholder theory as the analytical framework to look at how football
governance in China reacts to the global implication at different levels.

The stakeholder approach helps a sports organisation to improve communication with its
stakeholders and take multiple interests into account in a decision-making process, so
minimising conflicts between stakeholders (Walters 2007, Ducery et al 2003). Moreover,
it also has been recognised in research focusing on the governance of the football
industry at both national and international levels. At the international level, Sugden (2002)
argues that access gained by the media and multinational corporations to football has
established their overriding influence in the global development and political control of
world football by becoming partners with FIFA and thereby transforming the game into
Network Football. Ducrey et al (2003), and Holt (2006, 2007) illustrate the complexity of
a stakeholder network in Europe, and how key stakeholders are able to influence the
game’s governance structure and how stakeholder management has been practiced by the
game’s governing bodies. “The ‘football business’ is not a passive player within the

64
network, rather it is a proactive and increasingly aggressive stakeholder” (Sugden 2002
p75 cited Conn 1997).

At the national level, Armara et al (2005) explain the different football governing
systems in five countries at national level within a stakeholder context, including China.
Having a similar approach, the first two sub-questions of this study focuses on the CFA
and national leagues, at this level and how these organisations facilitate football
professionalisation by utilizing stakeholder management in order to face new challenges.
Stakeholder theory addresses business-society relations, and the new forms of football
governance (made up of a network of stakeholders), exemplify the trend in football
development. Boon (2000) depicts a ‘hub and spoke’ stakeholder diagram at football club
level and illustrates the need for clubs to build mutually beneficial relationships with their
stakeholders. Walters (2007) presents a stakeholder map from a football club-centric
perspective. In this study, the sub-questions three, four and five look at the development
of football governance with a more balanced approach at the club level from clubs, as
well as fans’ and players’ perspectives respectively. The stakeholder analysis provides
not only industrial insights and a bigger picture of its governance development but also
unveils different stakeholder relationships within the Chinese football industry. Just as
Steurer (2006) argues the full spectrum of business-society relations should be looked at
from various points of view, therefore, stakeholder management can be approached from
the corporate, the stakeholder, and the conceptual perspectives simultaneously.

Especially within the football industry, without the revenue generated by elite
competitions, the whole football system would collapse. In the new network based
governance model, governing bodies are no longer capable of dictating to their own
sports, furthermore, without the co-operation of major stakeholders, they will not be able
to successfully carry out the task of developing the sport. This key shift in the way that
sport is organised has been explained by Henry and Lee’s (2004) systemic governance
approach, and such a shift is, in part a reflection of sports globalisation and commercial

65
development trends. The recent governance crisis of FIFA9 demonstrates that lack of an
inclusive approach and transparency at the decision-making level can damage integrity of
the game; and the modern football industry certainly needs to be placed under
examination from a number of different stakeholder perspectives.

Due to the emergence in the field of large commercial sponsors, investors, agents, civil
regulatory bodies as well as illegitimate betting organisations and criminal individuals,
the top-down traditional model has developed to a stakeholder interacted neo-liberal
model, demonstrating a systemic governance shift. The vertical channels of authority
have gradually transformed to a structure of network governance (Henry and Lee 2004,
Garcia 2011, Rhodes 1997, Holt 2007). As a result, the implications of the new forms of
systemic governance have been clear - significant policy changes can only be achieved
by negotiations between a wide range of stakeholders in the network. In this study,
football governance in China has also raised the same concerns from governance crisis of
the governing bodies and corruption at different levels which involved CFA officials,
club management and players. Despite both the government and the CFA launched
stakeholder initiatives in order to improve governance standards and to clear up the
overall football environment, the final result remains to be seen. The sub-question
number six explores those challenges facing the Chinese game with further discussions
based on research findings.

In a nutshell, it is evident that the football governance model has been shifting at both
macro and micro levels, globally, continentally, and nationally. As a result, the
stakeholder approach has been widely recognised as an appropriate framework for the
analysis of football governance at different levels both theoretically and practically. As
Morrow (2000, 2003) states that the stakeholder concept has greater relevance for the
football industry due to the particular features of certain stakeholders and their demands
for accountability. The organisational perspective of sport governance is clearly
interrelated to business ethics. Henry and Lee (2004) discuss the connection from seven

9
A series of bribery allegations involving some FIFA executive members during the process of the World
Cup bid (2018/2022) and its Presidential election campaign that left the world football governing body’s
reputation at an all-time low.

66
key principles – transparency, accountability, democracy, responsibility, equity,
effectiveness and efficiency. All these principles are in effect normative ethical
guidelines, providing a checklist on how sport organisations should operate. Echoing the
good practice principles of corporate governance mentioned previously.

2.4 Football governance and Europeanisation


In terms of European political governance, the EU steers European sport development
rather than through direct action and control (Henry and Lee 2004). On the one hand, the
EU project and the single market create new opportunities for industrial transformation
and cross-border mergers. On the other hand, the EU seeks to protect the new European
values and principles through various forms of European social policy and laws as the EU
does not want to see sport ‘subverted’ by commercial abuse, reflecting the moral concern
of political governance (Niemann et al 2011, Henry and Lee 2004). The most notable EU
contribution to the transformation process of football was highlighted by two cases – the
Bosman ruling and broadcasting policies.

European football has experienced a remarkable transformation as a result of both EU


policies and economic market forces over the past two decades. The game’s strong
commercial and economic developments influence its governance development at the
domestic level. This has not been perceived as only “one way traffic” in the process, and
such a development pattern of Europeanisation is described by Niemann et al (2011) as
top-down and bottom-up. In other words, European football development at the state
level does not just passively absorb European level pressure (legally binding EU policies)
as local political and cultural elements also play important roles shaping the game
domestically.

Before the Bosman ruling in 1995, players were traditionally employed under the
registration and transfer systems in their respective governing bodies with nationality
quotas applied to each club. Although the Fédération Internationale des Associations de

67
Footballeurs Professionnels (FIFPro)’s legitimacy is recognised by FIFA and UEFA,
players have been fighting for more rights in the decision-making process at the national
level. For example, in England, the retain and transfer system existed, even though the
‘retain’ aspect was modified after 1963 and the ‘transfer’ aspect remained until 1995. In
France, clubs could tie up players until the age of 35 (Lanfranchi & Taylor 2001); in
Spain, a right to retain system also existed. Despite some small differences around
transfer rules in different counties, transfer fees were normally required when players
changed their clubs, even when their contacts had expired. Moreover, nationality quotas
applied for foreign players in different European domestic leagues. Such practices
prevented the free movement of players until 1995 when Jean Marco Bosman won his
personal case at of the European Court of Justice (ECJ). At the political governance level,
the verdict sent a clear message that sport was regarded as an area of trade (Henry & Lee
2004). Gammelsӕter & Senaux (2011, 2013) refer to governance as government which
entails the notion that a governing body defines its domain by competing, adjusting and
cooperating with other organisations. The outcome of the Bosman case forced UEFA
(even FIFA) to abide with EU law and weakened the sport’s own regulatory bodies by
restricting their abilities to control the sport.

Out-of-contract transfer fees were abolished soon after the ECJ’s decision, which
demonstrated the impact of political governance from the ‘top-down’ direction. By
contrast, transfer systems have been amended gradually at the national level as more
national factors have contributed to this ‘bottom-up’ modification in different countries
(Garcia et al 2011). During the transformation process, even the top state politicians
campaigned for a steady restructuring. For instance, a joint statement was issued by the
British Prime Minster, Tony Blair and the German Chancellor, Gerhard Schröder in 2000
to express their concerns over a radical change in the football governance system without
proper consideration of the game’s own peculiarity and cultural backgrounds in different
countries (Brand & Niemann 2011).

68
The Bosman ruling also brought down the nationality quota that existed in the EU
members, as the ECJ saw such regulations discriminated against players from EU states.
As the market became liberalised, more foreign players joined the top European leagues
for better financial rewards. By January 2014, they were 60.4% foreign players in the
Premier League compared to eleven foreign players in 1992 (Gibson 2014, Grant 2004).
In the 2007/8 season, 33.4% foreign players played in French leagues, and the figures
were 46.5% for Germany and 36.5% for Italy (Ranc & Sonntag 2011). In terms of
‘bottom-up’ response, the UK government responded in 1999 and changed work permit
rules for non-EU nationals who would need to have played in 75% of their countries’
‘competitive’ international matches in the previous two years in order to play in the UK
professional leagues. In Germany, the restriction was lifted not only for EU nationals but
also expanded to players from UEFA member states. However, the ruling was applied to
the top two Bundesliga tiers only. The French and Spanish leagues had a tradition of
employing foreign players before the Bosman ruling. Subsequently, the ECJ’s decision
has not led to a significant increase of foreign players in both countries compared to other
major European leagues (ibid).

The broadcasting sector has also transformed European football significantly. Alongside
the gradually enlarged European market, state monopoly of the broadcasting industry in
each member state could not be maintained. As private providers entered the market,
many commercial media corporations have seen live football as their core business
models for revenue generation, a practice that consequently transformed the football
industry in Europe. As a result, broadcasting rights have become the largest revenue
source for football. Since EU intervention is less constraining on how national governing
bodies sell their TV rights, both the collective selling model and the individual selling
model exist in different countries.

The EPL model is based on TV money, especially for networks who aim to attract
subscribers to sign up for their services. The sale of rights is centralised and shared by all

69
Premier League clubs in England. The domestic right of EPL was sold exclusively to
BSkyB from 1992. However, the practice was challenged by the European Commission,
arguing this was a monopoly on TV rights. Therefore, the domestic right had to be split
into several packages from 2007, with at least one package having to go to a different
broadcaster.

The EPL, the German Bundesliga, the French Ligue 1 and many other countries also
employ the collective selling system. The collective selling model ensures more balanced
revenue distribution and survival of the financially weaker clubs (Brand & Niemann
2011). By contrast, TV rights of Spanish, Portugal La Liga and Italian Serie A are sold by
each club individually. Such a model creates a clear revenue difference between big clubs
and small clubs, which is more likely to reduce the leagues’ overall competitive balance
and financial transparency. Although the European Commission does not directly prevent
clubs doing deals with broadcasters individually, at the national level, the Spanish
government plans to introduce a new law that will give the league control over the
collective selling of TV rights. The ultimate aim is to improve competitive balance and
governing standards. For the same reason, in Italy, from the 2010/11 season, Serie A
negotiated a deal collectively worth over €900m per annum (Deloitte 2011). In fact, sport
was considered as a special commodity in 1997 when the EU introduced Television
without Frontiers to protect European citizens’ access to selected sport events on
terrestrial TV. This included football tournaments such as the FIFA World Cup, and the
UEFA European Championship (Henry and Lee 2004).

The transformation of European football is due to a combination of different factors; it is


the combination of systemic governance, organisation governance and political
governance, with economic market forces playing the most significate role in the process
(Henry and Lee 2004, Niemann et al, 2011). As Garcia et al (2011) state, football
Europeanisation touches on some serious EU issues, such as freedom of movement,
migration policy and competition policies. The top-down dimension has greatly

70
liberalised the labour market by abolishing nationality quotas within the EU states. This
has resulted in a fundamental change of the transfer system (Parrish 2011). The bottom-
up dimension has shown that individual states have not taken EU policies as given, as
certain counter-measures have been employed by national football associations to
mitigate the top-down impact. In a nutshell, despite football Europeanisation in its
various forms in different countries, the transformation reflects the EU single market
development, based on market principles and neo-liberal ideology. As Gammelsӕter &
Senaux (2013, p159) state: “the transformation in Europe football came out of largely
intended political, cultural and socio-economic transformation of the society.” Moreover,
different countries offer different models of football governance; as the most important
global football force in the modern era, national differences are not simply domestic as
they can be imitated elsewhere in the world.

2.5 The peculiarity of the football industry requires the stakeholder approach
A monopoly position is the ideal market position for a firm in a conventional business to
maximise its profit. However, it is not one which would yield any progress or efficiency.
Therefore it is a position which is unlikely to be achieved in most developed capitalised
countries, where competition law and regulations are set in place to prevent a single
firm’s monopoly or dominance. In the case of football, a monopoly position cannot be
achieved by the individual clubs themselves. However, a natural monopoly does appear
when you take account the fact that all clubs in a sporting league will be working
cooperatively in order to produce league games.

Nevertheless, there are differences between professional sport leagues in America and
Europe, and in terms of operation, they have many things in common. Neale (1964)
argued that professional league sports have a strong tendency towards monopoly and a
single league structure. League sport is a unique market in that a total monopoly is
unthinkable - competitors are needed in order to prosper. Ultimately, it is the uncertainty
of match outcome that adds so much attractiveness to a league, and hence the need for
competitions (Meier 2005, Madrigal 1995). Because of league sports firms collectively

71
produce a joint product - league matches, a single club alone cannot do so. Ultimately, it
needs other clubs in order to secure its own existence. In a rather counter-intuitive sense,
on the one hand, teams are competing for resources and market dominance but at the
same time they also cooperate together in order to produce matches. In effect, the league
becomes the monopoly firm; it becomes the decision-making unit for all the teams within
it. The decisions are joint ones, and will affect all members that fall within its umbrella
(Mason 1999). Because the business of sport is a peculiar one in both production and
consumption, as a result, it has always been highly regulated (Scully 1995, Meier 2005).

The challenges of corporate governance in sports, especially in team sports, are


substantially different from other conventional businesses. The section below uses the
English football industry as an example to provide a better understanding of the relevance
of stakeholder theory and football governance.

At the club level, the nature of a football club has two objectives – winning on the pitch
and making profits. However, most clubs in England have been been as loss-making
entities for a considerable time, and there are no clear signs to indicate this situation will
change in the foreseeable future. Sloane (1971) argues that compared to other
conventional enterprises, football clubs are less profit oriented, performance on the pitch
often overweighs clubs’ financial interest, and that clubs are utility maximisers rather
than profit maximisers. In terms of governance control, agency theory emphasises
shareholders’ investment return and firms’ profit maximisation. By contrast, stakeholder
theory emphasises firms’ overall well being, sustainable development and balanced
stakeholder interest. Therefore stakeholder theory provides an ideal framework to analyse
corporate governance in football clubs as utility maximisers, as well as social and cultural
institutions.

McMaster (1997) even argues that the economic features of the professional football
clubs do not point to any agency problems. For instance, in terms of on field performance,
players and coaching staff have an interest which aligns with their clubs’ success, as it is
a performance link with their reputation as well as market valuation. Moreover, despite

72
players’ performance being assessed on the basis of team success, each individual’s
contribution is easy to judge, and therefore playing staff are unlikely to shirk or to take a
free ride (ibid).

In addition, supporters are a special type of customer. Their loyalty to a particular club is
different compared with normal customers’ loyalty to a particular brand of product in a
conventional business. Most fans are life-long supporters of a particular club and this
special relationship leaves them in a vulnerable position to clubs’ financial exploitation.
Therefore, fans deserve special consideration in football governance and their demands
need to be addressed.

On the one hand, most English clubs are privately owned companies. Although the chief
executives may have considerable authority, club owners have the true power, therefore
the typical agency issues arising from separation of ownership and controls do not apply
(Farquhar et al, 2005). On the other hand, for publicly owned clubs, utility maximisation
still applies. However, as social institutions, underperforming financial results and
shareholder dissatisfaction are unlikely to trigger clubs’ owners to sell their shares or
allow takeover bids from other investors (Szymanski & Hall, 2003). Club owners have
greater non-economic objectives for owning clubs, and there is a lack of a market for
corporate control in football (Farquhar et al, 2005).

Football clubs are organised in a league structure, consisting of several tiers of


professional leagues and armature leagues with promotion and relegation throughout the
hierarchy. The whole system of football governance demonstrates a particular form of
mutual interdependency and cohesion within the football industry, which could be
viewed as a network arrangement, and so requiring a model of network governance and a
stakeholder approach to analyse it (Sloane 1971, Farquhar et al 2005, Szymanski 1997).

For instance, within the English football network, there has been a widening of the
revenue gap between the Premier League clubs and the Football League clubs. The
growth of inequality has caused serious concerns not only about the integrity of the game,

73
but also clubs’ overspending tendency in both the Premier League and the Football
League. Moreover, the number of clubs entering into administration in the recent years
indicates financial problems with English clubs and also suggestes that the football
industry needs to be better governed. The increased financial inequality between clubs
decreases the structural stability of leagues (Farquhar, et al, 2005). In order to address the
financial inequality and sustainable development issues, the Premier League distributed
£189.4m in the 2011/2 season to other stakeholders outside the league – including
solidarity packages and parachute payments (Gibson, 2013).

Alongside further commercialisation, good communication between different


stakeholders became an important issue to address their relationships for existing models
of corporate governance in the football industry at all levels. Such governance
relationships include international relationships between different governing bodies,
between international law and courts; domestic relationships between national governing
bodies and clubs, between clubs and supporters and so on. In this network based
governance structure, stakeholders are interdependent and the stakeholder approach is
essential for each individual stakeholder to cooperate in order to underpin the balance of
the whole governance system.

2.6 Summary
A stakeholder approach unveils the bilateral relationship not only between principal and
agent, but also more the complex relationships amongst other stakeholders. Compared to
agency theory, a stakeholder approach can penetrate deeper into areas concerning
stakeholder motivation and the way they manage their relationships with other
stakeholders. Especially in the football industry, football clubs, leagues and FAs are
organisations which have more varied aims than solely shareholder maximisation.
Therefore, when analysing the relationship between different stakeholders in order to
gain a better understanding of the industry, stakeholder theory is a more suitable
approach.

74
This chapter provides the overview of the current literature on corporate governance,
with a particular focus on agency theory and stakeholder theory. It draws particular
attention to stakeholder theory as it underpins the principal analysis of this thesis. The
justification for doing so was discussed during the chapter and research questions were
linked to literature review. The literature line was drawn based on the general field of
corporate governance in sports and the football industry. Reviewed works of Szymanski,
Hamil and Oughton provide a comprehensive overview of the modern football
governance - in terms of its financial, social and economic underpinning. The next
chapter will review the concept in the Chinese case.

75
Chapter Three: Chinese Economy and Sports Development

3.1 Brief history of the Chinese economy and sport development since 1949
This chapter outlines the development patterns in the Chinese economy and sport since
the establishment of communist China, setting an overall background for the thesis. It
aims to provide a bigger picture for readers to gain a better understanding of the football
industry within the Chinese context.

Communist China’s influence in the world economy was minor until the late 1980s.
Since the Chinese government adopted the ‘open door’ policy launching economic
reform in the later 1970s, China’s economy has been growing rapidly for 30 years with
an average annual growth rate around 10 percent, including during the recent financial
crisis, with growth still continuing at a strong pace (World Bank 2011).

In December 1978, the Third Plenum of the 11th Congress of the Central Committee of
the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) marked a watershed in communist China’s 60-year
economic development history. The government adopted economic reform policies and
declared that the top priority was economic reconstruction and achievement of the Four
Modernisations 10 by the end of the 20th century. Reform policies set a clear goal for
China’s economic development, despite its gross domestic product (GDP) per person
remaining small, with the latest data showing China already becoming the world’s second
biggest economy in 2010 (ibid).

3.1.1 The pre-reform era


The CCP was a fully Marxist party, when it took power in 1949, its priority was solving
economic problems that had worsened since the Second World War and the Chinese
Civil War (1946-1949). However, economic development was further delayed by the
Korean War (1950-1953). By the early 1950s, in material terms, China was very poor, its
agriculture sector produced about 50 percent of GDP and provided 80 percent of

10
Industry, agriculture, defence, science and technology modernisations

76
employment, which posed great challenges for a social transition to an industrial
economy (Bramall, 2009). Per capita GDP in 1953 was $552, by 1955 it was still a little
below the 1937 level11 (Davies et al, 1994; Maddison, 2003).

At the beginning of the communist era, most of the industrial resources and distribution
facilities were still in private hands, which the new government could not take over
immediately, therefore private enterprises were permitted in the interest of production,
but would be subject to government control (Hughes & Luard 1959). As centralised
management and control of the national finances were introduced, the government not
only controlled the profits generated in industry but also controlled the allocation and
pricing of the outputs and inputs of industry, both of state-owned and privately owned
enterprises (Gabriel, 1998b). According to Premier Zhou Enlai, capitalism was only
utilised to rebuild the economy, and it would be finally merged into communism
(Spencer, 1999).

When the first Five-Year Plan (1953-1957) was announced, development priority was
given to heavy industry. Mao Zedong believed the best way to finance industrialisation
was for the state to take total control of agriculture, thereby ‘collectivisation’ was made
mandatory in the countryside, farmers being obliged to work in the communes, and all
the surplus generated was under the control of the state (Kueh 2006). Jing (2009) argues
that collectivisation failed to provide incentives to farmers. Despite Mao indicating that
the economic transition period (from a mixed model to the socialist model) was a long
process, by 1956, the mixed economy had changed into a highly-centralised planned
economy, and collectivisation was completed in both the countryside and urban areas.

The central plan provided an expedient means for raising revenue and controlling
inflation (Gabriel, 1998a). Official data suggested that the growth rate was encouraging
and performance was far superior compared to that of the republican era (Bramall, 2009).
As a result, the first Five-Year plan basically achieved its goals. Unfortunately, Mao took
these achievements for granted and launched an even more aggressive Second Five-Year

11
A full scale Japanese invasion occurred in 1937.

77
Plan (the Great Leap Forward (GLF)), which was scheduled for 1958-1963. The plan set
unrealistic targets for both industrial and agricultural sectors, as Mao assumed that high
productivity could be achieved by a massive supply of manpower without the need for a
big investment by the state (Kueh 2006). In reality, collectivisation provided no incentive
for the farmers in the countryside, and was coupled with a series of natural and human-
made disasters, which resulted in large-scale famines throughout the country from 1959
to 1962. Consequently, there was no appreciable surplus from the countryside for the
government to sustain its rapid industrialisation: the growth was simply unsustainable,
the GLF failed miserably, with the resulting loss of tens of millions of lives as the failure
affected China in the years that followed (Li 1998).

The period between 1963 and 1978 is viewed as a coherent whole as its key structures
and policies were kept consistent to ensure the non-restoration of capitalist - collective
farming and state agencies were to meet peoples’ basic needs in both the countryside and
the urban areas respectively (Bramall, 2009). Bramall argues (2009) that during this
period, Mao attempted to transform the superstructure 12 of society rather than being
desperate to retain his power. This process kicked-off from the Socialist Education
Movement (SEM) in May 1963, and was followed up by the Cultural Revolution in 1966.
The SEM initially sought to curb corruption in the countryside, however it became a
movement to purge cadres. The Cultural Revolution was used by Mao to insist on
enforcement of his orthodox Marxist ideology and at the same time to crush people13 who
were taking ‘the capitalist road’. The movement plunged both the education and the
political system into deep chaos, eventually leading to widespread social violence and
persecution. As much economic activity was halted, GDP growth (indexed to 1990 prices)
per annum was only 5.1%, per capita reached only 2.6%, and 250 million people lived
below the poverty line (ibid). These figures are rather shameful considering China’s low
starting point in 1949, as a result, Mao’s initial economic development strategy – to
tackle the inequalities between urban and rural areas through industrialisation were not
realised. The whole period is now considered as a ‘lost time’ for economic development.

12
The sum of the system of law and government, the process of cultural production and ideology (Bramall
2009, p171)
13
The pragmatists such as Liu Shaoqi and Deng Xiaoping.

78
3.1.2 Deng’s economy reform
Since 1978, China has been engaged in a massive transformation of its economy,
gradually dismantling the command economy. Deng Xiaoping realised that China cannot
be self-limited by orthodox Marxism, and Mao’s development model was gradually
abandoned. Deng knew the Chinese-Soviet system was poorly structured for entering the
global economy, and he was convinced that excessive bureaucratic control stifled
changes and efficiency (Lieberthal 1995). Deng (1980) stated: “our leading organs at
various levels have taken charge of many matters which they should not or cannot handle
effectively. These matters could have been easily handled by the enterprises, institutions
and communities at grass-roots level”. As such, it was necessary to decentralise power
and control in order to encourage the adoption of market principles.

As Marx argued that capitalism had to precede socialism, so Mr Deng invented the phase
‘primary stage of socialism’ to serve as the substitute for capitalism within the Chinese
context, which provided the theoretical framework to underpin China’s economical
experiment. In the development period of this “primary stage of socialism”, a range of
material incentives and social inequalities were recognised as necessary elements for
raising productivity (Bramall, 2009).

The reform started in the countryside in 1979. Individual economic family farming units
were encouraged, and the collective farming model was gradually abolished with
communes eventually being terminated in 1985 (Gabriel, 1998a). Grain output shot up
from 303 million tonnes in 1978 to 407.3 million tonnes in 1984, with application of new
technology and fertilisers, achieving the 500 million tonnes mark by the late 1990s
(China Statistical Yearbooks, 2009). The real per capita growth rate of farmers’ income
reached 15 percent per annum between 1978 - 1984, which created conditions for growth
of township/village enterprises and capitalist social relationships amongst farmers
(Gabriel, 2006). In the urban industrial sector, the government gradually devolved control
over surpluses and enterprises were allowed to trade a proportion of surplus outside the

79
state plan once they had met the state targets. Despite decision-making and fiscal power
being decentralised, price-setting remained in state hands14.

After 1982, controls on private industry were relaxed, and price controls were lifted. As
Deng (1985, p152) stated: “It is clear now that the right approach is to open up to the
outside world, combine a planned economy with a market economy and introduce
structural reforms”. By 1987, the private sector was legalised as a ‘complement’ to the
public sector, and became a component part of the socialist economy (Su 2009). When
the ‘contract system’ was introduced, it signalled the first step towards creation of a
capitalist labour market.

Before 1992, China only partially integrated into the world economy, its tariffs remained
high and the private sector remained small. The phase of the “socialistic market
economy” kicked in after Deng’s ‘spring tour’ to southeast China in 1992. Den urged
pushing reform forwards in order to increase the growth rate, however the socialist status
quo had to be secured by means of authoritarianism and state ownership of the key
industries (Bramall, 2009). The tour made a big impact both politically and socially, and
against this backdrop, the fourteenth Congress of the CCP called for the establishment of
the “modern enterprise system”, and the government introduced the Western corporate
governance concept to promote modern management and to improve the performance of
state owned enterprises. As a result, the labour market was mobilised and transferred to a
capitalist model, and SOEs were floated on the financial markets, which dramatically
accelerated China’s rate of integration into the world economy. A further integration was
achieved by China became a full member of World Trade Organisation (WTO) in 2000.

The volume of foreign direct investment (FDI) being attracted into China increased
significantly, and China was receiving more FDI than any other country by 2003 (World
Bank 2005, p342/3). Foreign-invested enterprises contributed 58% to exports in 2005
(Chan et al 1999), when foreign trade was worth $851billion (Zhang, 2005), both factors
being important elements for Chinese economic growth.

14
State Bureau of Commodity Prices still exits even today.

80
1953 the 1990 set
First up
Five- Shanghai 1994 set the
1966 The Company 2000
Year Cultural stock joined
Law
Plan Revolution exchange WTO

1949 1958 1979 the 1992 Deng’s ‘spring


Controlled Aggressive ‘Open door’ tour’ pushed reform
national the Second policy; forwards for “Socialist
finance; Five-Year Collective Market Economy”;
enacted Plan (the farming was 14th Congress of the
collectivi- Great Leap gradually CCP called for
sation Forward) abolished establishing ‘modern
enterprise system’

3-1 Chronological chart – Economic & political policy

3.1.3 Summary
The first 30 years of Chinese economic development under the communist rule achieved
a little in terms of both GDP growth and improvement in peoples’ living standard. The
backwardness in the 1950s was simply due to the process of recovery from the Second
World War and the Civil War; the slow development pace from late 1950s to late 1970s
was due to a combination of its own closeness to the world, the Western embargo, and
more importantly, Mao’s disaster policies of the GLF and the Cultural Revolution. By
1978, the per capita income of farmers was ¥133, which had increased by 1.8 percent
compared to 1952; per capita grain output in 1977 was roughly the same as 1957 (Huang,
1998, p35). China accounted for less than one percent of the world economy in 1978, and
total foreign trade was worth only $20.6billion (Zhang, 2005).

By contrast, Deng’s open door policy, the Four Modernisation Programme, and
establishment of Special Economic Zones are testimony to his own theory – the socialist
state with Chinese characteristics, which has been the engine for Chinese economy
growth for the last 30 years. The Chinese economy now stands in a different league

81
compared to the pre-reform era. In the agricultural sector, grain output reached 528
million tonnes in 2008 (China Statistical Yearbooks, 2009). According to the World Bank
data for 2008, China’s GDP reached $4.33 trillion and accounted for more than seven
percent of the world economy. China’s total foreign trade was $2.1 trillion in 2009 (CIA
World Factbook).

Despite the consistent growth of capitalism, the bulk of the industrial sector remained in
the hands of the state. The phase of ‘primary stage of socialism’ does not feature in
Marxian theories, and China interprets Marxism with flexibility in order to fit its
economic transformation. Development involves costs, however it is difficult to argue
that costs outweighed the benefits, therefore the government is being careful in how far it
goes in deregulating markets to ensure economic growth in a sustained fashion. As the
transactions from planned economy to market economy is always likely to generate social
problems, Chinese leaders considered it was necessary to keep a certain degree of control
over these process of transitions by behaving in a risk-averse manner with risk aversion.
Mr Deng’s phrase depicts it as: – Crossing the river by feeling for stones.

3.2 Corporate governance in China


Corporate governance is a developing concept in China. Chinese economic reforms
began in the late 1970s and its economic structure gradually took shape shortly
afterwards. The Chinese economy made gradual institutional changes towards a market-
oriented system by accepting some capitalist concepts and values. However, the Western
concept of “property rights” was never properly altered from its traditional Marxist
ideology and communist values (Clarke & Du 1998). One of the main goals of Chinese
reform was to establish a corporate governance system which could provide incentives
for investment, adequately restrain and monitor management, and promote the optimal
use of resources for wealth creation (Chen, 2003). In 1990, China set up a stock exchange
in Shanghai, and became the first communist state to do so. The stock exchange triggered
ownership reform and a process by which the separation between government and
enterprise could be realised. In the early 1990s, a wide range of reforms were introduced

82
in the state owned sectors and by the end of 1998 24,000 - 10.1% of state owned
enterprises (SOEs) had been either privatised or corporatised (People’s Daily, 1999).

3.2.1 The law and regulation framework


Law and regulation are essential for corporate governance as it defines the
responsibilities of stakeholders in firms, and shapes the way firms should be controlled
and run (Liu 2005). The legal framework of corporate governance in China is based on
1994 Company Law. This legislation specifies two types of company, the limited liability
company and the stock listed company. Both types signal the transition to a ‘socialist
market economy’ (Kirby, 1995). Another major legal development was the 1999
Securities Law, which aimed to regulate the trading of securities. Both these laws set the
basic operational structure to ensure a fair, healthy and lawful relationship between firm’s
stakeholders. Company Law has the purpose of promoting effectiveness and efficiency
by accepting the Western concept of a ‘company’ and promoting the growth of an
independent non-state sector. Nonetheless, despite this, it does not completely embrace a
capitalist understanding of property ownership. Even though the Chinese economic
model has moved away from the traditional Marxist one, the authorities have maintained
aspects of socialist ideology.

According to Clarke (2003), research into corporate governance in China tends to focus
on SOEs and listed companies, in which agency issues are almost exclusively the subject.
Liu (2005) argues the system of law and institution is not complete in developing
countries, and China is certainly no different. On the one hand, the Chinese government
wants SOEs to be run effectively; on the other hand, it does not want these firms to
develop into solely profit-oriented enterprises. Therefore, the government maintains full
or controlling ownership in key industries and large firms. By contrast, in less important
sectors and relatively small enterprises, the government tends to relax its control.

With the introduction of Western capitalism in China, the government brought in a


UK/US board room structure to many of its companies (Chen, 2003). According to 1994

83
Chinese Company Law, the number of Directors on the Board should between 5 and 19,
and the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC, 2001) requires listed
companies to have at least one third of their board of directors independent. However, in
contrast to recommendations of the Financial Reporting Council in the UK, it is common
practice that one individual combines the two key organisational roles - Board Chairman
and General Manager/CEO. In addition, directors are normally from a holding company
or appointed by the government. The CSRC (2001) code is enforced by the government
department – CSRC and the State Economic and Trade Commission (SETC). Compared
to the UK, “it is more a question of regulations rather than a matter of market-led
principles or recommendation” (Chambers, 2005, p100).

By combining the roles of Chairman and CEO, which seems to increase a firm’s
efficiency, it also weakens the function of Directors as checks on CEO power. From a
Western perspective, close ties between directors and management can lead to conflicts
of interest and prevent the board from undertaking its role as a mechanism for monitoring
accountability. The Cadbury Report (1992), Higgs Report (2003) and the latest UK
Corporate Governance Code (2010), suggested a greater role and involvement for
independent non-executive directors during the decision-making process in order to
protect the interests of all shareholders.

The Company Law reflects the state’s willingness to impose a Western corporate
governance approach on its enterprises by structuring the board size and regulating the
amount of reinvestment of profits. However, there are still no regulations governing the
internal structure of a company’s subsidiary, nor does it provide a clear indication of how
shareholders can effectively act together against incompetent directors. Indeed, “The
Company Law speaks only of a duty of loyalty, it is far from clear that shareholders
could successfully sue for a breach” (Clarke, 2003 p504).

There are several features of Chinese economic reform which are related in the context of
the corporate governance system.

84
 China’s approach to corporate governance was limited to its ideological position.
The transition from a planned economy to a market-orientated economy was
adopted as a solution for promoting effectiveness and efficiency for its state
owned enterprises, however for the state, collectivist and socialist values
remained essential features.

 In terms of ownership reform, for small to medium SOEs, privatisation did take
place, with large SOEs, there was systematic corporatisation.

 In the Chinese stock market, shares of listed, large SOEs often consist of three
parts: state owned shares, legal person15 owned shares and tradable shares. State
owned and legal person owned shares cannot be traded in the market. These
shares account for most of the capital, and therefore, technically the state remains
in control of the enterprises.

Although the state has varied its ownership structures in many Chinese firms, it has
nevertheless maintained its control over large SOEs and important sectors. For example,
SOEs issue a significant proportion of shares to the government when going public
(Cheung & Jiang 2010). As a result, a typical enterprise’s behaviour is often based on the
combination of non-market structures and market incentives. Indeed, Clarke (2003, p497)
states: “the policy of corporatisation does not involve a renunciation by the state of its
ambition to remain the direct owner of enterprises in a number of sectors, this ambition
makes no sense if profits are the only objectives”. It is the role of the state, not the market,
to control the development of corporate governance and its implementation as both the
major shareholder and regulator of the firm simultaneously (Liu, 2005).

3.2.2 Corporate governance implementation


The system of Chinese corporate governance depends on its institutional implementation.
The economic reform aims to separate corporate ownership and control, reducing
15
Defined as enterprises or economic entities with legal status, the state controls the legal person who in
turn controls the firm, so ultimate the owner is the state (Liu & Sun, 2005).

85
government interference in order to increase corporate efficiency. However, Clarke (2003)
questions the conflict of interest between the state as controlling shareholder and other
shareholders. The state can be seen as using its position to serve its own interests at the
expense of others.

According to Tam (2000) the corporate governance process in practice is dominated by


government ministries and the Chinese Communist Party (CCP). The involvement of the
state in enterprise has taken place at both central and local government levels, with
government appointed officials acting as the equivalent of the board of directors. This is
referred to as “state corporatism” by Qi (1992 cited by Kirby, 1995). Tam (2000) states
that state representatives are normally appointed to the board as directors to newly
formed corporations, therefore, the old links between government and enterprises are not
disconnected, and these directors are not capable of serving the broader stakeholder
interests. From a commercial point of view, there is doubt over the capability and skills
of the state appointed agents in understanding the complexity of real business activities.
Moreover, the executive managers are generally not subject to effective monitoring by
the board of directors, nor do they operate in a transparent and accountable manner (Tam,
2000; Liu & Sun, 2005). As Holstein (2008) describes the Chinese corporate governance
system - China is noise-free but biased, you can get a clear story but the story is not
always right.

Even though state ownership is spread across different shareholders, the government is
still in a dominant position with direct or indirect controls over large enterprises in key
sectors (Clarke 2003). Ong & Baxter (1999) argue that the state adopts a managerial
approach towards companies to ensure its power and control via centralised management
(state appointed directors). The directors of SOEs are neither shareholders’ agents nor
stakeholders’, but a formal extension of the state. Most decisions they put forward are
based on the interests of the state alone. Indeed, the Chinese government justifies its
interference on the basis that in any transitional economy, a certain degree of government
impetus can promote effectiveness and efficiency. Furthermore, “extensive Chinese state
control safeguards socialist objectives and prevents uncontrolled capitalism” (ibid, p48).

86
China’s corporate governance structure is modelled on the Anglo-American model (Tam
2000, Young 2010). It is a system based on a competitive external market with a strong
judical system. However, at this particular stage of development, the Chinese economy is
still in a transitional state and the government has not yet established the necessary social
institutions in order to successfully mirror the Anglo-American model. Therefore,
corporate governance restructuring has yet to yield a strong benefit from the transition. In
reality, shareholders – both the state and minor individuals - are unable to exercise their
control rights. Even the right to attend a general meeting is not necessarily guaranteed.
The Chinese corporate governance mechanism needs more effective representation of
state ownership, as well as institutional arrangements between stakeholders, for the
system to function properly. Clarke (2003) points out that in the matter of state ownership,
due to the absence of an ultimate owner, the state is practically incapable of monitoring
the enterprises. Furthermore, its agents lack incentives to perform their duties, as nobody
is entitled to any profit that the company makes (Clarke 2003, Conyon & He 2011). In
other words, because they’re not shareholders, they’re not entitled to benefit from any
profit increases.

In summary, the implementation of corporate governance under Chinese Company Law


was designed to dilute state ownership in order to promote economic efficiency and
effectiveness. Because of the ideological influence and the sharp differences in property
rights compared to the West, profit maximisation has never been a priority for the
Chinese state. In important sectors and large SOEs, the state can exercise its controlling
power either through a formal shareholder voting system (as a major shareholder) or
through an informal political influential system by infiltrating the board. Therefore, the
interests of minority shareholders are never served. Fang (2000, p40, cited by Clarke
2003, p500) made the point “The whole Company Law is pervaded with the attitude of
‘making decisions on behalf of the people’”. It gives too much power to controlling
shareholders, and as a result, the state can easily abuse its dominant position and exploit
the interests of minority shareholders.

87
3.3 Brief history of Chinese sports development since 1949
The word ‘sports’ in Chinese terms covers a wide range. It can mean physical exercise in
both a competitive and non-competitive sense, and it can also be understood as physical
education within the school system. Since the establishment of the PRC in 1949, the CCP
introduced a new governance philosophy, as Kolatch (1972, p75) explains: “Every
activity is defined as to how it will be conducted and as to what its exact role is within the
entire system”. Not surprisingly, Chinese sports was considered a part of the socialist
construction and deeply attached to socialist ideology.

Mao was a strong proponent of the value of sports and saw sports as a tool for ideological
education and national rejuvenation (Kanin, 1978). He believed the value of a highly
centralised sports programme can strengthen the physique of the Chinese people and
develop a strong national unity. Mao was keen to eliminate China’s weakness and earn it
respect in the modern world. When power changed hands, Mao had an opportunity to put
his philosophy into practice - improving people’s health and developing strong physical
ability in all Chinese people became a priority of the new government.

China has been a highly centralised country for thousands of years. The CCP inherited
this tradition and developed its own centralised administrative hierarchy. The CCP’s
governance system operates from the national level down to county and district level. In
the early days of the People’s Republic, the government worked hard in order to erase
China’s old image – the sick man of the Far East. As Mao believed that “the national
spirit was to be awakened by means of strenuous physical activity” (Kanin, 1978, p264),
the primary function of sports was to enhance the people’s fitness level.

In October 1949, the All-China Sports Federation was created, it was the only national
sports organisation with branches at the provincial, city and county levels (Wu & Que
1990). The Federation was responsible for development of physical culture within the
country, and it also functioned as “the Chinese Olympic Committee” until 1958. After the
creation of the National Physical Education and Sports Commission (NPESC) in 1952,

88
the All-China Sports Federation mainly focused on sports development in various
industries and trades (ibid).

3.3.1 The top-down administrative structure


The People’s Republic applies the Soviet model of highly centralised sports
administration. Before the reform era, the government funded all sports activities and
guided sports development with policies, decrees and plans, this practice enabling the
government to effectively utilise all the resources available in order to achieve its goals in
a relatively short period (Kanin, 1978).

The NPESC was at the top of the administrative hierarchy with ministry status under the
State Council. The NPESC also functioned as the association of all national sports
governing bodies with the power to appoint leaders of any individual sport governing
body, including its president. The first minister was Marshal Helong - concurrently a
Vice-Premier of the State Council, and a Vice-Chairman of the Central Military
Committee, a situation which demonstrated the importance of the NPESC in Chinese
political life (Wu & Que 1990). Following the creation of the NPESC, local commissions
were organised not only at the provincial, city and county levels but also in trade unions
and the army. The NPESC was responsible for guiding, developing and governing all
China’s sports activities at both elite and amateur levels. At the provincial, city and
county levels, local commissions played the same role within their geographical
boundaries. Although the local commissions were supervised by the NPESC, they were
part of their local governments and served local interests simultaneously.

Given this administrative structure, state policies could be easily implemented within the
sport system throughout the country. In terms of an individual sports, top level decisions
were reached down to lower administrative levels through the related governing bodies.

In the reform era, alongside Chinese economic development and political decentralisation,
the NPESC has been experiencing a series of changes in order to meet the demands of the

89
market-oriented economy. A major internal reconstruction took place in 1997, as a part of
political decentralisation and the State Council reform, which saw 40 ministries cut to 29
in early 1998, consequently, the NPESC no longer held ministry status, and was
downgraded to become the State General Sports Administration (SGSA). It delegated its
power to twenty16 newly created management centres, responsible for all training and
competitions in their sports at national level, and these twenty management centres
covered over eighty sports (Reekie, 1999b). Due to the SGSA having various training
centres for each sport, different national teams are managed directly by related
management centres or governing bodies under the market economy. For example, some
national teams’ athletes are accommodated on site and train together all year round as
they used to be, such as ping-pong, gymnastics; some teams are not, such as football, and
basketball.

Football Martial Art Boxing & Auto & Moto


Management Centre Management Centre Taekwondo Management Centre
Management Centre
Basketball Weight-lifting, Small Balls Bicycle & Fencing
Management Centre Wrestling & Judo Management Centre Management Centre
Management Centre
Volleyball Handball, Hockey, Climbing Swimming
Management Centre Baseball & Softball Management Centre Management Centre
Management Centre
Aqua Management Tennis Management Shooting & Archery Chess & Cards
Centre Centre Management Centre Management Centre
Gymnastic Fitness & Qi Gong Athletics
Management Centre Management Centre Management Centre
Ping-Pong & Winter Sports Aeronautical &
Badminton Management Centre Radio Models
Management Centre Management Centre
Table 3-1: All sports management centres under the SGSA (Source: the SGSA website)

16
The Football Management Centre was created under the NPESC in 1995, and the Basketball
Management Centre and the Volleyball Management Centre followed suit in 1996. The Fitness & Qi Gong
Management Centre, Auto & Moto Management Centre were created in 2001 and 2002 respectively.

90
3.3.2 Sports policies
The development of Chinese sports and sports policies mirror the Chinese socialist
society, in which political principles serve as guidelines. Mao’s sports policy had to be
aimed at mass sport, for the purposes of reeducation of the population and national
defence (Kanin 1978). As Mr Feng Wenpin, the inaugural president of the All-China
Sports Federation stated concisely: “the new physical culture to be national, scientific and
mass, the new democratic physical culture’s motto is to develop sports for people’s health,
new democratic construction, and the people’s national defence” (Kolatch, 1972, p88).

In the early days of the Mao era, when local PESCs were established throughout the
country at different levels, they effectively facilitated mass participation in both
traditional sports and western sports. Under Mao’s sports policy, on the one hand, the
authority paid attention to developing Chinese traditional sports, such as a simplified 24-
form Tai Ji Quan; yet on the other hand, the government also made big efforts to
popularise western sports, such as basketball and football. Furthermore, the National
Training Programme set up national standards 17 , encouraging all Chinese people to
advance their performance so as in turn to raise the national fitness level as a whole
(Kolatch 1972, Reekie 1999a).

On the international stage, sports policies were underpinned by ideological purpose.


Communist China stood with the Soviet Union in the early days of the Cold War, and
America cut off Chinese trade with the West to the maximum extent possible, especially
after the Korean War (Lieberthal, 1995). As a result, on the international stage,
opportunities for Chinese athletes to compete were limited to the Soviet Bloc countries,
and “Friendly First, Competition Second” was the leading guideline of Mao’s era.
Winning events was not prioritised, the process that brought Chinese athletes and their
opponents together being more important because “the Chinese recognise that their
opponents do not react with awe and admiration every time they are defeated” (Kanin,
1978, p267).

17
Standards for Master of Sports, 1st Class Sportsman, 2nd Class Sportsman, and 3rd Class Sportsman.

91
In terms of the Olympic Movement, China was battling with Taiwan (ultimately the
United States) over the legitimacy of the Chinese seat in the IOC. As both Taiwan
(Republic of China) and communist China (PRC) refused to accept the “Two Chinas”
policy18, the PRC did not participate in the Olympic Games, eventually, withdrawing
from the Olympic Movement in 1958.

The Sino-Soviet relationship turned sour from the early 1960s. At that time, China
focused developing relationships with “Third World” countries before the Cultural
Revolution, ties which were strengthened via the first Games of the Newly Emerging
Forces (GANEFO), held in Djakarta in 1964 (Whitby 1999). However, the GANEFO
movement was not able to continue, as both external and internal environments were
changing19.

As the Sino-American relationship improved after the Vietnam War, China gradually
came back to the international sport arena. After Mao’s death, Deng Xiaoping’s
flexibility and the “open door” policy led to China’s return to the IOC in 1979. Since then,
China has been fully engaged with the international community (ibid).

The new sports slogan “Break Out of Asia, Advance on the World” replaced the old
“Friendly First, Competition Second”, which characterised the direction of Deng’s policy
towards the development of elite sports. Moreover, the NPESC launched the Olympic
Strategy after the 1984 Los Angeles Games in order to further strengthen the national
system for competitive sports, and as a result, the NPESC spent 90 percent of its budget
on competition-related activities (Reekie, 1999a). For example, new steps were taken to
revamp the sports programmes, the National Games and long-term training schemes for
national teams in line with the Olympic Games (Ren, 1999, Yang et al, 2004). As Mr
Wu Shaozu – Minister of Sports (1990 – 2000) once claimed: “The highest goal of

18
Both Taiwan and Mainland China claimed that they were the only legal representative for the whole of
China and both parties refused the PRC and the ROC being recognised at the same time internationally.
19
Externally, a military coup in Indonesia in 1965, and Egypt (the planned host for the second GANEFO)
did not prepare for it, then, it involved in the 1967 Middle East War; Internally, China entered into the
Cultural Revolution.

92
Chinese sport is success in the Olympic Games. We must concentrate our resources on it.
To raise the our national flag at the Olympics is our major task” (Fan & Mangan, 2004,
p55).

On the one hand, the new policy had a positive impact in improving China’s performance
at the Olympic Games; one the other hand, it disadvantaged development of traditional
sports and non-Olympic events. Moreover, with limited investment available for mass
participation and sports popularisation, more people became spectators rather than
participants, generating debate on the purpose of sport development and the worthwhile
of gold medals.

In the 1990s, alongside governance decentralisation and separating the government


agencies from sports administration, there were corresponding changes to Chinese sports
organisations and sports policy. The Sports Law was promulgated in 1995, setting a new
framework of sports development (Theodoraki, 2004). As a result, the government
reduced its direct involvement and financial support to some elite sports. Individual
governing bodies were left to take more responsibility to develop their own sports as well
as to finance their programmes. Therefore sponsorship became an important element in
financing elite sports development. In addition, the sports lottery plan was given special
permission 20 to go ahead by the State Council in 1994, providing extra funding for
overall sports development (Liu, 2009).

3.3.3 Mass Participation


In 1950, Mao declared “Let health be first” at the First National Middle School
Conference (Li, 1956); in 1952, Mao officially called upon the Chinese people to
“promote physical culture and sports, and strengthen the physique of the people”. This
endorsement is often used in combination with the slogan “train the body, defend the
nation”, which clearly demonstrated Mao’s belief.

20
According to Chinese law, gambling is illegal.

93
In response to Mao’s call, the state introduced the first set of calisthenics in 1951, and it
was widely practiced in both urban and rural areas, with people engaging in “broadcast
exercises” every morning throughout the country. Moreover, the first National Training
Programme was devised in the early 1950s for schools, factories, farms and the army,
modifying the Soviet “Ready for Labour and Defence” scheme, but reflecting the
position in China at the time (Reekie, 1999a). As a result, the number of people involved
in regular exercise and sports activities increased significantly, and by 1956, nearly a
million people achieved standards set by the National Training Programme. Moreover,
efforts were made to promote sports amongst state employees, sports associations being
formed in trade unions, regular competitions organised, so that by the end of the 1950s,
there were more than four million active members (ibid).

