Untitled
Untitled
Untitled
SPECULATION
Q
ii
SPECULATION
Q
A HISTORY OF THE FINE LINE
BETWEEN GAMBLING
AND INVESTING
S TUART B ANNER
1
iv
1
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers
the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education
by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University
Press in the UK and certain other countries.
1 3 5 7 9 8 6 4 2
Printed by Sheridan Books, Inc., United States of America
C ON T E N T S
q
Acknowledgmentsâ•… vii
Abbreviationsâ•… ix
Introductionâ•… 1
1.╇ The Land of Speculation╅ 6
2.╇ Betting on Prices╅ 56
3.╇ The Anti-╉Option Era╅ 105
4.╇ Selling Blue Sky╅ 138
5.╇ Aftershocks of the Crash╅ 164
6.╇ Land and Onions╅ 218
7.╇ Inside Information╅ 241
8.╇ Speculation or Investment?╅ 279
9.╇ Deregulation and Crisis?╅ 307
Indexâ•… 331
v
vi
AC K NOW L E D G M E N T S
q
For advice on drafts of chapters, thanks to Iman Anabtawi, Steve
Bainbridge, Steve Bank, James Park, and participants in workshops at
the University of Minnesota, UNLV, and UCLA. For help with the re-
search, thanks to the librarians at the UCLA School of Law and the ar-
chivists at the Franklin D. Roosevelt Presidential Library, the Harvard
Law Library, the Herbert Hoover Presidential Library, the John
F. Kennedy Presidential Library, the Library of Congress, the Morgan
Library, the New York Stock Exchange, the University of Illinois at
Chicago, the University of Virginia, the Wisconsin Historical Society,
and Yale University.
vii
viii
A BBR E V I AT IONS
q
AAB Adolf A. Berle papers, Franklin D. Roosevelt Presidential
Library, Hyde Park, New York
AS Alexander Sachs papers, Franklin D. Roosevelt Presidential
Library, Hyde Park, New York
CBT Chicago Board of Trade records, Special Collections,
University of Illinois at Chicago
CG Carter Glass papers, Albert and Shirley Small Special
Collections Library, University of Virginia
FDR Franklin D. Roosevelt papers as president, Franklin
D. Roosevelt Presidential Library, Hyde Park, New York
FF Felix Frankfurter papers, Manuscript Division, Library of
Congress, Washington, DC
GEA George E. Akerson papers, Herbert Hoover Presidential
Library, West Branch, Iowa
HHL Hoover Presidential files, Herbert Hoover Presidential
Library, West Branch, Iowa
HPPF Hoover Post-Presidential files, Herbert Hoover Presidential
Library, West Branch, Iowa
JML-HLS James McCauley Landis papers, Harvard Law School
Library, Cambridge, Massachusetts
JML-LC James McCauley Landis papers, Manuscript Division,
Library of Congress, Washington, DC
ix
x
x Abbreviations
SPECULATION
Q
xii
Introduction
1
2
2 Speculation
The issue is particularly salient today, when many argue that the
recent financial crisis was caused by overspeculation, and that the way
to prevent a recurrence is to prohibit certain risky transactions. Others
respond by citing the benefits of robust markets and the dangers of
overregulation. This book shows that this debate has been a perennial
feature of our history, and that many of the same arguments have been
made, on both sides, after every financial downturn since the 1790s.
Ambivalence about speculation can be found in the slipperiness of
the word itself, which is notoriously hard to pin down.2 Americans have
offered competing definitions for two centuries, without coming any
closer to agreement. Sometimes “speculation” is a pejorative term, im-
plying that a speculator is someone engaging in unsavory conduct, as
distinguished from an investor or a businessperson. Sometimes it is used
in a morally neutral sense. And sometimes “speculation” is a term used
with approval, often to distinguish the speculator from the gambler.
The difficulty in distinguishing the good risky transactions from the
bad, and thus the difficulty in figuring out how to regulate speculators,
has been caused by genuine substantive disagreement about the pros
and cons of particular sorts of transactions. Should people be allowed
to risk their fortunes and the welfare of their families by buying assets
solely for the purpose of selling them later at a higher price? Should
they be allowed to sell assets they don’t yet own, in the hopes of prof-
iting from a decline in the assets’ value? Should they be allowed to
buy and sell complex financial derivatives? Questions like these have
constantly been asked throughout American history. The conflicting
answers have been driven in part by differences in opinion about the
economic consequences of particular transactions and in part by differ-
ences in moral views as to the propriety of particular forms of conduct.
Introduction 3
4 Speculation
Introduction 5
4 Alexander Hamilton to William Seton, 4 Apr. 1792, Harold C. Syrett et al.,
eds., The Papers of Alexander Hamilton (New York: Columbia University Press,
1961–87), 11:225–26; Thomas Jefferson to David Humphreys, 9 Apr. 1792, Julian
P. Boyd et al., eds., The Papers of Thomas Jefferson (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press, 1950–), 23:386–87; Nathaniel Hazard to John Adams, 16 Apr.
1792, Founders Online, National Archives (founders.archives.gov/documents/
Adams/99-02-02-1337).
1
Q
The Land of Speculation
6
╇ 7
8 Speculation
4 Francis J. Grund, The Americans, in Their Moral, Social, and Political Relations
(Boston: Marsh, Capen and Lyon, 1837), 240–41; Harriet Martineau, Society in
America (London: Saunders and Otley, 1837), 1:350; Michel Chevalier, Society,
Manners and Politics in the United States (Boston: Weeks, Jordan and Co., 1839),
305; Isaac Fidler, Observations on Professions, Literature, Manners, and Emigration,
in the United States and Canada (New York: J. & J. Harper, 1833), 76.
5 Alexis de Tocqueville, Democracy in America (1835– 40), ed. Harvey C.
Mansfield and Delba Winthrop (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000),
528; Chevalier, Society, Manners and Politics, 309; Frederick Marryat, Diary in
America (1839), ed. Jules Zanger (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1960),
137; William Priest, Travels in the United States of America (London: J. Johnson,
1802), 132.
9
6 Charles G. Haines, Substance of Mr. Haines’ Remarks, Made at the City Hotel
(New York: William A. Mercein, 1823), 9; Auctions Inconsistent with Regular Trade
(New York: Van Winkle, Wiley & Co., 1817), 4; “Merchants and Speculators,”
The Round Table 9 (1869): 294; Letter on the Use and Abuse of Incorporations
(New York: G. & C. Carvill, 1827), 23; New-Bedford Mercury, 15 Apr. 1825, 3.
10
10 Speculation
been more fully shown than in the United States.” But this was hardly
a universal view. James Kent, one of the leading judges of the early
republic, recalled that there was no shortage of speculation in Europe
either. “The dreams and the madness of speculation,” he concluded, “is
a disease which has prevailed on each side of the Atlantic.”7
The primary commodity in which early Americans speculated was
land. There was plenty of it; it came in all kinds, from small parcels of
developed land in eastern cities to vast and scarcely populated western
territories; and its prices fluctuated, sometimes quite sharply. As Charles
Francis Adams complained, “the great object of domestic speculation in
America is undoubtedly land.” When lots were sold in the new capital
city of Washington, according to Justice Hugh Henry Brackenridge of
the Pennsylvania Supreme Court, most of the initial purchases “were
on the speculation of an under sale to others, before the money was
paid” by the ostensible buyer. Up in Maine, reported the promoter
Moses Greenleaf, many of the landholders were nonresident specula-
tors, who “purchased with a view of retaining the land for a time, in
expectation of immense profits from the sale, when the country about
them should become improved, and peopled by the exertions of others,
without any trouble of their own.” Affluent and prominent Americans
pooled their capital to form land companies, some of the largest busi-
ness enterprises of the era, to buy enormous swaths of land in the West
in the hope that future settlement would make the land more valuable.
Land was simply a smart investment, advised the French lawyer J. P.
Brissot de Warville, who took a close look at the land market while
touring the new nation in 1788. Rather than putting money in a bank
to provide for one’s children, Brissot suggested, “nothing appears to me
better to answer this wise precaution, than to place such money on the
cultivated soil of the United States.”8
Contemporaries had little doubt that the United States was very dif-
ferent from Europe in this regard. “In Europe the value of real estate is
in general comparatively stationary,” explained the chemist Robert Hare,
“but here it is always an article of speculation; and as a large portion,
while unproductive, is still held with a view to its future value, the es-
timate put upon that value is liable to great changes.” In Britain, noted
Massachusetts Chief Justice Isaac Parker, no one owned sections of forest
far away from their homes. “In this country, on the contrary,” he ob-
served, “there are many large tracts of uncultivated territory owned by
individuals who have no intention of reducing them to a state of im-
provement, but consider them rather as subjects of speculation and sale.”
It was because of “the unrestrained spirit of speculation,” agreed William
Tilghman, the chief justice of Pennsylvania’s Supreme Court, that “we see
freehold estates pass in rapid circulation from owner to owner.”9
Financial assets soon became a second big area of speculation, first
with the issuance of state and national public debt securities to finance
the American Revolution, then with the sale of US debt securities in
the early 1790s, and finally with the steady expansion, all through the
early republic, of the market for shares in banks and other business cor-
porations. “Stockjobbing drowns every other subject,” James Madison
complained in 1791, shortly after shares of the Bank of the United States
were first sold to the public. In New York, he reported, “the Coffee
House is in an eternal buzz with the gamblers.” Henry Lee traveled from
Philadelphia to Alexandria, Virginia, around the same time and discov-
ered that “my whole rout[e]presented to me one continued scene of
stock gambling; agriculture commerce & even the fair sex relinquished,
for Rent, 1785–1850 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1989), 183–212; Charles
Francis Adams, Reflections Upon the Present State of the Currency in the United
States (Boston: Ezra Lincoln, 1837), 21; Stoddart v. Smith, 5 Binn. 355 (Pa. 1812);
Moses Greenleaf, A Statistical View of the District of Maine (Boston: Cummings
and Hilliard, 1816), 92; Shaw Livermore, Early American Land Companies: Their
Influence on Corporate Development (New York: Commonwealth Fund, 1939);
J. P. Brissot de Warville, New Travels in the United States of America (Boston:
Joseph Bumstead, 1797), 41.
9 Robert Hare, An Effort to Refute the Opinion, That No Addition Is Made to the
Capital of a Community by Banking (s.l.: s.n., 1834); Conner v. Shepherd, 15 Mass.
164 (1818); Jack v. Shoemaker, 3 Binn. 280 (Pa. 1810).
12
12 Speculation
14 Speculation
16 Speculation
future lord chancellor) Thomas Erskine agreed that gambling “is from
the very beginning a sordid, ungenerous, dishonest passion.” American
ministers had long decried gambling as an especially grievous sin. “It
is not easy to conceive any vice more hateful to God than Gambling,”
screamed the itinerant minister Mason Locke Weems in all upper-case
letters, “because none can be conceived more diametrically op-
posite to the very end of our creation!” Secular critics emphasized
that gambling led inexorably to idleness and financial ruin, and often
to madness and even suicide. Calling speculation a kind of gambling
was a shorthand way of summoning up all these dire consequences.
“Speculation and Gambling,” mused one journalist—“on many oc-
casions, these words are synonymous—and on some, there is another
which has nearly the same meaning—to wit, roguery. Sometimes, per-
haps also, insanity may convey nearly a similar idea.”16
Like gambling, speculation was widely viewed as immoral and un-
christian. This was a common theme in the religious press. “Speculation
is contrary to the spirit of Christianity and a great hindrance to the
spread of the gospel throughout the world,” declared the Religious
Intelligencer. The Episcopal Recorder maintained that “it is our duty not
to sanction the pursuit of wealth through the medium of speculation,”
18 Speculation
into distress and ruin[?]” Learned treatises and popular advice manu-
als alike advised the uninitiated to avoid speculating, lest they plunge
themselves and their families into poverty. The French Duke de la
Rochefoucault, traveling through the United States in the 1790s, wor-
ried that middling farmers were losing their farms—ironically, after an
especially plentiful harvest—because they had been speculating in crop
prices, which fell due to the increase in supply. Speculation was dan-
gerous even for those who could afford to lose the most, warned John
Bannister Gibson, Pennsylvania’s long-serving chief justice. “We know
from experience,” he cautioned, “that when a spirit of speculation, or
desire of inordinate gain, infects the rich, it terminates in scenes of ruin
and devastation, as wide spread and deplorable in their consequences
of misery and want, in the domestic relations of life, as if it had been
confined to those who had comparatively little to lose.”18
Other critics focused not on speculation’s economic effects but on its
moral and psychological implications. The problem was not that specu-
lation made people poorer, but that it made them selfish and imprudent.
By enabling one person to gain at the expense of another, one correspon-
dent charged, speculation “tends to dissolve that natural tie, that binds
man to man.” As they grew accustomed to cheating, another alleged,
“speculators have been generally strangers to mercantile habits, to mer-
cantile accuracy and rectitude.” The stereotype of the speculator was one
who thought only of his own profit and would not hesitate to take ad-
vantage of others. As the poet Philip Freneau depicted him in the 1790s,
18 New Jersey Journal, 10 Aug. 1791, 3; A Peep Into the Banks (New York: Vanderpool
& Cole, 1828), 29; Francis Wayland, The Elements of Political Economy
(New York: Leavitt, Lord & Co., 1837), 379; Hints to Young Tradesmen
(Boston: Perkins & Marvin, 1838), 51; “Commercial Chronicle and Review,”
Merchants’ Magazine 28 (1853): 466–67; Duke de la Rochefoucault Liancourt,
Travels Through the United States of North America, 2nd ed. (London: R. Phillips,
1800), 1:242–43; Seidenbender v. Charles’s Administrators, 4 Serg. & Rawle 151
(Pa. 1818).
19
The printer Asa Greene summed up this line of thought in his account
of New York’s commercial life, a book he subtitled A Taste of the Dangers
of Wall Street. “The more a man engages in speculation,” Greene argued,
“the less tender his conscience grows on the subject of doing to others
as he would have them do to him. So debasing are the arts and shifts
which are too apt to prevail in a mercantile community.”19
Speculation did not just make people meaner, on this view; it also
made them turn to lives of luxury and vice. The young Clement Clarke
Moore, who as an older man would become better known for the poem
“A Visit from St. Nicholas,” condemned “a spirit of speculation which
tends, not to advance the permanent good of the society at large, but
to the introduction of that luxury and dissipation which pervades our
sea-ports.” The scientist William Maclure agreed that speculation had
the effect of “increasing luxury, dissipation and vice, by introducing an
artificial anticipation of riches.”20
Meanwhile, speculation made people unhappy and unpleasant.
Speculative emotions in business “are transfused from the counting-
house to the fire-side,” one critic charged. “The visionary profits of one
day stimulate extravagance, and the positive losses of another engender
spleen, irritation, restlessness, a spirit of gambling and domestic inqui-
etude.” What is the “difference between speculation and honesty?” an-
other asked. “Honesty is modest, humble, distant and reserved,” while
“speculation is forward, froward, bullying, hectoring and insinuating.”
The reason, according to one rural newspaper, was that “a Speculator
appears surrounded by wants, when in fact he wants Nothing. He too
frequently grasps at what he cannot get.”21
20 Speculation
22 Speculation
27 William Beach Lawrence, Two Lectures on Political Economy (New York: G. &
C. & H. Carvill, 1832), 63–64; Federal Gazette [Philadelphia], 25 Apr. 1792, 3;
Timothy Dwight, Travels; in New England and New York (New Haven, Conn.:
Timothy Dwight, 1821), 1:218; Bayard Tuckerman, ed., The Diary of Philip
Hone 1828–1851 (New York: Dodd, Mead and Co., 1889), 1:251.
24
24 Speculation
26 Speculation
28 Speculation
Emerson. “How did our factories get built?” Emerson asked. “How
did North America get netted with iron rails, except by the impor-
tunity of these orators who dragged all the prudent men in? Is party
the madness of many for the gain of a few? This speculative genius is
the madness of a few for the gain of the world. The projectors are
sacrificed, but the public is the gainer.”35
To encourage investment (which was universally acknowledged to be
good) while discouraging speculation (which was often said to be bad),
one would need to distinguish between the two. Contemporaries sug-
gested several ways to draw the line separating investment and industry
from speculation and gambling. One possibility was to draw a line be-
tween investors who had a long-term interest in the success of a venture
and those who had no such interest but were merely hoping to sell after
a short-term rise in the value of an asset. Alexander Hamilton seems to
have been groping toward this distinction between two types of holders
of the national debt in its early bubbly days. “’Tis time there should be
a line of separation,” he insisted, “between respectable stockholders and
dealers in the funds, and mere unprincipled Gamblers.”36 Hamilton’s
meaning was not entirely clear, but his separation of “stockholders”
from “Gamblers” suggests a difference between those who invested in
the federal government out of patriotic motives, or at least an interest
in the long-run welfare of the United States, and those who invested in
the debt just to make money in the short run.
Another distinction that could be drawn was between people who
bought an asset because they actually wanted to use the asset itself
and those who bought the asset only because they hoped to be able
to sell it later for a higher price. Congressman Gulian Verplanck
drew this distinction in his treatise on the law of contracts. In his
30 Speculation
never venture their all like gamesters, they try their fortunes again;
the latter hope to win by chance alone, the former by industry, well-
judged speculation, and some hazard.” The same line was drawn by
the commercial moralist John Frost, who sought to confine the term
speculation to “incurring extensive hazards of any kind in the hope of
extensive emolument; in short, to whatever is foreign to the proper
business of the individual.”39 On this view, there was nothing wrong
with the inherent risks of a conventional business venture. It was only
when the risk was larger than normal that it should be condemned as
overly speculative.
A final possibility was to distinguish between positive-sum and zero-
sum transactions, and to condemn only the latter. “There are two ways
of acquiring wealth, not only essentially different, but as opposite to
each other as east is opposite to west,” the Mechanics’ Magazine lec-
tured its younger readers. “One of these ways may be properly denomi-
nated enterprise, the other speculation. The first of these ways creates the
wealth it accumulates by bringing into existence the articles of which it
is composed, or by increasing the value of articles which existed before;
the other draws the wealth, generally, by some kind of deception or
delusive practices, out of the possession of its right owner, without in-
creasing its value, or adding anything to the public stock.” The maga-
zine had no doubt which was better. “The first of these modes is honest
and highly laudable,” readers were advised, but the second is “wholly
dishonest, and subversive to the peace and happiness of mankind, be-
cause in the same ratio that it makes one richer it makes others poorer.”
The Princeton Review drew the same distinction, between “normal
trade,” in which the trader was compensated for performing some
useful function like transporting a commodity from the producer to
the consumer, and speculation, in which the trader performed no such
function but merely hoped to profit from a change in the price. Even
where they were equally risky, the risks of normal trade were inherent
32 Speculation
42 Legislative and Documentary History of the Bank of the United States (Washington,
D.C.: Gales and Seaton, 1832), 519; General Advertiser [Philadelphia], 23 Mar.
1792, 2.
43 Selected Speeches of John Sergeant, of Pennsylvania (Philadelphia: E. L. Carey &
A. Hart, 1832), 164.
34
34 Speculation
flow of the sea, or direct the course of the whirlwind,” despaired the
playwright and journalist Mordecai Noah, “as to say who shall, or who
shall not speculate.”44
The difficulty of distinguishing gambling from commerce was not
necessarily a reason to refrain from regulating speculation. “If there
be a want of precision in defining the thing condemned, it arises from
the very nature of the case,” one editorialist reasoned. “It is one which
admits of no precise and infallible rules. There are instances where the
evil is so palpable, that every eye can see it; but between this point
and the point of departure from legitimate business, there is an infi-
nite variety of abuses.” “Let us not,” another agreed, “confound reckless
speculation and commercial pursuits in the same category.” While there
might be a blurry line between them, “they are in truth ‘wide as the
poles asunder.’ ” If “it would perhaps be difficult, in some cases,” to dis-
tinguish legitimate from illegitimate speculation, a third insisted, “there
are nevertheless certain broad distinctions between the two classes of
operations.”45
But others concluded that even if some speculation should, in prin-
ciple, be prohibited, it would be impossible for the law to ban the bad
without also sweeping away the good. “Speculation in paper hath been
a kind of gambling,” one observer lamented, but there was nothing
the law could do about it. “It is not possible,” he explained, for the
government to inspect “all the private bargains of jockies, speculators
and dunces—No rule of right can be ascertained” for separating the
permissible from the impermissible. And even if it could be done, he
continued, the cost would far exceed the benefits: “The expence of at-
tempting it would bring a new debt on the country, ten fold greater
than all the savings which can be made.” Speculators would have to be
left to their own devices. “One quarter of the bargains made are detri-
mental to one, and some of them to both parties,” he concluded. “They
were made in folly, but for national policy particularly to inspect them
would be greater folly, and a most unmanageable and endless business.”
People entered into all kinds of transactions in all kinds of commodi-
ties at all kinds of prices, another agreed. How could one ever figure
out which transactions were too speculative? “Even at this time there
is an extensive speculation all over the country in the article of bread
stuffs, and advantage is taken of the necessities of consumers to demand
exorbitant prices,” he pointed out. “Does the law afford any relief? And
what relief could it afford? Would you annul contracts between land-
lord and tenant, because the rents were excessive?”46 If the law could
not draw a line between the speculation that should be allowed and the
speculation that should be prohibited, the wisest course was to refrain
from limiting speculation at all.
Some took the argument a step further. Not only was speculation
inseparable from ordinary commercial life, they contended, but specu-
lation was also a positive good in its own right. One early proponent of
this view was Alexander Hamilton, who had to justify speculation while
responding to criticism of his financial program, a key part of which
was the issuance of debt securities that were the primary speculative
assets in the bubble and crash of 1791–92. Just after the crash, Thomas
Jefferson wrote a long letter to George Washington summing up his
complaints about Hamilton’s policies. One of Jefferson’s critiques was
his characteristically negative view of the buying and selling of securi-
ties. “All the capital employed in paper speculation is barren and useless,
producing, like that on a gaming table, no accession to itself,” Jefferson
argued. The capital spent on speculation “is withdrawn from commerce
and agriculture where it would have produced addition to the common
mass,” he continued. Instead, “it nourishes in our citizens habits of vice
and idleness instead of industry and morality.” Washington promptly
wrote to Hamilton to hear his response. (Although Washington did not
specify whose critique he was quoting—he referred only to his efforts
“to learn from sensible & moderate men … the sentiments which are
36 Speculation
true, that Stock operates as Capital, the effect upon the Citizens at large
is different. It promotes among them industry by furnishing a larger
field of employment.”48
Hamilton was defending a broad financial program, of which pro-
viding the material for speculation was just a part, but others made
the same point while offering more specific defenses of speculation in
its own right. Speculation did not reduce the amount of capital in the
productive economy, one correspondent insisted, but rather increased
that amount. “Speculators neither bury nor export their money,” he
pointed out. “On the contrary, they continually circulate it.” To be
sure, speculation was liable to abuse, but so was anything. “Honor and
religion—everything that is useful, noble or virtuous, may be abused.
Ought they therefore to be condemned or avoided? No, certainly.” And
while speculators might harm themselves, argued the Reverend Cyrus
Mason of New York University, by spurring economic activity, they
indirectly helped others. Mason was speaking just after the bursting
of the mulberry tree bubble of the 1830s. (Silkworms live in mulberry
trees, and the prospect of a domestic silk industry gave rise to overin-
vestment in mulberry trees.) “When the fever of speculation has gone
by, and the laughers at speculation have had their turn, the mulberry
trees will be found growing in vast numbers all over the face of this
country,” Mason affirmed. “And when there has been time to mature
their growth, the business will be found attractive and profitable.” He
looked back at the Merino sheep bubble of a few years earlier, when the
collapse of wool prices had left farmers throughout the northern states
with a glut of sheep. “The fever had its course, and the laughers their
fun,” Mason recalled, “but the improved breed of sheep remains, the
public revenue from imported fine wool and cloth has been reduced,
and a rich blessing to our country has been the result.”49
A second common defense of speculation was that it provided the
useful service of deepening markets. It was widely recognized in the
38 Speculation
late eighteenth century that speculators in any kind of asset made non-
speculators more willing to hold that asset, and thus made the asset
more valuable, because the speculators stood ready to buy and sell
at any time. “As to Stock-jobbers he saw no reason for the censures
thrown upon them,” Elbridge Gerry remarked at the Constitutional
Convention. “They keep up the value of the paper. Without them there
would be no market.” Robert Morris, one of the leading speculators of
the era, agreed that “even if it were possible to prevent Speculation, it is
precisely the Thing which ought not to be prevented; because he who
wants Money to commence, pursue or extend his Business, is more
benefited by selling Stock of any kind (even at a considerable Discount)
than he could be by the Rise of it at a future Period.”50 On this view,
speculators reduced the risk of investment, because an investor could
have some confidence that someone would step up to buy in the event
he needed to sell.
Another justification of speculation became common in the first half
of the nineteenth century. Speculators, some argued, stabilized prices,
by buying when the market was low and selling when it was high.
“When the price has very much declined,” Willard Phillips reasoned,
“those who suppose it to be verging on its lowest point, and about to
seek again its natural level, the mean cost, naturally use their funds and
credit in purchasing, to take advantage of the change.” By boosting
demand, speculators reversed the decline in prices. “Speculations may
have the effect of limiting the vibrations of price within narrower ex-
tremes,” Phillips continued, “for if a great quantity be withdrawn from
a declining market, it may cause a rise, and the same quantity being
thrown onto a rising market may accelerate the change to a decline
of the price.” Speculators thus helped their fellow participants in the
economy. “As far as speculation has these effects it is useful,” Phillips
concluded, “since extremes and irregular fluctuations of price, are fol-
lowed by embarrassments and bankruptcies, by which the community
at large suffers.” By the same mechanism, others suggested, speculators
40 Speculation
53 Village Register and Norfolk County Advertiser, 27 Apr. 1821, 1; “High Prices—╉
Speculation,” New-╉Yorker 2 (1837): 345.
54 Richard Hildreth, The History of Banks (Boston: Hilliard, Gray & Co., 1837),
77; National Era, 29 July 1847, 4; “Lucius” to Robert Morris, 12 Mar. 1783,
in Papers of Robert Morris, 7:561; Scott A. Sandage, Born Losers: A History of
Failure in America (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2005).
41
42 Speculation
were simply too speculative to be enforced, and he decided that this was
one of them. Hanson concluded that a “court ought not to give its aid
towards enforcing the specific performance of any speculating engage-
ments.” Rather than ordering Wright to convey the land to Perkins, he
ordered Wright to give Perkins his money back. “A speculating contract
for continental money,” Hanson explained in a case involving a similar
transaction, “is such a contract as this court has again and again said it
will not enforce.”57
Other early American judges, however, took a more benign view of
speculative transactions. In November 1791, John Wilkes agreed to buy
US “stock” (what we would today call bonds) from Robert Gilchreest
ten months later, in September 1792. The stock’s value dropped in the
interim, a period encompassing the crash of 1792, so when Gilchreest
delivered it to Wilkes in September, Wilkes refused to pay. The
Pennsylvania Supreme Court had little trouble finding the contract
enforceable. “The sale of stock is neither unlawful nor immoral,” the
court declared. “It is confessed, that an inordinate spirit of speculation
approaches to gaming, and tends to corrupt the morals of the people.
When the public mind is thus affected, it becomes the legislature to
interpose. But we have no such law at present.” The risk that prices
might rise or fall was inherent in virtually all transactions, the court
noted. “Call the 6 per cent. stock so many bushels of wheat,” the court
asked: “if it had fallen in price on the day of delivery, and the vendor
was then ready and willing, and offered to perform his contract in all
parts, ought not the principal or his surety to make him full compensa-
tion? If the wheat had risen in price, would not the adverse party be
enabled to get like compensation, in case the vendor had receded from
his bargain?”58 If risk was a normal part of commercial life, judges had
no basis for distinguishing lawful transactions from those too specula-
tive to enforce.
This became the prevailing view in the early nineteenth century. In
1803, for example, Virginia’s Supreme Court of Appeals considered the
57 Perkins v. Wright, 3 H. & McH. 324 (Md. Ct. App. 1793); Hopkins v. Stump, 2
H. & J. 301 (Md. Ct. App. 1808) (Hanson decided this case in 1804 and died
in 1806; the Court of Appeals affirmed his decision in 1808).
58 Gilchreest v. Pollock, 2 Yeates 18 (Pa. 1795).
44
44 Speculation
59 Brachan v. Griffin, 7 Va. 433 (1803); Ridgely v. Riggs, 4 H. & J. 358 (Md. Ct.
App. 1818).
45
46 Speculation
begin to tax the public debt, when we are afraid to tax snuff, is a bad
omen.” This proposed tax was approved by a committee of the whole
House, but it was then added to a long list of other taxes that were
rejected as a package. In 1834, a committee of the New York Assembly
condemned “the great and palpable evils attendant upon the exist-
ing system of buying and selling stocks in the city of New-York,” a
system that in the committee’s view “gives rise to a spirit of gambling
which is carried out to an alarming extent.” Nothing came of this
report. But other states imposed limits on speculative transactions.
Pennsylvania and Maryland voided all futures contracts for the sale of
securities where the delivery date would be more than five days after
the contract date. Several states required shareholders to own stock
for a certain minimum period before selling it, to encourage long-
term investment while discouraging short-term speculation. Some
states restricted the amount of shares that could be purchased in a
single day, to make it harder for one person to buy large quantities.
The federal government repeatedly tried to discourage speculation in
public land, through such methods as limiting the amount a single
person could purchase and requiring grantees to reside on the land.62
These were all efforts to ban a narrow range of the most speculative
transactions without tramping too heavily on commercial activity
considered more legitimate.
American law governing risky transactions thus distinguished, at
an early date, between gambling and speculation. Transactions classi-
fied as wagers were presumed unenforceable, with certain exceptions.
Transactions classified as speculation, by contrast, were presumed en-
forceable, again with certain exceptions. As historians have pointed out,
the difference between the two categories was never completely stable,
and it drew in part on a class distinction between the socially accept-
able risks taken by respectable members of society and the less polite
62 Seth Ames, ed., Works of Fisher Ames (Boston: Little, Brown and Co.,
1854), 1:141; Documents of the Assembly of the State of New-York, Fifty-
Seventh Session (Albany, N.Y.: E. Croswell, 1834), No. 339; Banner,
Anglo-American Securities Regulation, 222–2 6; Paul W. Gates, History of
Public Land Law Development (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing
Office, 1968).
47
risks taken by those on the margins.63 But the difference between gam-
bling and speculation was not entirely a matter of class, and it was not
entirely void of substance. It was based on a perception, apparently
widely shared among the managers of the legal system, that risk was
tolerable as a means to some greater end, but that it was not a worth-
while end in itself. In the transactions proscribed as “wagers”—bets on
horse races, card games, and the like—there was no purpose beyond
the participants’ enjoyment of the risk itself. The transactions called
“speculation,” on the other hand, involved some other useful societal
end, even if the risks associated with speculation were indistinguishable
from the risks associated with gambling. Speculation in trade made
society richer, even if it made half the speculators poorer. Speculation
in shares gave rise to valuable new enterprises, even if it beggared some
of the shareholders. The line between speculation and gambling was
often difficult to draw with precision, but this seems to have been the
intuition behind the view that some such line had to be drawn.
Insurance provides the clearest early example. Marine insurance was
already common by the late eighteenth century. It looked a lot like
gambling: the insured would pay a small sum, and if the ship went
down, he would receive a large payoff from the insurer. As Judge Jacob
Peck of the Tennessee Supreme Court wondered, gaming “depends
upon hazard and chance; so do all insurances depend upon hazard
and chance. What is the difference?” Yet insurance also served a useful
purpose. Insurance was “much for the benefit and extension of trade,”
William Blackstone explained in his commentaries on English law, “by
distributing the loss or gain among a number of adventurers.”64
English law accordingly adopted the concept of the “insurable inter-
est,” which permitted people to buy insurance only if they themselves
48 Speculation
would bear a loss if the ship failed to arrive. Insurance policies on other
people’s voyages were unenforceable, because they “were very justly
considered as mere gaming or wager-policies,” declared the barrister
James Park in his treatise on insurance. American law followed suit.
“Wager policies … though dressed up in the garb of insurance, are
in fact nothing more than gambling contracts,” huffed George Caines
of New York. A wager policy was one in which “the party insured has
not any interest in the thing underwritten.” When the question came
before the Massachusetts Supreme Court for the first time in 1806, the
court found it an easy one. Thomas Amory had purchased two different
insurance policies, from two different companies, on the same cargo
aboard a ship that was to sail from the Canary Islands to the United
States. On the way, the ship and its cargo were captured by the British
and taken to Jamaica. Armory recovered on his first policy. When he
tried to recover on the second, the second insurance company defended
on the ground that Armory had already been fully compensated, and
that his second policy was nothing but a wager that the ship would
never reach its destination. The court agreed. “It would seem a dis-
graceful occupation of the courts of any country, to sit in judgment
between two gamblers, in order to decide which was the best calculator
of chances, or which had the most cunning of the two,” sniffed Justice
Isaac Parker. “There could be but one step of degradation below this—
which is, that the judges should be the stake-holders of the parties.”
Chief Justice Francis Dana took the same view. “Wager policies are
injurious to the morals of the citizens,” he reasoned, and “tend to en-
courage an extravagant and particularly hazardous species of gaming.”
Insurance “ought to be reserved for the benefit of real commerce.”65
By allowing merchants to insure their own losses but not the losses
of others, judges were able to draw a line between commerce and gam-
bling. “An insurance amongst us, is a contract of indemnity,” reasoned
Judge Jasper Yeates of Pennsylvania. “Its object is, not to make a positive
gain, but to avert a possible loss. … A policy therefore made without
65 James Allan Park, A System of the Law of Marine Insurances, 2nd American ed.
(Boston: Thomas and Andrews, 1800), 262; George Caines, Enquiry Into the
Law Merchant of the United States (New York: Abraham and Arthur Stansbury,
1802), 1:313; Amory v. Gilman, 2 Mass. 1 (1806).
49
66 Pritchet v. Insurance Company of North America, 3 Yeates 458 (Pa. 1803);
Clendining v. Church, 3 Cai. R. 141 (N.Y. Sup. 1805).
50
50 Speculation
52 Speculation
There would always be debate over precisely where to draw the line, and
over whether particular kinds of transactions should be placed on one side
or the other. But there was little controversy over whether some such line
had to be drawn. Speculation was something to be tolerated in general,
but specific instances of speculation might be too harmful to be allowed.
Gamblers in€Gold
The controversy over gold speculation during the Civil War was just one
more installment in this recurring debate, but it was one with an espe-
cially sharp edge. Speculators were blamed, not merely for bringing ruin
on themselves or for harming the wider economy, but for subverting the
war effort. Abraham Lincoln was but one of many observers who held
speculators responsible for the dollar’s decline against gold. “Two-╉thirds
of the public have been until now, and a very large proportion of them
are still thoroughly satisfied that the rise in gold has been solely due to
the efforts of speculators to break down the Government,” reported the
New York Times. One critic charged that fluctuations in gold prices were
caused by “the reckless and gambling maneouvres of speculators, through
fictitious sales, long and short, ‘cornering’ operations, and false rumours
in regard to the war, and everything else that can further their nefarious
schemes, by producing public distrust.” Another New York paper de-
clared that “partisans of the Rebellion quartered in our city have system-
atically and by concert striven and employed their means to increase the
premium on Gold.” The paper was certain that “they did this on behalf of
their master, Jeff. Davis, and in the conviction that they were aiding the
Rebellion as truly and palpably as though they were wielding muskets in
the front rank of Lee’s army.” A judge in Washington, DC, went so far as
to instruct a jury that the common law prohibited speculation in gold,
which he deemed “contrary to public policy, and calculated to depreciate
the value of the Treasury notes of the United States.”70
In response to this widespread belief that gold speculators were weak-
ening the Union Army, Senator John Sherman of Ohio introduced
70 New York Times, 20 Apr. 1864, 4; “The War and National Wealth,” Princeton Review
36 (1864): 470–╉71; New-╉York Daily Tribune, 15 June 1864, 4; “The Legal Character
of Gold Speculations,” Bankers’ Magazine and Statistical Register 14 (1864): 33.