Although the NPESC was responsible for overall sports development, school sports were
managed by the National Education Commission through its own vertical administration
at local levels. Physical culture was also regarded as an important means of education by
the CCP, as Mao pointed out in 1957 “Our educational policy must enable everyone who
gets an education to develop morally, intellectually and physically and become a cultured
socialist-minded worker” (Chen 1962, p98). Physical education classes are now
mandatory for Chinese students from primary schools to universities, and there are also
after-school programs available for further development. Apart from improving students’
fitness standard, sport has been used as a tool for ideological education. For example, the
Chinese PE curriculum places great emphasis on collective efforts and the virtue of unity,
students being required to prepare and collect equipment before and after class, which in
a way fosters their sense of morality and social responsibility (Xie, 1990).

The Cultural Revolution (1966-1976) put an end to all mass sports programmes
completely21, and it was not until 1971 that the number of people participating in regular
exercises started to pick up gradually. Mass participation boomed after the Cultural
Revolution, and it was partially encouraged by China’s full participation in the

21
The Cultural Revolution emphasised class struggle in stead of social development; Mao used the Cultural
Revolution to purge dissidents.

94
international arena. Foremost in this was the Chinese women’s volleyball team who won
the World Cup in 1981, and China’s outstanding performance in 1984 Olympic Games 22.
Traditional sports were also promoted by the state during this period, for example, Qi
gong – crane style spread rapidly throughout the country (Reekie, 1999a).

In the 1990s, rapid economic growth provided more opportunities for mass participation
to develop. On the one hand, the State Council launched the National Fitness Promotion
Programme in 1995, which has since been implemented throughout the country with
government financial support (Ren, 1999). On the other hand, with improved income and
the newly introduced five-day working week 23, people were more willing to participate in
sports activities, therefore business-oriented sports clubs emerged, providing privately-
funded facilities for public use.

3.3.4 Elite sports


Elite sports are based on a strong, multi-level sports training system directly supported by
the government through the sports commissions at all levels. The goal of each city and
district sports commission is to identify athletes to compete in the provincial games, and
each provincial commission to train the provincial team to compete at the National
Games. The NPESC is responsible for the Chinese national teams’ participation in
international competitions and the Olympic Games. Sports officials are judged according
to their teams’ standing in the respective medal tables.

Athletes are developed through a long process of training and selection in a Soviet style
pyramid structure. At the bottom of the pyramid structure, some primary and middle
schools possessing adequate facilities and strength in a certain sport are appointed as key
sport schools by their local sports commissions (Jones 1999a). In those key schools,
young athletes are trained after school hours by PE teachers under the supervision of
local sports commissions. Local sports commissions also have their own spare-time

22
The first PRC full participation. Boycotted by the Soviet Bloc, China came fourth in the medal table with
15 Gold, 8 Silver and 9 Bronze.
23
The five-day working week was gradually introduced in 1994.

95
sports schools staffed by full-time coaches. Better athletes selected from the same
catchment area are able to develop their skills in these spare-time sports schools. Key
sports schools and spare-time sports schools normally major in a single sport event only 24,
and form the base of the elite development pyramid.

In the middle of the fostering system, each provincial sports commission has a central
sports school. It is equipped with boarding facilities, and staffed by full-time coaches and
academic teachers. A provincial central sports school accommodates athletes from
various disciplines (like an Olympic training camp), each sports team selecting the best
athletes from key sports schools and spare-time sports schools within the provincial
boundary. Athletes study and train together25 for five or six days a week, and the best
athletes in a provincial sports school have opportunities to progress to the provincial team,
and becoming full-time athletes (Whitby,1999).

Provincial teams are at the top of the pyramid. Full-time athletes accommodated and paid
by their provincial sports commissions. The best athletes have opportunities to become
coaches following their careers as active sportsmen. National teams select their players
from different provincial teams throughout the country. Chinese athletes are expected to
be social role-models, being fostered through this pyramid system from a young age by
the state. They are educated to compete for “the motherland” and “to win glory for the
socialist state”, they must be public in their expressions of gratitude and delight over the
generous of the state (Kanin, 1978).

National teams used to be directly managed by the NPESC, however this pattern has
slightly changed since the 1990s. For example, as Western style professional football was
introduced in 1994, the national football team players no longer trained together in
Beijing, with basketball and volleyball following suit shortly afterwards. Now, players
are fully involved in league competitions and stay with their own clubs.

24
Athletics (track & field) is considered as a single sport.
25
Normally, study in the mornings and training in the afternoons.

96
Although the Soviet-style elite development model has shortcomings, the overall process
provides good links between different stages of an athlete development within the system,
and good cohesion exists to guarantee quality athletes being produced systematically.
Furthermore, state funding ensures some unpopular sports (with no/little market value in
the market economy, but which are Olympic events) can be developed to a high
competitive level. For example, shooting, weightlifting and so on.

During the 1950s & 60s The 1984 LA 1994: Sports


– Sports for all; Friendly Olympics, Lottery; 1995:
First & Competition then the Sports Law –
Second 1979 return Olympic balancing elite &
to the IOC Strategy mass sports

1949 the CCP 1966 the The early 1980s The Early 1998 NPESC
took power Cultural sports 1990s, calls downgraded
Revolution, commercialization for sports to SGSA, no
sports Break Out of Asia, reform longer
activities Advance in the without holding a
ceased World delay ministry
status

3-2 Chronological chart – Chinese sports’ policy development

3.3.5 Why Chinese sports were re-constructed


As the Maoist economic development model was gradually abandoned after Deng
Xiaoping seized power in 1978, China moved towards a more diverse and market-
oriented economic development model. Although the Western capitalist concept of
economic development has been embraced by the Chinese government, the process of
transition from a centrally-planned structure to a market socialist system was more
gradually introduced - step by step and slowly but surely. The reform has been subsumed
by a well-known phase – socialism with Chinese characteristics.

Despite modern sports being primarily Western phenomena, deeply embedded in the
Western culture, Chinese experiments with capitalism, as well as Marxism have led it to

97
assimilate forms of Western culture (Kanin, 1978, p263). As Brownell (1995, p62) points
out: “modern sports have occupied a definite place in the Chinese moral order, but that
place has been constructed differently at different times in history”. There is no doubt
that, in Deng’s reform era, Chinese sports were re-constructed, including football, and
this re-construction is inseparable from China’s rapid economic development, social
transition and changing position in the global political economy.

Sport is used as a tool in ideological education by the CCP, which ensures its popularity
and maintains its close relationship with government policies. This section describes the
unfolding Chinese reform policies, the economic development pattern, and the sports re-
construction process after the ‘open door’ policy, in order to explain the reasons why
Chinese sports and football were re-constructed.

Economic reform affects sports


In December 1978, the Third Plenum of the Eleventh Central Committee of the CCP laid
the groundwork for a new phase in Chinese political and economic development. Deng
Xiaoping was convinced that China’s straight bureaucratic control and centralised plan
system harmed both farmers’ and workers’ initiatives, stifling efficiency and impeding
China’s economic development as a whole. In Deng’s (1980) speech, he demanded
relaxation of state control, an increase in the efficiency of the SOEs, and promotion of the
principles of the market economy. A fundamental reform was carried out to encourage
flexibility and productivity. Developing the forces of production were given priority,
which coupled with the adoption of the ‘open door’ policy, resulted in the process of
political decentralisation being gradually introduced.

Bear in mind, as Bramall (2009, p326) points out: “policy changed in many respects after
1978. For one thing, the post-1978 era was one in which economics, rather than politics,
was in command”. The government introduced the Four-Modernisation Programme to
guide economic development. Due to a highly centralised system certainly cannot meet
the needs of modern economic development, state control has been gradually relaxed.

98
Special Economic Zones 26 were also established, once the price control was lifted,
commodities increased both in production and variety, China became increasingly
commercialised. Although China opened its doors to the ‘cultural’ influences of
capitalism, Deng had no desire to promote Western-style democracy, and insisted
promoting the four cardinal principles during the reform, given voice in his speech –
“keeping to a socialist road; upholding the people’s democratic dictatorship; upholding
the leadership of the CCP; and upholding Marxism-Leninism and parts of Mao Zedong’s
thought” (Deng 1984, p339). Consequently, Chinese reform had to occur within the
‘comfort zone’ of the CCP without challenge to its hegemony. The Chinese reform was a
gradual process compared to that in the former Soviet Bloc countries, starting only in the
late 1970s, and still largely behind the Western definition in terms of privatisation and
full market economy status. The logic behind this was that Deng felt that “even with
economic reform and a wealthier society, China would have to be ruled solely by the
CCP” (Lieberthal 1995, p127).

The development of sports has been accompanied by economic reform, its modernisation
necessitating a new ideological interpretation of sport (Hwang & Jarvie, 2003).
Following China’s return to the IOC in 1979 27 , sports were widely promoted. The
Chinese Women’s Volleyball Team immediately created a major success story on the
world stage, winning China’s first ever World Cup in 1981, and hugely boosted the
popularity of sports in general and volleyball in particular throughout the country.
Furthermore, the Women’s Volleyball Team went on to win major world titles four more
times - making it five in a row28. The legendary victory played an important role in the
construction of the national consciousness, and strongly promoted nationalism after the
Cultural Revolution.

26
For example, Shenzhen, Zhuhai in south China, enjoyed different taxation and export policies.
27
This development came with China’s overall political environmental change, which was highlighted by
the famous ‘Pin-pong Diplomacy’ and Nixon’s historic state visit in 1972. As the ‘Two Chinas Problem’
has been solved, China returned to the UN and the IOC in 1972 and in 1979 respectively.
28
Football, Basketball and Volleyball are considered as ‘Three Big-Ball Games’ in Chinese sports.
Successes achieved from such sports make far more impact to society compared to other sports. The five
major world titles were: the 3rd World Cup (1981); the 9th World Women Championship (1982); the 23rd
Olympic Games (1984); the 4th World Cup (1985) and the 10th World Women Championship (1986).

99
In the early 1980s, Chinese sports authorities suggested that China should become a
world sports power by the end of the twentieth century, and all sports personnel should
strive for the realisation of this goal (Liang, 1990). Despite the definition of ‘a world
sports power’ consisting of many dimensions, such as competitive sports, mass sports,
sports sciences, and so on, it was generally interpreted by Chinese people and media as:
placing China amongst the most successful nations in competitive sports and developing
outstanding sports facilities for both mass sports and elite development (ibid). Four
primary sport ideological elements were emphasised, namely competition, high-
performance sports, sporting ethic, and scientific sport. ‘Break out of Asia, advance on
the world’ became the leading sport slogan, underpinned by the strong political purpose
of Chinese nationalism in the international arena (Hwang & Jarvie, 2003).

In Theory, mass sports’ participation has been an important part of Chinese sports
development. Due to the lack of funds and access to facilities, it was largely ignored
before middle of the 1990s. The majority of the sports’ budget was spent on the so-called
national system for competitive sports to realise China’s ultimate goal of becoming ‘a
world sports power’.

The gold rush


Alongside the growing marketisation and commercialisation in the sport field, elite sports
were encouraged to team up with sponsors in order to improve their own financial
circumstances. By the early 1980s, many provincial elite teams managed to sell their
naming rights; at the national level, the 1983 National Games was also introduced to
commercial elements and the market approach for the first time (Guo 2009).

The 1983 National Games’ poster below provides some details of the paradigm shift of
Chinese sports in the early days of the reform era (The right bottom sign is advertisement
of the sponsor; the main background is the Chinese Women’s Volleyball team; the
bottom slogan is – Winning glory for homeland, revitalise the Chinese nation). Moreover,
relaxed state control coupled with extra funds from enterprises allowed some elite teams

100
to operate according to their own perceived needs. For instance, they were able to train in
better conditions and to compete in more tournaments.

Source: Guo (2009)

The Chinese delegation overtook Japan on the medal table for the first time ever in the
1982 New Deli Asian Games, demonstrating that the overall competiveness of Chinese
sports had improved. In the 1984 LA Summer Olympic Games, the PRC won 15 gold, 8
silver, and 9 bronze on its debut, a good enough performance to put China in fourth place
on the medal table (Ren, 1999). The excellent results hugely boosted China’s image and
national pride, leading the NPESC to launch the Olympic Strategy shortly after the LA
Games as a guideline for elite sports development.

At the top level, government funding only for those sports unable to attract major
sponsors, such as diving, shooting etc, left sponsors supporting the rest, such as football,

101
basketball etc; and for competitive sports, only the Olympic events had access to state
funds (Jones 2000). On the one hand, this imbalanced in practice indicated a strong
political purpose of the Chinese government and its sports focus, whereby it wished to
make the nation’s priority quite obvious (ibid). On the other hand, the Olympic Strategy
“also brought a degree of negative influence on those non-Olympic events and teams
sports, such as football, basketball and volleyball, which maybe deemed to be less medal-
intensive” (Ren 1999, p206).

Countries Gold Sliver Bronze Total


China 61 51 41 153
Japan 57 52 44 153
South Korea 28 28 37 93
Source: Olympic Council of Asia – 1982 Asian Games Medal Table
Table 3-2 The New Deli 1982 Asian Games Medal Table (top three)

Countries Gold Sliver Bronze Total


United States 83 61 30 174
Romania 20 16 17 53
West Germany 17 19 23 59
China 15 8 9 32
Source: IOC – LA 1984 Medal Table
Table 3-3 The LA 1984 Olympic Games Medal Table (top four)

The Olympic Strategy strengthens the national system for competitive sports, its ultimate
task being ‘Winning glory for homeland’ on the international stage, especially at the
Olympic Games. Under the new guideline, the National Games and Provincial Games
were re-constructed (in terms of both time and events) to align with the Olympics. For
example, boxing was restored after years of prohibition as a “bourgeois” sport, the reason
behind this was the fact that boxing rewards numerous medals in the Olympics (Brownell,
1995, p301).

102
Despite enormous efforts being made by the NPESC, the Chinese team had a rather
disappointing performance at the Seoul Olympics in 1988 29, winning merely five gold,
eleven silver, and twelve bronze (Ren, 1999). Such a bad result was deeply reflected, and
led to the sack of Mr Li Menghua – the Head of the NPESC at that time. The new
administration (under Mr Wu Shaozu) emphasised further the Olympic Strategy, however,
it had a different approach compared to the previous administration. Medal-hopeful
events were guaranteed to receive sufficient funds, whereas team sports, especially
football and basketball, were pushed further towards the market in order to reduce their
shares in the whole sports budget30. This new approach assured the Chinese team of two
splendid performances in the 1990 Beijing Asian Games and the 1992 Barcelona
Olympics.

Countries Gold Sliver Bronze Total


China 183 107 51 341
South Korea 54 54 73 181
Japan 38 60 76 174
Source: Olympic Council of Asia – 1990 Asian Games Medal Table
Table 3-4 The Beijing 1990 Asian Games Medal Table (top three)

Countries Gold Sliver Bronze Total


Unified Team 45 38 29 112
United States 37 34 37 108
Germany 33 21 28 82
China 16 22 16 54
Source: IOC – Barcelona 1992 Medal Table
Table 3-5 The Barcelona 1992 Olympic Games Medal Table (top four)

In the big picture, political policy determines the pattern of sports development. Chinese
sports re-construction followed political changes and economic reform in order to meet

29
The partial reason was the Soviet Union and East European countries took part in the Seoul Games. The
Soviet Block did not take part in the 1984 LA Games as retaliation for the US-led boycott of the 1980
Moscow Games.
30
“The Chinese government doesn't release meaningful sports-budget statistics, but national expenditure is
surely many times greater than the $130 million that the United States Olympic Committee spends each
year. This has led some Chinese intellectuals to openly question whether a developing nation like China
should spend so much on something so trivial as gold medals.” (Forney 2008, P. A23).

103
the needs of the state. On the one hand, China was using sports to improve Sino-Western
relations in order to serve its national interests; on the other hand, Western capitalists
have gradually set up sports-related businesses in China since the late 1980s. Including
“Trans World International (IMG/TWI) in sports marketing and sports television, News
Corporation in broadcasting, Nike and Adidas in sporting goods, and some multinational
sponsors, especially from the tobacco, beverages and communications industries,
amongst them Philip Morris, British American Tobacco, Coca-Cola and Ericsson”
(Hwang & Jarvie 2003, p84).

Against this backdrop, was the changing social behaviour of organisations, and sports
were not immune to that change (ibid). Following the pattern of political decentralisation,
increasing commercialisation, and improvement in people’s living standards, sports re-
construction occurred naturally, gradually, and inevitability.

After 1995, sports re-construction was determined by the tenets of the Sports Law (1995).
The new guideline of sports reform was to commercialise certain sports and to integrate
sports into people’s daily life. In terms of practice, firstly, its aim was to balance elite
sports and mass participation – the ‘Fitness for All’ project was introduced; secondly, it
focused more on Olympic events; and thirdly, it pushed certain sports to go over to a
Western style professionalism – fostering a club system and promoting the sport’s
commercial market potential (Fan 1997). Chinese sports’ reform and football re-
construction were driven by a government determination to succeed. Even if that meant
bringing more market forces into the game, and reducing the influence of the state (Jones,
2004). As a result, the administrative style was shifted towards a more professional and
expertise–oriented characteristic, underpinned by formal regulation and law (Theodoraki,
2004).

In the reform era, there were two main reasons for re-constructing Chinese sports. Firstly,
the nature of the sports management reforms - sports needed to be re-constructed in order
to fit in with the new political environment, and to meet the demands of the ‘open door’
policy. The national system for competitive sports was restored after the Cultural

104
Revolution, and the Olympic Strategy was implemented in the 1980s. Secondly, the re-
construction process followed economic development and the trend of commercialisation.
Therefore sports were encouraged to operate with flexibility in order to discover market
opportunities.

It is fair to say that Chinese sports have moved away from the original Soviet model.
However, sports’ re-construction has not switched away from a medal-winning
orientation. On the one hand, private sponsors are encouraged to invest in mass
participation, with participants required to bear a certain degree of their own costs. On the
other hand, the reform pushes certain sports into the market, especially team sports with
marketing appeal. By doing so, the NPESC further reduces its financial burden in order to
focus on more Olympic events (Ren 1999). For example, football and basketball teams
having a large number of athletes, but only a few medals available to these events in the
Olympics. By pushing some team sports into the market, the NPESC is able to invest
even more in other Olympic events (the ones lacking marketing appeal but with a haul of
several medals available). Such a balance between elite development and mass
participation, between state plans and market forces, was facilitated by the introduction of
the Chinese Sports Lottery in 1994, which has substantially increased the size of financial
pie for both elite development and mass participation. Moreover, it has become an
important resource of funding for overall sports development in China.

3.4 Corporate governance in Chinese sports


In the Chinese sport sector, the governance structure has been moving towards a more
decentralised model since the Chinese economic reform. More power is now in the hands
of sports associations such that they can act more independently and following a more
commercially orientated approach (Jones, 1999a). One of the purposes of this reform was
to promote efficiency by separating functions between government administration and
business practice in the public sector. As a result, decentralisation was employed by
government for both SOEs and sports organisations. By relaxing control over SOEs and
sports governance, the state not only reduced centralised bureaucratic practices but was

105
also able to shift some responsibilities and financial burden onto individual organisations.
Against this backdrop, both SOEs and sports associations needed to become more
market-oriented dynamic organisations.

Xu et al (2005) found the reform’s success positively affected by the lessening of


political control, increasing the firm’s flexibility in labour deployment and introducing
more effective corporate mechanisms. Since the 1980s Chinese sport has developed more
of its commercial activities, however, it was not until 1994 that the fundamental structure
changed with the launch of the new professionalised football league (China, 2006). The
so called “state amateur” teams have gradually transformed themselves into Western
style “professional” club companies, in which they are regulated by both of Company
Law and Sports Law. Indeed, Liang (2003) states that in the Chinese case, the level of
state control related to the level of playing competitiveness was one of an inverse
relationship - less state control related to a higher level of competitiveness.

3.4.1 The legislative framework of Chinese sport governance


Prior to economic reform, the Chinese sports system was a replica model of the Soviet
style centralised model whereby the state provided all necessary financing. Dong &
Mangan (2001) saw not only the Chinese sports administration, but also the entire
Chinese society, as being built on a vast hierarchical pyramid with power channelled
down from the very top. At the top of the sports system sat the NPESC, a ministry within
the State Council. The NPESC is responsible for drafting and implementing sports policy;
to promote sport at all levels, as well as to liaise with other government ministries.

In Mao’s era (1949-1976), sport was developed under communist ideology and state
policy. Sport was identified as a cultural activity and as a means of promoting peoples’
health without any commercial involvement. According to communist ideology and
China’s socialist sports policy, the purpose of sports development is to promote socialist
spiritual awareness and to enrich the cultural life of the people (Brownell, 1995). Both

106
domestic and international exchange programmes were implemented, reinforcing the
ideology made famous by slogan “friendship first, competition second”.

Economic reform brought not only the recognition of capitalist ideals but capitalist ways
of practice to sports. Under the new “Open Door” policy, many sports were
commercialised and the state gradually relaxed its control in order to push sports towards
a more market-orientated model. Consequently, football was chosen as the first pilot
sport to under-take the transformation.

The Sports Law was introduced in 1995 – the year after football professionalisation.
Nafziger & Li (1998) argued that this law represented a systematic transition in Chinese
thinking. It encouraged the establishment of market-oriented Western style sports
associations to carry out state sports policy, as well as to set objectives for Chinese
sports’ development. On the one hand, it shifted the state day-to-day control to sports
organisations; on the other hand, it confirmed state control and political ideology over
sports development.

The Sports Law provides a new legal framework for sports commercialisation as it sets
several major objectives both in terms of elite sport and mass sports development under
the market economy. It shows a clear anti-doping policy and delivers guidelines for
creating dynamic sports organisations.

The Sports Law contains eight chapters31, and mainly outlines five major points
 The state promotes overall sports’ development and sports’ reform.
 Local governments and trade unions are encouraged to promote and to organize
mass participation and traditional sports.
 Both youth athletes and national team athletes are encouraged to achieve
excellence and win honours for the nation in competitive sports.

31
Chapters 1-8 are: General Provisions, Community Sports, School Sports, Competitive Sports, Sports
Associations, Supporting Conditions, Legal Liability and Supplementary Provisions.

107
 Commercial activities and sponsorship are welcomed in order to raise funds for
sports’ development.
 Drug abuse, fraud and violation of rules shall be sanctioned.

Despite the Sports Laws demonstrating the state’s commitment to sports, Nafziger & Li
(1998) see this development as merely a pronouncement of policy rather than the
enforcement of strict rules - the Sports Law appears to rest on a more bureaucratic
foundation rather than anything tangible. From a stakeholder perspective, the operative
elements of the legislation fail to assign any direct rights to individual athletes and deny
them the chance to contest the governing bodies over disputes. On this point, in the
creation of the Sports Law, there was never an intention to promote a more Western-style
capitalist individualism, furthermore, the state athletes were a product made entirely by
the state in order to achieve glory for the ‘socialist motherland’. In that sense, any
individualism clearly reflects a social aberration which stands as an affront to socialist
collectivism.

Apart from a failure to address any rights for athletes, the Sports Law did not explicitly
protect the rights of either athletes as individuals nor clubs as organisations to challenge
sports associations’ decisions - despite the existence of an arbitration body. Although it
addressed some emerging problems of sports commercialisation, it failed to clarify the
penalties for sports related crimes (e.g. match fixing, gambling, drug offences etc…).

The Sports Law was introduced in a broader political setting wherein the Chinese state
was concentrating on economic construction. Both Company Law and the Sports Law
encouraged the development of the market economy by transforming the ownership of
SOEs and reforming sports organisations respectively. Sports organisations were
reconstructed with a more dynamic structure and a more commercial approach.

Alongside Company Law, Sports Law placed emphasis on the transitional environment
and commercial development in sport. Overall, it aimed to transform sport from a purely
cultural activity to a profitable entertainment industry, under the guidance of a more

108
dynamically structured sporting association. With this new market-oriented approach,
government funds were no longer the sole financial source for sports development. Many
professional teams were required to fund themselves, particularly through sponsorship
deals and other commercial activities. As a pioneer sport, football teams reformed under
the Sports Law with the ownership structure changing from state owned work units to
effectively Western style club companies.

Sports associations at all levels were reconstructed with a more Western style structure in
order to take profit-orientated initiatives. Indeed, new financial resources from the private
sector and commercial activities poured in. Due to the change in structure, sports
associations are now able to operate with fewer restrictions imposed by authorities, as
well as to be more active in terms of adopting commercially orientated strategies –
something which would previously not have been an option with limited government
funding. Despite such improvement in the associations, the Sports Law failed to address
how governing bodies could achieve a balanced development of mass participation and
elite sports with improved financial power.

Any effective corporate governance system relies on the institutional systems of other
sectors for its implementation (e.g. legal institutions, auditing institutions, accountancy
firms, etc). A single legislator (e.g. CFA) alone has limited scope to enforce regulations.
However, the reality faced by many Chinese clubs in terms of the environment in which
they operate, is far removed from the professional services and institutional systems that
exist in its Western counterparts. In a transitional economy like China, the legal system is
still incomplete and underdeveloped in some areas – particularly with regard to more
commercially-oriented areas. Furthermore, there exists a strong linkage between
government and SOEs, as well as club companies. Hence, despite the adoption of the
capitalistic corporate structure - the governance system is still very much determined by
the state rather than the market.

The Chinese state plays a dual role both as a major shareholder and as an industry
regulator. Corporate governance based on the Western model cannot be copied and

109
applied in the same way. Clarke (2003) states that corporate governance is not about
simply getting the law in place, it is about ensuring that institutional systems across
different sectors work together, with a degree of accountability. In effect, China needs
comprehensive institutional reform across both the political and economic spectrum in
order to make corporate governance function well.

Nevertheless, the Chinese football industry has not yet provided an attractive financial
return. Its potential market size still holds unfulfilled appeal for investors. If China
presently needs better corporate governance in order to raise the level of its commercial
enterprise to a modern standard, then the football industry is an ideal place to start - not
only due to its position as a pioneer sport in Chinese sports’ reform, but also due to the
game’s popularity and high social profile. Better corporate governance within football
would also set the tone for commercial development within other Chinese sports.

3.5 Summary
This chapter reviewed the application of corporate governance in China and Chinese
sports, which serves to emphasis the striking lack of study between corporate governance
as a general theory, and its application within the Chinese football industry. In a
transitional economy like China, the application of corporate governance in either
conventional business or sport is not adequately addressed. Even studies on SOEs and
listed companies merely seems to focus on the agency theory perspective – never mind
trying to apply corporate governance research in the football industry with a stakeholder
approach.

By applying managerial theory to the business of football provides not only an insight
into football as a competitive sport and social institution but also as an entertainment
industry. The corporate governance concept provides a legislative framework for this
thesis to explore the football industry in China. It allows one to apply a modern
managerial approach that incorporates a wider range of differing stakeholders.

110
Chapter Four: Research Methodology
The aim of this chapter is to explain the specific methods used in this research, the
techniques used to collect the data, and the strengths and limitations of each method
undertaken. Furthermore, it outlines the main philosophical and methodological reasons
for adopting those particular research methods.

4.1 Methodology and epistemology


With any research topic, the aim is to determine a particular reality that exists within that
particular field of research (Usher, 1997). With that in mind, to determine the basis of any
research topic, one must look towards an epistemological and ontological assessment of
the research topic.

Epistemology is regarded as a major branch of philosophy, which studies the nature of


knowledge. In particular, it addresses the philosophical problems surrounding the theory
of knowledge - such as its foundations, scope, and validity. Epistemology addresses
questions such as, "What is to count as knowledge?", and "How is knowledge acquired?"
Epistemology can be seen as defining a set of universal rules or a scientific method for
conducting research.

However, an epistemological research programme must also be seen and understood as a


reflection of both a cultural artifact, and a historically located paradigm. In greater depth,
as Usher (1997) states, rather than see an epistemological research paradigm as a
technical philosophical procedure – “it is better understood as a particular way of
understanding the world and acting within it through research” (ibid, p4). Hence, any
research is subject to being value-laden, which will have an implication on how research
is carried out.

Saunders et al (2003) advocates positivism, interpretivism and realism as the main


philosophical approaches towards social research.

111
“Positivism is an epistemological position that advocates the application of the methods
of natural sciences to the study of social reality and beyond” (Bryman, 2001, p12).
Positivism has often been seen as a search for “the truth”, where there is a reality that can
be studied or quantified. Objectivity in social science is defined within the positivist
nomenclature as being tantamount to the study of natural science. It is a philosophy that
claims knowledge can only come from the positive affirmation of scientific methods. For
positivists, the scientific method is objective and value-free. In this sense, science is seen
as the only way to get to the truth and to better understand the world. Positivism is the
culmination of that basic premise, and therefore a positivist research paradigm is built on
experimentation as the key method for discovery.

With the positivist approach, the method of investigation is to produce a set of ‘true’,
precise and wide-ranging ‘laws’. This will enable researchers to generalise human
behaviour and social phenomenon based on those observations (May, 1993). A positivist
research programme assumes that the role of the researcher is independent, and that is
neither affects nor is affected by the subject matter of the research (Remenyi, et al, 1998).

Positivism includes elements of both a deductive and inductive approach. In addition, a


positivist research is predominately quantitative - using hypothesis to test theory and the
gathering of facts to develop universal laws. The positivist believed in empiricism -
observation and measurement was the core of their scientific endeavors, and the best
method for limiting a biased perspective is to triangulate and make use of multiple
perspectives.

Another major epistemological position is interpretivism. Unlike positivism, it argues the


social world of business and management is far too complex and therefore cannot be fully
explained by a series of law-like generalisations. As Bryman (2001) states, reality is
socially constructed, and therefore requires the social scientist to grasp the subjective
meaning of social action. Interpretive epistemology argues that “the test of knowledge
should not be generalisation and prediction but interpretive power, meaning and
illumination” (Usher, 1997, p5).

112
By its very nature, study of the social sciences focuses on people, institutions and human
behaviour, which, as Max Weber argues, should not simply quantify what actually
happens in social situations. A study of social sciences should provide an interpretation of
how people are involved and aim to understand their actions in social phenomena.
Therefore, an analysis of a social situation includes both explanation and understanding.
On the other hand, a series of law-like generalisations would in fact reduce the
complexity of the social world and therefore limit one’s research.

Interpretivism claims that research objectives and techniques, suited to the natural
sciences, are not necessarily appropriate for the social sciences. Ultimately, this is
because the observational field of social reality has a specific meaning and a relevant
structure for the subject living, acting and thinking within it (Bryman & Bell 2003). As
Schwandt (2003, p296) states “To find meaning in an action or to say one understands
what a particular action means, requires that one interpret in a particular way what the
actors are doing”. Interpretivism tries to gain knowledge through an individual’s
experience and involvement in the social phenomena. It is more interested in finding the
motivation that lies behind people’s actions. In addition, an interpretive stance can
provide surprising findings in comparison to positivism.

Realism shares common features with both positivism and interpretivism. It argues that a
reality exists independent of human beliefs, social objects or phenomena, and this can
affect the way people perceive their world (Bryman, 2001). Realists also believe that the
truth consists of a belief’s correspondence to reality, and that every new observation
brings us closer to understanding reality. Whatever we believe now is just an
approximation of reality. Although positivism, interpretivism and realism carry three
different views on the research process, they are not mutually exclusive (Saunders et al
2003).

113
4.1.1 Research paradigm
In “The Structure of Scientific Revolutions” Kuhn (1962) presents an analysis of
scientific progress, however, his approach is radically different from any other standard
historical treatment of scientific development. In contrast to others, Kuhn sees the
development of science as a sequence of periodic ‘revolutions’, where each scientific
period is governed by a series of specific rules and methodological truths. Kuhn refers to
these specific research periods as ‘paradigms’. To elaborate, a paradigm is a set of
practices that define a scientific discipline during a particular period of time. Usher (1997
p6) furthers this point: “Paradigms are frameworks that function as maps or guides for
research communities, whether in the natural or social sciences. They provide ways of
looking at and ways of working in the world.” For Kuhn, a paradigm is a logical
framework within which theories are created. In his book, Kuhn takes specific scientific
discoveries, for example, the discovery of atomism or the Copernican revolution, and
then focuses on conceptual issues such as “what ideas were thinkable at the time?” and
“what strategies were available?”.

Research paradigms consist of a diverse array of conceptual and philosophical elements


(ontological, epistemological, methodological, and axiological), which drive the
development of science (Curd & Cover, 1998). Any research paradigm has its own
epistemology - its own way of asking questions. As such, any research community will
each have its own research paradigm that will shape and determine its work. In essence, it
is a disciplined process built on a particular methodology. In each research paradigm, a
unique methodology is considered appropriate for producing a particular vision of the
world.

Kuhn (1962) claims science can only progress based on the development of paradigms.
Individual theory is couched in these research paradigms, thereby making them a
fundamental entity for scientific research. From this starting position, scientific
development occurs during the successive transition from one paradigm to another, via
what Kuhn termed ‘scientific revolution’. These scientific revolutions occur when the
theoretical and empirical evidence is inconsistent with existing theories. As a result, the

114
research paradigm begins to collapse, a scientific revolution occurs, and a new paradigm
replaces the old one. Each time this occurs science is said to progress (ibid). According to
Kuhn, a paradigm change involves conceptual changes at three particular levels –
cognitive, ontological and methodological. Kuhan views these changes as simultaneous
transitions – unlike Laudan (1984) who sees them as a sequential change.

Kuhn (1962) argues that different paradigms will have different ontologies. Each will
espouse a different set of cognitive goals or ideals. As such, one paradigm is effectively
at odds with the methodologies of any other competing paradigm. For example, Kuhn
regards Roentgen’s X ray discovery as paradigm breaking, because it required physicists
to revise the way they practised and interpreted their research with cathode ray tubes
(Curd & Cover, 1998).

Furthermore, Kuhn states that paradigms are incommensurable - two paradigms cannot
be reconciled into one. There is no baseline for comparison between the two, as each
paradigm will employ different scientific standards. At stated above, the process by
which one paradigm replaces another is a simultaneous event: - “Just because it is a
transition between incommensurables, the transition between competing paradigms
cannot be made a step at a time - like the Gestalt-switch, it must occur all at once or not
at all” (Kuhan 1962,p149). As a result, researchers need to revise the way they conduct
and interpret their experiments from one network of scientific commitment to another.

By contrast, Laudan (1984) states paradigm changes can occur individually at any level
(cognitive, ontological and methodological). Changes at one level do not necessitate a
change at another. This is a point which Kuhn flatly disagrees. For Kuhn, the language of
each paradigm is quite distinct (Curd & Cover, 1998). Laudan’s (1984) view of a
paradigm model is reticulated rather than hierarchical, and scientific change is more
‘piecemeal’ than ‘holistic’. He argues the various components of a paradigm are
individually replaceable and negotiable, and that paradigm transition is a step-by-step
process - requiring none of the wholesale shifts advocated by Kuhn. Moreover, an
important feature of the reticulational model is the fact that it allows for rational debate

115
and scientific justification. Scientists are able to accept or reject the components of
paradigms in a piecemeal fashion (Laudan 1984). As such, for Laudan, scientific
revolutions can be resolved by rational argument – based on shared evidence and shared
rules.

Clarke & Clegg (1998) state that the concept of paradigm has been widely received in
management. However, in the social sciences, paradigms are far more flexible in
comparison to natural sciences field. Different paradigms co-exist together and each of
them reveals different facts about our understanding of management (Clarke & Clegg
2000). As modern organisations have multiple purposes and are subject to different rules,
research studies typically go beyond the boundaries of a particular paradigm. In fact there
is a risk that each paradigm is too “narrow” for the purposes of management research and
there is a further risk that one is locked into a particular concept, thereby limiting the
avenues for research.

Furthermore, due to the fact that management research is a relatively new scientific field,
there is a greater degree of commensurability between different paradigms. Therefore,
Kuhn’s research paradigm becomes problematic when it is applied to social science
studies. Although it allows us to analyse certain things, it would be impossible to analyse
events that do not ‘belong’ within the paradigm (ibid). For example, during business
practice, opportunities can be missed if managers are locked into a particular set of
practices (paradigm) without a flexible approach.

4.1.2 Theory and research


Ultimately, theories exist in order to provide logical explanations. Theory is the
framework through which we can inform our thinking, which helps us to understand
findings and to make sense of data. Research employs different methods that are closely
linked with different visions of how social reality should be studied.

116
May (1993) argues that on the one hand theory enables us to break-free from everyday
thinking, allowing us to have a perspective on our social universe. On the other hand he
maintains that some theories lack a universal generality, such that researchers can
effectively determine a perspective in relations to particular areas of society. Indeed, the
role of research is to test theories in order to provide material for the development of
general laws, and, as Williams (2003) points out, to establish academic legitimacy and act
as a powerful explanatory tool.

Williams (2003) argues that theory and research are rarely processed smoothly.
Confirmation and rejection of part or of the whole theory can occur during any period of
the research stage. To generate a new theory we often begin with pre-existing ones.
Theory building and testing are interactive. May (1993) argues that in practice, existing
theories are difficult to reject even if they have been falsified by empirical evidence.
Ultimately, such a rejection must be sufficient before a new theory can be proved. Until
that point, pre-existing theory is likely to assist us in explaining social phenomena.

4.1.3 Inductive approach


Induction is a form of reasoning that makes generalisations based on individual
circumstances. Social scientists begin constructing a theory by observing aspects of social
phenomena. They then seek to discover patterns that may develop into universal
principles (Babbie 2007). An inductive approach moves from specific observations to
broader generalisations and theories. This is also known as a “bottom up” approach.

Inductive research begins with specific investigations. From this, we can gradually
establish a pattern of regularly re-occurring social events from which we can devise
hypotheses, and thereby enable researchers to explore a final result and generate an
overall conclusion. Inductive research uses a specific proposition to infer a general
proposition. In a broader sense, it produces conclusions for unobserved matters on the
basis of what has been observed from present knowledge and evidence. This is evidenced
in most scientific discoveries. Single observations and reasoning from specific examples

117
are developed into general principles. As William & May (1996) state, the experiment is
pointless unless it makes a general claim.

Most inductive research derives from the tradition of grounded theory (Bryman 2001).
Inductive research uses the grounded theory approach to analyse data and at the same
time generate theory (Glaser and Strauss, 1967). In the context of social science, the
inductive approach begins with data collection to examine particular aspects of social life,
and derives theories from resultant data. In research practice, induction is more
commonly associated with qualitative methods and proves advantageous in addressing
three practical purposes (Maxwell 1996, p21):

1. Generating results and theories that are understandable and experientially credible,
both to the people you are studying and to others
2. Conducting formative evaluations, ones that are intended to help improve existing
practice, rather than simply assessing the value of the programme or product being
evaluated
3. Engaging in collaborative or action based research with practitioners or research
participants

Although generating theory from data is considered a reliable approach, the inductive
approach is not always straightforward, and the generalisations such an approach yields
can lead to weakness and censure. William & May (1996) argue that, in everyday science,
most generalisations are made on the basis of the researchers’ present knowledge and
current evidence. The weakness of the inductive approach stems from the fact that the
generalisations that are made in the present cannot be guaranteed to be true in the future.
William & May (1996) claim that induction is about making a statement for an infinite
number of possible situations based on observations of finite number.

The inductive approach is more closely associated with qualitative data, which can be
collected by using a variety of methods. In terms of social research, an interview method
is most commonly adopted in the inductive approach. This research method is closely

118
associated with the philosophy of interpretivism, which has been seen as one of the
strengths of inductive research. This research mainly employs the inductive approach.

4.1.4 Deductive approach


Whilst an inductive approach generates theory from data, a deductive approach is used to
test or refute theory and can be seen as the opposite to inductive research. It is also
commonly referred to as a “top-down” approach. The deductive approach is a theory-
driven approach which advocates that there are a set of methodological rules by which we
proceed in our research. In essence, data collection is theory driven and the final result
tests the validity of our initial hypothesis. A deductive statement is one where the
conclusion must follow the premise. It follows that the truth of the conclusion depends on
the truth of the premise. However, merely because the conclusion follows the premise
and is therefore logically correct, doesn’t necessarily mean it is a true statement or true
result (Willams & May, 1996).

Compared with the inductive approach, deduction is rather narrow in nature and applies
general principles to a specific conclusion. It is usually associated with more quantitative
research and the process can be very linear – one step follows the next in a rational and
clear sequence. Even though the deductive approach does not initially reject a theory, it
nevertheless believes that a theory can only be considered valid once it has been tested.
In other words, an idea or hypothesis can only be “true” if it is supported by the data we
produce.

Deductive research is more closely linked with quantitative data and is therefore
commonly associated with a positivist philosophical approach. As Saunders et al (2003
p86) explain: “An important character of deduction is that concepts need to be
operationalised in a way that enables facts to be measured quantitatively”. A deductive
approach needs to be associated with sufficient numerical sample sizes to make a
generalisation. As such, the survey method is commonly used by deductive research.

119
In short, both approaches serve as valid avenues for social research. Induction is
concerned with theory building, where theory follows data. Deduction centres around
theory testing focusing on which data follows from theory. Most researchers use both
inductive and deductive approaches, which combing the strength of both approaches in
order to achieve more credibility. Just like Babbie (2007) points out, deduction begins
with “why” and moves to “whether”, whereas induction has the opposite pattern.

4.2 Research strategy


Bryman (2001) defines a research strategy as a general orientation to conduct social
research. In order to answer a particular research question, one must have a general plan
in mind. It is philosophical belief which determines the overall research approach and
specific research methods. As Williams and May (1996) claim, with each different
research strategy, comes a different epistemological and ontological presupposition.
However, when you compare both a quantitative and qualitative research strategy in
terms of its epistemological, ontological and theoretical framework, the distinction is not
always obvious.

4.2.1 Quantitative approach


Quantitative research is a systematic way of investigating social phenomena. It is used to
develop and employ mathematical models to measure observations. Both the natural and
social sciences make use of this particular research programme. The process of
measurement provides the fundamental connection between empirical observation and
the mathematical expression of quantitative relationships. In broad terms, quantitative
research is described as “entailing the collection of numerical data and as exhibiting a
view of the relationship between theory and research as deductive, a predilection for a
natural science approach, and as having an objectivist conception of social reality”
(Bryman 2001, p62). In this sense, quantitative research is more closely associated with a
positivist epistemology.

120
Quantitative research normally involves structured questions, such as, “How many…?”
and “How strong is the association…?” Due to the quantitative approach holding a large
number of respondents as samples, it can be used to identify correlations (not causation),
as well as to ensure findings with an acceptable degree of accuracy.

Most survey research is based on what is referred to as ‘correlation’ research or ‘cross-


sectional’ research. Samples are chosen within the population, data is collected from a
cross-section of people at a single point in time. This cross section of people will then be
asked a set of questions, and their responses are typically tabulated so that a result can be
analysed quickly. As long as the sample is sufficiently large, the results can be applied to
the entire population and used beyond the participating group.

4.2.1a Quantitative data validity, reliability and limitation


Data validity is about correctness and reasonableness of data, data validation checks that
data are valid, sensible, reasonable and secure before they are processed. Quantitative
research requires the measurement to be objective, quantitative and statistically valid.

In any quantitative research, an objective approach is a key element to ensure the


reliability and consistency of the results generated. Reliability of data refers to the
consistency of a measure – such that if the test is repeated over and over, it will yield the
same answer.

In quantitative research, researchers mostly work with a sample of the subject. This
sample size has its limitations when being used as a basis for determining general
theories regarding the entire population. It is crucial that the sample size used is reflective
of whatever general subject you are attempting to analyse.

4.2.2 Qualitative approach


Qualitative research predominantly emphasises an inductive and qualitative researchers
aim to gain an in-depth understanding of human behaviour and the reasons behind such

121
behaviour. A qualitative approach tries to understand the complexity of the organisation
and the reality of it by offering a variety of methods, such as interviews, observation and
documentation. Such methods are able to address research issues from different angles,
thereby boosting data validity and research reliability. For example, the interview
interpretation can be supported by documentary evidence, as well as through observation
by the researcher. Qualitative research aims to generate rich, detailed and valid data that
is necessary for increasing the understanding of:

a) Complex and sensitive impacts and processes;


b) Differential impacts between stakeholders and the reasons for these; and
c) Potential consequences of any practical recommendations (Mayoux, 2001).

Bryman & Bell (2003) claim that defining characteristic of a qualitative research method
is in its distinct epistemological and ontological position. Although it is not restricted to
the mere presence of numbers, a qualitative research programme often appears in a
narrative format. It has rejected the practices and norms of the natural scientific model
and is more in favour of the individual’s interpretation of the social world. Maxwell
(1996, p17-20) outlined the strength of qualitative research and illustrated five reasons
for choosing a qualitative research programme:

1. Understanding the meaning of the events you are participating in


2. Understanding the particular context within which the participants act, and their
actions which have been influenced by the context
3. Identifying unanticipated phenomena and influences, and generating theories
4. Understanding the process by which events and actions take place
5. Developing causal explanations

Qualitative research is becoming an increasingly popular approach for the purposes of


business research. As previously stated, it emphasises words rather than numbers, and
stands as a more interpretive, inductive and constructive programme. Maxwell (1996)
also points out that qualitative researchers tend to place more emphasis on understanding

122
the rationale behind the phenomena. In comparison to quantitative approaches, in which
there are limitations regarding the extent to which social reality can be observed and
measured in a positivistic way, the qualitative approach provides means by which to
investigate and understand complex and sensitive issues in generate depth.

4.2.2a Qualitative data validity, reliability and limitation

The validity and reliability of qualitative data depends to a great extent on the
methodological skill, sensitivity and integrity of the researcher (Patton, 1990). Qualitative
research forms a critique of positivist thought, it approaches ‘reality’ as something that
can never really be fully captured. It is more value-laden towards research process, and
argues that researchers can only provide relatively adequate and valid approximation
through their analyses to explain the phenomenon in the social world.

According to Shipman (1998), reliability in qualitative research can rarely be fully


achieved, because researchers are not in total control of their interaction with the social
environment. Moreover, all the events are unique and non-replicable for repeated studies.
Validity is a goal rather than a product; it is relative and must be assessed in relation to
the purposes and circumstances of the research, rather than being the contextually-
independent property of methods or conclusion (Maxwell, 1996).

Maxwell (1996) argues that once qualitative research has begun, it has to immediately
rule out threats to its validity. The main threats come from subjective description,
interpretation and unsuitable theories, and the best way to limit these threats is to use
credible, certifiable methods and appropriated theoretical frameworks to conduct
research.

A further requirement is that a researcher should avoid bias towards his studies. An
understanding of how a particular researcher’s values influence the conduct and
conclusion of the study in order to explain the possible bias, as well as how this bias

123
should be dealt with during research is important for qualitative studies. For example, a
significant problem in interviews is ‘reactivity’, where the researcher influences the
informants during the interviews. Even though ‘reactivity’ cannot be eliminated during
interviews, it can nevertheless be minimised by taking precautions, such as avoiding
leading questions (Maxwell, 1996). An interview is based on the informant’s perception
of ‘what happened’ rather than ‘what exactly happened’ and crosschecking the
information by different sources at different times can enhance the validity of the data
deriving from the informant’s claims.

In addition, translation from different languages poses another threat for researchers;
there is always a danger of losing or misunderstanding information. In the case of this
thesis, all the interviews were conducted in Chinese and subsequently translated into
English, thus exact words provided by both the researcher and interviewees may lose
some accuracy during the translation process.

4.2.3 Comparison between the quantitative and qualitative approach


Bryman (2001) seeks to distinguish between quantitative and qualitative methods. For
Bryman the two methods have very different epistemological foundations - he has
outlined three specific areas that differ between the two approaches.

Quantitative Qualitative
Principal orientation to the Deductive; Inductive;
role of theory in relation to Testing of theory Generation of theory
research
Epistemological Nature science model, in Interpretivism
orientation particular positivism
Ontological orientation Objectivism Constructionism
Source: Bryman 2001 Social Research Method, p20
Table 4-1: Fundamental differences between quantitative and qualitative research strategies

Although there is a clear distinction between quantitative and qualitative approaches, in


social research, it is common for the two to go hand in hand. The quantitative approach

124
is often used to test theories through qualitative research of the subject, and a qualitative
method might be used to understand the meanings of numbers produced by quantitative
methods.

Quantitative Qualitative
Objective “hard science” Subjective “soft science”
Relating to research questions: “How Relating to research questions: What…?
many…? How strongly associated…?” Why…? How…?
Deductive; testing theory or hypothesis to
Inductive; developing theory for
gain understanding understanding
Data based on meaning derived from Data based on meaning expressed
numbers through words
Collection results in numerical and Collection results in non-standardised
standardised data data requiring classification into
categories
Analysis conducted through the use of Analysis conducted through the use of
diagrams and statistics - establishes conceptualisation - describes meanings
relationships and causation (measurable) (interpretive)
Uses instruments Uses communication and observation
Facts are value-free and unbiased Facts are value-laden biased
One reality: focus is concise and narrow Multiple reality: focus is complex and
broad
Striving for generalisation Striving for uniqueness

Based on Bryman (2001) and Saunder et al (2003, p378)


Table 4-2: Characteristics of quantitative and qualitative research

Quantitative and qualitative approaches do not stand in opposition to each other, but
instead offer different ways to approach and understand social reality. They merely
reflect different processes and methods used to reach a common standpoint. A
quantitative approach seeks explanatory laws and generalisation, qualitative research
aims at a more in-depth description of uniqueness. The decision of choosing whether one
employs a quantitative or qualitative approach depends on the nature of the research and
the information needed for the context of the study, as well as taking into account any
research constraints. It is important to note that all research has its limitations, there is a
modern tendency in social research to use both quantitative and qualitative methods.

125
Apart from both qualitative and quantitate approaches, case study is a research strategy
that has a wide usage and can be based on a mixture of quantitative and qualitative
evidence. Yin (1984) defines a ‘case study’ as an empirical enquiry that investigates a
subject within its real life context. In management research, the case could be an event,
an organisation or particular industry, and the research object in a case study is often a
programme, an entity, a person or a group of people. Morris & Wood (1991) point out
that a case study strategy is particularly suited to gaining a rich understanding of the
context of the research. Case studies will tend to concentrate on the subject matter itself,
with less focus on the theoretical inference or empirical generalisation.

Critics of the case study method believe that a small number of cases cannot represent the
view of an entire population, contending that it is no means of positive generalisation.
Therefore, it can offer no grounds for establishing reliability or generality of truth. Others
argue that the case study approach is highly subjective, relying heavily on our previous
experience and our sense of worth, which can render the findings biased.

In contrast to such criticism, a case study approach also has its advantages. Firstly, a
single or a few case studies, studied over a sufficient length of time, can yield
generalisations and a testable theory. Moreover, despite this seemingly narrow approach,
the wider relevant findings can be conceptualised as a basis for ‘naturalistic
generalisation’. Although, the result of the case study does not always have to be
proposing new theory, it can also modify existing results and increase the validity of the
research with a new case (Stake, 1995).

4.3 Methodology implementation


Different research approaches have strengths in different areas. As Saunders et al (2003,
p85) state, “Business and management research is often a mixture between positivist and
interpretivist approaches - perhaps reflecting the stance of realism”. There are many

126
complexities surrounding the newly professionalised Chinese football industry, the
overriding question of this thesis demands more exploratory research, and exploratory
research is more akin to the qualitative approach. Furthermore, a systematic study on the
topic of corporate governance in the Chinese football industry requires an in-depth
understanding of the different behaviors of diverging organisations and stakeholder
groups. The questions being asked are often why and how rather than where or what,
when exploring a new field or subject such as this, a qualitative approach is more suitable
than a quantitative approach.

The aim of this thesis is to look at the corporate governance of the Chinese football
industry, drawing on stakeholder theory as the framework for analysis. The business of
Chinese football and its governance is a complex social phenomenon which is heavily
influenced by political policies and other social developments in China. Interpretivism is
the main philosophical approach used in this thesis which underpinned by
epistemological and ontological assumptions to better understand the structures and
development pattern of the Chinese football industry.

From an epistemological point of view, an objective and fuller understanding can be


gained through a well-designed research methodology. The implementation of such a
methodology is based on the research questions. However, while quantitative research of
a more positivistic orientation begins with the development of research questions for
testing, the development of research questions within the interpretivist framework can
often be developed at a later stage. As Maxwell (1996, p49) states: “The research
question in a qualitative study should not be formulated in detail until the purposes and
context (sometimes general aspects of sampling and data collection) of the design are
clarified, and they should remain sensitive and adaptable to the implications of other parts
of the design. Often you will need to do a significant part of the research before it is clear
what specific research questions you should try to answer”. Indeed, this study mainly
adopt the interpretivism approach, it echoes Maxwell’s statement, the explicit research
questions relating to the thesis did not emerge until I actually went out into the field and
started a project work with the AFC. This job gave me the opportunity to tour from one

127
city to another and communicates with individuals within the Chinese football industry.
Once the fieldwork began, I was gradually able to establish all my research questions.

Dixon et al (1987, p16) states: “A researchable question is usually a small fragment of a


large question. One of the hardest things for a researcher to do is to leave behind that
large burning issue and settle down to tackle one small, manageable part of it”. In
establishing my research questions, the process mirrors Dixon’s statement, that by
“piecing together a number of smaller answers a larger answer may be discovered” (ibid).

For example, this research has an overriding question: - “How has professionalisation
impacted on the governance and development of the football industry in China?” Just as
aforementioned, the researcher is reducing the overriding question down to six more
easily manageable sub-questions:

1. To what extent did the Chinese FA and the top leagues facilitate the development of an
increasingly professionalised football industry?

2. How does the Chinese FA balance the needs of the professional football industry and
the grassroots development?

3. How do professional football clubs manage relationships between multiple


stakeholders?

4. How has professionalisation impacted on the relationship between supporters and


football clubs?

5. How has increasing professionalism affected players?

6. What are the key governance challenges facing the Chinese football industry?

Six sub-questions direct my research to identified specific areas helping to generate a


more complete picture of the football industry in China, while at the same time
addressing the overriding research question.

128
As a part of contribution to the research field, this explorative study is adding the current
literature of corporate governance on the Chinese football industry. The current cooperate
governance literature has been applied on some European football counties and their
commercial development, which is based on a relatively complete Western legal system
and a free-market economy. From this standpoint, the current literature, although
providing a useful source for referencing, is inadequate for conducting detailed research
within the Chinese football industry. This research is an exploration of the newly
professionalised Chinese football industry, which is subsequently founded on an
incomplete legal system and a transitional economy.

The literature review chapter explained and justified that using the stakeholder approach
to conduct research on the football industry at different levels has become a trend of
management study, especially as the game has developed to a highly commercialised
entertainment industry. This research also employs the triple-perspective approach
(Steurer 2006) towards the stakeholder theory framework in order to gain a
comprehensive understanding. As aforementioned, the overriding research question is
approached from various angles of sub-questions which are linked to different
stakeholders’ perspectives. Players, fans, clubs and the governing bodies were defined as
separate stakeholder groups, interview data were categorised, and responses were marked
carefully in order to capture ideas. Stakeholder relationships between different
stakeholder groups were analysed by looking at different themes, such as conflict of
interests, stakeholders’ resource dependence based on either elaborated interview analysis
or different analytical stakeholder models mentioned in the literature review chapter.
More importantly, using constructed graphs to demonstrate the development trends of
stakeholder relationships and stakeholder influence make a further contribution to the
research field.

This thesis is based on an inductive approach, where the empirical work involves a series
of interviews. During the empirical work, the first step of the process is to identify
interviewees who work within the football industry, determine the relevant individual
stakeholder groups and ensure that all candidates have sufficient knowledge and

129
experience. Interviewees are categorised into different stakeholder groups, thereby
allowing not only individual opinions to come forward but also garner information
regarding the stakeholder groups as a collective. In that respect, it provides us with
different angles and perspectives from which one can better understand corporate
governance in Chinese football.

All interviewees sampled from clubs were senior members of staff, such as CEOs, and
senior managers. The reason for this is that they possess personal experiences of running
football businesses at the club senior level, which allows them to offer a valuable insight
into club management. Selected clubs which are located all over the country include well-
established big clubs with strong financial backing and relatively smaller clubs with
weaker financial powers. Interviews with officials from a wide range of clubs can
sufficiently generate more balanced insights to achieve a deeper understanding of the
issues.

In the fan category, the study focuses on organised fan associations not individuals,
therefore, all interviewees were fan organization leaders - Presidents and Vice Presidents.
The approach explores varying structural mechanisms of fan organisations and their
relationships with clubs.

All player interviewees were current or past players with personal experiences of the
professional leagues. Despite geographical difference, Chinese players progress from
young amateurs to mature professionals via a similar route within the same training
system. Having such a strong common characteristic industrial background, even small
samples of players are able to have valuable opinions and a representative voice on the
system. Unlike fan associations, Chinese players do not have their own
union/organisation to represent them either as individuals or as a group. Nine players
were interviewed, included retired players - with experience of the professional league
who still work in the industry; active players - old/experienced players (28 years of age or
older facing retirement) and young players (first team players younger than 28 years of
age). In that respect, information generated from interviews can provide a balanced

130
picture that shows football governance in a progressive way. More importantly, the goal
of the interviews is to gain a better understanding from the respondents’ perspective.

In addition, interviews conducted at one particular club always include at least three
interviews - one from a player, one from a club official and one from a club’s fan group.
The systematical approach and triangulated information boost credibility of data as well
as the analysis of stakeholder relationships at the club level. In some cases, extra
interviews were conducted when opportunities were available.

Officials from the CFA and local FAs were also interviewed in order to understand the
role of governing bodies at different levels and in particular their different approaches to
develop the Chinese game.

The primary data was obtained through semi-structured interviews within the framework
of a stakeholder theory concept. Interviews were designed using open-ended questions to
ensure that interviewees expressed their own opinions - thereby ensuring objectivity and
limiting the interviewer’s influence over the results.

Majority of interviews were conducted in 2008, followed by more interviews in 2012 and
2013 after submission of the first draft with suggestions from supervisors. The researcher
worked at Shenzhen FC over the Summer 2012, the opportunity provided the research not
only to update knowledge but also to observe the industry at the club level for a half
season. As a result, more semi-structured interviews with club officials, fan associations
and players were conducted, including interviews within Shenzhen FC and its fan
association. Some interviews with other clubs were also organised during Shenzhen FC’s
away trips. Moreover, a survey amongst professional clubs was also conducted at two
separate football meetings32 with permission from the CFA. A questionnaire was handed
out to senior managers of all professional clubs and completed questionnaires were
collected at the end of each meeting. With help from the CFA and the researcher’s own

32
Meeting for general managers of Super League clubs, 11& 12 September 2012, Hangzhou; Meeting for
general managers of Jia League clubs, 13 & 14 September, Shanghai.

131
efforts the response rate was 100% and analyses of the survey elucidate complementary
aspects of club governance.

After the Shenzhen spell, the researcher started to work at IMG’s Global Business
Development Football in October 2012 when IMG signed a ten-year commercial deal
with CSL. As a result, the researcher has established a close working relationship with
the CFA and CSL since, which further increased the researcher’s accessibility to some of
the most senior football administrators in China and some of the most valuable insights
into the industry that ultimately facilitated the completion of this study. For example, the
researcher conducted interviews with the chairman of the CSL and the chief financial
officer of the CFA in May 2013 when they were on a business trip to IMG’s London
headquarter and UEFA’s Champions League Final.

As is well known, a single method of data collection would be insufficient to capture the
richness of any research scenario. In fact, data collected from interviews, a survey and
secondary data from other documents and related literature provide cross-data validity
checks when addressing the smaller research questions separately. Thereafter, the
researcher was able to piece together the results for each smaller research question and
address the overriding question.

The data sources used for this research consisted of:


 Interviews with officials from the CFA, the CSL, local FA and football clubs, as
well as football players, academics, and fans33.

 Informal meetings and social conversations with the officers from the AFC, the
CSL, local FA, players, fans and so on, to capture wider information which could
not be obtained from formal interviews.

 The researchers’ own observation during the time with Shenzhen FC

 Documents collected from the CFA, the CSL, clubs, books, papers and academic
studies as well as web searches on all the related fields.

33
See appendix for the interviewees’ list.

132
 Formal meeting records and other material gathered during the tour with the AFC
on its Vision Asia project and the CSL meetings.

 A survey includes all professional clubs in 2012.

In addition, I had been given a work opportunity by the AFC in October 2007. I was
mainly involved with the Asian Vision project, which includes the Vision China
programme. At that time, the Vision China team was preparing to expand its programme
in Zibo City, and, as a result, I had a series of meetings with officials from the Zibo city
government and Zibo FA, regular communication with the AFC’s Vision China officials,
as well as officials from Chelsea FC (the club has established a working partnership with
the Vision China programme).

I travelled to a number of Chinese cities which had participated in the Vision China
programme – these included Jinan, Zibo and Qingdao. During the trip, I attended a series
of seminars conducted by officials from the AFC and Chelsea FC. One of my tasks was
to interpret these seminars into Chinese and I therefore had the opportunity to talk to the
officials and speakers before and after the seminars.

This work enabled me to acquire a better understanding of the Vision China programme
and some local football development at the grassroots level – the foundation of the
football pyramid structure and the base of the professional game.

4.4 Data analysis


The major analysis is based on more than thirty interviews. Most of the interviews were
tape recordings taken with the interviewees’ permission. However, some interviewees
were not prepared to be recorded and in those cases, interviews were recorded in writing
and transcribed shortly after the interview.

133
A transcription of the tape recording is a more efficient means of conducting the
interview, compared with a written format, as this reduces the ‘threat’ of misrepresenting
or introducing any un-necessary bias on the part of the interviewer. Furthermore, if there
are any doubts that come to light I can always go back to the original records.

This thesis has employed a descriptive approach in the process of analysis. However,
even though the descriptive method is a suitable procedure when used to describe the
development of the Chinese game, having a solely descriptive research programme will
lead to criticism. The study uses combined methods with a variety of date sources in the
process of analysis to avoid an overly descriptive approach at the same time to unveil the
governance of the game and relationships amongst stakeholders within the industry.

Data analysis focuses on how the interviewees responded to each question. As this was
done with open-ended questions, data from each question was treated not only as
individual but also all the data was collated together within categorised different
stakeholder groups and organised by questions to look across all respondents and their
answers in order to identify consistencies and differences. Moreover, the connections and
relationships between topics were also explored.

In order to bring meaning to the words, three different themes were identified - conflicts
of interest, resource dependency and sustainable development, which organised the data
into categories – either by question or case. The themes provided directions for what the
researcher was looking for in the data, and enabled a search of the data for text that
matched the themes. In such a way, the researcher was able to see patterns and
connections both within and between categories. Of course each category includes some
sub-categories which reflect the nuances in the data. Findings came from analysing the
information that was captured through interviews – similarities and differences in
interviewees’ responses were further elaborated to provide analytical insights within

134
categories and important points were emphasised with interview quotations to support
findings and bring the data to life.

Ferkins et al (2005) claim a qualitative approach may better capture the diversity that
exists in sport. It may gather new data in different ways that assists in creating new
governance designs. However, a caveat to this is that quantitative data can be difficult to
access or collect among Chinese governmental organisations and departments. This is
partly due to the political culture and ideology and the lack of transparency between
public and governmental spheres. Due to a lack of accessibility to clubs’ and CFA’s
business accounts, the research has not been able to draw on or analyse detailed
quantitative financial data. In addition, it is a common fact in China that most members
of staff are unwilling to pass inside information on to others, including researchers.

Despite the fact that social improvement has been made by the ‘Open door’ policy and
economic reform, China is still a totalitarian state, the working culture in the political
system lacks transparency, and in terms of work practice, government officials and civil
servants have more concerns about peoples above them than about the public interest and
moral issues. Such working culture and practice causes difficulties for researchers
conducting interviews in the public sector. Moreover, an exploratory study about
corporate governance in Chinese football such as this has never been done before, and
arranging interviews in China was a big challenge. For example, many officials were not
willing to make themselves available for interviews in the first place and even when
interviews go ahead as planned, some officials are reluctant to reveal the true stories
behind scenes, in fear of criticizing government policy and practice. In addition, Chinese
officials are less professional compared to the Western civil servants, they can cancel
interviews without any notice.

Against this Chinese cultural backdrop, all researchers need good contacts within the
system for data collection. In this case, it down to researcher’s own personal connections

135
in the Chinese football industry and work contacts that researcher has established during
time spent in the AFC and IMG. Having these advantages, the researcher was able to
arrange a rough time table for interviews with local FAs and clubs across China before
travelling to each location. Despite all preparation in advance, there were still problems
along the way. For example, the interview with the Shanghai FA official was rescheduled
twice, researcher eventually managed to get it done on the last day of the five-day stay in
the city. In Nanjing city, one interview was initially arranged with the CEO of Sainty FC,
when researcher arrived in Nanjing, the CEO was no longer available as promised, the
Vice General Manager was recommended as a replacement. In spite of the difficulty that
researcher faced in conducting field work, there was also co-operation. For example, the
CEO of Ginde FC welcomed researcher and provided accommodation for three days free
of charge, he also helped researcher to get in touch with the local fan association.

The process of field work as a whole had ups and downs. Generally speaking, it was not
only difficult but frustrating, involving the last minute cancellation of interviews;
prolonged waiting time for rescheduled interviews or confirmations. Furthermore,
travelling brought with it additional problems, not only in terms of travelling costs itself
but also with the trade-off between budget and length of stay at each destination. Many
interviews were conducted in the summer of 2008, which saw researcher travel through a
vast expanse of Chinese territory in a relatively short space of time. Some unforeseen
circumstances were therefore bound to pop up during the processes which were capable
of affecting the next leg of journey and other pre-arranged interviews. The trip spanned
the Northern city of Changchun, to the Southern city of Guangzhou, with over 3,500
kilometers between them; as well as the Eastern city of Shanghai to the midland city of
Zhengzhou, which have over 1,000 kilometers of land between them. By contrast, during
the time when researcher worked at Shenzhen FC in 2012 and IMG afterwards,
interviews were arranged relatively easier and the execution was less problematic.

136
4.5 Summary
This chapter has outlined the philosophical approach and the theoretical framework
underpinning the research methodology employed by this thesis. It demonstrates not only
researcher’s knowledge but also provides a systematical overview and implementation of
each specific research method involved – which is subsequently supported with
theoretical justification. Such methods include a survey and semi-structured interviews
analysis. The semi-structured interview was dominate research method because it
allowed exploration and better understanding of particular subject, however, by using
several sources of data, the triangulated data ensures a good standard of data reliability at
the same time enhancing the credibility of the findings, and the conclusions made are
drawn from rational explanations and analysis to provide insights for deeper
understanding of the subject.

Although this study attempts to approach even wider stakeholder groups, there are always
limitations to what this research can achieve. Further with time and financial constraints,
it is impossible to interview all the stakeholder groups, and it is necessary to be selective.
For example the media was not chosen to be interviewed. Despite television playing an
important role financially in Europe, it does not do so on the same scale in the Chinese
football industry.

137
Chapter Five: From State Amateur to Professional

5.1 The background and basic infrastructure of Chinese football

5.1.1 The administrative structure


Football in China underwent a huge political upheaval after 1949 when the Communist
Party took power. The new government adopted a highly centralised administrative
system to ensure that the top leaders in Beijing had the leverage necessary to determine
the national agenda. The so called “people’s democracy” system became embedded in the
whole civil service – including the sports administration. The National Physical
Education and Sports Commission (NPESC) was the top administrative body within the
wider sphere of sports administration, it oversaw sports development in the country.

In terms of football, the CFA is responsible for football development at both amateur and
professional levels. Its members consist of provincial FAs, municipalities’ FAs, army,
and trade unions. The national competitions organised by the CFA and regional FAs are
responsible for football development and competitions within their geographical
boundaries.

The governance structure within football takes the form of a pyramid, with the CFA at
the top. The second tier of the football pyramid is governed by the provincial FAs
(including municipalities’ FAs), army, and trade union FAs. Each one is responsible for
football development at the regional levels or within their respective industry. The city
FAs are positioned at the bottom of the governance pyramid.

There are 31 Provincial and 384 city FAs affiliated with the CFA at different levels.
Before professionalisation, the elite football teams34 were named after their regions and
managed by the provincial or city FAs. Trade union teams were affiliated with their
respective trade union FAs.

34
China did not recognise its elite sports as professional until the 1990s, the state amateur teams
transformed to clubs after professionalisation.

138
5.1.2 The elite system
The Chinese elite sports training system was established in the mid-1950s soon after the
consolidation work following the civil war (apart from the Cultural Revolution period
during 1966-1976, the structure was well maintained until professionalisation in the mid-
1990s). Numerous spare-time sports schools and provincial centre sports schools were
founded with the aim of reinforcing and recruiting for elite sports (Whitby, 1999).
Football was one of the major sports practised by the majority of such sports schools
nationwide.

In terms of developing players, ordinary primary and middle schools acted as ‘feeder’
points. Students showing football potential during physical education (PE) classes were
selected for their school teams, which were supervised and trained by PE teachers on a
regular basis. In conjunction with their local sports programmes, some schools were
identified as key schools for a particular sport35 (Wu, 1990). For instance, certain schools
were proficient in developing young football players, and such school became known as
key football schools, whilst others, which focused on athletics or basketball, were known
as key athletics or key basketball schools respectively (Liang 2003).

Students who excelled at football could be selected for extra-curricular football training
after school. In China, this is commonly referred to as ‘spare-time’ football schools
Whitby, 1999). Such schools are managed by local FAs and staffed with full-time
coaches. All students in the local catchment area would be selected for one of these
specialists.

The best athletes with good potential from the spare-time football schools or the key
football schools are selected by the provincial central sports schools (these include army
and trade union youth academies). The provincial sports schools are very much the next
step in the youth development providing training and boarding facilities (Wu 1990,

35
Depending on the facilities and the particular sports specialisations held by the PE teachers in that school.

139
Whitby 1999). Competition for selection into these schools is fierce as candidates are
selected from within the provincial boundaries 36. Players who reach this stage can benefit
from free boarding and financial aid.

On gaining entry the athletes have the opportunity to move a step further towards a
‘professional’ career within either the provincial, army, or trade unions teams. These
teams stand at the top of the pyramid structure and provide players for the national team.

The national
& provincial
teams

Provincial centre
sports schools
(Managed by the provincial FAs)

Spare-time football schools


& key football schools
(Managed by city FAs)

Figure 5-1 the elite training & selection system

Figure 5-1 shows the echelon training and selection system, which provided good links
between different tiers of the football pyramid. The national team and the provincial
teams were situated at the top, and all athletes at this level were full-time state employees.
The middle tier of the system consisted of provincial centre sports schools, which were
under the administration of their respective provincial FAs. Although, all young athletes
at this level were considered part-time players, they lived on board and were trained
collectively on a daily basis. Local spare-time and key football schools feature at the

36
The average size of a Chinese province is similar to the whole size of the UK.

140
bottom of the pyramid. Despite having armature status, players still enjoyed state
subsidies from local city FAs. Underpinned by the state funds at the different levels, this
elite training and selection system ensured that children could receive systematic training
from a young age with the possibility of progressing all the way to the top.

5.1.3 The league structure


In the pre-professional era, the Competition Department of the CFA was the chief league
organiser. The national league competitions were held in a round-robin tournament
format - whereby all teams in the same division gathered in one city to play an intensive
round-robin fixture within a relatively short space of time 37 . The length of the
competition normally stretched over a month, and the team with the most points won the
league. At the national level, the top two league competitions were Jia League (Division
1) and Yi League (Division 2). Each league consisted of numerous provincial, army, and
trade union teams, with a promotion and relegation system between them.

In the mid-1990s, the League Department was created. It co-organised national leagues
with the Competition Department. Following the transformation of elite teams into
professional clubs in 1994, all leagues’ fixtures were redesigned to a home-away
formation and played at weekends. This was more akin to the Western game, and as a
result, the professional football season extended accordingly from March to
October/November. In 1994, the top Jia League was divided into two groups - Jia A (12
teams) and Jia B (12 teams), and in the same year foreign players were introduced for the
first time in Chinese football history.

In 2004, the Super League Committee and the League Committee were created to govern
the top tier Super League and the second tier Jia Leagues respectively.

37
Such format save money for all teams as frequent travelling over a year in a vast country was not realistic
under their limited budget in the pre-professional era.

141
5.2 The policy shifting and the emergence of football professionalisation

5.2.1 Political influence, sport policy and the development pattern before 1994
5.2.1a Football under Mao’s leadership
Football development in Communist China can be divided into two historical phases; pre-
professionalisation and post-professionalisation. With this in mind, the game has always
been developed under the heavy influence of government sport policies.

Under Mao’s leadership, the pattern of football development can be analysed as ‘one step
forward and one step back’ (Liang, 2003). At the beginning of the People’s Republic of
China (PRC), physical education commissions were established at different
administrative levels. Elite teams and competitions gradually developed until the Cultural
Revolution in 1966. During this period, sports development followed Mao’s official
endorsement (sanctioned in 1952) - to “promote physical culture and sports, strengthen
the people’s physiques” (Xie 1990, p29). This had the effect of focusing public attention
on the importance of physical culture – something which continues to be an important
aspect of daily life in China to this day (Clumpner & Pendleton, 1978).

Mao had ambitions to eliminate China’s weakness and to earn the respect of the modern
world38 (Xie 1990). His ideology was centred around the building of the physical strength
of the Chinese people in order to raise the strength of the nation. Therefore, the prospect
of creating stronger physiques among the Chinese people became the priority of the
PRC’s sports policy. As a result, the state devised the first National Physical Training
Programme in the early 1950s and followed it up with the first set of callisthenics
exercises (ibid).

As part of the implementation of Mao’s ideology, the development of football was


afforded a great deal of attention by state leaders, and the game was rebuilt quickly after
the Civil War. Although there was a shortage of leading players, coaches and equipment,
the first National Football Competition was held and a new training base for the national

38
His view appeared in his article “A Study of Physical Culture” which was written in his early years as a
revolutionary in 1917.

142
team was built in 1951 (Twydell, 1994). Following this, a training and selection structure
was established throughout the country, and from this point on, football was
institutionalised by the new regime.

On the international stage, China faced a bipolar world. The Cold War had intensified,
and China took its stand with the USSR and the Eastern bloc. Following the bloody
conflict in the Korean Peninsula, American tightened its economic noose around China
by preventing it from trading with the West (Lieberthal 1995). With such tension in
international politics, there were few opponents the Chinese football teams could face,
and build international experiences with, leaving only the Soviet bloc countries.

Hungary and the USSR played at a very high standard in the 1950s, and some Chinese
teams were trained by either Hungarian or Soviet coaches under the sport and cultural
exchange programmes (Simons, 2008). Furthermore, the Hungarian National Selective
team toured China and played a series of friendly matches in 1954. In response, China
sent a total of 35 players 39 to Hungary for a year and half training shortly after the
Hungarian tour, and players were trained under the Hungarian coach Josef Ember, who
went on to be head coach of the Chinese national team (ibid). The Soviet team Znit also
visited China in October 1955, with Mao attending the match in Beijing. In addition,
other Hungarian and Soviet football experts came to China to train Chinese players and
coaches on a regular basis in the late 1950s (NPESC Sports Literature and History
Committee & the CFA, 1993). The influential sports slogan ‘Friendly First, Competition
Second’ highlighted the development of the game in this period.

By the end of the 1950s, with the improvement in financial aid, training facilities and
foreign professional help, Chinese football reached its initial peak and the national team
was not only able to beat strong Asian teams (such as Japan and Iraq) but was able to
compete with strong European sides. For example, in November1958, China beat

39
35 players were sent in two groups separately, the first group went six month earlier, and the two groups
emerged as one in Hungary.

143
Swedish club Djurgardens40 (1:0); in 1959, Hungary National B Team (1:0), in the Three-
nation Tournament, and only lost to the Soviet National Team (0:1) (ibid).

Government sports policy, systematic support and leaders’ personal influence played
major roles in raising the playing standard. In addition, China’s strong socialist affinity
with the USSR and Soviet Bloc states deserves recognition, as many sports exchange
programmes took place within the socialist camp during this period, and Chinese football
greatly benefited from such initiatives (Liang, 2003).

Chinese football was at a low ebb in the early 1960s, as China suffered three years of
economic hardship caused by Mao’s political movement - the Great Leap Forward
(Simons, 2008). Due to the economic difficulties, the number of elite teams and
competitive matches were reduced. Despite a short revival in 1964 and 1965 when the
NPESC issued a resolution “Strongly promoting football, quickly raising skills and
playing standards” (NPESC Sports Literature and History Committee & the CFA, 1993,
p134), the arrival of the Cultural Revolution in 1966 killed the efforts.

5.2.1b Football after the Cultural Revolution


The Cultural Revolution lasted 10 years, and football, alongside the entire social
infrastructure was destroyed. It was not until Mao’s death in September 1976, that
football began to develop again. Amazingly, China held a twelve-team international
tournament in 1977, including nine teams from overseas (Simons, 2008). From 1977-
1978, Chinese football hosted three international invitational tournaments where 24
teams from different countries and regions visited China, and different Chinese teams
visited 52 countries/regions (NPESC Sports Literature and History Committee & the
CFA 1993). Football also played a positive role in improving the Sino-US relationship. A
series of football matches were played between the New York Cosmos and the Chinese
National Team in China and America, with the New York Cosmos becoming the first
Western club to visit China in 1977, including star players Pele and Beckenbauer (ibid).

40
It was the first time a Swedish club lost to an Asian team. Djurgarden won the Swedish League in the
1959 season.

144
The rise of Mr Deng Xiaoping to power at the end of 1970s brought with it economic
reform and the ‘Open door’ policy. Under the ‘Open door’ policy and the subsequent
political decentralisation, sports were allowed to move towards market forces and
commercialism. The training system was quickly restored from top to bottom, and the
league competitions were reassembled. Provincial teams and local FAs were quickly
equipped with the new policy and subsequently adopted a more commercial approach. In
order to generate extra funds, partnerships with enterprises were established. As a result,
elite teams had more flexibility in gaining sponsorship and benefiting from commercial
activity.

Moreover, to install the reform policy, the State Council approved the NPESC’s proposal
– A Number of Measures to Improve Football Skills and the Playing Standard (NPESC,
1979), which set out eight principles mandated to enhance the game’s development and
competitiveness.
1. Popularising the game among youths
2. Concentrating development in key football regions
3. Forming a National Youth team
4. Reinforcing international exchanges, inviting foreign teams in and sending
Chinese teams out
5. To strengthen scientific research
6. To continue hosting international tournaments
7. To build football training centres
8. To give football more social publicity

These principles demonstrated that the government still determined the direction for
football development. Furthermore, the coherent training and selection system was re-
institutionalised, and the implementation of the 1979 proposal became the priority for
Chinese football development over the following ten years (NPESC Sports Literature and
History Committee & the CFA, 1993).

145
By the early 1980s, national competitions were held at all tiers of the pyramid structure.
The elite system was quickly revived, and a national cohesive competition structure was
re-established once more. For example, the Sprout Cup, the Seedling Cup and the Hope
Cup were introduced for players in different age groups nationwide, and the annual youth
tournament for 16 key football cities (Liang 2003, Simons 2008). At the top level, two
tiers of league competitions were reorganised - Jia League and Yi League.

Generally speaking, football development in China was controlled by the government and
influenced strongly by the overall political environment, and government sport policy. In
the early days of the PRC under Mao’s administration, sport policies placed an emphasis
on ‘sports for all’. That is to say, mass participation was considered more important than
elite competitions, and this was both reflected in Mao’s cultural doctrine and reinforced
by his popular social slogans (Wu 1990).

Once the reformation of the economy had begun, the sports policy and priority shifted
from mass participation to elite development in the 1980s, accelerated by the Los
Angeles Olympic Games. The sports slogans changed, highlighting the sudden paradigm
shift - from ‘Friendly First, Competition Second’ to ‘Break out of Asia, Advance in the
World’ (Jarvie et al 2008; Whitby 1999). As competitiveness was increasingly promoted,
the government noted that sport could not only motivate patriotism, but could also be
utlised as a profit-making institution (ibid).

In terms of football governance, the principles of political decentralisation, recognition of


market forces and use of economic incentives are increasingly affecting the way that
football is managed. At the top level, the NPESC delegated more power to the newly
created Football Office in 1986. The Football Office dealt with overall football
development issues, and was also the decision-making body linked between the CFA and
the NPESC. The NPESC mainly dealt with policy-making and supervised the overall
Chinese sports development, while the CFA focused on the game’s popularisation as well
as to improving international relationships with other overseas organisations (NPESC
Sports Literature and History Committee & the CFA 1993). Such structure allowed major

146
decisions to be made one level below the NPESC, which brought additional flexibility for
the game to develop with increased market activities.

As football development got back on track in the 1980s, market elements became
increasingly involved in the game under the reform policies. Enterprises began
sponsoring elite teams and tournaments in order to enhance their business images and
even the naming rights of the 1986 and 1987 national Jia league were sold for the first
time41 (ibid). Moreover, in 1986 the first football trust was established by individuals and
social groups in Guangdong province, which supported the Fushan football team, and
staged many local tournaments. Despite this new lease of commercial life, the overall
top-down governance structure remained distinctly state-controlled. This pattern
demonstrates the trade-off between the capitalist market approach and the communist
state control. The logic behind this was summarised by senior politician Chen Yun (1986,
p287): “We cannot hold the bird too tightly. If we do so, the bird will be suffocated.
Therefore, we must allow it to fly, but only allow it to fly within a cage. If there were no
cage, it would fly away. If we can say that the bird is the revitalisation of the economy,
then the cage is the state plan. Of course, the size of this ‘cage’ must be proper. This
‘cage’ per se must continuously be adjusted.”

5.2.2 Professionalisation
Turner (1976, 1978) suggests that cultural readjustment typically follows a crisis, and that
it is a crisis that brings about change. In the Chinese case, the economic crises following
Mao’s Cultural Revolution led to Deng’s economic reforms and brought with it new
policies, a new attitude and new expectations in sports development.

The Tiananmen Event in 1989, the collapse of the Soviet Union and the East European
communist countries in the early 1990s had been seen as a warning sign for the CCP to
instigate political reform, however, the events signalled that change was inevitable
(Jones, 2000). In the wider economic sphere, the Communist Party’s 14th Congress

41
Hong Kong based Goldlion Holding Limited sponsored the 1986 & 1987 league competitions, which was
named as The Goldlion Cup National Jia League. The champion won the Goldlion Cup trophy.

147
adopted proposals for establishing the socialist market economy in 1992. In 1993, the
Third Plenum of the 14th Party Congress administrated a report entitled Decisions on
Issues Concerning the Establishment of a Socialist Market Economic Structure (Central
Committee CCP, 1993), which made four major advances. These included establishing a
more rule-based system, building market-supporting institutions, protecting property
rights and ownership (Qian, 1999). As the scale and the scope of the reforms expanded,
further strategies for dismantling planning controls and transferring state-owned
enterprises into “trusts” were laid down (Amara, et al 2005).

In 1989, the CFA proposed to adapt a business model to its operation. By February 1990,
the NPESC had approved the CFA’s proposal, and delegated all football administrative
power to the governing body, while at the same time abolishing the Football Offices
(ibid). After a further re-construction, the CFA was required to work like a business
entity. By 1993, the CFA became responsible for its own administrative costs, and its
income had to be accounted for as a part of its annual budget.

Within the sporting system, all major changes occurred in the 1990s, “a reduction in the
size of the Sports Commission had already been implemented at the beginning of the
1990s” (Jones, 1999b p5) when the central government demanded a further
decentralisation in sports, while simultaneously moving certain sports towards Western
style professionalism. Promoting professionalism was also part of introduced idea of
accountability, which can be separated from the government’s direct control over sport to
a certain degree. Furthermore, the promotion of professional sports reduces direct state
investment (ibid). In 1998, even the NPESC was downgraded from its ministry status.

Against the backdrop of the economic reform, the Chinese government intended to utilise
the commercial approach towards sports development in order to promote both patriotism
and consumption (Jarvie et al 2008). As the most popular sport, and with well-developed
professional models available in Europe to follow, football was chosen as a pioneering
sport in undergoing professional transformation (Jones, 1999b). The reason being this
was that the immense popularity of the game and its high social profile in the country

148
greatly raised expectations placed upon the national team. This was especially poignant
after China’s first ever world cup campaigns in 1981/2, in which China eventually lost in
an ill-prepared play-off following New Zealand’s dramatic away win against Saudi
Arabia in the last group match42. This campaign brought the World Cup qualification
tantalisingly close, heightening expectations for the national team to qualify for the
World Cup Finals during the early reform period, similar to people’s high hopes for
economic reform after the Cultural Revolution at this time.

Yet despite the best efforts of the CFA, a series of defeats since the 1980s at the World
Cup qualifying round placed an inordinate amount pressure on the governing body and its
officials. By the 1990s, the pressure had reached boiling point, the catalyst being failure
to qualify for the 1994 World Cup. The defeat triggered a massive public outcry. “It was
unprecedented and became a Chinese version of football being more than a matter of life
and death” (Ashton, 2002 p64). The CFA, the national team and the overall football
policy were thoroughly criticised in every respect, Chinese football was not living up to
its potential or to people’s expectations, and people began calling for fundamental
reform.

Against this backdrop, the government had to do something in order to ease the pressure
from the governing body and save football from the unprecedented crisis. Moreover,
neighbouring countries, Japan and Korea had already successfully launched their
professional leagues, and this, coupled with the European football models to copy, made
football an obvious choice for the Chinese authorities to pioneer its sports reform and
further marketisation. Indeed, the professional league was announced under the new
sports policies and the government’s determination. Coupled with economic growth and a

42
New Zealand (away) beat Saudi Arabia 5: 0 (the first home match 2:2). The result was widely suspected
of being fixed before kick-off., however, it earned New Zealand a play-off opportunity with China. China
finished the qualify campaign two rounds before New Zealand with three points and five clear goals lead,
she actually had one foot in the WC Finals but she was caught off guard, then lost 1: 2 in the unprepared
play-off. From the Kiwi’s point of view, the match was a miracle; from the Chinese perspective, the match
was a scandal – with half-time score line at 5: 0. Moreover, the direct result of the match forced the AFC to
make rule change. From that match onwards the last round matches in all major AFC tournaments and
World Cup qualifiers are scheduled to be played at the same time.

149
newly launched five-day working week, the CFA Marlboro Jia A League kicked-off in
1994.

The new Jia A League started with twelve teams and its structure was a typical European
home-away set up. A major novelty in this professional league was the introduction of
foreign players. Moreover, a transfer system was also introduced the following season. 11
Jia A clubs were sponsored by their local enterprises 43 , and the league itself was
sponsored by Philip Morris ($1.2m) 44 , which took the name Marlboro Jia A League
(Saisai 2011). The league also attracted other sponsors at different levels, including
“Budweiser, Clarion, Canon, Ericsson, Ford, Pepsi, Samsung, Fuji Film, General Motors,
JVC, Korean Air, Olympus, Santafe, and Vinda; the CFA Cup was also sponsored by
Philips” (Hwang & Jarvie 2003, p84).

The open ceremony of the 1994 Marlboro Jia A League. Source: (Saisai 2011)

43
The Army team was the exception because of political sensitivity
44
According to the exchange rates then $1.2m equivalent just under ¥ 15m. The full table of the league
naming sponsorship over the years can be seen at the Section 5.4.3.

150
At this particular stage in the game’s reform, government financial support was no longer
the principal source of income for the clubs (with the exception of the Army team).
Instead, money from lucrative sponsorship contracts became an even more important
source of liquidity. A typical professional football club was sponsored by a local SOE,
and it provided the majority of the funds. For example, Sichuan FC had an eight-year
contract (from 1993) with local alcoholic company – Quang Xing, which was worth ¥1m
per year. Based on the club’s performance there was the potential for a further ¥2m
(Jones 1999b). Due to a strong financial commitment, the enterprises gradually took
control of the club management.

In 1995, the government issued a new sports policy – the President Order (Jiang, 1995),
which consists of eight chapters, the key features being:
● To move towards market forces and commercialism;
● To separate the government agency from sports agencies;
● Concerns for mass sport, leisure and free time;
● Sports management issue – as opposed to simply sport provision;
● The active promotion of sponsorship;
Some of the details of this regulation made clear what was desired. For example in
Article 3
Sport is valued for its contribution to the economic, social and military development of
China…
Article 24
China promotes the development of competitive sport and encourages athletes to improve
the level of their skills, in order to raise the standard of sports competition in China, and
gain honours for the country.

The new policy indicated the direction for sports development and the government’s
overarching desire for a market-orientated economics. Compared with the State Council
approved NPESC (1979)’s old football development principles, the new policy linked
economic development and sports development, combining the sporting goal of gaining
honours for the nation and the commercial goal of financial self-sustainability.

151
Despite the football re-construction being a policy-led reform, the failure of the World
Cup campaign in 1993 directly accelerated the speed of policy implementation and the
process of professionalisation. By contrast, after the professional league took off, more
commercial activities were drawn into the game. “The whole concept of sports in China
is shifting radically towards more professionalism, rethinking sports management,
improving the infrastructure and boosting commercial opportunities from events”
(Ashton 2002, p23). In 1995, the NPESC set up a Football Management Centre in order
to meet the commercial demands of the professional game (Jones 1999b).

Compared to the ‘state amateur’ model, professionalisation also created a transfer market,
which allowed not only Chinese players to move between different clubs but also foreign
players, who were introduced into the Chinese professional leagues. As Mr Lang
Xiaonong – former Head of the League Department explains (interview 03/09/08):

“A relaxation on players’ mobility underlines many of the principles of the reform - it


brings more dynamic elements into the game, and encourages healthy competition
amongst players as a whole. Moreover, the transfer system signals professionalisation
and the free market development.”

Although professionalisation provided a new opportunity for players to move between


clubs, the transfer system was introduced with Chinese characteristics (not exactly
according to FIFA regulation) as the transfer rules adjusted from season to season.
Despite the fact that players are able to move between clubs under the transfer system,
the CFA has placed the labour market firmly under its control, especially in relation to
international transfers. Although a system in line with FIFA regulations is expected to be
introduced in the near future, no date has been determined. As Professor Jin Zhiyang
explains (interview, 08/08/08)45:

“A market-orientated industry should provide players with more freedom – the


international transfer model has to be the ultimate aim. However, Chinese football has its

45
Senior Consultant of the CFA, a former national team coach.

152
uniqueness which therefore requires more time for the CFA to fully adopt FIFA
regulations. Putting the transfer system in line with the international model is the aim
and given time it will be employed.”

1966 the 1979 1986 Set


The CFA was Cultural returned to up the 1995 set
reestablished Revolution FIFA & Football up the
in 1955 under severely NPESC Office; Football
the damaged proposal to Sold Manage-
Communist football raise the league’s ment
regime development playing naming Centre
as a whole standard right

The early The 1950s 1978 reviving The early 1993 CFA 2004
1950s, the & 60s, football 1980s responsible Launched
elite learning activities & adopted the for its own the Super
training and from the organising commercial budget; 1994 League
selection Soviet & E, international approach professional-
system was Europeans tournaments isation
introduced

5-2 Chronological chart – Key football policy development

The drive behind the re-construction of sports and football was a gradual change of the
overall environment of Chinese economic development. Professionalisation brought
significant changes into the football industry, which affected not only the CFA’s business
practice, but also the relationships between itself and other stakeholders. The following
section will analyse the impact of these changes and the conflicts raised.

5.3 Modern development and current issues of the CFA

5.3.1 The NPESC and the CFA


The NPESC was the ministry in charge of all individual sports governing bodies. Formed
in 1952, it was responsible for promoting and developing sport throughout the country
(Xie 1990). The NPESC had branches both at the provincial and city levels. Its mission
included carrying out a long-term sports development strategy alongside government

153
policy; increasing mass participation in sports; supporting sports research; and
supervising international exchange programmes.

The CFA was originally formed in 1924 and affiliated to FIFA in 1931 under the
Nationalist government. It was then relocated to Taiwan after the Civil War (Twydell
1994). The Communist government reconstructed the CFA in January 1955, and it is self-
defined as a non-governmental organisation, which ‘justifies’ a suitable status to affiliate
with external bodies, such as FIFA and the AFC.

5.3.1a Historical development of the CFA and its relationship with the AFC and
FIFA
Due to both the People’s Republic of China (PRC supported by the Soviet Bloc) and the
Republic of China’s [ROC (Taiwan) supported by the West] claims to represent the
whole China after the Civil War in 1949, the Communist delegate rejected the ROC’s
admission to FIFA during the 1954 FIFA Congress, and eventually withdrew from FIFA
in 1958 (Homburg 2006). In addition, on creation of the AFC in 1954, the Chinese
Communist government refused to recognise it as truly representative of the Asian
associations (ibid). As a result, China was isolated from world football.

1993 failed 2004


1955 1976 1980 to reach the hosted
establis joined group 1984 final the Asian
hed the the AFC; stage the qualifiers of Cup;
CFA Placed 3rd of the Asian the World
Cup that
Finished
under in the Asian Cup
accelerated as
CCP Asian Cup runner-
the process runner-up
Cup Finals up

1958 1979 the 1981 lost 1985 the 2002


withdrew CFA the extra World reached the
from agreed to play-off Cup World Cup
FIFA for rejoin in the Qualifier Finals for
political FIFA World May 19th the first
reasons Cup Event time
qualify

5-3 Chronological chart – key AFC & FIFA events that had a major impact on Chinese football development

154
Alongside the improved Sino-US relationship and the global political environment
towards Communist China, the PRC replaced the ROC in the UN Security Council as the
sole representative of the whole China in 1972. Consequently, international football
development gradually came to China’s term. The CFA joined the AFC in 1976 and
played the Asian Cup in the same year. With help from the first non-European FIFA
president Joan Havelange, the CFA returned to FIFA in 1979 46 and reintegrated into the
international football community (ibid).

In 1995, the first year after professionalisation, the NPESC set up its first management
centre - the Chinese Football Management Centre (CFMC), as part of a sports reform to
deal with football commercialisation (Jones 1999b). The CFMC focuses on strategy
making and internal communications within the government hierarchy. In 1998, the
NPESC was downgraded to bureau status following the State Council restructuring, and
it was renamed the SGSA. On the one hand, the CFMC is, in theory, one of the many
sports management centres under the SGSA positioned above the CFA within the
governance hierarchical order. On the other hand, and in practice, the CFMC is based
within the CFA’s headquarter and all its officials are also staff of the CFA. The Director
of the CFMC is appointed by the NPESC/SGSA and also holds the post of Deputy
President of the CFA simultaneously. Therefore the CFMC and the CFA are in fact
effectively the same administration merely operating under difference names. As the
CFMC, it deals predominately with internal sports bureaucracy and policy-orientated
development within the Chinese sports governance system. By contrast, as the CFA, it
deals with external, international affairs and more practical/experimental orientated
development. The implication of this structure is that the governing body of Chinese
football is a mix between a governmental organisation (CFMC) and a non-governmental
organisation (CFA).

46
Taiwan based federation remained in FIFA & the AFC under the name of Chinese Taipei.

155
5.3.2 Stakeholders in the Chinese football industry
In order to draw a successful stakeholder analysis of the football industry, key
stakeholders within the football industry must be identified. According to Philips’s (2003)
fairness framework and identification of the stakeholder research places stakeholders into
two categories: normative stakeholders and derivative stakeholders. Normative
stakeholders are indentified based on fairness and moral principles. The management is
under an ethical obligation to address the interests of normative stakeholders, as their
organisations voluntarily accept the contribution from them. However, such obligations
are not imposed or stipulated by others from outside (Philips, 2003). Derivative
stakeholders are indentified based on power influence. The management is required to
address the interest of these derivative stakeholders, as they are the group holding power
to affect the organisation.

Ducrey et al (2003) and Armara et al (2005) draw stakeholders’ maps of the football
industry which do not distinguish the different categories amongst stakeholders.
According to Philips’s (2003) definition, football authorities and the government are
considered derivative stakeholders as they possess the power to affect the way the
football industry develops. Fans, players, clubs, investors, and so on are considered
normative stakeholders as they do not necessarily have any formal representation at the
top of industry’s decision-making level. However, there is no explicit boundary between
normative and derivative stakeholders. Neither a normative nor a derivative status is
steady for a stakeholder, and it can change depending on timing and the issues involved.
For example, sponsors can influence the game significantly through their financial power.
Despite that, they do not have the same strong position as governing bodies, and
moreover sponsors can be easily replaced. As derivative stakeholders, football
authorities’ potential claims must be accounted for due to their potential effects on the
industry. This does not mean however, that the football industry should pay less attention
to other stakeholders’ interests. For instance, fans are normative stakeholders but they do
possess derivative claims in terms of their financial contribution and loyalty. In addition,
and within the same normative stakeholder category, all stakeholders differ according to
their legitimate claims and contributions to the industry. Stakeholder theory offers an

156
adequate means through which one can not only understand different interests from a
range of stakeholders within the football network, but also comprehend the complex
relationships amongst them.

5.3.2a Normative and derivative stakeholders and the stakeholder map


Base on the Philips’s (2003) definition, this section looks at different normative and
derivative stakeholder groups individually, identifying their interests and positions within
the Chinese football industry.

Normative stakeholders:
Fans/Supporters: They are typically associated with a particular club, and have an
emotional investment in the game. The fans’ strong attachment to the game leaves them
in a relatively weak position to face the clubs’ financial exploitation and poor treatment
(Hamil, 1999). Their main interests include demanding good results and expecting their
club to listen to their views. Despite fans rarely changing their support (emotions run
higher than a simple cost/benefit application) towards their clubs, fan groups are not often
sufficiently organised.