53
54 Speculation
New York may choose to do in the premises, but what the world at large
does,” Cowan continued. “The operation of this bill is not worth any-
thing.” Even some of the supporters of Sherman’s bill admitted that it
was very unlikely to stop the dollar from falling against gold. “Although
we may not believe or feel that a bill of this kind will necessarily produce
the effect,” explained Senator William Fessenden of Maine, “it is never-
theless a duty in the present condition of things in this country to leave
nothing untried.” If Congress could do nothing about the fall of the
dollar, at least it could make a show of trying to do something. Sherman’s
bill was enacted into law in June 1864, shortly after the Confederacy de-
feated the Union at the Battle of Cold Harbor.73
The ban on gold futures did nothing to halt the dollar’s slide. Its only
effect was to shut down the Gold Exchange, which made it more diffi-
cult even for lawful buyers and sellers of gold to find one another. “The
passage of the gold act will long be remembered as the acme of folly at
Washington,” the Bankers’ Magazine lamented. “Thus far every attempt
made by the Secretary of the Treasury and Congress to stop the rise in
gold has only accelerated the downward course of currency,” despaired the
Commercial Advertiser. “The veriest tyro in political science might have
foreseen this.” A hastily assembled group of New York bankers and mer-
chants appointed a committee to travel to Washington to urge Congress
and the Lincoln administration to repeal the gold law. At a meeting with
Treasury Secretary Salmon Chase—which Chase found “good tempered
on both sides & to me instructive”—the bankers argued that restricting
the gold trade would only drive the greenback lower against gold. Chase
replied that he “could not see that licence to gambling was essential to
freedom of trade,” and that the bankers’ arguments were in any event
better directed at Congress. Congress proved to be more receptive than
Chase. The prohibition of gold futures, in effect since June 17, was re-
pealed on July 2.74 The speculators were back in business.
In its details, the controversy over gold futures grew out of the unique
crisis of the Civil War, but the controversy shared a structure with many
other debates that took place in the early republic, and many more that
would arise in later years. It required drawing a line between trans-
actions thought to be harmful and those thought to be beneficial, a
line between gambling and legitimate commerce. Everyone agreed that
gambling was bad and that commerce was necessary. The difficulty was
in telling the two apart.
2
Q
Betting on Prices
Ira Foote and Stephen hooker were carpenters from Peru, Illinois.
They both moved to Chicago in 1854, within a few months of each
other. Chicago was booming: the city’s population nearly quadrupled
in the 1850s, so there was plenty of work in the building trades. Foote
was already thirty-eight years old when he arrived in Chicago. He
would remain a carpenter for the rest of his working life. Hooker was
a younger man. When he got to the big city he did not stay a carpen-
ter for long. There was an exciting new kind of business underway in
Chicago, and Hooker got in early. He became a broker on the Chicago
Board of Trade.1
Foote kept his distance from the board of trade for many years. As
the Chicago judge William McAllister would later put it, Foote was
“rather ignorant and inexperienced in matters outside of his own proper
business.” It was not until 1874, when Foote was in his late fifties, that
he was tempted to try his hand at speculating. McAllister said Foote
was suddenly “seized with the desire to make money fast and easy,” but
that seems an uncharitable view.2 After all, fortunes were being made
at the board of trade, including by Hooker, Foote’s former colleague
in carpentry. For two decades Foote had been on the outside looking
56
57
Betting on Prices 57
58 Speculation
3 Pearce v. Rice, 142 U.S. 28, 31–32 (1891); Chicago Daily Tribune, 29 Dec. 1892, 14.
59
Betting on Prices 59
4 Tenney, 597–601.
5 Jackson v. Foote, 12 F. 37, 39–41 (N.D. Ill. 1882). Strictly speaking, Blodgett con-
ceded that the trades might have been unenforceable at common law as wagers,
had the suit been brought by Hooker against Foote, but he held that this would
not bar the notes’ enforcement by a bona fide holder, and that the transactions
did not violate the Illinois anti-option statute, which would have made the
notes unenforceable by a third party. In the other case, McAllister held that the
transactions did violate the Illinois statute. This statute and the common law
will be discussed later.
60
60 Speculation
6 For a wide range of perspectives on this set of questions, see Urs Stäheli,
Spectacular Speculation: Thrills, the Economy, and Popular Discourse, trans. Eric
Savoth (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2013), 43–92; Jonathan
Levy, Freaks of Fortune: The Emerging World of Capitalism and Risk in America
(Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2012), 231–63; Roy Kreitner,
Calculating Promises: The Emergence of Modern American Contract Doctrine
(Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2007), 105–25; Joshua C. Tate,
╇ 61
Betting on Prices 61
answers that were worked out would help shape much of the economy
for a long time to come.
62 Speculation
8 Daniel Defoe, The Villainy of Stock-Jobbers Detected (London: s.n., 1701), 24;
Thomas Gordon, An Essay on the Practice of Stock-Jobbing (London: J. Peele,
1724), 18; 7 Geo. III c. 8 (1734); Stuart Banner, Anglo-American Securities
Regulation: Cultural and Political Roots, 1690–1860 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1998), 106–7.
63
Betting on Prices 63
64 Speculation
to make candles.) Those who expected the price of tallow to rise “pur-
chased on speculation, never intending to take or pay for them [that is,
shipments of tallow], but to receive the difference between the contract
prices and the market rates.” Such merchants were not in the candle
business; they were placing bets on the price of tallow. By the 1840s,
New York and Buffalo had markets for trading grain futures, markets
likewise organized to permit the “purchase” of future rights to receive
agricultural commodities by people with no intention of ever receiving
them, and the “sale” of such rights by people who would never possess
them.10 There was not yet any law prohibiting these transactions. Nor
was there any in England, where the analogous statutes did not restrict
trading in anything other than securities.
Speculating on commodity prices was nevertheless troubling to some
judges, who looked for ways of interpreting the law so as to limit these
transactions. In an English case from 1822, Chief Justice Charles Abbott
allowed a buyer to rescind a contract for the future purchase of wheat
when the seller admitted that he could not show samples of the wheat
to the buyer because he did not yet have any wheat. If such a contract
were enforceable, Abbott reasoned, “a man might bargain to deliver
corn not then in his possession, and rely upon making a future pur-
chase in time to fulfil his undertaking; but that is a mode of dealing not
to be encouraged.” A few years later Abbott refused to enforce a similar
contract for the sale of nutmeg. In February, the seller had agreed to de-
liver nutmeg in May, but he did not acquire any nutmeg until March.
The seller was speculating that nutmeg prices would decline between
February and March. “Such a contract amounts, on the part of the
vendor, to a wager on the price of the commodity,” Abbott lectured,
“and is attended with the most mischievous consequences.” When
the seller’s lawyer informed him that such contracts were common,
and that his decision would “introduce a most material change in the
proceedings of the Royal Exchange,” Abbott retorted that any such
Betting on Prices 65
change would be for the better. “If it had been acted upon during the
last twelve months,” he declared, “much of that distress which now
presses upon the community would have been avoided.”11
In the United States, Supreme Court Justice Joseph Story shared
Abbott’s concern about the ability of merchants to wager on prices by
selling things they did not yet own. Story tried to influence the law as
much through his legal treatises as through his judicial opinions. In his
Commentaries on the Law of Agency, first published in 1839, he quoted
Abbott at length in urging the adoption of a similar rule in the United
States. “Such a contract amounts, on the part of the vendor, to a wager
on the price of the commodity, and is attended with such mischie-
vous consequences as to be prohibited by public policy,” Story insisted.
“There can be little doubt, that it is a gaming speculation, which no
court ought to enforce or encourage.”12 Story, like Abbott, proposed to
curb speculation with a simple rule: one could not contract to sell what
one did not own.
The difficulty with the rule Abbott and Story sought to introduce was
that such contracts had long been common. Farmers, for example, sold
crops before the harvest, while manufacturers sold products before they
were made. In such circumstances, the seller could not avoid selling
something he did not yet own. It was hard to argue that such contracts
posed dangers to trade, and even harder to claim that all along they
had been contrary to the common law. In England, Abbott’s holdings
lasted only a bit more than a decade before being overruled. “I cannot
see what principle of law is at all affected by a man’s being allowed to
contract for the sale of goods, of which he has not possession at the
time of the bargain,” declared Judge James Parke. “Such a contract does
not amount to a wager … and even if it were a wager, it is not ille-
gal, because it has no necessary tendency to injure third parties.” Judge
William Henry Maule agreed that Abbott’s rule was “contrary to law,
and most inconvenient in practice: and I have often heard it spoken of
with great suspicion, both by lawyers and mercantile men upon both
11 Lorymer v. Smith, 107 Eng. Rep. 1, 2 (K.B. 1822); Bryan v. Lewis, 171 Eng.
Rep. 1058, 1059 (K.B. 1826).
12 Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Law of Agency (Boston: Little, Brown and
Co., 1839), 233–34.
66
66 Speculation
13 Hibblewhite v. M’Morine, 151 Eng. Rep. 195, 197 (Exch. 1839); Frost v. Clarkson,
7 Cow. 24 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1827); Eastman v. Fiske, 9 N.H. 182 (1838); Noyes
v. Spaulding, 27 Vt. 429 (1855); Stanton v. Small, 3 Sandf. 230, 237–38 (N.Y.
Super. Ct. 1849); Gregory v. Wendell, 39 Mich. 337, 340 (1878).
14 Jonathan Lurie, The Chicago Board of Trade 1859–1905: The Dynamics of Self-
Regulation (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1979), 25; William Cronon,
67
Betting on Prices 67
Nature’s Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West (New York: W. W. Norton, 1991),
97–147.
68
68 Speculation
Betting on Prices 69
were true, the contract would still be valid. As a result, Justice Murray
Hoffman of New York’s Superior Court confronted a pure question of
law: if neither a buyer nor a seller expects delivery of the item being
sold, but both merely intend to bet on whether its price rises or falls,
is their contract void as a wager?18
Hoffman decided that the contract was indeed void as a wager. After
quoting extensively from Grizewood v. Blane, the English case from a
few years before, he made no secret of his distaste for “the unbridled
and defiant spirit of speculation.” Hoffman was a prominent layman in
the Episcopal Church. He had recently authored a lengthy treatise on
Episcopal canon law, and he would later write books about ecclesiasti-
cal law more broadly. His opinion suggests that his religious convictions
played a role in forming his view of speculation. Hoffman declared:
“I rejoice that a court of justice is able to do this at least—to con-
demn the offence—to annul the contract; and to clear the law from the
stain of enduring a practice teeming with temptation and disgrace to
those engaged in it, and with baneful influences upon the efforts of the
honest and just.” The decision was affirmed on appeal, by judges who
likewise quoted Grizewood at length.19 In New York, a contract was
now an unlawful wager on prices if neither party expected the delivery
of the item supposedly being sold.
This new rule would eventually spread throughout the United States,
but for several years New York was the only state to adopt it, because
the new rule was not easy to reconcile with two well-accepted legal
principles. One principle was that a party to a contract was normally
not allowed to claim the existence of an oral understanding at variance
with the written terms of the contract. If a contract said it was for the
sale of pork, then it was for the sale of pork, and a person who had
signed the contract could not evade his obligation by asserting that the
contract was really about something else. The second principle was that
70 Speculation
the normal remedy for a breach of contract was the payment of money
from the breaching party to the innocent party, in an amount equal
to the difference between the contract price and the market price at
the time of the breach, precisely the outcome that the New York rule
condemned as a wager. When a pork seller failed to deliver pork to the
buyer, a court normally would not order him to deliver the missing
pork; rather, it would order him to compensate the buyer with enough
money to enable the buyer to obtain equivalent pork from another
vendor.20 New York’s new rule appeared to contravene both of these
principles. The new rule allowed parties to wriggle out of contracts that
were lawful as written by claiming that the written contract was merely
a cover for what was truly a wager. And the new rule seemed to prohibit
contracting parties from settling their differences by the method that
judges routinely employed in contract cases—the payment of money
from the breaching party to the nonbreaching party.
For these reasons, the first American court outside of New York to
consider the question rejected New York’s new rule. The case before
Judge Thomas Drummond of Chicago involved an April contract to
sell fifteen thousand bushels of corn in June at 48 cents a bushel. By
June, corn was at 63 cents a bushel, and the seller had lost interest in
delivering it for 48 cents. When the buyer sued for breach of contract,
the seller tried the defense that had worked in New York: he argued
that neither he nor the buyer had any expectation of possessing any
corn, but that the contract had been a pure wager on the price of corn
and was thus unenforceable. Judge Drummond would have none of it.
The contract was for the purchase of corn, he observed, and “the rule
is well settled that when two men make a contract, and reduce it to
writing, and sign it that it is the contract between them. It cannot be
shown verbally that something different was intended at the time from
what appears in the writing.” Drummond conceded that the outcome
of the case—a judgment requiring the seller to compensate the buyer
for the difference in the price of corn between April and June—would
be identical to the outcome of a wager on prices. “So it is in any case of
Betting on Prices 71
this kind, when a party does not perform his contract,” he noted. “But
that circumstance does not make the contract the same” as a wager.21
The new rule nevertheless spread from state to state in the 1860s
and 1870s. The reason is not hard to find. Judges often laid their cards
on the table: they straightforwardly declared their moral opposition to
speculation. Pennsylvania became the second state to adopt the rule in
1867, when the Pennsylvania Supreme Court heard a case involving a
short sale of two hundred shares of Harlem Railroad stock. “It is said
the form in which this contract appears enters largely into the business
of stock brokerage,” observed Chief Justice James Thompson. But he
meant to put a stop to it. “The fewer licenses that are issued for such a
business the better,” Thompson continued. “Anything which induces
men to risk their money or property without any other hope of return
other than to get for nothing any given amount from another, is gam-
bling, and demoralizing to the community, no matter by what name it
may be called. It is the same whether the promise be to pay on the color
of a card, or the fleetness of a horse.” Thompson concluded with a sum-
mary of the dire consequences of speculation: “I apprehend that the
losses incident to the practice disclosed in this very case, within the past
five years, have contributed more to the failures and embezzlements by
public officers, clerks, agents and others acting in fiduciary relations,
public and private, than any other known, or perhaps all other causes;
and the worst of it is, that in the train of its evils, there is a vast amount
of misery and suffering by persons entirely guiltless of any partition
in the cause of it.” Thompson was careful to distinguish “bona fide
time contracts about subjects of actual purchase” from mere wagers on
prices. The former, he reluctantly acknowledged, “seem from custom
necessary in our country.” But he had no doubt that the parties before
him were gamblers through and through. Their contract took the form
of a sale of stock, but, as in famous historical episodes like the South
Sea Bubble and the tulip mania in Holland, “the form served only as a
thin covering of the most frightful systems of gambling ever known.”22
72 Speculation
23 Ex parte Young, 30 F. Cas. 828, 832–33 (N.D. Ill. 1874); Justh v. Holliday, 13 D.C.
346, 348–49 (1883); Rudolf v. Winters, 7 Neb. 125, 130 (1878); Cunningham
v. National Bank of Augusta, 71 Ga. 400, 403 (1883).
73
Betting on Prices 73
after state, judges clearly took great satisfaction in adopting a rule that
promised to limit practices they viewed as grave dangers.
This judicial attitude was almost certainly reflective of wider public
opinion. There does not appear to have been any significant effort, in
any state, to enact a statute to undo what the judges had done and
allow transactions in which neither party had the intent to deliver. The
prevailing view seems rather to have been that of the Bankers’ Magazine,
which declared that “in this evil time, when no power seems able to
stay the spirit of speculation, it is cheerful to note how strongly and
uniformly the Courts have set their faces against sustaining specula-
tive transactions.” In summarizing the decided cases, a pair of lawyers
approvingly remarked of the line the judges had drawn, a “distinction
between gambling with a commodity, and dealing there in by way of
legitimate speculation.”24
Occasional judges went so far as to declare that all options were il-
legal wagers. The transaction “called an ‘option sale,’ ” averred Judge
Thomas Gantt of St. Louis, was in fact “a wager respecting the rise and
fall in the market of mess pork.” Missouri law did not prohibit options,
he acknowledged, but “it is altogether inadmissible to infer that every-
thing is moral which the penal law does not forbid.” Gambling was
illegal and options were a form of gambling. A commentator agreed
that “options” were lawful so long as the only choice open to the seller
was the precise time of delivery, but that options were illegal where
the seller had the option not to deliver the goods at all. But this was
an extreme view. As the New York lawyer John Dos Passos (the novel-
ist’s father) explained, “options frequently represent real transactions.”
Where the owner of stock desired to sell if the price rose high enough,
or to buy more if the price dropped low enough, it would be possible
to wait for the market to change and act accordingly, but one could
achieve the same result with more certainty simply by entering into
option contracts to buy or sell stock at the appropriate prices. In such
a case, Dos Passos observed, the stock owner was not wagering; he was
74 Speculation
Betting on Prices 75
27 Kirkpatrick & Lyons v. Bonsall, 72 Pa. 155, 158 (1872); Clarke v. Foss, 5 F. Cas.
955, 960 (W.D. Wisc. 1878); Bigelow v. Benedict, 70 N.Y. 202, 206 (1877).
28 Irwin v. Williar, 110 U.S. 499, 508–9 (1884).
76
76 Speculation
Betting on Prices 77
defenses was that Melchert had not in fact lost anything, because his rye
contracts were unenforceable wagers. Melchert did not have to buy any
rye, the telegraph company argued, because neither he nor his counter-
parties ever intended that any rye would be transferred between them.
They were merely betting on rye prices.30
The law was clear by 1880: if no one involved in these contracts con-
templated the delivery of any rye, the contracts were unenforceable,
and Melchert would lose his suit against the telegraph company. Judge
James Love accordingly focused his attention on what was in Melchert’s
mind when he entered into the contracts. Did Melchert actually own
any rye in the summer, when he agreed to sell fifteen thousand bushels
of it? No, he hadn’t owned any rye whatsoever. When Melchert in-
structed Gerstenberg to “cover immediately,” was it likely that Melchert
actually meant for Gerstenberg to go out and purchase fifteen thousand
bushels of physical rye? To purchase fifteen thousand bushels of rye
at 80 cents per bushel would have cost $12,000, but Melchert did not
send any money to Gerstenberg, and it was not likely that Gerstenberg
would have lent so much money to Melchert. In fact, Gerstenberg did
not buy any physical rye. Rather, he entered into a contract to purchase
fifteen thousand bushels of rye from a firm called A. M. Wright &
Co., which turned out to be the very same firm to which Melchert had
sold the fifteen thousand bushels back in the summer. And did A. M.
Wright & Co. actually own any rye? No. Like Melchert himself, the
firm owned no rye at all. Melchert’s “purchase” from A. M. Wright
served merely to cancel out his “sale” to A. M. Wright from two months
before. Neither side ever had any rye, and neither ever intended to de-
liver rye to the other.31
These facts prompted Judge Love to consider why such an arrange-
ment should be illegal, when the very same transactions would have
been lawful had Melchert and A. M. Wright simply intended to trans-
fer ownership of some real rye. The answer, Love suggested, was that re-
quiring the intent to transfer property was a way of limiting speculation
to those who could best afford it. Someone who actually owned fifteen
78 Speculation
32 Id. at 195.
79
Betting on Prices 79
80 Speculation
task so difficult was that there was nothing illegal about paying price
differences to settle a contract, so long as the parties had originally in-
tended to transfer some item at the time they signed the contract. “If a
contract for future delivery be made in good faith,” explained the New
Orleans lawyer Julius Aroni, “its validity cannot be affected by the fact
that afterwards the parties may agree to settle it by waiving delivery and
settling differences.”34 The fact that one party paid money to the other,
rather than delivering or accepting the item being sold, was thus not
enough to establish that the contract was unlawful. The payment of
money was relevant only if it revealed what the intent of the parties had
been back when they signed the contract.
One clue to someone’s intent was his past conduct. If the person
purporting to buy grain were a grain dealer, who had received ship-
ments of grain in the past, one might take his grain contracts at face
value, whereas if he had engaged in a series of gambling transactions in
the past, one might suppose that his contracts were mere vehicles for
wagering on prices. But “it would be very dangerous to permit the pre-
vious illegal conduct of one party” to invalidate a contract, cautioned
the Michigan judge Thomas Cooley. A contract was only void if both
parties intended to wager. And even an experienced bettor might genu-
inely buy grain, Cooley acknowledged, “for gamblers may make lawful
contracts as well as others.”35 Past conduct was a clue, but that’s all it
was. There was no easy way for judges to figure out what was in the
minds of people who entered into speculative contracts.
Further complicating matters was the circumstance that in all these
cases, someone was trying to wriggle out of a contract by claiming that
it had been illegal all along. Strictly speaking, the law paid no regard to
whether a person’s conduct was consistent with norms of appropriate
34 Francis A. Lewis, Law Relating to Stocks, Bonds, and Other Securities, in the
United States (Philadelphia: Rees Welsh & Co., 1881), 95; James C. McMath,
“Investment, Speculation and Gambling on the Fluctuations of the Market
Prices of Corporate Stocks and Other Commodities,” Central Law Journal 93
(1921): 225; Arthur Biddle and George Biddle, A Treatise on the Law of Stock
Brokers (Philadelphia: J. B. Lippincott & Co., 1882), 313; Julius Aroni, Futures
(New Orleans, La.: James A. Gresham, 1882), 10.
35 Gregory v. Wendell, 40 Mich. 432, 438 (1879).
81
Betting on Prices 81
82 Speculation
3 8 Id. at 573.
39 Beveridge v. Hewitt, 8 Ill. App. 467, 479, 482 (1881).
╇ 83
Betting on Prices 83
84 Speculation
to do.” As Dunlap saw it, “it is a practice that should not be permitted
among a class of men whose integrity is a large part of their capital.”41
In 1874, when the Illinois legislature convened to revise the state’s
statutes, agrarian pressure produced a bill to prohibit contracts for the
sale of any commodity that the seller did not own and actually have in
his possession at the time of the contract. This was the same rule first
suggested in the United States by Joseph Story thirty-five years earlier,
when it had been roundly rejected. The proposal was directly targeted
at short selling on the Chicago Board of Trade, the single most vivid
circumstance in which a trader necessarily contracted to sell something
he did not yet own.
The bill was promptly criticized, for the same reason that Story’s
proposal had been criticized—it banned good transactions, as well as
bad. “So far as such a law could be made to prevent wild speculations,
‘scalping’ options and their resultant ‘corners,’ it would prove benefi-
cial,” the Chicago Tribune argued, “but, unfortunately, the law is so
sweeping.” Farmers could not survive without making contracts to sell
grain before the harvest, the Tribune pointed out. “With such a law in
operation, it would require an amount of capital to transact business
which would simply be unattainable, and the farmers would soon find
themselves ruined.” And the law would yield even more absurd results
in other industries. A meat packer could not contract to deliver meat in
advance. An opera manager could not sell tickets in advance, because
the singers were not yet in the theater. A newspaper could not sell a
year’s subscription, because the publisher did not yet possess the entire
year’s news. “Such a law,” the Tribune lamented, “would put a complete
embargo on all business.”42
The bill was especially unpopular at the board of trade. Many of the
contracts made at the board were for large quantities, like a thousand
hogs or ten thousand bushels of grain. The board’s president wondered
how sellers could fit so many hogs or so much grain into their offices to
satisfy the “possession” requirement. The broker John Bensley thought
41 Lurie, The Chicago Board of Trade, 52–56; Proceedings of the Illinois Farmers’
State Convention, Held at Bloomington, Ills., Jan. 15 & 16, 1873 (Chicago: Inter-
Ocean Print, 1873), 22–23.
42 Chicago Daily Tribune, 15 Jan. 1874, 4.
85
Betting on Prices 85
the bill would only hurt farmers by reducing prices. “If the grain was
shipped in here, and left for sale to only those men who would come
forward and buy it for shipment, they would only buy when it had ac-
cumulated here to such extent as to be sold cheap,” he argued. “As it
is now, there is a constant market, and if they are not ready to take it,
speculators are, and they keep it up to a price higher than the country
shippers would be able to get for it.”43
These concerns sparked extended debate in the Illinois legislature.
On one side were rural members who, as the Tribune put it, “expatiated
on the wickedness of the Chicago Board of Trade, and the way in which
country innocents were fleeced.” On the other were urban legislators
who could see value in the board’s activities. The resulting compromise
yielded a weaker bill, one that prohibited options but preserved fu-
tures trading in commodities one did not yet own or possess. This was
the bill that became law in 1874. It made the sale of options a crime
punishable by fine or prison sentence up to a year, and declared that
options “shall be considered gambling contracts, and shall be void.” As
the Illinois Supreme Court explained several years later, the purpose of
the law was “to break down the pernicious practice of gambling on the
market prices of grain and other commodities.” There was “nothing
illegal or even immoral in an option contract within itself,” the court
noted. “The evil aimed at nevertheless grew out of such contracts,” and
for that reason Illinois abolished them.44
In California at approximately the same time, a different political
issue yielded a different prohibition. The Nevada mining boom of the
1870s was financed in large part by the sale of mining company stock
in California, especially in San Francisco, which was the tenth-biggest
city in the country and home to the region’s only stock exchange.
“Californians, as a class, gamble in mining stocks,” the San Francisco
Chronicle observed in 1875. “From the lady leader of fashion to the
poorest seamstress, from the dignified bishop and the august Judge,
down to the boy who blacked their boots, each and all owned shares.”
86 Speculation
Betting on Prices 87
46 California Constitution of 1879, art. IV, sec. 26; Los Angeles Express quoted
in San Francisco Chronicle, 25 Mar. 1879, 1; San Francisco Chronicle, 29 Apr.
1879, 2.
47 Petition, June 1886, CBT, box 13, folder 29; Chicago Tribune, 11 Feb. 1892, 4;
John Percy to A. M. Clement, 25 June 1910, CBT, box 353, folder 8.
88
88 Speculation
The propriety of betting on prices was not just a legal question. The
experience of Illinois and California showed that under the right circum-
stances, it could be a significant political question as well. Before long, as
we will see in �chapter 3, it would assume a large role in national politics.
48 CBT, box 351, folder 1, page 3; J.B. Lyon & Co. v. Culbertson, Blair & Co., 83 Ill.
33, 40 (1876); CBT, box 3, folder 6; box 352, pages 935–╉36; box 352, page 182.
89
Betting on Prices 89
90 Speculation
Farmers also confronted the risk of price changes, so they too could
benefit from hedging. A farmer had to decide whether to plant seed
long before there would be any crops to sell. A sensible decision at
planting season could turn disastrous by the harvest if grain prices fell
in the interim. One way a farmer could avoid this risk was by find-
ing a customer who was willing to lock in a price and buy his crop
far in advance. But another method was to hedge. Like a grain dealer,
the farmer could simply sell futures in the planting season that would
come due at the harvest. By doing so, the farmer was, in effect, insuring
against the risk of price changes.
Hedgers, like speculators, normally did not intend to settle their fu-
tures contracts by delivering or receiving any grain. The grain futures
that Bradenbaugh sold at the board of trade nominally obligated him to
deliver a certain quantity of grain on a given day for a stated price. Once
Bradenbaugh no longer needed to hedge, however, he simply returned
to the board of trade and closed the transaction by purchasing grain
futures in the same amount as he had previously sold. When commodi-
ties were sold as hedges, Walter Haugh recalled, they were never actu-
ally delivered, and when they were bought as hedges they were never
actually received. Such contracts were settled the way Bradenbaugh set-
tled his, by a second transaction that was a mirror image of the first.50
The second transaction did not have to be with the same counterparty
as the first. When Bradenbaugh closed out his position by purchasing
grain futures, he could buy them from someone other than the person
to whom he had sold grain futures months before. At the end of each
day, when all the transactions on the board of trade were tallied up,
long and short positions would mostly cancel out, and all that would
be left was a list of who owed money to whom.
The board of trade’s rules explicitly permitted parties to settle their
contracts by the payment of money rather than the transfer of the com-
modities nominally purchased.51 The rules could hardly have stated
Betting on Prices 91
92 Speculation
53 Lurie, The Chicago Board of Trade, 29; CBT, box 13, folder 31; box 4, folder 34;
Letters to Board of Directors from Howard Priestley (8 May 1873), J. K. Fisher
& Co. (24 May 1873), and Dupee & Hammond (29 May 1873), all in CBT,
box 1, folder 16.
54 The best account of bucket shops is David Hochfelder, “ ‘Where the Common
People Could Speculate’: The Ticker, Bucket Shops, and the Origins of
Popular Participation in Financial Markets,” Journal of American History 93
(2006): 335–58.
93
Betting on Prices 93
bucket shop, on the contrary, simply bets its patrons that stocks,
grain, cotton, provisions, or any other speculative commodity will
go up or down.”55 Brokerage houses earned commissions on their
clients’ trades, whether the clients made or lost money. Bucket shops
took commissions too, but they profited mainly by winning whatever
their clients lost.
By the later decades of the nineteenth century, there were bucket
shops in towns all over the country. Some offered honest gambles
on prices without any pretense of doing anything else. Some falsely
claimed to be real brokers with membership in an established exchange.
Some were pure swindles, with concocted prices that always seemed to
move against the customer. All of them hurt the exchanges. The honest
bucket shops took legitimate clients away from the exchanges, while
the dishonest ones brought the entire enterprise of speculation into
disrepute.
Dishonest bucket shops used a variety of tricks. Prices came by tele-
graph from the cities where the exchanges were located. In small towns,
customers without telegraph connections of their own had no way of
knowing whether the prices posted by the bucket shop were the real
ones, so a bucket shop could make its prices rise or fall nearly at will.
“The city trader can compare bucket-shop prices with the regular Board
of Trade figures, and thus to a degree protect himself against whole-
sale extortion,” the Chicago Tribune cautioned—under the large head-
line “How Bucket Shop Men Fatten on Dupe Speculators”—“but the
countryman is entirely at the mercy of the firm with which he deals.”
Or a bucket shop could “hold the market”—that is, post prices only
after a delay, so the bucket shop operator would know the market’s
direction before his clients did. A bucket shop could even fleece its cus-
tomers with real prices. Customers typically purchased on very small
margins, putting down as little as 1 percent of the value of the stock
or commodity nominally being purchased, so a price movement of 1
percent in the wrong direction was enough to wipe out a customer’s ac-
count. A bucket shop operator seeking to make prices move by 1 percent
94 Speculation
could buy from a confederate on the real exchange at the desired price,
which would be duly reported by telegraph. Once the customers’ ac-
counts had been emptied, the confederate would buy back at the same
price from the bucket shop operator. As the financial journalist Edwin
Lefèvre recalled in his thinly fictionalized biography of the speculator
Jesse Livermore, on the New York Stock Exchange “they had what were
frankly referred to as ‘bucket-shop drives,’ when a stock was offered
down two or three points in a jiffy just to establish the decline on the
tape and wipe up the myriad shoe-string traders who were long of the
stock in the bucket shops.” And if all else failed, and the market turned
in favor of the customers, the bucket shop operator “simply locks his
door at night and disappears from the town before morning,” one critic
charged, “leaving the traders who have taken profits, to bewail their
losses and their cupidity.”56
It was commonly observed that dishonest bucket shops harmed the
reputation of the established exchanges, because many customers could
not tell the difference between the two. As a special committee of the
New York Stock Exchange lamented, “the ignorant people who have
been robbed by the bucket-shop feel that they have been robbed by the
Stock Exchange.” This was one reason the exchanges tried for decades
to stamp out the bucket shops. Dishonest bucket shops also harmed
the reputation of honest bucket shops, who thus had an interest in sup-
porting the exchanges’ efforts, so long as those efforts could be narrowly
targeted. An agent of the board of trade reported that the proprietor
of a Cincinnati bucket shop “says that he would be glad if the B. of
T. would go after several b[ucket] s[hop] houses who are doing business
on the bunco plan, as they are [the] kind who are giving houses who
do business on strictly business principles a black eye, and he would
like to see them all put out of business.”57 The dishonest bucket shops
Betting on Prices 95
had no defenders. Everyone agreed that fraud was wrong and should
be stopped.
The exchanges had a harder time fighting off the honest bucket shops,
which took customers away by offering similar services at lower prices.
Bucket shops normally allowed trading in smaller lots than the ex-
changes did. They required smaller margins. They typically took a lower
rate of commission. Bucket shops could thus be an attractive alternative
to speculators and hedgers alike. John Bradenbaugh, the Kansas City
grain merchant, often hedged on the Chicago Board of Trade, but he
also often used a Kansas City bucket shop for that purpose. “So far as
we are concerned it was identically the same,” Bradenbaugh explained.
“Exactly the same in every particular.” From his point of view, “the
whole Chicago Board of Trade has been a bucket shop for the last ten
years.”58
Attitudes like Bradenbaugh’s were of great concern to the exchanges.
“The idea is assiduously cultivated by the proprietors of these places
that the bucket-shop is the poor man’s stock exchange,” the New York
Stock Exchange complained. People who might otherwise have been its
own customers “feel that the bucket-shop performs a useful function
in no way different from that of the great central Exchange.”59 The ex-
changes accordingly went to great lengths to suppress this competition.
They sponsored state legislation to outlaw bucket shops. They helped
prosecutors prepare cases against bucket shops. They took to the press
with public relations campaigns aimed at dissuading customers from
resorting to bucket shops. In all of these efforts, the first step was to
establish that the exchanges were fundamentally different from bucket
shops. The exchanges were sites of legitimate commerce, the argument
went, while the bucket shops were not, because the business of bucket
shops was betting on prices.
96 Speculation
60 What Is the Bucket Shop?, CBT, box 326, folder 8, page 3; The Grain Exchanges
Versus Bucket Shops, CBT, box 326, folder 8, page 3; Evils of the Bucket Shop
System, CBT, box 326, folder 8, page 3; Why Bucket Shops Should Be Outlawed,
CBT, box 326, folder 8, n.p.
97
Betting on Prices 97
61 Ann Fabian, Card Sharps, Dream Books, & Bucket Shops: Gambling in
19th-Century America (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), 198;
C. C. Christie, “Bucket-Shop vs. Board of Trade,” Everybody’s Magazine 15
(1906): 707, 708; “A Plea for Bucket-Shops,” Puck, 10 Sept. 1884, 23; Wall
Street Journal, 10 Aug. 1904, 1; Frederick S. Dickson, “The Poison of the
Street,” Everybody’s Magazine 20 (1909): 230; Chicago Daily Tribune, 31 Oct.
1895, 6; New York Times, 7 Oct. 1878, 2.
98
98 Speculation
Whenever the board of trade sued a bucket shop, this strategy left
the board’s leaders stammering under cross-examination as they strug-
gled to articulate why bucket shops were any different from the board
of trade. “What is a bucket shop?” one lawyer asked William Warren,
the board’s president. Warren replied, “It is a place where dealings are
had upon the fluctuations of the market without any bona fide transac-
tion.” The lawyer continued: “Would it be a bona fide transaction if the
parties did not intend to receive or deliver?” Warren said it would not.
And here the lawyer moved in for the kill. He and Warren both knew
that the transactions he was describing were common on bucket shops
and the board of trade alike. “But if they did intend to receive or de-
liver,” the lawyer asked, “and did then settle on the difference in market
prices, that would be a bona fide transaction?” All Warren could do was
feebly reply: “Not in a bucket shop.” The lawyer: “Would that trans-
action have to be conducted on the Board of Trade in order to make
it bona fide?” Warren: “I think it would.” The president of the board
of trade had been forced to concede that there was no real difference
between the business of his organization and that of a bucket shop. In
the board’s view, the very same transaction was lawful on the board and
illegal anywhere else.62
When the Chicago Board of Trade and the New York Stock
Exchange tried to help prosecutors go after bucket shops for violat-
ing the laws against gambling, they faced the same problem of dis-
tinguishing the bucket shop business from their own. The board of
trade sent George Burmeister all over the country to explain to dis-
trict attorneys and grand juries why bucket shops were different from
exchanges. “I take pleasure in telling you that I done my little stunt
before the Grand Jury today,” Burmeister reported from Detroit. “I
was first and had to give them a wide-scope outline of a legitimate
house and a bucket-shop, the way we execute orders and the way they
are filled in a bucket-shop. Several very inquisitive fellows on it but
I gave a most satisfactory explanation; the two assistant prosecutors
both complimented me after we all got out saying they both learned
a heap.” From Cleveland, Burmeister reported: “I have spent all my
Betting on Prices 99
time in the District Attys office here while they are writing indict-
ments.” He lamented that “this case is entirely strange to all of them,
the Dist Atty, Asst Dist Attys and the Inspector have never made a
trade or even been in a Brokerage office or Bucketshop and practically
had to learn the entire business.”63
The same problem arose when the exchanges lobbied state legisla-
tures for statutes banning bucket shops. “I went to Sacramento for
the purpose of securing the introduction of a bill to put the bucket-
shops out of business,” John Percy reported to the board of trade. “I
was personally acquainted with a large number of the members of
both houses, and interviewed them on this subject.” But Percy had no
success, because he could not persuade legislators that bucket shops
were any different from the board. “In practically every instance,” he
despaired, “I found that the members were entirely ignorant as to
the difference between bucket-shops and legitimate brokerage houses,
and all seemed to have the idea that a marginal trade through a le-
gitimate broker was, to all intents and purposes, as fictitious as the
so-called ‘purchases’ and ‘sales’ in the bucket-shops. The general im-
pression seemed to be that the legislation I was urging was simply
an attempt on the part of the big fellows to squeeze out the little
ones.” The grain dealer Harry Kress was a board of trade member who
lived in Piqua, Ohio. He tried to persuade his state legislature to ban
bucket shops as gambling houses, but he was not optimistic, because
most people thought the board’s transactions were gambles too. “The
average individual having no connection with the Grain Trade, does
not understand the necessity of trading in futures,” Kress complained,
“and right here is where we may expect trouble.” The proponent of
an Indiana bill to prohibit bucket shops acknowledged that “the first
question that will naturally arise in the minds of my colleagues is,
what is the difference between a bucket shop and a legitimate board
of trade[?]” The bucket shops themselves did much to promote the
impression that bucket shops and exchanges were identical. As one
Illinois legislator observed, the bucket shops’ standard argument
63 George Burmeister to H. A. Foss, 16 Dec. 1912, CBT, box 329, folder 1;
George Burmeister to J. C. F. Merrill, 13 Oct. 1914, CBT, box 329, folder
6. Burmeister’s reports fill several folders in CBT, box 329.
100
100 Speculation
against this sort of legislation was “We are bad of course, rotten in
fact, but no worse than the board of trade.”64
The exchanges were walking a very thin line. They were trying to
stamp out a business that was not very different from their own, based
on the one attribute that exchanges and bucket shops shared in abun-
dance. Despite this obstacle, several states did enact statutes prohibiting
bucket shops in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. But
this only converted the problem into one of legislative drafting, be-
cause any such statute had to distinguish bucket shops from exchanges.