Clubs: They are the basic cells of the industry, and contribute the most valuable products
– matches, with the top professional clubs also generating the most revenue in the
industry. They are organised differently according to their status and ownership structures.
Their main interests are on pitch performance and financial success.

Shareholders: Owners of football clubs who contribute capital. Their main interests are
receiving a return on their investment, team success on the pitch and acquiring social
prestige as club owners. They also can have derivative role if a shareholder owns a large
stake of a club.

Sponsors: One of the major financial sources for the industry. Their main interests
including having a close association with the game or particular clubs and a high degree

157
of exposure and visibility to the public, through which they can market their goods or
themselves.

Players: They possess specialised skills and are in limited supply at the top end of the
game. Top players command high bargaining powers, which demonstrate the derivative
claim they hold over clubs. However, at the lower end of the game, players can be easily
replaced. Despite the existence of a players’ union in some countries, Chinese players are
not well organised as a whole. Their main interests are financial reward and self-
realisation.

Community: Communities in which football clubs are located provide a core fan base
for the clubs. As social institutions, clubs owe an obligation of fairness to these groups.
Communities play their social role mostly through community schemes with their local
clubs. Their main interests are promoting sport, local identity, prestige and mutual benefit.

Derivative stakeholders:
FIFA: The supreme body of world football, setting rules and regulations for the game
and promoting football worldwide at all levels. Its main aims are developing the game’s
solidarity and maintaining a strong control.

The AFC: The governing body in Asia. It promotes the game at both professional and
grass-roots level and ensures alignment with FIFA regulations. The main function is
holding a monopolised position in Asia.

The CFA: This governs football in China, and promotes the game at all levels. Internally,
it is also known as the Chinese Football Management Centre. Its main interest is to
creating good conditions for national teams with the aim of achieving desired results.

The SGSA: The government department (formerly known as NPESC) oversees the
overall sporting development in China. It has a hierarchical position directly above the
CFMC, with power to appoint the Director of the CFMC and pick the presidential

158
candidate of the CFA. Its main function is pursuing national sport teams’ success at all
level on the international stage, with a specific focus on the Olympic Games.

The Super League/League Committees: The decision-making bodies of Chinese


professional leagues. Their main responsibilities are promoting both the Super League
and Jia League, and making decisions about important issues on a professional level.

The Super League Company: This company limited by shares, is owned by all Super
League clubs and the CFA. Its main activities are collectively selling the commercial
rights of the Super League in order to generate revenue and expanding its market value.

Media/Press: Both the media and the press have significant coverage over the game’s
development. Their main interests lie in selling their products – TV programmes,
newspapers; and generating revenue through subscriptions and advertisements.

Local FAs/Authorities: These often own facilities and have the power to influence the
way a club operates. They main interests are winning medals at competitions and
National Games; using football clubs as vehicles to promote sport, local identity and
prestige for mutual benefit.

Although normative and derivative concepts are able to make a distinction between
stakeholders, there is no explicit boundary. Normative and derivative stakeholders are not
mutually exclusive, normative stakeholders can have derivative claims and vice versa.
Furthermore, both listed stakeholders and the stakeholder map (below) are not exhaustive.
The purpose of this section is to provide a starting point and basic framework from which
to move on to further stakeholder analysis in the Chinese football industry.

159
Shareholders Sponsors

Support er s
Players

Clubs
Community

FIFA The SGSA


The Chinese Football Industry

The AFC The CFA

Media/Press Local
FAs/Authorities

The SL/League The SL Company


Committees

Normative stakeholder
Derivative stakeholder
Based on Duerey et al (2003) and Amara et al (2005) stakeholder football models
Figure 5-4 Stakeholder map of the Chinese football industry

5.3.3 The mission of the CFA


The CFA is the sole national governing body for football in China. According to the CFA
Charter (2005) chapter 1, it complies with Chinese Civil Law, Sports law, FIFA and the
AFC regulations. Its missions include governing the game and its development,
organising competitions, promoting football in society, widening its popularity,
representing China by participating in international affairs, and generating capital for
football development through necessary activities.

160
As the sole governing body, the CFA enjoys a monopolised position in the game’s
development. Its principal responsibility is to ensure that its objectives are achieved
through the implementation of good governance. With this in mind, good governance can
be achieved through 1) clearly defined roles and responsibilities of all participants; 2)
transparency in how these roles and responsibilities are defined, monitored and enforced
by governing organisations. Good governance is even more important for organisations
that enjoy a monopolised position in their industry, as this can have a direct impact on the
industry’s development.

Compared to fifty years ago, the CFA has undoubtedly had to adapt to some new features
to push forward football reform. The newly introduced Sports Law remains the principal
legislation to which it must adhere. Practically, the CFA has the incentive to finance itself
and to take the necessary initiatives in facing challenges posted by the market economy.

The CFA Charter (2005) defines the CFA’s responsibilities and roles below:

● Taking full responsibility for football administration, drawing up development policies,


strategy and plans, and supervising member associations.

● Managing national teams at all levels.

● Responsible for supervising the development of football clubs and overseeing youth
development programmes.

● Drawing up the institutional structure for national competitions, development plans


and refereeing regulations, and responsible for organising national competitions.

● Responsible for training programmes for referees, coaches and staff from member
associations and clubs.

● Organising scientific research for football training in order to raise training standards.

● Setting standards for grounds and other equipment.

161
● Drawing up plans for international exchanges and holding responsibility for the
implementation of such exchanges.

● Providing professional consultation and related services, as well as generating revenue


for further development.

● Ensuring improved self-development and integration with society.

Looking at the CFA’s responsibility and roles confirms that the CFA maintains its
monopolised position, safeguarding the coherent football structure between all levels.
This demonstrates a hands-on approach on a national level.

5.3.4 The structure of the CFA

The CFA was led by the SGSA. It currently has two types of membership - union
membership and individual membership (the CFA, Charter 2005). Union members are
the local FAs, which include provincial, municipality, key football developing cities, and
trade unions. Individual members are honorary members, which are awarded to people
who make significant contributions to Chinese football (ibid, Chapter 3).

According to the CFA Charter (2005), the congress is the supreme controlling organ of
the CFA. It is held every four years and handles matters such as the election of the
President, and the election of members to the Executive Committee. An ‘extraordinary
meeting’ can be called if requested by over one third of its members. The congress
enables all members to gather together and conduct the important business of Chinese
football such as proposing, adopting and amending statutes; and considering the
Secretary General’s reports. The congress itself is made up of two types of delegate: 1)
the delegates from each local FA; 2) all Executive Committee members of the CFA (the
President, Deputy and Vice Presidents, the Secretary General, the Financial Director)

162
plus all heads of the CFA’s various technical committees. Furthermore, representatives of
clubs from the top two divisions can attend meetings47.

The Chinese Football Association


(The Congress)

The Executive Committee

The Chairmen Committee

The Secretary General

Professional Competition Team International General Technical Youth &


Development Department China Affairs Administration Department Social
& Regulatory Develop-
Department ment
National Vision
teams: China
The Super League U-23, U-
21, U-19
and U-
17
The Jia League

Figure 5-5 The structure of the CFA

The Executive Committee holds a term of four years, and is the highest management
organ and responsible for implementing congress statutes and decisions. Annual meetings
of the Executive Committee require at least two thirds of members to attend in order to be
quorate. Its powers include the right to nominate candidates for the Presidency, recall the
President of congress; commission work reports for congress; and approve/recall
membership, and so on. Any decision made by the Executive Committee requires a two
third majority of votes to be passed.

47
Club representatives do not have the voting right, only the previous two types of delegate can vote.

163
The Chairmen Committee implements the decisions of the Executive Committee. It
approves football development strategy and policy, as well as approving the final
selection for national teams’ coaches. The CFA President appoints several Vice
Presidents, with the Secretary General and the Financial Director forming the committee.
The committee members meet on a monthly basis and the CFA President attends
meetings when necessary. The Secretary General is the highest administrative official
who leads a department which deals solely with daily affairs.

5.3.5 Modern conflicts of the CFA

Conflict with local FAs

The CFA operates many programmes, ranging from the grassroots to top-flight levels,
whilst the provincial FAs are responsible for football development at a regional level. In
the pre-professional era, local FAs were limited to a fixed budget when to implementing
the CFA’s programmes, as well as their own programmes. With political decentralisation
and a market-oriented economy gradually introduced, the CFA and local FAs’ budgets
were slowly cut by both central government and local government respectively. As a
result, implementing the CFA’s programmes at local level became more challenging with
less effective funding granted each time. In theory, the CFA oversees the whole football
development through its pyramid structure. However, it has limited means to implement
its overall development plans at local levels. This is particularly the case for grassroots
development, which largely relies on local FAs to do the job.

As affiliated members of the CFA, local FAs have a good understanding of long-term
development strategy. However, local FAs are under the direct leadership of their
regional sports bureaus48, their performance is directly assessed by their local government
rather than by the CFA and based on achievement of local elite teams, especially

48
The local Physical Education Commissions were downgraded to local Sports Bureaus in 1998 when the
NPSEC was downgraded to the SGSA.

164
performance in the National Games, even the number of players who were selected by
the national team is counted. Moreover, football officials’ own promotion is also
determined by such results. Compared to elite development, implementing a long-term
grassroots programme has consequently become less appealing to local FAs.

On the one hand, there is an overlapping emphasis on elite development from both the
CFA and local FAs; on the other hand, both the CFA and local FAs lack the incentive to
work on grassroots programmes. Mr Li Lipeng, Chief Officer of the CFA’s League
Department49 believes that the priority of the CFA has to be on elite development, as only
the local FAs can effectively promote the game at the grassroots level. He explains:
(personal interview, 10/01/08)

“As the governing body, we have a responsibility to strengthen our football development
at all levels. However, we cannot implement all our plans in every single respect. Local
FAs can function more effectively than us locally, especially at the grassroots
development. Unfortunately, they lack the initiative to do so, and they give priority to
elite teams too. The balance between professional and grassroots development is not
right.”

By contrast, at the local level, Ms Zo Xioudi – Vice Director of Competition Department


of Shanghai FA states: (personal interview, 17/01/08)

“As a member of the SLC, a good communicative structure is maintained between us and
the CFA at professional level, however, at the grassroots level, it lacks incentives (for us)
and effective communication between the CFA and local FAs. The overall national
cohesiveness of development strategy does not exist”.

The lack of cohesion between the CFA and local authorities at a practical level is not due

49
The League Department was renamed as the Professional Development & Regulatory Department in
April 2010.

165
to the officials being unable to comprehend the importance of grassroots development,
but is simply a by-product of the cultural/political reality that existed when grassroots
programmes were implemented. As Ms Zo Xioudi explains further in the same interview
(17/01/08):

“A strategic and succinct goal is missing with regards to our grassroots programmes.
Firstly, with limited grassroots budget most local programmes are lacking depth and
consistency; secondly, the CFA designed programmes can be expensive or unrealistic to
implement in the long run; thirdly, local politicians pay less attention to these
programmes”.

For example, after 2004 the CFA promised ¥8m to eight districts across the country for
grassroots development. However, ¥2m was never distributed for implementation (Ran,
2008a). Mr Chen Xiaozheng, General Sectary of Qingdao FA states (at an official
meeting of Vision China project, 18/11/07):

“To get financial support from the CFA is difficult, even just for a small amount, the
procedure is very bureaucratic, and at the end of the day, you are not guaranteed
anything. I wonder anyone in the CFA really care about grassroots development, as you
can see, someone from the CFA should have been at this meeting (suggested and invited
by the AFC), where are they? We have to depend on ourselves to fund our grassroots
programmes. Support from the CFA is limited.”

The researcher observed that a similar situation also happened in Zibo and Jinan during
the researcher was working on the Vision China project with both local FAs. On the one
hand, there is lack of financial support for grassroots development from the CFA at local
level; on the other hand, CFA promoted its own grassroots programmes without support
from the local FAs. Mr Li Lipeng also explains that how CFA tried to implement various
grassroots programmes of its own (personal interview, 10/01/08).

166
“We directly invested several million Yuan into some grassroots programmes a few
years ago (when the CFA’s financial status was healthy), but the results did not come out
as good as we expected, therefore, further investment was stopped because we did not
have the same financial strength as we used to be. Purely relying on the local FAs for
grassroots development does not work, but the CFA cannot be committed fully to
grassroots projects either”.

Contingent Necessary

(High Level common values) ◙

Compatible

(Low) Present (Highly connected)

Incompatible (Low)

◙ The CFA/local FA relationship

Figure 5-6 The development trend of the CFA /local FA relationship

The relationship between the CFA and local FAs is a compatible one in terms of their
common values – both of them are working together to promote the game, albeit at
different levels within the same pyramid structure. The CFA/local FAs’ relationship can
be described as being ‘Necessary Compatible’. Since professionalisation, the nature of
this relationship has dramatically developed. Figure 5-6 depicts the shift towards a
‘Necessary Incompatible’ relationship. It is still a ‘necessary’ relationship as both are
intertwined within the pyramid structure, however, it is seen as ‘incompatible’ in the
sense that through a more aggressive market-orientated approach and reduced state direct
funding at all levels. As both governing bodies prioritise elite development, the cohesion
and communication at the grassroots level became inconsistent. These changes have
increased and diversified the material interests available to local FAs and in so doing
have weakened the ‘compatible’ relationship and policy consistency between the CFA
and local FAs. Mr Song Xiaochun – the Chief Financial Officer of CFA and the CSL
points out: (personal interview, 23/05/2013)

167
“Under the market economy both the local FAs and the CFA try to generate more income
through market activities. We are working together within the same system but financed
separately. There is only one CFA funding grassroots programme designated in five
cities. Local programmes can be more money-orientated and conflict with our guideline,
due to the fact that they are financed by local FAs, we have a very limited influence.”

Despite weakened cohesion between the two parties, the relationship of the CFA and
local FAs remains in the structure of the ‘Necessary Compatible’. Both parties need to
continually work together, and their association is strong despite their more diversified
material interests. The CFA needs local FAs to promote the game at different levels
locally, and local FAs need to remain in the CFA’s framework in order to access national
competitions.

Conflicts with clubs

The market approach and subsequent professionalisation brought a proliferation of


stakeholders and a variety of economic interests into the Chinese football industry. As
such, the CFA lost its state financial backing, even though it maintained considerable
power and authority. All the CFA’s operational expenses rely heavily on professional
leagues’ sponsorship (for example, the CFA controls overall sponsorship, naming rights,
and national & international broadcasting rights).

In adopting market-focused commercial activities in 1993, the CFA set up its own
commercial enterprise called the China Football Industrial Development Company 50
(CFIDC) with the aim of marketing the association (the CFA) and negotiating business
deals on behalf of the CFA and the leagues.

50
It is also called FU TE BAO (using the direct pronunciation from the English word ‘Football’) Company.

168
At clubs level, the clubs gained financial flexibility through ownership reform. A football
club has to be sustained and operated as a company according to Company Law (1994).
Therefore, financial sustainability became an important element for professional clubs.

Before the launch of the Super League, the CFA also took a ‘gate income’ of 5% and
2.5% from both the Jia A and Jia B clubs respectively (Eaves et al 2003). In terms of
revenue redistribution, the collective operation of the Super League extracts roughly 60-
70% of commercial resources from every club, and revenue redistributed to clubs
accounts for only 10-20% of their operational costs (Ran 2008b). These practices
naturally caused serious concerns from a wide range of stakeholders. As Mr Wei Jizhong,
Chairman of the China Sports Industry Company points out (Ashton, 2002 p68): “How
much football revenue remains unrecorded? How many riches are lost? Everyone agrees
that reform is required, yet no one involved at the structural level wants to change their
own methods of governing or themselves”.

As the CFA is in a monopolised position and controls all the resources, all profit acquired
does not necessarily benefit the clubs and government, but instead becomes a private
asset for the association. These practices created conflicts with the clubs’ financial
interests, and put the CFA’s credibility in balance.

When market forces play an increasing role in the development of football, the CFA’s old
dictatorial philosophy has caused a degree of tension with the clubs’ own unilaterally fair
commercial approach and business practice. Ultimately, the CFA’s priority lies in
international success, with this in mind, club competitions are organised around the
national teams’ international fixtures. For example, the 2001 season began in May - two
months later than the normal season to allow the Olympic squad more time to prepare for
the Athens Games’ qualifying campaign. Despite significant consternation from clubs,
the CFA pursued this alone, as it viewed this campaign as a rehearsal for the Beijing
Games. The delay had an adverse impact on clubs’ commercial operations and business
commitments, with both clubs and media heavily criticising the CFA. As a result, the
2001 season ended in a compromise between the clubs and the CFA. In order to protect

169
clubs’ business interests, the 2001 season became a promotion-only affair, and the 2002
season subsequently became relegation only.

Once more, to ensure thorough preparation for the 2008 Olympic Games, the SGSA
attempted to order the CFA to replace the current league fixture with a new formation
consisting of North and South regional competitions – a plan to limit the 2008 season
from September to December, thereby ensuring no league matches took place before the
Beijing Olympic Games. The proposal did not sit well with all clubs - some of them even
threatened to organise their own league (Li, 2007). Against this backdrop, the SGSA and
the CFA found a degree of compromise, but the 2008 season had to be divided into two
phases, separated by a two-month summer break.

The above example demonstrates that it has been typical of the CFA to break the league’s
integrity without consulting the clubs first. Promotion and relegation are basic principles
in allowing clubs to compete in professional leagues. It is essential that they are
implemented with consistency to avoid a detrimental effect on clubs’ operational and
business development, especially under the market economy. Mr Li Lipeng recognises
this conflict and explains (personal interview, 10/01/08):

“The Association’s focus is on top level football, in particular national teams. We have
significant pressures from people above, therefore, good performances are required. The
national team can lose once, twice, but the third time there will be casualties.”

Indeed, the CFA sacked national team coach Carmacho after embarrassing defeat by
Thailand on 15 June 201351 confirmed governing philosophy of the CFA at the top level.
Mr Li compared football with the long jump – one athletics event:

“Leagues like the running phase, the national team likes that final jump. No matter how
you run, when you get to the point, you try to jump the best you can. We understood

51
The China vs Thailand match was the third defeat that followed defeats by Uzbekistan and Holland
earlier in the same month. The sacking of Camacho was swift despite his $8.5m contract payoff.

170
leagues and grassroots development as the foundations of the game, however, within the
current system, as the national governing body we have our own priorities that need to be
addressed first”.

Mr Li essentially states that despite the governing body understanding the importance of
the league and its integrity, the CFA has to do anything within its power to ensure the
national team performs on the international stage.

By taking up Mr Li’s ‘long-jump’ metaphor, only a solid run will be able to produce a
decent jump. As such, consistent performances from the national team are based on
competitive and consistent leagues (‘the running phase’). The question is that: how far is
it possible to jump without a good run? The running phase is even more important than
the jump itself – its quality determines the jumping distance. Indeed, the reality is cruel,
and the Chinese Olympic team’s performance in Beijing demonstrated that without a
solid run, the best jump can never be far52.

Since the principal source of income for the CFA consists of league sponsorship and
corporate partnerships, conflict of interest has become a key issue of the CFA/club
relationship as the CFA’s political-led practices and self-interest conflict with clubs’
business-orientated operation and such conflicts were highlighted during the 2004 season.
Seven clubs, led by Dalian Shide threatened to withdraw from the league after an on-field
incident (see Chapter Six for more details). As a result, they formed a so-called ‘G7
Group’ 53 and made demands for greater governance accountability and financial
transparency of the CFA.

In Figure 5-7, the relationship between the CFA and clubs is moving towards right and
downwards after professionalisation. It now represents a Necessary/Incompatible
relationship. The advent of professionalisation has resulted in the relationship between

52
The Chinese Olympic Team failed at the group stage.
53
‘G-7’ includes Dalian Shide FC, Liaoning Zhongyu FC, Beijing Hyundai FC, Qingdao Yizhong FC,
Sichuan Guanchen FC, Shenzhen Jianlibao FC and Shanghai International FC.

171
the CFA and clubs becoming more incompatible and less necessary. From the realist
position, the two parties need to be bonded together in order to develop professional
leagues within a legitimate. However, alongside commercial development and
government decentralisation, the relationship between the two parties turns sour, it
becomes less necessary, and their material interests, particularly in a financial sense, have
become more incompatible.

Contingent Necessary
(High level common value)

Compatible ●

(Low) (Highly connected)

Incompatible Present

●the CFA/Clubs relationship (Low)

Figure 5-7 The development trend of the CFA/Club relationship

The CFA needs professional clubs to serve both its political and financial interests, which
often conflict with clubs’ business practices and financial interests under the market
economy. For example, the way that CFA prepares for Olympics. As a result, the
development pattern of the CFA/Club relationship has moved from the state of Necessary
Compatible to Necessary Incompatible. Since professionalisation, the CFA deals with far
more commercial, legal and economic issues than ever-before. Indeed, its self-centred
practices do not favour for the game’s development, and football remains ‘stuck’ between
the market forces that control the clubs and the government that controls the game
(Manzenreiter & Horne 2007).

Internal conflicts - the contradictory nature of the CFA

The governing structure of the CFA is, confusingly, a single administrative body
encompassed under two different names – the CFMC and the CFA. On the one hand, it is

172
the CFMC - a government department union that sits under the leadership of the SGSA,
and which is mandated to follow government sports policies and instructions; on the
other hand, the CFA professes itself to be a non-governmental organisation (following
FIFA regulation). According to its charter (2005), it operates independently to promote
the best interests of the game without political interference. We can therefore see that the
two functions of the CFMC and the CFA are ultimately conflicting. It is not possible for
an organisation to operate as a government department and a non-governmental
organisation simultaneously.

The CFMC represents the government in drawing up policies and developing strategies to
regulate the game. In contrast, the CFA uses its controlling power, through its own
CFIDC, to financially benefit from the game’s commercial development. Historically,
football has been part of a state-organised, government-funded and centrally-controlled
sports system in China since 1949. There is therefore a tendency for politicians to use the
game for mass public campaigns in order to drum up support and underline patriotic
fervour (Brownell 1995). Although FIFA regulations state that a national governing body
should be a non-governmental organisation, yet all CFA staff enjoy civil servant status,
and its non-governmental organisation’s status exists only on paper. The CFA is not only
a government body with substantial powers, but is also directly involved with the
commercial development of the game. In fact, it plays a dual role – that of regulator to
the game, and as a commercial entity. This contradictory nature of the practical term
means that the governing body cannot function effectively either as a governmental
regulator, independent from the game’s commercial development, or as a non-
governmental organisation to represent the best interests of the game under the market-
oriented economy. The broken season of 2008 highlighted the political mismatch and
remains as a testament to its failing.

According to the CFA’s own 2005 Charter, the congress is the highest decision-making
body. As the Chapter Four, Article 17 (1) states:

173
“The congress is called by the Executive Committee and it needs to be held every four
years, in special circumstances it can be delayed for a maximum of one year”.

In fact, no congress was held between 1979 to 2003, and over ten years have passed with
no news of another congress meeting. The Chapter Four, Article 21 (4) states that the
CFA President must be elected by the congress for a four-year term. It is clear that this
rule has not been adhered to as no congressional meetings have taken place since 2003. In
fact, the current administration was appointed by the SGSA and the incumbent President
and its administration fail to meet the legal criteria set out by the latest 2005 charter.

5.4 Development and current issues of league governance

5.4.1 The governance structure


Generally speaking, the league is an organisation that provides a regulated competition
for a certain number of teams to compete in a specific sport. Unlike some European
countries, the football league in China is characterised more as an umbrella department of
the CFA than an independent organisation.

In the pre-professional era, league competitions were staged in one particular city and
played in a single round-robin tournament format. Aside from this, teams were based and
trained in their own cities. The league structure consisted of two divisional league
competitions organised by the CFA at national level - the Jia League and the Yi League.
Further down the scale at the regional level was the Bing League54. Three divisions were
interconnected with promotion and relegation between them. A major weakness of this
round-robin tournament format was that it could not develop strong links between
football teams and their local supporters, as all games were played in one particular city
in a short period of time, and fans rarely had a chance to watch their teams play locally.

54
The Jia League and the Yi League are equivalent to English old Division One and Two respectively.

174
5.4.2 The more inclusive managerial approach
As a result of relaxed state control and economic reform, elite teams transformed into
professional clubs, whose ownership was no longer dictated by the local sports
authorities. The League Department of the CFA was also set up just before the
inauguration of the professional league in 1994. This department was responsible for
dealing with league affairs for both Jia A and Jia B. Alongside ownership transformation
and increasing commercial autonomy, an increasing number of conflicts between clubs
and the CFA began to emerge, and figure 5-7 shows the trend of this development. The
CFA took governance measurements to tackle a variety of conflicts. 15 subcommittees
were created in 2003, a year before the Jia A League was re-launched to the Super
League (Yan 2004). The Super League Committee (SLC) and the League Committee (LC)
were created to organise the Super League and the Jia League respectively.

The SLC began with 15 members - twelve members from twelve clubs, plus three
members from the CFA (one of the CFA Vice-presidents who chairs the Committee, the
Head of the CFA’s League Department and the CEO of the CFIDC 55 ). The CFA
members possess the power of veto. Five club representatives and two CFA members
form the CSL Standing Committee, which is the body mandated to deal with the daily
affairs of the Super League. The SLC was expanded in 2004, with members now
including not only all 16 Super League clubs, but also their related local FAs.

On the topic of league governance, Mr. Yan Shize (2004), the former President of the
CFA stated that: “The Super League Committee provides a platform for a wider range of
stakeholders to get involved in a more democratic decision-making process which
demonstrates a big improvement in our governing mechanism within the CFA’s
framework. It shows our governance structure has been developing towards the direction
of maturity and perfection. The CFA needs to make decisions based on different interests
from various stakeholders in order to achieve the balanced development”. Such
comments indicate that the CFA has recognised increased demands and power of clubs

55
Replaced by CEO of Chinese Super League Company in 2005.

175
with abdication of its dominate governance position by allowing clubs and other
stakeholders into the decision-making process to facilitate professionalisation.

The creation of the SLC has improved the traditional top-down governing mechanism
with a more inclusive approach, it is a step forward for better corporate governance of the
industry allowing for a greater range of interest groups (stakeholders) to take part in one
decision-making body. Mr Yang Yimin (2005), former Vice-president of the CFA,
emphasised the importance of better governance practice and greater representation in his
Work Report of the SLC:

 Expanding the SLC built a greater, more inclusive governance approach for a wider
range of stakeholders. Consequently all stakeholders were allowed a greater involvement
in the decision-making process

 Promoting better communication channels among clubs, as well as between the CFA
and clubs, thereby, and allowing for a better consultation on all aspects of football
development

 Strengthening the CFA’s governing position through transparent and democratic


commercial mechanisms, through which greater accountability can be achieved

Mr Zhu Qilin, member of SLC, Chairman of CSLC explains: (personal interview,


23/05/2013)

“The SLC provides a democratic platform for its members to discuss both business and
football related issues in order to make decisions in the best interest of the league as a
whole. The governance structure strikes for a balanced approach, which fits into China’s
socialist marketing economy.”

5.4.3 Commercial development of the League


The CFA signed a commercial partnership package with the International Management
Group (IMG) in 1993 to promote incoming professional leagues. The IMG was

176
responsible for the leagues’ commercial operation, the CFIDC was dealing with
advertising contracts for both Jia A and Jia B through IMG (Ashton 2002). In 1994 the
Jia A League was sponsored $1.2m 56 by the Philip Morris tobacco company and the
Marlboro League was born. However, new government legislation was introduced in
1998, and tobacco advertising was substantially restricted (tobacco advertising was
banned from stadiums and the TV screens for the interest of public health), as a result,
Philip Morris terminated its sponsorship (Jones 1999b).

From 1999-2002, Pepsi Cola paid $10m57 for the naming rights of the Jia A League.
Siemens spent $5m when it took over in 2003 and paid €8m for the newly launched
Super League in 2004 (Ran 2008b).

The CSL lost its biggest sponsor in 2005 due to the CFA’s inconsistent policies and
unprofessional business practices. As a result of this, the league’s naming rights could not
be sold (ibid). A British broadband telecom company Iphox bought the 2006 naming
right for €8m58. A Chinese brewery company, Kingway paid ¥36m per season for the
2007 and 2008 naming rights, in 2009, the Italian company Pirelli signed a three-year
deal for around €5m a year. However the sponsorship ended in 2010 and the Chinese
property developer Wanda Group took CSL’s naming rights for three years, for the price
of ¥ 195m (Gong 2011).

Due to the CFIDC’s failure to sell the naming rights of the 2005 season, it could no
longer carry responsibility for the league’s commercial operations. After such a
disastrous failure, it was replaced by the newly created Chinese Super League Company
(CSLC) in September 2005. The CSLC is a company limited by shares and concentrates
solely on the leagues’ collective commercial development, sponsorship and so on. The
profits made by the CSLC through collective business operations are redistributed to all
clubs equally. Unlike European football, television revenue has never been a major
income for Chinese clubs. The Chinese Central Television (CCTV) does not pay to

56
10% increase each year thereafter.
57
10% increase each year thereafter.
58
The €8m was not paid fully by Iphox.

177
broadcast league games, but instead gives a specified commercial slot to the CFA. For
example, from 1994-1998, CCTV used two minutes of advertising time in exchange for a
live Jia A League match (Liao 1998). At a local level, clubs negotiate TV rights
individually, and in fact, most matches are free of charge.

Seasons Naming right sponsors Sponsor deals

2011 - 2013 Wanda Group ¥ 195m

2009 - 2010 Pirelli Tyre €5m each year

2007 and 2008 Kingway Beer ¥36m each year

2006 Iphox €8m (paid €500,000)

2005 ----- ------

2003 and 2004 Siemens $5m for 2003


€8m for 2004
1999 - 2002 Pepsi Cola $10m from 1999, 10%
increase each year
afterwards
1994 - 1998 Marlboro $1.2m form 1994, 10%
increase each year
afterwards
Table 5-1: League sponsors (based on all sources analysis)

The CSLC is owned by the CFA and 16 Super League clubs – the CFA owns 36%, and
64% is owned equally by these 16 Super League clubs. According to the 1994 Company
Law, major decisions or changes to the company require two-thirds majority
shareholding approval. Therefore, the structure of the CSLC leaves the CFA with a
controlling power. However, as a gesture of goodwill, the CFA insists on taking an
annual profit of 10%, up to a maximum of ¥10m a year, rather than the 36% it is entitled
to through its shareholding. Mr Li Lipeng – Chief Officer of the CFA’s League
Department explains (personal interview, 10/01/08):

178
“This structure gives stability to the company, as the CFA is always in control. It also
prevents clubs from establishing the 2/3rd majority required to undermine the CFA’s
authority. Financial benefit is not our priority here”.

Stakeholder Density

(High)

The CFA’s Present

(Low) (High)

Centrality

(Low) ◙

◙ before the CSL launch

Figure 5-8 The league governance transition and stakeholder influence

The figure 5-8 summarises the pattern of league governance transition from the CFA’s
perspective. As is shown, the pattern moves to the left and upwards, and the CFA
governing position has changed from a state of high centrality (with dominate powers) to
less centrality. As other stakeholders have been drawn into the decision-making process
(particularly clubs), connections between other stakeholders are closer and more direct,
meaning stakeholder density has developed from low to high. It is worth noting however,
other stakeholders’ influence has increased significantly, the CFA has maintained its
overarching authority. According to Mr Yang Yimin, the former vice-president of the
CFA, the CFA is certainly seeking a leading role in a close working relationship with
clubs. As he stated in an interview (Yang 2003) “Professional leagues are under the
leadership of the CFA, its various committees are dealing with different daily affairs, and
clubs are encouraged to be involved in a democratic decision-making process within
different committees”. As a result, stakeholder influence and the CFA’s governing
position transferred from a configuration of Low Density/High Centrality to High

179
Density/High Centrality. This means that the CFA and its stakeholders are often engaged
in negotiations in order to achieve a mutually satisfactory position. The final decisions on
the 2001 and 2008 league fixtures that aforementioned are clear evidence of such
consensus between the two parties. This development trend of leagues governance is also
recognised by Zhu Qilin - member of SLC, Chairman of CSLC: (personal interview,
23/05/2013)

“Despite the gradually progressed league governance and increased club influence, the
CFA’s veto power in SLC and its 36% share ownership in the CSLC demonstrate the
leading position of the governing body. The SLC is a platform for clubs and the CFA to
manage their conflict of interests, and to work together for the best outcomes of both
parties in a democratic manner.”

The ownership structure of the CSLC indicates that the CFA’s 36% of share ownership is
a strategic design. On the one hand, it allows all clubs’ involvement at the decision-
making body; on the other hand, it prevents clubs to form a 2/3 majority at the CSLC. In
other words, in terms of CSLC development, clubs are not able to make any fundamental
changes or pass any major business plan without CFA’s approval, therefore, within such
a structure, the governing body still plays a leading role but accommodates more
diversified interests of clubs simultaneously.

5.5 Summary
The economic reform and market-oriented practices brought radical changes into the
Chinese sports and the football industry. Market forces have transformed the traditional
top-down governance structure, and administrative sport departments are able to operate
more independently. Nevertheless, sport associations remain deeply connected with the
government. Due to this strong government affiliation, succeeding on the international
and national levels are still the major targets for national and local governing bodies
respectively. In this regard, elite sports remain the principal focus, often to the detriment
of professional and grassroots development. Moreover, the heavy commercial approach

180
and political decentralisation have created an imbalance between professional and
grassroots development, which destroyed the old Soviet style cohesive training and
selection system, along with the integrity of the game.

Within the football industry, conflicts exist between the state control and free-market
forces. For example, the Super League governance is a mixture of state involvement of
the CFA and commercial practices of the clubs. The CFA has adopted a more active
strategy and an inclusive approach towards other stakeholders’ increasing influence in
order to minimise the conflicts. Apart from conflict of interest, the stakeholder approach
also explores the evidence of the aspect of financial dependency. Although the CFA
attempts to maintain a leading role in the decentralisation process, it has to compromise
power with other stakeholders in order to achieve legitimate, credible governance as well
as to meet the demands of the modern industry practice.

Football reform must aim to not only raise playing standards, but also to create a more
dynamic and increasingly efficient sports organisations. Therefore, the CFA and other
sports associations need to adapt a more inclusive stakeholder practices in order to meet
the needs of the sporting markets, and the challenges of sports commercialisation.
Striking the correct balance between professional and grassroots development can create
a positive cycle. On the one hand, an effective professional system creates a desirable
football environment, through which a greater number of people can be drawn into the
game. On the other hand, a solid grassroots foundation is more likely to produce more
quality professional players who can enhance the game at the professional level. By
contrast, overemphasising professional development weakens the foundations of the
football pyramid and overemphasising grassroots development limits financial resources
to the professional game, which reduces the commercial value of the game as a whole.
This phenomenon has an even greater impact on football development in China, where
the community based club model does not exist, and the national team’s performance can
significantly influence the overall football environment. The stakeholder approach sees
the contradictory nature of the CFA triggers strong dissatisfaction with public opinion,

181
due to the governing body remains subject to the state intervention, one of the
fundamental governance problem of the Chinese game remain unsolved.

182
Chapter Six: Clubs’ Perspective on Football Governance

6.1 Clubs’ status

6.1.1 Clubs before professionalisation

The professionalisation of the industry has transformed provincial elite football teams
into professional clubs. Originally, all elite teams were owned and managed by their local
PECs throughout the country. Despite those elite teams being ‘professional teams’ and
players being ‘professional players’ in terms of their commitment to the game, the
existence of ‘professional sports’ was not officially recognised within the framework of a
planned economy and the Soviet style sports system. Furthermore, the Soviet style
sporting system did not provide social links between elite sport teams and their local
communities, a football team was no different to other state-owned work unions.

Under such a system, coaches, players and local FA officers were employed by their local
PECs on a permanent basis. Their employment status was not affected by their teams’
overall performance. The local PEC appointed coaches on a long-term basis, and, if
coaching proved fruitless, the PECs always had alternative positions. The spirit of
patriotism and collectivism was the main motivation for playing staff to pursue good
performance. There was no monetary incentive for success until the end of the 1980s
when the economic reform kicked-off (Baruch, et al 2004).

Following the market-oriented economic policy, performance related pay (PRP) was
introduced as a part of sports reform just one year after the LA 1984 Olympic Games
(Baruch et al 2004). In the case of football, a monetary incentive was introduced to
encourage success on the pitch. The commercial approach coupled with a decline in the
state budget, which encouraged for football teams to pursue sponsorship in order to
improve their financial status. For instance, in economically developed regions, elite
football teams could attract more money and bigger sponsorships, however, teams based
in less economically developed regions struggled financially. In response, some local

183
PECs dissolved football teams in order to focus on the National Games and the NPESC’s
Olympic strategy, meaning the limited budget could be spent on their key sports.

6.1.2 Clubs after professionalisation

The professionalisation of the game was part of an ongoing planned process, which was
underpinned by the 1995 Presidential Order (Jiang). It states key features, including:

● The move towards a market economy and commercialism

● The separation between state control and sports management

● The active promotion of sponsorship, retention of the state concern for nationalism,
collectivism and socialist philosophy

● Providing opportunities for athletes to build careers after their retirement from sports

The regulation clearly indicates that sports organisations were encouraged to raise money
through commercial activities, however, it less clear with regards to policy
implementation. In order to maintain the separation between government and sports
agencies, the government would only fund the key Olympic sports, which led to an
emergence of different levels of funding. Notably, at the grass-roots level, parents are
contributing towards their children’s sports training (Jones 1999a).

When the professional league started in 1994, transformed professional clubs no longer
only relied on state budget. Instead, sponsorship became the principal revenue stream.
Henceforth, according to the CFA Chart (2005) article eight, rule 45 – Nature of
professional football clubs: “a professional football club must be registered as an
independent legal person with its local FA, it has to be operated with the market approach
and aims to improve the standard of Chinese football”.

184
Despite the game in China being as popular as it is in Europe, unlike Western clubs, the
Chinese clubs are not community based. They lack both the community connections and
traditional heritages. This gives the Chinese clubs an advantage, enabling them to have a
greater degree of freedom to operate in as capitalistic manners as they choose. In other
words, they are value-free business firms that are not tied to the goodwill or desires of
their fan base. For example, the provincial teams were originally named after their
regional affiliation. When a club managed to secure sponsorship, the sponsor’s name
became a part of the club’s official name (e.g. Beijing Snowflake, Liaoning Fareast, etc).
There are often changes in a team’s main sponsor, therefore, name changes can be
frequent (Manzenreiter & Horne, 2007).

During the beginning of the professionalisation period, clubs were mainly managed by
their local PECs - in much the same fashion compared the state amateur era. However,
with the introduction of foreign players and a new transfer system, many corporations
saw football as a new opportunity for commercial development (Ashton 2002). They
invested heavily in the football industry, and with their financial strength, corporations
gradually began taking control of the clubs.

Alongside a further separation between government function and sports agency, more
enterprises took larger stakes in football clubs, and became major shareholders. Coaching
and playing staff became employees of the clubs rather than their local PECs. This meant
that football became the first sport in China to achieve a market status, independent from
the tightened state control through a Westernised professionalisation. Local PECs and
FAs had lost a substantial amount of control over clubs, their governance was limited to
the role of regulators and had very little impact in the day to day running of the clubs.

Since 1994 the CFA has indicated that all clubs must implement a commercially-driven
professional management system in order to ensure clubs are self-sufficient. Bearing this
in mind, one of the initial purposes for the introduction of the CSL was to push clubs to

185
operate in a more business like model under the market economy, with better governance
structure in order to achieve long-term sustainability (Yang 2003). According to the
Entry Criteria for the CSL Clubs (CFA, 2002)

● A football club should be a modern company, registered as a limited liability company


or a share limited company and complying with the PRC’s Company Law.

● Clubs should be established as independent legal representatives and acquire business


licences.

● Share limited companies should have appropriate mechanisms in place. Such as


shareholders’ meetings, Board structures and so on. Major decisions should be taken
through a democratic process.

This regulation established clear guidelines on a club’s governance structure by


successfully introducing modern management practices into the football industry. It was
aimed specifically at the top professional clubs to ensure their healthy development.

6.1.3 Changing goals

All elite football teams existed for the same purpose prior to professionalisation - to
comply with the national sports policy and to promote the game at the regional level. The
teams were then owned by local PECs and served as an extension of the political interests
of the government (Clumpner & Pendelton, 1978).

Since the economic reform, the separation of the government function and sports agency
created different goals for sports authorities and the clubs (Jones 1999b, 2000, 2004).
Following the new sports policy and the Communist party's guidelines, state control over
football was relaxed. With European football models to follow, clubs adopted various
business strategies and tactics in order to be successful both commercially and
competitively. As a result, professionalisation and commercialisation becoming the main

186
characteristics of the football reform, political interest became an inferior objective for
professional clubs.

Total Super League clubs Jia League clubs

50
50
45 43.75
40
35
30 28.125 28.125
25 21.875
20
15.625
15
10 6.25 6.25
5
0
0
Financial balance (S5, Commercial Sporting performance
J9) performance (S2) (S9, J7)

(SX) – X number of Super League clubs; (JX) – X number of Jia League clubs

Graph 6.1Percentage of clubs focal performance

Graph 6.1 shows the 2012 survey results. 43.75% of clubs see a balanced book as their
main focus when running business as these clubs pursue financial stability, and their
spending powers are normally related to their ability of revenue generation. Only 6.25%
of clubs set main focus on good commercial performances, they are CSL clubs with an
emphasis on commercial sale orientated activities and business development. 50% of
clubs emphasise success on the field, they see sporting success as the most important goal,
making it the priority over other targets. Sporting performance outweighs bank balance
and commercial performance as the major object for most Chinese professional clubs.

When the state policy shifted from a planned economy to a market-orientated economy,
the ownership of clubs changed accordingly. The 2002 club license system required that

187
all professional clubs must operate in a business model at the same time registering with
the local Trading Office as limited or share limited companies.

Total Super League clubs Jia League clubs

60
53.125
50

40 34.375
30 28.125
25
21.875
20
12.5 12.5 12.5
10
0
0
Single ownership (S9, Muti share ownership Others (J4)
J8) (S7, J4)

(SX) – X number of Super League clubs; (JX) – X number of Jia League clubs

Graph 6.2 Percentage of clubs’ ownership structure in professional leagues

Graph 6.2 shows clubs’ ownership structure. 53.1% of clubs have a single ownership -
often owned by big corporations, a club is one of the subsidiaries of a holding company;
34.4% of clubs are owned by multi shareholders, and local sport authorities are often
shareholders. 12.5% of clubs at the Jia League level are still owned in other forms59.
Shareholders can be considered as normative stakeholders, Chinese clubs are normally
owned by few shareholders with a high concentration of share ownership.

The main purpose of an enterprise is to invest in a football club, gain rights of control
over the club’s assets and ensure that there is a financial returns (direct or indirect)
received from that investment. Many clubs are owned by big corporations whose
priorities lie outside of the football industry - they often use clubs as a vehicle to raise

59
In the process of ownership transition, clubs are temporarily under administration of local FAs.

188
their brand profile or to forge a close political linkage with local government before
selling them a few years down the line (Ashton 2002). Therefore, clubs face the risk that
corporate backers have very little long-term interest in the club and are simply involved
to make a profit. Consequently, clubs face an impossible struggle in establishing a brand
for themselves - the continuous buying and selling of clubs by corporate backers means
the constant re-branding of a club. According to Mr Yang (2005) the former Vice
president of the CFA, during the 10-year (1994-2003) pre Super League era, 127 clubs
entered the professional leagues, and clubs had changed hands 32 times 60; while clubs
changed their names 55 times and seven clubs were dissolved after their relegation. This
also prevents the clubs from forming a true affinity with their local communities. Mr
Ning Zhixiong, the CEO of Guangzhou Zhongyi FC explains (personal interview,
30/06/08):

“The main sponsors changed so often in the past, so did the club’s names, there is no
consistency to build a club culture and brand image. The investors have a lack of a long-
term vision and commitment, which cannot lead to good business practices.”

The football industry has its own peculiarity. Clubs not only need to make profits for
shareholders but also have to pursue success on the field to satisfy their supporters. In
order to balance the two objectives requires a club to have a good vision on its long-term
development strategy as well as mid-term and short-term business plans.

Graph 6.3 shows 93.8% of clubs have annual business plans; 75% of clubs have three-
year business plans and 59.4% of clubs have business plans set longer than three years.
The result suggests that most clubs set short-term goals with annual business plan to
focus on their current task, less than two-third of clubs have longer visions with mid-term
business plans and long-term business strategies, and Super League clubs are generally
better positioned than Jia League clubs in terms of setting long-term goals. In terms of
risk management, only 40.6% of clubs have included risk assessment in their business
plans. Now a club business model is a standard corporate structure based on market

60
Including the same club changed hands for more than one time.

189
principles. The survey results demonstrate that clubs are lacking a long-term commitment
as well as risk awareness to identify and to pre-assess risks, such practice put clubs into a
turbulent circumstance, which echo the fact that Chinese professional clubs having been
put on sale 32 times during 1994-2003, and partially reflected venerability of the clubs.

Graph 6.3 Percentage of clubs with proper business plans in place

6.2 Clubs’ view on the current governance issues


Giulianotti (1999 p86, 2002) argues that globalisation and the international circulation of
sports capital has eroded many of the traditional or cultural characteristics which existed
within sports in different countries. Football reform has transformed the Chinese football
industry, and with that the commercial approach and its economic development has re-
shaped the traditional governing structure. The CFA established the League Department,
followed by the Super League Committee and the Super League Company in order to
lead the industrial development at a steady but progressive pace. Consequently, football
clubs registered as companies with football as their principle source of business. When a
football team becomes a club company, it must be managed using a sensible, business-
like approach, as well as being able to trade independently without interference. This

190
included dealing with multi stakeholders and establishing a strong fan base to gain
sufficient access to markets and ensures a healthy revenue stream in the market-oriented
economy. The following section discusses the governing mechanisms of the industry
from the clubs’ perspective.

6.2.1 The governing mechanisms

6.2.1a The decision-making structure


In terms of the club/CFA relationship, all clubs were in support of the current governance
framework and recognised the leadership of the CFA after the professionalisation of the
game. As Mr Zhang Defa, General Manager of Shanghai Shenhua FC, states (personal
interview, 18/01/08):

“The current framework suits the current development of the game, we need the CFA to
take the lead. I do not think an independent league can make significant improvements. It
is a tough business dealing with the government in China, only the CFA with its political
background can ensure a smooth development of the industry”.

Such a statement recognises that a real non-governmental status for either the CFA or the
league is impossible in China. However, clubs believe that the current structure has
improved compared to previous structure. The creation of the SLC is an innovative
progress in terms of corporate governance development, with an inclusive approach,
more stakeholders have been drawn into the decision-making panel, in which clubs are
able to share more information with the governing body. However, in practice, this
accessibility does not necessarily mean involvement in a decision-making process. Clubs
want to play a more active role, rather than passively participate. Most clubs felt some of
the rules (for example, abolishing promotion and regulations; dividing the integrity of the
season) were subjectively introduced without proper consultation. Mr Hu Wei, Chief
Assistant of Shenhua FC, explains: (personal interview, 18/01/08)

191
“The CFA has adopted an inclusive approach by setting up the SLC, we need it to be
more effective and more efficient. Many decisions made by the CFA actually did not go
through the SLC. Moreover, some proposals do not allow enough time for clubs to
discuss thoroughly”.

Clubs are demanding a more transparent system with democratic decision-making


processes. Practically, full consultation on important governance issues, updated
information on business development projects and so on. Such needs indicate that more
diversified interests exist between clubs and the CFA. As business entities, clubs demand
more accountability from the governing body in order to protect their own interests. Mr
Zhen Ming, Deputy General Manager of Jiangsu Sainty FC, states: (personal interview,
07/07/08)

“The establishment of the SLC is a big improvement on football governance, it provides a


platform for clubs to exchange information and to discuss related governance issues,
however, it should have been more democratic for making decisions”.

The creation of the SLC has certainly provided an official platform from which clubs can
work together, with increased communication between them, and clubs as a whole are
more influential within the game’s decision-making structure. Despite increased
influence and demand of clubs, with the political background and veto power, the CFA
maintains its focal position in the SLC structure.

6.2.1b the collective selling structure and revenue distribution


The Super League is commercially managed by the CSLC, both its chairman and
president are appointed by the CFA. The CSLC is responsible for selling the league’s
naming rights, and it also takes 24 hoarding boards from every club for collective
commercial sales. In terms of distribution, the revenue generated through the CSLC
(minus all its administrative costs) is shared by the 17 shareholders - the CFA takes 10%
or ¥10m at the maximum, the rest is distributed to all 16 clubs equally (Ran 2008b).

192
These collective sales demonstrate an established integrity within the league that has not
existed in the past. This mechanism is supported by most clubs (especially small clubs, as
they are more reliant on centralised management), however, larger clubs or clubs from
developed economic regions prefer smaller collective packages and greater flexibility.
Despite the CFA taking only a 10% share of the revenue according to the distribution
arrangement, clubs are demanding greater transparency. As Mr Zheng Ming, Deputy
General Manager of Jiangsu Sainty FC explains: (personal interview 07/07/08)

“The naming right is enough for the CSLC, we want to control our ground hoardings.
Being based in the Yangzi Delta, we can develop regional business models from these
hoardings which may work better for us financially”.

By contrast, Mr Jin Yan, CEO of Changsha Gide FC states: (personal interview, 06/07/08)

“A centralised management and the distribution system are good practice to demonstrate
the integrity and solidarity of the league. This distribution is not a decisive income, it is
an important one for small clubs. We are a small club and our local market has not been
well developed either, so the centralised marketing approach helps us significantly”.

Although there is no argument to sell the league’s title right collectively and the revenue
distribution mechanism, some clubs believe that they can negotiate more favourable deals
with other resources locally. Accountability and business transparency of the CSLC also
have been scrutinised which demonstrates the level of trust between clubs and the CFA-
led CSLC is low, especially on financial issues. Mr Ning Zhixiong, the CEO of
Guangzhou Zhongyi FC emphasises (personal interview, 30/06/08):

“We understand the importance of collective selling, we have no problem with that. The
problems we have are that the CSLC took our best assets and gave us a lump-sum. We do
not know how much we are getting for each item, and feel we could probably sell them
for more. There is no break down of information. A more transparent mechanism is
needed”.

193
In fact, the Super League’s naming rights are the biggest asset currently managed by the
CSLC. It takes advantage of these in order to strike large commercial deals. Yet taking
the 24 hoarding boards from clubs’ premier locations, causes separate consternation.
Furthermore, the financial transparency and effectiveness of the CSLC is problematic, as
another CEO61 of a club says:

“The CSLC has taken 60-70% of our commercial resources, but the rewards are limited.
We invest ¥50-60m annually, and believe the CSLC and the CFA should have rewarded
us around ¥20m. In fact, we got only about 10% of our investment through the revenue
share. We support the collective selling mechanism, which helps the club to get big name
sponsors that we normally do not get as individual local businesses, therefore we are not
complaining about how many resources have been taken by the CSLC. However, we want
to see a good financial reward from the league, we have concerns over the CSLC’s
business capability as well as its accountability”.

The collective selling and redistribution of revenue is justified within sporting


competitions as a way of trying to ensure the game’s integrity and competitive balance
(Mckeown 2011). Despite the importance of the collective selling being well understood
and supported by all clubs, the argument remains surrounding how many resources the
CSLC has taken and how many benefits the clubs can accrue through such a mechanism.

Graph 6.4 shows 62.5% of clubs see revenue redistribution can boost their financial
performance; 56.25% of clubs think their own sporting competitiveness can be enhanced
through revenue redistribution; 56.25% of clubs believe such redistribution reduces
business risks; 87.5% of clubs believe revenue redistribution increasing clubs’ social
influence.

61
He wanted to keep anonymous.

194
Total Super League clubs Jia League clubs

90 87.5
80
70
62.5
60 56.25 56.25
50 50
43.75
40 37.5 37.5
31.25
30 25
20 18.75 18.75
10
0
Enhance financial Enhance sporting Reduce business Increas social
performance performance risks influence

Graph 6.4 Percentage of clubs who believe in benefits through a wider range of revenue redistribution

One of the objectives of collective selling is to foster solidarity within the league and
provide small clubs with financial support. However, the commercial independence of
the CSLC as a company, and the financial benefit it delivers to each club, is debatable.
For example, the CSLC moved to the CFA’s HQ in 2006, the CFA asked the CSLC to
pay rent for one whole floor of office space (1600m2 ). The CSLC had only 24 staff at
that time, which can be calculated as equivalent to 67m2 per person. Although, following
a protest by all the clubs, the CSLC did not pay the extra ¥3m, the incident provides an
evidence of conflict of interest between the CFA and clubs. The case demonstrated why
the CSLC could not run as efficiently as it should.

On the one hand, the CFA blames short-sighed corporations for lack of long-term
commitment towards the game, which conversely caused clubs to change hands
frequently. However, on the other hand, the CFA’s own practices discouraged
corporations from committing on a long-term basis. From the clubs’ point of view, the
CFA puts its own financial interest ahead of the league’s interests. In other words, it has a
tendency to use clubs’ money to cover its own costs, which ultimately damages the
overall football environment and sets a very bad governance example. As Nene Leung –

195
founder of the Champion Projects sports consultancy agency concludes (Ashton, 2002,
p70): “Clubs want to have their voice heard in the key decision-making process with
minimum external control of their destiny, the CFA is prepared to change, a lot is still to
be swallowed in terms of resource allocation and finding the right people to manage clubs
professionally”.

The Figure 5-7 shows the different material interests that have developed between clubs
and the CFA. Poor governance practices of the CFA do not favour the corporations’ long-
term football commitment; moreover, an inefficient managerial mechanism and self-
interest orientated practices of the governing body will ultimately reduce the
effectiveness of the revenue distribution amongst clubs.

6.2.2 The impact of professionalisation on clubs

6.2.2a Clubs’ relationship with main stakeholders


The football industry has been changing from a top-down governance system to a
network system hinged on interrelationships between its stakeholders (Amara et al 2005,
Boon 2000, Walters 2007). In the stakeholder network, different stakeholder groups exert
power in different ways, and in different contexts. What you find is that power gradually
shifts from football governing bodies to clubs and stakeholder groups. In the Chinese
case, compared to the pre-professional era, there have been fundamental changes to the
clubs. Not only has the sole state ownership structure changed, but also the relationships
between clubs and their stakeholders.

The relationships with the CFA


Football markets were non-existent in the pre professional era. Compared to state
amateur teams in the pre-professional era, clubs are business-orientated companies - they
have increased commercial awareness and are profit-driven. In fact, both clubs and the
CFA now have a wider diversity of interests, and inevitably some of these interests are
more likely to conflict under the framework of a market economy. As stated by Professor

196
Jin Zhiyang, the Head Coach of Beijing Institute of Technology, and Senior Consultant
of the CFA, (personal interview, 08/08/08)

“With increased business awareness, clubs need to look after their own interests - which
consequently may not necessarily align with the CFA’s demands. Therefore, clubs want
to have more say over football development. The CFA should give more consideration to
clubs’ financial interests before making any decisions. The SLC and the League
Committee must be accountable, and a democratic decision-making mechanism must be
implemented thoroughly in order to meet the demands of modern industry practice”.

In some respects, the creation of the SLC has brought clubs into the decision-making
circle, whilst the CFA maintains in a focal position. However, by having the SLC in place
does not necessarily mean that there is full involvement of the clubs in the decision-
making process - the governing body is still capable of making independent decisions
without consultations of clubs.

As an example underpinning Mr Jin’s point: the CFA’s decision to abolish relegation


during the 2002 season severely damaged the reputation of the league, as well as the
clubs’ financial income. Many sponsors did not like the idea and subsequently reduced
their sponsorships. Clubs considered that the money they had spent was a waste. “What is
the point in strengthening squads if there is no relegation pressure?” Professor Jin
questioned in the same interview. Such collisions show that clubs’ financial interest
conflicts with the CFA’s political interest. Mr Zhou Xiaobo, Chief Assistant of CEO,
Henan Jianye FC, has the similar view: (personal interview, 09/07/08)

“We may get used to the leadership of the CFA, but now clubs need deeper involvement
in the decision-making process not just voting in favour of the CFA’s decisions. Our own
proposals should be treated in the same way as the SGSA’s. The SLC can be more
accountable”.

197
Compared to the pre-professional era, clubs are now more out-spoken, and implement a
more active approach towards their relationship with the CFA. Although the leadership of
the CFA has been recognised, its dominance and accountability has been consistently
questioned and challenged. Within the stakeholder analytical framework, the
development trend of this relationship has moved from necessary compatible towards
necessary incompatible that shows increasing conflicts and diversified interests between
clubs and the CFA. As Mr Zhang Defa, Genaral Manager of Shanghai Shenhua FC states:
(personal interview, 18/01/08)

“The CFA has a big responsibility to improve our football environment. Clubs need the
CFA to work unselfishly without abusing its position. Many clubs in China have an
unstable financial status, and the CFA should be less selfish and help clubs financially”.

The accountability of the CFA is not the only debate. Its overall responsibility as the
governing body is also questioned. In the professional era, clubs need training support
from professionals, and the CFA offers very limited support indeed. Clubs insisted on
marketing workshops, management seminars, and a necessary level of support. However,
the CFA does not offer any support to the clubs, neither does it advise them on the full
range of business activities that they could get involved with. Mr Sui Yan, Deputy
General Manager of Liaoning FC explains (Personal interview, 28/07/08):

“The CFA introduced the licence system for all professional clubs in order to improve
governance at a club level. I believe the system should not be just criteria for clubs to
meet, but more importantly the CFA has a responsibility to ensure the right knowledge
can be passed to every single club’s management”.

Although the needs for training are different according to each club’s size and business
activity, clubs feel that the CFA could have been more active in the training and
education of the clubs’ management. Chinese clubs are still in a nascent stage and the
CFA could have provided a greater level support in order to develop the industry

198
forwards. Mr Hu Wei, Chief Assistant to the CEO of Shanghai Shenhua FC explains:
(personal interview, 18/01/08)

“There are needs for commercial training and education. The CFA should organise
training programmes to develop professional knowledge and expertise at the club level.
Clubs have different requirements in terms of knowledge, and therefore specifically
designed seminars and workshops could be a possible solution”.

Hudson & Herbane (2000, p26) state that “Staff training has been widely recognised as a
facilitator for greater productivity, job satisfaction and skills development”. Despite most
clubs’ need for greater levels of training, there remains little available. The research
(Zhang et al 2006) based on 29 professional clubs indicates that only 51% of managerial
staff in Chinese clubs possess diploma degrees and above. Although most of them having
some managerial experience with other firms, it is difficult to see anyone who possesses
professional knowledge and expertise which can bridge the gap between business
development and the football industry. From the clubs’ point of view, the CFA’s support
does not meet the clubs’ development needs.

Conflicts between clubs and the CFA have been growing since professionalisation. This
is borne out of a conflict between the CFA’s politically motivated, old management style
and the new demands from clubs for having more transparent market-oriented business
practices. The CFA possesses political power and a centralised position, it used to having
a commanding position within the industry. By contrast, the clubs are in an inferior
position, and are used to simply obeying government orders. As a result, despite
competing voices gradually emerging from the industry, the CFA can simply turn a blind
eye and push ahead with its own decisions. From the clubs’ perspective, although the
CFA’s efforts in adopting the inclusive governance approach, its unprofessional
managerial manner fails to meet the demands of the modern industry practice, which
consequently severely damages the reputation of the league as well as the clubs’ financial
interests.

199
In 2004, alongside further football reform and deeper professionlisation, clubs’ the
passive relationship with the CFA took a sharp turn. An on field accident during a match
between Beijing Hyundai and Shenyang Ginde sparked a controversial decision62 by the
referee, and Hyundai abandoned the match in protest. It was the first time a match had
been abandoned in Chinese football history, and the incident was highlighted by the
media. Hyundai took the initiative and acted quickly insisting that there had been an
‘unfair’ penalty decision. More importantly, off the back of the media attention, they
demanded that the CFA undergo radical reform. By contrast, the CFA was sluggish in
response, and left the PR initiative to Hyundai for a one-sided story. However, a hefty
punishment was handed out twelve days later - Hyundai was stripped of three points,
disqualified from the match and fined ¥300,000.

Ten days after the Hyundai & Ginde match, Dalian Shide abandoned another match
against Shengyang Ginde. This time Shide only took slightly umbrage against the match
referees, but directed the majority of its indignation towards the CFA. The club held a
series of press conferences in order to publicly criticise the CFA’s unpopular politically-
led exercises during the course of its history, and to lambast against its ambiguous and
opaque practices as being detrimental to both the game’s reputation and the clubs’
sustainable development. In short, Shide’s PR campaign was so successful, that even the
media cast the club a sympathetic light.

The CFA was blamed for attracting negative publicity towards the game. More
importantly, the incident highlighted the fact that the tide had turned, placing clubs in a
more commanding position. This power shift was best demonstrated when Shide and six
other clubs threatened to break away from the league if the CFA did not introduce a more
transparent business practice and fundamental reform. The event became known as the
‘G-7 Revolution’.

With such intensive media coverage and the proximity of the two separate attacks on the
CFA, a huge amount public interest was consequently generated. Up until this point,

62
A penalty was awarded to Ginde FC.

200
football, as a pioneer of sporting reform with little political sensitivity, had enjoyed a
relatively relaxed censorship within the Chinese political environment. The two incidents
therefore trigged massive debate amongst the media. Indeed, the governing body was
embarrassed by its inactivity and poor practice over past years, and it was severely
reprimanded by the central government. As Simons (2008, p224) states: “Since football
had been allowed to leave state control, the state media faced far fewer restrictions in its
reporting, and sports journalism became the frontline of oblique comments on the system
itself”. Consequently, the CFA succumbed to the ‘G-7’s proposals. Firstly, it abandoned
the original relegation plan 63 in the middle of the season; more importantly, the CFA
agreed to open its bank accounts and adopt a more transparent working practice. Despite
such compromise from the CFA, Shide FC was still docked six points and fined.

The ‘G-7 Revolution’ demonstrates that clubs’ started to employ a proactive approach to
managing their relationship with the CFA in order to protect their own interests under the
market-orientated economy. Secondly, more communication has gradually been forged
between the clubs. This helped align their behaviour and increased their legitimacy and
collective clout. As a result, the focal position of the CFA became marginalised when
clubs formed a closely well-organised, high-density network. It allowed the clubs to
constrain the CFA’s actions through a show of collective strength alone, and thereby
increasing clubs’ influence as a whole.

Figure 6-1 shows that the clubs-CFA relationship development trend. On the one hand,
clubs’ operations do not depend (or depend little) on direct government funds, and the
central position of the CFA has been marginalised gradually as a result. On the other
hand, more direct connections were formed amongst clubs through different mechanisms,
meaning bonds and links amongst clubs became closer and denser. However, despite the
fact that the market economy has undermined a certain degree of the CFA’s power, under
the current political environment, the CFA still holds a leading role in terms of shaping
the institutional rules. It is safe to say that the CFA can no longer operate without

63
The original plan was one relegation but the “‘G-7’ Revolution” demanded no relegation for the
inauguration of the Super League.

201
impunity or scrutiny, either from the clubs or from society. Therefore, the clubs-CFA
relationship and its network structure moved from a Low Density/High Centrality
configuration to High Density/High Centrality. As clubs went through the transition from
passivity to more active presence, the CFA’s dominance role weakened.

Stakeholder Density

(High)

Subordinate Compromiser

Firm’s Present

(Low) (High)

Centrality

Solitarian ◙ Commander

(Low)

◙ The clubs-CFA relationship

Figure 6-1 The clubs-CFA network configuration and firm response

Although the clubs are able to coordinate their efforts more effectively, the CFA is still
capable of influencing the clubs’ actions. The “‘G-7’ Revolution” shows a high level of
interdependence between the CFA and ‘G-7’; neither party can replace the other, and
therefore, in order to avoid an uncertain future, both parties will need to compromise with
one another in order to reach a mutually satisfactory position. Apart from G7’s politically
motivated unity, there are also direct commercial interests for some clubs to take
initiatives to form close ties amongst themselves. Mr Hu Wei, Chief Assistant to the CEO
of Shanghai Shenhua FC explains: (personal interview 18/01/08)

202
“There is a good communication channel between us and a couple of clubs. We are
currently discussing the possibility of having regional collective sponsorships and
therefore effective communication provides opportunities and makes clubs stronger.”

In terms of clubs’ influence, Figure 6-2 shows that although an individual club does not
depend on the CFA financially, the CFA still maintains an institutional power over the
club. Therefore, the governing body has a low level of dependence on an individual club,
but by contrast, an individual club has a high level of dependence on the CFA in order to
remain a part of the game. As a result, an individual club has a limited influence over the
CFA, and the CFA does not need to be responsive to that particular club. Hyundai’s case
against the CFA illustrated this relationship. On the contrary, due to seven clubs forming
an internal alliance amongst themselves to coordinate their actions, the ‘G-7’ case
differed from such a relationship. The level of dependence of the CFA on ‘G-7’ as a
whole was high, but by the same token, ‘G-7’ was also highly dependent on the CFA.
Without the CFA, they would have no legitimacy. Ultimately neither party could do well
without the other.

Although in two separate events both Hyundai and the ‘G-7’ chose an indirect pathway to
influence the CFA with the same successful PR efforts by seeking out the media as an
external force to pressure the CFA, their strategies made very different impacts. Only the
‘G-7’ was able to negotiate with the CFA to reach a mutually acceptable settlement. This
indicated that the CFA’s reaction towards the two events was not entirely based on
media’s pressure. Figure 6-2 also demonstrates the choice of influence strategies adopted
by Beijing Hyundai and the ‘G-7’.

In configuration A, the CFA’s institutional power was a key determinate for Hyundai’s
position. On the one hand, Hyundai possesses a high dependency relationship with the
CFA; on the other hand, the club hold no means of actually constraining the governing
body. As a result, Hyundai could only influence the CFA by choosing an indirect/usage
strategy via the media to pressure the CFA. Despite this, the CFA was impervious to

203
Hyundai’s position and media criticism in this asymmetrical relationship, and as
demonstrated by the outcome, the club was fined nonetheless.

Level of stakeholder dependence on firm

(High)

A B

Level of firm ◘ ‘G-7’/the CFA

depend on (Low) (High)

stakeholder ◙ Hyundai/the CFA

C D

A: Indirect/usage (Firm power) (Low)

B: Direct/usage (High interdependence) ◙ Guan/the CFA relationship

C: Indirect/withholding (Low interdependence) ◘ ‘G-7’/the CFA relationship

D: Direct/withholding (Stakeholder power)

Figure 6-2 club/the CFA resource dependence relationship and club influence strategies

Employing alternative tactics, Shide cleverly united other clubs under a structure of the
‘G-7’ which granted these clubs a different status and dislocated them from the authority
of the CFA. In configuration B, the CFA maintained its legitimate power, yet, the ‘G-7’
possessed powerful advantages over the CFA as a group. It threatened to withhold its
resources and withdraw from the league. In this relationship, there is a great degree of
symmetry between the two parties. Both are dependent on each other, and both possess
sufficient resources with which they can bargain. Ultimately, the ‘G-7’s
direct/withholding strategy was the ultimate reason which led the CFA to concede. The
media in this case was used to exert extra pressure. In short, based on these two examples,
the indirect/usage strategy adopted by Hyundai was not as effective as the
direct/withholding strategy adopted by ‘G-7’, however, this in part is due to the resources

204
and respective positions of power held by both parties. In the latter example, that position
was stronger.

Within the stakeholder analytical framework, the governing body has derivative
legitimate claim on clubs, it possesses an overwhelming institutional power and
legitimacy in the club/CFA relationship. By identifying such a relationship and to analyse
it with a stakeholder relationship model (shown at figure 6-2) can help clubs to
understand better of stakeholder management, especially their relationship with the CFA.
A club alone is hardly to have any influence over the CFA’s decision-making; when more
clubs united, they will possess a certain degree of bargaining power and shift the
relationship from stakeholder power towards interdependence, therefore, clubs as a united
group is able to make a certain impact on the CFA’s decision-making.

Clubs vs Country
Club v Country is a trade-off in the modern football industry. It is a relationship whereby
a player is caught between conflicting duties – one to his club, and the other to the
national squad. Players will always be first and foremost assert of clubs (since they are
paid by their clubs). As such, it is reasonable for clubs to want to protect their players and
their own interests. Much like any investment, clubs want to see a return. However, in the
Chinese case, traditionally and politically, all players were paid by the government, the
country and national pride come before any other market-oriented priority. Furthermore,
in terms of players’ psyche representing one’s country is considered the highest honour.

Post-professionalisation however, we see clubs operating under a different guise,


harbouring different priorities. The market-orientated paradigm is now the overriding
authority for a club as a company, but not for the government. This creates great schism
between two very differently positioned entities. Currently, the national team players
continue to be fed into the system from clubs, but the difference being, they are now paid
by their clubs. Meaning clubs are paying for players that risk getting injured, and the
CFA offers absolutely no direct benefit. Even though players are now gathered only
before the international matches, it is hardly a great return on an investment.

205
To add to this, some clubs argue that as players will continue to be paid, clubs evidently
face the risk of players suffering injury, which will ultimately affects the player’s market
value and future performance for the club. Mr Jin Yan, CEO of Changsha Ginde FC
states: (personal interview 06/07/08)

“There is a match calendar that allows us to plan ahead. The only problem for us is that
the CFA tries to call up players too early, despite we have different views on this, clubs in
China are used to this kind of arrangement”.

Even though, clubs are aware of the negative impact of the club vs country saga, yet they
readily accept the arrangement and rarely demand compensation. In fact, most Chinese
clubs’ psyche is more aligned with the government in that they do believe that playing for
one’s country represents the highest accolade for players and it is therefore obligatory for
them to support the CFA. The national interest is placed before clubs’ interest. The
reason for this prioritisation is probably rooted in the national education. The socialist
collectivism and philosophy maintain a strong impact on clubs to such extent that it
overrides commercial sense. Surprisingly, some clubs do see the positive elements of this
trade-off. Mr Liu Yuming, President and CEO of Yatai FC explains: (personal interview
02/08/08)

“Firstly, we are proud of our players who play for our country, not only do they gain a
good reputation for our club, they also increase their own market values by playing on
the international stage. Secondly, it provides opportunities for reserve players to break
through, and clubs can benefit from that in the long run”.

Despite the tug of war between clubs and the country, there are fewer conflicts and
financial issues in the club vs country saga in China than in European football 64 .
Generally speaking, clubs are willing to accept the negative impact caused by the national

64
UEFA compensates €100m to 575 clubs for releasing their players for Euro 2012, no such payment has
made in Asia and China yet.

206
team selection. Despite the trade-off offering some positive elements, some due concerns
have been noted. Indeed, conflicts have been increasing as clubs worry that players’
national services might jeopardise their success in the league, some clubs are reluctant to
release their players either with injury excuses or delaying their national services. For
example, in January 2013, Lunneng FC and Evergrande FC openly questioned CFA’s
selection of its players and delayed its players to report national duty respectively65.

In the pre-professional era, provincial teams fed their best players into the national team
and the national team players were trained together all year-round in Beijing (paid by the
state). There was never any conflict between the two parties. After football reform, clubs
became utility maximisers, their ultimate interest does not necessarily align with the
national team (as shown by graph 6.1).

Necessity aligned interests

Financial dependency

level of clubs on (Low ) (High)

the state

▄ The club/country relationship

Contingent diverse interests

Figure 6-3 The development pattern of the clubs/country relationship

Figure 6-3 shows that clubs have developed more diverse interests along with their
declined financial dependency on the state. The less a club’s financial dependence on the
state, the less aligned interests they have, therefore, the development pattern of the
club/national team relationship has developed towards less necessity. At the practical

65
Five Lunneng players and seven Evergrande players were selected by the national team.

207
level, clubs often think their own interests first. Mr Cao Liang, Marketing Director of
Guoan FC explains: (personal interview 03/09/08)

“Financially, club competitions contribute a great deal to the CFA, and we deserve fair
treatment. The national team’s preparation should not be scheduled at the expense of the
league - promotion and regulation should be maintained with consistency, because all
these facts can make significant impacts on clubs’ incomes and operational tactics”.

Relationships with players


After professionalisation, players became employees of the club rather than the local SB.
Instead of the pervious life-long job security, players are tied in by contracts. Moreover,
there is never any guarantee that a club will renew its contract with a player on expiry.
Clubs are no longer obliged to help players find new employment. This is representative
of the rather callous change in the labour market.

Figure 6-4 shows the developmental pattern of a club/player relationship. Under the
market-oriented economy, the employee’s material interests differed considerably
compared with that of the employer. Players pursue financial rewards and self-realisation,
whereas clubs are in pursuit of on field success, and financial return. Therefore, the
pattern of the club/player relationship moved downwards and shifted from Necessary
Compatible to Necessary Incompatible.

Contingent Necessary
(High level common value)

Compatible ◙

(Low) (Highly connected)

Incompatible Present

◙ The Club/player relationship (Low)

Figure 6-4 The development pattern of the Club/player relationship

208
As a result of this change, a financial dispute between clubs and players emerged.
Examples include Shenzhen Jianlibao FC failing to pay players for six months in order to
ease the club’s cash flow in 2004 and Tianjin Taida delaying payment for players’
salaries in 2008. Both disputes led to protests from players, and eventually they refused to
train. The CFA introduced a new measure in 2010 to limit disputes between clubs and
players over payment, meaning clubs can be fined, and their points can be docked if they
fail to pay players on time (Jia 2011). Despite the CFA’s measurement, delaying players’
payment is a common practice amongst Chinese clubs, including Shenzhen FC – the
researcher worked for during the summer 2012.

Players’ remuneration also increased significantly after professionalisation. Total wage


bills rose 10-20 times compared with 1994, and the Chinese league is one of the most
expensive in Asia, second to Japan (Ashton 2002).

Both the CFA and clubs has realised the danger of the high salaries and therefore adopted
a more rational approach. Firstly, clubs avoided entering into bidding wars as big salaries
and transfer fees can easily bring clubs into financial difficulty, and can have a
detrimental impact on the healthy development of the industry. Secondly, the CFA
introduced a transfer ceiling in 2003 (Eaves Et al 2003) and a salary cap for clubs in
April 2004 respectively – clubs are not allowed to spend more than 55% of their annual
revenue on players and coaching staff’s salaries (CFA 2004b). Mr Zhou Xiaobo, Chief
Assistant of CEO, Henan Jianye FC explains: (personal interview 09/07/08)

“Players’ wages are rational now, although they are still on a relatively high level
compared to the national average, but it is not a sky high. We take our responsibility
seriously, however, we need to recognise footballers have specialised skills and they
limited playing careers”.

Not only did player salary increase after professionalisation, the payment structure
changed too. A performance-based structure replaced the old structure based on

209
egalitarianism, and all clubs link their performance to players’ salary today. This change
indicates the impact of market forces on the club management. Mr Zheng Ming, Vice
General Manager of Jiangsu Sainty FC explains: (personal interview, 07/07/08)

“We do not encourage high wages, even though we have a strong financial backing, we
believe in a more performance-based wage structure, which is a rational approach for a
limited company”.

During the last couple of years, players’ wages up again. Right now, not only do
domestic players earn big salaries, the foreign players earn even more, for instance,
Anelka €10.06m, Conca €7m, and ¥3billion will be invested by 16 Super League clubs
for the 2012 season (Dong 2012). Just bonus alone, eight clubs have already exceeded the
¥10m mark after 22 rounds in the 2013 season, and Evergrande’s ¥57m tops the list
(Chen 2013).

Despite the fact that players are well remunerated compared to pre-professional era, the
football market gives more initiative to clubs in contract negotiations. Apart from few
foreign players on multi-year deals, most domestic players are contracted on an annual
basis, their contracts are subject to a renewal every year. On the one hand, players have to
be consistent in order to earn their next contracts, but on the other hand, they have
opportunities to improve their contracts through good performance in a relatively short
period. If a club decides not to renew a player’s contract, the player will be put on the
transfer list. Mr Liu Yuming, President & CEO of Changchun Yatai FC explains
(personal interview, 02/08/08):

“We do not offer long-term contracts, all contracts are signed annually and reflect
players’ performance based on the last season. It is rational business practice for all
clubs, therefore reflecting fairness for both players and the club.”

210
Figure 6-5 demonstrates the club/player relationship based on the level of two parties’
interdependency. In the pre-professional era, players enjoyed a stable employment status
with provincial teams, and both parties worked together within a highly interdependent
relationship. Despite players gaining the freedom to change clubs with relative ease after
professionalisation, they are no longer guaranteed steady employment. With the creation
of the transfer system, clubs are less ready to rely on particular individual players, but
instead they want the flexibility of being able to replace them easily. As a result, the
club/player relationship pattern shifted to the left, from a status of High Interdependence
to a status of Club/(firm) Power. The new pattern skews towards the clubs and puts them
in a commanding position, giving the clubs an upper hand over players in the labour
market.

Level of stakeholder dependence on firm

(High)

Level of firm Present ◙

depend on (Low) (High)

stakeholder

(Low)

◙ The Club/player relationship

Figure 6-5 The club/player relationship development pattern

In the new club/player relationship, professionalism is required for both clubs and players
in order to manage a smooth relationship. From a clubs’ perspective, Chinese players are
not professional enough both on and off the field. Mr. Han Gongzheng, Deputy General
Manager of Luneng Taishan FC (personal interview, 05/01/08) states:

211
“Our players make so many negative headlines, which damages football’s credibility and
sets bad examples for the youth. Commercialisation brought us professional football but
without professionalism.”

The statement indicates that players need to be more professional and self-disciplined in
order to meet the new requirements of the modern game.

Relationship with fan groups


A team and fans come together to become a football club, and part of the attractiveness of
football is the atmosphere created by the fans. Despite fan associations emerging in the
middle of the 1980s - a decade before professionalisation, elite teams and fan groups
were independent organisations with no direct relationship existing between them.

According to Friedman and Miles (2002), the stakeholder relationship can be defined by
contracts between different stakeholders, and this, in turn, applied to elite teams and fan
associations, can be defined as Implicitly Unrecognised contracts between them 66 . In
Friedman’s stakeholder relationship model, the relationship of an elite team and its fans
can be categorised as one of the Contingent Compatible under the planned economy. The
market approach and professionalisation raised clubs’ awareness, soon afterwards, clubs
realised the importance of the fans’ involvement and support as being critical to their
business success. Therefore, all clubs today are centred on establishing close links with
their supporters. Some clubs have even created their own fan associations. This new
practice established a new relationship between the clubs and fan associations, and as a
result, an explicit or implicit recognised contract 67 formed between the two parties,
therefore the relationship becoming a Necessary Compatible under the market economy.

Figure 6-6 shows a development pattern of the club/fan relationship. Professionalisation


brought a new business philosophy to club management - clubs gradually engaged with

66
Not recognised by the parties involved (elite teams and fan associations), but recognised by certain
‘sensitized’ others (Friedman, 2002, p8).
67
Explicitly recognised contract: written or verbal, can be via a third party; Implicitly recognised contract:
recognised by parties involved and/or significant others (Friedman and Miles, 2002, p8).

212
local fans associations with a more direct relationship in order to expand their fan bases.
As more direct links between the two parties were established, the old implicit
unrecognised contract was replaced by the new explicit/implicit recognised contract, due
to this, the pattern of club/fan relationship moved to the right, the status changing from
the Contingent Compatible towards the Necessary Compatible68.

Contingent Necessary

(High level common values)

Compatible ◙ Present

(Low) (Highly connected)

Incompatible

◙ The Club/fan relationship (Low)

Figure 6-6 The development pattern of club/ fan relationship

The Chinese football market is still in an early stage of development - local markets vary
from place to place, and therefore clubs adapt different business approaches to manage
their relationship with their supporters and fan associations. Despite clubs’ own efforts, a
strong bond between clubs and fans has to be forged over time. At present, the most
common practice for Chinese clubs is to provide access and opportunities for fans to meet
players and club officials on a regular basis. Mr Zheng Ming, Vice General Manager of
Jiangsu Sainty FC explains: (personal interview 07/07/08)

“We are trying to foster our market by increasing our fan base and creating our fan
culture. We organise our own fan associations within the province, we help them to
develop. The club needs their involvement, however, there is a cultural difference

68
The exact status of the club/fan relationship (Contingent Compatible or Necessary Compatible) depends
on the contracts (explicit or implicit) between the two parties.

213
between China and the West - fans’ financial contribution has not been important, but we
believe it will be an import factor when the football market matures”.

With various market approaches, some clubs are making efforts to increase their fan
bases by offering discounted tickets or even free entry and subsidised travel. Mr Jin Yan,
CEO of Changsha Ginde FC states: (personal interview 06/07/08)

“There is no market for charging fans when the domestic environment is so bad. We give
some tickets to fan associations for free. Ultimately, we are looking at long-term
profitability, bringing people back to the game first, then re-establishing the market”

Despite clubs realising the importance of fan support, they fail to identify their own
social value as intrinsic parts of local community. Community schemes have been widely
recognised by European clubs not only as an effective tool to forge a close links and
loyalty amongst supporters, but also to demonstrate a club’s traditional value.
Furthermore, football is regarded as a representational sport, with clubs representing
specific geographical locations. Clubs can engage with communities’ based not only on
specific geographical areas but also on wider social issues. Morrow (1999) sees the
alienation with supporter community as the principle business risk for a club, especially
when the new fans may not be as loyal as the old ones.

Indeed, clubs create a social bond with their local fans in order to develop their identities
as well as a club culture. However, not a single Chinese club has its community
programmes or provides its facilities for use as a community resource to allow a better
links to be forged more efficiently. Compared to European clubs, they remain ignorant.
Clubs fail to identify the importance of community football illustrates not only a shortage
of competent managerial staff at the club level, but also limits clubs’ development as a
social institution, which in turn affects clubs’ sustainable development. Just as Professor
Jin Zhiyang, states: (personal interview, 08/08/08)

214
“Fans are god, even more so than the customer. A strong fan base is built through social
connections and bilateral communication. Good governance and strong social
connections build a club’s legacy which enhances its image and brand value as a whole”.

Total Super League clubs Jia League clubs

90 84.375
80
70
60
50 46.875
40 37.5
30
20 18.7518.75 18.7518.75
10
0 0 0 0 0 0
Websites E-commerce Social media Own TV channels
or games

Graph 6.5Percentage of clubs communicate with new media interaction

In the new media era, social media tools create big business opportunities and make huge
impact on clubs’ commercial development. Graph 6.5 shows only 18.8% of clubs have
social media platforms for the club/fan interactions; 84.4% of clubs have their websites.
Despite 17 clubs claim that having a close and very close relationship with supporters
(survey result), only 18.8% of clubs have e-commerce as part of business practice.
Moreover none of the clubs have created their own TV channels or games to engage with
their supports. Ms Li Hong – CEO of Shenzhen FC states: (personal interview, 20/08/12)

“Although we need to embrace the available new technology, it takes time for us to figure
out how such technology works for a football club and what we can really do with it.
Chinese clubs are not good at these things including us. I found it is very difficult to get
few capable people to develop this sector. Look at our website, it is not even updated”

215
The survey result and Ms Li’s statement reflect that clubs failed to draw their fans into a
richer relationship with new technology, which reflected the fact that few competent
managerial staff with business acumen exist at the club level. More important, such a
situation fails clubs’ real potential growth opportunities in a more connected world.

At the digital age, it comes digital engagement and a digital culture. It is important to
understand who makes up clubs’ followers, to provide them with relevant content on the
right devices at the right time. Social media is a fantastic tool for allowing fans to openly
exchange views and letting them be active members of the clubs. Social media interaction
with fans has been largely employed by big European clubs to build strong engagement
with their fans. It is also growing interest for clubs to provide both current and potential
business partners with real insight into that audience, ensuring they understand and use
that information to deliver return on investment.

Interestingly, Chinese clubs normally see school football as a good alternative in terms of
increasing social cohesion and popularity. School football can engage young people and
provide a feeding structure into clubs’ academies. Mr Zheng Ming, Vice General
Manager of Jiangsu Sainty FC explains (personal interview, 07/07/08):

“We send our players to some local schools. These are key football schools with a strong
history of producing players. As such we have a close working relationship with them,
they are capable of producing players for the academy”.

School football focus on the playing aspect of the game and targets a specific group of
young people within the education system, it lacks of width and depth in terms of
creating community links and building sustainable a fan base. By contrast, running
community programmes can provide tailor-made services through social media and e-
commerce to engage not only local fan base but also a wider range of stakeholders.

6.2.2b the clubs’ perception on other changes

216
Professionalisation changed the structure of the academy and grass-roots development, as
local sports authorities have gradually shifted youth teams from provincial central sports
schools to clubs, and at the same time pushed spare-time football schools into the market.
By the end of the 1990s, most clubs already ran their own academies. In fact the club
academy was made compulsory for all professional clubs by 2003. Clubs are required to
invest at least 10% of their revenue to academies, which includes a minimum of three
teams U-19, U-17 and U-15 (Article 2, rule 9). However, critics do not see this as a
success story, as Professor Jin Zhiyang explains: (personal interview 08/08/08)

“The club academy structure has destroyed the old fostering system. There are only 2-3
players that can break into the first team each time, the remaining players have nowhere
to go. This discourages children from playing football. Furthermore, maintaining three
youth teams do not make financial sense for a club, most clubs prefer to buy young
players”.

In terms of sustainable development, the old fostering model was directly funded by the
government, and players spent their time equally on training and study. Academy players
always had a job guarantee and continued further education if they could not break into
the first team before graduating. By contrast, the club academy model does not provide
the same opportunities. This discourages young people from playing football, especially
when they can look beyond the early salary temptation.

Corruption is considered the biggest threat to the Chinese game. According to Chinese
media, the culture within the football industry is rife with corruption, which forces clubs
to compromise their principles. Moreover, there is a great deal of “flexibility” on players’
ages, falsification is a common place within the industry, for example, Italian club
Perugia prepared to buy Ma Mingyu, but in fact, he was older than Perugia was led to
believe, and as a result, his trial in Italy ended up with a negative consequences (Eaves et
al, 2003). According to a BBC (2009) report, bone tests on teenage athletes in southern
China have shown that more than 3,000 out of nearly 13,000 faked their ages in order to

217
keep competing in junior events. Mr Jin Yan, CEO of Ginde FC states: (personal
interview, 06/07/08)

“Gambling and falsification of players’ ages are the main problems. Despite gambling
being illegal in China, it is an industry which still leads to match fixing. The government
should take a stronger stand and bring the judicial system into the game. Falsification of
players’ ages must be addressed, otherwise there is no hope for Chinese football”.

There is no a single club with a will to bribe, however, due to the stakes involved, clubs,
players and officials can be approached by other parties. A CFA official was quoted in a
Shanghai newspaper in 1998, as saying all professional clubs had falsified their accounts
in order to hide bribes gave away (Eaves, et al 2003). Mr Zhang Defa, General Manager
of Shanghai Shenhua FC recognises: (personal interview, 18/01/08)

“As you know, it is difficult to talk about corruption in the game. I can only say that there
is something we cannot control, there are unwritten rules existing in the industry,
sometimes you just have to adopt these rules in order to survive”.

It is fair to say that corruption is not limited to China and its football industry. However,
as a social phenomenon with political neutrality, these issues have been publicly debated.
Although all clubs recognised the problem and its existence, every one of them distanced
themselves from corruption. In comparison to other Chinese sectors, the football industry
is relatively exposed to media scrutiny. For example, following a poor performance by
the Olympic Team in Beijing, the Chinese fans held up placards demanding the CFA
chief’s resignation. This is certainly something you would not see in any other realm of
Chinese society. It demonstrates a great openness within the industry (Borger, 2008).

6.3 Summary
Alongside the expansion of capitalism, and the modification of sports policies on a global
scare, football governance has developed significantly. Football in China has undergone

218
an unprecedented transformation since its professionalisation. The centrally controlled
top-down governance structure was modified during this transformation process.
Governance power shifted from governing bodies towards clubs. Having recognised their
increased power, clubs are more actively managing their relationship with their
stakeholders through different mechanisms. Moreover, with a more commercial approach
and sensible financial awareness, clubs are learning how to exercise their power properly
in an improved and influential manner.

Having the stakeholder theory framework to analyse governance at club level, the
researcher focusssed on clubs’ operational practice and their relationships with other
stakeholders. Findings are based on both descriptive and quantitative analyses and the
development trends are explained with different theoretical models and visualised with
appropriate graphs, which provide fresh analytical insights into football development. For
instance, the transition of the club/CFA relationship pattern (Figure 6-1) illustrates
increasingly diversified clubs’ interests, growing power and demands. The theoretical
approach also combines two themes - conflict of interest and financial dependency to
explore the clubs versus country relationship. The analytical model (Figure 6-3) and
findings show clubs are more proactively managing their relationships with the CFA and
having more accountability demands.

Modern football clubs must recognise the conflicts they hold, both as community
resources and as profit-making companies. Due to their overriding business nature, it is
important for them to function as businesses; it is equally important to recognise that
clubs are more than just businesses. One needs to see a club both in terms of its social
and cultural application, just as much as its financial application. The insights of the
clubs’ relationships with other stakeholders that are obtained from stakeholder analysis
answer the sub-research question – how clubs manage relationships with multiple
stakeholders? The analytical findings contribute enormously to sport governance studies
in China especially to better understand the football industry at club level.

219
For a football club, it is the club’s responsibility to have a positive influence in the lives
of employees, fans, investors and so on, therefore, it is necessary to recognise the
importance of all the stakeholders’ involvement and their interests when a club carries
out its businesses in order to minimise conflicts. Lacking a proactive approach and
having a short-sighted vision reduces clubs ability to manage their business effectively.
The stakeholder models and findings from this chapter provide constructive predictions,
and the sooner all stakeholders pay attention to proper governance, the earlier the football
industry will benefit as a whole.

This chapter explore the club’s perspective to address the research question. It reveals the
conflicts and needs of club management, through analysing relationships between the
clubs and their main stakeholders in order to understand how the clubs resolve conflicts
with different stakeholders. The next chapter looks at the industry from the player’s
perspective.

220
Chapter Seven: The Players’ Perspective

7.1 The players’ status


A modern commercial business will see its workforce as its greatest asset, and many
managers recognise their staff as being highly valuable and worthy of investment. To that
end, effective management of a company’s workforce has been viewed as an important
element for corporate success.

The football industry revolves around games and the games revolve around players. It is
true that players are the most valuable assets for the clubs, and they play an essential role
in the industry. Players as a whole form a normative stakeholder group and are, in effect
the main workforce involved in producing matches. Looking at the role of players from
football economic perspective, they are also viewed as fixed capital in the eyes of the
clubs and their market values are included in the clubs’ balance sheets, as such a
relationship will be governed by strictly legal contracts (Healey 2009). By contrast, in
many other industries, a firm’s workforce is not included in its balance sheet.

There is a dearth of literature on characteristics of Chinese football players as regards


their perspective on football development both as individuals and as a stakeholder group.
This chapter provides not only a brief overview of Chinese football players’ status but
also to explore the players’ view of the industry with descriptive analysis.

7.1.1 The status before professionalisation


After the communist party ascended to power in 1949, a centralised sports system was
established. The new government placed an emphasis not only on stabilising the new
regime, but also on improving the overall health standard of the population. Therefore,
under the political ideology, sport has been used as an effective means of achieving both
these goals.

221
Whitby (1999) contends that the elite development of Chinese sport has been achieved by
combining rigorous implementation of programmes and athletes’ development. In the
case of football, the Soviet style fostering system was adopted in order to develop elite
players - a pyramid structure with good cohesion between each layer.

F-T players
(elite teams)

P-T & fully subsidised players


(provincial centre
sports schools)

Partially subsidised amateur players


(spare-time & key football schools)

Figure 7-1 the pyramid structure of elite development

The talented youngsters from spare-time football schools and key football schools could
be selected by provincial central sports schools, and from there, they could work all the
way up to provincial teams and even into the national team.

Spare-time football schools provide specialist coaching for selected youngsters aged
between 8-15. Players were trained together after school during the afternoon. Students
with promising potentials could go a step further to provincial central sports schools.
Each province and municipality city had one central sports school with boarding facilities
and many of them had football squads. Players were selected across the whole province
and lived on site as “semi-professionals”. The best players from a provincial central
school could progress to break into a provincial team or its reserve team to become

222
“professionals”, while the unlucky ones were either given jobs by the state after they
graduated or returned to normal high schools to continue their education.

In the state amateur system, selection was based on players’ ability and potential. From
these two elements, the higher up the ladder a player could climb, the more lucrative
subsidy he could receive. For example, such subsidies at the spare-time school level
included players receiving free clothes, food and travel subsidies during competition
events, and at the provincial central sports school level, players enjoyed free boarding,
clothes and small monthly stipend. If a player managed to break into one of the provincial
teams, they were collectively accommodated and paid as state employees with free food,
clothes and medical care. The reward system at all three levels of the elite development
structure was inherently a socialist ideology. The Soviet style sports system avoided
material incentives instead promoting collectivism and egalitarianism. Moreover, state
employers were encouraged to contribute more to the ‘motherland’ therefore no bonuses
were awarded, regardless of a player’s performance. Under the planned economy, players
were rewarded equally – the only difference was reflected in seniority.

At the top level, national team players were trained collectively all year round in Beijing,
where they enjoyed the best facilities with a state employment security. They did not
need to return to their provincial teams to compete domestically, as their focus was on
international competitions only. Although elite team coaches were judged based on merit,
their employment status was permanent, and they often enjoyed long career spells with
their teams. Against this backdrop, many senior players were also able to hold a stable
position under the same coach with fewer intense challenges from junior players. As a
result, it was made difficult for provincial team players to break into the national team,
which in turn made it increasing tough for young players to break into the provincial
teams.

Furthermore, the transfer system did not exist in the pre-professional era. Players were
tied to their provincial teams throughout the duration of their careers. By the end of their
playing careers, local PESCs had a responsibility to find appropriate jobs for retired

223
players. Despite only the best players having opportunities to be retained as coaches,
opportunities for further study to qualify as PE teachers were widely available for others,
and such training was provided even before the end of their playing days.

In short, before professionalisation, the whole football system was funded by both local
and the central governments. Despite top level elite players earning a full-time salary
while training and playing on a full-time basis, they were still officially recognised as
amateurs. There was a systematic procedure for indentifying and training young athletes
from an early age - but few resources were attributed directly towards public use.
Motivation for sporting success was borne out of patriotism and collective success -
players were competing for ‘the glory of socialism and the motherland’.

7.1.2 The status after professionalisation


By the mid-1980s, many Western concepts had been accepted by the Chinese
government - politics and sports became less intermingled (Jones 2000). As the
commercial approach was widely adopted socially, there was increasing demand for
sports to be financially self-sufficient. As such, football became the first sport exposed to
the Western influence and was encouraged to pioneer the Chinese sport reform.

The football reform transformed the industry through professionalisation. With this, the
combined market approach and sponsorship played important roles in the transition.
Players saw huge increases in their financial reward and the introduction of the transfer
system. This provided elite players with more flexibility to maximise their labour value
under market-oriented economy. On the one hand, players were now able to enjoy more
freedom in terms of movement, however on the other hand, the market-orientated reform
provides less job security in the shape of players’ employment status changing from
permanent state employees to contractual employees of club companies – players could
now be released at the end of their contracts without any guaranteed alternatives to
safeguard their future.

224
The commercial approach and reform policy led to substantial reduction of direct
government funding, with spare-time football schools and provincial central sport schools
affected the most. As a result, spare-time football schools had to adapt the market-
oriented approach in order to operate on reduced state budget, leaving most students now
needing to pay training fees. Moreover, the majority of provincial central sport schools
dissolved their football squads in order to focus on other Olympic sports (Fan 1997). As a
direct result, some young players were transferred to football clubs’ academies.

Unlike during the pre-professional era, each different club’s academies are now managed
in accordance with that club’s policy. Some academies require players to pay full or
partial training fees in order to stay on board, while some others are free of charge. In
addition to the state funded schools, private football schools emerged in the market.
There were about 1,000 schools throughout the country in the 1990s, less than 100 are
still operating at present (Ran, 2008a). This dramatic reduction has been concluded by
media to be a result of short-sighted behaviour of investors and an over-commercial
approach at the grassroots level.

The ‘westernisation’ of football management can also be analysed at the very top level -
the national team. The method of long-practices and collective training has been replaced
by the temporary grouping of players who are most on form, which increases competition
for every position. National team players are gathered just before international duties.

7.2 Impact of professionalisation on players

7.2.1 Players’ wages


The market-orientated economy brought to the Chinese football industry Western
managerial practices, along with its cultural values. Players’ wages have been increased
significantly since professionalisation, but, unlike their counterparts in Europe, the
increase is not a direct result of the infusion of money derived from television, but a
product of sponsorships.

225
Before professionalisation, players were paid like any other state employees – with a
national average salary standard. Today, players are paid according to their individual
contracts, which reflect their market values and are based on the PRP structure, and it
also provides a link between pay and employees’ overall performance. This acts as a
motivational force and allows for successful employees to be rewarded more generously
(Baruch et al 2004).

In tune with the ‘Western’ concept of individualism, the PRP structure has been widely
accepted by both Chinese clubs and the players. A typical professional footballer’s salary
is divided into three parts: basic salary, training performance and match bonus, with each
of these parts determined by the player’s performance in that particular area. The PRP
salary structure has certainly made a substantial impact on players’ attitudes towards their
job. As Lu Chang explains: (personal interview 31/08/08)

“During the state amateur era, it was my team that needed me (for training and
competitions), and now it is I that needs to train & play in order to be match-fit. A
passive attitude is replaced by willingness and initiatives”.