Some of these laws did not even try to define the term bucket shop.
In Iowa, for example, the legislature simply declared that its purpose
was to prohibit “places commonly known and designated as bucket-
shops.” The statutes that defined the term did so by restating the fa-
miliar common-law ban on transactions where neither party intended
delivery. Wisconsin, for instance, declared that “a bucket-shop, within
the meaning of this act, is defined to be an office, store or other place”
in which transactions were made “for the purchase or sale of any such
commodity wherein the parties do not contemplate the actual or bona
fide receipt or delivery of such property, but do contemplate a settle-
ment thereof based upon differences in the prices at which said prop-
erty is, or is claimed to be, bought and sold.” The statutes added new
penalties to bucket shopping, but they did not make anything unlawful
that was not already unlawful. They merely replicated the problem of
how to distinguish bucket shops from legitimate exchanges, because by
this definition, the exchanges were bucket shops too. “We do not see
how any legal distinction can be made between the two operations,” the
New York Times noted shortly after New York enacted its statute. Was
the business of a bucket shop “betting on future prices? In form it is
not, and in substance it is no more so than the ‘regular’ speculation” on
the New York Stock Exchange. After more than a decade of ineffective
enforcement, the Times concluded that no law could be drafted to ban
bucket shops without also banning the exchanges. “Bucket shops in a
6 4 John A. Percy to A. M. Clement, 25 June 1910, CBT, box 353, folder 8; Harry
W. Kress to A. H. Schuyler, 19 Feb. 1908, CBT, box 331, folder 7; CBT, box
353, folder 3; “Anti-Bucket Shop Bill,” CBT, box 353, folder 9.
101
financial community are something like sorrel in one’s front lawn,” the
paper mused. “No general methods can be taken to exterminate them
without danger to the legitimate growth surrounding them.” Even the
New York Stock Exchange lost faith in the ability of the legal system to
stamp out bucket shops. A stock exchange committee appointed to rec-
ommend some course of action regarding bucket shops concluded that
“these laws are not enforced and never can be enforced.” The bucket
shops were too popular, and they were popular because they provided
the same service as the stock exchange itself. New York and Pennsylvania
had enacted statutes prohibiting bucket shops, largely at the stock ex-
change’s behest, but “there are more bucket-shops in New York State
and Pennsylvania today than there ever were before.”65
The exchanges eventually won the war against the bucket shops, not
by persuading anyone that they were fundamentally different, but by
cutting off the bucket shops’ access to the exchanges’ price quotations.
A bucket shop could not exist without timely price information, so if
the exchanges could prevent the bucket shops from receiving price quo-
tations, they could put the bucket shops out of business. But that was
easier said than done. The exchanges repeatedly tried to persuade the
telegraph companies to deny service to nonmembers, without much
success, because the bucket shop business was simply too lucrative for
the telegraph companies. In 1890, the board of trade took the extreme
step of stopping the telegraphic distribution of price quotations, an ex-
traordinary inconvenience to the board’s many out-of-town members
who were accustomed to receiving prices by telegraph. But the board
quickly discovered that the bucket shops were getting the quotations
anyway, apparently because someone inside the board was flashing sig-
nals out the window. The next day the board tried soaping the windows,
but even that desperate measure only delayed the bucket shops by about
fifteen minutes. The board resumed telegraphing its prices. In 1898,
when the board suspected that someone was using the new telephones
102 Speculation
on the exchange floor to leak price quotes to bucket shops, there was a
proposal to remove them, which drew complaints from board members
all over the country that without telephone contact they could not com-
pete with the bucket shops, because the telephone was the only way they
could get prices faster than the bucket shops did.66
Toward the end of the century, the exchanges turned to a different
tactic. They began filing suits against bucket shops, alleging that the
price quotations were their property and that the bucket shops had
stolen it. These suits had a mixed record at first, but in 1905 the ex-
changes scored a final victory in the US Supreme Court, which affirmed
that the prices resulting from transactions on an exchange were prop-
erty belonging to the exchange. The case was brought by the Chicago
Board of Trade against the Christie Grain & Stock Company, a Kansas
City bucket shop that was presumably obtaining board price quota-
tions by telegraph, despite a provision in the board’s contracts with the
telegraph companies not to furnish price information to any bucket
shop. The board’s “collection of quotations is entitled to the protection
of the law,” Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes wrote for the court. “It
stands like a trade secret. The plaintiff has the right to keep the work
which it had done, or paid for doing, to itself.” By sending prices over
the telegraph wires to members throughout the country, Holmes con-
tinued, the board had not given up this privilege of secrecy. “The plain-
tiff does not lose its rights by communicating the result to persons, even
if many, in confidential relations to itself, under a contract not to make
it public,” the court held. “Strangers to the trust”—that is, the bucket
shops—“will be restrained from getting at the knowledge by inducing a
breach of trust, and using knowledge obtained by such a breach.”67 The
exchanges had established their right to control their price quotations.
The Christie Grain & Stock Company’s primary defense was that
the board of trade “itself keeps the greatest of bucket shops,” that its
price quotations were thus the product of illegal conduct, and that even
if prices were property when created lawfully, the board should not be
allowed to profit from its own illegality. In the course of rebuffing this
defense, Holmes launched into an extended discussion of the legitimacy
and importance of speculative trading on organized exchanges, using
words that would be quoted liberally by the exchanges in the years to
come whenever the opportunity arose. “In a modern market, contracts
are not confined to sales for immediate delivery,” Holmes began. “People
will endeavor to forecast the future, and to make agreements according
to their prophecy. Speculation of this kind by competent men is the self-
adjustment of society to the probable. Its value is well known.” Even if
some of the contracts on the board of trade were unenforceable wagers, he
continued, “there is no doubt that a large part of those contracts is made
for serious business purposes.” The idea that the board’s transactions were
mere wagers “seems to us hardly consistent with the admitted fact that
the quotations of prices from the market are of the utmost importance
to the business world.”68 Of course, many bucket shop transactions were
made for business purposes that were just as serious, but unlike transac-
tions on the board of trade, they did not set prices for the country.
Holmes’s opinion in the Chicago Board of Trade case was a strong
endorsement of the exchanges, but it did not change the law. Most
of the transactions on the exchanges were still unlawful, just as they
had been since state courts began adopting the intent-to-deliver rule
a few decades before. The Supreme Court had ratified the prevailing
view among the lower courts that price quotations were the exchanges’
property, but that did not stop the bucket shops from continuing to
use every means at their disposal to get the quotations anyway. It would
be another decade before the exchanges finally won the war. The key to
victory was probably not the spate of anti–bucket shop statutes or the
Supreme Court’s formal recognition of a property right in price quota-
tions, but rather the increasing size and thus clout of the exchanges,
which eventually enabled them to force the telegraph companies to
restrict the distribution of price information. When the bucket shops
were starved for prices, most of them died.
104 Speculation
“Time was when the bucket shop was almost as the locust in a sev-
enth year,” the Saturday Evening Post recalled in 1916. “Every consid-
erable town had from one to forty concerns where the inexperienced
and credulous could bet away their money on variations in the price
of grain, cotton, stocks.” But not any longer. “Our impression is that
the species has been pretty nearly exterminated. Certainly it persists
only sporadically and in a meager fashion.”69 Bucket shops never disap-
peared completely, but they ceased to be serious competition for the
exchanges.
The intent-to-deliver rule had not disappeared, however. It was still
a part of the common law throughout the country, and it had been
enacted into statute in many states as well. The rule drew a line—a very
fine line, as many saw it—between legitimate and illegitimate spec-
ulation, between speculation considered as business and speculation
considered as gambling. Meanwhile, even before the bucket shop war
ended, the exchanges had to confront another challenge, in the form
of a concerted national effort to redraw the line so as to prohibit even
more forms of speculation.
69 “A Scientific Reform,” Saturday Evening Post, 13 May 1916, in CBT, box 353,
folder 10.
3
Q
The Anti-Option Era
1 Susan B. Carter et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial
Edition On Line (Cambridge University Press, 2006), tables Da719, Da757,
Da697, Da672; Lawrence Goodwin, Democratic Promise: The Populist Movement
in America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1976).
105
106
106 Speculation
2 Jerry W. Markham, The History of Commodity Futures Trading and Its Regulation
(New York: Praeger, 1987), 7–8; “Speculation and Money,” Bankers’ Magazine
and Statistical Register 37 (1883): 811.
╇ 107
like red to a bull,” agreed the philosopher Robert Hutcheon. “All his
latent belligerency against things as they are is roused into strenuous
action when he hears the word or reflects on the crazy mentality and
the reckless activities it stands for.”3
But there was much more than ignorance behind the farmers’ call to
prohibit speculation in their products. The anti-╉option movement was
part of a broader battle over the organization of agriculture, fought by
an occupational group who could see their relative numbers dwindling
and their influence in the market slipping away. Many of the farmers’
arguments against speculation may have been wrong as a matter of
economics, but there was nothing irrational about them as a matter of
politics.
Hayseed Legislation
William Vilas served only a single term as a senator from Wisconsin, but
it lasted from 1891 to 1897, when the agitation for restricting commod-
ity speculation was at its peak, so he found himself bombarded with
appeals from both sides of the struggle. Political considerations pulled
Vilas in both directions. There were many farmers in Wisconsin, but
Milwaukee was already a big city, and the Milwaukee Grain Exchange
was a center of grain speculation, so any position Vilas took would be
sure to alienate a substantial fraction of voters and a good number of
the state legislators who still had the power to select Wisconsin’s sena-
tors. Vilas was a Democrat, in an era when the Democratic Party, espe-
cially in the West, was identified with the small farmer, but Vilas him-
self was about as far from the farm as a Wisconsinite could be. He had
been a lawyer, a law professor at the state university in Madison, and
then postmaster general and secretary of the interior during the first
Grover Cleveland administration. He had much more in common with
the bankers and brokers of Milwaukee than with the state’s farmers.
3 John Hill Jr. to E. F. Ladd, 17 June 1921, CBT, box 328, folder 3; Bills in Congress
Affecting Cotton Contracts for Future Delivery (New York: Latham, Alexander
& Co., 1908); Louis Guenther, Investment and Speculation (Chicago: La Salle
Extension University, 1921), 157; Robert J. Hutcheon, “Speculation, Legitimate
and Illegitimate,” International Journal of Ethics 32 (1922): 289.
108
108 Speculation
4 G. E. Stowe to Vilas, 9 May 1892, box 14, folder 1; Milton George to Vilas, 6
July 1892, box 14, folder 1; N. F. Fox to Vilas, 29 Feb. 1892, box 13, folder 1, all
in WFV.
5 E. P. Bacon to Vilas, 5 Mar. 1892, 29 Apr. 1892, and 3 Dec. 1892, and “A Protest”
(27 Apr. 1892), all in WFV, box 14, folder 1; Robert Eliot to Vilas, 15 Jan. 1892,
WFV, box 13, folder 1; John Johnston to Vilas, 17 Feb. 1892, WFV, box 13, folder
1; George Stone to Vilas, 30 Dec. 1892, WFV, box 15, folder 1; Denison B. Smith
109
to Vilas, 11 Mar. 1892, WFV, box 13, folder 2; Vilas to E. P. Bacon, 7 Mar. 1892,
WFV, box 14, folder 1; New York Times, 6 Jan. 1893, 3.
6 Cedric B. Cowing, Populists, Plungers, and Progressives: A Social History of Stock
and Commodity Speculation, 1890–1936 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press, 1965), 22; Journal of the House of Representatives of the United States, 51st
Cong., 2nd Sess. (1890), 69, 118, 114, 169; New York Times, 12 Apr. 1890, 3.
110
110 Speculation
voted for it are anxious to promote the interests of the agricultural class,
but only that they think to help their party by humoring a silly preju-
dice against a certain form of trading.” The Pittsburg Dispatch sarcasti-
cally referred to the bills’ House and Senate sponsors as “Farmer Hatch”
and “Farmer Washburn,” despite the fact that neither William Hatch of
Missouri nor William Washburn of Minnesota was a farmer; Hatch
was a lawyer and Washburn engaged in a variety of businesses. The bill
was “hayseed legislation,” cracked one member of the New York Produce
Exchange. “The farmer, as a rule, imagines everyone in the city is his
enemy, and there are just enough demagogues lying around loose to en-
courage him in this opinion.”7
The Senate’s version of the bill was slightly different from the
House’s, so it had to return to the House, but by then the 1892 election
had already taken place, so there was less need to make a conspicuous
show of supporting the farmers. Opponents of the bill were able to stall
until the session expired. “By persistently postponing a vote on the bill
to prohibit dealings in options and futures, the minority of the mem-
bers of the House accomplished its defeat,” a relieved New York Times
reported.8
Proponents of a national ban on commodity speculation would
never come so close again. Hatch returned with a similar bill in 1894;
it passed the House but never came to a vote in the Senate. Another
bill in 1895 could not get through the House. Commodity prices lev-
eled off and even rose a bit over the next few years, so there would be
no more antispeculation bills until 1903, but then they started appear-
ing in increasing numbers. The Panic of 1907 elicited no fewer than
twenty bills to prohibit futures trading, followed by thirteen more in
1909 and another eight in 1911. In 1912, the Democratic Party platform
7 Journal of the House of Representatives of the United States, 52nd Cong., 1st Sess.
(1892), part II, 251, 255, 267, 270, 275, 277, 278, 282; Dealings in “Options” and
“Futures”: Protests, Memorials and Arguments Against Bills Introduced in the Fifty-
Second Congress (s.l.: New York Cotton Exchange et al., 1892); Globe-Democrat
quoted in Chicago Daily Tribune, 13 June 1892, 4; Pittsburg Dispatch, 20 Feb.
1892, 1; New York Times, 18 July 1892, 10.
8 New York Times, 2 Mar. 1893, 5.
111
9 H.R. Rep. No. 845, 53rd Cong., 2nd Sess. (1894); H.R. Rep. No. 1999, 53rd
Cong., 3rd Sess. (1895); Carl Parker, “Governmental Regulation of Speculation,”
Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 38 (1911): 141–
44; Democratic platform at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index
.php?pid=29590.
112
112 Speculation
speculation caused prices to diverge from the true values they would
have had in a market free from manipulation. “We neither ask for our
produce, and are unwilling to pay more than the actual value,” de-
clared T. J. Kimbrough, master of the Georgia State Grange. “Supply
and demand should control.”10
Opponents of legislation replied that while speculators might be
able to manipulate prices for very short periods of time, they lacked
the resources to do so for long. “With regard to the present price of
cotton,” argued the cotton speculator Daniel Sully, “no plan of ma-
nipulation, unless financed on a scale sufficient to take over a large
portion of the crop,” could keep prices higher or lower. “No clique of
speculators could be found with money enough and daring enough to
attempt such a thing.” As the economist Richard Ely put it, “buying
and selling in themselves cannot raise prices. … If it were possible thus
to raise prices, there would be an easy road to fortune for everyone.”
Speculators thus could not be blamed for the long-term decline in com-
modity prices. Others repeated the familiar observation that the effect
of speculation was not to increase fluctuations but to smooth them out,
because speculators bought in a declining market and sold in a rising
one. Without them, reasoned the journalist Harold Howland, “booms
would tend to be wild and unrestrained, with inevitable disaster when
the break finally came,” while “declines would be sudden, rapid, and
extensive, with equally disastrous consequences.” The financial writer
Charles Conant, anticipating a way of thinking that would become
orthodoxy later in the twentieth century, provided a second method by
which speculators smoothed price changes. “Every event in the world
which affects price is felt upon the exchanges; and it comes to be said
that future events, when they occur, have been already ‘discounted,’ ”
11 Daniel J. Sully, “Is the High Price of Cotton the Result of Manipulation?,”
North American Review 178 (1904): 194; Richard T. Ely, “Land Speculation,”
Journal of Farm Economics 2 (1920): 130; Harold J. Howland, “Gambling Joint
or Market Place?,” Outlook 104 (1913): 437; Charles A. Conant, “The Uses of
Speculation,” Forum 31 (1901): 701; Egerton R. Williams, “Thirty Years in the
Grain Trade,” North American Review 161 (1895): 33.
114
114 Speculation
116 Speculation
17 John Hill Jr., Gold Bricks of Speculation (Chicago: Lincoln Book Concern, 1904),
420–21; “Business and Speculation,” Independent 48 (1896): 21; Chicago Daily
Tribune, 25 Dec. 1891, 4; Alexander M. Hudnut, “Dealing in Futures Is Not
Gambling,” Town and Country, 20 May 1905, 37; L. D. H. Weld, “High Food
Prices, Middlemen, and Speculation,” North American Review 206 (1917): 589.
118
118 Speculation
18 Daily Market Record, 8 Jan. 1892, 1; Fictitious Dealing, 213; Future Trading in
Grain: Hearings Before the Committee on Agriculture and Forestry, United States
Senate, 67th Cong., 1st Sess. (1921), 109–10, 207.
19 Hearings Before the Committee on Agriculture During the Second Session of the
Sixty-First Congress, vol. II, Hearings on Bills for the Prevention of “Dealing in
Futures” on Boards of Trade, Etc. (1910), 438; Board of Directors Resolution, 28
Feb. 1921, CBT, box 334, folder 8; Future Trading in Grain, 393–94.
119
120 Speculation
the public, the professionals, the cash grain men, elevator companies
and others, continue to go on just to create an insurance market for a
few grain dealers? That is what it amounts to.” Norris replied, “If you
ask me, I say I do not know why.” “Neither do I,” admitted Smith, “but
that is the situation.”21
Norris and Smith were likely being disingenuous, because the ex-
changes and their supporters had been providing an answer to their
question for three decades: if the intermediaries in the distribution
system had to bear their own risks, they would have to be compensated
for doing so, in the form of a bigger spread between the price they paid
to farmers and the price they charged to consumers. Without specula-
tors, the farmers’ earnings would be even lower than they already were.
Traders “would certainly be compelled to buy on a wider margin to
protect themselves against declining markets while the grain is in tran-
sit,” the grain merchant S. W. Tallmadge advised William Vilas, “and
in so doing the producer receives less pay for his grain.” “If the farm-
ers succeed” in their efforts to ban the exchanges, the Chicago Tribune
editorialized, “they will find themselves even worse off than now, the
remedy being even more bad than the disease they seek to have cured.”
The broker S. V. White wondered: “Is there a man so blind as not to see
that if the buyer had to take the risk of a two weeks’ fluctuation in the
grain market he could not pay within many cents per bushel of the ad-
vanced prices?” R. C. Clark, a member of the Chicago Board of Trade,
agreed that “there isn’t a farmer in the West who could get as much for
his grain by two to five cents a bushel as he gets now if trading in futures
were prohibited.” “Before trading in grain for future delivery became
a custom,” recalled John Messmore of the St. Louis Grain Exchange,
grain exporters “made from 10 to 20 cents per bushel on every bushel
they exported.” The exchanges had driven this margin sharply down.
“The exporter of today works on a very small margin, frequently only 1
cent per bushel profit,” Messmore explained. “The millers also work on
a small margin. They are able to do this because they can protect their
purchases or sales in the terminal or primary markets, by buying or sell-
ing the grain for future delivery.” Speculation thus left more money for
farmers. Messmore concluded that “to pass a law abolishing the trading
in grain for future delivery would be a calamity to the farmers.”22
Even worse, exchange members suggested, an inability to hedge
might make the grain trade too risky for all but the largest dealers,
which would leave the farmer with a constricted market for his prod-
ucts. “The result of the bill,” predicted Murry Nelson of the Chicago
Board of Trade, “would be to crush out the small dealers and place the
farmer at the mercy of the large capitalist, who can buy cash grain; but
they will buy it at such a price that they can hold it until Gabriel blows
his horn without sustaining loss.”23 Without competition among many
potential purchasers for grain, farmers would be forced to sell at lower
prices.
Of course, it would be possible for farmers to bypass the interme-
diaries altogether and sell grain directly to the consumer as in the old
days, but this was yet another route to lower prices. “If the producer
should sell direct to the consumer,” board of trade member Charles
Counselman expected, “the farmers of Kansas and Nebraska, instead
of receiving 10 to 15 cents a bushel for corn this winter, which was little
enough, would not have received five cents a bushel.” Counselman’s col-
league J. H. Norton pointed out that “the speculator doesn’t buy merely
what he himself can consume, as does the farmer’s neighbor, but he
buys what a nation or part of a nation may need. In this way he gives
the farmer the benefit of the world’s prices instead of being limited to
local demand.” Benjamin Hutchinson, one of the leading grain specula-
tors of the 1880s, posed the problem in more concrete terms. “If there
were no speculation,” he suggested, “the farmers could only sell their
grain to local buyers, who would be liable to get full and stop buying,
and then the farmer would be compelled to wait for customers; and in
the meantime a mortgage might be foreclosed on his farm, even while
the wheat in his bins would more than satisfy the mortgage, if converted
into cash. But speculation, flashing its news over the wires from one
side of the world to the other, keeps the market always open to him.”
22 S. W. Tallmadge to William Vilas, 12 Mar. 1892, WFV, box 14, folder 1; Chicago
Daily Tribune, 6 Mar. 1892, 12; 26 Aug. 1890, 5; Jan. 1891, 7; Hearings Before the
Committee on Agriculture, 470.
23 Chicago Daily Tribune, 12 Apr. 1890, 5.
122
122 Speculation
Hutchinson concluded that “if farmers are hostile to boards of trade and
futures, in my opinion they are mistaken.”24
On this view, the farmers were miscalculating their own interests
and agitating for measures that would leave them worse off. “The de-
struction of the system, which is a perfectly legitimate development of
trade, would produce immediate disaster” for farmers, the New York
Times editorialized. “Their demand for its abolition comes from a
lack of understanding of the function performed by the system and
a misconception of its effects.”25 But how could millions of farmers
have made such a big mistake about a matter so central to their own
well-╉being?26
ready to defend his vote back home in Wisconsin, where the farm-
ers believed that the board of trade was responsible for their financial
distress. “We want to say answer a fool according to his folly and pass
him by. But you can’t do it,” Vilas lamented. “You have got to begin pa-
tiently at the bottom and build up this argument.” As Vilas saw it, the
farmers “have been in a certain sense hoodwinked into the support of
something that was not to their interest.” Vilas hoped to set the farmers
straight, but he knew it would not be easy. “I should have no apprehen-
sion of meeting any farmers in this world,” he explained, “but there is
a class of men who make a very loud outcry—what I call the political
farmers; they are presidents of alliances, and all sorts of agricultural
organizations.” These were “men who are continually making political
headway for themselves,” in Vilas’s view, rather than looking out for the
real interests of the farmer.27
On the exchanges there was little doubt that “the farmers have been
misled on this subject,” as a member of the Toledo Produce Exchange
put it. “I do not wonder that the uninstructed person” could be con-
vinced that speculation reduces prices, agreed Charles Hamill of the
board of trade.28 But who would take the trouble to deceive so many
farmers about commodity trading? Who had an interest in making
them believe it was harmful? On the exchanges and in the urban press,
the answer seemed clear: the real backers of this legislation, the men
pulling the strings behind the scenes, were the millers.
Millers bought grain from farmers, just like speculators did. If they
could push the speculators out of the market, they would be the only
buyers left. “The only competition the millers now have is in the ex-
changes in the buying of grain for future delivery,” declared H. A. Foss
of the board of trade. “Therefore, the abolition of time dealings would
eliminate this competition and in the end surely would reduce the
number of buyers of cash cereals from the farmer.” The Chicago Tribune
recognized that the bill “will benefit the millers more than any other
class,” because it would allow them “to beat down the farmer when he
wants to sell his wheat.” In Congress, the New York Times reported, the
2 7 “Minutes of Conference,” 2 Jan. 1893, WFV, box 15, folder 2, 1, 8–9, 20, 49.
28 Denison B. Smith to Vilas, 15 Dec. 1892, WFV, box 15, folder 1; “Minutes of
Conference,” 1.
124
124 Speculation
bill was known as “the millers’ friend.” The Times alleged that the peti-
tions of support ostensibly streaming in from farmers’ organizations
throughout the country were in fact written in Washington and sent
out for signatures, as part of a public relations campaign funded by the
millers. “There isn’t any question about it,” William Vilas told the lead-
ers of the board of trade. “They have worked up a fictitious, apparently
agricultural sentiment to support their interests.”29
Several of Vilas’s correspondents likewise singled out the millers.
“It is promoted by the millers,” insisted the grain merchant Robert
Eliot, “who seem to wish to get a monopoly of the trade, and rule
out the speculator, who is a competitor and who aids in keeping up
prices.” E. C. Wall, writing on behalf of the Milwaukee Chamber of
Commerce, called the legislation “an absurd bill” that “will do the
farmers infinite harm,” but one that “is a good thing for wealthy mill-
ers; for they can then buy the farmers’ grain at their own price.” Even
some of Wisconsin’s farmers recognized who stood to gain. “I am a
farmer,” declared E. H. Harris of Beloit, “and while I am opposed to
the Chicago methods of playing wheat ‘Poker,’ still I prefer it rather
than take the chances of being dumped bodily into the Mill Elevators
at Minneapolis.”30
Indeed, William Washburn, the Senate’s leading proponent of leg-
islation, was in the milling business himself, as the urban press missed
no opportunity to point out. His family owned a large milling com-
pany in Minneapolis, the predecessor to the firm that would later be
called General Mills. The Tribune accused him of “pushing this bill for
mercenary and not philanthropic motives.” Washburn provided only
the lamest of defenses. “I know there has been a good deal of this talk
running in the newspapers, assuming that this bill is in the interest of
the millers,” he acknowledged on the Senate floor. “I should like to un-
derstand under what provision of this bill the miller gets any advantage
29 Untitled typescript (1909), CBT, box 328, folder 2; Chicago Daily Tribune, 26
Aug. 1890, 5; New York Times, 31 Jan. 1893, 3; 25 June 1892, 5; 28 Feb. 1893, 4;
“Minutes of Conference,” 20.
30 Robert Eliot to Vilas, 15 Jan. 1892, box 13, folder 1; E. C. Wall to Vilas, 3 Mar.
1892, box 13, folder 2; E. H. Harris to Vilas, 3 Jan. 1893, box 15, folder 2, all
in WFV.
125
over anybody else in the world; how he occupies any different position
from anybody else who wants to buy wheat.”31 Of course, other than
speculators, no one but a miller had any occasion to buy wheat straight
from the farmer.
For opponents of the legislation, the millers’ incentive to push the
speculators aside provided the answer to the puzzle of how so many
farmers could be so wrong. It was all a nefarious plot: the millers had
tricked the farmers into believing that speculators were taking their
money, when in fact the speculators were the very people who were
protecting the farmers from the millers themselves, who would take
even more of the farmers’ money if speculation were prohibited.
In assessing the truth of this theory, it will be useful to separate the
incentives of the millers from those of the farmers. The largest millers
almost certainly did stand to gain from the abolition of commodity
speculation. Smaller millers needed to hedge on the exchanges, but the
bigger millers may well have been able to bear the risk of price declines
themselves, if they could pay a low enough price to farmers. Prohibiting
commodity speculation might have cleared the field, not just of the
speculators, but of the smaller millers as well. At harvest time, the big
millers would have had the farmers over a barrel. “Gentlemen, if you
put the exchanges out of business, who would profit?” the cotton dealer
Solomon Cone asked the House Agriculture Committee. “Do you see
the representatives of the big mill interests of the South?” Cone was
there to testify against the legislation, but, he explained, “I guarantee
that my own brother, who buys for his different mills over 100,000
bales of cotton, if he could control me, would not have me here.”32 The
millers would likely have been the main beneficiaries of prohibiting
commodity speculation.
But the millers hardly invented the notion that speculation hurt
farmers. As we saw in chapter 1, there was a long tradition of belief
that speculators could manipulate prices to their advantage, and that
speculators were nonproductive middlemen who took money out of
the pockets of producers. These propositions would have been tenets
31 Boston Evening Transcript, 13 July 1892, 5; New York Times, 16 July 1892, 9;
Chicago Daily Tribune, 23 July 1892, 4; Congressional Record 23 (1892): 6442.
32 Hearings Before the Committee on Agriculture, 95.
126
126 Speculation
Arriving there he finds that on this exchange they are not selling
horses but future contracts for the delivery of horses, and that these
transactions were going to control the price he was to receive for
his horse. Suppose he should see a future contract for the delivery
of a horse sold for a given price, then another future contract for a
horse at a lower price, and then another at a higher price, and some-
body standing by, a member of the exchange, should say to him as
these contracts were being sold and bought: “Now, the price of your
horse has gone down, now it has gone up.” And if you asked why,
should answer, “Because these sale contracts for the delivery of horses
that are taking place, actual contracts, where there is an expectation
that delivery will take place, indicate the market value of your horse,
in fact control the price you are to receive for him.” When he saw
these transactions going on and on and on would it be surprising if
he finally asked, “Where are all these horses? I don’t see any horses
that are being traded in under these contracts; where are the horses?
I have seen dozens of sales, I have seen hundreds of contracts for
horses sold, but I have not seen a horse.” Would you blame him if
he reached the conclusion that they were phantom horses that were
being dealt in? Why, of course, you would not. Neither would you
blame him if he objected to having the market price of his horse
influenced or controlled by these transactions.
128 Speculation
any economic effects the bills might have, but because, as the Observer
put it, “the principle that controls in this matter is set forth by the
Lord in the decalogue”—the commandment that prohibits stealing.
The Union saw the bills as evidence of “the awakening moral sentiment
of the Nation.” The journalist George Muller pronounced commodity
speculation “unworthy of nineteenth century progress. It is selfish and
dehumanizing.” He thought it should be abolished on moral grounds
even “if in the process of reformation, the farmer temporarily gets less
for his product.” The minister George Hubbard agreed that “when
weighed in the balances of eternal justice, speculation is found want-
ing. Its character will not stand the supreme test. It is a moral wrong.”35
Speculation was still widely understood as a form of gambling, a
practice moralists considered wrong regardless of whether it was profit-
able to any particular participant. Speculation on the board of trade
“can hardly be justified in the light of the moral law,” one critic charged.
“With regard to the character of gambling there is no controversy. Every
one admits its immorality.” The Massachusetts Ploughman contrasted
the gambler, who knows he is doing wrong, with the grain speculator,
who erroneously “imagines he is doing a very respectable thing.” In
the late nineteenth century, the Louisiana State Lottery was a popu-
lar metaphor for all the evils associated with gambling, because it was
the only legal state lottery in the country. “But, after all, what a small
affair has the Louisiana lottery been,” declared one magazine in 1892,
“when compared with the ‘bucket shop’ and Board of Trade.” When
the lottery was abolished, a rural Minnesota newspaper declared that
it was “time that the option room of the Chicago Board of Trade was
catalogued with the Louisiana State Lottery and relegated to the shades
of an ancient and barbarous method of appropriating the unearned
increment from the pockets of the hardworking citizens of the great
northwest. By the side of comparatively honest methods in gambling,
trading in options will in the history of the near future take its place
as the co-partner and twin fraud of bunco steering.” In the Senate,
130 Speculation
But the agrarian critique of speculation was often something more than
that. It was a critique of the entire system, a desire to return to ear-
lier ways of moving food from the farm to the consumer. If the entire
system could have been dismantled, commodity markets would have
been local once again, and prices would have once again varied widely
from one place to the next. The economic effect on farmers would have
varied widely too. Some would have been better off some of the time,
and some would have been worse off some of the time.
Of course, there was no possibility of dismantling the entire distri-
bution network. The only parts of it available to attack were the ex-
changes. The farmers had to focus on the exchanges, but by linking
speculation on the exchanges to the decline in commodity prices, the
farmers were stuck with an implausible economic argument. And while
lower commodity prices were bad for farmers, they were a great ben-
efit to consumers, so in calling for legislation on the ostensible ground
that it would raise food prices, the farmers were making it much less
likely that nonfarmers would join their cause. That Congress neverthe-
less came so close to shutting down the exchanges is a testament to the
political force of the agrarian movement in the 1890s.
Justifiable Gambling
The argument that commodity speculation hurt farmers was even less
plausible in 1920 than it had been in 1890. In the intervening years,
the issue’s political visibility had given rise to some thorough defenses
of speculation’s role in the economy. The American political econo-
mists of the first half of the nineteenth century had tended to classify
speculation as a nonproductive activity, one that added no value to the
goods being traded. In the later part of the century, however, American
economists began to take a different view. Speculation, they asserted,
was just as useful as manufacturing.
The leading voice in this school of thought was Henry Crosby
Emery, who spent most of his career in the economics department at
Yale. Emery’s doctoral dissertation, Speculation on the Stock and Produce
Exchanges of the United States, was published as a book in 1896, not
long after the peak of antispeculation agitation. “The criticism directed
against speculation is made from two somewhat conflicting points of
132
132 Speculation
40 Henry Crosby Emery, Speculation on the Stock and Produce Exchanges of the
United States (New York: Columbia University, 1896), 98; Henry Crosby
Emery, “Legislation Against Futures,” Political Science Quarterly 10 (1895): 62–
64; Henry Crosby Emery, “The Place of the Speculator in the Theory of
Distribution,” American Economic Association Publications 1 (1900): 103.
133
established, added the Chicago law professor Van Buren Denslow, they
were telegraphed around the world, “so that every producer and pur-
chaser gets his quotation with his morning paper and as often during
the day as he wishes.” The value of such timely and exact knowledge of
prices, Denslow explained, could be seen by contrasting grain markets
with markets in nonstandardized items like clothing, furniture, and
jewelry, where participants had to spend substantial time simply trying
to ascertain the true value of what they were buying and selling. With
the commodities traded on exchanges, market participants “know that
millions of dollars are staked in behalf of a rise in price, and an equal
number of millions in favor of a fall, and that the actual price quoted
is the precise point at which these millions balance. They know that
the published quotation is not one fixed by the arbitrary determina-
tion of any one dealer, but by the aggregate verdict of them all.” As the
Cornell economist James Boyle concluded in his book-length defense
of the board of trade, speculation’s long-term benefits greatly exceeded
whatever temporary dislocations it might cause.41
These new, sophisticated defenses of speculation joined the older,
more intuitive defenses that had been circulating for a century.
Opponents of regulation still argued that every merchant was in some
sense a speculator. They still pointed out that speculation was the driv-
ing force behind the establishment of new enterprises. And they still
contended that regulation would in any event be fruitless. “What a
bewildering effect Washington air must have on the human brain!” ex-
claimed one commercial newspaper while Congress was considering
the Hatch and Washburn bills in 1892. “So many men when they get
there acquire so exaggerated an idea of the power of a statute as panacea
for every commercial and financial irregularity.” The Chicago Tribune
agreed that “the amateur merchants who think they know it all suppose
themselves able to legislate the community into a Utopia.” In fact, the
134 Speculation
136 Speculation
4 7 42 Stat. 187 (1921); S. Rep. No. 212, 67th Cong., 1st Sess. (1921), 4.
48 Hill v. Wallace, 259 U.S. 44 (1922); 42 Stat. 998 (1922); Board of Trade v. Olsen,
262 U.S. 1 (1923).
4
Q
Selling Blue Sky
1 Will Payne, “How Kansas Drove Out a Set of Thieves,” Saturday Evening Post,
2 Dec. 1911, 3–4.
138
139
2 Kansas City Journal, 2 Apr. 1910; Topeka Journal, 8 Apr. 1910; Kansas City
Journal, 4 June 1910. The citations in this chapter to Kansas newspapers are
from the Kansas Historical Society’s Kansas Memory website, at http://www.
kansasmemory.org.