The fixed salary structure based on egalitarianism that was practised in the pre-
professional era provided no financial incentives for players’ good performance and
achievements. In direct contrast, the PRP salary structure, upheld in the professional era,
has created strong internal competition between players. The PRP structure certainly
stimulates players’ desire to play and to win. Indeed, every competitive match has
become important as it is now intertwined with players’ income. In addition, training
sessions carry further importance, as players need to demonstrate their current form
during training sessions in order to make the starting line-up. As a result, the internal
relationship between players is more competitive and players’ behaviour more
professional. As Tao Wei explains: (personal interview 02/09/08)

226
“We have to be more professional and treat matches and training seriously. As any
injury can affect our potential earning, we need to learn how to protect ourselves - to
perform and to avoid injury at the same time in order to shine on big stages.”

Baruch et al (2004) argue that these new elements are based on the capitalist ideology of
individualism (which emphasises individual achievement with an ‘I’ orientation) and
clearly contradict the fundamental ideology of socialism, which promotes collectivism
and egalitarianism. Despite the ideological contradiction, the PRP structure has been
adopted by all clubs in China since professionlisation as an effective tool to encourage
their players.

7.2.2 The transfer system and foreign players


The transfer system was introduced in 1994, and took effect just before the 1995 season.
The new system provides a structure of transfer fees and opportunities for players to
move between clubs. As the CFA tries to keep the transfer system in tune with the pace
of development, details of transfer rules are modified slightly from year to year.

Number of players Number of players The top transfer fee


Seasons requested for completed transfer achieved
transfer
1995 28 16 ¥ 600,000
1996 62 44 ¥ 1,150,000
1997 72 60 ¥ 2,200,000
Source: (Zhou, 1997)
Table 7-1 The transfer figures from 1995-1997

In the first three seasons (1995 – 1997), players could negotiate with any club. Due to the
introduction of the transfer system providing a platform of mutual selection for both
players and clubs according to the market principles, the number of transfers increased
each year.

During the1998 – 2004 seasons, a draft scheme was introduced that was similar to the
NBA’s - those players whose transfer requests had either been approved by their clubs or

227
who were no longer wanted by their clubs were listed on the CFA’s transfer list, and the
club that finished at the bottom of last season’s league table had the right to the first pick.
During this period there were two transfer windows – before the season began and the
half way through the season. The number of choices was also restricted for each club. As
the Players’ Status and Transfer Regulation (CFA 2001, p6) Article 2 Rule 16 states:
Each club is eligible to pick maximum seven indigenous players each season, and five
maximum during the first transfer window.

Despite this system having many problems, both clubs and players had to obey the
transfer rules. Even if a player has a preference for a particular club, and that club agrees
to sign him, there is still a possibility that another club will interject during the drafting
process. For instance, a player who wanted to join club A was more likely to end up with
club B because the club B’s picking order was ahead of club A’s.

The Players’ Status and Transfer Regulation (CFA, 2001, p7) states in Article 2, Rule 19,
No.3
Neither clubs nor players can withdraw from the transfer process after picking, otherwise
they will lose their status to compete for this season or an even longer period of time.

Table 7-2 shows some of these ‘mismarriages’ between players (worth over ¥ 1m in the
transfer market then) and clubs in the 1999 season.

Players’ original Ideal clubs for Clubs that players


Players clubs transfer ended up with
Wang Tao Dalian Shide Xiameng Xiaxin Beijing Guoan
Deng Lejun Shandong Luneng Shenzhen Pingan Xiameng Xiaxin
Shen Si Shanghai Shenhua Daliang Wanda Shanghai Shenhua
Zhu Qi Shanghai Shenhua Overseas Sichuan Quanxing
Ou Chuliang Shanghai Shenhua Top Jia A club Yunan Hongta
Jiang Hong Qingdao Yizhong Shenzhen Pingan Shanxi Guoli
Gao Feng Qianwei Huandao Overseas Shenyang Haishi
Jiang Jin Bayi Jia A Tianjin Taida
Wei Yimin Daliang Wanda Xiameng Xiaxin Qianwei Huandao
Source: Gong (2000)
Table 7-2: The 1999 season transfer list of mismatches

228
An updated transfer regulation (CFA 2004) was started from 2005 season, which
abolished the draft system and set just one transfer window. Although there was no
restriction for clubs to sell their players, it allowed each club to purchase no more than
five native players each season (ibid).

The new regulation gives priority to clubs in retaining their old players, as the Article
Four, Rule 15, No.5 states (p3)
“If a player’s current club is willing to extend his contract, then the player can not be
transferred”.
No6 (p3)
“Relegated clubs can refuse transfer request from any of their players without reason”.

In contrast, foreign transfers are made according to FIFA rules and the AFC regulations
(Cong & Shi 2009). Both transfer regulations (2001, 2004) allow each club to sign three
foreign players at one time, while in addition, since 10th October 2000, no foreign
goalkeepers were allowed in order to protect the interest of Chinese football (ibid). From
the 2010 season onwards, five foreign players are permitted for each Super League club
and four foreign players for each Jia League club69.

The AFC introduced a ‘3+1’ rule for its 2009 Champions League competition – a club
can play three foreign players (from outside of the AFC members) plus one Asian player
(from the AFC members) at the same time (Duerden 2009).

Looking at the Chinese transfer market, the ‘free agent’ status does not exist, even once a
player’s contract with a club has expired. A player can only become a ‘free agent’ (be
eligible to sign a new contract without a transfer fee) after 30 months’ expiration of his
last contract, and if a player signs for another club within the 30-month period, a transfer
fee is required. The term ‘free agent’ was defined in both the CFA transfer regulations
(2001, 2004), as the Article Four, Rule 12 states (2004, p2):

69
The latest regulation for the 2012 season (the CFA 2011).

229
“A player either has not played for any clubs for 30 months or more than 30 months, or
has never played for a club before he can be registered as a free agent in his local FA”.

This means that Chinese clubs have more power to retain their best assets than their
international counterparts within the heavily regulated market.

The introduction of foreign players in 1994 hugely boosted the popularity of the
professional game. Now, all the super league clubs and most of Jia League clubs have
foreign players. Chinese clubs mainly sign older and relatively high profile out-of-
contract players from Europe, whereas young players from South America and Africa are
often hired due to their relative cost-efficiency. Good quality foreign players have
enhanced clubs’ competitiveness, and some of them played a vital role during the clubs’
promotion and relegation battles. As a result, most indigenous players perceive foreign
players as making a positive impact on Chinese football. This is especially poignant when
considering the experience and professional attitude they brought into the Chinese game
and the way in which their involvement has moved the game forwards.

Compared to the presence of foreign players in China, not many Chinese players play
abroad. The first two players played abroad were Jia Xiouquan and Liu Haiguang in the
1980s with Partizan Belgrade, which was orchestrated by special agreement between the
governments of China and the former Yugoslavia (Liang 2003). After professionalisation,
Fan Zhiyi and Sun Jihai played for Crystal Palace in 1998, Fan also played for Dundee in
2001 and Sun played for Manchester City and Sheffield United before moving back to
China in 2009. Dong Fangzhuo played for both Royal Antwerp and Manchester United
between 2004 and 2008 under a contract with Manchester United. Another player, Zheng
Zhi, played for Charlton Athletic and Celtic, and moved back to China in 2010. Few
Chinese players are able to play in high profile European Leagues. There are many
difficulties for foreign clubs when signing Chinese players. Firstly, the playing standard
of Chinese players is not appealing - the national team is currently placing just 97th in the
FIFA rankings70. As a direct result of this, immigration laws in many European countries

70
October 2013. The highest position was 37th in December 1998.

230
restrict work for players from low-ranking countries. Secondly, the lack of licensed
agents poses obstacles. Almost all Chinese players lack agents. This is detrimental to
players’ interests, as they cannot be represented by professionals in business meetings,
and have no one to look out for opportunities for them to play abroad. As Li Zhihai
explains: (personal interview 30/06/08)

“The opportunity for us to play abroad depends on the clubs - we have to rely on our
club’s overseas connections. We do not have agents, and only few players can meet the
European playing standards, so currently, we just deal with everything ourselves”.

Both the introduction of foreign players and the transfer system have affected players
internally as well as externally. Externally, the transfer system creates a relatively
mobilised labour market, which provides more options and flexibility for players to move
between clubs. Internally, the mobilised labour market and foreign players increased
internal competition between players. As a result, at the professional level, the game has
advanced into a much stronger competitive environment. Today, all players have to be
competitive enough in order to survive, regardless of which club they are playing for.

7.2.3 The fitness test and the lifestyle


Chinese teams need more in-depth physical strength to sustain themselves through
challenges. The national team in particular has failed many times on important occasions,
either allowing late goals, or in some cases having players collapsing towards the end of
the game. Players’ poor performance was affecting Chinese teams’ progress in major
tournaments, and the CFA consequently introduced the fitness test in 1994 as one of the
measurements to counter the lack of physical strengthen in Chinese players. This fitness
test consisted of two parts – a 12 minute run and a (5-25) x 5 shuttle run.

The introduction of a fitness test has had the biggest impact for professional players. In
the inaugural year of professionalisation, 359 players attended the fitness test in March.
Of these, 114 players failed at their first attempt, including national team players, and 28

231
players even failed the benchmark for retaking the test (Wang, 2004). The result
indicated that many elite Chinese players needed to improve their physical fitness in
order to pass the test and to be fitter for professional competitions. We can now see a
parallel development of the professional games, as players are now more capable of
dealing with the test, fewer players fail each year and the physical side of the game is
stronger. In addition, from 2003 onwards the test was changed to a yo-yo test71, but it was
still a compulsory for all players to take part every year before the start of the new season.
In the latest development, the CFA abolished the fitness test all together in 2011.

Despite the many changes that have taken place in the industry, the way clubs manage
players remains largely unchanged. Chinese players live communally in their training
bases, where players are less likely to stray from the straight and narrow path of clean
living, regular daily routine, controlled diet and training. Jones (1999a) recognises that
the practice of housing all players together is a part of the communist system in which
players can be kept in a disciplined manner. Before professionalisation, players were
housed by their local sports authorities and had to share bedrooms. Today, players are
housed by clubs in training bases, where most players have their own studios. Food and
leisure facilities are provided free of charge. A former Vila and Blackpool player Marlon
Harewood sees the Chinese regime was a tough one72 and states (Drew, 2011, p4):

“Chinese managers have their strict rules and routines that they go by, for example, all
players stayed at the same hotel for the duration of the season, it was like preparing for
an away game every day”.

“The foreign players have the freedom to go out, the Chinese players have a 10o’clock
curfew and their rooms are checked to make sure they are in, we could do what we
wanted to a certain extent but we did not abuse it”.

71
A different type of shuttle run.
72
Harewood jointed Guangzhou R&F in July 2011 on a short-term contract.

232
Compared to European professional players, Chinese players appear to live like soldiers
in an army compound. Although most foreign players are accommodated in the same way,
they enjoy more freedom and may get better accommodation and special treatments.

Most players are used to this type of management, since they have experienced similar
management as youth players in provincial central sports schools. Guangzhou FC
attempted the ‘Western’ way of management in the early days of professionalisation,
allowing their players the freedom to live where they liked, but found that this trial did
not lead to success on the field. With this relative freedom, some players found
themselves involved in unsavoury activities off the field, which were highlighted by local
media. Due to the onslaught of negative publicity and debate about the ‘westernised’
living arrangement, the club reverted to its previous practice. As Lu Chang states:
(personal interview, 31/08/08)

“Compared to European players, our players have a lack of self-discipline and


professionalism, they are used to being controlled rather than applying self-control.
Clubs do not want their players to make trouble off the field. The communal system is
therefore the better choice”.

Tang Jing expressed a similar opinion: (personal interview, 04/08/08)

“The communal system may not be the best way but it is the most suitable way at moment
for Chinese players. Chinese football is still in a transitional period, and so is its
governance. I adore the life style of European players, but I can cope with the Chinese
system. We have not developed to that stage yet”.

Chinese players are used to the communal way of living, and because not many players
possess personal experience abroad, only a select few are able to make a comparison
between the two types of player management based on their own experience. Zhang
Xiaobin - a Ginde player who had playing experience outside China (in England &
Australia), provides his view: (personal interview, 05/07/08)

233
“Our life style is too simple compared to Western professionals. The same eating-
training-sleeping pattern is repeated everyday within the same training base, and makes
our life quality low. It makes me feel depressed. I do not know anyone else outside the
training base, and it is likes a prison to me”.

Zhang Xiaobin also mentioned that western players have varied lifestyles and are free to
do whatever they like after training. A varied lifestyle creates a good mindset for
individual players as well as a good atmosphere overall for the team, which is an
important and a positive element for players in producing high quality training sessions
and matches. Hao Haidong73 expressed the same thought in a CCTV documentary - he
enjoyed to be free and to be close with his family after training, the life style was superb
at Sheffield for him as a professional footballer.

Communal living and free living arrangements are two different ways of player
management, and each one comes with its own advantages and disadvantages. Generally
speaking, indigenous players without playing experience abroad prefer to be managed
rather than manage themselves. Moreover, clubs also see communal living as a simple
and effective practice, especially at the current development stage of Chinese football -
players still lack professionalism and self-discipline. Many players lack awareness and
knowledge about being professionals.

7.3 Relationships with other stakeholders


The economic reform brought ‘Western’ capitalist values into the Chinese society,
including those of the sports field. These values are associated with the concepts of
striving to be the best and individual liberty. This conflicts directly with China’s socialist
ideology which is associated with collectivism, egalitarianism and discipline (Baruch et
al, 2004).

73
A player signed by Sheffield United in January 2005, he made little impact after suffering from injuries
and worked mainly as a coach in Sheffield's academy before deciding to end his playing career and retire.

234
When compared to the pre-professional era, the advent of professionalisation created not
only a brand new football industry, but also new relationships between the different
stakeholders under the new values. As an important stakeholder group within the industry,
players’ relationships with other stakeholders are also affected by the game’s
transformation. Players attract constant media interest, without players, there are no clubs,
no fans and no professional football. The view of the players therefore deserve
acknowledgement.

7.3.1 The relationship with clubs


As a direct result of professionalisation, players’ once permanent ‘iron rice bowl’ has
now been replaced by seasonal contracts, which demonstrated a major change in players’
employment status. Players and clubs are employers and employees, respectively. In the
football industry, under the principle of the market economy, the two parties have diverse
financial interest.

In Chapter Six, figure 6-4 indicates how the relationship between clubs and players has
transformed from the Necessary Compatible to the Necessary Incompatible as the direct
result of professionalisation. It is important that we recreate the figure below to refresh
our memory.

(High level common value)


Contingent Necessary
Compatible ◙
(Low) (Highly connected)
Incompatible Present
(Low)
◙ The Club/player relationship

Figure 6-4 The development pattern of the Club/player relationship

235
In a resource dependence concept, players are highly relying on clubs to pay their salary,
the level of players’ dependence on clubs is high. In contrast, clubs’ financial dependency
on players is almost nil, the level of clubs’ dependence on players is low, which leaves
clubs to dominate the player/club relationship. With the financial strength they possess,
clubs are capable of shaping the labour market. Especially since those players are not
well-organised individuals. In the pre-professional era, even though players relied highly
on elite teams, without the transfer market, elite teams were also highly relying on their
limited number of players to function.

Level of players dependency on clubs


(High)
A B

Level of club Present ◙

dependency on
players (Low) (High)

C D

A: Indirect/usage (Club power) (Low)


B: Direct/usage (High interdependence)
C: Indirect/withholding (Low interdependence) ◙ the player/club relationship
D: Direct/withholding (Player power)

Figure 7-2 The player/club relationship

Figure 7-2 demonstrates how the player/club relationship changed. Under the state
amateur model without the transfer market, players were relatively difficult to replace not
only due to their stable employment status but also the low number available at the top
level within the same region. Alongside professionalisation and introduction of the
transfer market, not only players’ employment status changed but there were also more
players (including foreign players) available for clubs to select. As a result, the level of
clubs dependency on players reduced and the player/club relationship moved to the left,
the status changing from high interdependence (configuration B) to club power

236
(configuration A). The transformation put clubs in a dominate position in the labour
market.

Furthermore, Chinese players lack organisation amongst themselves, and under the
current political environment, they are not able to form a players’ union to promote their
own interests through a united voice. As a result, Chinese players can only manage a low-
density network relationship amongst themselves. Compared to players, clubs are more
centrally located within the industry network. Consequently, during any dispute between
players and other stakeholders, players have to fight as individuals or as an inefficiently
linked small group without support from an official organisation of their own.

Players’ network density


(High)
Club’s
(Low) (High)
Centrality ◙ Low Density/High Centrality

(Low)
◙ The player/club relationship

Figure 7-3 Players’ influences over clubs

The figure 7-3 also explains the relationship between players and clubs in the labour
market from the stakeholder centrality perspective. As clubs’ centrality is high and
players’ network density is low, clubs are capable of resisting pressure from players,
especially when they are acting as unorganised individuals. As the labour market is
regulated skew towards clubs, therefore, in this relationship, the relative power balance is
in favor of clubs. With better accesses to information and strong financial backings clubs
can adapt a commanding role. In effect, clubs are capable of controlling players in a
heavily regulated labour market. Chinese players feel helpless to address their interests
when conflicts arise. As Tao Wei highlights the skewed relationship: (personal interview,
02/09/08)

237
“Our contracts are signed on a yearly basis, which provides only a short period of
security. Despite the poor treatment, we have no right act dissatisfied. If you try to argue
with your club, you are the one who gets hurt eventually”.

Despite the introduction of the Labour Law and the 1995 Sports Law, players have a hard
time finding anything specifically related to professional footballers in these two laws.
Moreover, the Sports Law has intentionally omitted rights of individual athletes, which
makes it very difficult for an individual athlete to protect his/her personal interests or to
raise issues against an established organisation (e.g. the governing body or a club)
(Nafziger & Wei, 1998).

In contrast to those in Europe, trade unions in China are strictly controlled by the state.
Chinese trade unions only have a decorative function with practically no power at all74.
This ironically illustrates the so-called socialist democracy with distinctly ‘Chinese
characteristics’. As Lu Chang states: (personal interview, 31/08/08)

“Our status has changed from that of state employees to company employees. We lost all
the benefits of stability and job security provided by the state during this transformation.
Today neither the state nor the clubs take enough responsibility, our interests are not
well protected”.

Under the state amateur system in the pre professional era, there was less need for a
players’ union, as all players were treated in a similar way and enjoyed state job security
for life with free medical care attached. Professionalisation has changed their
employment status, life-long state job security has been replaced by short-term
employment contracts, as clubs take no responsibility for players’ long-term welfare.
Moreover, even short-term contracts are not fully honored when the clubs’ benefactors
experience financial hardship. From the players’ point of view, a need to form their own
work union arises in order to protect their own interests. Players in particular see

74
The Chinese Constitution pronounces strikes are illegal.

238
themselves as a vulnerable stakeholder group within the industry. As the national team
captain Li Weifeng said (Sinasports, 2008):

“Although players look glamourous in public eye, in fact, we are the vulnerable group.
We cannot even protect our own interests and have no influence over the game”.

Li Weifeng’s statement echoes aforementioned analytical findings. Players especially


those with overseas experience, see their welfare and individual rights as some of the top
issues that need to be properly addressed. However, Chinese laws often provide implicit
rights for individuals to challenge the decisions of authorities, but lack explicit legislation
to protect their legal rights (Nafziger & Wei, 1998). Again, the Sports Law (1995) failed
to articulate any rights for athletes, and with human rights being of low priority on the
Chinese authorities’ list, a players’ association cannot be created without the
government’s blessing. As a result, it is impossible in the current political environment
for players to form a union to promote their interests, despite many players’ desire to do
so. Tao Wei explains: (personal interview, 02/09/08)

“Our welfare and rights are only covered during the time disclosed in the contract, and
even that cannot be guaranteed. We do not feel any security, especially in the case of the
older players. The uncertainty at the end of each season can affect a team’s performance
and takes our concentration away from competitions”.

Furthermore, there are no measures in place to ensure that players are paid on time and
according to their contracts. There have been cases in which some clubs delayed players’
payment. Despite collective action from players in complaint, the central position and
superior power that clubs hold over players allows clubs to resolve such conflicts on their
own terms. Apart from the skewed power that clubs hold over players in the labour
market, the CFA’s transfer regulations (2001, 2004) ensure that players continue to feel
powerless even after the expiration of their contracts.

239
Apart from other primary and secondary data, the researcher’s own experience and
observation at Shenzhen FC also reflects the players’ position of low centrality and high
dependency in the player/club relationship. For example, there was three professional
clubs in Shenzhen and all of them had pay disputes with their players over either salary or
bonus, including the researcher’s own club. Players were powerless to address the issue,
even at a point of three months delaying. As Liu Shuai complains (Personal interview,
02/08/12):

“We were paid on time for just once this season, sounds like a joke but it is a reality of
the club and the industry. The situation does affect our competitiveness and match
preparation. We did a couple of mini strikes (in training sessions) this season but those
were not effective enough. We do not want to strike, it has negative impacts on our match
fitness but we have no means to hold the club to be accountable.”

7.3.2 The relationship with fans


After professionalisation, the importance of fans has become more obvious to clubs. The
market-orientated reform forced clubs to pay more attention to their supporters, as fans
are part of the product of the game and are becoming increasingly important for clubs’
revenue stream. In contrast, although players acknowledge the fans’ contribution to the
game, they are less concerned about fans’ financial input towards their clubs and the
industry as a whole due to a community-based football infrastructure has not been
soundly developed in China.

The clubs’ relatively short history and heritage has resulted in limited social engagement
and links between clubs, players and fans. Despite enjoying a high social profile, players
show a lack of awareness about their community roles and responsibilities, especially as
role models for youngsters. As a result, both clubs and players are void of any vision in
employing well-designed initiatives to explore their social status effectively, which in
turn can affect clubs’ long-term development. According to Tang Jing: (personal
interview, 04/08/08)

240
“Fans are important for creating atmosphere, with fans behind us we play football better.
The links we have with our fans are mainly through our club’s initiatives, and a closer
relationship between players and fans helps to develop the local market”.

The statement indicates that players mainly meet local fans in pre/post-season events, and
players judge the closeness of their relationship with fans simply based on number of
such events their clubs hold each season. On these occasions, players are only there to
help clubs explore local markets. Nevertheless, most players do feel that a close
relationship with local fans is necessary for the modern game.

Level of players dependency on fans


(High)
A B

Level of fans
dependency on (Low) (High)

players ◙ players/fans

C D

(Low)
A: Indirect/usage (Player power)
B: Direct/usage (High interdependence)
C: Indirect/withholding (Low interdependence) ◙ the player/fan relationship
D: Direct/withholding (Fan power)

Figure 7-4 The player/fan relationship

Players and fans are two different stakeholder groups with a corresponding functional
interest, thereby making their relationship a Contingent Compatible arrangement within
the industry. In the current football market, Chinese clubs depend little on direct financial
contribution from supporters. Players’ salaries are mainly contributed by clubs’
sponsoring corporations, therefore, from a financial dependency point of view, the

241
relationship of the two parties is also one of Low Interdependence, as illustrated in Figure
7-4 above.

Although fans only account for limited direct financial contribution to the game at its
current stage of development, many stakeholders acknowledge that fans deserve better
treatment regardless of their direct financial input, as they are an integral part of the game
and a stakeholder group with normative legitimacy. Compared to players, fans are better
organised at the local level. Organised fans are more demanding than individuals,
especially after professionalisation. Despite the current football infrastructure not being
prepared to include fans in the decision-making process at any level, a well-organised fan
association is always respected by its club and other stakeholders. As the Chinese football
market matures little by little, the low interdependency status of player/fan relationship
will further intertwine and developed, especially in the digital era today. Mr Wei Kexing
(ex-Chinese international and Guoan player) Vice General Manager of Guoan FC
explains (personal conversation, 02/09/08):

“Players are passive and only act as a link to connect clubs and local fans. Both players
and clubs focus only on fans’ direct financial contribution and market expansion, but
they should realise that fans’ social involvement is also vital for the game’s long-term
development. Fans are important stakeholders for a market-orientated football industry
for certain.”

Despite efforts made by the players (and clubs) go to local schools and colleges to
promote football and their clubs, there remaining a lack of coordinated initiatives
between clubs and local authorities for the purpose of exploring the social function of the
game in order to establish clubs as focal points of their local communities. In other words,
to establish football clubs as social institutions. Players have not been effectively
deployed to forge strong bonds between themselves and their supporters within the
infrastructure of community initiatives. Zhang Xiaobin explains: (personal interview,
05/07/08)

242
“We go to colleges to attract young supporters, how loyal those students will be after
graduation remains a question. Moreover, I have not seen our club or local authority
run any planned community programmes. We have much less social engagement
compared to European players, there are many things we need to learn”.

7.4 The players’ perspective on the game’s development


Players have witnessed and experienced some great changes since the advent of
professionalisation. The commercialisation of the professional game has inevitably raised
the profile of Chinese football. But looking beneath the surface, one can appreciate both
the positive and the negative impressions that have derived from the game’s
transformation.

7.4.1 The positive impression


From the players’ point of view the quality of the game has certainly improved. In spite
of debates surrounding the fitness test, a strictly physical test set to higher criteria,
coupled with the introduction of foreign players and coaches, has enhanced the playing
standard, and has brought the game to a new level. Lu Chang states: (personal interview,
31/08/08)

“Competitions are strong and competitive; results are related to players’ salaries, which
create an incentive for players to perform better. Apart from financial rewards, foreign
players and coaches brought new knowledge and skills into our game, which enhanced
the game’s quality and competitiveness”.

The environment surrounding the game has also changed. Not only are players competing
for places, but coaches are also under pressure to perform. Their jobs are even less secure
than those of the players. Lu Chang explains further:

“In the pre-professional era, there was little in the way of pressure, a few bad results
could not threaten a coach’s job. Now it is a different story, no one is secure in the game,

243
which makes things more exciting. Sometimes you feel a cruel side of the game, but that
is the way professional football goes”.

Many players have experienced the game’s transformation with the belief that
professionalisation has made a positive impact both on the development of the game and
on their own play. Financial reward is the most obvious impact on players. Their salary
has been on an upwards spiral since 1994, standing on a level that is many times higher
than that of the national average. Moreover, with improved overall commercial backing,
professionalisation provides more opportunities for players to gain international
experience. For example, clubs do not only recruit foreign players and coaches but are
also able to play more international tournaments and friendly matches. As Tao Wei
explains: (personal interview, 02/09/08)

“We play many pre-season international matches and post-season commercial


exhibitions. Furthermore, we play the AFC’s Champions League during season. Both
clubs and players have benefited from these opportunities. Professionalisation provides
more opportunities for us to experience international football, which helps to improve
our game’s competitiveness”.

Professionalisation has not only increased the quantity of international experience but has
also enriched playing style. During the pre-professional period, Chinese football accrued
international experience, accumulated mainly from playing the Soviet Bloc countries
(Liang 2003, Simons 2008). After professionalisation, Chinese football established links
and regular exchange programmes with countries from all over the world. Especially with
more advanced football nations in Europe and South America.

The professional leagues’ home-away formation provides regular opportunities for fans
to watch their own clubs at home, and more fans are able to access matches directly in
stadiums. As a result, the professional leagues are closely followed by a steadily
increased number of people week-in week-out compared to the pre-professional era. With

244
an increased fan-base, the game has a much broader social influence than the state
amateur model at both the national and the local levels.

7.4.2 The negative impact of professionalisation


Professionalisation has changed many aspects of the football industry significantly,
including the games’ integration of professional and amateur, the financial structure and
the labour market. Although the national playing standard has improved, it has made
relatively little progress compared to some neighbouring countries, especially at the top
level. For example: Korea and Japan have been making consistent appearances in the
Worlds Cup Finals since the 1990s, compared to China’s only one in 2002. Other points
of contention include the current unpromising overall football environment, the
commercial approach at the grass-roots level and the weakened cohesion between
different layers of development within the pyramid structure.

The commercial approach taken at the grass-roots level has raised the financial threshold
for children to participate in training sessions at football schools. Many parents are
reluctant to pay for their children to join, or simply cannot afford ‘the luxury’. As a result,
some talented children are priced out of the systematic training & selection structure that
marks the very beginning of a career in football. By contrast, children who do participate
in this system do not necessarily possess a talent for the game. As Tao Wei explains:
(personal interview, 02/09/08)

“I feel our academy players are worse than before, their maturity comes quite late and
ability-wise they are no better. They have been spoiled too much at home, which affects
their training attitude. Coaches are not better either, the money-oriented approach does
not help our grass-roots development”.

Furthermore, after witnessing the state of Chinese football after a few years of
professionalisation, many parents become more rational no longer see professional
football as a promising career for their children. Adding to this is the current birth control

245
policy, which leads to many children are spoiled, and also puts pressure on parents to not
allow their only child to take part in such a risky venture, as failure is not an option even
at an early age in Chinese culture. Yu Zhen – Fujian Junhao FC player expresses:
(personal interview, 30/09/2012)

“When I was younger, many of my friends back to home liked to play football. However,
they played only for fun and very few tried to pursue a football career like me. They were
not encouraged by their parents or even teachers. Apart from financial costs,
professional football is no longer considered as a proper career these days.”

Due to the twin aspects of the game – the sports aspect and commercialisation have not
been integrated as well as originally expected, which causes the selection system and the
development of grass-roots players to suffer from the market-driven approach, rather than
benefit from it. Having have lived through the fostering pyramid system, and being able
to observe the transition process, players see the failings of the system, and blame the
incompetence of the CFA’s governance. The fact is that the governing body places its
emphasis on the professional leagues. It has become more interested in making money
out of the game than in putting money into the development of a well-integrated and
balanced structure. As Tao Wei states in the same interview:

“Grass-roots development should be strategically planned to attracted as many young


kids as possible. The money-orientated market approach has been proven as a failure,
especially at the grass-roots level. We cannot afford to go on like this. The CFA should
come up with an alternative to not only can rebuild our football foundation, but also to
strength our professional game”.

Another negative aspect having arisen from professionalisation concerns players’


personal behaviour. Chinese players are not used to being managed passively. Compared
to players from Western nations, they are lacking in both professionalism and public
awareness. In the professional era, the relaxation of state control, the mobilised labour
market and their raised social profile did not help them to improve their weakness in their

246
self-discipline. As a result, players are often dragged into news headlines for all the
wrong reasons. Zhang Xiaobin explains: (personal interview, 05/07/08)

“Players should behave like professionals and consider themselves as role models for
youngsters. Bad behavior and negative images not only damage players’ reputation but
also damage the credibility of the game”.

Match-fixing, ‘black whistles’ and falsification of players’ ages are also recognised by
players as great threats to the game. The current anti-corruption movement led by the
state Police Department has resulted in a few high profile arrests, indicating that the
industry needs greater transparency and tighter regulations in order to withstand public
scrutiny and improve the game’s credibility from the harsh reality of the present. As Lu
Chang explains: (personal interview, 31/08/08)

“There is a long way to go to fight corruptions. Although the media is relatively open and
critical towards the game, it cannot criticise the government too much, especially with
regards to the number of age falsifications that were deliberately fabricated by local
officials. Laws and regulations have to be respected and severe punishment must be
handed to corrupted individuals without any excuse. That is the only way to reinstate
public confidence”.

7.5 The way forwards


As the game has been developed in a commercial way, the intertwined development of
the game’s sport and business aspects requires proper regulation in order to move the
game forwards.

In practice, at the grass-roots level, increased accessibility should be ensured with more
government funds in place to ease the financial burden of parents. There have been
suggestions made to include football in school’s curriculums, even though not every

247
school has enough space to accommodate the game properly. Lu Chang explains in the
same interview:

“Something has to be done to bring children back to the game. Pay-to-play is not the way
it should be. Grass-roots football needs to be supported more financially even under the
market economy, the CFA and the government should take more responsibility to support
grass-roots development”.

At the club academy level, on-field performance is over emphasised. Clubs need to take
on the full responsibility of developing their youth players comprehensively. A balanced
approach between study and training provides those young players who are not able to
break into the professional levels with a better preparation for their lives outside football
in the future.

At the professional level, more concerns are raised on how to protect the players’
interests. Players believe that they are powerless - one of the weakest links within the
industry. The legislative framework provided by the Labour Law and the Sports Law is
implicit, and too general to apply to players’ individual cases. Furthermore, third party
representation to provide professional services (e.g. agent, the players’ union) to players
would be a great improvement on the current situation. In a stakeholder society,
authorities need to address individuals’ rights better. Too much propaganda with too little
practice is not an ideal way to move the game forwards.

7.6 Summary
Professionalisation in Chinese football may have been introduced too quickly without
any proper development strategy. One could argue it was entirely justifiable - the reform
was led by crisis, and demanded by China’s top leaders. On the other hand, the CFA had
plenty of good examples to draw from. Such as European football – how the professional
game is governed.

248
Players are an important stakeholder group, as they are one of the main pillars of the
industry and have the most familiarity with the game’s transition. This chapter has
considered professionalisation through the players’ perspective to underpin the
theoretical framework – the stakeholder approach. The stakeholder analytical models are
intended to allow a clear understanding of players’ relationships with clubs and fans as
well as how they influence each other in different ways, which answers the related sub-
research question – how has increasing professionalism affected players? The
understanding of the stakeholder relationships within particular configurations can
provide predictions for strategic management in the form of “if-then” solution.

In the current Chinese social and political environments, professionalisation is unable to


adopt many of the desirable elements which exist in European football. Although Chinese
authorities and the CFA argue that the intertwined development of Chinese football
possesses its own unique characteristics, these Chinese characteristics do not meet the
demands of the modern industry practice, and this may well explain the slow progress of
the Chinese game.

Compared to the state amateur model, the Chinese football foundation has been
weakened by the process of professionalisation. For example, senior players are not
satisfied with the quality of younger players, who have made it to the professional level
through academy rankings. Furthermore, there are concerns over both availability and
quality of academy coaches, especially in those purely market-driven, privately owned
football schools.

Professionalisation has raised players’ awareness on the subject of their personal welfare
and financial rewards, especially in the case of players who possess overseas experience
and are willing to promote players’ interests both individually and collectively. However,
when considering Chinese players’ lack of professionalism and awareness of their social
obligations, one could say that the players’ social value has not been fully employed to
benefit the game’s development.

249
Chapter Eight: The Fans’ Perspective
Fans are an indispensable part of the game, and the extent to which they are included and
made meaningful stakeholders of a football club has been the focus of many debates. In
Europe, and in particular in the UK - the involvement of fans has been a topic of much
importance in both legislative and social contexts, with European fans becoming
progressively more involved in activities and initiatives of football development.

In China, although fan associations are receiving more attention from other stakeholders
when compared to those of the pre-professional era, their needs and activities are yet to
be thoroughly understood. This chapter will provide an analysis from the fans’
perspective, along with an examination of the country’s wider social background, cultural
influences and stakeholder relationships in order to further illustrate the impact of
professionalisation on the development of the game. It will also serve to provide a better
understanding of the specific characteristics of the Chinese football fan.

8.1 Fandom development


What is a fan? The term is not easy to define as there are many definitions available.
Fandom (noun fan affix – dom) is a term used to refer to a subculture composed of “fans”,
who are characterised by a feeling of sympathy and camaraderie with others sharing a
common interest.

Hills (2002, p.ix) suggests that “A fan is somebody who is obsessed with a particular star,
celebrity, film, TV programme, band; someone who can produce reams of information on
their object of fandom, and can quote their favoured lines or lyrics, chapter and verse”.

Sandvoss (2005, p8) defines fandom as “the regular, emotionally involved consumption
of a given popular narrative or text in the form of books, television shows, films or music,
as well as popular text in a broader sense such as sports teams, and popular icons and
stars ranging from athletes and musicians to actors”.

250
Finding a single definition of “fan” has proven difficult. As Hills (2002, p.xi) points out:
“Fandom is not simply a ‘thing’ that can be picked over analytically, being a fan is not
just a label or category, it is also an identity which is (dis-)claimed, and which performs
culture work”.

Despite the many definitions of what constitutes a fan, there is one constant: the interests
of a fan can be narrowly defined. Whether it be an individual celebrity, a hobby, specific
fashion or a sport, fans normally spend a considerable proportion of time, energy and
money on their object of interest, delving into minute detail, and, in extreme cases,
developing an interest which can grow to dominate their lifestyles. In the popular culture,
the word “fanbase” is normally used to refer the totality of fans devoted to a particular
area of interest, such as in the entertainment industry, and regardless those fans are
organised or not.

Sandvoss (2005) focuses his academic study of “fandom” on specific social and cultural
aspects of committed groups of fans and how they interact with institutions and
communities, rather than on the activities of individuals. Jones (2000a) argues that
individuals seek their social identities within these groups, and that one of the most
important social identities comes from groups of a larger scale, such as any identity
derived from basing itself on sports.

In terms of football, a club is a vehicle for its fans to share their experience, and to
express solidarity with their fellow fans. The Football Task Force (1999) recognises that
the football industry is fundamentally about the community and not the individual, and is
centred on a sense of shared emotional ownership. “Fan equity” is the term that has been
used (Salomon Brothers 1997, Hamil 1999) to describe the relationship between fans and
their football clubs within a commercial context. Fans associate themselves with clubs by
attending matches and buying merchandise, their consumption demonstrating loyalty,
emotion and shared identity, so making clubs into valuable as businesses and the game
into a lucrative industry (Hamil, 1999). Moreover, a fan’s loyalty rarely shifts regardless

251
their clubs performance. Winning is desirable but not a condition (at least not in the
short-term) for their support.

Hamil (1999) sees the fan/club relationship, or the characteristic of “fan equity”, as the
driving force behind the commercialisation of football, and believes that clubs have been
taking “fan equity” for granted.

Modern football was codified in England, where spectating always meant a highly
participatory role from the very beginning. Taylor (1992) points out that in the early days
of the game’s development, supporters were closely related to their clubs, with bonds
often based on personal friendship or locality. Membership not only gave access to
matches, but also involved fans in the running of their clubs. Football flourished in
England during 1870 – 1900, with thousands of local teams playing across the country. In
the early days of the professional era, football clubs often appealed for additional money
from local fans to cover their costs, and supporters could be encouraged to provide it on
an ad hoc basis (Morrow, 2003). From an historical point of view, without the active
engagement and generosity of the local community and fans, football could never have
spread so widely or grown such deep roots.

It has been proven that local support is essential for the existence of a football club. With
this in mind, although football as an industry needs to be managed as the business that it
is, it is inappropriate for clubs to be run with conventional governance techniques and
structure (Hamil 1999, Taylor Report 1990). Football fans deserve better treatment from
other stakeholders, particularly their clubs. The rampant commercialism and
overexploitation on “fan equity” damages the game’s link with the community as well as
the traditional values and fans’ emotional involvement.

8.2 Football fans in China

8.2.1 Fans in the pre-communist era


The modern game of football had been brought to China by British service men after the
Opium War, with Hong Kong being the first place where football was played in the

252
country. Matches were played between “scratch” teams made up of British personnel.
Spectators were mainly other British servicemen and the odd local. When the British
firmly established a settlement in Hong Kong, they introduced football into schools for
their own children (Twydell, 1994).

Football spread along the coastal cities of China during the period from the 1880s to
1890s. Despite the playing of football amongst locals having been encouraged by the
foreigners (especially missionary schools such as the YMCA), it was not until the 20th
century that the game was widely played in both missionary and local schools. As the
Chinese started to get to know the game better, football spread into wider society - from
schools to local communities, from the coast areas to the inland regions. Coastal cities
such as Shanghai and Tianjin became the leading football regions. In Shanghai - the
largest foreign settlement at the time, comprising of around 60,000 foreign residents -
different sport clubs were formed and competitions were organized (ibid). In 1887, the
FA committee (Shanghai city) decided football clubs had to separate from generic sport
clubs and became independent clubs (ibid).

By 1902, there were already football competitions taking place between different
universities in Shanghai, the most well-known being the annual meeting between St
John’s University and Nanyang University (ibid). As early as 1907, Shanghai had its first
league competition. College teams competed within the education sector and local clubs
competed within local leagues. By the early 20th century, most clubs represented
geographical locations and were rooted in their local communities. However, the game
remained very much dominated by foreigners at that time, especially by the English
speaking clubs. Hong Kong and Shanghai represented the highest standard of play in
Chinese football.

At the time, the fanbase was composed of college students and local populations
(including foreign settlers) who maintained connections with their local clubs. All
football clubs were of amateur status, and their membership was community-based.
Twydell (1994) recorded that to become a member of Shanghai FC, the only requirement

253
was a payment of a $5 membership fee. Within the same city league, there would be
clubs with an exclusively foreign membership, clubs with mixed foreign & Chinese
membership75, and clubs that were wholly made up of Chinese members.

The size of early crowds varied depending on the status of the competitions and venues,
with big occasions generating a great deal of interest. For instance, the “China-Scotland”
match in the 1926 International Cup in Shanghai (which was drawn 2-2) attracted a
crowd of 9,000 people. 10,000 people attended the following replay match (which
‘China’ lost 4-0). That same year, the football competition in the All China Games drew
over 20,000 spectators for the first match alone (ibid).

8.2.2 Fan development in the New China


During the Second World War, most football activities were suspended, as few cities had
any organised football competitions. When the Communist Party took power after the
Civil War, the way of organising football changed forever. As the Chinese establishment
adopted the Soviet governance model, city FAs were reorganised and were made a part of
local authorities. Under the new regime, sport development was regarded as part of the
planned economic system. As a result, football and other social activities were totally
planned by related government departments. The various local clubs of the pre-
communist era that had been based on the membership structure, and rooted in local
communities, disappeared – they were replaced by state-funded, work-union structured,
provincial/city elite teams. Football, at both national and local levels, was developed
according to planned government sport programmes.

Although, there had been over one hundred elite teams across the country in the middle
of the 1950s, rarely had two elite teams existed in the same city. Local leagues that
organised during the pre-communist era, no longer existed. As national league
competitions were organised in a round-robin championship format, it meant that few
teams had any real opportunity to play on their home grounds. In terms of accessibility to

75
Chinese elites and their family members were welcomed by foreign settlers, it was quite an international
atmosphere within settlements in coast cities.

254
high level matches, only fans in big cities (e.g. Beijing or Shanghai) had the opportunities
to watch matches in stadiums, as major national competitions and international friendly
matches were normally held in big cities. By contrast, fans from other places rarely had
the chance to watch either the national team or their local teams.

Under the planned economy, the elite teams were not dependent financially on the local
communities, and no direct linkages between the two parties. With no regular football
matches to offer locally, local fans did not consider any elite team as a part of their social
lives, therefore these elite teams became no different to other state-run work unions in
other industries. As a result, fans’ loyalty and emotional attachment to local football
teams suffered. The only connection between an ordinary local fan and an elite football
team was their common geographical identity without the fundamental social roots. The
Soviet-style governance model simply destroyed the strong community roots and local
connections that existed in the pre-communist era.

On one hand, the new infrastructure and centrally-planned football programmes were
efficient ways for the state to control the football development pattern and to lift the
playing standard in a short space of time following the Civil War; on the other hand, they
damaged links that existed between a local team and its community, and destroyed a
club’s traditional role as a social institution. The Soviet-style sport structure was not able
to maintain an optimal football environment for fans to thrive.

In the early days of the PRC, the low standard of economic development and tight state
control led to a monotonous social environment, whereas sport events, or any form of
entertainment, generated big social interest. Therefore football matches, in particular
international matches, were well-attended. In fact, many spectators went to the stadium to
enjoy football as a sporadic entertaining occasion rather than to show their support to the
teams. In addition, it was common practice for the government to order local work
unions’ employees or army soldiers to attend matches in order to create a better
atmosphere.

255
By the end of the 1970s, the Chinese government adopted the “Open Door” policy of
economic reform. Shortly after China rejoined FIFA in October 1979, the national team
played in the qualifiers of the 1982 World Cup. The team progressed well, generating
huge excitement across the country. All qualifying matches were broadcast on TV and
radio. Millions of people watched live coverage, and all seats for home matches in
Beijing were taken. Despite the Chinese national team failing to qualify at the last play-
off, the whole campaign was followed by millions of people, many of whom eventually
became real football fans. During the qualifying process, football established itself as the
most influential sport in the country, and fans’ expectations were further increased by the
1984 Asian Cup Finals, where the Chinese team finished as the runner-up.

Fans’ high expectations were dashed by the national team’s performance in May 1985
when China suffered an unexpected defeat to Hong Kong at the group stage of the World
Cup qualifying campaign. Fans from Beijing gathered around the stadium smashed 28
cars belonging to foreign diplomats and reporters, which led to 127 arrests, five of them
being subsequently sentenced (Dong & Mangan, 2001). This incident, remembered as the
‘May 19th event’, has been described as the most serious riot in Chinese football history
(Hua, 2004). The event generated a huge social debate, and shocked the Chinese
government, which was used to well-behaved spectators. When the dust gradually died
down, fan development entered a different phase.

Fans started to organise themselves, and several fan organisations emerged, among which
were the Shenyang Fans Association, Chongqing Fans Association, Anshan Fans
Association (all founded in 1986) and the Chengdu Fans Association (founded in 1987)
(ibid). From that point on, fan associations began to sprout across the country, many of
them based in cities that did not even have a local elite team participating in national
leagues.

The Chinese government has always been sensitive about non-governmental


organisations. It is not prepared to tolerate any organisation which harbours any potential
threat to challenge its authority. Fan associations certainly have this kind of potential, as

256
they have the ability to incite crowds into mass eruption. Hua (2004) argues that the
initial tolerance of the creation of fan associations was the government’s attempt to allow
those fan associations to organise their members in order to prevent the spontaneous
breakout of riots like the ‘May 19 th Event’ in the future. In fact, the actual statistics
showed that more violent incidents occurred across the country after the establishment of
the first fan associations than any time since 1986. Despite the increasing trend of
football-related social disturbances, fan associations have been accepted by authorities as
one means of helping to organise football fans.

8.3 Fan culture


Let us look at the development process of the fans’ movement in China. The earlier
model of the pre-communist era was similar to that of the European fan movement; local
fans closely attached to their local clubs, and the fan culture based on social links, plus
the concept of community loyalty. Most competitions were organised at local level,
although there being some ad hoc inter-city tournaments, a national league did not exist.

When the Communist Party assumed power, the government took a controlling role in
building both the national economy and people’s social lives. Under planned institutions,
football no longer played a significant role in communal affairs. Although elite teams still
represented their geographical locations, the original club names of these district
associations were replaced by regional names of covering wider geographical areas. In
addition, elite teams did not depend on financial support or emotional loyalty from local
communities to survive, therefore they showed no interest in maintaining the traditional
relationships with locals, even though most provincial teams “represented” regions with
millions of residents. The community-based club model was destroyed along with its
cultural tradition.

China’s social and economic systems were based on Marxist ideology, and sport was
used as an effective tool to not only build strong national unity and further a sense of
patriotism, but also to demonstrate confidence in the advantages of a socialist approach

257
and deliver hope for the renaissance of the Chinese nation (Kolatch, 1972). The concept
of patriotic emotion is another distinctive feature of Chinese fan culture. Fans always
closely follow the national team. On one hand, it can be put down to the strong influence
of nationalist propaganda used by authorities - sport and football have been used as a
political tool to bond people together in order to foster socialist collectivism and national
pride (Clumpner & Pendleton, 1978); on the other hand, the lost relationship between
fans and local elite teams resulted in an opportunity for the national team to fill the
emotional gap. Furthermore, the national team has always been easier to follow than the
provincial teams, with good media coverage giving it the edge in generating interest
across the country.

8.3.1 Fans’ attachment to clubs


The Chinese national team has always been passionately supported throughout the
country, in part due to the Soviet-style top-down sport model, which exercises a good
elite fostering system and a tendency to positively-developed nationalism. At the local
level, fans’ connection with elite teams is mainly based on a geographical identity and
personal passion for the game, rather than community links or clubs’ traditional values.
This characteristic is quite a contrast to European fan culture - which is based on clubs’
traditional values and community connections. Giulianotti (2002, cited by Morrow 2003)
observes that traditional fans have a long, more localised and popular cultural
identification with a club, with loyalty indicating an intense kind of solidarity and
identification with the club. The “Club is a living symbol for its fans and their identities
and supporters have emotional ties to the club’s ground and to its community
significance” (Morrow, 2003, p51).

By contrast, the state-owned elite teams lack both traditional values and social
connections with locals. In this case, a fan’s attachment to a team is based solely on a
sense of geographical identification. It is not difficult to understand that Chinese clubs do
not possess the strong symbolic status in their local communities that most European
clubs enjoy. As a result, fans are not deeply attached to the club that they support and

258
their loyalty is relatively weak. Such insights were highlighted by some personal
interviews (4th July, 2008) with Hu Ge, President of Changsha Red Pepper Fan
Association, illustrates this phenomenon:

“We support Ginde FC, only because it represents our city and our province. Before
Ginde moved to Changsha, we supported Xiangjun FC76. We support any club as long as
it represents Changsha city or Hunan province”.