3 Tenth Biennial Report of the Bank Commissioner of the State of Kansas
(Topeka: State Printing Office, 1910), xiii; Rick A. Fleming, “100 Years of
Securities Law: Examining a Foundation Laid in the Kansas Blue Sky,”
Washburn Law Journal 50 (2011): 583–609.
4 The blue sky laws, with dates of adoption, are usefully summarized in Paul
G. Mahoney, “The Origin of the Blue- Sky Laws: A Test of Competing
Hypotheses,” Journal of Law & Economics 46 (2003): 232. For details of the blue
140
140 Speculation
blue sky laws because “blue sky” was a common metaphor for a worth-
less investment. “When a promoter by artful persuasions succeeds in
getting money for something which has no value except in the mind
of the credulous purchaser,” an 1895 newspaper explained, “he is said
to have been selling ‘blue sky.’â•›” In a 1906 advertisement for shares in a
Colorado mine, the promoter insisted, “I am not selling ‘Blue Sky.’â•›”5
Selling blue sky was what the blue sky laws were supposed to prevent.
The blue sky laws responded to a very old concern with speculation—╉
that speculators were likely to harm themselves and their families by
taking on risks they lacked the ability to evaluate intelligently. But if
the problem was an old one, the solution was something that had never
been tried before: to have the government evaluate the risks and guide
investors to safety. If the state could screen out the investments that
were too speculative or were likely to be frauds, one of the primary
dangers of speculation would be a thing of the past.
A Fair€Return
No one could have expected the blue sky law movement in 1910, when
Joseph Dolley opened his informal investment advisory service in the
office of the Kansas state bank commissioner. In retrospect, to be sure,
one can see the blue sky laws as emblematic of a broader concern for
consumer protection in the progressive era, the same concern that gave
rise to pure food and drug laws, occupational licensing, and antitrust
laws.6 More broadly, one can see the blue sky laws as an example of
the use of government to mitigate risk, like the establishment of work-
ers’ compensation and unemployment insurance, two other develop-
ments that were then in progress.7 But at the time it would have been
sky laws in effect as of 1919, see John M. Elliott, The Annotated Blue Sky Laws of
the United States (Cincinnati: W. H. Anderson Co., 1919).
5 Lawrence R. Gelber, The Gelberlaw Glossary, http://╉www.gelberlaw.net/╉Glossary
.html; Chicago Tribune, 25 Feb. 1906, 10.
6 Morton Keller, Regulating a New Economy: Public Policy and Economic Change
in America, 1900–╉1933 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990).
For contemporary recognition of this point, see William B. Shaw, “Progressive
Law-╉Making in Many States,” Review of Reviews 48 (1913): 84–╉93.
7 David A. Moss, When All Else Fails: Government as the Ultimate Risk Manager
(Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2002).
141
very difficult, probably impossible, to predict that the first serious stock
market regulation of the twentieth century would take the form of blue
sky laws. In the preceding decades, while there had been calls to regu-
late securities sales in just about every other conceivable way, no one
had proposed that government officials should decide, company by
company, which investments would offer a fair return.
All the old worries about speculation were still very much alive.
Speculation was still widely viewed as a form of gambling. “Of all the
varied types of gambling doubtless the most colossal is that of the great
stock exchanges,” declared one minister in 1895, “and the success of
every rich man’s corner is apt to be followed by the dishonesty or sui-
cide, or both, of some of his victims.” As the humor magazine Puck de-
scribed the successful speculator, “it is a common thing to see bestowed
upon a man who began with nothing of his own and ended with a great
deal of other people’s property the flattering commendation that he
was a self-made man.” The press was still full of articles worrying that
speculators would bankrupt themselves and their families, that specula-
tion was a nonproductive activity, and that prices were controlled by
a small cabal of insiders. “The editor who fails to have a fling at Wall
Street as often as two or three times a week, especially if he live[s]in the
South or West, must be unusually well supplied with prize fights and
divorce cases,” smirked Brayton Ives, the president of the New York
Stock Exchange. “And what demagogue addressing his constituents
omits in any speech to denounce it as the home of the monopolist and
the hotbed of injustice?” The investment banker Henry Clews agreed
that “it seems to be a genial pastime for men in various walks of life
who know very little about financial affairs, and the methods of doing
business in Wall Street, to denounce this great centre of the moneyed
interests, as the sum of all villanies, a kind of Pandora’s box, but with-
out any hope at the bottom.”8
142 Speculation
stock price declined, and then make even more by buying as it went
back up. “This is pure swindling,” he concluded.11
To level the playing field, some proposed requiring corporations to
disclose their financial status. “Make the seller of securities publish an
accurate analysis of the values, equities, and earnings of which these
securities are representative,” one writer urged. “Such reports should
be promptly published in order to permit investors to see exactly what
the assets and liabilities are,” agreed Charles Batchelder, a director of the
Boston Lumber Company. If the law could require food to be honestly
labeled, he suggested, it could do the same for securities. “Publicity,”
he concluded, was “the best safeguard [not only] for the investor, but
also for the community.” In the first decade of the twentieth century, a
handful of states began to require such disclosures, but only for public
utility companies and railroads, two kinds of firms the states already
regulated more intensively than other forms of enterprise. The econo-
mist Earl Howard even proposed a similar disclosure requirement for
brokers. If they had to reveal the name of the person for whom they
were trading, he argued, the manipulation of prices by insiders would
become impossible. “No manipulator would care to try the game with
all the cards on the table,” he concluded, “for the first essential of ma-
nipulation is secrecy.”12 But no state adopted this proposal.
144 Speculation
146 Speculation
companies had been investigated by his office, and fewer than one hun-
dred had been allowed to sell securities. Dolley also provided recurring
but widely variant estimates of how much the people of Kansas had
saved in investment losses by virtue of his guidance—amounts ranging
from $2 million to $77 million in the first year alone. He often declared
with pride that whatever the annual figure, it was more than the cost of
running the entire state government for the year.16
How could an office consisting of only a few people conduct in-
vestigations of so many companies in such a short time? The task was
perhaps not as monumental as it might seem. By Dolley’s own account,
most of the firms “never get farther than making the application. It was
not necessary for us to turn them all down. As soon as they found out
what information we were going to ask them for and what the nature
of our investigation was going to be they suddenly changed their minds
and withdrew their applications.” When necessary, Dolley could also
seek advice from other government officials and from experts at the
University of Kansas. “For example,” he explained, “a company recently
came to the department with a new electric battery, which they claimed
was going to revolutionize the electrical world.” The firm had endorse-
ments from prominent bankers. “We at once presented the matter to
the electrical experts at our State University, and they advised us within
thirty days that the battery was an absolute fake, and would not do
what the company claimed for it.” Dolley refused to allow the company
to sell stock in Kansas.17
But even with many applications aborted, and even with the as-
sistance of experts, Dolley’s office still had to evaluate the merits of
hundreds of securities offerings, many of which were based on assets
located out of state. Dolley claimed to conduct thorough investiga-
tions of all of them. “If the financial statement does not satisfy him—
and he is a trained banker—he sends an expert auditor to go over
16 New York Times, 13 Oct. 1911, 10; Wall Street Journal, 2 Mar. 1912, 6; Eleventh
Biennial Report of the Bank Commissioner of the State of Kansas (Topeka: State
Printing Office, 1912), 6; William Allen White, “Free Kansas: Where the People
Rule the People,” Outlook, 24 Feb. 1912, 412; “A Blue Sky Law,” Independent 72
(1912): 375; Topeka Capital, 12 May 1912.
17 “The Kansas ‘Blue Sky Law,’ ” Central Law Journal 75 (1912): 222.
147
148 Speculation
verbatim. By the end of 1913, twenty-four states had blue sky laws. Most
of the remaining states would have blue sky laws by the end of the
decade. Even the US-governed Philippines got one.20
Why were blue sky laws so popular? Some of their support no doubt
came from prospective investors, who were genuinely fearful of being
defrauded by fast-talking salesmen. Public participation in the securities
markets increased dramatically in the early twentieth century.21 Many
people were buying stocks and bonds for the first time. They must have
welcomed some guidance from the state. Stock promoters “are said to
fleece Californians out of at least $20,000,000 a year,” gasped the San
Francisco Chronicle in an editorial urging California to give its citizens
the protection Kansans already enjoyed. In the paper’s view, the blue
sky law was simply “a good idea, floated on a good phrase.”22
But inexperienced investors were not the only supporters of blue
sky laws. In Kansas, Joseph Dolley’s scrutiny of securities sales had
been welcomed by the state’s business community, who recognized
that the blue sky law would be a barrier to out-of-state competitors.
One of Topeka’s leading bond brokers praised Dolley for making it
easier for in-state firms to sell bonds. The treasurer of the Atchison,
Topeka & Santa Fe Railroad was just as happy with Dolley’s work. “I
believe the established corporations of the state … should receive the
support of the people of the state,” he explained. “A Kansan having
20 Letters to Walter Stubbs from John Sullivan, 7 Feb. 1912; W. C. Edson, 16 May
1912; H. J. Fitzgerald, 9 July 1912; Wade H. Barnes, 28 Aug. 1912; John Wright,
12 Oct. 1912; William Dinwiddie, 30 Dec. 1912; E. T. Merritt, 30 Dec. 1912, all
from the Kansas Historical Society’s Kansas Memory website, at http://www
.kansasmemory.org; Topeka Capital, n.d.; C. A. Dykstra, “Blue Sky
Legislation,” American Political Science Review 7 (1913): 231–32; Los Angeles
Times, 5 Feb. 1916, 12.
21 Julia C. Ott, When Wall Street Met Main Street: The Quest for an Investors’
Democracy (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2011); Mary
O’Sullivan, “The Expansion of the U.S. Stock Market, 1885–1930: Historical
Facts and Theoretical Fashions,” Enterprise and Society 8 (2007): 489–542. For
an argument that increased public participation in the stock market funda-
mentally changed the nature of speculation, an argument I find unpersuasive,
see Lawrence E. Mitchell, The Speculation Economy: How Finance Triumphed
Over Industry (San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Publishers, 2007).
22 San Francisco Chronicle, 11 Sept. 1912, 6.
149
23 Topeka Journal, 25 Sept. 1910; Kansas City Journal, 30 Dec. 1910; Jonathan
R. Macey and Geoffrey P. Miller, “Origin of the Blue Sky Laws,” Texas Law
Review 70 (1991): 347–97. For the view that protectionist concerns were a big-
ger influence on the form of blue sky laws than on whether blue sky laws were
adopted, see Mahoney, “Origins of the Blue-Sky Laws,” 229–51.
24 Chicago Daily Tribune, 18 Feb. 1912, 5; 22 Feb. 1912, 14; 26 Feb. 1912, 14;
Wall Street Journal, 22 Nov. 1912, 6; Los Angeles Times, 17 Oct. 1912, II2; San
Francisco Chronicle, 3 June 1915, 16; “The Kansas ‘Blue Sky Law,’ ” Central Law
Journal 75 (1912): 222; Lee Herdman to L. W. Berle, 6 Oct. 1932, AAB, box 20.
150
150 Speculation
law,” because it made politicians “the judges of the solvency … and the
honest intentions of corporations.”26
The IBA pursued a two-part strategy. The first part was to propose
a milder blue sky law for states to adopt, one that required sellers of
securities to disclose information about the securities but did not em-
power a government official to determine whether they would be a
sound investment. The IBA wished to avoid giving the “impression that
the position of the Association is negative and opposed to the popu-
lar sentiment in favor of necessary legislation to prevent the promo-
tion of fraudulent securities,” explained Robert Reed, the IBA’s lawyer.
Instead, “we should try to work out an effective general law that will
meet the situation,” a law that “will settle the ‘blue sky’ frauds without
further resort to ‘blue sky’ or imaginative remedies.” Reputable sellers
of securities had an interest in driving the disreputable out of business,
so long as that could be accomplished without unduly burdening the
reputable. The IBA accordingly drafted a model blue sky law, which it
circulated to its members, who sought to have it introduced in their
home state legislatures. The IBA’s version of a blue sky law borrowed
from the British Companies Act of 1908, which required a company
selling securities to file a prospectus with the government, disclosing a
wide range of information about the company.27
The second part of the IBA’s strategy involved filing lawsuits seeking
to have the existing blue sky laws declared unconstitutional. The IBA
did not file the suits itself; rather, it organized them, by identifying
plaintiffs, retaining local counsel, and formulating legal arguments. The
plaintiffs were typically out-of-state investment banks and corporations.
26 “The ‘Blue-Sky’ Laws,” Bankers’ Magazine 84 (1912): 636; Henry C. Emery,
“Speculation on the Stock Exchanges and Public Regulation of the Exchanges,”
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 5 (1915): 80; Wall Street
Journal, 11 Apr. 1913, 1; New York Times, 27 Mar. 1913, 10; Los Angeles Times, 30
June 1913, II4; 1 Mar. 1913, II8.
27 “Report of General Counsel,” Investment Bankers’ Association of America
Bulletin 2 (1914): 8–9; Robert R. Reed and Lester H. Washburn, Blue Sky
Laws: Analysis and Text (New York: Clark Boardman Co., 1921), x–xi; “Pursuit
of Swindlers,” Independent 74 (1913): 486; Wall Street Journal, 21 Feb. 1913, 5;
Wall Street Journal, 26 Nov. 1912, 1; 27 Mar. 1913, 1; “Blue Sky Laws,” Columbia
Law Review 24 (1924): 79–80.
152
152 Speculation
These efforts bore fruit quickly. In 1914, courts invalidated the blue sky
laws of Michigan, Iowa, and West Virginia. The Michigan judges seem
to have been taken aback by the breadth of the state’s law, which, as
in Kansas, prohibited the sale of securities if a state commission con-
cluded that investors were likely to lose their money. “It does not cover
fraudulent securities merely, but reaches the sale of securities that are
honest, valid, and safe,” the court huffed. “It does not simply protect
the unwary citizen against fraudulent misleading, but it prevents
the experienced investor from deliberately assisting an enterprise which
he thinks gives sufficient promise of gain to offset the risk of loss.” The
judges were equally alarmed by the commission’s “uncontrolled discre-
tion” to grant or deny approval based on its view as to the fairness of the
company’s business plan. “Broader and vaguer language could not be
chosen,” the court observed. That was enough for the court to find that
Michigan’s blue sky law unconstitutionally denied due process and in-
terfered with interstate commerce. The Iowa and West Virginia judges
had the same reaction. The Iowa court acknowledged that Iowa’s blue
sky law was enacted with a laudable purpose—“to protect the humble,
honest citizens of the state, unlearned in the intricacy of business affairs
as conducted at this day from being plundered and despoiled of their
small earnings and property, acquired through years of patient toil, by
the alluring machinations and the deceptive, misleading, and fraudu-
lent devices which the unscrupulous, cunning, and deceitful ‘Get-Rich-
Quick-Wallingfords’ of our day practice.” But a praiseworthy goal did
not allow the state “to punish the doing of such customary, everyday
transactions” as the sale of securities, because the prohibition exceeded
the state’s limited power over interstate commerce.28
The IBA’s winning streak continued in 1915 and 1916. Ohio’s blue
sky law met the same fate. After the Michigan legislature amended its
blue sky law, the court struck it down once again. In light of all these
decisions, concluded the lawyer Lee Perrin, while a state could prohibit
fraud in the sale of securities, the state lacked the power to substitute
its own judgment for that of the investor. “With the security and the
material facts once fairly before him,” Perrin advised, “he should be left
to his own discretion.”29
Meanwhile, in states with blue sky laws that were still in force, ad-
ministrators were reconsidering the wisdom of evaluating the sound-
ness of every security offered in the state. Even Joseph Dolley was
having second thoughts as he neared the end of his term in office. It
was simply impossible to investigate them all. He proposed a new law
that would allow reputable investment bankers to obtain licenses that
would entitle them to sell any security, without the state having to scru-
tinize each one. The Kansas legislature enacted this new law in 1913.30
As a result of these three developments—lobbying by the IBA,
court decisions striking down several of the early statutes, and state
officials’ realization that a full merit review of all securities issues was
impractical—the nature of blue sky laws changed in the mid-1910s.
Most of the states in the first wave of blue sky laws, from 1911 to 1913,
sought to prohibit the sale of securities that were unlikely to offer a
fair return. But the second generation of blue sky laws, from 1915 on,
by and large abandoned the effort to evaluate the soundness of invest-
ments. The new laws tended instead merely to prohibit fraud and to
require sellers to disclose information. Even Kansas, which had pio-
neered merit review in 1911, gave it up in 1915. Kansas’s new law, like
its counterparts in other states, omitted any requirement that securities
offer a fair return.31 The IBA’s campaign had been a success.
By the time the constitutionality of blue sky laws reached the United
States Supreme Court, in three cases decided in 1917, all three of the laws
at issue were of the second-wave type, prohibiting fraud but not oth-
erwise empowering state officials to judge the merits of an investment.
The court upheld all three. “It may be that there are better ways to meet
the evils at which the statute is directed,” Justice Joseph McKenna said
29 Geiger-Jones Co. v. Turner, 230 F. 233 (S.D. Ohio 1916); N.W. Halsey & Co.
v. Merrick, 228 F. 805 (E.D. Mich. 1915); Lee J. Perrin, “The ‘Blue Sky Laws,’ ”
Bench & Bar 10 (1916): 496
30 New York Times, 18 Mar. 1913, 10; Fleming, “100 Years,” 604–5.
31 Fleming, “100 Years,” 606.
154
154 Speculation
of Michigan’s revised law. “We can only reply that it is not our func-
tion to decide between measures.” In prohibiting fraud, the state was
doing what it had always done. All that was new was that the state was
policing fraudulent sales before the sales took place rather than after.
“The policy of a state and its expression in laws must vary with circum-
stances,” McKenna continued. “It burdens honest business, it is true,
but burdens it only that, under its forms, dishonest business cannot be
done.”32 Had one of the first-╉wave statutes reached the court, the result
might well have been different.
Only seven years had passed since Joseph Dolley had begun offering
investment advice to the citizens of Kansas. Blue sky laws had swept the
country, but they had weakened. Many states had briefly experimented
with a scheme in which government officials would serve as investment
advisors to the public, separating the good investments from the bad,
to ensure that state residents were not ruined by speculation. The ex-
periment had been a failure. The plan exceeded both the states’ author-
ity under the constitutional law of the era and the limited institutional
capacities of the officials charged with determining which investments
would offer a fair return.
A Ridiculous Situation
Joseph Dolley’s experiment had failed, but the nation was left with a
body of law that had not existed before he began offering investment
advice to Kansans. By the late 1910s and early 1920s, most of the state
blue sky laws had a family resemblance. They required sellers of securi-
ties to disclose information, and most authorized government officials
to scrutinize these filings for signs of fraud before granting permission
to sell. But this similarity on paper concealed some very large differ-
ences among states in practice.
Wisconsin, for example, had a typical second-╉generation blue sky law.
The law did not even apply to many classes of securities that were unlikely
32 Merrick v. N.W. Halsey & Co., 242, U.S. 568, 589, 586–╉87 (1917). The other
two cases were Hall v. Geiger Jones Co., 242 U.S. 539 (1917) (concerning Ohio’s
law), and Caldwell v. Sioux Falls Stock Yards Co., 242 U.S. 559 (1917) (concern-
ing South Dakota’s).
155
156 Speculation
Much of the division’s work involved simply making sure that sell-
ers of securities complied with the rules. Greenbaum Sons, a Chicago
bond dealer, sold 182 different bond issues in Wisconsin before it both-
ered to apply for permission. The division informed Greenbaum Sons
that it would be barred from doing business in Wisconsin unless it
promptly qualified all those bonds. Nearly half of the issues had been
under $1,000, and for those the division allowed Greenbaum Sons the
alternative of repurchasing them from their holders for the sale price
plus accrued interest. But the division made clear that its authority
under the blue sky law concerned only the sale of securities, not the
ongoing conduct of corporations once the securities had been sold. “It
was not intended that stockholders should be freed from any necessity
of protecting their rights when this law was passed,” explained Garfield
Canright, the division’s director in the 1920s. “Our jurisdiction has to
do rather with the right to start the enterprise. After it is started the
stockholders must see that they elect proper directors and that the di-
rectors properly perform their duties.” So far as one can tell today, the
Wisconsin blue sky law seems to have succeeded in preventing at least
some of the more egregious forms of fraud in the sale of securities.
“It is, of course, impossible entirely to prevent violations of any law,”
Canright acknowledged. “We believe, however, that this situation is
gradually improving.”37
At the other end of the spectrum was Illinois, which had a blue
sky law that was similar to Wisconsin’s on paper but very different in
practice. “The Illinois blue sky law is practically null and void in its
operation,” admitted Walter Flint, who ran the state’s securities depart-
ment. “There is no appropriation for its enforcement.” Flint’s office
had allowed approximately seven hundred companies to sell securities
without conducting much of an investigation. “The trouble is that we
have no investigators,” Flint explained. “Our method is simply this. We
take the list of officers of the company applying for a license and ask
for their references. We then correspond with the persons referred to.
158 Speculation
40 James Waterhouse Angell, “The Illinois Blue Sky Law,” Journal of Political
Economy 28 (1920): 316, 314.
41 Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Convention of the Investment Bankers Association
of America (Chicago: Investment Bankers Association of America, 1919), 122.
160
160 Speculation
43 New York Times, 3 Sept. 1912, 2; Current Literature, Dec. 1912, 34; “Regulation
of the Sale of Securities,” Bankers’ Magazine 86 (1913): 418–19; “ ‘Blue Sky’ Laws
Obscured by a Judicial Cloud,” Bankers’ Magazine 88 (1914): 283; “Federal Blue-
Sky Legislation,” Bankers’ Magazine 104 (1922): 979; Los Angeles Times, 9 July
1914, I5; New York Times, 8 Oct. 1919, 29; Robert R. Reed, “ ‘Blue Sky’ Laws,”
Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 88 (1920): 184, 183.
See also “Finance & Investment,” Current Opinion, 1 Nov. 1924, 652.
44 Money Trust Investigation: Investigation of Financial and Monetary Conditions
in the United States (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1913),
part I, 6; H.R. Rep. No. 1593, 62nd Cong., 3rd Sess. (1913), 42–54, 162–63.
162
162 Speculation
wet states. But Denison’s bills were consistently opposed by the IBA,
who wanted federal legislation precisely so that state officials would not
be able to exercise so much discretionary power over their business.
“It would be a ridiculous situation,” scoffed the New York investment
banker George Hodges, “for the Federal Government to delegate its
power to a blue-sky commission in Kansas or wherever it might be.”46
By the late 1920s, despite the existence of blue sky laws in nearly
every state, and despite the interest of both bankers and regulators in
adopting a federal version, Congress’s efforts to enact a federal blue sky
law had foundered on disagreement over the details. Of course, the
stock market was booming. Speculators were making money. It was not
the best time to interest lawmakers or investors in imposing new limits
on speculation.
That would change.
Between March 1925 and September 1929, the Dow Jones Industrial
Average rose from 115 to 381. By the middle of 1932, it had plummeted
to 41. The stocks listed on the New York Stock Exchange were worth
nearly $90 million in the fall of 1929, but by the summer of 1932, their
value was only $15.6 million.1 Never before in the history of the United
States had so many people lost so much money so quickly.
The stock market crash of 1929–32 gave rise to several far-reaching
reforms. The Securities Act of 1933 required sellers of securities to dis-
close a wide range of information. The Securities Exchange Act of 1934
imposed a variety of restrictions on the buying and selling of stock.2
The Glass-Steagall Act (a part of the Banking Act of 1933) separated
commercial banks from investment banks. The two securities acts still
govern the stock market today; the Glass-Steagall Act would continue
to structure the banking industry, despite gradual weakening, until it
was repealed in 1999.
164
╇ 165
3 Lewis H. Haney, “The Stock Market and Business,” North American Review
225 (1928): 175; Alan H. Temple, “The Financial Outlook,” North American
166
166 Speculation
Review 226 (1928): 641; “Stock Market Jamboree,” Time, 28 May 1928, 32; A. M.
Sakolski, “American Speculative Manias, Past and Present,” Current History 30
(1929): 861; Carter Glass to G. H. Gray, 11 Feb. 1929, CG, box 311.
4 Wall Street Journal, 15 May 1928, 1; Donald Rea Hanson, “In Defense of
Speculation,” Forum 81 (1929): 57; Thomas W. Lamont to Herbert Hoover,
19 Oct. 1929, HHL, box 1049; H. W. Moorhouse, “What’s Happening in
Wall Street,” North American Review 226 (1928): 678; New York Times, 16 Oct.
1929, 8.
167
Some were worried that stock speculation had spiraled out of con-
trol, others thought it entirely justified, and there was a third position
in the middle, that even if there was too much speculation, nothing
constructive could be done about it. George Roberts, the vice presi-
dent of the National City Bank of New York, was willing to concede
that “there is a vast amount of uninformed speculation” that served no
economic purpose. But “it is impossible to require everybody to pass a
civil service examination before engaging in any kind of speculation,”
Roberts observed, “and it is exceedingly difficult if not impossible to
discriminate at least in law, between acts of the same kind which in
one case represent perfectly legitimate operations and in another case
may be of the undesirable class.” Legislation curbing speculation might
be a cure worse than the disease, because it risked driving off the good
transactions, as well as the bad. Without speculation, “the conduct of
railways and large-scale industry would probably be found a hard job,”
reckoned the Bankers’ Magazine. “To carry on these enterprises requires
a lot of money, which cannot be had from those who are investors of
the purely conservative type.”5
Previous booms had seen similar debates about the dangers of specu-
lation, but the debate in the 1920s was more intense and more con-
sequential than in earlier episodes, because the establishment of the
Federal Reserve System in 1913 gave the government a new policy lever.
By raising interest rates, the Federal Reserve could dampen speculation,
by making it more difficult for speculators to earn a positive return
with borrowed money. Throughout the second half of the decade, crit-
ics repeatedly called upon the Federal Reserve to do just that. “I have
noted with growing anxiety the steady increase in speculation in the
country, more particularly centered in the New York Stock Market,
which has for some time been engaged in positive gambling in secu-
rities,” Wisconsin senator Irvine Lenroot wrote in 1925, in an urgent
plea to Federal Reserve Board governor Daniel Crissinger to raise in-
terest rates. “Does not the present cheap money induced by the low
discount rates indirectly stimulate speculation on the New York Stock
5 George E. Roberts, “Speculation and Its Influence Upon Business,” Bankers’
Magazine 117 (1928): 967; “Fresh Outburst of Speculation,” Bankers’ Magazine
116 (1928): 625.
168
168 Speculation
6 Irvine Lenroot to D. R. Crissinger, 23 Nov. 1925, HPPF, box 122. Herbert
Hoover claimed in his memoirs to have written this letter for Lenroot to
sign, while Hoover was secretary of commerce. Herbert Hoover, Memoirs
(New York: Macmillan, 1951–52), 3:9–11.
7 “Federal Reserve System and Speculation,” Bankers’ Magazine 115 (1927): 129.
8 Washington Post, 6 June 1929, 6; New York Times, 19 Jan. 1928, 10; “Federal
Reserve v. Speculation,” Time, 25 Feb. 1929, 49.
169
just speculation. Was it worth it? “The policy of raising the rediscount
rate in order to stop speculation is … based on the theory that the mil-
lions of innocents should be punished for the sins of the few,” argued
the banker Edward C. Stokes, the former governor of New Jersey. “If a
young inexperienced patron of my bank is branching out too much in
the speculative field, I quietly call him to my desk and tell him that he
has reached his limit, but I don’t raise the rate of interest on every other
borrower of our institution.” The banker Russell Leffingwell cautioned
that it would be impossible for the Federal Reserve to distinguish bor-
rowers seeking to speculate from borrowers seeking to use money for
ends that seemed more productive. “We are all, good and bad, sheep
and goats, farmers and bankers and merchants and speculators and in-
dustrialists, engaged in one great joint venture,” Leffingwell mused. “If
the Federal Reserve authorities set out to ruin some, by denying credit
to those they don’t approve of, the speculators, they will most likely
injure us all.”9
Higher interest rates, moreover, would slow or even reverse the re-
markable rise in stock prices, a result that was sure to be unpopular.
Before taking such action, the Federal Reserve had to be confident that
curtailing speculation justified harming so many people, but how could
officials, or indeed anyone, be sure that prices were already too high?
And as many suggested, any move by the government, even by the
quasi-independent Federal Reserve, that was perceived to have ended
the boom was likely to have disastrous consequences for the incumbent
Republican Party. As one editorialist noted of Treasury Secretary and
Federal Reserve Board member Andrew Mellon shortly after the 1928
presidential election, “it would be too much to expect of any incum-
bent of that distinguished office to take otherwise than a roseate view of
the situation in the face of a national political campaign.”10
170 Speculation
As it turned out, the Federal Reserve did raise the discount rate three
times in 1928, from 3.5 percent to 4 percent, then to 4.5 percent, and
finally to 5 percent. These measures had no discernible effect on the
amount of speculation or on stock prices. In the spring of 1929, as
the market continued to rise, Hoover and Mellon urged the Federal
Reserve Board to raise the rate yet again. The Federal Reserve Bank of
New York asked the board several times to increase the rate to 6 per-
cent. Each time, a majority of the board declined to do so.11
“The stock boom was blowing great guns when I came into the
White House,” Hoover recalled in his memoirs. “Being fully alive to
the danger inherent in this South Sea Bubble and its inevitable reaction,
my first interest was to get it under restraint.” Hoover’s memory was
colored by hindsight. Before the crash he had told the banker Martin
Egan that he was “dubious about doing anything for fear that more
harm than good might result.” And of course in his later years Hoover
had an interest in defending himself against charges that as president
he had done too little—he pointedly titled this chapter of his memoirs
“We Attempt to Stop the Orgy of Speculation.” Even so, Hoover was
no doubt right that there was not much even a president could do
apart from badgering the Federal Reserve to lower interest rates. “To
ask Congress for powers to interfere in the stock market was futile,”
he recalled, “and, in any event, for the President to dictate the price of
stocks was an expansion of Presidential power without any established
constitutional basis.” So Hoover did what he could to talk the market
down. He asked the publishers of the major newspapers and magazines
to run editorials warning readers of the dangers of speculation. He gave
speeches to the same effect. He urged bankers to exercise restraint in
lending, and he urged Richard Whitney, the president of the New York
Stock Exchange, to do something to curb the manipulation of stock
prices. None of these actions had any effect. In August 1929, the Federal
Reserve Board finally did raise the discount rate to 6 percent. It made
no difference. “The real trouble,” Hoover lamented, “was that the bell-
boys, the waiters, and the host of unknowing people, as well as the
11 David Cannadine, Mellon: An American Life (New York: Alfred A. Knopf,
2006), 359, 388–89.
171
12 Martin Egan to Thomas Lamont, 23 Oct. 1929, HHL, box 1049; Hoover,
Memoirs, 3:16–19.
13 Alexander D. Noyes, “The Stock Market Panic,” Current History 31
(1929): 619; John T. Flynn, “Speculation and Gambling,” Harper’s Magazine
160 (1930): 201; John T. Flynn, “The Wall Street Debt Machine,” Harper’s
Magazine 167 (1933): 138; Max Winkler, “Paying the Piper,” North American
Review 229 (1930): 50; Wall Street Journal, 5 Nov. 1929, 1.
172
172 Speculation
174 Speculation
stock prices should be pegged at their values as of some date in the past
and then not permitted to decline. The Boston banker Allan Forbes had
the same idea, but his friend J. P. Morgan politely talked him out of it.
If “people did not like the prices when they were fixed,” Morgan told
Forbes, “it would simply mean they would go and set up an outside
market” and trade there instead of on the exchange.18 It is a good indi-
cator of the magnitude of the crisis that such desperate measures could
have been proposed by such knowledgeable people.
Previous downturns had given rise to proposals to ban short selling,
the practice of agreeing to sell in the future an item one did not yet own
to profit from a decline in its price. There were many more such calls
in the early 1930s. Letters poured into the White House decrying “the
destructive practice of short selling,” as one New Jersey entrepreneur
put it. An engineering professor at the University of Michigan insisted
in 1930 that “if there had not been avalanche after avalanche of short
selling last fall we would have had an orderly recession of only about
half the historic panic drop.” As always, something seemed unsavory
about a practice that made someone desire—and possibly even act to
bring about—a crash. “A man who sells and destroys the value of your
securities is no better than the man who burns down your house,” in-
sisted one of Herbert Hoover’s many correspondents. One of Arthur
Capper’s constituents urged him to “tell the Banking Committee that
if they have any doubt that short selling is the principal cause of the
depression to put a ban on short sales for ninety days and watch the
general market advance fifty percent.” It seemed unfair that short sell-
ers should profit from the despair of others. “How is it that a practice
so contrary to public policy can be permitted in this country?” asked
the oilman Joseph Pointer. “In whose possession are the twenty bil-
lions that disappeared from the pockets of the carpenter, the actor, the
18 George W. McPherson to Herbert Hoover, 29 Oct. 1929, HHL, box 159,
folder 4; M. B. Friend to Lawrence Richey, 1 June 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder
3; Arthur Capper to Hebert Hoover, 27 Apr. 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder
2; Congressional Record 78 (1934): 8016; Herman H. Handmaker to Herbert
Hoover, 13 Nov. 1929, HHL, box 159, folder 5; Henry H. Heimann to Herbert
Hoover, 26 May 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder 3; J. P. Morgan Jr. to Allan
Forbes, 19 Apr. 1932, JPM, box 25, letterpress book 43.
175
small executive, and the chorus girl?” Short sellers were “people who
put profits before patriotism,” reasoned William Buck, a Philadelphia
salesman—or else they were “foreigners who wish no good to the
United States.” The Kansas Republican Charles Scott advised Hoover
that “if you can succeed in suppressing short selling in stocks and bonds
and food products it will win you the vote of every Republican farmer
in the country.” Democrats too, suggested the humorist Will Rogers. If
the practice were banned, he predicted, “at least 115,000,000 out of the
120,000,000 would put on a celebration that would make Armistice
Day look like a wake.”19
Hoover himself was dubious about short selling. “Men are not justi-
fied in deliberately making a profit from the losses of other people,” he
wrote in early 1932. Hoover also shared the widespread suspicion that
short sellers manipulated prices by “pounding down” the market. He
worried that “these operations destroy public confidence and induce
a slowing down of business.” The Hoover administration accordingly
took some modest steps to limit short selling. George Akerson, Hoover’s
press secretary, prepared a list of prominent New York “bears” who “or-
ganize short selling at certain hours of the day, thereby creating a real
strain on the market.” Hoover met with the leaders of the New York
Stock Exchange and the Chicago Board of Trade, to urge them to adopt
rules to curb short selling. He told Richard Whitney, the president of
the stock exchange, that “whatever defense there may be for the prac-
tice of short selling during ordinary and normal times,” it was “most
injurious during periods of depression like the present.” Hoover issued
Whitney an ambiguous threat, that “unless the Stock Exchange itself
would promptly take steps to stop such injurious practices he would feel
it his duty to proceed along other lines.” At Hoover’s request, in January
19 Ansley H. Fox to Herbert Hoover, 17 Oct. 1930, HHL, box 159A, folder 7;
William S. Hazelton to Herbert Hoover, 16 Oct. 1930, HHL, box 159A, folder
7; E. C. Stokes to Herbert Hoover, 27 Sept. 1930, HHL, box 159A, folder 7;
H. L. Stout to Arthur Capper, 23 Apr. 1930, HHL, box 159A, folder 2; Joseph
Pointer to Herbert Hoover, 20 Nov. 1929, HHL, box 159A, folder 6; W. L.
Buck to Louis McHenry Howe, 23 Mar. 1933, FDR, POF 34, box 1; Charles
F. Scott to Herbert Hoover, 24 Feb. 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder 5; Rogers
quoted in Nathan T. Porter, “Business and Finance,” Overland Monthly and
Out West Magazine 90 (1932): 41.
176
176 Speculation
20 Herbert Hoover to Thomas W. Lamont, 2 Apr. 1932, HHL, box 1049;
“Memorandum,” 3 Oct. 1930, GEA, box 19; Silas H. Strawn to Lawrence
Richey, 28 Oct. 1931, HHL, box 851; B. H. Meyer to Theodore Joslin, 19 Mar.
1932, HHL, box 159A, folder 10; short-sale reports in HHL, box 159A, folder 13.
21 Congressional Record 78 (1934): 8028, 8027; Short Selling of Securities: Hearing
Before the Committee on the Judiciary, House of Representatives (Washington,
D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1932); Frederic C. Walcott to Walter H.
Newton, 20 Apr. 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder 2.
177
perceived that “short selling is coming into bad repute with the public,”
and he thought it a good development in a depression, because “it is in
just such a time that everyone should endeavor to employ his abilities
and resources towards the maintenance of public confidence.”22
The leaders of the New York financial community nevertheless made
the case for short selling, both in private and in public. “We are deathly
afraid of Hoover,” the New York broker Charles Chambers told Carter
Glass. “The big men in the street do not know just what piece of eco-
nomic quackery he is going to propose next. It is plain that he is a
desperate man and is snatching at every little straw in order to attempt
to stave off the bad beating that is surely coming to him in the next
election.” Chambers and his colleagues were particularly worried about
a ban on short selling. “Hoover and the group of petty men who are
running the government will stoop to anything, even to ruining an
organized security market,” Chambers despaired. “For centuries we
have been striving for liquidity and now certain members of Congress
propose to ruin the liquidity of securities by abolishing short selling.
Senator, it would be a catastrophe.” Thomas Lamont assured Hoover
that the fall in the stock market was caused not by short sellers but by
declining company earnings, and that banning short selling would only
impede the recovery, because “bulls will not buy in a market where
bears cannot sell, for today’s bull wants to be able to change his foot and
sell tomorrow.” New York Stock Exchange president Richard Whitney
defended short selling in speeches all over the country, some of which
were broadcast live on the radio and printed as pamphlets for distri-
bution. His 1931 speech before the Hartford Chamber of Commerce,
entitled “Short Selling,” was heard on sixty radio stations in over forty
states and had a print run of more than 750,000 copies.23
22 J. George Frederick, “Short Selling Loses Caste,” North American Review
234 (1932): 58; Louis Guenther, “Vicious Short Selling,” Financial World, 22
Oct. 1930.
23 Charles W. Chambers to Carter Glass, 14 Dec. 1931, CG, box 301; Thomas
W. Lamont to Herbert Hoover, 1 Apr. 1932, HHL, box 1049; Richard Whitney,
“Short Selling” (16 Oct. 1931), HHL, box 160, folder 8; Richard Whitney to
“All Members and Partners of Stock Exchange Firms,” 4 Nov. 1931, HHL, box
159A, folder 12. Other examples of Whitney speeches defending short selling
include “Speculation” (10 Oct. 1930), “Short Selling and Liquidation” (15 Dec.
178
178 Speculation
The major exchanges also took small steps of their own to limit short
selling, in the hope of fending off more serious legislative incursions.
In 1931, the New York Stock Exchange asked its members not to accept
orders for short sales except where customers were hedging against losses
from securities they already owned. The following year the stock ex-
change prohibited members from lending customers’ securities to other
brokers (short sellers borrowed securities before selling them) without
first obtaining the customers’ written authorization. These measures
were more cosmetic than substantive; the former carried no sanctions
for violators, and the latter was easy to comply with. The New York
lawyer W. R. Perkins shared what seemed to be the unanimous view of
the local press that short selling would proceed unabated. The Chicago
Board of Trade prohibited what the board called “harmful speculative
short selling.” This was likely just as cosmetic, as it was clear that the
board of trade did not share the Hoover administration’s view as to
which kinds of transactions were harmful.24 Despite such efforts, there
was a real possibility in the years after the crash that the government
would do something to curb short selling, certainly a greater possibility
than at any time since the agrarian protests against commodity trading
in the 1890s.
Another common regulatory proposal was a ban on margin trad-
ing. Stockbrokers and commodity brokers normally did not require
their customers to pay the full price of whatever the brokers bought
on their behalf. The customer merely had to deposit a “margin,” or
a percentage of the purchase price, and the broker would lend him
the rest. If the customer’s losses reached the margin, the broker would
call upon the customer for more money, and if the customer did not
deposit more, the broker would close out the customer’s account. It
1931), and “The New York Stock Exchange” (27 Dec. 1932), all in HHL, box
160, folder 8.
24 A. S. Brown to Herbert Hoover, 25 Sept. 1931, HHL, box 159A, folder 8;
New York Stock Exchange Circular, 18 Feb. 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder
10; W. R. Perkins to Herbert Hoover, 20 Feb. 1932, HHL, box 159A,
folder 9; Chicago Board of Trade Circular, 26 Oct. 1932, HHL, box 159A,
folder 5; Walter H. Newton to Arthur M. Hyde, 20 Oct. 1932, HHL, box
159A, folder 5; Chicago Board of Trade to Herbert Hoover, 2 Nov. 1931,
HHL, box 159A, folder 4.
179
2 5 Michael B. Cahill to Herbert Hoover, 3 May 1930, HHL, box 159, folder 6.
26 Arthur Capper to Herbert Hoover, 26 Jan. 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder 9;
“Memorandum to the Committee on Stock Exchange Regulation” (24 Oct.
1933), AAB, box 22.
180
180 Speculation
In the floor debates over the bills that would become the legislation
of 1933 and 1934, several members of Congress urged the prohibition
of margin trading. “Security speculation is practically the only gam-
bling game which can be carried on on credit,” argued Senator Robert
Bulkley of Ohio. “You cannot go to a race track and make a bet on
a horse race unless you have your money in your hand. There is no
money desk in the betting ring where loans can be negotiated for bet-
ting purposes. And there ought not to be a money desk on the floor
of the stock exchange.” Margin trading, Bulkley declared, “is funda-
mentally wrong.” Duncan Fletcher, who chaired the Senate Banking
Committee, believed that “margin trading in this country has led to a
great many abuses and to excessive speculation,” because it allowed too
many people to get in over their heads. “When a person is permitted
to put up a few dollars on margin to buy stocks and take chances of
winning or losing, he is tempted to do so,” Fletcher worried. “Margin
operation, in my judgment, is responsible for the ruin of thousands
and thousands of people.” In the House, Martin Smith of Washington
State described margin trading as “evil,” because it “acts as a snare or
a trap, and a great many people buy more stocks than they can afford
to buy, and when the call for additional margin comes their accounts
are wiped out. Undoubtedly more money was lost by the American
public because of marginal sales in the stock collapse of 1929 than
on account of insufficiency of value in the securities when they were
originally issued.” This heartfelt statement moved Smith’s colleagues
to applause.27
Another proposal aimed at the same target was to ban banks from
lending to brokers and speculators. The chain of credit from brokers
to their customers had banks at its origin, so if the funds could be cut
off at their source, speculators would be unable to buy stock with bor-
rowed money. Behind the banks lay the Federal Reserve, which meant
that the government was in effect the ultimate source of the loans. The
Senate Banking Committee held hearings on the subject as early as
1928, when the market was still on the way up. “I do not object to a
man throwing away his money,” declared Earle Mayfield of Texas, “but
what I object to is the Government lending about $3,000,000,000 to
help him do it.” A few months before the crash, William Henry King of
Utah again proposed an investigation into the propriety of bank loans
to brokers and speculators. The idea was revived after the crash. If his
proposal had been acted upon promptly, King argued, it “would have
prevented the debacle of 1929.”28
There were also several proposals for a federal tax on securities trans-
actions as a means of curbing speculation. The federal government al-
ready taxed stock transactions, as did New York, but these taxes were
very small because they were intended to raise revenue rather than
to deter trading. The new proposals were much more substantial.
Representative Fiorello La Guardia of New York introduced a bill im-
posing a quarter of a percent tax on all securities sales and a 25 percent
tax on short selling, the latter of which would have been tantamount
to a prohibition. Herbert Claiborne Pell, the former congressman (and
the father of Claiborne Pell, who would represent Rhode Island in the
Senate for decades), repeatedly suggested a 1 percent tax on all sales of
securities, to prevent speculative transactions without deterring genu-
ine investment. “Such a tax would practically do away with all ‘in and
out’ speculation as it would be too big a percentage for the gambler
to face,” Pell reasoned, but the tax would be small enough to “achieve
this result without in any way interfering with legitimate purchase and
sale.” As Pell told his friend “Frank” Roosevelt, “a tax of one percent
would so lessen the profits of those who have to rely on the mainte-
nance of a quick market for their profits that the business would be
wound up.” Carter Glass favored a tax on sales of stock held by the
seller for less than sixty days. “People do not ordinarily ‘invest’ their
funds for an hour or day or week or month,” Glass insisted. “Ninety
per cent of such transactions constitute unadulterated gambling on the
state of the market and the thing should be abated.” Representative Jed
Johnson of Oklahoma introduced legislation imposing a 1 percent tax
28 Brokers’ Loans: Hearings Before the Committee on Banking and Currency, United
States Senate (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1928), 7; New
York Times, 11 July 1929, 33; 25 Oct. 1929, 3; 15 May 1930, 21; Congressional
Record 78 (1934): 1991.
182
182 Speculation
30 “The Purpose of National Blue Sky Regulation,” n.d., AAB, box 20; New York
Times, 6 Feb. 1932, 25; Donald L. Pomeroy to A. A. Berle Jr., 28 Nov. 1932,
AAB, box 20; Congressional Record 78 (1934): 8101; Congressional Record 77
(1933): 2947.
184
184 Speculation
33 James M. Smallwood and Steven K. Gragert, eds., Will Rogers’ Daily Telegrams
(1978) (Claremore, Okla.: Will Rogers Memorial Museums, 2008), 2:1929;
Anonymous memorandum, 25 Oct. 1929, HHL, box 154, folder 14.
186
186 Speculation
every twenty five of its members are republicans and contribute toward
republican campaigns.”34
On the other hand, not proposing new restrictions opened the ad-
ministration up to considerable criticism. Roosevelt’s strategy in the
1932 election “was to allege that I had made the depression and then
done nothing about it,” Hoover later complained—“that I was person-
ally responsible for the stock market boom and the orgy of specula-
tion.” The Hoover administration had pursued none of the regulatory
options that were on the table. Roosevelt took the opportunity to cam-
paign on a vague promise to clean up Wall Street. “The money chang-
ers have fled from their high seats in the temple of our civilization,” he
declared in his inaugural address. “We may now restore that temple to
the ancient truths. The measure of the restoration lies in the extent to
which we apply social values more noble than mere monetary profit.”
Among the needed “safeguards against a return of the evils of the old
order,” Roosevelt announced, was “a strict supervision of all banking
and credits and investments, so that there will be an end to speculation
with other people’s money.”35
Roosevelt became president on March 4, 1933. By March 29, securities
bills had been introduced in both houses of Congress, and the Securities
Act of 1933 was enacted in late May, as part of the flurry of legislation
in the first hundred days of Roosevelt’s presidency. The act required a
company issuing securities to file with the Federal Trade Commission a
registration statement containing a great deal of information about the
company’s financial condition. (The FTC would be replaced in this role
a year later by a new agency, the Securities and Exchange Commission.)
Companies also had to disclose much of the same information to pro-
spective purchasers. In broad outline, corporate insiders would be liable
to purchasers of the stock for their losses if their disclosures included
any material falsehoods or omitted any important facts.36 The Securities
Act did not impose any substantive limits on trading: it did not regulate
short selling or margin trading, it did not prohibit corporate insiders
from taking advantage of their positions, and it said nothing about what
kinds of transactions would be permitted or forbidden. Nor did the
Securities Act empower government officials to protect investors by re-
viewing the merits of a proposed offering. Instead, the act required only
the disclosure of information before selling stock.
Why this reliance solely on disclosure? Disclosure had been a favored
regulatory strategy of the progressive reformers earlier in the century.
“Sunlight is said to be the best of disinfectants,” Louis Brandeis had
famously written in 1913. Indeed, Brandeis coined this metaphor while
arguing that investment bankers should be forced to reveal to inves-
tors the commissions they had received for their services.37 Progressive
reformers, who had long looked across the Atlantic for inspiration,
could cite the example of the British Companies Act, which required
corporations issuing stock to publish a prospectus containing speci-
fied information.38 The second wave of state blue sky laws, from the
mid-1910s forward, had required many new companies to make various
disclosures before selling stock. In the intervening years, others had
applied this principle to corporate information more generally. The
economist William Ripley contended in 1926 that shareholders even in
established companies had a “right to adequate information” and that
official corporate pamphlets fell woefully short of telling shareholders
what they needed to know. During the 1932 presidential campaign,
Ripley urged Herbert Hoover to make corporate disclosure part of his
platform and warned that if Hoover did not, Roosevelt would.39
37 Louis D. Brandeis, “What Publicity Can Do,” Harper’s Weekly, 20 Dec. 1913,
10–12. This essay was later published as a chapter in Louis D. Brandeis, Other
People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It (New York: Frederick A. Stokes Co.,
1914), 92–108.
38 On Progressive reformers’ use of European models, see Daniel T. Rodgers,
Atlantic Crossings: Social Politics in a Progressive Age (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press, 1998).
39 William Z. Ripley, “Stop, Look, Listen! The Shareholder’s Right to Adequate
Information,” Atlantic Monthly, Sept. 1926; William Z. Ripley, Wall Street
and Main Street (Boston: Little, Brown and Co., 1927), 156–207; William Z.
Ripley to Herbert Hoover, 11 July 1932, HHL, box 159A, folder 3.
188
188 Speculation
40 http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=75174; http://www.presidency.ucsb
.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29595; Seligman, Transformation, 19–20, 41–42.
41 James M. Landis, “The Legislative History of the Securities Act of 1933,” George
Washington Law Review 28 (1959): 29; Donald A. Ritchie, James M. Landis: Dean
of the Regulators (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980), 43–61;
William Lasser, Benjamin V. Cohen: Architect of the New Deal (New Haven,
Conn.: Yale University Press, 2002), 65–85; Bruce Allen Murphy, The Brandeis/
Frankfurter Connection: The Secret Political Activities of Two Supreme Court
Justices (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982), 132–38; Raymond Moley,
The First New Deal (New York: Harcourt, Brace & World, 1966), 306.
189
42 Adolf Berle to William H. Woodin, 12 Apr. 1933, AAB, box 20; Adolf Berle
to Franklin Roosevelt, 11 Jan. 1933, FDR, PPF 1306; Arthur H. Dean to
Alexander Sachs, 16 Sept. 1933, AS, box 150; James Landis to Alexander Sachs,
5 Oct. 1933, JML-HLS, box 9, folder 7.
190
190 Speculation
43 Edwin Lefèvre, “Blame the Broker,” Saturday Evening Post, 9 Apr. 1932,
26; Address of Hon. Joseph P. Kennedy, Chairman of Securities and Exchange
Commission, at Meeting of the Boston Chamber of Commerce (Washington,
D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1934), 2; Jerome Frank to Emanuel Celler,
28 Aug. 1939, JNF, box 23, folder 90; Press conference, 22 Sept. 1937, 2–3,
WOD, box 24, folder 3.
191
192 Speculation
liability for “an untrue statement of a material fact” or the omission “to
state a material fact.” But how could anyone be 100 percent sure that
every single sentence in a long document was exactly correct? “Officers
and directors of a company must rely upon engineers, accountants and
attorneys for information,” D. F. Kelly of Chicago protested. “No man
who values his good name would be willing … to jeopardize his repu-
tation and accept the responsibility for the errors of his professional
advisers.” And of the infinite number of facts that were not included
in a registration statement or a prospectus, how could anyone predict
which ones a court, years later, might deem “material”? The banker
W. B. Neergaard worried that “if we sell to an investor, bonds, even of
such quality of those of the American Telephone & Telegraph Company
or first mortgage bonds of the Union Pacific Railway, and the bond
market, as a whole, should decline ten points, that investor could bring
an action against us to recover his loss marketwise on the grounds that
we did not disclose to him all of the material facts.” The law “would
effectively cripple the financing of all corporations,” complained the
Merchants’ Association of New York, “because of the excessively drastic
responsibilities imposed … upon directors and professional advisors.”
The Boston investment banker Waldo Kendall concluded that “if the
intent of the Act had been to put all reputable investment bankers out
of business it could not have been better framed.”46
Not long after the law’s enactment, it was already a common view
among the New York investment banking and legal community that the
liability provisions in the Securities Act were deterring companies from
issuing securities. The banker W. C. van Antwerp told Felix Frankfurter
in June that the act had already driven one investment bank out of
business. “In my own certain knowledge,” thundered the lawyer Henry
Stimson, “that Act today, by reason of the dangerous liability which it
imposes upon those who must sign the registration statements for all
46 Russell Leffingwell to Franklin Roosevelt, 4 Jan. 1934, FDR, PPF 866; D. F.
Kelly to Franklin Roosevelt, 11 May 1933, FDR, POF 242, box 1; Barrett
Wendell Jr. to William Phillips, 3 June 1933, FDR, POF 242, box 1; W. B.
Neergaard to Duncan U. Fletcher, 15 Dec. 1933, JML-LC, box 149; S. C. Mead
to Franklin Roosevelt, 12 May 1933, FDR, POF 242, box 1; Waldo Kendall to
James Landis, 18 Jan. 1934, JML-HLS, box 7, folder 12.
193
47 Arthur F. Dean, “Economic and Legal Aspects of the Federal Securities Act of
1933” (19 Sept. 1933), 2–3, AS, box 150; W. W. Dulles to Alexander Sachs, 12
Sept. 1933, JPL, box 68; Henry Bruère to Franklin Roosevelt, 1933, JPL, box
68; W. C. van Antwerp to Felix Frankfurter, 9 June 1933, FF, reel 84; Henry
Stimson to Felix Frankfurter, 5 Dec. 1933, FF, reel 84; John W. Prentiss to
Franklin Roosevelt, 15 Feb. 1934, FDR, POF 242, box 1 (emphasis added);
Otto H. Kahn to Franklin Roosevelt, 12 May 1933, FDR, POF 242, box 1;
The Federal Securities Act of 1933 (Washington, D.C.: Chamber of Commerce,
1934), 5, 9, in JML-HLS, box 9, folder 2; Daniel Roper to Franklin Roosevelt,
2 Feb. 1934, FDR, POF 34, box 1; E. L. Rice to Franklin Roosevelt, 24 May
1933, FDR, POF 242, box 1.
194
194 Speculation
48 Franklin Roosevelt to Felix Frankfurter, 2 Nov. 1934, FDR, PPF 866; Franklin
Roosevelt to Otto H. Kahn, 22 May 1933, FDR, POF 242, box 1; Bernard
Flexner, “The Fight on the Securities Act,” Atlantic Monthly, Feb. 1934; Eustace
Seligman to Felix Frankfurter, 24 Apr. 1933, and Felix Frankfurter to Eustace
Seligman, 25 Apr. 1933, FF, reel 84.
49 Max Freedman, ed., Roosevelt and Frankfurter: Their Correspondence 1928–
1945 (Boston: Little, Brown and Co., 1967), 158; Franklin Roosevelt to Walter
Nesbit, 11 Dec. 1933, FDR, PPF 1057; Felix Frankfurter to Louis Howe, 13
Sept. 1933, FF, reel 84.
195
196 Speculation
53 John M. Hancock to Franklin Roosevelt, 1 Feb. 1934, AS, box 150; L. M. von
Schilling to Carter Glass, 26 Feb. 1934, CG, box 316; Henry A. Miller to
Carter Glass, 28 Feb. 1934, CG, box 316.
54 Frazier Jelke & Co., “Morning Stock Letter” (22 Mar. 1934), FDR, POF 34,
box 1; Robert Patterson Jr. and M. M. Harrod to Carter Glass, 27 Feb. 1934,
CG, box 316.
197
pay any gain to the Corporation?” Catchings predicted that “men of af-
fairs will be reluctant to act as directors.” His concern was shared by the
vice president of a cement company, who feared that “responsible and
able corporate directors and executives throughout the country will feel
constrained to tender their resignations.”55
The New York Stock Exchange complained about the regular reports
that listed corporations would have to file, a burden the exchange con-
sidered so onerous that the government “might dominate and actually
control the management of each listed corporation.” And many wor-
ried that the 1934 act would discourage so much capital from entering
the market that the value of all stocks would plummet. “Is it fair to
the people who own securities?” asked one of Carter Glass’s correspon-
dents. “It may be popular at the minute to punish Wall Street, but
I am wondering how popular this bill will be with investors all over the
country, when they see the marketability and prices of their securities
perhaps seriously affected.”56
In practice, the 1934 act’s bite would depend on how much of a
margin the Federal Reserve required and on the precise nature of the
short-selling regulations that would be promulgated by the Securities
and Exchange Commission. The Federal Reserve initially required a
minimum margin of only 25 percent—that is, brokers could still lend
their customers 75 percent of the value of what the customers were
buying. The margin requirement fluctuated thereafter, to 55 percent in
1936, then back down to 40 percent in 1937. Since World War II it
has been at 50 percent or higher, and it has stayed right at 50 percent
since 1974.57 The purpose of giving the Federal Reserve the authority
to set a margin requirement was to reduce the volatility of stock prices,
which was widely thought to be a product of speculative trading on
credit. In fact, however, the effect of the margin requirement has been
55 Waddill Catchings to Marvin H. McIntyre, 23 Apr. 1934, FDR, POF 34, box
2; Dwight Morgan to Carter Glass, 5 Mar. 1934, CG, box 316.
56 Richard Whitney to the Presidents of All Listed Corporations, 14 Feb. 1934,
AAB, box 22; Frank McNulty Ransom to Carter Glass, 29 Mar. 1934, CG,
box 316.
57 Susan B. Carter et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United States (Cambridge
University Press Online Edition, 2006), table Cj863.
198
198 Speculation
studied extensively over the years by economists, who have been nearly
unanimous in concluding that the margin requirement has had little
or no effect on the volatility of stock prices.58 Even without a margin
requirement, brokers may well be careful about lending their money to
customers engaging in risky purchases. And of course borrowing from
a broker is not the only way to speculate. The margin requirements au-
thorized by the 1934 act thus appear not to have done much to curtail
speculation.
The same is true of the short-selling regulations authorized by the
1934 act. The Securities and Exchange Commission did not regulate
short selling until 1938, and even then, all it did was promulgate the
“uptick rule,” which prohibited short sales only at prices lower than
the last sale price.59 The consensus among economists is that the uptick
rule imposed a cost on traders without producing any corresponding
benefit: it made short selling slightly more difficult, but it had no effect
whatsoever on the speed with which prices declined in a downturn.60
For this reason, the SEC repealed the uptick rule in 2007.
The New Deal securities acts thus imposed only relatively mild re-
strictions on speculation, certainly much milder than might have been
expected given the severity of the Depression and the extent to which
speculation was considered responsible for it.
Capitalistic Reformers
Part of the reason for this mildness was of course the countervailing
pressure from the New York financial community, a powerful lobby
with a strong and focused interest in fending off regulation.61 But this is
hardly a complete explanation. The big New York banks were unable to
prevent Congress from erecting a wall between investment banks and
commercial banks. The banks and the stock exchange were unable to
exert much influence on the disclosure requirements of the Securities
Act of 1933, which they opposed just as strongly. And while they
succeeded somewhat in weakening the initial draft of the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934, they could not stop that legislation either. There
was considerable sentiment in Congress to strike hard at Wall Street. If
the New Dealers had wanted to impose stricter limits on speculation,
they probably could have.
But they did not want to. The primary reason for the moderation
of the New Deal securities acts lies in the backgrounds and interests
of the New Dealers themselves. They were, by and large, urban in-
tellectuals who accepted the existence of big financial institutions
as necessary. They had no desire to change the structure of the na-
tion’s financial system in any significant way. They recognized that
they differed in this regard from the earlier generation of Progressive
reformers, epitomized for the New Dealers by the octogenarian
Louis Brandeis, who was still active on the Supreme Court. Brandeis
“wants drastic taxation of big business units, accompanied by leav-
ing small business … strictly alone,” Berle informed Roosevelt. “His
view, if ever stated, would command wide popular support.” But
Berle made clear that he disagreed. “As long as people want Ford
61 Ron Chernow, The House of Morgan: An American Banking Dynasty and the
Rise of Modern Finance (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1990), 379–╉81.
200
200 Speculation
cars,” he told Roosevelt, “they are likely to have Ford factories and
finance to match.”62
From the New Dealers’ perspective, the goal of regulating the securi-
ties markets was not to transform them but to preserve them, by ward-
ing off more serious changes. The New Deal took place while European
countries were turning to communism and fascism. Much of the mo-
tivation for the securities acts, as with the rest of the New Deal, was
to prevent such threats to capitalism from taking root in the United
States. The 1934 act “is conceived in a spirit of the truest conservatism,”
declared the House report that brought it to the floor of Congress.
“This bill seeks to save, not destroy, stock markets and business, by
making necessary changes in time.” As one investment bank approv-
ingly observed, the New Dealers “who drafted the bill in its original
form are not Bolsheviks or Communists, but Capitalistic Reformers.”
Or as Berle explained, the SEC “is in existence primarily to preserve the
capitalist form.”63
This was a major theme in the correspondence of the veteran
New Dealer Jerome Frank, who chaired the SEC from 1939 to 1941
after serving in the Agricultural Adjustment Administration and the
Reconstruction Finance Corporation. “Unfairness certainly arouses the
ire of investors,” he declared. “If they are seriously mulcted, they will
grow impatient with a government that allows such things to happen.
Such an attitude will pave the way for Fascism—and a Fascism which
will lead to a deadly attack on the very investment bankers and security
traders who are today loudest in their protests against regulation.” As he
explained on another occasion, “loss of public confidence in the integ-
rity of our securities markets might be fatal to the existence of such mar-
kets.” For this reason, he proudly informed the New York Times reporter
Arthur Krock, Frank considered the SEC “a conservative institution,
62 Adolf Berle to Franklin Roosevelt, 23 Apr. 1934, FDR, PPF 1306. See also
Jerome Frank to Morris Ernst, 30 Sept. 1939, JNF, box 21, folder 15; Jerome
Frank to Randolph Paul, 24 Sept. 1938, JNF, box 36, folder 554.
63 Ira Katznelson, Fear Itself: The New Deal and the Origins of Our Time (New
York: W. W. Norton, 2013); H.R. Rep. No. 1383, 73rd Cong., 2nd Sess., 3
(1934); Grant & Co., “Weekly Investment Letter,” 1934, FDR, POF 34, box 2;
Adolf Berle to Jerome Frank, 8 Feb. 1939, JNF, box 22, folder 41.
201
202 Speculation
65 Richard Whitney to Franklin Roosevelt, 10 Oct. 1934, FDR, PPF 1275; Marvin
H. McIntyre to Franklin Roosevelt, 7 Feb. 1934, FDR, PPF 1275; Richard
Whitney to FDR, 8 Feb. 1934, FDR, PPF 1275; James L. Houghteling to
Franklin Roosevelt, 19 Apr. 1934, FDR, POF 242, box 1; Henry McVickar
to Franklin Roosevelt, 27 Feb. 1934, FDR, POF 34, box 1; Daniel R. Ernst,
“Lawyers, Bureaucratic Autonomy, and Securities Regulation During the New
Deal” (unpublished paper, 2009), 7; Katie Louchheim, ed., The Making of the
New Deal: The Insiders Speak (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press,
1983), 141; James Landis to William Harding Jackson, 22 Feb. 1932, Jackson to
Landis, 25 Feb. 1932, and Jackson to Landis, 14 Apr. 1932, all in JML-LC, box 6.
66 John W. Hanes to Jerome Frank, 15 Apr. 1938, JNF, box 28, folder 290; William
O. Douglas to Henry A. Wallace, 11 Apr. 1936, WOD, box 24, folder 1.
203
that the government’s goals should be “(a) to protect investors, and also,
(b) always to avoid substantial impediments to expansion of capital,”
but he acknowledged that “those two objectives frequently cannot be
reconciled.” The New Dealers were willing to sacrifice a measure of eco-
nomic activity to protect investors. “Speculative trading must be very
greatly curtailed,” Franklin Roosevelt remarked to Henry Morgenthau
in early 1934. “That means, inevitably, a much smaller volume of trad-
ing on the stock exchanges.” Not long after, at a question-and-answer
session at the Economic Club of Chicago, James Landis likewise con-
ceded that it was “inevitable that in the case of some stocks the spread
between bid and asked prices will be somewhat increased due to less-
ened volume.”67
Roosevelt and Landis were right: trading volume did decline as a
result of the securities acts. As the SEC staffer (and future chairman)
Ganson Purcell recognized in 1938, “volume has been considerably re-
duced in recent years, and other elements of what has traditionally been
known as liquidity are presently absent from our market.” But Purcell
thought this reduction in volume a worthwhile price to pay “for the
elimination of undesirable manipulative activity” and “restriction on
the irresponsible in and out speculation.” Frank conceded that “there
can be no doubt that prior to the 1929 crash we had a thicker market,”
but he too preferred a thinner market if it meant avoiding a return to
the practices of the 1920s. “If those practices are sufficiently unfair to
investors,” Frank warned, “they will revolt not only against investing,
but against the economic and political system which permits them to
be injured.”68
Opposition from brokers waned over time. “I think I am in pretty
close touch with the brokerage and investment banking community
67 Jerome Frank to “the Commission,” 11 June 1938, JNF, box 22, folder 62;
Henry Morgenthau Jr. to Franklin Roosevelt, 22 Mar. 1934, FDR, POF 34,
box 1; James Landis, untitled document with answers to questions from the
audience after a speech at the Economic Club of Chicago, 5 June 1934, JML-
HLS, box 6, folder 2.
68 James C. Dolley, “The Effect of Government Regulation on the Stock-Trading
Volume of the New York Stock Exchange,” American Economic Review 28
(1938): 8–26; Ganson Purcell to Jerome Frank, 18 Nov. 1938, JNF, box 37,
folder 580; Jerome Frank to Elisha M. Friedman, n.d., JNF, box 27, folder 233.
204
204 Speculation
69 Lester Watson to Joseph P. Kennedy, 20 Sept. 1935, JPK, box 83; Lester Watson
to Joseph P. Kennedy, 7 Feb. 1935, JPK, box 83; Vincent P. Carosso, Investment
Banking in America: A History (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press,
1970), 380–81; William O. Douglas to Stephen A. Early, 31 Oct. 1938, FDR,
POF 1060, box 2; Jerome Frank to Frank Murphy, 15 Mar. 1939, JNF, box 34,
folder 508.
╇ 205
Speculating€Banks
For all the discussion in the early 1930s about prohibiting various spec-
ulative transactions, the most significant limit on speculation to arise
from the crash of 1929–╉33 concerned not types of speculation but types
of speculators. In four scattered sections of the Banking Act of 1933 that
have been known ever since as the Glass-╉Steagall Act, Congress prohib-
ited deposit-╉taking banks from selling or underwriting securities.73 For
the rest of the twentieth century, commercial banks (which take de-
posits and make loans) would be separate enterprises from investment
70 Paul G. Mahoney, “The Political Economy of the Securities Act of 1933,”
Journal of Legal Studies 30 (2001): 1–╉31.
71 Arthur H. Dean, “The Lawyer’s Problems in the Registration of Securities,”
Law & Contemporary Problems 4 (1937): 155.
72 Thomas McCraw makes a similar point about accountants in Prophets of
Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984), 188–╉92.
73 48 Stat. 162, §§ 16, 20, 21, 32 (1933).
206
206 Speculation
74 H. Parker Willis and John M. Chapman, The Banking Situation: American
Post-
War Problems and Developments (New York: Columbia University
Press, 1934), 3–20; Elmus Wicker, The Banking Panics of the Great Depression
(New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996), xv; Ben S. Bernanke, Essays on
the Great Depression (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2000), 44.
207
208 Speculation
77 William C. Deming to Herbert Hoover, 19 June 1931, HHL, box 154, folder
15; H. Parker Willis, “Reforms Due in Investment Banking—and in Bank
Relations to Affiliates,” The Annalist, 17 Jan. 1930, 44; H. Parker Willis, “Who
Caused the Panic of 1929?,” North American Review 229 (1930): 179. Willis made
the same argument in academic journals, e.g., H. Parker Willis, “The Banking
Act of 1933—An Appraisal,” American Economic Review 24 (1934): 108–9.
209
78 Operation of the National and Federal Reserve Banking Systems: Hearings Before a
Subcommittee of the Committee on Banking and Currency, United States Senate,
Seventy-First Congress, Third Session, Pursuant to S. Res. 71 (Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office, 1931), 1063; S. Rep. No. 584, 72nd Cong., 1st
Sess. (1932), 9–10.
210
210 Speculation
79 Washington Herald, 18 Jan. 1933, CG, box 305; “Untermyer on the Glass Bill,”
Bankers’ Magazine 124 (1932): 510; Richard Feakes to David I. Walsh, 5 Jan.
1932, CG, box 284; see also Raymond E. Herman to Carter Glass, 13 Feb. 1932,
CG, box 293; Carter Glass to Garland A. Tunstill, 20 Jan. 1932, CG, box 285.
80 Robert N. Carson to Carter Glass, 10 May 1932, CG, box 296; Ralph G.
Lindstrom to Carter Glass, 7 Mar. 1933, CG, box 308; Samuel Berman to
Carter Glass, 13 May 1932, CG, box 296; L. R. Packard to Carter Glass, 20
May 1932, CG, box 297.
211
81 Edgar A. Rossiter to Carter Glass, 12 May 1932, CG, box 297; Frederick
B. Wells to Carter Glass, 21 Mar. 1933, CG, box 310.
82 Julian W. Tyler to Carter Glass, 5 Apr. 1932, CG, box 285.
83 Congressional Record 75 (1932): 9904; Operation of the National and Federal
Reserve Banking Systems, 52; Robert C. Hopkins to Carter Glass, 31 Mar. 1932,
CG, box 284. See also F. W. Buell to Carter Glass, 3 Jan. 1933, CG, box 296;
212
212 Speculation
George M. Coffin to Carter Glass, 22 Mar. 1932, CG, box 284; Walter
Schaffner to Carter Glass, 10 Oct. 1931, CG, box 302.
84 L. C. Irvine to Henry B. Steagall and Carter Glass, 1932, CG, box 293; J. F.
Galvin to Carter Glass, 12 May 1932, CG, box 296; A. H. Eckles, “A Country
Banker Looks at the Glass Bill,” Bankers’ Magazine 125 (1932): 136; Winthrop
A. Mandell to Carter Glass, 1 Apr. 1932, CG, box 285; W. A. Matthews to
Carter Glass, 12 Feb. 1932, CG, box 285.
213
85 “Banking, Group and Branch,” Fortune, Feb. 1930, 140; William Stark Smith
to Carter Glass, 27 Apr. 1932, CG, box 291; Anonymous to Carter Glass, 3
Dec. 1931, CG, box 301; John T. Flynn, “The Dangers of Branch Banking,”
Forum and Century 89 (1933), 261.
86 Garland A. Tunstill to Carter Glass, 26 Jan. 1932, CG, box 285; Leon Franks
to Carter Glass, 6 Feb. 1932, CG, box 284.
214
214 Speculation
gain from the measure—the investment banks that were not affiliated
with a commercial bank. These banks, which were often called “private”
banks to distinguish them from the “national” commercial banks that
were under the jurisdiction of the Federal Reserve, had lost a big part
of their market share when the commercial banks entered the securities
business, and the separation of commercial banking from investment
banking promised to bring that market share back. Carter Glass could
hardly have been surprised to discover that among the heartiest sup-
porters of his banking bill were the investment bankers. “For years it
has been a great source of worry to the private banking houses that the
banks had, through their affiliates, gobbled up so large a part of the
issues of new securities to such a degree that the small houses were being
practically starved out of such business,” explained Waldo Kendall, an
investment banker in Boston. But Kendall could see better days around
the corner. “The fact is that all of this work has been done throughout
history up to within a few years ago by the private investment houses,
who stand ready and willing to do the necessary work,” he promised.87
The only significant opponents of the bill were, again not surpris-
ingly, the commercial banks. Their primary argument was that they
were needed, because the investment banks could not provide enough
capital to finance American business. “The long term capital market in
the United States has been developed in large part by member banks
and their securities affiliates,” insisted Charles McCain, the chairman
of the Chase National Bank, and William Potter, the president of the
Guaranty Trust Company of New York. They warned that forcing com-
mercial banks out of the securities business “will seriously impair the
ability of business in the future to get long term capital.” At its 1932
annual meeting, the American Bankers Association adopted a resolu-
tion emphasizing that “for many years national banks and state member
banks through their powers of underwriting and investing in securities
have supplied long-term capital to many important industries,” and
87 Jonathan R. Macey, “Special Interest Groups Legislation and the Judicial
Function: The Dilemma of Glass-Steagall,” Emory Law Journal 33 (1984): 20;
E. B. Parsly to Carter Glass, 10 Feb. 1932, CG, box 285; J. F. B. Mitchell to
Carter Glass, 22 Nov. 1933, CG, box 311; Waldo S. Kendall to Carter Glass, 4
May 1932, CG, box 291.
215
that “it has been the history of past depressions that recovery has largely
come about through the refinancing of industry and commerce in
which the member banks have played a material and important part.”