In another personal interview with Mr Yuan Qiyou, Chariman of Jiangsu Sainty Yuanyou
Fan Association on 7th July 2008, Mr Yuan states:

“We love football first, then we love our hometown football. We always support Jiangsu
football. Sainty FC has been established more than eight years, Jiajia FC and Maint FC
represented Jiangsu province during 96-00 and 94-95, respectively. Before Sainty FC, we
supported them too, as long as a football club can represent our province, we can be its
fans”.

Mr Yuan Haishan, the President of Henan Jianye Football Fan Union states (personal
interview 09/07/08):

“Our motivations are driven by football fever, football first, and then hometown football,
we have passion for the game, that is why we support our hometown club.”

Those interviews provide insights to demonstrate that how Chinese fan culture is
different to that of European ones, in which traditional value and community links play a
significant role. When comparing the two, supporters’ attitudes towards their clubs,
motivation, solidarity and emotional attachment are at entirely different levels. Moreover,
due to the lack of common value between fans and a particular club, a fan can
simultaneously support all local clubs, as their loyalty is interchangeable. This kind of
behaviour is common amongst Chinese fans across the country, if one city has two or

76
Dissolved after 2006 season.

259
more football clubs, fans normally support them all. However, the bigger club with a
longer history may have some advantage. As Mr Yuan Qiyou, Chariman of Jiangsu
Sainty Yuanyou Fan Association stated (personal interview, 07/07/08):

“Although we are fans of Sainty FC, we still go to Yoyo’s77 matches to cheer for them as
they represent our city too. During derby matches, of course we support Sainty FC. I
think that provincial football is bigger than city football, in this case, despite being from
Nanjing city, I stand by Sainty FC, it represents Jiangsu province.”

Mr. Meng Ran, the President of Beijing Green Storm Fan Association highlights this in
an interview (07/08/08):

“We support both local teams as they all represent Beijing City. If there is a derby
match78, we may support Guoan FC more as it has longer history and bigger influence,
however, we do hope Hongden FC performs well”.

The fan/club relationship can be explained like so - fans love the game first, and have a
secondary attachment to their hometown or provincial clubs. Chinese fans’ attitude
towards local rivals is astonishing in the eyes of European fans - there is no way for an
Everton fan to support Liverpool, or a Manchester City fan to support Manchester United.
Compared to European fan culture, Chinese fans and clubs lack common traditional
values and community links, and this has led to weaker fan loyalty. Although the
common concept of geographic identity is deeply rooted, fans’ sense of football tradition
and emotional involvement are simple. Mr Sun Zhimin – President of Shenzhen Fan
Association concludes (personal interview, 20/07/13):

“We follow all three clubs in Shenzhen, not particularly closer to anyone of them.
However, derby matches are exciting and there are inspirational stories, the tales that

77
Yoyo FC is a Jia League club and represents Nanjing city. Nanjing is the capital city of Jiangsu province.
78
Beijing Guoan FC plays in Super League, Beijing Hongden FC plays in the Jia League, where derbies
can happen in cup competitions.

260
make you feel pride to be involved in such occasions beyond a particular favourite
team.”

Both Hamil (1999) and Salmon Brother (1997) mentioned that irrational ‘fan equality’ is
a different cultural asset. In the Chinese culture, ‘fan equality’ is the loyalty a fan shows
more towards the game and their geographical identity than any loyalty to a club or its
heritage. This is a characteristic which is very important for other stakeholders to
understand, especially for those investors and foreign clubs who are interested in
exploring the Chinese football market. A football club can win local support easily in
China as long as it represents the region and plays football. For it to forge strong social
links based on shared values and to foster real fan loyalty however, is a different story.
Bringing fans into stadiums week in and week out is a huge challenge for all Chinese
clubs. Developing a successful football club based on a sustainable business model
requires good vision and an appropriate strategy, and, more importantly, a long-term
commitment and professional knowledge of the industry.

Although at a club level, Chinese fan loyalty is ‘misplaced’, at the national level, fans are
quite patriotic. The national team has always been well-supported throughout the country,
regardless of its results. As the most popular sport, football has been used as a vehicle to
deliver communist values, self-assertiveness and national pride. Fans’ emotional
involvement and commitment are at highest during international matches; victories
intensify national pride amongst Chinese people, and by contrast, defeats bring huge
disappointment. The strong ‘fan equity’ in the national team cannot be simply evaluated
by considering traditional community links. As the former national team manager Klaus
Schlappner said: “China has no top level players, but has top level fans.” (Dong &
Mangan, 2001, p90).

8.4 The Fan/club relationship


Hunt (et al 1999) classifies five different types of sport fans: the temporary fan, the local
fan, the devoted fan, the fanatical fan and the dysfunctional fan. They suggest that each

261
different type of fan has a different type of motivation and behavior. Dolles & Soderman
(2005) propose a different dimension, and identify two types of fan in modern football:
local fans and international fans - local fans having close geographic connections, and
international fans being based abroad. In reality, only a few big clubs and high profile
national sides have international fans, such as Manchester United, the Brazilian national
team. In terms of Chinese football, local fans are the only fan base for clubs to explore.
Eaves (et al, 2003) divide Chinese fans into three broad categories: professional elder
fans, young affluent urban fans and female fans. Despite his classification being based on
a national survey undertaken by one of the biggest Chinese sport newspapers, the survey
ignored fans’ geographical identities. Moreover, the survey only identified fans
individually, not collectively as organised associations.

In terms of social influence, fan organisations possess more strength than individual fans.
Although different fan organisations have different needs according to their structures,
they provide a formal entity for individuals to promote their interests collectively; the
legitimate rights and demands of fans can be enhanced by fan orgnisations. As Morrow
(2003, p52) quoted from Michie & Ramalingam (1999), fan organisations offer
individuals the opportunity “to transform the power of their voice from one that can be
heard to one that is listened to”.

The relationship between clubs and fans seems straightforward - fans support their clubs
and clubs need fans’ support to develop their business. This relationship, however, is not
as clear-cut as it seems. It is not only individual fans who can be categorised, in this study,
fan associations are also sub-categorised according to their different organisational
models. The next section analyses the fan association/club relationship for two forms of
fan associations - an independent position, and a dependent position. It primarily focuses
on local fan associations and extends to how they maintain their organisational structures
and manage their relationships with local clubs.

262
8.4.1 The dependent position
Fan associations bloomed in the 1980s, when football fans voluntarily formed their own
associations throughout the country as independent non-governmental organisations,
which were then eventually sanctioned by the government (Hua 2004). Alongside
commercial development of the football industry and further professionalisation, clubs
realised that fan associations possessed both social and economic values which could
contribute to their long-term success. With business in mind, clubs gradually established
direct contacts with their local fan associations. For example, some clubs set up fan
departments to develop effective communications; some clubs even formed their own fan
associations.

Similar to football clubs, fan associations are ritually identified with a geographic
location and are associated with certain territories. Although the majority of fan
associations maintain an independent status, fan associations under the leadership of a
particular football club still exist, and now even more clubs intend to form their own fan
associations. A dependent fan association is under the leadership of the club, and its
actions largely follow the club’s instructions. “Explicit contracts” exist between the two
parties, due to the fact that they have the same goals under the same framework of being
a Club Company. As a result, their relationship can be classified as Necessary
Compatible. Figure 8-1 shows the relationship between a dependent fan association and
its club. This relationship was explained by Mr Yuan Qiyou, Chariman of Jiangsu Sainty
Yuanyou Fan Association (personal interview, 07/07/08):

“We, the fan association, have our own regulations and a management team which
includes a Vice-Chairman, a Secretary, and an Accountant. We are, however, under the
leadership of the club. Furthermore, we have good access to club management, players
and coaching staff.

263
Contingent Necessary
Compatible ▲ ◙

Incompatible

◙ The dependent fan association/club relationship


▲The independent fan association/club relationship

Figure 8-1 The fan associations/clubs relationship

The Necessary Compatible relationship forms effective communication channels between


clubs and fan associations, allowing fan associations to pass their suggestions or
criticisms to both club management and playing staff easily. As Mr Yuan explains further:

“The voice of our association can reach to top management. For example, I am able to
see the club’s CEO often, we can discuss issues informally in places like the staff canteen,
and formal meetings can also be arranged. In addition, we have a very good relationship
with playing staff at both personal and professional levels. However, the good
relationship does not prevent our criticism over their performance. We can go to the
training base to express our views to playing staff.

In terms of financial dependency, despite the fact that dependent fan associations have
their own financial income through membership fees, their operations heavily rely on
their clubs’ financial support. This dependence entails an asymmetrical involvement:
such associations need clubs monetarily, not the other way around. On the one hand,
some association members enjoy clubs’ subsidies to attend matches; on the other hand,
they need to serve clubs’ interests. For example, when preparing stands for other fans and
the association band before kick-off, moreover, they are required to chant in unison. As
Mr Yuan explains in the same interview:

“It is free for us to go to home matches. Some members can go to away matches with
costs paid for by the club. All members go to an away match with subsidies (e.g. ¥20

264
lunch fee, drummers get ¥50). The club arranges transport for nearby away matches free
of charge and even pays for key members’ flights to go to long-distance away matches.
From the association point of view, we are not in stadiums to simply attend matches and
cheer our team on, it is also a great responsibility and obligation to show our support”.

Figure 8-2 also shows the relationship between a dependent fan association and its club
from a resource dependency perspective. The continuation of the association relies
greatly on financial support from the club; by contrast, the level of a club’s financial
dependency on its fan association is very low. The result, as shown in the figure below
determines their financial dependency, the relationship of the two parties at the status of
D – giving the club great power over its fan association.

Level of clubs’ financial dependence on fan associations


(High)
A B

Level of fan
associations (Low) (High)

depend on the clubs ▲ ◙


C D

A: Fan power (Indirect/usage) (Low)


B: High interdependence (Direct/usage) ◙ The dependent fan association/club relationship
C: Low interdependence (Indirect/withholding) ▲The independent fan association/club relationship
D: Club power (Direct/withholding)

Figure 8-2 The fan association/club relationships

A dependent association, on the one hand, has good communication channels with its
club; on the other hand, its inferior position and financial dependence limits its influence
over club governance. In fact, clubs are in a very strong position to dominate this
relationship. As Mr Yuan admitted in his interview, his fan association has to follow the
club’s instructions, even if it conflicts with their own wishes – “Our advice can be

265
adopted if the club considers it to be valuable, regardless of the outcome, we have to
accept the club’s decision, as the club leads us”.

Despite the limited impact of the dependent associations’ involvement in the club’s
decision-making, this relationship provides effective communications between the two
parties. Financial subsidies play an important role in this particular type of fan/club
relationship. It enables a club to attract more supporters to join its fan group, however,
such subsidies are difficult to maintain within a mature market environment, especially
on a large scale, and this introduces doubts over clubs’ long-term financial sustainability.
Arguably, the tactic of using subsidies can therefore only be employed as a temporary
measure and cannot be maintained in the long term.

8.4.2 The independent position


The majority of fan associations are independent organisations that are financially
autonomous. These associations deal directly with individual fans and their clubs. As
most Chinese clubs play under regional names and normally represent provinces, they
need to deal with the different fan associations within the same provincial boundaries79
that support the same club. To add to this, some of these associations, from different
provincial locations, voluntarily formed a fan union under the same club banner.

Figure 8-1 also shows the relationship between an independent fan association and its
club. They are separate organisations that exist without explicit contracts between them.
Despite sharing only external links, the two parties have one major goal in common –
building a successful club. Therefore, their relationship status can be referred to as being
Contingently Compatible.

Despite fan associations supporting their local clubs within the Compatible structure, the
actual relationship varies according to their size, location and their clubs’ perception and
policies. This research finds that independent fan associations describe their interactions

79
The average size of a Chinese province is similar to the size of Great Britain in terms of both population
and geographical area.

266
with clubs as three types of relationships – the close relationship, the distant relationship
and the partnership.

The close relationship possesses efficient communication in both directions. Clubs and
associations coordinate their efforts during business practices in order to develop
simultaneously and derive benefit from that coordination. This relationship was explained
by Mr. Meng Ran, the President of Beijing Green Storm Fan Association (personal
interview, 07/08/08):

“We have efficient contact with the club (Beijing Guoan FC). I can call club management
anytime, the club also call us to discuss (or for meetings) related issues (e.g. crowd
control and ticket distribution). In particular they consulted us about this season’s price
increase, as they qualified for the AFC’s Champions’ League. As a result, seasonal
tickets still work out much cheaper for our members, and that helped us to increase our
membership this year. Moreover, our close relationship is also based on the business
aspect the club has approved us to sell club merchandise”.

The statement demonstrates that the fan association participates in some of its club’s
business operation, and there are well maintained communication mechanisms between
the two parties. From the stakeholder theoretical point of view, fan association’s
normative legitimate claims are respected and considered in the club’s decision-making
process.

By contrast, a distant relationship provides for less efficient communication – mostly


one-way traffic of information from clubs. Although clubs acknowledge the necessity of
maintaining a compatible relationship with local fan associations, they do not take the
extra care or measures to manage the ‘special’ relationship with these associations. Mr.
Yu Fuzhi, Vice Chairman of Changchun Fan Association explains the distant relationship
with Changchun Yatai FC (personal interview, 01/08/08):

267
“The club doesn’t treat the association as an important stakeholder. We feel that they
treat us the same way as they would do to any other organisations or individuals, which
makes it hard for us to recruit members. Of course, they welcome our support during
football matches and other social events. Nevertheless, they seem not to care much about
how strong our support is. The price of seasonal tickets has risen 100% this season80
without consulting us – making it the most expensive in the country. Even though we try
our best to support our club by any means, we don’t feel the club appreciates our efforts
very much. The dialogue between the club and us is symbolic – they have no senior
managers to deal with us.”

Mr Yu feels his association has not been treated fairly. The communication channel with
the club does not exist for them. It is a typical behavior form a stakeholder relationship
status of low dependency/low centrality, therefore, club’s normative claims are simply
ignored.

The partnership relationship consists of clubs and associations communicating and


coordinating for mutual benefit. In this partnership, both coordination and conflicts may
occur according to how each party’s interests align over particular issues at particular
times. There is effective communication between the two parties, who not only share
information but also strive to understand each other’s opinions. Mr Sun Changlong,
President of Shenyan Fan Association - the first fan association formed in China to see
‘partnership’ as the best word to describe their relationship with Liaoning FC explains
(personal interview, 30/07/08):

“We coordinate with the club over many events. The club needs us for its business
development (as fans have been seen as part of football product in the market economy)
and we need football as a platform to grow, it is a reciprocal synergy. Although the
interests of the club and the association do not always go in the same direction, we are
trying to understand each other’s positions and to work accordingly for mutual benefit.
Furthermore, we hold our own press conference regularly, and have also bought regular

80
Yatai FC won the Super League in 2007 and qualified for AFC’s Champions’ League in the 2008 season.

268
TV times to broadcast our own programmes in order to make our voice louder and more
influential towards the club”.

Despite each of the three types of relationship between fan associations and their clubs
having their own individual characteristics, they have one common ground - it is the
associations’ financial independency. These fan associations’ exist and operations do not
depend on their clubs monetarily, and vice versa. Therefore, the relationship between an
independent fan association and its club is of Low Interdependence, as shown in Figure
8-2. The Low Interdependence relationship suggests fan associations could try the
indirect withholding strategy in order to force issues. An example of this is Shenyang Fan
Association’s use of media (buying broadcasting time from local TV stations) as an
effective tool, not only to generate more widely appeal to society, but also to gain extra
weight and influence in its relationship with Liaoning FC.

Unlike most individual independent fan associations, some associations within the same
province voluntarily formed a fan union. A fan union is a collection of associations - its
memberships consist not of individuals, but of different fan associations within the same
provincial boundaries. Each member of the fan union consists of a large amount of
individual fans throughout the province. Despite a fan union being a collection of
relatively loose organisations, its members have one collective voice. As Mr Yuan
Haishan, the President of Henan Jianye Football Fan Union explains (personal interview,
09/0708):

“We are a union that consists of 33 association members. Each of them operates
independently in their own area. We hold elections at the annual congress, where
representatives from all members elect a President of the union and board members.
Currently we have 13 board members who work collaboratively on different areas. For
important issues, we make decisions collectively within a democratic process”.

As local fan associations are different in size and in their ability to influence clubs, a fan
union, as a well-organised society, increases fans’ influence by giving them an even

269
bigger unanimous voice. A fan union is therefore powerful in terms of social influence.
Keeping this in mind, clubs will acknowledge a union’s influence and are happy to work
with the union over both social and developmental issues. As Mr Yuan further explains,
the case of Jianye Fan Union:

“The club has improved their relationship with the fans since we formed a union. We are
now able to organize for fans from different areas to meet players. Moreover, the club
provides us with an office and union leaders can use all the facilities like other club
administration staff. Because we have a limited income, the club subsidizes partial wages
of all 13 board members. This indicates that the club treats us as an important
stakeholder. In addition, good communication channels are in place, our views can be
expressed at regular and irregular meetings with club management, responses from the
club are normally quick”.

The constitution of a fan union as a whole has enhanced network ‘density’. Compared to
that of individual fan associations, the structure of a fan union provides a more efficient
connection amongst its members. Links amongst member associations become denser,
and information flows more freely. As a result, a fan union possesses more influence and
power than a single association or individual fans. It is more resistant towards other
stakeholders, including the club it supports. Figure 8-3 shows this relationship.

Fan association density


(High)
Club’s ▲High Density/High Centrality▲
(Low) (High)
Centrality ◙ Low Density/High Centrality

(Low)
◙ Individual fan associations/clubs relationship
▲ Fan union/club relationship

Figure 8-3 Fan associations’ influences towards clubs

270
Generally speaking, clubs hold more power in the industry, and in the fan/club
relationship, clubs are in a dominant central position. Fan associations, as opposed to the
club they represent, are less influential, and maintain a less central position, especially as
an individual association without close/dense links with other stakeholders. Knowing this,
the association/club relationship is one of Low Density/High Centrality. By contrast, the
fan union structure possesses efficient internal communication links, which create
coordination and the possibility of collective and unanimous action amongst union
members. The fan union as a whole, with its enhanced orgnisational density, enjoys a
different status in its relationship with a club, which can be described as High
Density/High Centrality.

In the High Density/High Centrality position, a fan union is capable of influencing a club
in many ways. According to both the institutional theory and resources dependent theory,
“organisational decision makers have a strong preference for certainty, stability and
predictability” (Oliver, 1991, p170). Therefore, a club is friendlier towards a fan union,
and is more likely to adopt an inclusive approach and willingness to compromise and
negotiate a mutually satisfactory position with a fan union. Jianye’s case demonstrates
this relationship. Just as Mr Yuan states in the same interview:

“We meet club’s top management to discuss many issues, such as crowd control, or the
price of seasonal tickets. Although the club is the one to make the final decision, our
opinions are respected and we do get feedback and explanation afterwards”.

According to Mr Yuan, the Jiaye Fan Union is included in some forms of decision-
making processes. It shows that fan organisations can make a certain impact on club
governance through good organisation. However, when a fan union takes financial
subsidies, especially in the case of board members who are partially paid by its club, just
like in the case of the Jiaye Fan Union, it raises concerns over the union’s “true
independence” and a possible conflict of interest. Furthermore, a fan union does not

271
consist of individual fans. It is therefore questionable how effective a fan union is in
terms of representing the needs of individual fans.

In short, professionalisation has changed the nature of the fan/club relationship. As clubs
adopt industrial practices with increased business awareness, fan associations are
gradually being acknowledged as an important stakeholder group, even though their
direct financial contribution towards clubs is still at a low level. Under the market
economy, clubs cannot afford to ignore fans’ demands completely, even in a distant
fan/club relationship fans are still a part of football product, which is marketed as a whole.
Indeed, efforts have been made by both clubs and fan associations in order to understand
one other, and the once alienated fan/club relationship that existed in the pre-professional
era has moved much closer together since the advent of professionalisation,

Good communication in both directions is one of the key elements for building a close
fan/club relationship. It can improve mutual understanding, especially when both parties
are pursuing compatible goals. By contrast, a distant relationship with inefficient
communication creates more conflicts between a club and its fan associations. This
distance can cause dissatisfaction amongst fans, which undermines their support for the
club. Moreover, it discourages fans’ initiative and therefore jeopardizes the club’s long-
term financial resources and the promise of sustainable development.

Despite improvements made to the nature of the relationship, fan associations in general
have limited influence over club governance, and especially lack involvement in a club’s
decision-making process. A dependent fan association has the least influence over club
governance and can contribute little to club developmental issues during the decision-
making process. Independent fan associations have various ranges of relationship with
their clubs in terms of closeness. Although they may still lack influence over club
governance, some of them are able to pursue their interests more actively and effectively
by using different strategies. For instance, by using a third party, or forming an alliance.

272
As for club subsidies, on one hand, they help fan associations to develop themselves and
encourage fan participation; on the other hand, they reduce an associations’ independence
and cast doubt on who it is they represent.

The fan union structure has been managed using a proactive approach, which
demonstrates that fans have a desire to get more involved in the game, not only as
spectators but also as an important stakeholder, especially at the club governance level. It
demonstrates that fan associations can be developed to be more influential as a
meaningful stakeholder group. With the right approach, and with appropriate managerial
skills and strategies, their voices are not only just for others to hear, but should be
listened to. Being listened to, as opposed to merely being heard, can become a metaphor
for being understood and being valued.

The following section unveils how professionalisation has been perceived by fan
associations.

8.5 The fans’ perception of the football industry


Under a planned economy, football existed purely as a sport. The specialised elite teams
relied on the state budget, and fans had limited opportunities to watch their local teams.
In this situation, the fan/team relationship was distant, with no inter-relationship between
the two parties. This meant that Chinese fans were presented as self-disciplined, and
caused very little trouble, and in many selected matches and events, spectators had been
instructed to attend by the government (Hua, 2004). In reality, fans were lacking in their
own initiative and awareness, and did not know any better ways to express their demands
and opinions.

The real change came after the ‘May 19th Event’, when the government adopted a
different approach towards crowd control, which allowed fan associations to prosper
across the country. Today, fan associations are one of the few real non-governmental
organisations in China, many of which have consolidated their positions in their

273
respective regions. Although different associations have different structures and operate
in various forms, they undertake almost the same activities (e.g. organising travel,
distributing tickets). More importantly, the government and clubs see them as strong
allies to tackle sport-related social disorder.

8.5.1 The governance structure


Despite improved governance and a more inclusive approach at the professional level, the
current structure of the CFA has been heavily criticised by fans. The two different
governance functions (the external function as the CFA which is a member of FIFA, and
the internal function as the CFMC under the leadership of SGSA) of the governing body
have conflicting goals, as its political interests conflict with the modern industry practice
under the market economy. FIFA’s rule clearly states that its member associations cannot
be interfered with by political powers in the running of the governing bodies. The
President of the CFA is appointed by the Chinese government, and its politically-led
causes and shortsighted practices harm the game’s development in a long term. Mr Yuan
Haishan, the President of Henan Jianye Football Fan Union points out (personal
interview 09/07/08):

“The CFA is one organisation with two different faces. In fact, under the market economy,
more political interference harms football development. As we can see, the CFA officials
are short-sighted, especially on youth development, as all leaders of the CFA have one
thing in common – focusing on the national team and sacrificing youth development,
because good results from the national team can lead to their own personal promotion”.

The top CFA officials are appointed by the government, and do not have the patience to
work on grass-roots development. Furthermore, the dual roles of the governing body do
not fit the purpose of modern football development, which may explain the failure of the
academy system after professionalisation. The CFA carries the banner of sport reform,
however, the politically-led reform promoted an unbalanced approach and short-sighted
practices towards youth development, which undermined the old fostering system. For

274
example, the well-designed Soviet style cohesion amongst different development layers
was destroyed. This, coupled with a lack of strategic planning in the process of
professionalisation, has resulted in the weakening of the foundation of Chinese football
and the decline of the national team’s FIFA ranking. Mr Sun Changlong, President of
Shenyan Fan Association explains (personal interview 30/07/08):

“Despite professionalisation being a step forward compared to the state amateur model,
the gap has widened between us and our neighboring countries (e.g. Japan, Korean). The
governance system seems improved in terms of an European-like package and
commercial development, however, the improvement cannot be fully justified by the
results on the international stage”.

The football reform focuses on professionalisation, the commercial approach, and market
development, which leaves youth development in a shambolic state - with ‘no financial
support’; ‘no policy’; ‘no development strategy’; ‘no regulation’ and ‘no effective
management’. Many football schools pursue a short-term financial gain rather than well-
planned, long-term sustainable development. Once the cash flow dries up, schools have
no options but to close. As Mr Sun explains further in the same interview:

“At the beginning of professionalisation, there were many football schools competing for
students, and now, 90% are closed. The CFA and local FA did not have clear visions and
appropriate measures from the very beginning, and weak regulations coupled with an
overly-commercial approach wasted our limited resources and cost us the academy
system”.

Football schools are not strictly regulated, many of their coaching staff and equipment are
not up to standard. Most schools are extremely money-orientated and lack a long-term
development strategy. This phenomenon was also pointed out by Hu Ge, President of
Changsha Red pepper Fan Association (personal interview, 04/07/08):

275
“Football schools are expensive, only kids from rich families can afford to attend, which
sends the wrong signal to society. It is the governance failure after professionalisation”.

Mr Ma Jianming, the former Director of the Youth Department of the CFA summarised
the unhealthy development trend: “There were more than 1,000 football schools across
the country at the beginning of professionlisation, in fact, most of them could not satisfy
the basic requirement as a football school, few of them can be self-sustained, the situation
is not promising” (Ran, 2008a). By 2000, there were only 84 football schools registered
with the CFA, with 37,051 amateur (so called youth players) players; by 2007, there were
only 56 football schools registered with 13,524 youth players (ibid).

Necessity aligned interests

Financial dependency level of

academy/football schools (Low ) (High)

on the state

▄ The development trend of academy

Contingent diverse interests

Figure 8-4 The development pattern of the clubs/country relationship

Figure 8-4 shows the development trend at an academy level. Before prfessionalisation,
all football schools were owned by the state and relied fully on the state investment. In
the Soviet structure both the state and all football schools had aligned interests. When the
state budget was reduced, football schools were forced to adopt the market approach,
coupled with the emergence of private schools in the market, the aligned interest was
diversified along with reduced funding. Private schools especially can adopt the market
approach more aggressively even without satisfying basic requirements. For some of
them, making a profit is more interesting than developing football.

276
Due to lack of long term strategy and regulation to develop the grass-roots market in a
sustainable manner, the foundation of the football pyramid has been damaged, which in
turn affected professional clubs and the national team at the top level. The fact is
demonstrated by the gradually widening gap between the performance of Chinese teams
and its neighboring counties on the international stage.

8.5.2 Fans’ impression of players


Fans consider Chinese players are not professional enough. Professionalisation brought in
the Western style league formation but failed to adopt its professionalism and managerial
mechanisms. Despite much-improved salaries and increased social profile, most players
failed to meet their new responsibilities both as professional footballers and role models
for young people. Players have been accused of lacking even minimal professional ethics
(Bristow, 2008), which has raised concern over their behavior.

This problem has been highlighted again by a fight on the pitch between players of the
two top clubs during a league match81, and more recently in the 2010 National Games
qualification, when four players were punished for chasing referees. One of these players
was banned for life for his part in the incident. A combination of high salaries and a lack
of discipline has caused a negative image, which damages the game’s credibility. As Mr
Yuan Haishan points out (personal interview, 09/07/08):

“Look at news about players, can you see anything positive? Gambling, drinking,
fighting etc, which reflect the overall governance standard. The managerial competence
at both the CFA and club levels is questionable, they are not professional enough - the
old style management does not answer new questions”.

Match attendance had a promising start in 1994, when the Jia A League attracted over
20,000 spectators per match. However, negative incidents damaged the credibility of both

81
League match between Beijing Guan FC and Tianjin Taida FC on 16th Nov, 2008.

277
players and the game, and, 14 years on, with ongoing scandals, attendance has declined.
Due to the many negative images generated by Chinese football82, the CCTV stopped
broadcasting league matches in November 2008 (ibid).

Indeed, professional football is experiencing more difficulties than ever before.


According to Hu Ge, the President of Changsha Red Pepper Fan Association (personal
interview, 04/07/08):

“Despite being in the JiaB League at the beginning of professionlisation, it was very
hard to get a ticket. The stadium was so full every time the club played that even plants
around stadium died on match days (people stepped on them). Now we are playing in the
top league, attendance is only 8,000-10,000 per match, and many spectators get free
tickets. The playing standard has improved, however, the overall football environment
has declined”.

Mr Sun Changlong, President of Shenyan Fan Association, expressed a similar


experience relating to the decline (personal interview, 30/07/08):

“When the professional league first started, tickets were in short supply. You really had
to know someone in order to get a ticket. With the increasingly commercialised approach,
the football market became sloppy. We have had discussions amongst our members about
this sloppiness, and we do not think the playing standard has dropped, actually, the game
has become more competitive. The partial explanation for this may be increased
availability of other entertainment - people have far more choices now, and football
needs to compete for spectators. Moreover, players’ bad examples, corruption and bad
results from the national team also affect the football market severely”.

Figure 8-5 indicates that the average match attendance soared immediately after
professionalisation, especially in the first three years, where it was improving every

82
CCTV broadcasted the last two rounds of the 2009 Super League, and live coverage resumed in the 2012
season.

278
season. Although the attendance dropped after 1996, it maintained the 20,000 per match
mark up until 2000. The Jia A League did not design relegation for the 2001 season, and
in the following 2002 season neither promotion or relegation were designed by the CFA,
coupled with widely speculated ‘black whistles’ on the field, the attendance plunged to
under the 15,000 per match mark. Despite the CFA’s clean-up efforts, attendance did not
improve much in the 2003 season. The ‘G-7’ event and other scandals combined with the
CFA’s unprofessional practices imprinted on the inauguration of the Super League, and
match attendance remained at a low of just over the 10,000 mark for three consecutive
seasons. When the AFC was preparing to re-launch its reconstructed Champions
League83 in 2008, the 2007 season provided an opportunity for clubs to maximise their
performance in order to qualify on the continental stage. As clubs had more incentive to
play well, attendance picked up.

30000

25000

20000

15000

10000

5000

0
1994199519961997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009

Source: The CFA League Department


Figure 8-5 The average match attendance per match

As football clubs are not deeply rooted in local communities, supporters can turn their
backs on the game with relative ease if the CFA, clubs and players do not take
responsibility and run the game with an appropriate degree of accountability.

83
The Super League entitles four entries.

279
8.5.3 Fans’ concern about the current development problems
Apart from the positive impact that market-oriented reform has made, corruption and
incompetent governance within the industry has caused fans to foster serious concerns.
Mr Yuan Haishang, President of Henan Jianye Fan Union highlights that it is not only the
players that are involved in the many incidents such as gambling, fighting and drinking,
that have blemished the game, but also match officials (personal interview, 09/07/08):

“Even though referees have improved these couple of years, some of them are not up to
the desired standard. They can referee matches only because they know someone in the
CFA”.
He goes on:
“Incompetent governance is the main reason causing the industry to decline. Firstly, the
governing body has few competent staff; secondly, with the governmental background, it
places emphasis on short-sighted politically-led practices. At the club level, few clubs
have high standard academies, many clubs prefer to buy youngsters instead of fostering
their own.”

The quality of the national team is determined by the quality of leagues and professional
clubs; the quality of clubs is largely determined by whether their academies and youth
development programmes are scientifically designed and well-implemented. As no
Chinese clubs have deep community-roots, they have little to offer in the way of history
and heritage. As a result, contemporary credibility of the game plays a more important
role in Chinese football development than tradition, with emphasis on the performance of
the national team. The performance of the national team has a great effect on fans’
enthusiasm, the overall football environment and on league attendance. As Hu Ge,
President of Changsha Red Pepper Fan Association explains (personal interview,
04/07/08):

“The overall football environment is not good, especially as the national team has lost
too many games. That damaged fans’ participation, as well as the football market. When

280
coupled with corruption, this has led to a tough environment for football development at
all levels.”
He explains further:
“The CFA places emphasis on the national team, clubs concentrate on their first teams,
what about the grass-roots football? In Changsha city, there is not enough space for kids
to play, even in their schools. Without a good coherent structure, how can we build
quality clubs and the national team?”

Professionalisation broke the old cohesive structure of the game. It is making a negative
impact on both the long-term development of the industry and the current performance of
the national team. Poor international results coupled with scandals damage the game’s
contemporary credibility and put Chinese football into a vicious circle. The community
based grass-roots infrastructure has been debated. However, explicit plans and
implementation are still off the agenda, even though these are essential elements in
achieving sustainable development under the market economy.

What is the best way forward for Chinese football? Ashton (2002) points out that every
sport, including football, relies upon the savvy of their governing body to develop,
implement and oversee regulations, as it cannot rely on civil law for all its specific issues.
It is a real challenge for the industry, which is experiencing a vicious circle of corruption
and lack of transparency. As Mr Yuan Haishan, President of Henan Jianye Fan Union
suggests: (personal interview, 09/07/08)

“Cutting off direct government links and making the CFA a real NGO; establishing
appropriate governance mechanisms and setting up good youth development programs”.

The dual position of the CFA and its organisational structure determines its own
accountability. The governing body is simply not fit for purpose. As a result, it neither
meets the demands of the modern industry practice at the professional level, nor does it
fulfill its duty to promote the game at the grass-roots level.

281
8.6 Summary
Jones (1998, cited by Morrow 2003) indicates that fandom is characterised by a
particularly strong level of commitment and self-identification, which means die-hard
fans continually support their team irrespective of performance. However, in the Chinese
case, the fan/club relationship and fans’ loyalty are not based on community connections
and clubs’ traditional values. ‘Fan equity’ is relatively weak in terms of commitment and
emotional attachment towards a particular club. Fans’ loyalty is, however, strong towards
the game and the national team. Indeed, many people claim they are die-hard football
fans when in fact few are die-hard fans of a particular club, even though they do support
their local clubs in general.

Despite some fan associations being successful in terms of maintaining a dialogue with
their local clubs, few of them are drawn into the actual decision-making panels by their
clubs and treated as an important stakeholder group, which, as fans, they deserve.
Compared to European fans, Chinese fans are less demanding. Although Chinese fans
have football knowledge as well as business awareness, they are in a weak position when
required to take more initiative and display determination in order to drive their own
issues forward. In fact, fans are not properly consulted on all major issues facing the
game, and are excluded from having any meaningful say in the decision-making bodies.

Chinese fans are not against the commercial approach, however, they are recognising
problems such as incompetent governance and corruption. Fans want to see fewer poorly
run clubs, governing bodies, proper behaved players, and more credibility in the Chinese
game. This chapter draws upon the Chinese fan culture to set the background, then uses
stakeholder analytical models to outline different relationships that fan associations have
with their clubs. Findings are intended to allow a clear understanding of the impact that
professionalisation made on the relationship between supporters and clubs. Although fans
are aware of their legitimate rights, they lack the eagerness to play more important roles
(such as demanding more involvement in the decision-making process at different levels)
in order to improve the integrity and the governance structure of the game.

282
Chapter Nine: Conclusion

This thesis draws on stakeholder theory as the theoretical framework of analysis, and
examines corporate governance in the Chinese football industry from various angles –
different stakeholders’ perspectives to assess the advent of professionalisation and its
impact on the development of the Chinese game. The justification for employing the
stakeholder theory for studying the football industry comes from the widely accepted
concept that particular features of certain stakeholders within the game require a balanced
analysis need to be addressed with a balanced approach in order to raise the industry’s
accountability 84 (Morrow, 1999, 2000, 2003). This thesis sets the overriding research
question: “How has professionalisation impacted on the governance and
development of the football industry in China?”, and it is the first work to employ the
corporate governance concept and theoretical framework of stakeholder theory into the
Chinese football industry. The research question particularly focuses on the game’s
modern development, gathering information from key stakeholder groups in order to
explore the state of Chinese football. The ultimate purpose lies in reviewing the evidence
and arguments that concern the game’s governance and stakeholder relationships within
the Chinese football industry, assimilating and evaluating them and reaching a logical
and timely conclusion supported by research. The contribution made by stakeholder
theory to Chinese football led to a better understanding of the game from the corporate
governance aspect by utilising stakeholder relationship models, which providing
predicable mechanisms to describe different stakeholder relationships and their
development trends within the industry. A few recommendations are also made based on
findings regarding how to mitigate conflicts between stakeholders at different levels in
order to improve the governance standards of the Chinese game. The next section tries to
discuss how research findings help to answer research questions.

9.1 Discussion
 The top-down governance model turned to stakeholder network

84
See also Chapter Two Literature Review section four.

283
In an increasingly commercialised environment, the top-down football governance model
and the exclusive managerial approach have been challenged by many stakeholders
within the industry. Stakeholder theory and the inclusive approach have proven valuable
concepts untilised by many sport governing bodies and professional clubs to meet the
demands of the modern industry practices. This was most notably achieved by reducing
the level of conflict between sporting and financial issues, as well as between different
stakeholders, therefore, enhancing both transparency and governance standards.
Examples of IOC, FIFA, UEFA and the SLC in China’s football governance have
demonstrated how different sport governing bodies implement the inclusive approach to
bring a wider range of stakeholder groups in their decision-making process. In other
words, this represents a governance shift from a model of direct control from the
government or sporting authorities towards a model with a more inclusive decision-
making mechanism. As Rahman et al (2003, p12) state, “The role of management
becomes immeasurably more challenging, when stakeholders are no longer seen as
simply the objects of managerial action but as subjects with their own objectives and
purposes”.

Looking at the development trend of Chinese governance model, the CFA’s centralised
position has been consistently challenged by other stakeholders, especially clubs. The
governing body gradually facilitated the changes with enhanced transparency and a more
inclusive approach at the decision-making level to accommodate the more diversified
interests of other stakeholders. For example, opening its bank accounts to clubs; the
creation of the SLC. Such governance reform shows the CFA concedes some powers to
other stakeholders, especially to clubs after its dominant position weakened. Nevertheless,
the power balance between the CFA and other stakeholders is not static, it can skew
towards either the CFA or its stakeholders on different occasions, and such a balance
depends on various elements, such as the level of their financial dependency, the third
party influence and other stakeholders’ connections.

Another debating point is the self-conflicted function of the governing body as both a
government organisation – CFMC and a non-governmental organisation – CFA. Due to

284
the “two” bodies carrying different missions with different interests, such an awkward
position casts doubts over the governing body’s accountability and its governance
practices. For example, the officials of governing bodies at different levels being
appointed by their related governments, the practice not only contradict FIFA rules, but
also leave football governance heavily influenced by government decrees, rather than
industry professionals. Clearly, separating the CFA’s government functions and football
practice is the best way to move the game forward. It will not only eliminate the CFA’s
self-conflicted functions but also reshape its governance structure to fit for purpose.
Under the current system, government officials are too eager for quick success. Mr Wei
Di (Mulvenney & Liu, 2010) the former leader of the CFA, has also recognised this
necessity. However, he still sees a certain degree of government involvement as a
preventative measure, keeping the game from completely chaotic and fundamental
problems.

Within the Chinese football industry, conflicts between all stakeholders were not exposed
under the planned economy. All stakeholders had similar interests and little conflict
within the state funded system. However, the football reform moved the game into the
territory of the market economy. With more stakeholders from different backgrounds
becoming involved in the game, more conflicts emerged. By applying stakeholder
analysis, findings at different levels confirm that the necessary compatible relationships
of CFA/local FAs, CFA/clubs and club/country have developed towards the necessary
incompatible direction with a more diverse interest between stakeholders.

Indeed, the top-down governance structure was not designed for transparency, nor for
balancing stakeholders’ interests, but specifically for issuing orders and implementing
policies. Without close public scrutiny and transparent mechanisms, the CFA can hardly
keep its credibility in line with other stakeholders’ expectation and demands, coupled
with the governing body’s unprofessional practices, the reputation of Chinese football
and its sustainable development under the market economy have been put in jeopardy. As
Mr Zheng Jinlong – Senior Vice President, Acting President of AFC (personal interview,
20/04/12) states:

285
“It is the wrong administrations (and) management make the Chinese game suffering.
Chinese football should pay more attentions to reform its orgnisations and
administrations. We cannot blame players and coaches, they are working hard and they
are serious. It is the administrators and the FA, they are not serious to contribute
towards football development in China.”

The modern game governance requires both market knowledge and experience, and
appointed officials often lack business sense and expertise. Many officials only know to
copy the professional models of the European game, but fail to understand that their
models were growing out of communities, based on the universal concept of fair play
(Lau, 2010).

 Clubs became business entities with increased power and influence within the
industry
At the clubs level, football clubs are unusual business entities, and many social,
commercial and emotional attachments from other stakeholders can have financial
implications for clubs. The majority of Chinese clubs are owned by big corporations,
corporations will seek to benefit from their investment directly or indirectly. Many
corporations use clubs not only to raise their brand profiles, but also to maintain a close
association with their local governments in order to gain a business advantage. As clubs
rely heavily on the financial support of corporations, clubs’ own brand integrity is
compromised, which has a harmful effect on long-term sustainability and supporters’
affinity85. It is a big challenge for Chinese clubs to find the right mechanism that retains
the positive involvement of corporations, while at the same time giving clubs greater
consistency of ownership, strategic direction and brand profile (Eaves et al, 2003). As
Morrow (2005) points out: “An unbalanced narrative about the club’s position and
prospective requiring the discharge of financial prudence and common sense is simply
iniquitous”.

85
See examples in Chapter Six, Section Two.

286
Clubs form the basis of the football industry, both economically and socially (Ducrey et
al, 2003). Running a football club is not only an economic issue, it has social
implications too. The interdependent relationship between clubs and their combined
objectives, namely the sporting objective and the commercial objective as well as the
unique club-fan relationship, demonstrate that a football club exists as both a business
and as a social institution (Morrow 2003, 2005).

The study shows that within the football industry, clubs gained substantial power towards
other stakeholders including football authorities. At the professional level, clubs are
directly involve in the decision-making panels and sharing power with the CFA. They are
in a strong position with strong influence. The club/fan relationships in this study also
shows that Chinese clubs increased their awareness of the game’s social implication,
however, they failed to understand how important this social dimension can be in
benefiting clubs’ long-term development. Moreover, a lack of professional knowledge,
coupled with a grave misunderstanding on how to build a community based football club
at this level, has led to clubs’ human and material resources not being fully utilized to
engage with fans and local communities. As a result, local markets are left largely
underdeveloped, which in turn affects clubs’ long-term revenue stream and self-
sustainability. From the Western perspective, clubs’ most loyal fans are from local
communities, and this is the concept that Chinese clubs have not been able to learn and
understand entirely. Chinese clubs are trying hard to develop a straight consumer-supplier
relationship with their local fans, instead of fostering a club/fan culture based on common
values and deep social connections. Although fans may pay considerable sums to watch
the national team or European club tours, the football merchandise market has performed
poorly, which confirms the immaturity of club development (Beere, 2009). This fact
partially explains why Chinese clubs are lacking their own die-hard fans86.

86
A community based club model with an inclusive approach has many advantages, which need to be
acknowledged by the clubs, regardless of their ownership structures. Firstly, a community based club
model creates social bonds between a club and its local community, which gives the club true
representation and identity. Secondly, as clubs’ influence go beyond the realm of economics, various
community schemes can be utilised to boost clubs’ positive social image and popularity, especially
amongst their local authorities and supporters. Thirdly, the inclusive governance approach at the club level
needs the involvement of players and fans – two crucial elements for clubs’ long-term sustainable

287
 Players became a vulnerable group in a highly regulated labour market
Professionalisation has brought changes to players’ employment status at the same time
created a transfer market. Alongside these developments, increased conflicts between
players and clubs emerged. Even though players have gained more flexibility to change
clubs compared to the pre-professional era, the labour market is heavily restricted.
Despite them being able to negotiate contracts individually, they are poorly organised as
a whole. Stakeholder analytical models demonstrated that players are highly dependent
on clubs financially, coupled with their inefficient organisation amongst themselves,
players are not occupying an influential position (they are in the low centrality/low
density position) in the football network. As a result, players’ demands are often ignored.

The research finding illustrated that there is a growing need for players’ voices to be
heard and interests to be considered, especially in a decision-making process at all levels.
As one of the important stakeholder groups, there is a lack of professional advisory
bodies available to players. A players’ union does not exist, and coupled with dearth of
agents, players’ welfare is not properly protected. Mr Zhang Xiaobin concluded that
Chinese football needs time to mature, to create a players’ association is not realistic in
the foreseeable future. The clubs’ lack of vision surrounding community football coupled
with players’ lack of awareness of their social responsibilities have led to a very passive
player/fan relationship, which limits the relationship to a purely market-orientated fragile
bond, based on nothing more than autographs and PR photographs.

 Fans have a limited influence over football governance despite being well
organised at the local level

The fan/club relationship is beyond a conventional ‘customer relations’ status, therefore it


can be argued that fans deserve more say over the game’s governance and development.
The Chinese fan culture is different compared to European culture. Many individual fans

development and stability under the market economy. Fourthly and finally, adopting best practice in all
aspects of corporate behaviour is essential to ensure improved governance (Morrow, 1999).

288
are ‘star driven’ rather than ‘club driven’. Despite the fan loyalty being relatively weak,
fan associations are well organised locally. The study shows that in the fan/club
relationship, fan associations have a limited influence over their local clubs, and they are
not included in any important decision-making process. Despite this fact, fans want their
voices to be heard. For example, some independent fan associations are capable of
employing a pro-active strategy in order to demonstrate that fans have the desire to
increase their influence and to get more involved, especially at the club managerial level,
and there is indeed room for improvement. Moreover, a club needs to be accountable in
order to address fans’ emotional involvement appropriately, including being respectful to
fans’ views in order to foster the club culture and market, and to enrich ‘fan equity’ as
well as to strengthen the special bonds between them.

9.2 The way forward


The multi-disciplinary nature of corporate governance theory has led to different
perceptions relating to how an organisation should be governed due to peculiarity of the
football industry. For example, the interdependence between clubs, the uniqueness of fan
equity and monopoly of league sports. The stakeholder approach and its related analytical
models can offer fresh insights and a better understanding of the Chinese game.

To apply the stakeholder approach to the football industry has been justified in previous
chapters. By taking into account multiple viewpoints with some further development of
analytical models of stakeholder relationship to address the development trends and
consequences of Chinese football professionalisation, the thesis has made a contribution
to both Chinese corporate governance study and better understanding of football
governance. This approach is especially poignant in the current Chinese corporate
governance study environment, due to the whole research field of being dominated by
studies of SOE from the agency theory approach, which lacks both stakeholder approach
and non-SOE subject matter. The research introduced the stakeholder environment by
identifying different stakeholders within the Chinese football industry, then it collected
an analysis from some key stakeholders’ perspectives to answer the overarching research

289
question comprehensively and at the same time revealed governance implications for
each of the main stakeholder group.

The CFA
With sufficient power available, the governing bodies must take a leading and proactive
role to employ best practice. This especially entails being proactive in order to lead
constructive development on the governance structure and revenue distribution
mechanism rather than being reactive to changes. Moreover, setting up a healthy
infrastructure will ensure the game’s credibility, integrity and stakeholder involvement
are protected (Morrow 2003). The governing body has to consider the football institution
as a whole, not just the legal, or economic but also the social aspects, which are essential
in operating the governance model as designed – in the best interests of the game. As
Morrow (2003, p183) states: “But when it really matters, it is inescapable that while some
football communities have sufficient power to look after their own interests unaided,
other communities or stakeholders – often those whose objectives are likely to encompass
social concerns – are powerless. This is why governing bodies must take a leading and
proactive role”.

The CFA has certainly taken initiatives in terms of improving its governance standard at
the professional level, most notably with the creation of the SLC, which includes all
Super League clubs and their local FAs. The change demonstrates a marked improvement
compared to pre-professional era, however, the current study contends that there remains
room for further improvement. For examples, in order to mitigate conflicts, players’
representatives need to be directly involved in the decision-making process and included
in the SLC. Media, sponsors and fans are important stakeholder groups and must be taken
into consideration as credible media scrutiny significantly reduces bad governance and
corruption within the industry. A more transparent mechanism need to be in place to
make the CFA more accountable, especially in terms of its financial accounts and the
revenue distribution process, which should be subject to strict scrutiny. The stakeholder
approach also enable the identification of different type of stakeholders and their related
interest, which the governing bodies can use it as a guide to improve their governance

290
standards at different level. This could be achieved by establishing regular dialogue and
official communication channels between the CFA and all provincial/city FAs to run
grass-roots schemes more effectively in order to rebuild the overall cohesion of the game,
thereby consolidating the foundation of the pyramid.

The Clubs
Professional clubs draw the largest fan base, therefore their interest must be fully
considered. As clubs are gradually taking a strong position within the stakeholder
network, the top flight requires increased autonomy in order to meet the challenges posed
by the rise in football commercialisation. The licensing system sets minimum criteria of
club operations and governance for the interest of sustainable development. Moreover,
clubs should not simply adopt the name of their principal sponsors or owners, their own
brand images must be respected and developed in the long-term.