Fred Kent, a director of the Bankers Trust Company, testified that the
stock market would collapse even more than it already had if banks
like his were no longer allowed to sell securities. “It is not conceivable
that such a market could exist,” Kent reasoned, “if every natural chan-
nel through which funds are applied to maintain it was stopped up or
curtailed through legislation.”88
The weakness of this argument, as the investment bankers pointed
out, was that the commercial banks had been selling securities in large
quantities only for the previous few years. Before that, the business had
been in the hands of the investment banks, and no one had thought the
investment banks lacked access to sufficient capital. The commercial
banks had not added new capital to the system so much as they substi-
tuted themselves for the investment banks.
The commercial banks had a second argument against the Glass bill.
Commercial banks were regulated by the federal government, but the
private investment banks were not. “By divorcing the security busi-
ness from commercial banking,” the commercial banks contended,
“the former is turned over either to unregulated dealers, or to those
regulated only by such varying laws as the forty-eight states may pro-
vide.” They suggested that a better plan would be to keep the securities
business with the federally regulated commercial banks, perhaps with a
new layer of regulation to prevent a recurrence of the abuses of the past
few years. “I think you will agree with me,” the Detroit banker E. F.
Connely wrote to Glass, “that it would be far better to have this busi-
ness conducted in connection with the banking business where it might
be rigidly administered than to have it revert to the hands of private
bankers answerable only to state governments subject to no examina-
tion and free to do about as they please.” But Glass did not agree, no
88 H. H. Preston and Allan R. Finlay, “Era Favors Investment Affiliates,”
American Bankers Association Journal 22 (1930): 1153; Charles S. McCain and
William C. Potter to Carter Glass, 29 Apr. 1932, CG, box 291; “Resolution of
American Bankers Association Upon Glass Banking Bill, S. 4412,” CG, box
296; Operation of the National and Federal Reserve Banking Systems, 512.
216
216 Speculation
89 “Glass Banking Bill Passes the Senate,” Bankers’ Magazine 126 (1933): 210; E. F.
Connely to Carter Glass, 29 Mar. 1932, CG, box 293; T. J. Morrison to Carter
Glass, 24 Dec. 1932, CG, box 297.
90 New York Times, 25 June 1933, 3; “Wall Street Accepts New Deal in Finance,”
Literary Digest, 23 June 1934, 36; Chernow, House of Morgan, 384–88; Carosso,
Investment Banking in America, 372–75.
217
One of the Broadway hits of 1925 was the Marx Brothers’ musical
The Cocoanuts. It opened during the Florida land boom, which served
as the show’s setting. Real estate prices in Florida were rising quickly.
Speculators were flocking south to buy and sell parcels of land. Irving
Berlin wrote the songs for The Cocoanuts, one of which, “Florida by the
Sea,” gently parodied the promotional literature for Florida that was
blanketing the rest of the country:
By the time the film version of The Cocoanuts appeared four years
later, the bubble had burst. Florida land was selling for a small frac-
tion of 1925 prices. “Florida by the Sea” was moved from the middle
of the Broadway show to the opening credits of the movie, where it
took on a sharper satirical edge, as a reminder of the madness of a few
years before. Also acquiring a sharper edge were the words of Groucho
Marx, who plays a huckster trying to sell off land he knows is worthless.
218
╇ 219
“All ye suckers who are gonna get trimmed, step this way for the big
swindle!” Groucho announces. “Friends, you are now in Cocoanut
Manor, one of the finest cities in Florida. Of course, we still need a few
finishing touches, but who doesn’t? This is the heart of the residential
district. Every lot is a stone’s throw from the station. As soon as they
throw enough stones, we’re going to build a station. Eight hundred
wonderful residences will be built right here. Why, they’re as good as
up. Better. You can have any kind of home you want to. You can even
get stucco—╉Oh, how you can get stuck-╉o!”
Everyone remembers the stock market boom and bust of the 1920s,
but only historians and film buffs remember that there was a nearly
simultaneous boom and bust in the real estate market, most vividly
in Florida, but not only there. The rise and fall of the stock market
gave rise to a national debate about limiting speculation in financial
assets, a debate that produced the New Deal financial regulation that
continues to structure the market today. But the rise and fall of the real
estate market did not give rise to an analogous debate or any analogous
regulation. And of course the real estate bubble of the 1920s was not
the first in American history, and it would not be the last. A similar
episode took place in the first decade of the twenty-╉first century, as real
estate prices soared upward, amidst considerable speculation, only to
plummet back down to earth. Once again, there would be considerable
discussion about speculation in financial assets, especially securities
backed by loans on real estate, but scarcely any debate about specula-
tion in real estate itself. Why the difference? Why have Americans been
so much more concerned about financial speculation than about real
estate speculation?
Florida€Frenzy
Land speculation has been a constant feature of American life since the
seventeenth century.1 So have periodic booms and busts, in both urban
220 Speculation
and rural areas. Recent studies suggest a common dynamic: as the pop-
ulation of an area grows, it takes some time to develop a corresponding
quantity of land. Land grows scarcer in the short run. Investors bid up
its price, but they underestimate the elasticity of the supply of land in
the long run. Eventually more land is developed and its price tumbles
back down.2
In the 1920s, older investors could still remember the real estate bub-
bles of the previous generation. Retail space in central Chicago that sold
for $1,500 per front foot in 1883 was worth $4,000 in 1889 and reached
$7,000 to $10,000 in 1891, only to drop back down in the 1890s. In
towns all over Nebraska, speculators poured millions into undeveloped
lots in 1886 and 1887, lured by easy credit and the hope that new rail-
roads would turn remote agricultural areas into bustling cities. A 640-
acre farm near Omaha that had been bought several years earlier for
$2.50 an acre sold in 1887 for $1,000 an acre, and then a 120-acre por-
tion of the farm sold a few months later for $2,500 an acre. Soon after,
prices were back where they had started. Similar bubbles blew up and
popped up all over the Midwest at around the same time, in Minnesota
and the Dakotas, in Kansas, in Texas, and in parts of Iowa, Wisconsin,
and Missouri. “The East invested vast sums in Western property,” one
observer recalled. “The rapid development of the resources of the West
lent plausibility to every reckless prophecy of higher prices; the con-
tinued inundation of Eastern money seeking chances of speculation
falsified the predictions of the foreboding.”3
Perhaps the sharpest rise and fall in real estate prices during the
late nineteenth century took place in Los Angeles during the boom
of 1887. When artesian well water began to be used for irrigation, and
the coming of the Southern Pacific Railroad introduced competition
between railroad lines and thus lower fares, emigrants and speculators
swarmed into southern California. Sixty new townsites were put on
the market in 1887 alone, most of which consisted of undeveloped land
in the middle of nowhere, bordered only by other equally imaginary
townsites. Some, including Claremont, actually got built, but most
would never exist except on paper. Land was typically purchased with
small down payments. Speculators bought and sold options to buy
land, and an option on a particular parcel often changed hands several
times before it expired. Prices skyrocketed. A thirty-two-acre parcel just
south of what is now downtown Los Angeles that sold in 1885 for $8,500
was resold in 1887 for $40,000, to be subdivided. In Hollywood, land
worth $100 per acre in 1886 was worth $600 per acre a year later. In
Boyle Heights, parcels that had been worth $150 only a few years earlier
sold in 1887 for $10,000. By the end of the year, the bubble had burst.
Many of the lots purchased at fabulous prices were abandoned by the
buyers as worthless.4
It happened again in the 1920s. As the stock market rose to new
heights in the middle of the decade, so did the real estate market in
much of the country. National real estate prices peaked in 1926 and
dropped sharply thereafter. In New York, real estate prices closely
tracked stock prices, peaking in 1929 and then declining rapidly be-
tween 1929 and 1932. The boom of the 1920s gave rise to considerable
speculation in real estate and also in a new kind of financial asset, bonds
backed by real estate, the forerunners of the mortgage-backed securi-
ties that would play a big part in the boom of the early 2000s. By the
mid-twenties, issuances of real estate bonds constituted nearly a quarter
of all corporate debt issues, an even larger share than bonds issued by
railroads. Just as contemporaries worried that there was too much stock
speculation in the mid-1920s, they worried that there was too much real
4 Joseph Netz, “The Great Los Angeles Real Estate Boom of 1887,” Annual
Publication of the Historical Society of Southern California 10 (1915–16): 54–68.
222
222 Speculation
5 Eugene N. White, “Lessons From the Great American Real Estate Boom and
Bust of the 1920s,” NBER Working Paper 15573 (2009); Alexander James Field,
“Uncontrolled Land Development and the Duration of the Depression in the
United States,” Journal of Economic History 52 (1992): 785–805; Tom Nicholas
and Anna Scherbina, “Real Estate Prices During the Roaring Twenties and
the Great Depression,” Real Estate Economics 41 (2013): 278–309; William N.
Goetzmann and Frank Newman, “Securitization in the 1920s,” NBER Working
Paper 15650 (2010); New York Times, 18 Nov. 1925, 36.
6 William Frazer and John J. Guthrie Jr., The Florida Land Boom: Speculation,
Money and the Banks (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books, 1995); Mark S. Foster,
Castles in the Sand: The Life and Times of Carl Graham Fisher (Gainesville:
University Press of Florida, 2000); Raymond B. Vickers, Panic in Paradise:
Florida’s Banking Crash of 1926 (Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press, 1994);
Homer B. Vanderblue, “The Florida Land Boom,” Journal of Land & Public
Utility Economics 3 (1927): 118–19; Paul S. George, “Brokers, Binders, and
Builders: Greater Miami’s Boom of the Mid-1920s,” Florida Historical Quarterly
65 (1986): 34; W. L. George, “Humanity at Palm Beach,” Harper’s Monthly
Magazine 150 (1924): 221; Gertrude Mathews Shelby, “Florida Frenzy,” Harper’s
Monthly Magazine 152 (1925): 177.
223
While Florida land prices were on the rise, there was no shortage of
sober justifications for them. “The bubble will not burst for the very good
and sufficient reason that there is no bubble,” insisted Elmer Youngman
in early 1926, just before the bubble burst. Youngman, the editor of the
Bankers’ Magazine, declared that “some of the ablest men in America
are pouring millions into Florida.” He attributed the new values being
placed on Florida real estate to the increased prosperity of the country,
which gave the masses the means to enjoy leisure and travel, and to the
invention of the automobile, which gave them an easy way to reach a
warm climate. The journalist Frank Stockbridge emphasized the recent
drainage of Florida’s swamps, which eliminated the mosquito and the
attendant threats of malaria and yellow fever. Others simply liked the
weather. “One may swim in the surf, pick strawberries and wear roses in
December,” marveled one correspondent. “You can go fishing, boating
and surf bathing when the waters of the north are covered with ice.”7
Florida’s real estate prices came crashing down in 1926. The New York
Times summed up the situation at the year’s end: there was “a large class
of investors who, having made payments ranging from a few hundred
to several thousand dollars, now have nothing to show for their money
except parcels of waste land.” Banks all over the state failed within a few
months, after making real estate loans that now had no hope of being
repaid.8 The banks and the speculators alike were, as Groucho Marx
put it, stuck-o.
By the early 1930s, after similar if less colorful episodes in many
cities, there was a general recognition that real estate speculation had
gotten out of hand in the previous decade. “Real estate values, we were
told, could never go down—only up. You simply could not lose out
on any real estate investment,” the North American Review recalled.
“Therefore money poured into the real estate field.” Chicago was awash
in foreclosures because of overspeculation, lamented the vice president
224 Speculation
of the Chicago Title and Trust Company. Land speculation had left
“wreckage” all over the New York area, a regional board concluded,
in the form of hundreds of thousands of undeveloped lots whose pur-
chasers had defaulted on their loans. The economist Herbert Simpson
observed that local governments were victims as well. Most of their
revenue came from property taxes, and many had embarked on ambi-
tious public works based on the assumption that property values would
continue to rise. As the Atlantic magazine despaired in 1931, the nation
was now reaping the “whirlwinds of speculation.”9
Analogous events in the securities markets gave rise to an extensive
debate in the late 1920s and early 1930s about how to regulate the mar-
kets to prevent another crash. There was no parallel debate concerning
real estate. Occasionally, to be sure, someone would call for greater reg-
ulation. During the midst of the Florida land boom, for example, at the
annual meeting of the Investment Bankers Association, the Chicago
banker Walter Greenbaum proposed a national blue sky law for real
estate. Greenbaum had become exasperated with the glowing public
relations material touting land in Florida. He wanted a federal agency
to screen out the bad investments before real estate could be offered
to the public, just like the first wave of state blue sky commissions
screened out unsound stock offerings.10 This idea went nowhere. And
such calls for regulation of the real estate market seem to have been
exceedingly rare. Certainly they were much rarer than calls to regulate
the stock market.
transfers. In the early 1930s, there were many calls to tax stock transfers
for the same purpose, to deter speculation in stock. In more recent
times, a few jurisdictions imposed taxes on real estate transfers in an
effort to dampen real estate speculation. Vermont established such a tax
in 1973, for example, and Ontario did the same in 1974. In earlier eras,
frontier residents had clamored for special property taxes on absentee
land speculators, and the available evidence suggests that at least some
jurisdictions satisfied that demand indirectly, by assessing absentee-
owned property at higher values than comparable property owned
by residents. Taxing land speculation to reduce its quantity was thus
well within the realm of possibility in the late 1920s and early 1930s.
D. E. French, a West Virginia lawyer, suggested in 1931 that the federal
government could curtail real estate speculation by imposing a special
income tax on the profits of sales of real estate held for less than twelve
months. Booms were always followed by depressions, French pointed
out, so “if we can find a way to eliminate booms we will thereby elim-
inate the depression.”11 But no such tax was seriously considered by
Congress or any state legislature.
There was a debate about real estate taxation during the period, one
that bore tangentially upon speculation, but it had little to do with the
boom and bust of the 1920s. In the late nineteenth century the political
economist Henry George had proposed his famous “single tax,” a tax
on increases in the value of land. The primary reason George favored
this tax was to reduce inequality, but, he contended, the single tax had
the additional advantage of deterring real estate speculation. “That land
speculation is the true cause of industrial depression is, in the United
States, clearly evident,” George argued. He thought his tax would “tend
to increase production, by destroying speculative rent,” because “if land
were taxed to anything near its rental value, no one could afford to
hold land that he was not using, and, consequently, land not in use
226 Speculation
would be thrown open to those who would use it.” By the 1920s, this
claim does not appear to have been widely believed, at least among
economists and those with experience collecting taxes. But there was
always a small cohort of ardent Georgists who kept the faith, like the
economist Harry Gunnison Brown, who still argued that the single
tax really would discourage speculation.12 The debate over the single
tax had mostly petered out by the 1920s, however, and the effect of the
single tax on speculation was, in any event, a minor issue within that
debate.
Why were contemporaries so much more interested in limiting spec-
ulation in securities than in real estate? Any answer to this question re-
quires some guessing, because there does not appear to have been much
discussion of the question at the time, but it is not hard to identify five
related reasons for the disparity. None provides a full explanation, but
together they can explain why there was no new regulation for land
comparable to the New Deal limits on speculation in securities.
First, while securities were intangible, man-made, and a bit mys-
terious to the average person, land was a physical, natural thing with
qualities that were easily understood. Many more people owned land
than securities, and while most people had never seen securities and
may have had only a vague sense of what they were, everyone had seen
land and knew exactly what it was. The buying and selling of land was a
well-known part of everyday life, from the biggest cities to the smallest
towns. The same was not true of securities.
Second, speculators in securities engaged in all sorts of arcane and
unnatural-seeming transactions. They made short sales, of items they
did not even own, to profit from price declines, which gave some
speculators the unneighborly incentive to make their fellows poorer.
12 Henry George, Progress and Poverty: An Inquiry Into the Cause of Industrial
Depressions and of Increase of Want with Increase of Wealth (1879) (San
Francisco: National Single Tax League, 1905), 266, 411; Adam Shortt,
“Municipal Taxation in Relation to Speculative Land Values,” Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science 58 (1915): 214–21; J. Hamilton
Ferns, “Single Tax in Theory and Practice,” Bulletin of the National Tax
Association 5 (1919): 75–80; Harry Gunnison Brown, “Land Speculation and
Land-Value Taxation,” Journal of Political Economy 35 (1927): 390–402.
227
They entered into futures contracts, for things they might never even
see. They hedged against price movements by buying and selling at
the same time. The repertoire of transactions in real estate was much
smaller. There were no short sales, so there was no way to profit from
a decline in real estate prices, and there were no real estate speculators
hoping for a crash. There were no futures and there was no hedging.
Real estate speculators could buy options, and in the bubblier loca-
tions, like Florida, options were bought and sold in their own right,
but this was small stuff compared with the transactions on the stock
and commodity exchanges. The main way to speculate in real estate was
straightforward: buy land and hope it rose in price so it could be sold
to someone else. The transactions in securities that seemed artificial and
even pernicious had no parallels in real estate.
Third, real estate seemed like a more level playing field than securities
for the average investor. An ordinary person venturing into the stock
market was competing with corporate insiders, who knew much more
about their own firms than anyone on the outside possibly could. And
he was competing with professionals who were widely suspected to have
tricks up their sleeves that allowed them to manipulate prices, at least
in the short run, to fleece the amateurs. Not so with land. “Generally
speaking, the prudent purchase of land is a better investment for the or-
dinary man than stocks and bonds, because in the former case he does
not pit his judgment against the machinations of a board,” advised the
economist Richard Ely. “For example, you buy some stock. You know
some of the facts with regard to the stock, but you cannot know all the
facts which are known to the president and the board of directors, even
supposing they are honest and do not want to swindle anyone. But, if
they do not want to be honest, the buyer is playing with dice loaded
against him.”13 Real estate was more transparent. Its value might fluctu-
ate, but the average investor could see why.
Fourth, crashes in securities markets affected the country as a whole,
all at once, while crashes in real estate markets, although often corre-
lated, were local events. When the Florida land bubble burst in 1926,
it harmed only people who had bought land in Florida. When the
228 Speculation
stock market crashed three years later, it harmed everyone. Real estate
downturns were less likely than stock market downturns to mobilize
political support for regulation.
Finally, with real estate, there was no interest group that was always
on one side of a transaction. Anyone who was a buyer of land one day
could be a seller of land another day; there was no group of people who
were always one or the other. That made land very different from com-
modities, where farmers were always sellers and their customers were
always buyers. Arguments that speculation pushed prices up or down
had a sharp impact for commodities, because if those arguments were
true, there would be clear winners and losers. Not so with real estate,
where if speculation pushed prices up, any given participant would gain
as a seller whatever he lost as a buyer, and vice versa if speculation
pushed prices down. Corporate stock was somewhere in the middle.
Anyone who bought stock one day might sell it another day, so in that
sense stock was like land. But when new stock was issued, corporate
insiders were always sellers, and members of the general public were
always buyers. In that sense, stock was like commodities. All else equal,
one would expect interest groups to form most readily to regulate
speculation in commodities, least readily to regulate speculation in real
estate, and somewhere in the middle to regulate speculation in stock.
Real estate speculation thus seemed more natural and less dangerous
than speculation in securities. “Real-estate booms probably will con-
stantly recur,” the Atlantic observed in 1931, “because the real-estate
men involved—drifters from other industries—naturally will cooperate
with local interests to sell through high-pressure sales methods as many
lots as the public can possibly be induced to buy.” But the magazine did
not think any regulation was needed to prevent the next bubble from
inflating and bursting. “The only hope here is increased caution, born
of experience, on the part of the public,” the Atlantic concluded, “and
the influence of the established and more experienced local real-estate
firms in checking boom tendencies.”14 With land, unlike with the stock
market, contemporaries perceived nothing for regulators to do.
14 Spring, “Whirlwinds.”
╇ 229
An Onion€Ring
To gain some perspective on the lack of interest in limiting speculation
in real estate, it is useful to look at a very different market, one in which
Congress, in relatively short order, completely banned speculation. In
the Onion Futures Act of 1958, Congress made it a crime to enter into
a contract for the sale of onions for future delivery.15 To this day, onions
are the one agricultural commodity in which futures trading is illegal.
Onion futures were relatively new in 1958. The Chicago Mercantile
Exchange began trading onion futures in 1942, and the New York
Mercantile Exchange followed suit in 1946. By the mid-╉1950s, the
Chicago exchange hosted nearly all of the transactions, in what was still
a tiny market compared with more established commodity futures like
wheat or corn.16
Then disaster struck—╉disaster from the perspective of an onion
farmer. In August 1955, a fifty-╉pound bag of onions was worth $2.75. By
March 1956, the same onions were worth 10 cents, less than the cost of
the bag. It turned out that two onion dealers, Sam Siegel of Chicago and
Vincent Kosuga of New York, had outmaneuvered the onion market.
In the fall of 1955, Siegel and Kosuga bought virtually the entire onion
crop available on the Chicago market. Once they had the onions, they
threatened the leading onion growers that they would flood the market,
and depress the price, unless the growers bought about a third of the
onions back from them at high prices. The growers agreed to buy a
third of the onions back. Siegel and Kosuga then double-╉crossed the
growers. They sold onions short on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange,
to the point where they acquired short positions that exceeded the
amount of onions they had originally purchased. They then flooded the
market with the remaining two-╉thirds of the onions. They even shipped
some of their onions out of town, repackaged them, and shipped them
back to Chicago to make it appear as if still more new onions were
coming on the market. Onion prices fell through the floor. The growers
230 Speculation
were left holding very expensive onions, while Siegel and Kosuga made
millions on their short positions.17
Onion farmers were devastated by the fall in prices. Within a few
months, the Commodity Exchange Authority (the agency within the
Department of Agriculture that administered the Commodity Exchange
Act of 1936) set sharp limits on trading in onion futures. Under the new
rules, no trader could hold net long or short positions of more than two
hundred car lots of onions, about a sixth of the short position accumu-
lated by Siegel and Kosuga.18 But this was not enough for the onion
farmers, who urged Congress to ban the futures trade completely. Their
testimony before Congress demonstrated that the market in onions was
very different from the market in real estate in each of the respects that
made limiting speculation in real estate so unlikely.
Onion farmers, unlike real estate investors, were a tightly focused
interest group who were always on the same side of the transaction.
They sold onions and never bought them. Their livelihood thus de-
pended on keeping onion prices up. Anything that was perceived to
depress onion prices was a menace. Farmers had long believed that
commodity speculation depressed prices, and the events of 1955–56
had confirmed for the onion farmers that this was indeed the case.
There was no comparable interest group on the other side of the trans-
action. Lower onion prices were good for consumers, who were always
onion buyers and never onion sellers, but of course onions made up
a negligible portion of their food budget, so they had little reason to
lobby for lower prices.
Onions, unlike real estate, traded in a national market. A fall in prices
affected onion farmers everywhere. And onions were grown all over the
country. Letters poured into the Senate from onion growers in Oregon
and Wisconsin, Texas and Michigan, Idaho and New York. The growers
were represented by the National Onion Association, which gained the
support of larger agricultural organizations like the Vegetable Growers
of America and the National Farm Bureau, who had members in all
17 “Odorous Onions,” Time, 2 July 1956, 70; Chicago Daily Tribune, 22 June
1956, B7.
18 Wall Street Journal, 23 July 1956, 15.
231
but the most urban congressional districts.19 The Florida real estate bust
was well known throughout the country, but it personally affected only
those who had bought land in Florida. The great onion bust was prob-
ably less famous, outside the onion trade. It did not serve as the setting
for any Marx Brothers movies or Irving Berlin songs. But it affected
onion growers nationwide.
Onions, like land, were an easily understood physical commodity,
but onion futures were not. Most onion farmers did not hedge, testified
Veril Baldwin of Stockbridge, Michigan, the president of the National
Onion Association. “Onions are not processed or used in manufactur-
ing to any extent,” he explained, “so buying to hedge for future use is
almost nonexistent,” and “the average grower cannot successfully use
the market to hedge his sales.” The onion farmers had little or no expe-
rience with onion futures, which were primarily the province of specu-
lators. Onion futures, sneered the Texas grower Austin Anson, were
traded by “smart boys who had never owned an onion in their lives.”20
And those smart boys were engaging in unnatural-seeming transac-
tions that seemed to flout the laws of supply and demand, by causing
the price of onions to fluctuate wildly when neither the supply of onions
nor the demand for them was changing. “It is only in a futures market,”
Baldwin complained, that a person “can make money by depressing
the market, and that is what is the matter with it.” John Hardwicke,
another Texas grower, emphasized how little the onion farmers were
asking for. They were “not asking for a handout or subsidy, not asking
for price supports,” he noted. The industry was “simply asking for its
God-given right to conduct its own free business according to the laws
of supply and demand without some speculators being in a position to
often make a lot of money by scheming up to demoralize and ruin the
onion growers’ market.”21
232 Speculation
The Subprime€Crisis
Real estate speculation returned to the headlines in the first decade
of the twenty-╉first century, which saw the biggest rise and fall in real
estate since the 1920s. Nationally, home prices more than doubled
between 1995 and 2007. As in the 1920s, rising prices attracted pur-
chasers who hoped to own real estate only briefly before selling it on
to someone else. By 2005, according to the National Association of
Realtors, 28 percent of the people buying homes were seeking invest-
ments rather than places to live. Perhaps the best barometer of the
public interest in real estate speculation was the proliferation between
2005 and 2007 of reality television programs devoted to “flipping”
houses, in which purchasers with no real estate experience were de-
picted as making quick profits by speculating in single-╉family homes.
234 Speculation
26 Congressional Budget Office, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Role
in the Secondary Mortgage Market (2010), S1–S4, 4–7.
236
236 Speculation
28 Atif Mian and Amir Sufi, “The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion:
Evidence From the U.S. Mortgage Default Crisis,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 124 (2009): 1449–96; Benjamin J. Keys et al., “Did Securitization
Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence From Subprime Loans,” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 125 (2010): 307–62; Oren Bar-Gill, “The Law, Economics and
Psychology of Subprime Mortgage Contracts,” Cornell Law Review 94 (2009):
1073–151; Sumit Agarwal et al., “Predatory Lending and the Subprime Crisis,”
NBER Working Paper 19550 (2013); Alan M. White, “The Case for Banning
Subprime Mortgages,” University of Cincinnati Law Review 77 (2008): 617–44;
Antje Berndt et al., “The Role of Mortgage Brokers in the Subprime Crisis,”
NBER Working Paper 16175 (2010).
29 Cathy Lesser Mansfield, “The Road to Subprime ‘HEL’ Was Paved With
Good Congressional Intentions: Usury Deregulation and the Subprime Home
Equity Market,” South Carolina Law Review 51 (2000): 473– 587; Patricia
238
238 Speculation
31 Robert J. Shiller, The Subprime Solution: How Today’s Global Financial Crisis
Happened, and What to Do about It (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press, 2008), 39–68; Yuliya Demyanyk and Otto Van Hemert, “Understanding
the Subprime Mortgage Crisis,” Review of Financial Studies 24 (2011): 1848–
80; William M. Goetzmann et al., “The Subprime Crisis and House Price
Appreciation,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 44 (2012): 36–
66; Ing-Haw Cheng et al., “Wall Street and the Housing Bubble,” NBER
Working Paper 18904 (2013).
32 122 Stat. 2264 (2008).
240
240 Speculation
241
242
242 Speculation
to take advantage of them by purchasing their stock for less than its
true value.
The Massachusetts Supreme Court held that Agassiz had not broken
the law. Corporate directors and officers owed a duty to the corpora-
tion, explained Chief Justice Arthur Prentice Rugg in his opinion for
the court, but not to each of the corporation’s shareholders as indi-
viduals. Besides, directors bought and sold their own company’s stock
all the time. “An honest director would be in a difficult situation,”
Rugg worried, “if he could neither buy nor sell on the stock exchange
shares of stock in his own corporation without first seeking out the
other actual ultimate party to the transaction and disclosing to him
everything which a court or jury might later find that he then knew.”
Disclosure might be morally right, but it was not a legal requirement.
“Business of that nature is a matter to be governed by practical rules,”
Rugg observed. “Law in its sanctions is not coextensive with morality.”
And who would serve as the director of a corporation if he had to pay
the heavy price of not dealing in the corporation’s stock? The court
concluded: “Fiduciary obligations of directors ought not to be made
so onerous that men of experience and ability will be deterred from
accepting such office.”3
Rugg pointed out that most transactions in the economy were just like
the one between Goodwin and Agassiz, in that they involved one party
who possessed more information than the other. Inequality was inherent in
contracting. The law “cannot undertake to put all parties to every contract
on an equality as to knowledge, experience, skill and shrewdness,” Rugg
insisted. Sometimes the party with superior information got the better of
the deal, but that was life. A court “cannot undertake to relieve against
hard bargains made between competent parties without fraud.” Agassiz
knew more about the financial condition of the Cliff Mining Company
than Goodwin did, but Goodwin’s remedy was not to force Agassiz to
share what he knew. Rather, it was to find out the information for him-
self. Goodwin “was no novice,” Rugg lectured. “He was a member of the
Boston stock exchange.” Before selling his stock, “he made no inquiries
of” Agassiz “or of other officers of the company.” If he had asked about the
244 Speculation
mines in Michigan, and if Agassiz had lied to him, that would have been
fraud, and Goodwin would have been entitled to rescind the transaction.
As Rugg put it, “directors cannot rightly be allowed to indulge with impu-
nity in practices which do violence to prevailing standards of upright busi-
ness men.” But Agassiz had not lied to anyone, much less to Goodwin. He
had merely stayed quiet about what he knew, and that did not disable him
from dealing in the stock of his own company.4
Seventy years later, Samuel Waksal found himself in the same posi-
tion as Rodolphe Agassiz. Waksal, a former immunologist, had started
a company called ImClone, whose primary product was a promising
cancer treatment called Erbitux. But Waksal learned, to his disap-
pointment, that the Food and Drug Administration would not permit
Erbitux to be sold. When the rest of the world found out, ImClone’s
share price would plummet. Just as Rodolphe Agassiz had taken ad-
vantage of his access to good news, Waksal sought to take advantage
of his own access to bad news. He immediately tried to sell $5 million
of ImClone stock before the FDA announced its decision. But times
had changed. Waksal’s brokers refused to execute his sell order, because
they knew he was not allowed to sell his ImClone stock until the news
reached the public. Waksal was arrested a few months later. He pled
guilty to securities fraud and several other crimes, and he was sentenced
to seven years in prison. While he was trying to sell his own shares,
Waksal had urged friends and family members to sell their shares too.
One of those friends was the celebrity homemaker Martha Stewart,
who ended up serving a five-month prison sentence for making false
statements during the investigation of the incident.5
Over the course of the twentieth century, the law’s treatment of inside
information had changed dramatically. At the beginning of the century,
speculators’ ability to exploit their superior access to knowledge was
considered at worst inevitable, and at best a positive good. By the end of
the century, at least in certain circumstances, exploiting one’s knowledge
in this way was a serious crime. Rodolphe Agassiz had been esteemed
a shrewd businessman. Although he died a mere two months after the
Massachusetts Supreme Court decided his case, his lengthy obituary in
4 Id. at 661–62.
5 Daniel Kadlec, “Sam’s Club,” Time, 17 June 2002.
╇ 245
the New York Times discussed his polo playing and his service on corpo-
rate boards but did not even mention Homer Goodwin’s lawsuit against
him. Samuel Waksal did the same thing Agassiz had done, but when his
obituary is written he will likely be remembered as a criminal. Between
Agassiz’s era and Waksal’s, speculating on inside information had been
transformed from a normal, sound business practice into a vice.
One-╉Sided Knowledge
Insider trading in the shares of a corporation is just one instance of a
much broader and much older question of commercial morality. Where
a buyer or a seller knows more than his counterpart, when should he
be able to use that knowledge to his advantage, and when should he
be required to disclose the information before entering into a transac-
tion? This was an important and unsettled question in the early United
States.
The issue was sharply presented to the US Supreme Court in 1817 in
Laidlaw v. Organ, which became one of the court’s most well-╉known com-
mercial cases in its early years. During the War of 1812, tobacco prices were
much lower than normal due to the British blockade of southern ports,
which deprived tobacco growers of foreign markets. The war formally
ended in December 1814 with the signing of the Treaty of Ghent, but it
took some time for news of the treaty to reach the United States. In the eve-
ning of February 18, 1815, Hector Organ, a New Orleans tobacco merchant,
learned about the treaty. He realized that the news would spread quickly,
and that tobacco prices would rise with the lifting of the blockade. Early
the next morning, just after sunrise, he called on another tobacco mer-
chant in the city, Peter Laidlaw & Company, and offered to buy approxi-
mately 120,000 pounds of tobacco. Francis Girault, a member of Laidlaw
& Company, asked Organ if there was any news that might influence the
price of tobacco. Organ did not respond. Girault nevertheless sold Organ
the tobacco. Within a day, as news of the treaty filtered through New
Orleans, the price of tobacco rose 30 to 50 percent. Laidlaw & Company
seized the tobacco it had just delivered to Organ. Organ sued.6
6 Laidlaw v. Organ, 15 U.S. 178 (1817); M. H. Hoeflich, “Laidlaw v. Organ,
Gulian C. Verplanck, and the Shaping of Early Nineteenth Century Contract
246
246 Speculation
obligation to reveal what they knew. As the old Latin expression put it,
caveat emptor—let the buyer beware.
But this view was controversial. In a similar case a few years ear-
lier, for example, a Kentucky court had reached the opposite result.
A Virginian named Bowman owned a tract of land in Illinois that he
had never seen. (This was not unusual at the time. Bowman was appar-
ently a war veteran who had received the land as part of the compensa-
tion for his military service.) John Bates lived near the tract. He knew
that it included salt water, which made it more valuable, and he knew
that Bowman was unaware of the salt water. Bates communicated this
information to his brother James, who lived near Bowman. James Bates
purchased the land from Bowman without telling him about the salt
water. Bowman sued, and the court set aside the sale. To allow one
person to take advantage of another’s ignorance “might become perni-
cious in practice,” the court worried. It would allow “the dishonesty
and cunning of some to operate upon the honest credulity of others.”9
Indeed, a year after Laidlaw v. Organ, the Mississippi Supreme
Court disagreed with the US Supreme Court even more directly. Frazer
v. Gervais was nearly a carbon copy of Laidlaw: a merchant who knew of
the Treaty of Ghent bought cotton from a merchant who did not, at a
price that seemed far too low once the news of the treaty had spread. The
Mississippi court refused to enforce the transaction. Once the purchaser
heard information that would affect the price of cotton, the court con-
cluded, he could not buy cotton without first divulging the information
to the seller.10
The lawyer and future congressman Gulian Verplanck was so out-
raged by Laidlaw v. Organ that he wrote an entire book criticizing it.
Verplanck’s Essay on the Doctrine of Contracts was devoted to answering
the question posed by Laidlaw and similar cases. “We shall find num-
berless cases of the most opposite moral character, from the arts of de-
liberate knavery to the fairest gains of industry and enterprise, all agree-
ing in this one prominent feature: that the profits of the transaction
arose from the superiority of one party to the other in some material
248 Speculation
Thomas Cooper. “It is a disgrace to the law that such a maxim should
be adopted.” Cooper thought the court opinions applying the doc-
trine “ought to be classed as cases in support of falsehood and fraud.”
An admiring reviewer of Verplanck’s book blamed the doctrine on
the American inheritance of English common law, which had been
formed long before under primitive circumstances. “A savage race, like
the Saxons, and a nation of military barbarians, like the Normans,” he
scoffed, “could hardly be expected to derive their law of contracts from
a very pure and enlightened source, or to found it upon the enlarged
principles of civilized morality.” A Kentucky court refused to enforce
a contract for the sale of a horse when the seller failed to tell the buyer
that the horse was blind. “It will better comport with morality and
sound policy,” the court insisted, “to subject the seller to an action at
law, and thereby impose upon him the legal, as well as moral duty of
telling the whole truth.” James Kent, whose four-volume treatise on
American law was a standard reference work for decades after its publi-
cation in the 1820s, declared that “as a general rule, each party is bound
in every case to communicate to the other his knowledge of material
facts, provided he knows the other to be ignorant of them, and they be
not open and naked, or equally within the reach of his observation.”12
On this view, information was not a weapon to be wielded in the mar-
ketplace. The law, like common morality, should forbid the informed
from taking advantage of the ignorant.
But if there were many voices speaking against the caveat emptor
doctrine in the early nineteenth century, there were also many, prob-
ably more, speaking in its favor. “It would certainly be well, for the
best interests of society, if the pure principles of morality … could be
established as the law of the land, and practically enforced in the or-
dinary transactions of life,” one Mississippi lawyer acknowledged. But
requiring that contracting parties tell each other all they knew would be
“replete with difficulties.” Was a buyer bound to tell a seller “every fact
or rumor calculated to enhance the price of the article—or if not every
250 Speculation
fact, what facts, and who is to be the judge?” The law had to facilitate
commerce, not just promote morality, and the most moral rule was
not always the most practical. “In some special cases the law of the land
and morality are the same,” reasoned the Boston lawyer Nathan Dane,
but the two differed when “policy” was taken into account. Thus, every
“undue advantage in a bargain, to the hurt of another party, practised
by one, is an act of injustice in the eyes of morality; yet it is not the
means of restitution in the eyes of the law.” As another commentator
put it, caveat emptor “furnishes a plain, simple and practical rule for
the decision of all controversies of this nature,” even if “it is said by
some to be a hard, inequitable doctrine, repugnant to sound morality,
and productive of fraud, injustice and oppression.”13 Buyers or sellers
could not lie, but they had no duty to volunteer the truth.
Between the 1830s and 1850s, several courts accordingly declared that
American law embodied the principle of caveat emptor. A contract for
the sale of coffee beans was enforceable, held the US Supreme Court
Justice Henry Baldwin, even if one party failed to disclose his superior
knowledge of the state of the coffee market. “A purchaser may avail
himself of information which affects the price of the article, though it is
not known to the seller,” Baldwin explained. “Though the latter inquires
if there is any news which affects the price, the purchaser is not bound
to answer, and the contract is binding, though there was news then
in the place which raised the price.” As Baldwin saw it, acquiring and
exploiting information was a normal part of conducting business. “The
buying and selling [of ] merchandize being for mutual profit,” he rea-
soned, “one is not bound to impart to another his views of speculation,
his opinion of the effect of news or events, the bearing of the rise of one
article on another, or the results of his mercantile skill and knowledge
of the markets.” A few years later, the Indiana Supreme Court agreed,
in enforcing a contract in which a professional pork dealer bought ap-
proximately a thousand hogs, at a price well below market value, from
an elderly man unfamiliar with the value of pork. “However justly the
14 Blydenburg v. Welsh, 3 F. Cas. 771, 773 (C.C.D. Pa. 1831); Foley v. Cowgill, 5
Blackf. 18, 20 (Ind. 1838); Harris v. Tyson, 24 Pa. 347, 359–60 (1855).
252
252 Speculation
“The like reason would apply,” Story added, “where the vendor should
sell a house, situate[d]in a distant town, which he knew at the time to
be burnt down.” Story maintained that cases like these were exceptions
to the general rule of caveat emptor, because “there are circumstances of
peculiar trust and confidence, or relation between the parties.”15
Story’s view soon became orthodoxy. It was a middle ground be-
tween a strict rule of caveat emptor and a rule requiring disclosure.
In the 1820s, James Kent had argued that disclosure should always be
required, but in later editions of his treatise, beginning in the 1840s, he
conceded that such a requirement, “though one undoubtedly of moral
obligation, is perhaps too broadly stated, to be sustained by the practi-
cal doctrine of the courts.” He agreed with Story that disclosure was
required only where the person knowing the facts was “under some spe-
cial obligation, by confidence reposed, or otherwise, to communicate
them truly and fairly.” The courts agreed as well. In Maine, for example,
the state supreme court considered the case of a man who had paid for
a carriage with a note (that is, a promise to pay) from a third party. He
failed to tell the carriage seller that it would be impossible to collect on
the note. The court required him to give the carriage back to the seller.
A person had to disclose such information “if the means of information
are not equally accessible to both” the buyer and the seller, the court
held, “and especially when one of the parties relies upon the other to
communicate to him the true state of facts to enable him to judge of the
expediency of the bargain.”16 By the middle of the nineteenth century,
it was fairly well settled that one party to a contract had no obligation
to disclose information to the other, even information that might have
a big effect on the price of whatever was being sold, unless there was
some special relationship between the parties that imposed such a duty.
15 Kim Lane Scheppele, Legal Secrets: Equality and Efficiency in the Common Law
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), 269–98; Paula J. Dalley, “The
Law of Deceit, 1790–1860: Continuity Amidst Change,” American Journal
of Legal History 39 (1995): 405–42; Joseph Story, Commentaries on Equity
Jurisprudence (Boston: Hilliard, Gray & Co., 1836), 1:218–19, 221.
16 James Kent, Commentaries on American Law, 5th ed. (New York: Printed for
the author, 1844), 2:482 note a; Prentiss v. Russ, 16 Me. 30, 32–33 (1839); William
W. Story, A Treatise on the Law of Contracts Not Under Seal (Boston: Charles
C. Little and James Brown, 1844), 109.
253
254 Speculation
2 0 Id. at 584, 589.
21 Board of Commissioners of Tippecanoe County v. Reynolds, 44 Ind. 509, 513
(1873); Deaderick v. Wilson, 67 Tenn. 108 (1874); Crowell v. Jackson, 23 A. 426,
427 (N.J. 1891). See also Grant v. Attrill, 11 F. 469, 470 (C.C.S.D.N.Y. 1882);
Gillett v. Bowen, 23 F. 625, 626 (C.C.D. Colo. 1885).
256
256 Speculation
over the person with whom he deals, does not affect the validity of the
transaction.”22
While the judges tended to emphasize the doctrinal justification for
allowing corporate directors to trade on inside information—the lack
of any duty they owed to shareholders with respect to their ownership
of shares—the judges also sometimes provided practical reasons for
permitting insider trading. Stocks were constantly fluctuating in value,
the Utah Supreme Court reasoned, and one “who assumes to know the
most about them is frequently the first one to be deceived.” Information
was money in this uncertain world, so a director, like anyone, “is en-
titled to the benefit of his facilities for information.” The solution to the
problem of unequal information was not compelled disclosure, argued
the Michigan Supreme Court. It was for the less-informed party to find
out what the insiders already knew. “The books of the corporation are
open to all stockholders alike,” the court noted, “and each may inform
himself of the condition of the company.” If a shareholder did not avail
himself of this opportunity, lectured Maryland’s highest court, he had
only “his own lack of business prudence” to blame.23
In reaching this conclusion, American courts were both ratifying a
pervasive practice and ensuring that it would continue. By all accounts,
insider trading was very common. Guides for investors routinely
warned that the market was an uneven playing field, where newcomers
would be up against better-informed insiders. In eighteenth-century
England, when government debt securities (then also called “stocks”)
were traded more widely than shares of businesses, Thomas Mortimer’s
oft-reprinted Every Man His Own Broker cautioned that government of-
ficials “have the earliest intelligence of all events that can tend either to
raise or fall the Stocks,” and that an official, “if he should be a Jobber,”
might “settle a great account … to his advantage.” In the nineteenth
century, as corporate shares became an ever-larger part of the market,
American authors repeated the same warning. “Sometimes the funds
of a Bank are employed in purchasing its own stock,” lamented the
economist and journalist William Gouge, “and then, if the price of-
fered be sufficiently high, those who have the management contrive
to sell their own shares.” The same was true of all corporations, which
were “liable to be abused,” cautioned the economist Daniel Raymond.
“This is mostly done by speculators and stock-jobbers, getting control
and management of them, and then managing them with a view to
their own speculations,” a feat they could accomplish by keeping “the
stockholders and the public in the dark respecting the conditions of the
corporation, while they are themselves in the light.”24
The difficulty of matching wits with wily insiders was a staple of
the breathless exposés of Wall Street published at midcentury. “Certain
Stockholders are the losers,” one such publication reported, while “those
most active in getting up the concern are greatly improved in circum-
stances.” For this reason, “we advise those not acquainted with active
business, widows, orphans, &c. to leave all new undertakings to busi-
ness men.” Another cautioned that Wall Street was no place for “small
victims and outsiders.” “Don’t let speculators have anything to do with
the management,” insisted another. “Ask for the accounts; examine well
the details. … You have certainly a right to inquire about investing
your own money.”25 It was well understood, although often deplored,
that one of the customary perks of being the director of a corporation
was the opportunity to profit from trading in the corporation’s stock.
Two New York stockbrokers published books in 1888 that were
part memoir and part investment guide, and both brokers discussed
the prevalence of insider trading. “Incomplete or insufficient informa-
tion is especially dangerous,” Henry Clews explained in an account of
his twenty-eight years on the New York Stock Exchange. “One-sided
knowledge is nowhere as deceiving as here.” Clews recalled examples
24 Thomas Mortimer, Every Man His Own Broker (London: S. Hooper, 1761), 44;
William M. Gouge, A Short History of Paper Money and Banking in the United
States (Philadelphia: T. W. Ustick, 1833), 76; Daniel Raymond, The Elements
of Constitutional Law and of Political Economy, 4th ed. (Baltimore: Cushing &
Brother, 1840), 276.
25 William Armstrong, Stocks and Stock- Jobbing in Wall- Street
(New York: New York Publishing Co., 1848), 28; George G. Foster, New York
in Slices (New York: W. F. Burgess, 1849), 16; George Francis Train, Young
America in Wall-Street (New York: Derby & Jackson, 1857), 212–13.
258
258 Speculation
260 Speculation
29 Paula J. Dalley, “From Horse Trading to Insider Trading: The Historical
Antecedents of the Insider Trading Debate,” William & Mary Law Review 39
(1998): 1289–1353; Fisher v. Budlong, 10 R.I. 525, 527–29 (1873).
30 Ritchie v. McMullen, 79 F. 522, 532–34 (6th Cir. 1897).
261
supreme court determined. Once he had received the offer to buy the
company, he also had “a special agency for the sale,” under which “he
was specially authorized to find a purchaser,” and that special agency
imposed an obligation of candor toward the shareholders greater than
that of an ordinary insider. In Utah, when Alviras Snow, the treasurer
of a mining company, bought shares from C. D. Morrison for much
less than their true value, the state supreme court rescinded the transac-
tion. Snow was “a dealer in mines and mining stock” who had “almost
absolute control of the business affairs.” Morrison, by contrast, “was
a poor man, with a family, and had to keep constantly at work. He
resided at a wayside station on the railroad 500 miles from Salt Lake
City, where the books of the company were kept.” Morrison had never
even been to Salt Lake City. He knew little or nothing about the busi-
ness. He was entirely dependent on Snow for information. The stock
sale was “the culmination or final act of a scheme conceived by Snow,
weeks before, to defraud Morrison out of his stock.” These special facts
sufficed to render the normal caveat emptor rule inapplicable. “Under
these circumstances,” the court held, “Snow was both morally and le-
gally bound to refrain from doing anything … to mislead or deceive
Morrison.”31 Where an insider’s conduct seemed especially reprehen-
sible, or where a shareholder was particularly sympathetic, it did not
take much for courts to find special circumstances that allowed them to
disregard the usual rule.
The most famous of these “special facts” cases, Strong v. Repide, was
decided by the US Supreme Court in 1909. It came from the Philippines,
which had become an American colony shortly before. When the
United States assumed control of the Philippines, one of its first acts
was to purchase much of the colony’s land. One of the big landowners
was the Philippine Sugar Estates Development Company, which, after
protracted negotiations, reached an agreement in 1903 to sell a large
parcel to the government at a price favorable to the company, a deal
that would cause the company’s stock price to rise. Francisco Repide,
a director of the company and the owner of nearly three-quarters of
262 Speculation
the contract to sell the plant, he exercised the options and immediately
resold the shares, yielding him an instant profit of nearly $50,000.
This scheme did not sit right with Joseph Lamar of the Georgia
Supreme Court. Lamar had just been appointed to the court. He was a
corporate lawyer from Augusta, who would stay on the court for only
two years before returning to his law practice. (In 1911, President Taft
would appoint him to the US Supreme Court, where he would serve
until his death five years later.) Lamar knew full well that under existing
law there was nothing illegal about Oliver’s transactions. But he did not
like it. “It is a matter of common knowledge,” Lamar noted, “that the
market value of shares rises and falls, not only because of an increase
or decrease in tangible property, but by reason of real or contemplated
action on the part of managing officers.” To allow an insider to trade on
his superior knowledge, “without making a full disclosure, and putting
the stockholder on an equality of knowledge as to those facts, would
offer a premium for faithless silence, and give a reward for the suppres-
sion of truth.” Lamar was dismayed that the law would allow a director
“to take advantage of his own wrong—a thing abhorrent to a court.”
So he and his colleagues established a new rule. In Georgia, Lamar ex-
plained, the inside information obtained by a corporate director “is a
quasi asset of the company, and the shareholder is as much entitled to
the advantage of that sort of asset as to any other regularly entered on
the list of the company’s holdings.” Information about corporate deal-
ings belonged to the corporation, not to the director. “Where the direc-
tor obtains the information giving added value to the stock by virtue
of his official position,” Lamar declared, “he holds this information in
trust for the benefit of those who placed him where this knowledge was
obtained.” The director was thus “a quasi trustee as to the shareholder’s
interest in the shares.” He could not use inside information to take ad-
vantage of the shareholders.33
Kansas followed suit the next year. “The managing officers of a cor-
poration are not only trustees in relation to the corporate entity,” the
state’s supreme court held, “but they are also to some extent and in
many respects trustees of the corporate shareholders.” John Stewart,
264 Speculation
that the law yet allows him to do this, does more to discourage legiti-
mate investment in corporate shares than almost anything else.” Adolf
Berle approvingly predicted that the recent cases classifying directors
as trustees for the shareholders “are merely specific applications of a
much wider fiduciary relationship which will ultimately transform the
publicly financed corporations of today into organisms having many of
the characteristics of investment trusts.”36
The Securities Exchange Act of 1934 addressed the propriety of in-
sider trading only indirectly. The act did not prohibit insiders from
buying or selling stock or require them to disclose their inside informa-
tion before trading. Instead, section 16(a) of the act required directors,
officers, and large shareholders (those who own more than 10 percent
of the stock) to file monthly statements revealing any purchases or sales.
This requirement was “based upon the theory that if such transactions
were publicized they would be discontinued,” explained Securities and
Exchange Commission Chairman Donald Cook. In addition, “for the
purpose of preventing the unfair use of information,” section 16(b) of
the act barred directors, officers, and large shareholders from profiting
from purchases and sales (or sales and purchases) within a six-month
span. The corporation itself could sue to recover any such short-swing
profits. Finally, section 16(c) of the act prohibited directors, officers,
and large shareholders from making short sales of shares they did not
yet own.37
This was an extremely oblique way of preventing insider trading.
The Securities Exchange Act applied only to the largest corporations,
those traded on a stock exchange, so it did not limit insider trading in
the shares of smaller companies. As for the largest corporations, the act
made insider trading more difficult. Insiders could not profit secretly or
266 Speculation
quickly. But they could still profit, by buying shares before publicizing
good news or selling before publicizing bad, so long as they were willing
to hold the shares (or refrain from repurchasing them) for more than six
months. And as a committee of the American Bar Association pointed
out a few years after the law’s enactment, the act “does not meet the
problem squarely, for it neither compensates the losing party to a trade
nor confines its punitive effect to actual instances where information
confidentially obtained is used for private profit.”38 Section 16 failed to
reach many instances of insider trading, while it forced insiders to dis-
gorge profits even if they were not acquired by virtue of inside informa-
tion. In retrospect, the strategy pursued in the Securities Exchange Act
can be understood as a snapshot of informed opinion during an era of
transition. Just as the states were dividing over the propriety of insider
trading, the federal government occupied an intermediate position as
well, neither fully approving nor fully forbidding it.
cards, and much more. If caveat emptor was the background rule of
commercial law in the late nineteenth century, disclosure—the oppo-
site of caveat emptor—had become the background rule by the late
twentieth.39
These legal changes reflected a growing ethical interest in protect-
ing consumers against sharp practices by knowledgeable insiders in the
marketplace. In the stock market, ordinary shareholders were consum-
ers of a sort; they were buying (and selling) a product they often knew
much less about than the person on the other side of the trade. The
law’s treatment of insider trading began to change accordingly.
Courts in rural states had already condemned insider trading, but in
the late 1940s, the practice came in for condemnation by judges in urban
states and eastern financial centers as well. The California Supreme
Court held that “an officer, in buying or selling to a shareholder, must
inform him of those matters relating to the corporate business of which
the officer has knowledge.” A court in Chicago required a director to
reveal his advance knowledge of the sale of the corporation’s assets before
buying stock. The Delaware Court of Chancery, an important decision
maker because of the many corporations chartered in Delaware, held
that a corporate employee could not purchase the corporation’s stock
when he knew that the price would soon rise because the corporation
itself planned to purchase its own stock. Louis Loss, the associate gen-
eral counsel for the Securities and Exchange Commission, concluded
in 1951 that “the so-called ‘majority’ view,” which permitted insiders to
buy and sell freely without disclosure, “is gradually giving way to the
generally growing feeling of responsibility of corporate insiders—the
development of a status of ‘trusteeship’ in a non-technical sense.”40
The SEC helped this development along. In 1942, the SEC pro-
mulgated Rule 10b-5, a catch-all provision that prohibited “any act,
268 Speculation
and I received a call from Jim Treanor who was then the Director of
the Trading and Exchange Division. He said, “I have just been on
the telephone with Paul Rowen,” who was then the S.E.C. Regional
Administrator in Boston, “and he has told me about the president of
some company in Boston who is going around buying up the stock
of his company from his own shareholders at $4.00 a share, and he
has been telling them that the company is doing very badly, whereas,
in fact, the earnings are going to be quadrupled and will be $2.00 a
share for the coming year. Is there anything we can do about it?”
material facts” constituted a violation of the new Rule 10b-5.42 This was
just an administrative decision, not the judgment of a court, but it was
important nonetheless, because as a practical matter many of the cases
before the SEC never reached a court. In the view of the SEC, at least,
insider trading was now illegal.
Investors soon began using the rule to sue insiders to recover the
insiders’ profits from such trades. In 1946, the managers of the Western
Board and Paper Company bought company stock from fellow share-
holders without telling the shareholders that they had reached an agree-
ment to sell the company’s plant and equipment to another firm. The
shareholders sued the managers under Rule 10b-5 and won. “Under
any reasonably liberal construction” of the rule, the judge explained,
“these provisions apply to directors and officers who, in purchasing the
stock of the corporation from others, fail to disclose a fact coming to
their knowledge by reason of their position, which would materially
affect the judgment of the other party to the transaction.” In a similar
case a few years later, another judge declared that “the rule is clear. It is
unlawful for an insider, such as a majority stockholder, to purchase the
stock of minority stockholders without disclosing material facts affect-
ing the value of the stock, known to the majority stockholder by virtue
of his inside position.” The judge reasoned that “the duty of disclosure
stems from the necessity of preventing a corporate insider from utiliz-
ing his position to take unfair advantage of the uninformed minority
stockholders. It is an attempt to provide some degree of equalization of
bargaining position.” By the late 1950s, the leading treatise on closely
held corporations advised the victims of insider trading to sue under
Rule 10b-5 rather than state common law, because the rule imposed
stricter duties of disclosure on insiders.43
The norms of corporate insiders changed accordingly. In the early
twentieth century, Donald Cook recalled, profits from insider trading
270 Speculation
Jones until 11:45, and it did not reach the stock exchange until 12:29.
In the interim, a Curtiss-Wright director named J. Cheever Cowdin
left the meeting. Cowdin was also a representative of a brokerage firm
called Cady, Roberts and Company. He phoned Robert Gintel, a col-
league at Cady Roberts, and told Gintel about the reduction of the div-
idend. Gintel promptly sold Curtiss-Wright stock on behalf of several
of the brokerage firm’s customers, and sold the stock short on behalf of
several others. One of the customers was Gintel’s wife. When the news
of the dividend was finally made public, Curtiss-Wright’s stock price
plummeted. By selling as soon as Cowdin told him about the dividend,
Gintel had saved his clients a bundle.
William Cary had just been appointed by President Kennedy as
chairman of the SEC. Cary had spent most of his career as a law profes-
sor at Columbia. He had a particular interest in stamping out insider
trading. The SEC’s earlier cases had involved insiders who traded with
shareholders in face-to-face transactions, and Cary recognized that the
Cady Roberts case presented a chance to extend the ban on insider trad-
ing to trades on a stock exchange, where the person on the other side
of the trade was unknown. He took the opportunity to write a lengthy
opinion spelling out the SEC’s view of the law. “The securities acts
may be said to have generated a wholly new and far-reaching body of
Federal corporation law,” Cary declared. Part of that law, he explained,
was a ban on insider trading. “We and the courts have consistently
held that insiders must disclose material facts which are known to them
by virtue of their position but which are not known to persons with
whom they deal,” he explained. This was just as true for transactions on
a stock exchange as for face-to-face transactions. “It would be anoma-
lous indeed,” Cary insisted, “if the protection afforded by the antifraud
provisions were withdrawn from transactions effected on exchanges,”
which were the “primary markets for securities transactions.” Because
neither Cowdin nor Gintel had disclosed the dividend reduction before
Gintel sold Curtiss-Wright stock, they had broken the law. Cowdin had
died shortly after the incident, so the SEC could not punish him, but
the SEC suspended Gintel from the stock exchange for twenty days.46
272 Speculation
illegal. “How about the case in which the partner of this brokerage
house has lunch with his friend, the vice-president, and is told, ‘You
know, Bill, that new combustion engine that we wrote about in our
last report to stockholders, we spent fifteen million dollars on it,
but it turned out to be a complete dud.’ ” Had the broker become
an “insider” who owed a duty to the corporation not to trade in
its stock? And what about his duty to the clients whose money he
was investing—which took priority? The Chicago lawyer W. McNeil
Kennedy was a former regional administrator of the SEC, but even
he was positive that the decision “foreshadows grave problems for the
securities industry.”49
The view was quite different outside Wall Street. Louis Loss had left
the SEC for Harvard Law School, where he would teach for decades. “I
think if Professor Cary does nothing else at the SEC he has earned his
pay in Cady,” Loss exclaimed. “I view that as a landmark in the law.” As
Loss saw it, Cary had said “officially what needed to be said a long time
ago. Of course it opens problems—what does not?”50
Another set of problems was opened a few years later, when the US
Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, the federal appellate court
with jurisdiction over New York and thus the most important to secu-
rities law, decided the Texas Gulf Sulphur case. Directors and officers
of a mining company bought company stock when they, but not the
public, knew that the company had found unusually rich ores and thus
that the stock price was certain to rise. These directors and officers were
paradigmatic insiders, and their knowledge of the ores was informa-
tion as important to the stock price as any information could be. The
difficult thing about the case was not the result, although the case did
mark the first occasion in which a court of appeals blessed the SEC’s
now two-decades-old view that Rule 10b-5 barred insider trading. The
problems were caused instead by the court’s broad language, which
suggested a prohibition on insider trading even wider than the SEC
274 Speculation
51 Securities and Exchange Commission v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833,
848, 851–52 (2d Cir. 1968) (en banc).
275
52 Wall Street Journal, 14 Aug. 1968, 3; 19 Aug. 1968, 5; New York Times, 15 Aug.
1968, 54; 18 Aug. 1968, F1; Wall Street Journal, 3 Sept. 1968, 30; New York
Times, 1 Sept. 1968, E5; 25 Aug. 1968, F14; 13 Oct. 1968, F1; 11 Oct. 1968, 67.
276
276 Speculation
278 Speculation
279
280
280 Speculation
apply in concrete cases. How was a judge supposed to tell whether this
or that transaction was speculation or investment?
A second context was the capital gains tax. A capital gain is income
from the sale of an asset at a price higher than was paid for it. Capital
gains have been taxed as income since the birth of the modern federal
income tax in the early twentieth century. For nearly as long, Congress
has sought to impose higher tax rates on speculators than on investors,
so as not to deter investment. Of course, to do so requires some method
of telling the two groups apart. The drafters of the tax code have thus
faced the same question as judges evaluating the transactions of trust-
ees. How could they distinguish speculation from investment?
A third context in which the question arose was in the design of a
securities transaction tax. Since the late nineteenth century, the federal
government and the state of New York have, off and on, imposed small
taxes on the sale of stock. The primary goal of these taxes has been
to raise revenue, not to deter speculation. There have been recurring
suggestions, however, that the tax should be increased to the point
where it would make speculation uncomfortably expensive, as a way
of reducing the amount of it. And these suggestions have inevitably
raised the same old nagging questions: Is it possible to deter specu-
lation without also deterring investment? Can one be distinguished
from the other?
The Prudent€Man
When the wealthy Boston merchant John McLean died in 1823, he left
the then-╉enormous sum of $50,000 to a trust, the income from which
was to support his widow, Ann, for the rest of her life. Upon Ann’s
death, the fund would be divided evenly between Harvard College and
the Massachusetts General Hospital. McLean placed the money in the
care of two other Boston merchants, Jonathan and Francis Amory, who
used it to purchase the stock of a bank, an insurance company, and
two textile firms. A few years later, the value of the insurance stock
had fallen from $16,000 to $12,000, and the shares in the two textile
companies, which the Amorys had bought for $25,000, were worth
only $17,000. Harvard and the Massachusetts General Hospital were
not pleased. They sued Francis Amory (Jonathan had died), and they
281
282 Speculation
3 Smyth v. Burns, 25 Miss. 422, 427 (1853); Gray v. Fox, 1 N.J. Eq. 259, 266–67
(N.J. Ct. Ch. 1831); Ackerman v. Emott, 4 Barb. 626, 646–47 (N.Y. Super. 1848).
4 Vidal v. Philadelphia, 43 U.S. 127 (1844).
283
the interest on this sum for her life, and then on her death the money
would be divided among her children. The trustees used part of the
money to buy shares of the Bank of the United States. Girard himself
had been intimately involved in creating the bank, had been one of
the bank’s directors, and had owned a significant fraction of the bank’s
stock. No financial institution, with the exception of Girard’s own pri-
vate bank, was as closely associated with Stephen Girard as the Bank of
the United States. But the trustees had the misfortune to buy the shares
just before the panic of 1837 shut the bank’s doors for good.
“We have not a doubt, that the investment was made in perfect good
faith,” explained the Pennsylvania Supreme Court. But the court re-
quired the trustees to compensate the Hemphills for the loss, because
they had speculated with the Hemphills’ money. “If a trustee may
throw off his responsibility by investing the trust fund in the stock
of a corporation, what security is left?” the court asked. “There is no
reason why the trustee should not make the investment in some secu-
rity which cannot fail. It is just as convenient.” The court held that the
trustees should have invested in land or in government bonds, which
were less likely to lose their value. “It is better for trustees that the rule
of their conduct should be clearly defined and well understood,” the
court concluded. “A plain path, though it may be a narrow one, is safer
to walk in than a trackless waste, where no man can be sure that he is
on the right course.”5
A few years later the New Hampshire Supreme Court was just as
dubious about a trustee’s purchase of stock in the Boston, Concord,
and Montreal Railroad, stock that soon became worthless. “Safety is
the primary object to be secured in an investment of this kind,” the
court noted, “and the trustee is not chargeable with an income that
cannot be realized without hazard to the fund.” The construction of
a new railway line was the very opposite of safe. “Now it seems to us
that the building of a railroad must, from the very inherent nature of
the enterprise, have at all times been regarded by prudent men as a
doubtful adventure,” clucked the court. Even if the purchase of the
stock “was advised and approved by … judicious and prudent men
284 Speculation
whom the trustee consulted,” it was simply not the role of a trustee to
put funds into any business corporation.6
By 1872, when the Salem, Massachusetts, lawyer Jairus Perry pub-
lished his Treatise on the Law of Trusts and Trustees, he could report
that nearly all courts drew a sharp line between business corporations,
which were too speculative for trustees, and safe investments like land
and government bonds. Money put into business corporations “runs
the risks and chances of trade, business, and speculation,” Perry ex-
plained. “Calamities that depress public credit seldom occur, while the
risks of trade are constant. It would seem to be the wiser course to
withdraw the funds, settled for the support of women, children, and
other parties who cannot exercise an active discretion in the protection
of their interests, as much as possible from the chances of business.”7
The prudent man would stay away from such risks.
What made corporate stock too speculative? The problem with cor-
porations, a New York court explained, was that a stockholder had to
put his faith in the wisdom of other people, the directors and officers of
the firm, who were beyond the effective supervision of the trustee. “The
moment the fund is invested in bank, or insurance, or railroad stock, it
has left the control of the trustees,” the court reasoned. “Its safety and
the hazard, or risk of loss, is no longer dependent upon their skill, care,
or discretion, in its custody or management.” A trustee would be abdi-
cating his solemn responsibility if he delegated his duty of care to the
managers of such an enterprise. Of course, prudent men bought shares
of corporations all the time, with their own money, but in the court’s
view that was no reason for trustees to speculate with other people’s
money. “If it be said, that men of the highest prudence do, in fact, invest
their funds in such stocks,” the court concluded, “the answer is” that “in
their private affairs, they do, and they lawfully may, put their principal
funds at hazard; in the affairs of a trust they may not.”8
In many cases, the problem courts perceived was that the particular
corporation involved was so new that there was not yet any way to
286 Speculation
But there were other sources of risk besides novelty. One was dis-
tance. When a trustee in New York purchased a mortgage on land in
Toledo, Ohio, New York’s highest court took the opportunity to es-
tablish a general rule forbidding trustees from making investments in
other states. When money was sent so far away, the court fretted, “the
proper and prudent knowledge of values would become more difficult
and uncertain; watchfulness and personal care would in the main be
replaced by confidence in distant agents, and legal remedies would have
to be sought under the disadvantages of distance, and before different
and unfamiliar tribunals.” The Missouri Supreme Court was positively
scornful, for the same reason, about a trustee who purchased bonds
issued by the Mexican state of Jalisco. The court was shocked that a
trustee in St. Louis would go “thousands of miles into a foreign country
and among a strange people to obtain for his brother an investment in
6 per cent bonds.”10 A prudent man would keep his money closer to
home, where he could keep an eye on it himself, and where the rules of
the game were familiar and enforced by his own neighbors.
Any number of circumstances could push an investment into the
forbidden territory of speculation. Making an investment with bor-
rowed money, for example, was “purely a speculation,” one New York
judge declared, even where the investment would have been permis-
sible without the borrowing. The judge explained that an investment
is “for the purpose of securing an income for the beneficiaries, while
a speculation is for the purpose of realizing a profit from the trans-
action.” Making an investment in a business the trustee knew little
or nothing about was another circumstance that suggested specula-
tion. When Ezra Curtis died in 1882, he left a friend named Potter
in charge of managing the funds of his widow, Mary, who “had no
business experience whatever” and thus left all the decisions to Potter.
Potter put most of the money into shares of the Housatonic Rolling-
Stock Company, a manufacturer of railroad cars. “The stock of the
Housatonic Rolling-Stock Company was a speculative stock, of the
character or value of which it is found that Mr. Potter knew nothing,”
10 Ormiston v. Olcott, 84 N.Y. 339, 344 (1881); Cornet v. Cornet, 190 S.W. 333, 340
(Mo. 1916).
287
11 In re Hirsch’s Estate, 101 N.Y.S. 893, 899 (N.Y. App. Div. 1906); Appeal of Potter,
12 A. 513, 514 (Conn. 1888).
12 Fidelity T. & S.V. Co. v. Glover, 14 S.W. 343, 344 (Ky. Ct. App. 1890).
288
288 Speculation
bought shares in the hope that they would appreciate, that was specula-
tion. “The word ‘speculate’ means to purchase with the expectation of
an advance in price,” declared one Ohio judge. “An investment is the
laying out of money with the view of obtaining an income or profit
from the thing bought whether it be an interest in a business, a farm,
stocks or bonds; to place money so that it will be safe and yield a profit.”
On this definition, “investments can be made in stocks and stocks can
be taken as security for loans without the transactions becoming specu-
lations.” A judge in New Jersey similarly reasoned that “a speculative
investment is one in which there is a substantial danger of loss of prin-
cipal balanced by a prospect of appreciation of principal.” Many stock
purchases were speculative, but not all. “Some few common stocks,
because of the ample assets which they represent, the steady earnings
of the company, and the conservatism of its management, fall into the
class of safe investments, and such the trustee may properly retain.”13
There was more than one line that could be drawn between investment
and speculation.
Case by case, trustee by trustee, transaction by transaction, courts
were policing the boundary between investment and speculation, by
applying the vague standard of the prudent man to countless unique
factual situations. By the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries
it was commonplace to observe that the lines the courts drew were not
all consistent. The prudent man standard “is wholly valueless, except as
an indication of the animus of the court,” complained the Philadelphia
lawyer Jonathan Merrill. “What court could or would name the securi-
ties in which, and in which alone, diligent, careful and prudent men of
discretion and intelligence might place their funds?” “The word ‘specu-
lation’ is not capable of exact legal definition,” admitted Mayo Adams
Shattuck, a Boston trust lawyer. “It is a very difficult task to state what
it is that provides the distinction between the fiduciary attitude and
that of the business man or speculator.” When the Harvard law profes-
sor Austin Wakeman Scott surveyed the field in his magisterial treatise
on the law of trusts, he had to concede that “the line between what
13 State v. Gibbs, 18 Ohio Dec. 694, 695–96 (Ohio. Ct. Comm. Pleas 1908); Wild
v. Brown, 183 A. 899, 900 (N.J. Ct. Ch. 1936).
289
290 Speculation
On the other hand, cases only reached the courts when investments
went sour. Beneficiaries never complained when trustees took risks and
made money. With hindsight it was easy to condemn a transaction as
unduly speculative, after it had already proven disastrous. Judges’ aware-
ness that they encountered a biased sample of investments should have
counseled in favor of deference to the decisions of trustees, for fear of
classifying as speculation a transaction that would have seemed a prudent
investment if it had been taken to court when it was made. If many judges
were aware of this problem, however, it is not evident in their opinions,
which contain few traces of humility. As one judge wrote in 1931, speak-
ing of the state of the stock market two years earlier, just before the crash,
“it was common knowledge, not only amongst bankers and trust com-
panies, but the general public as well, that the stock market condition at
the time of the testator’s death was an unhealthy one, that values were
very much inflated, and that a crash was almost sure to occur.” The judge
accordingly blamed the trustees for lacking the foresight to anticipate the
crash, a prescience that had been possessed by very few in 1929.16
The line between speculation and investment, always unstable,
moved conspicuously in the twentieth century. Virtually all courts
began to permit trustees to buy shares of business corporations, so long
as the trustees intended to own the shares for a long time. “The dif-
ference between speculation and investment,” declared an Alabama
court, was that “one who buys common stocks with the idea of sell-
ing them on the market for higher prices is speculating. One who is
making a prudent investment examines the stocks’ intrinsic values and
purchases them for a long-term investment.” As Mayo Shattuck sum-
marized the cases at midcentury, “definitions of ‘speculative’ participa-
tions must vary with time and place and circumstances. The concept of
permanence of investment, as contrasted with transactions entered into
for a quick turnover or profit, is, however, basic.”17 In the nineteenth
century, judges had tended to draw the line between corporate stock
and government bonds, but in the twentieth they tended to draw it
between short-term and long-term purchases of corporate stock.
One reason for the line’s migration was simply that by the middle
of the twentieth century there were some corporations that had proven
stable and profitable for a long period of time. The St. Louis–based
International Shoe Company, for example, had been formed in 1911
by the merger of firms dating back to the 1890s. By the mid-twentieth
century it was the largest shoe manufacturer in the nation. Its sales
and its revenue had grown continuously for decades, except for a brief
downturn at the beginning of the Depression. It had operated at a
profit every year since its inception, and its stock had paid dividends
every year. It had no debt. In 1946, when a St. Louis court had to
decide whether stock in the International Shoe Company was an ap-
propriate investment for a trustee, the court had no doubt that it was.
“Generally speaking,” explained the Philadelphia lawyer James Moore,
shares “in a ‘well-seasoned’ corporation are acceptable for investment
and retention. By ‘well-seasoned’ (or similar phrases) the courts seem
to mean corporations which have been in existence for a substantial
period of time, which are leaders in their field, which have a back-
ground of steady earnings and growth, and whose securities, listed on a
recognized exchange, are not particularly subject to rapid fluctuations
in market price.” In short, “the background of the corporation will go
far toward determining whether the investment is speculative.”18
Another reason for the courts’ growing acceptance of stock purchases
as investments rather than speculations was the pervasive inflation of
the twentieth century. There had been inflationary periods in the nine-
teenth century, especially during the Civil War, but these had been
more than balanced out by long periods of deflation. Price levels in
1900 were only around two-thirds of what they had been in 1800. The
Man Rule for Fiduciary Investment in the United States in the Twentieth
Century,” Ohio State Law Journal 12 (1951): 517.
1 8 Louis S. Headley, “Trust Investments: Fundamental Principles Lawyers Should
Know,” Trusts and Estates 71 (1952): 740–41; Warmack v. Crawford, 195 S.W.2d
919, 920–21 (Mo. Ct. App. 1946); James A. Moore, “A Rationalization of the
Trust Surcharge Cases,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review 96 (1948): 668.