The community based club model possesses a different football philosophy, which not
only enriches the current Chinese football culture but more importantly encompasses club
development and community building. Ultimately, this establishes clubs’ local roots and
social integration. Furthermore, the community based club model provides sustainable
resources for clubs’ sustainable development under a market-oriented economy. The
inclusive approach and the transparent process require clubs to be accountable, and these
practices will eventually transcribe into clubs’ business advantages and benefits,
intertwined with their overall financial and social development.

Players
A players’ union which can truly represent players’ interests would be an ideal
improvement to a well-balanced modern football governance structure. However, the
reality of establishing such an organisation under the current environment in China is
pessimistic. The recommendation for players would be, to unite within their own clubs
first, and to have their own representatives involved in clubs’ decision-making structures
in order to protect their own interests at the club level. Moreover, creating a close
relationship with other external stakeholders (e.g. lawyers, fan groups and the media),

291
would untilise the third parties’ power, ensuring that their desired messages are respected
by the top levels of management.

Fans
Fans are not just customers, they are part of “match product”. Fan support is an important
element of football development under the market economy, in which the game needs to
gain popularity not only in terms of participation and revenue generation but also in terms
of emotional support from fans. A well-developed local market requires fans’
involvement and a club’s proactive approach in order to draw fans into its various
community schemes and business practices. If the Chinese football model fails to focus
on mass participation at the grass-roots level as well as failing to actively listen to fans,
the game will unable to develop into the people’s game, and the right football
infrastructure will unable to be created to allow Chinese football to prosper. The fan
union model is notably successful as it has increased density amongst individual
associations - the Jianye Fan Union has been treated with respect by Jianya FC, and has
been involved in club’s normal operations to a certain degree on a more regular basis.
The case demonstrates that as long as fans are well organised with the right strategy, they
are capable of playing an active role.

9.3 Summary

It can be argued that the football industry is developed in a market-orientated


environment and should therefore be governed through a business approach, especially at
the professional level. On the other hand, its social aspects (football clubs have been
deemed social institutions) and football’s characteristics as a league sport restricts the
game’s governance by employing purely economic practices, especially at the grass-roots
level. The football industry is complex and consists of multiple stakeholders with
different interests. Morrow (2005, p4) argues that it is necessary to identify “how the
game’s economic basis affects its community – those affected by its actions – or, to use
the language of business, its stakeholders”. In this case, Morrow’s statement underpins
the method of using the stakeholder theoretical framework for answering the overriding

292
research question – ‘How has professionalisation affected the governance and
development of the football industry in China?’ from different stakeholders’ perspectives.

The stakeholder mindset moves beyond stakeholder engagement and responsibility, it is a


new view of modern management. Inclusivity is the ‘golden key’ in a complex web of
relationships, allowing an organisation to solve various conflicts between different
stakeholder groups. The football industry is more than just a business, and stakeholders’
values are even more related to the game’s further development compared to other
conventional industries. Ideally, all stakeholders directly involved in the production of
football should be represented at the decision-making level, in order to find a way of
balancing the game’s sporting and business objectives, as well as to meet demands of the
modern industry practice. Building such governance structure requires an inclusive
approach and awareness that all stakeholders’ legitimate interests need to be respected.
As shown in Figure 5-4, the researcher has chosen the four main pillars of the Chinese
football industry as focal stakeholder groups for analysis and omitted others. The reasons
for this are partly time and financial constraints; more importantly, the focused key
stakeholder groups were considered fit for purpose for this research.

At the political governance level, FIFA and AFC set the major international regulatory
frameworks. Since the thesis focuses on the Chinese game’s ‘bottom-up’ response to
commercialisation domestically, FIFA and AFC’s perspectives were not deeply studied.
Media is a big contributor in the European football industry, especially the TV sector; by
contrast, TV provides a very limited financial contribution to the Chinese game. Despite
this, there are potential opportunities for media to play a more important role in the
game’s commercial development, especially in the new media era. At the present time,
traditional TV money is small, and new media platforms are still immature. As the
researcher has limited accessibility in this sector, media as a stakeholder group was not
examined in depth. At the organisational governance level, sponsors are big financial
contributors compared to the media sector. In fact, the biggest sponsors are club owners.
In its current stage of development, the Chinese football market has not been able to
attract big commercial deals. Nevertheless, the analysis of the clubs’ perspective (Chapter

293
Six) does reflect some main sponsors’ points of view (as clubs’ owners). Even though
more community elements have gradually emerged in the commercialised Chinese
football industry, Chinese clubs have not emerged from the community based football
culture and share little of the values of their local communities. More importantly, an
understanding of the different views can help detoxify the hostile situation and allow
stakeholders to make necessary adjustments. This thus provides the industry with an
increasing amount of opportunities, rather than challenges, for a sustainable and healthy
development (Morrow, 2003).

The challenges facing Chinese football have to be addressed at professional and strategic
level, and strategic vision is required to understand a wide range of stakeholders who
have vested interest within the game. Looking back on the whole process of
professionalisation in China and the CFA’s government background, the truth is, that on
the one hand China will never copy any of the European football governance models
entirely, on the other hand, Chinese football professionalisation involves using a variety
of elements, including the fundamental philosophy of European football87. As Amara et
al (2005, p195) state that: “a hybrid between the traditional centralised control of vertical
government of the game and the network system of governance evident in the European
context”. It is important for Chinese sporting officials to realise that traditional football
nations’ successful models cannot be simply copied, but first need to be understood
authentically, without compromising the core value and spirit of the game. As
professional leagues have become the main feeders for world football, an integrated
network of all stakeholders involved in the governance structure is essential to ensure the
healthy and sustainable development of the football industry. Football’s long-term
success is dependent on popularising the game through a broad section of the population,
rather than just a few elite clubs. Mass participation, community spirit, traditional values
and credibility are the key elements in developing a healthy industry and a powerful
football nation. Based on this research, other stakeholder models can be developed in
order to explore the Chinese football industry for further studies, not only at the
professional level but also at grassroots level.

87
Reflecting the Bird-cage theory in Chapter Five Section Two.

294
On-field fighting, off-field corruption and other related controversies should not prevent
Chinese football from moving forwards. The overall impact of professionalisation on
football development has been positive, as the game has continued to grow. The
transformation of football from a state amateur model under a planned economy to a
Western style professional model under a market-orientated economy reflects not only
the progress that Chinese football has made, but also the socio-economic changes that
have occurred, both globally and domestically. The healthy development of Chinese
football relies on a balanced, inclusive approach and effective integration of the game’s
sporting, financial and social dimensions. The inclusive approach and involvement of
more stakeholders in the decision-making process are the key elements for the modern
game in tackling conflicts caused by commercial development. With all stakeholders’
collective efforts combined, Chinese football can be cherished in the future.

295
Bibliography:

Agle, B., Mitchell, R. & Sonnenfeld, J. (1999) Who matters to CEOS? An investigation
of stakeholder attributes and salience, corporate performance and CEO values, Academy
of Management Journal, 42 (5): 507-525

Aglietta, M. (2000) Shareholder value and corporate governance: some tricky questions,
Economy and Society, 29: 146-159

Amara, M., Henry, I., Liang, J. & Uchiumi, K. (2005) The governance of professional
soccer: case studies – Algeria, China, England and Japan, European Journal of Sport
Science, December 5(4): 189-206

Andriof, J & Waddock, S. (2002) Unfolding stakeholder engagement, in Andriof, S.,


Waddock, S., Husted, B., Sutherland, Rahman, S. (eds) Unfolding Stakeholder Thinking:
Theory, Responsibility And Engagement, Sheffield: Greenleaf

Ang, J. S., Cole, R. A., & Lin, J. W (2000) Agency costs and ownership structure, The
Journal of Finance, LV (1), 81-106

Argenti, J. (1997) Stakeholders: the case against, long range planning, 30(3): 442-445

Arnaut, J. L. (2006) Preface, in The State of the Game 2006, Research Paper, No.3
Birkbeck, University of London

Ashton, C. (2002) China: Opportunities in the business of sport, London: SportBusiness


Group Limited

Babbie, E. (2007) The Practice of Social Research, Belmont: Thomson Higher Education

296
Barney, J. (1988) Agency theory, employee stock ownership and a firm’s cost of equity
capital, working paper, College Station: Texas A&M University

Baruch, Y., Wheeler, K. & Zhao, X. (2004) Performance-related pay in Chinese


professional sports, International Journal Of Human Resource Management, 15 (1): 245-
259

BBC (2009) China athletes ‘faked their age’ [Online] (Updated on 16 March 2009),
Available at: http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/asia-pacific/7945832.stm [Accessed 10,
October 2010]

Beaver, W. (1999) Is the stakeholder model dead? Business Horizon, March – April, 42
(2): 5-8

Beer, A. E (2009) The Big Leagues? The Business of Sports in China, London, New
York, Hong Kong, Economist Intelligence Unit

Berle, A. A. & Means, G. C. (1932) The Modern Corporation and Private Property, New
York: Macmillan

Blair, M. (1995) Ownership and Control: Rethinking Corporate Governance For The
Twenty-First Century, Washington DC: The Brooking Institution

Blair, M. (1998) For whom should corporations be run? An economic rationale for
stakeholder management, Long Range Planning, 31(2): 195-200

Boon, G. (2000) Football finances: too much money? in Hamil, S., Michie, J., Oughton,
C. & Warby, S. (eds) Football in the Digital Age, Edinburgh: Mainstream

Borger, J. (2008) “They think it is all over”, Guardian, 06 December

297
Bramall, C. (2009) Chinese Economic Development, London & New York, Routledge

Brand, A. & Niemann, A (2011) Germany:between modest adjustment and system


transformation, in in Niemann, A., Garcia, B. & Grant, W. (eds) The transformation of
European football, Manchester University Press, Manchester and New York

Bristow, M. (2008) China TV bans top football league, [Online] (Updated 17 Nov 2008)
Available at: http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/7733298.stm [Accessed 02 February 2009]

Brownell, S (1995) Training the Body for China, Chicago & London, University of
Chicago Press

Bryman, A. (2001) Social Research Methods, Oxford: Oxford University Press

Bryman, A. & Bell, E. (2003) Business Research Methods, Oxford: Oxford University
Press

Cadbury, A. (1992) The Final Report Of The Committee On The Financial Aspects Of
Corporate Governance – the Code of Best Practice, London: Gee and Co. Ltd

Campbell, A. (1997), Stakeholders: the case in favour, Long Range Planning, 30(3): 446-
449

Campos, C. E., Newell, R. E., & Wilson, G (2002) Corporate governance develops in
emerging markets, McKinsey on Finance 3: 15-18

Carr, J. & Brower, R. (1996) Principal-agent as an explanation of nonsanctioned


organization behaviors: is the theory useful? Academy of Management Proceedings. 323-
327

298
Carroll, A. & Bucholtz, A. (1989) Ethics and Stakeholder Management, Cincinnati:
Business and Society

Central Committee, CCP (2006) Communiqué of the Sixth Plenum of the 16 th CPC
Central Committee, October 11, http://news.xinhua.com/english (Accessed Oct 17, 2008)

The CFA Charter (2005), Beijing: the CFA

The CFA (2002) The Entry Criteria for CSL Clubs, Beijing: the CFA

The CFA (2011) Notice of player transfer and related matters for the 2012 season, 31 st
October, No.598, Beijing, the CFA

The CFA (2001) Player’s Status and Transfer Regulation, Beijing, the CFA

The CFA (2004) Player’s Status and Transfer Regulation, Beijing, the CFA

Chambers, A. D. (2005) Audit committees: practice, rules and enforcement in the UK


and China, Corporate Governance, 13 (1): 92-100

Chan, T.M.H., Tracy, N. & Zhu, W.H. (1999) China’s Export Miracle, Basingstoke:
Macmillan

Chen, J (2003) Essay on Corporate Governance in China, PhD, London: King’s College
London

Chen, T (1962) Elementary Education in Communist China, Cambridge: Cambridge


University Press

Chen, Y (1986) Bird cage economic theory, Chen Yun Wenxuan, 1956-1985, Vol.3,
Beijing: Chinese People’s Publishing House

299
Chen, Z (2013) The Bonus List of Super League Clubs, (Published 27 August) Available
at: http://sports.sohu.com/20130827/n385133852.shtml [Accessed 10 September]

Cheung, Y. & Jiang, P (2010) Corporate Governance in China: a step forward, European
Financial Management, 16 (1): 94-123

China (2006) Edited by Sue, D & Wang, M, Beijing: Foreign Language Press

China Statistical Yearbooks (2009) National Bureau of Statistics, Beijing

CIA World Factbook, (Online) Available at: https://www.cia.gov (accessed 23, June
2010)

Clark. T (2007) International Corporate Governance: A Comparative Approach, New


York: Routledge

Clarke. T (2004) Cycles of crisis and regulation: the enduring agency and stewardship
problems of corporate governance, Cycles of Crisis and Regulation, 12(2): 153-161

Clarke. D C (2003) Corporate governance in China: an overview, China Economic


Review 14: 494-507

Clarke, T & Clegg, S (1998) Changing Paradigms: The Transformation Of Management


Knowledge For The 21st Century, London: Harper Collins

Clarke, T & Clegg, S (2000) Management paradigms of the new millennium,


International Journal of Management Review, 2 (1): 45-64

Clarke, T & Du, Y (1998) Corporate governance in China: explosive growth and new
patterns of ownership, Long Range Planning, 31(2): 239-251

300
Clarkson, M (1995) A stakeholder framework for analyzing and evaluating corporate
social performance, Academy of Management Review, 20 (1): 92-117

Clumpner, R & Pendleton, B (1978) The People’s Republic of China in Riordan, J et al


(eds) Sport Under Communism, London & Montreal: C. Hurst & Co. Ltd

The Combined Code on Corporate Governance (2003) London: Financial Reporting


Council

Companies Act, 1980, Great Britain

Companies Act, 2006, Great Britain

The Company Law of the People’s Republic of China (1994) Eighth National People’s
Congress, 29 December, Beijing

Cong, P & Shi, W (2009) Research on the Transfer System of Professional Football
Players in China, China Sports Science, Vol.29 (5), 32-39

Conn. D (2007) ‘I am afraid of what has happened to football’, The Guardian, 28 Nov

Conyon, M. J & He, L (2011) Executive Compensation and Corporate Governance in


China, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University ILR School

Curd, M & Cover, J, A (1998) Philosophy of Science, London & New York: W.W.
Norton & Company

Davies, R. W., Harrison, M., & Wheatcroft, S. G. (1994) The Economic Transformation
of the Soviet Union, 1913-1945, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

301
Deloitte (2011) Broadcasting models – TV Times

Deng, X (1980) Reform of the Party System and State Leadership, China Daily, 31
August

Deng, X (1984) Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping. Beijing, Foreign Language Press

Dixon. Beverly R, Bouma. Gary D, Atkinson. G. B. J (1987) A Handbook of Social


Science Research, New York: Oxford University Press

Dolles, H & Soderman, S (2005) Ahead of the game – the network of value captures in
professional football, Working Paper, German Institution for Japanese Study

Donaldson, T, & Preston, L (1995) The stakeholder theory of the corporation: concepts,
evidence, and implications, Academy of Management Review, 20 (1): 65-91

Dong, J. & Mangan, J (2001) Football in the new China: political statement,
entrepreneurial enticement and patriotic passion, Soccer and Society 2 (3): 79-100

Drew, S (2011) Harewood takes China in his stride and his club into Super League, The
Guardian, 18 Nov, p.4 (Sports Section)

Ducrey, P., Ferreira, C. D., Huerta, G. & Marston, K. T. (2003) UEFA and Football
Governance: A New Model, Adoption for the Challenges of modern football, MA,
Leicester: De Montfort University

Duerden, J (2009) Asian Debate: Is the ‘3 plus 1’ rule changing Asian football for good?
[On line] Available at: http://www.goal.com/en/news/1775/asian-
editorials/2009/01/29/1082990/asian-debate-is-the-3-plus-1-rule-changing-asian-football
[Accessed on 29 January 2009]

302
Eaves, N., Empson, N. & Fletcher, D., (2003) Football in China, London: SportBusiness
Group/FMMIternational

Eisenhardt, K. M., (1985) Control: organisational and economic approaches,


Management Science, 31(2): 134-149

Eisenhardt, K. M. (1988) Agency – and institutional – theory explanations: The case of


retail sales compensation, Academy of Management Journal, 31(3): 488-511

Eisenhardt, K. M (1989) Agency theory: an assessment and review, Academy of


Management Review, 14(1): 57-74

Eliliot. D. & Smith, D., (2006) Culture readjustment after crisis; regulation and learning
from crisis within the UK soccer industry, Journal of Management Studies, 43(2): 289-
317

Fama, E. F (1980) Agency problems and the theory of the firm, The Journal Of Political
Economy, 88(2): 288-307

Fama. E. F & Jenson, M. C. (1983) Separation of ownership and control, Journal of Law
and Economics, 26(2): 301-325

Fan, H. (1997) Commercialism and sport in China: present situation and future
expectation, Journal of Sport Management, 11: 343-354

Fan, H & Mangan, J. A (2004) Will the ‘iron rose’ bloom forever? Women’s football in
China: changes and challenges in Mangan, J. A (ed) Soccer, Women, Sexual Liberation
Kicking Off a New Era, London: Frank Cass

303
Fang, L (2000) Reviewing the old to understand the new: A discussion of reform of the
Company Law in Guo, F. & Wang, J. (eds) An All-Around Discussion Of Reform Of
Company Law, Beijing: Falu Publishing House

Farquhar. S, Machold. S & Ahmed. P K (2005) Governance and football: an examination


of the relevance of corporate governance regulations for the sports sector, International
Journal Business Governance and Ethics, 1(4): 329-349

Ferkins, L. Shilbury, D. & McDonald, G. (2005) The role of the board in building
strategic capability: towards and integrated model of sport governance research, Sport
Management Review, 8: 195-225

Financial Times (1999), 21 June.

Football Governance Research Centre (2003) The State of the Game: The Corporate
Governance of Football Clubs, Research Paper 2005, No.4 Birkbeck, University of
London

Football Governance Research Centre (2004) The State of the Game: The Corporate
Governance of Football Clubs, Research Paper 2005, No.3 Birkbeck, University of
London

Football Governance Research Centre (2005) The State of the Game: The Corporate
Governance of Football Clubs, Research Paper 2005, No.3 Birkbeck, University of
London

Football Spectators Act 1989 (c.37), London: HMSO

The Football Task Force (1999) Investing in the Community: A submission by the
Football Task Force to the Minister of Sport, London: the Football Task Force

304
Freeman, R.E (1984) Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach, Boston: Pitman

Freeman, R.E (1994) The politics of stakeholder theory: some future directions, Business
Ethics Quarterly, 4(4): 409-421

Freeman, R. E., & Reed, D. L., (1983) Stockholders and stakeholders: A new perspective
on corporate governance, California Management Review, 25(3): 93-94

Freeman, R.E, Wicks, A.C, Parmar, B., (2004) Stakeholder Theory and “The Corporate
Objective Revisited”, Organisation Science, 15(3), 364-369

Friedman, A & Miles, S (2002) Developing stakeholder theory, Journal of Management


studies 39(1): 1-21

Frisby, W. (2005) The good, the bad, and the ugly: critical sport management research,
Journal of Sport Management, 19 (1): 1-12

Frooman, J. (1999) Stakeholder influence strategy, Academy of Management Review,


24(2): 191-205

Gabriel, S. J. (1998a) Economic Liberalisation in Post-Mao China: Crossing the River by


Feeling the Stones, (Online) Available at: http://www.mtholyoke.edu (accessed 22, June
2010)

Gabriel, S. J. (1998b) The Structure of a Post-Revolutionary Economic Transformation,


(Online) Available at: http://www.mtholyoke.edu (accessed 22, June 2010)

Gabriel, S. J. (2006) Chinese Capitalism and the Modernist Version, London & New
York: Routledge

305
Gammelsӕter, H. & Senaux, B (2011) Prespective on the Governance of Fotbball Across
Europe, in Gammelsӕter, H. & Senaux, B (eds) The Organisation and Governance of
Top Football Across Europe, Routledge, New York, London

Gammelsӕter, H. & Senaux, B (2013) The governance of the game: a review of the
research on football’s governance, in Sӧderman, S & Dolles, H (eds) Handbook of
Research on Sport and Business, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, Northampton, MA,
USA

Garcia, B (2011) The Influence of the EU on the Governance of Football, in


Gammelsӕter, H. & Senaux, B (eds) The Organisation and Governance of Top Football
Across Europe, Routledge, New York, London

Garcia, B., Niemann, A & Grant, W (2011) Conclusion: a Europeanised game? in


Niemann, A., Garcia, B. & Grant, W. (eds) The transformation of European football,
Manchester University Press, Manchester and New York

Gibson, O (2013) Premier League warned over ‘rich and poor’ split in wake of TV deal,
The Guardian, 19 March

Gibson, O (2014) Premier League has second-largest proportion of foreigners in Europe,


The Guardian, 21 January

Gioia, D. A., (1999) Practicability, paradigms and problems in stakeholder theory,


Academy of Management Journal, 24(2): 228-232

Giulianotti, R. (1999) Football: Sociology of the Global Game, Cambridge: Polity Press

306
Giulianotti, R. (2002) Supporters, followers, fans and flaneurs, Journal of Sport and
Social Issues, 26(1): 25-46

Glaser, B. G., & Strauss, A. L. (1967) The Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies for
Qualitative Research, Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company

Gong, S (2011) The Super League is named ‘Wanda Plaza’, Dongfang Daily, 5 July,
p.B12

Gong, Zh (2000) Players call for fairness – Analysis of the transfer system, Sports and
Science, No.3, 37-39

Grandori, A. & Soda, G. (1995) Inter-firm networks: antecedents, mechanisms and forms,
Organisation Studies, 16(2): 183-214

Grant, W (2004) England: A liberal model under challenge? in Niemann, A., Garcia, B.
& Grant, W. (eds) The transformation of European football, Manchester University Press,
Manchester and New York

Griffin, J. J., Mahon, J. F., (1997) The corporate social performance and corporate
financial performance debate, Business and Society, 36: 5-31

Gulati, R. (1998) Alliances and networks, Strategy Management Journal, 19(4): 293-371

Guo, L (2009) 1983 the Fifth National Games, Glory Belongs to the New Generation of
the 1980s, China Sports, 7th August, China Sports Magazine Publishing House

Hage, J & Alter, C (1997) A typology of interorganisational relationships and networks,


in Hollingsworth, J & Boyer, R (eds), Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of
Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

307
Hamil, S (1999) A whole new ball game, in Hamil. S, Michie. J and Oughton, C. (eds), A
Game of Two Halves, Edinburgh: Mainstream Publishing Company Ltd

Hamil, S., J. Michie, C. Oughton and S. Warby (eds) (2000) Football in the Digital Age:
Whose Game is it Anyway? Edinburgh: Mainstream

Harrison, J. & Freeman, R. E. (1999) Stakeholders, social responsibility, and


performance: empirical evidence and theoretical perspectives, Academy of Management
Journal, 42(5): 479-485

Healey, D (2009) Sports and the Law, 4th Edition, Sydney: University of New South
Wales Press Ltd

Henry, I & Lee, P. C. (2004) Governance and ethics in sport, in Beech, J & Chadwick, S.
(eds) The Business of Sport Management, Harlow, Pearson Education

Hendry, J. (2005) Beyond self-interest: agency theory and the board in a satisficing world,
British Journal of Management, 16: 55-63

Higgs Report (2003) Higgs Report – a more important role for non-executive directors,
London: Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer

Hills, M. (2002) Fan Cultures, London & New York: Routledge

Hillman, A. J. & Keim, G. D. (2001) Stakeholder value, stakeholder management, and


social issues: what’s the bottom line, Strategic Management Journal, 22: 125-139

Holt, M (2007) The Ownership and Control of Elite Club Competition in European
Football, Soccer and Society, 8, 50-67

308
Holstein, W. J (2008) Corporate Governance in China and India, Bloomberg
Businessweek, March 6

Homburg, H (2006) FIFA and the ‘Chinese Question”’ 1954-1980: an exercise of statutes,
Historical Social Research, 31(1): 69-87

Hua, T (2004) Football ‘hooligans’ and football supporters’ culture in China, in


Manzenreiter & Horne (eds) Football Goes East, London & New York: Routledge

Huang, Y. (1998) Agricultural Reform in China: Getting Institutions Right, Cambridge,


Cambridge University Press

Hudson, D. & Herbane, B. (2000) Marketing in English Professional Football Clubs,


Leicester: De Montfort University

Hughes, T. J., & Luard, D. E. T. (1959) The Economic Development of Communist


China 1949 – 1958, New York: Oxford University Press

Humber, J. M., (2002) Beyond stockholders and stakeholders: A plea for corporate moral
authority, Journal of Business Ethics, 36: 207-221

Hunt, K. A., Bristol, T. and Edward Bashaw, R (1999) A conceptual approach to


classifying sports fans, The Journal of Services Marketing, 16 (6): 439-454

Hwang, D., & Jarvie, G. (2003) Sport, postcolonialism and modern China: some
preliminary thoughts, in Bale, J., & Cronin, M. (eds) Sport and Postcolonialism, Oxford
& New York: Berg

The Independent (2008), Bundesliga foreign ownership ban continues, 17 October

309
Jarvie, G., Hwang, D & Brennan, M (2008) Sport, Revolution and the Beijing Olympics,
Oxford & New York: Berg

Jensen, M (1983) Organisational theory and methodology, Accounting Review, 56(2):


319-338

Jensen, M. C., (2002) Value maximization, stakeholder theory and the corporate
objective function, Business Ethics Quarterly, 12(2): 235-256

Jeansen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency
cost and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305-360

Jia, L (2011) the CFA Introduces New Measurement, Points Will be Deduced for Late
Payment, [Online] (Updated 28 Feb 2010) Available at:
http://sports.eastday.com/s/20110228/u1a5748549.html [Accessed 30 Nov 2011]

Jiang, Z. (1995) Presidential Order No.55, Beijing, 29 August

Jing, Z. (2009) Chinese Economy since 1949, China.org.cn, September 17

Jones, I. (1998) Football Fandom: Football Fan Identity and Identification at Luton Town
Football Club, PhD thesis, University of Luton

Jones, I. (2000a) A model of serious leisure identification: the case of football fandom,
Leisure Studies, 19(4): 283-298

Jones, R (1999a) Sport in China, in Riordan, J. and Jones, R. (eds), Sport and Physical
Education in China, London & New York: Taylor & Francis

Jones, R. (1999b) The emergence of the professional sport, in Riordan, J. and Jones, R.
(eds), Sport and Physical Education in China, London & New York: Taylor & Francis

310
Jones, R. (2000) Ten years of China watching: present trends and future directions on
sport in the People’s Republic, in Tolleneer, J., & Renson, R. (eds) Old Borders, New
Borders, No Borders, Oxford: Meyer & Meyer Sport

Jones, R. (2004) Football in the People’s Republic of China in Manzenreiter, W & Horne,
J (eds), Football Goes East, London & New York: Routledge

Jones, T. M. (1995) Instrumental stakeholder theory: a synthesis of ethics and economics,


Academy of Management Review, 20(2): 404-437

Kanin. D. B (1978) Ideology and diplomacy: the dimension of Chinese political sport, in
Lowe. B, Kanin. D. B and Strenk. A (eds) Sport and International Relations, Champaign,
Illinois: Stipes Publishing Company

Keeley, M. (1980) Organisational analogy: a comparison of organismic and social


contract models, Administrative Science Quarterly, 25(2): 337-361

Kirby, W. C (1995) China unincorporated: company law and business enterprise in


twentieth century China, Journal of Asian Studies, 54(1): 43-63

Kolatch, J (1972) Sports, Politics and Ideology in China, New York, Jonathan David
Publishers

Kueh, Y. Y. (2006) Mao and agriculture in China’s industrialisation: three antitheses in a


50-Year perspective, The China Quarterly, 187: 700-723

Kuhn, T. (1962) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago: University of Chicago


Press

311
Lanfranchi, P., & Taylor, M. (2001) Moving with the ball, the migration of professional
footballers, Oxford: Berg

Lago, U., Simmons, R., & Szymanski, S. (2006). The financial crisis in European
football: an introduction, Journal of Sports Economics, 7(1): 3–12

Laplume, A., Sonpar, K. & Litz, R. (2008) Stakeholder theory: reviewing a theory that
moves us, Journal of Management, 34(6): 1152-1189

Lau, C. L. (2010) Changing Chinese football from the bottom up [Online] (Updated 7
July) Available at: http://www.dimsum.co.uk/features/changing-chinese-football-from-
the-bottom-up.html [Accessed 10 August 2010]

Laudan, L. (1984) Science and Values: The Aims of Science and Their Role in Scientific
Debate, Berkeley: University of California Press

Lawler, E. E. III. (1981) Pay and Organisational Development, Reading: Mass: Addison-
Wesley

Leusse, P., Dimitrakos, T. & Brossard, D (2009) A Governance Model for SOA. In 2009
IEEE International Conference on Web Services, Los Angles, CA 6-10 July, ICWS, LA

Li Ch (2007) The Super League becomes North & South Regional Competitions, There
Is No Football in China [Online] (Updated 08 August 2007) Available at:
http://www.360doc.com/content/07/0808/17/9737_660548.shtml [Accessed 20
November 2011]

Li Chao (1956) Hsueh Hsiao Chung te Ti Yu, Hubei Jenmin Publication House, pp1-6

Liao, H (1998) Interview with Zhang Jilong, Cen Chuanli, Chai Yongguang, Di Lizhong
and Zhang Li, China Daily (Overseas), 23 October, p.7

312
Liang, Y (2003) Friendly First, Competition Second: the development of Chinese football
since 1949, MA dissertation, De Montfort University

Liang, Z., (1990) Looking Forward to the 21st Century, in Knuttegen, H. G., MA., Q., &
Wu, Zh. (eds) Sport in China, Illinois: Human Kinetics Publisher

Lieberthal, K (1995) Governing China, New York & London: Norton

Liu, G (2005) Comparative corporate governance: the experience between China and the
UK, Corporate Governance, 13(1): 1-4

Liu. G. S & Sun. P (2005) The Class of Shareholdings and its Impacts on Corporate
Performance; a case of state shareholding composition in Chinese public corporations,
Corporate Governance, 13 (1), 46-59

Liu. P (2009) “To Celebrate 60 Years Anniversary of the PRC, 60 Years Sports
Achievement of New China”, the State Council press conference, Press Office of the
State Council, 27 September

Low, C & Cowton, C (2004) Beyond stakeholder engagement: the challenges of


stakeholder participation in corporate governance, International Journal of Business
Governance and Ethics, 1(1): 45-55

Maddison, A. (2003) The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris: OECD

Madrigal, R (1995) Cognitive and affective determinants of fan satisfaction with sporting
event attendance, Journal of Sport Management, 27(3): 205-207

Mallin, C. (2004) Corporate Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press

313
Manzenreiter, W & Horne, J (2007) Playing the post-fordist game in/to the Far East: the
footballisation of China, Japan and South Korea, Soccer & Society, 8(4): 561-577

Margolis, J. D., Walsh, J. P., (2001) People And Profits? The Search For A Link Between
A Company’s Social And Financial Performance, Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum
Associates

Mason, D. S. (1999) What is the sports product and who buys it? The marketing of
professional sports leagues, European Journal of Marketing, 33(3/4): 402-415

Maxwell, J. A. (1996) Qualitative Research Design: An interactive approach, London:


Sage

May, T. (1993) Social Research – issues, methods and process, Buckingham: Open
University Press

Mayoux, L (2001) Qualitative Method, [On line] Available at:


http://www.proveandimprove.org/new/documents/QualMethods.pdf [Accessed 10 April
2009]

McKeown, J (2011) The economics of competitive balance: sports antitrust claims after
American Needle, Marquette Sports Law Review, 21(2): 516-550

McMaster, R. (1997) The market for corporate control in professional football: is there an
agency problem?, Economics Affairs, 17(3): 25-29

Meier, H. E. (2005) The rise of the regulatory state in sport, Paper presented at the 3 rd
ECPR conference, Budapest, 8-10 September

314
Michie, Jonathan & Shay Ramalingam (1999) Whose game is it anyway? Stakeholders,
mutuals and trusts, in Hamil, S, Michie, J & Oughton, C (eds), The Business of Football:
A Game of Two Halves? Edinburgh: Mainstream Publishing

Mitchell, R., Agel, B. and Wood, D. (1997) Towards a theory of stakeholder


identification and salience: defining the principle of who and what really counts,
Academy of Management Review, 22 (4): 853-886

Monks, R. & Minow, N. (2001) Corporate Governance, 2nd edition, Oxford: Blackwell

Morris, T & Wood. S (1991) Testing the survey method: continuity and change in British
industrial relations, Work Employment and Society, 5(2): 259-282

Morrow, S. (1999) The New Business of Football, Hampshire & London: Macmillan

Morrow, S. (2000) Football clubs on the stock exchange: An inappropriate match?, The
Irish Accounting Review, 7(2): 61-90

Morrow, S. (2003) The People’s Game, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan

Morrow, S. (2005) The Business of Football: Image Management in Narrative


Communication, Edinburgh: The Institute of Chartered Accountants of Scotland

Mulvenney, N. & Liu, Z. (2010) Interview – Soccer – New China chief target Clean-up
in three years, Reuters, 7th Apr, Beijing

Nafziger, J. & Li, W (1998) China’s sports law, The American Journal of Comparative
Law, 46(3): 453-483

315
Neale, W. C. (1964) The peculiar economics of professional sports: a contribution to the
theory of the firm in sporting competition and in market competition, The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 78(1): 1-14

Nevile, B. & Menguc, B. (2006) Stakeholder multiplicity: toward an understanding of the


interactions between stakeholders, Journal of Business Ethics, 66: 377-391

Niemann, A., Garcia, B. & Grant, W. (2011) Introduction: the transformation of


European football, in Niemann, A., Garcia, B. & Grant, W. (eds) The transformation of
European football, Manchester University Press, Manchester and New York

NPESC (1979) A Number of Measures to Improve Football Skills and the Playing
Standard, 6 June, Beijing, National Physical Education and Sports Commission

NPESC Sports Literature and History Committee & the CFA (1993) History of Chinese
Football, Wuhan, Wuhan Publishing House

Olive, C. (1991) Strategic responses to institutional processes, Academy of Management


Review, 16(1): 145-179

Ong, K. & Baxter, C. (1999) A comparative study of the fundamental elements of


Chinese and English law, The International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 48(1): 88-
126

Parent, M. & Deephouse, D. (2007) A case study of stakeholder identification and


prioritization by managers, Journal of Business Ethics, 75: 1-23

Parrish, R (2011) Europe: the transformation of football, in Niemann, A., Garcia, B. &
Grant, W. (eds) The transformation of European football, Manchester University Press,
Manchester and New York

316
Patton, M. Q. (1990) Qualitative Evaluation And Research Method, London: Sage

People’s Daily (1999) 7th August

Philips, R. (1997) Stakeholder theory and a principle of fairness, Business Ethics


Quarterly, 7(1): 51-66

Philips, R. (2003) Stakeholder legitimacy, Business Ethics Quarterly, 13(1): 25-41

Post, J., Preston, L. & Sachs, S. (2002) Managing the Extended Enterprise: The New
Stakeholder View, California Management Review, 45 (1), 6-28

Qian, Y. (1999) Institutional Foundations of China’s Market Transition, Annual


Conference on Development Economics, Washington, D.C., April 28-30, World Bank

Quirk, J and Ford, R. D. (1992) Pay Dirty: The Business of Professional Team Sport,
Princeton, NJ: University of Princeton Press

Rahman, S. S., Waddock, S., Andriof, J., Husted, B., (2003) Introduction in Andriof, J.,
Waddock, S., Husted, B., Rahman, S. S., (eds) Unfolding Stakeholder Thinking 2,
Sheffield: Greenleaf Publishing Limited

Ran, X (2008a) the Chinese Football Investigation – youth development, [Online]


(Undated 26 Sep 2008), Available at: http://ranxiongfei.bolg.sohu.com/100657692.html
[Accessed 02 Feb 2010]

Ran, X (2008b) the Chinese Football Investigation – Did the CFA destroy Chinese
football [Online] (Undated 29 Sep 2008), Available at:
http://ranxiongfei.blog.sohu.com/100944927.html [Accessed 02 Feb 2010]

317
Ranc, D. & Sonntag, A (2011) France: a case of UEFAisation? in Niemann, A., Garcia,
B. & Grant, W. (eds) The transformation of European football, Manchester University
Press, Manchester and New York

Reekie. S. (1999a) Mass fitness, in Riordan. J & Jones. R (eds) Sport and Physical
Education in China, London and New York: E & FN Spon

Reekie. S. (1999b) Administration of sports, in Riordan. J & Jones. R (eds) Sport and
Physical Education in China, London and New York: E & FN Spon

Remenyi, D., Williams, B., Money, A. & Swartz, A. (1998) Doing Research in Business
and Management: an introduction to process and method, London: Sage

Ren, H. (1999) China and the Olympic movement, in Riordan, J., & Jones, R. (eds)
Sports and Physical Education in China, London and New York: E & FN Spon

Rhodes, R (1997) Understanding Governance: Policy networks, governance, reflexivity


and accountability, Open University Press, Buckingham

Rowley, T. (1997) Moving beyond dyadic ties: a network theory of stakeholder influence,
Academy of Management Review, 22(4): 887-910

Rowley, T., & Berman, S. (2000) A brand new brand of corporate social performance,
Business and Society, 39: 397-418

Saisai Gong (2011) IMG wants to partner the Chinese Super League, dfdaily.com [Online]
(Updated 18 May 2011) Available at:
http://www.dfdaily.com/html/158/2011/5/18/606351.shtml [Accessed 14 November 2011]

318
Salomon Brothers (1997) UK Football Clubs: Valuable Asset? Global Equity Research:
Leisure, November, London: Salmon Brothers

Sandvoss, C. (2005) Fans, Cambridge & Malden: Polity Press

Saunders, M., Lewis, P., Thornhill, A. (2003) Research Methods for Business Students,
London: Pearson Education Limited

Schwandt, T. A. (2003) Three epistemological stances for qualitative inquiry’ in Denzin,


N & Lincoln, Y (eds) The Landscape of Qualitative Research, New York: Sage
Publications

Schweickart, D. (2006) Stakeholders and Terrorists: on Carol Gould’s Democratising


Globalisation and Human Rights, in Smith, T. & Van der Linda, H. (eds) Philosophy
Against Empire, Radical Philosophy Today, V.4 (Philosophical Documentation Centre)

Scott, S.G. & Lane, V.R. (2000) A stakeholder approach to organisational identity,
Academy of Management Review, 25(1): 43-62

Scully. G. (1995) The Market Structure of Sports, Chicago: University of Chicago Press

Sheridan, T. & Kendall, N. (1992) Corporate Governance: an action plan for profitability
and business success, London: Financial Times/Pitman

Shipman, M. (1998) The Limitation of Social Research, London: Longman

Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R. (1997) A survey of corporate governance, Journal of Finance


52(2): 737-783

Simons, R (2008) Bamboo Goalposts, London, Macmillan

319
Sinasport (2008) Do Athletes Belong to A Vulnerable Group? [On line] (Updated 15
October 2008), Available at: http://sports.sina.com.cn/n/2008-10-15/23144010868.shtml
[Accessed 10 January 2009]

Sloane, P. (1971) The economics of professional football: the football club as utility
maximiser, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 18(2): 121-146

Spencer, J. (1999) The Search for Modern China, 2nd edition, New York & London,
W.W.Norton & Company

Sports Law of the People’s Republic of China (1995) Beijing, Adopted by the Fifteenth
Session of the Standing Committee of the Eighth National People’s Congress on August
29

Stake, R. (1995) The Art of Case Study Research, Thousand Oaks, London: Sage

Sternberg, E. (1997) The defects of stakeholder theory, Corporate Governance, 5(1): 3-10

Steurer, R. (2006) Mapping stakeholder theory anew: from the ‘stakeholder theory of the
firm’ to three perspectives on business-society relations, Business Strategy and the
Environment, 15: 55-69

Su, C. (2009) Establishment and development of the Chinese economic legal system in
the past 60 years, Columbia Journal of Asian Law, 23: 109-115

Suchman, M. C. (1995) Managing legitimacy: strategic and institutional approaches,


Academy of Management Review, 20(3): 571-610

Sugden, J. (2002) Network football in Sugden, J & Tomlison, A. (eds) Power Games,
London: Routledge

320
Sundaram, A. K. & Inkpen, A. C. (2004) The cooperate objective revisited, Organisation
Science, 15(3): 350-363

Szymanski, S. (1997) The English football industry: profit, performance and industrial
structure, International Review of Applied Economics, 11(1):.135-153

Szymanski, S. & Hall, S. (2003) Making money out of football, The Business School,
Imperial College, London: Working Paper

Tam, O. K. (2000) Models of corporate governance for Chinese companies, Corporate


Governance, 8(1): 52-64

Taylor, Lord Justice (1990) The Hillsborough Stadium Disaster: Final Report, CM962,
London: HMSO

Taylor, R. (1992) Football And Its Fans, Leicester: Leicester University Press

Theodoraki, E. (2004) Sport management reform, national competitiveness and Olympic


glory in the People’s Republic of China, Management Leisure, 9: 193-211

Turnbull, S. (1997) Corporate governance: its scope, concerns and theories, Corporate
Governance, 5(4): 180-205

Turner, B. A. (1976) The organistion and interorganisational development of disaster.


Administrative Science Quarterly, 21: 378-97

Turner, B. A. (1978) Man-Made Disaster, London: Wykeham

Twydell, D. (1994) The Little Red book of Chinese Football, Harefield: Yore
Publications

321
The UK Corporate Governance Code (2010) Financial Reporting Council, London

Usher, R. (1997) Introduction, in Mckenzie, G, Powell, J. and Usher, R. (eds)


Understanding Social Research: perspectives on methodology and practices, London: The
Falmer Press

Walters, G. (`2007) Corporate Governance in the Football Industry: a Stakeholder


Analysis, PhD thesis, University of London

Wang, J (2004) Key Moments of the 12-year Professionalisation, [Online] (Updated Nov
2004) Available at: http://www.people.com.cn/GB/paper2086/13397/1200721.html
[Accessed 08 May 2009]

Waterman, R. & Meier, K. (1998) Principal-agent models: an expansion?, Journal of


Public Administration Research and Theory, J-Part 8: 173-202

Wheel, J (2011) Football Governance [Online] Available at:


http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201011/cmselect/cmcumeds/writev/792/fg1
5.htm [Accessed 09 August 2011]

Whitby, D. (1999) Elite sport in Riordan, J & Jones, R (eds) Sport and Physical
Education in China, London: E & FN Spon

Williams, M. (2003) Making Sense Of Social Research, London: Sage

Williams, M. & May, T. (1996) Introduction To The Philosophy Of Social Research,


London: UCL Press

World Bank (2005) World Development Indicators, World Bank, Washington DC

322
World Bank (2011) China Overview [On line] Available at:
http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/china/overview [Accessed 20 August 2011]

Wu, Zh & Q, Y. (1990) Organisational structure of China’s physical culture, in Knuttgen.


H. G, Ma. Q & Wu. Zh (eds) Sport in China, Champaign, IL: Human Kinetics Books

Wu, Zh. (1990) Development of competitive sports in Knuttgen, H. G, Ma, Q & Wu Zh


(eds) Sport in China, Champaign, IL: Human Kinetics Books

Xie, Q. (1990) Physical culture in the new China in Knuttgen, H. G, Ma, Q & Wu Zh
(eds) Sport in China, Champaign, IL: Human Kinetics Books

Xu, L. C; Zhu, T. & Lin, Y. (2005) Political control, agency problems and ownership
reform, Economics of Transitions, 13(1): 1-24

Yan, S. (2004) Yan Shize’s Official Speech at the National Leagues’ Conference. In
National Leagues’ Conference, Beijing, 5 March 2004, the CFA Beijing

Yang. H, Sun. Sh & Shu. W (2004) Upholding and Further the Whole – the National
System for Competitive Sports in China, Journal of Beijing Sport University, 27 (5), May

Yang, Y (2003) Ten Years of Jia A League, A Grim Situation for the Olympic Team
[Online] (Updated 12 December 2003) Available at:
http://sports.people.com.cn/GB/channel2/507/1111/2813/20031212/194671.html
[Accessed 12 December 2008]

Yang, Y. (2004) Yang Yimin’s Official Speech at the National Leagues’ Conference. In
National Leagues’ Conference, Beijing, 5 March 2004, the CFA Beijing

Yang, Y. (2005) Work Report of the Chinese Super League, Beijing, 25 February, the
Super League Committee of the CFA, Beijing

323
Yin, R. (1984) Case Study Research: Design And Methods, Newbury Park, CA: Sage.

Yin, K. Y. (2003) Application Of Case Study Research, 2nd edition, Applied social
research method series, Vol. 34, London: Sage

Young, A (2010) Regulating Corporate Governance in China and Hong Kong: Do


Chinese values and ethics have a place in the age of Globalisation, The Fifth Annual
Conference of the Asian Studies Association of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, 8-9 January,
University of Hong Kong

Zhang, B. (2005) China’s “peaceful rise” to great-power status, Foreign Affairs, 84(5):
Sep/Oct

Zhang, X. Xing, L. Zhou, Y. Tan, J. Wang, X. Zhang, Q. Li, J. Wan, C. Tang, F. and
Wang, Y (2006) Research into the System of Professional Football Clubs (Published 15
November 2006) Available at:
http://www.sport.gov.cn/n16/n1152/n2523/n377568/n377613/n377703/392493.html
[Accessed 30 November 2010]

Zhou, Zh. (1997) Analysis of the transfer phenomenon in Chinese professional football,
Sports Technology, 18(1-2): 16-19

324
List of Interviews
Zhu Qilin – Chairman of the CSL, 23/05/13
Song Xiaochun – Chief Financial Officer of the CFA and CSL, 23/05/13
Yang Peng – Former CEO, a Board Member of Fujian Junhao FC, 29/09/12
Yu Zhen – Player of Fujian Junhao FC, 30/09/12
Hong Atuo – Chairman of Fujian Minmo Fan Association, 30/09/12
Li Hong – CEO of Shenzhen FC, 20/08/12
Liu Shuai – Player of Shenzhen FC, 02/08/12
Sun Zhimin – President of Shenzhen Fan Association, 20/07/13
Wei Haili – Assistant coach of Shenzhen FC, ex-player, 08/07/12
Zhang Jilong – Senior Vice President (Acting President) of AFC, 20/04/12
Lang Xiaonong – Former Head of the CFA League Department, former CEO of the
League Company, 03/09/08
Cao Liang –Assistant to CEO, Marketing Director of Beijing Guoan FC, 03/09/08
Tao Wei – Captain of Beijing Guoan FC, 02/09/08
Wei Kexing – Vice General Manager of Beijing Guoan FC & a former player, 02/09/08
Lu Chang – Former player, academy coach of Shanghai Shenhua FC, 31/08/08
Jin Zhiyang88 – Professor, Head Coach of Beijing Institute of Technology, 08/08/08
Meng Ran - President of Beijing Green Strom Fan Association, 07/08/08
Tang Jing – Player of Changchun Yatai FC, 04/08/08
Liu Yuming – President & CEO of Changchun Yatai FC, 02/08/08
Yu Fuzhi - Vice Chairman of Changchun Fan Association, 01/08/08
Sun Changlong - President of Shenyan Fan Association, 30/07/08
Sui Yan – Deputy General Manager of Liaoning FC, 28/07/08
Yuan Haishan - President of Henan Jianye Football Fan Union, 09/07/08
Zhou Xiaobo – Chief Assistant of CEO, Henan Jianye FC, 09/07/08
Yuan Qiyou - Chairman of Jiangshu Sainty Yuangyou Fan Association, 07/07/08
Zheng Ming – Vice General Manager of Jiangsu Sainty FC, 07/07/08
Jin Yan – CEO of Changsha Ginde FC, 06/07/08

88
Mr Jin was coaching the National Team and Beijng Guoan FC at the late 1990s, he is also a senior
consultant for the CFA.

325
Zhang Xiaobin89 – Player of Changsha Ginde FC, 05/07/08
Hu Ge (Brother Hu) – President of Changsha Red Pepper Fan Association, 04/07/08
Ning Zhixiong – CEO of Guangzhou Zhongyi FC, 30/06/08
Li Zhihai – Captain of Guangzhou Zhongyi FC, 30/06/08
Zhang Defa – General Manager of Shanghai Shenhua FC, 18/01/08
Hu Wei – Chief Assistant of CEO, shanghai Shenhua FC, 18/01/08
Zuo Xiudi – Vice Director of Competition Department, Shanghai FA, 17/01/08
Li Lipeng – Chief Officer of the CFA’s League Department, 10/01/08
Duan lian – Commercial Director of Beijing Institute of Technology, 09/01/08
Han Gongzheng - Deputy General Manager of Luneng Taishan FC, 05/01/08

89
Played in England with Stock Port and played in Australian Super League.

326

You might also like