292
292 Speculation
twentieth century was very different. Prices nearly tripled between 1900
and 1950, even with the sharp deflation of the early 1930s, and in the
second half of the twentieth century they would rise even faster. This
new economic climate required a rethinking of trustees’ investment
strategies. In the nineteenth century, when even an investment that
paid no interest at all would leave the investor ahead after accounting
for deflation, the prudent man had no reason to take risks to seek a
higher return. But in the twentieth century, when a long-term invest-
ment at low interest rates would lose money in light of inflation, the
avoidance of all risk was no longer prudent. “Hardship has overtaken
the income beneficiaries of many trusts which, when created, were
thought to provide adequate support,” one commentator observed after
the inflation of the late 1940s. “The trouble with trust funds,” agreed
the financial journalist H. J. Maidenberg, was that the old standards of
prudence had become obsolete. Because of inflation, “in recent years,
trust funds have generally performed far worse than the portfolios of
most investors who have handled their own trading and investments.”19
The prudent man had to invest in stocks to keep up with inflation.
Finally, in the second half of the twentieth century, advances in
economics made the old prudent man rule seem even more outdated.
Judges had been in the habit of evaluating investments one by one,
when by modern lights the relevant question was not the wisdom of
any single investment but rather the wisdom of the entire portfolio
of investments chosen by the trustee. A purchase of stock that might
have been too risky on its own could be deemed prudent as part of a
larger diversified package. Along with the new economic theory came
new investment vehicles like index funds, which made it much easier
for trustees to diversify their investments. These developments put ad-
ditional pressure on the always-fragile line between speculation and
investment.20
19 Susan B. Carter et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United States: Millennial
Edition On Line (Cambridge University Press, 2006), table Cc1–2; Harry L.
Fledderman, “Prudent Man Investment of Trust Funds During Inflation,”
California Law Review 39 (1951): 380; New York Times, 18 Jan. 1981, F13.
20 John H. Langbein and Richard A. Posner, “Market Funds and Trust-
Investment Law,” American Bar Foundation Research Journal 1 (1976): 1–34;
Jeffrey N. Gordon, “The Puzzling Persistence of the Constrained Prudent Man
╇ 293
As a result, every state repealed the prudent man rule by the end
of the twentieth century. After nearly two centuries of trying to draw
a line between investment and speculation, the task was abandoned
as fruitless. “We no longer use speculation as a tool for dealing with
trustee investment misadventures because it is considered sloppy, sen-
timental, and inefficient,” one law professor explained. “The reforms
imported modern investing theory and practice into trust law.” Rather
than asking whether the trustee was investing or speculating, the new
laws tended instead to ask whether the trustee was advancing the pur-
pose of the trust with skill and diligence. Under this new rule, trusts
included more stock than they had before.21 It was simply too hard to
tell where investment stopped and speculation began.
Taxing Speculators
When the federal government began taxing income in 1913, capital
gains were not given any special treatment. They were taxed at the
same rates as other income. This was a recurring source of complaint
from people who owned land and other property that had appreciated
for many years and who thus faced very large tax bills when they sold
the property. “Under the present law,” explained the Senate Finance
Committee in 1921, “many sales of farms, mineral properties, and other
capital assets have been prevented by the fact that gains and profits
earned over a series of years are under the present law taxed as a lump
sum.” To provide relief to such taxpayers, Congress decided to count as
294 Speculation
income only 40 percent of the capital gains realized upon the sale of an
asset. The result was to make the tax on capital gains only 40 percent of
the tax on ordinary income.22
But this change raised a new problem. Many of the taxpayers who
would benefit from the reduced rate were not selling the family farm;
they were selling shares of corporations, sometimes shares they had
purchased but a short time before. Taxing capital gains at a lower rate
would be a windfall to speculators. “Is this desirable?” wondered the
economist Willford King. “Speculation tends to degenerate into gam-
bling and gambling is generally recognized as an anti-social form of
activity.” Senator David Walsh of Massachusetts raised the same con-
cern on the floor of the Senate. “Under the proposed amendment and
bill a lawyer or any other professional man who derived as a fee from
a large case or a merchant who through a substantial increase in sales
derived an income of, say, $100,000 per year is taxable upon the full
amount of income,” Walsh complained. But “the speculator who de-
rives an income of $100,000 a year upon the New York Stock Exchange
or in any other manner would be taxable only on 40 per cent of his net
income, or $40,000.”23 Why should speculators pay lower taxes than
everyone else?
Walsh proposed a solution. “If the benefits of this amendment are
limited to cases of the sale of capital assets which have been owned by
the taxpayer for a period of three years or more,” he suggested, relief
would be afforded to those who deserved it, “but the speculator will not
be included and will be forced to pay a tax upon his entire net income,
the same as every other taxpayer.” The idea of making speculators pay
the full tax received instant approval from Walsh’s colleagues, who quib-
bled only about how best to achieve that goal. Porter McCumber of
North Dakota proposed that the law should require full taxation only
of “speculative stocks and securities” and give preferential treatment to
all other capital gains. But this idea was shot down by Irvine Lenroot
of Wisconsin, who pointed out that it would be very difficult for the
296 Speculation
But taxing speculators more than investors was easier said than done,
because of the difficulty of drawing a clear line between speculation
and investment. On one side, there were repeated calls to lengthen the
required holding period on the ground that the existing period was so
short that it permitted speculators to get the advantage of the lower
rates, and there were frequent arguments for raising the rates on short-
term capital gains on the ground that higher rates were needed to deter
speculation. On the other side, there were repeated calls to shorten
the period and lower the rates, or even to exempt capital gains from
taxation completely, so as not to discourage investment.26 The age-old
debate over the distinction between investment and speculation had
become a debate over the capital gains tax.
In early 1945, for example, Federal Reserve Chair Marriner Eccles
proposed a sharp increase in the short- term capital gains rate, to
90 percent, and a lengthening of the holding period from six months
to two years, to tame wartime inflation. His proposal was aimed at
“speculation—not investment,” Eccles explained. It would “discour-
age all such speculative transactions, whether in homes, farms, stocks,
or commodities, and whether based upon credit or cash—and would
do so without interference with normal, non-speculative transactions.”
Eccles’s proposal aroused a storm of criticism. Taxing speculation would
not just be an ineffective way of reducing inflation, charged the econo-
mist Aaron Sakolski. It would also “stop progress,” because “without
speculation, would there be progress of any kind?” Barron’s, a business
newspaper, compared Eccles’s plan to a tax that had been imposed in
Nazi Germany.27 Eccles’s proposal was shelved.
Alongside these recurring political battles ran a long-standing debate
over a more fundamental question: was the distinction between short-
term and long-term holdings a sensible way to divide speculators from
investors? “There is nothing in accounting, in economics, or in fiscal
policy which justifies the distinction of speculation and investment on
26 Atlanta Constitution, 1 May 1929, 8; New York Times, 20 Jan. 1938, 1; 4 Jan. 1931,
N20; Wall Street Journal, 24 June 1931, 8; Chicago Daily Tribune, 18 Oct. 1935,
39; Daily Boston Globe, 27 Nov. 1936, 14; Wall Street Journal, 21 Mar. 1942, 3.
27 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 1 Mar. 1945, 963; 8 Mar. 1945, 1061; 1
Mar. 1945, 929, 943; Barron’s, 26 Mar. 1945, 5.
297
28 Revenue Revision of 1942: Hearings Before the Committee on Ways and Means,
House of Representatives, 75th Cong., 2nd Sess. (Washington, D.C.: Government
Printing Office, 1942), 1:944; Stanley S. Surrey, “Definitional Problems in
Capital Gains Taxation,” Harvard Law Review 69 (1956): 999–1000.
298
298 Speculation
living by stock transactions.” All others, the IBA argued, were investors
who deserved the lower rate.29
The standard response to such arguments was that the holding period,
while no doubt an imperfect way of distinguishing speculation from
investment, was the only feasible way. The economist Robert Murray
Haig noted that Weimar Germany had tried to distinguish specula-
tive from investment income on the basis of the taxpayer’s intent; if
he intended to speculate, he was a speculator. But this effort proved
impractical. “It led to vagueness, to debates between administrators and
taxpayers, and to litigation,” Haig recalled. After a few years, Germany
gave up. “In place of the vague test of ‘intent’ in the mind of the tax-
payer, appeared the definite test of the length of the time-period cov-
ered by the transaction,” Haig explained. In Germany, as in the United
States, “a speculation is a short-term transaction and an investment a
long-term venture.” The short-term/long-term distinction sometimes
produced anomalous results, acknowledged the New York tax lawyer
Peter Miller, but “the necessities of administration explain this anom-
aly.” Speculators differ from investors “only in state of mind and not in
easily recognizable overt behavior. If ‘the devil himself knoweth not the
thought of man,’ the Commissioner of Internal Revenue could hardly
be expected to.”30
There was little doubt, in any event, that the distinction between
short-term and long-term holdings mapped onto a widely held, if not
fully theorized, distinction in the public mind between speculators and
investors. When congressional committees tinkered with the length
of the holding period, they repeatedly explained that the holding pe-
riod’s purpose was “separating, in a practical way, speculative transac-
tions from investment transactions” (as a 1938 House report put it),
or to serve as “a sufficient deterrent to the speculator as contrasted
with the legitimate investor” (in the words of a 1942 Senate report).
“The underlying concept,” declared a 1976 report of Congress’s Joint
29 Herman T. Reiling, “Stock Transactions and the Income Tax,” Tax Magazine
10 (1932): 207; Los Angeles Times, 28 Nov. 1941, 29.
30 Wall Street Journal, 8 Apr. 1937, 4; Peter Miller, “The ‘Capital Asset’
Concept: A Critique of Capital Gains Taxation: I,” Yale Law Journal 59
(1950): 843.
299
Committee on Taxation, “is that a person who holds an asset for only a
short time is primarily interested in obtaining quick gains from short-
term market fluctuations, which is a distinctive speculative activity. In
contrast, the person who holds an asset for a long time probably is
interested fundamentally in the income from his investment and in the
long-term appreciation value.” All transactions involved an element of
investment and an element of speculation, conceded William Healy, a
federal judge in Idaho. But Healy, like many others, nevertheless per-
ceived a difference between the two. “The ‘in-and-out’ market hanger-
on who buys and sells through brokers on margin is a typical example
of the pure speculator,” he reasoned. “On the other hand, an investor is
ordinarily thought to be a person who acquires property for the income
it will yield rather than for the profit he hopes to obtain on a resale.”31
Of course, using the tax code to distinguish between speculation
and investment made sense only if there was a distinction between
speculation and investment, and opinion on that question was no
more settled than it had ever been. Beardsley Ruml, chairman of the
Macy’s department store company, thought “the discussion is some-
what confused by the use of the term speculation. It seems to me, as
an example, that at Macy’s when we buy some women’s dresses to sell
in six months or six weeks, that is speculation, if we want to use that
horrid term. What you have is buying and selling of things,” which was
the same no matter what name was attached to it. The Chicago Tribune
agreed that “the dividing line between investment and speculation is
often indistinct,” because even an ostensible investor hoped one day
to sell his investment for more than he had paid. “All investors are in-
terested in the probable price movements of their assets,” declared the
economist Lawrence Seltzer. “Like professional speculators, they try to
take future price movements into account in the prices at which they
buy and sell.”32 If investment and speculation were identical, there was
31 H.R. Rep. No. 1860, 75th Cong., 3rd Sess. (1938), 7; S. Rep. No. 1631, 77th
Cong., 2nd Sess. (1942), 50; Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation
of the Tax Reform Act of 1976 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office,
1976), 426; United States v. Chinook Inv. Co., 136 F.2d 984, 985 (9th Cir. 1943).
32 Capital Gains Taxation (New York: Tax Institute, 1946), 87–88; Chicago Daily
Tribune, 17 Nov. 1946, A11; Lawrence H. Seltzer, The Nature and Tax Treatment
300
300 Speculation
no reason to use the capital gains tax to encourage one and discourage
the other.
And even if speculation could be distinguished from investment,
there was always a considerable body of opinion that the two should be
treated identically, because speculation was just as good. In the 1950s,
Life magazine was willing to concede that speculation differed from in-
vestment, because “speculation is putting the desire for enhancement
ahead of the desire for generally predictable returns—for growth, rather
than dividends. It is the difference between buying Ford stock in 1903
and buying Standard Oil, whose success was already established; or be-
tween buying a uranium stock today and buying G.M.” But Life insisted
that speculation and investment should both be encouraged. “People
who are willing and able to take such risks enable new industries to get
born, and in that sense speculation is a social good,” the magazine rea-
soned. “In a very real sense, America grew great on speculation.”33
The use of the capital gains tax to encourage investment but dis-
courage speculation was also attacked on technical grounds, from both
directions. In the early years of the capital gains tax, critics charged
that differential tax rates had little influence on the conduct of either
investors or speculators, who had more important things to worry
about. “The operations of such individuals are … relatively insensi-
tive to capital gains tax provisions,” Treasury staff concluded in 1937.
“It must be emphasized that tax factors operate in practice among a
welter of other considerations, and that, by reason of this fact, they are
commonly robbed of a great deal of their force.” When the Twentieth
Century Fund studied the tax system at approximately the same
time, it likewise concluded that tax rates were unlikely to affect de-
cisions to buy or sell securities, decisions taxpayers would base solely
on their expectations as to future prices. If capital gains taxes did not
affect the conduct of speculators or investors, it would be pointless to
fiddle with rates as a means of deterring the former or encouraging
the latter. The Treasury could focus instead on raising revenue, a goal
34 “Tax Treatment of Capital Gains and Losses” (staff memo, Division of Tax
Research, Treasury Department, 1937), section V.A.2-3, http://www.taxhis-
tory.org/Civilization/Documents/Surveys/hst23731/23731-1.htm; Twentieth
Century Fund, Facing the Tax Problem: A Survey of Taxation in the United
States and a Program for the Future (New York: Twentieth Century Fund,
1937), 190; New York Times, 16 Feb. 1938, 20.
302
302 Speculation
him to sell the stock and buy it back at the same price thirty days later.
And this was just the beginning of a long list of clever transactions
savvy taxpayers engaged in, transactions with no purpose other than
taking advantage of the distinction between short-term and long-term
capital gains. “The dominant result of these interviews,” Stone con-
cluded, “appears to be that tax-saving manipulations are restricted to
a fairly limited group of large stockholders with ample cash reserves
who trade in substantial blocks of securities. This type of individual
has, in addition, sufficient time to discover the many available devices
and sufficient money to employ expert advice to inform him of these
possibilities.”35
One of those expert advisors was M. Francis Bravman, a tax lawyer
in New York and the chair of the American Bar Association’s committee
on income taxation. Bravman admitted that the structure of the capital
gains tax “places a very high premium on the use of devices to trans-
mute ordinary income into capital gains, or capital losses into ordinary
deductions, or short-term gains into long-term gains.” A great deal of
time, money, and intelligence was devoted to gaming the system, be-
cause “this approach to the taxation of capital gains has resulted in
a complicated federal income tax law, containing very tempting in-
centives for taxpayers to reduce their taxes.”36 If speculators could use
tricks to make themselves look like investors at tax time, there was no
point in trying to treat the two groups differently.
But all this criticism, from all these directions, had no discernible
effect on the apparently widespread belief that speculators should be
taxed more heavily than investors. Unlike the law of trusts, which aban-
doned as futile the effort to distinguish investment from speculation,
the tax law continues to draw a line between the capital gains of inves-
tors and those of speculators.
35 Goldie Stone, “How the Capital Gains Tax Affects Buying and Selling
Securities,” Taxes 26 (1948): 1041–48.
36 M. Francis Bravman, “Integration of Taxes on Capital Gains and Income,”
Virginia Law Review 37 (1951): 527–28.
╇ 303
37 Steven A. Bank, Kirk J. Stark, and Joseph J. Thorndike, War and Taxes
(Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 2008); 30 Stat. 448–╉70 (1898);
Nicol v. Ames, 173 U.S. 509, 516 (1899).
38 “Changes in the Tax Laws of New York State in 1905,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 20 (1905): 153; New York Times, 22 Apr. 1905, 10; Joseph J. Thorndike,
“Speculation and Taxation: Time for a Transaction Tax?” (2008), Tax History
Project Article Archive, http://╉www.taxhistory.org.
304
304 Speculation
say 1%, on all spot conversions of one currency into another.”40 The
idea was soon widely known as a “Tobin tax”—a tax intended to reduce
the number of transactions in a market thought to be too active, by
making the transactions substantially more expensive to carry out.
In the late 1980s, after a brief period of extraordinary volatility in
stock markets all over the world, including the largest one-day decline
in the history of the US market, several leading economists proposed a
similar tax on stock speculation. Joseph Stiglitz urged a tax “to discour-
age short-term speculative trading,” which he contended was the cause
of a wasteful arms race in which competing speculators made “excessive
expenditures on gathering information and on financial innovation.”
In Stiglitz’s view, “resources devoted to gambling—and to short-term
speculation in the stock market—could be devoted to more produc-
tive uses.” Lawrence Summers agreed that “the efficiency benefits of
curbing speculation are likely to exceed any costs of reduced liquidity
or increased costs of capital that come from taxing transactions more
heavily.” The Treasury Department contemplated proposing such a tax.
Members of Congress introduced narrower versions of a transaction
tax. A bill called the Excessive Churning and Speculation Act of 1989,
introduced by the two senators from Kansas, would have imposed a
10 percent tax on the gains of pension funds from the sale of assets
held for thirty days or less. Another bill introduced a few months later
would have barred pension funds from selling assets held for less than
three months. None of these proposed taxes was ever imposed, but the
idea of a tax to discourage stock speculation lingered on, to be debated
every few years by lawyers and economists.41
40 James Tobin, The New Economics One Decade Older (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press, 1974), 88– 89; see also James Tobin, “A Proposal for
International Monetary Reform,” Eastern Economic Journal 4 (1978): 153–59.
41 Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Using Tax Policy to Curb Speculative Short-Term Trading,”
Journal of Financial Services Research 3 (1989): 102– 3, 109; Lawrence H.
Summers and Victoria P. Summers, “When Financial Markets Work Too Well:
A Cautious Case for a Securities Transaction Tax,” Journal of Financial Services
Research 3 (1989): 263; Donald W. Kiefer, “The Security Transactions Tax: An
Overview of the Issues,” Tax Notes 48 (1990): 885; Joint Committee on Taxation,
Tax Treatment of Short-Term Trading (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing
Office, 1990), 8; Scott W. MacCormack, “A Critique of the Reemerging Securities
Transfer Excise Tax,” Tax Lawyer 44 (1991): 927–41; G. William Schwert and
306
306 Speculation
307
308
308 Speculation
regulatory jobs. Pass and enforce laws that put the American people
first, not banks and corporations.”1
These critics of the government were not experts. They were ordinary
citizens with strong opinions on financial regulation. As their com-
ments suggest, the financial crisis focused more public attention on
speculation than at any time since the Great Depression. Critiques of
speculation carried an even sharper edge this time, however, because
of the widely shared view that overspeculation was a direct result of
the deregulation of the financial markets. When Time magazine listed
the “25 people to blame for the financial crisis,” the list included Bill
Clinton, whom Time held responsible for “financial deregulation, which
in many ways set the stage for the excesses of recent years”; George
W. Bush, who “embraced a governing philosophy of deregulation”; and
Senator Phil Gramm, “Washington’s most prominent and outspoken
champion of financial deregulation.” It was a charge leveled over and
over again: overspeculation had once been contained by laws prohibit-
ing the most risky transactions, but those safeguards had been rashly re-
moved, and now we were all suffering the consequences. “Welcome to
the Third World!” smirked the law professor Rosa Brooks. “Policies of
irresponsible government deregulation” had produced “an energy crisis,
a housing crisis, a credit crisis and a financial market crisis, all at once,
and accompanied (and partly caused) by impressive levels of corruption
and speculation.”2
Critics saw deregulation as the triumph of ideology over common
sense. “The meltdown of the financial industry across the spectrum is
due to the failed economics of Milton Friedman–style, unstructured
capitalism,” insisted one newspaper columnist who had seen his re-
tirement account lose a third of its value. “Deregulation gives those
1 Comments 1373, 1338, 1379, 1358, 1378, 1380, and 1372 on Financial Stability
Oversight Council Notice 2010-0002, Public Input for the Study Regarding the
Implementation of the Prohibitions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Relationships
with Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds (Nov. 2010), available at http://www
.regulations.gov.
2 “25 People to Blame for the Financial Crisis,” Time, 11 Feb. 2009; Rosa Brooks,
“An Intervention Strategy for the U.S. Economic Mess,” L.A. Times, 18
Sept. 2008.
309
3 James Murr, “Financial Markets Must Be Regulated,” Santa Maria Times, 9 Jan.
2009; Jeanne Kirkton, “Financial Security Is National Security,” St. Louis Post-
Dispatch, 8 July 2011; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development,
The Global Economic Crisis: Systemic Failures and Multilateral Remedies (New
York and Geneva: United Nations, 2009), iii; The Financial Crisis Inquiry
Report (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 2011), xviii.
4 Lynn A. Stout, “Derivatives and the Legal Origin of the 2008 Credit Crisis,”
Harvard Business Law Review 1 (2011): 4; James Rickards, “Repeal of Glass-
Steagall Caused the Financial Crisis,” U.S. News & World Report, 27 Aug.
2012; Joseph E. Stiglitz, Freefall: America, Free Markets, and the Sinking of the
World Economy (New York: W. W. Norton, 2010), 163; Michael Hirsh, Capital
310
310 Speculation
Was it all true? What exactly had been deregulated, and why? And
what were the links between deregulation, speculation, and the finan-
cial crisis? Did deregulation give rise to unsafe levels of speculation? If
so, was speculation a cause of the crisis? Had we really forgotten the
lessons painfully learned in earlier depressions?
Badly€Burned
The idea of deregulating financial markets did not become a serious
possibility until the 1990s, by which time several other markets had
already undergone substantial and high-╉profile programs of deregula-
tion. Most of these programs yielded a similar pattern—╉greater com-
petition in the relevant industry, yielding enormous savings for con-
sumers and a correspondingly precarious position for producers and
their employees.
Perhaps the most conspicuous case was the airline industry. Before
1978, airfares and route changes had to be approved by a federal agency
called the Civil Aeronautics Board. The airlines were largely insulated
from price competition, so airfares were high and the airlines competed
instead to offer in-╉flight perks like food and drinks. Stephen Breyer,
who was counsel to the Senate Judiciary Committee in the 1970s, re-
called that when the committee held hearings about airline deregula-
tion, one of Senator Ted Kennedy’s constituents asked, “â•›‘Senator, why
are you holding hearings about airlines? I’ve never been able to fly.’
Kennedy replied: ‘That’s why I’m holding the hearings.’â•›” The move
toward deregulation began during the Ford administration and gained
momentum in 1977, when President Carter appointed the economist
Alfred Kahn as chair of the Civil Aeronautics Board. In the Airline
Deregulation Act of 1978, Congress ended the regulation of fares and
route changes. The airline industry was opened to competition.5
Offense: How Washington’s Wise Men Turned America’s Future Over to Wall Street
(Hoboken, N.J.: John Wiley & Sons, 2010).
5 Stephen G. Breyer, “Airline Deregulation, Revisited,” Bloomberg Businessweek,
20 Jan. 2011; Anthony E. Brown, The Politics of Airline Deregulation
(Knoxville: University of Tennessee Press, 1987).
311
The results were not surprising. Consumers were the net beneficia-
ries from competition, producers the net losers. Airfares declined dra-
matically, adjusted for inflation, which brought air travel within the
reach of millions of moderate-income passengers. This influx of new
price-conscious customers would itself cause some new problems, in-
cluding crowded airports and crowded planes, but there is little doubt
that on balance, deregulation increased consumer welfare. Not so for
the welfare of producers. Some airlines, unable to compete in the new
marketplace, went out of business. The surviving airlines had to cut
costs, which led to a decline in the wages of airline employees. But the
point of deregulation was to benefit consumers by forcing the airlines
to compete. From consumers’ point of view, the deregulation of the
airlines was a tremendous success.6
Similar events took place, with similar results, in several other markets
in ensuing years. Until 1980, trucking rates were set by “rate bureaus”
composed of trucking firms and overseen by the Interstate Commerce
Commission. The Motor Carrier Act of 1980 brought price competition
to trucking. “The purpose of the legislation is clear,” declared President
Jimmy Carter in his signing statement. “Protective and wasteful regula-
tions are to be replaced wherever possible by competition and the dis-
cipline of the free market. These changes will work to the benefit of all
consumers.” They did just that. Trucking prices declined steadily over
the ensuing decade. Gains to consumers were losses to trucking firms
and to truck drivers, whose wages underwent a corresponding decline.7
But that was precisely the purpose of deregulation—to subject produc-
ers to price competition, for the benefit of consumers.
312 Speculation
The railroad industry was also deregulated, in the Staggers Rail Act
of 1980. Price competition among railroads benefited consumers by re-
ducing the cost of shipping goods by rail. Some railroad lines went out
of business because they were unable to compete, and the surviving
railroads paid lower wages than they had before. Markets in telephone
service and natural gas were also opened to price competition during
this period, with broadly similar results.8
The lesson seemed to be that elementary economics was exactly
right. Regulatory schemes dating back to the 1930s insulated produc-
ers from competition. Deregulation forced these firms to compete on
price, which made life more difficult for the firms and their employ-
ees, but which yielded enormous benefits for consumers. Finance was
one more heavily regulated industry, also dating back to the 1930s. The
consumers of finance were investors on one side and enterprises seek-
ing investment on the other; the producers were the banks, the stock
exchanges, and the various other intermediaries between the two. The
experience of deregulation in the last quarter of the twentieth century
suggested that here, too, deregulation could facilitate competition
among producers and thus gains for consumers.
The period was one in which economic conditions were unusually
conducive to this view. Between the early 1980s and the late 2000s,
the volatility of economic activity declined quite sharply. Virtually
every aggregate measure— output, employment, inflation— became
much more stable than it had ever been. The business cycle seemed
to have nearly disappeared. By 2002, economists were speaking of a
“Great Moderation” that was taking place, not just in the United States
but throughout the industrialized world. The “problem of depression
prevention has been solved,” declared the Nobel Prize winner Robert
Lucas. Ben Bernanke, then one of the governors of the Federal Reserve
System, was only slightly less triumphant. He cited “the increased depth
and sophistication of financial markets, deregulation in many indus-
tries, the shift away from manufacturing toward services, and increased
openness to trade and international capital flows,” along with “better
monetary policy,” as causes of what appeared to be a permanently stable
economy.9
One persistent (although persistently disputed) rationale for limit-
ing speculation had always been that speculators amplified the busi-
ness cycle—that they made the highs even higher and the lows even
lower. But if the business cycle was no longer such a serious problem,
this rationale was no longer as important. The Great Moderation thus
contributed to an intellectual climate receptive to deregulating finan-
cial markets, by weakening one of the traditional arguments for regula-
tion. As the federal judge Richard Posner observed in his autopsy of the
crisis, deregulation “was a government failure abetted by the political
and ideological commitments of mainstream economists, who over-
looked the possibility that the financial markets seemed robust because
regulation had prevented previous financial crises.”10
The intellectual climate of the late twentieth century was also in-
fluenced by a view of financial markets called the efficient market
hypothesis. Here we need to be careful, because there is a mis-
understanding of the efficient market hypothesis that pervades
much of the post–financial crisis critique of deregulation and that
314 Speculation
ascribes too much direct causal force to the EMH.11 In correcting this
mistake, however, it would be equally wrong to deny any connection
between the EMH and one’s view as to the propriety of regulation.
The point that deserves emphasis is that this connection was more dif-
fuse and perhaps even more emotional than is usually acknowledged.
The efficient market hypothesis simply states that the prices in a
capital market (such as a stock market) fully reflect all available rel-
evant information. The implication is that investing in stocks chosen
by so-called experts will be no more profitable than investing in stocks
chosen at random. The EMH was a staple of the academic literature by
the early 1970s. Since then it has been criticized, defended, and restated
in various forms, but in all versions it is an empirical claim about how
quickly new information affects the prices of securities.12 The EMH is
not a normative claim that markets are good or that regulation is bad.
This point was sometimes lost in the aftermath of the financial
crisis, when critics blamed the efficient market hypothesis for caus-
ing regulators to fall asleep at the wheel. “The upside of the current
Great Recession is that it could drive a stake through the heart of the
academic nostrum known as the efficient-market hypothesis,” thun-
dered the journalist Roger Lowenstein. “The mistaken faith in mar-
kets turned regulators into fawning groupies.” The investor Jeremy
Grantham insisted that the efficient market hypothesis “left our eco-
nomic and government establishment sitting by confidently, even as
a lethally dangerous combination of asset bubbles, lax controls, per-
nicious incentives and wickedly complicated instruments led to our
current plight.”13 This sort of criticism is misdirected, if taken liter-
ally. The efficient market hypothesis has no necessary relationship to
11 For a forceful expression of this view, see Ray Ball, “The Global Financial
Crisis and the Efficient Market Hypothesis: What Have We Learned?,” Journal
of Applied Corporate Finance 21, no. 4 (2009): 8–16.
12 Eugene F. Fama, “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical
Work,” Journal of Finance 25 (1970): 383– 417; Burton G. Malkiel, “The
Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its Critics,” Journal of Economic Perspectives
17 (2003): 59–82.
13 Roger Lowenstein, “Book Review: ‘The Myth of the Rational Market,’ ”
Washington Post, 7 June 2009; Joe Nocera, “Poking Holes in a Theory on
Markets,” New York Times, 6 June 2009.
315
the appropriate level of regulation. One can believe that stock prices
incorporate all available information and simultaneously believe that
certain transactions should not be allowed, for any of the reasons
conventionally offered for prohibiting transactions. For example, an
adherent of the EMH can still favor limits on speculating with bor-
rowed money, on the ground that highly leveraged transactions are too
risky, whether for individual speculators or for the financial system as
a whole. To call the market “efficient” is merely to say that stock prices
cannot be predicted; the term does not imply that whatever we observe
in the market must be good.
On the other hand, there is a less direct relationship between the effi-
cient market hypothesis and one’s attitude toward financial regulation,
one that may have facilitated deregulation. The EMH implies that if in-
vestors have no way of knowing whether prices are too high or too low,
neither do regulators. There is no way to identify a bubble while it is
occurring, or even afterward—the best one can say is that prices at the
peak reflected the information available at the peak, and prices at the
trough reflected the information available at the trough. When it comes
to prices, regulators are no wiser than investors. A person accustomed
to thinking of markets in this way can easily grow skeptical that regula-
tors will be any wiser than investors when it comes to other matters,
like whether investors have taken on too much risk, or whether inves-
tors fully understand the securities they are buying. Attitudes toward
regulation are based on moods or general feelings as much as on careful
analyses of the pros and cons of particular regulatory programs. This
point obviously should not be taken too far. There were booms and
crashes, and arguments for and against regulation, long before anyone
thought of the efficient market hypothesis. The EMH did not cause the
financial crisis or even any of the legal developments that preceded it.
But the EMH may have helped to propagate a mood that was condu-
cive to deregulation.
There was considerable weakening, at the same time, in Americans’
traditional moral disapproval of gambling. In the 1970s, casino gambling
was lawful only in Nevada, but by the end of the century there were
casinos in nearly half the states and on many Indian reservations as well.
At midcentury there were no state-run lotteries, but by the century’s end
almost every state ran a lottery. Denunciations of speculative financial
316
316 Speculation
14 These figures come from the triennial reports published by the Bank for
International Settlements. They are available at the bank’s website, http://www
.bis.org.
317
the risk that prices would change between one time period and another.
The new derivatives allowed companies to hedge all sorts of other risks,
like changes in currency exchange rates, changes in interest rates, or
even bad weather. For example, a firm that had to make investments
in the present in one currency but expected future revenue in a differ-
ent currency could enter into a derivative contract that would allow
it to remove the risk of loss from an adverse change in the exchange
rate between the two currencies, by paying a counterparty to absorb
that risk. A firm with obligations to pay debt at a variable interest rate
but with expected income at a fixed rate could enter into a derivative
contract that would allow it, in effect, to convert its variable interest to
fixed interest, by swapping debt obligations with a counterparty will-
ing to absorb the risk of adverse changes in the variable interest rate.
Unlike the older, simpler derivatives, which had been standard con-
tracts traded on exchanges, the new derivatives tended to be custom
tailored to the needs of each individual purchaser and were thus not
traded on exchanges. But they served the same hedging purpose as the
older derivatives, by allowing parties to transfer risk, for a price, to
those willing to bear it.
And, as with the older derivatives, the hedgers were only part of the
market. It would be quite a coincidence if a firm wishing to hedge a
particular risk could find another firm that simultaneously wished to
hedge an equal and opposite risk, so the hedger’s counterparty in these
transactions was normally not a hedger but a speculator—someone
willing to take on risk in the expectation of making a profit. And many
transactions involved no hedgers at all, but rather speculators on both
sides, who simply had different expectations of what the future would
bring.15 The new derivatives, like the old, thus opened up new methods
of speculation.
As always, with new methods of speculation came new ways of
making or losing large sums of money very quickly. Startling stories
of massive losses from trading in derivatives, sometimes incurred by
318 Speculation
320 Speculation
22 See, e.g., Joseph Karl Grant, “What the Financial Services Industry Puts
Together Let No Person Put Asunder: How the Gramm-╉Leach-╉Bliley Act
Contributed to the 2008–2009 American Capital Markets Crisis,” Albany Law
Review 73 (2010): 371–╉420.
23 Clinton’s signing statement at http://╉www.presidency.ucsb.edu/╉ws/╉?pid=56922.
321
322 Speculation
Act was ratifying changes that had already taken place more than it
was actually making any change. “The Glass-Steagall Act was already a
dead letter when Gramm-Leach-Bliley was passed,” concluded the law
professor Jonathan Macey. “All the Act did was formalize the death.”25
Back in the early 1930s, much of the motivation for the Glass-Steagall
Act had been the cascade of bank failures, many of which contempo-
raries attributed to speculation. By the late twentieth century, banks
still failed, but bank failures had lost their sharp edge because of the
advent of deposit insurance. Losses from bank failures were now borne
by the banking system generally and by the government rather than by
the particular depositors unfortunate enough to have entrusted their
funds to a now-insolvent bank. In 1933, bank depositors were keen to
keep their money from being sent in risky directions. In 1999, they were
no longer as worried.
Because the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act was the culmination of incre-
mental changes rather than a major change in its own right, it makes
sense to ask, not whether the act itself contributed to the financial
crisis, but whether the crisis was facilitated by the gradual reblending
of commercial and investment banking. The answer is almost certainly
no. The Glass-Steagall Act would not have prevented any banks from
making subprime mortgage loans, investing in mortgage-backed se-
curities, or being so highly leveraged that a small drop in the value
of their assets would wipe them out. The activities that commercial
banks were newly allowed to enter were not the ones that lost them
vast sums of money. And many of the financial institutions that lost the
324 Speculation
financial crisis, although it is not clear that “deregulation” is the right word
for these changes, and even here the connection to the financial crisis is
uncertain.
In the 1980s, when the new derivatives became commercially signifi-
cant, transactions in derivatives were still largely governed by the legal
framework established in the 1920s, when the main derivatives were
options and futures relating to agricultural commodities. The Grain
Futures Act of 1922 had been replaced by the Commodity Exchange
Act of 1936, but both statutes essentially required derivatives to be
traded on organized exchanges approved by the federal government.
Many states still had their anti–bucket shop laws on the books, and
in principle the common law of every state still rendered unenforce-
able all off-exchange transactions in which the parties did not actually
intend the delivery of a physical commodity. In practice, though, state
law largely fell by the wayside after the enactment of the Commodity
Exchange Act, which created an administrative agency, the Commodity
Exchange Authority (later replaced by the Commodity Futures Trading
Commission), charged with overseeing derivative trading nationwide.
At first, the new derivatives of the 1980s occupied an uncertain
position within this legal framework.28 They tended to be tailored to
individual circumstances rather than being standardized products, so
they were not traded on exchanges. Did that make them unlawful? In
swap transactions, for example, parties exchanged future cash flows.
“The economic reality of swaps,” the CFTC observed, “resembles that
of futures contracts.” But were they futures contracts? If so, they were
illegal if they were not traded on an exchange, and they were subject
to the full array of CFTC regulation. In 1989, the CFTC determined
that swaps were not futures contracts so long as, among other things,
their terms were individually tailored and they were entered into “in
conjunction with a line of business”—that is, they were limited to
hedgers and financial institutions. The CFTC declared that it would
28 This discussion compresses and simplifies an intricate story; for more details,
see Philip McBride Johnson and Thomas Lee Hazen, Derivatives Regulation
(New York: Aspen, 2004), 1:50–85.
325
not regulate such transactions.29 In later years the CFTC would issue
similar determinations for other new kinds of derivatives.
But that only raised a new question. If the new derivatives were not
subject to CFTC regulation, did that mean they were governed by state
law instead? Could a state court condemn them as gambling transac-
tions in violation of state anti–bucket shop statutes or the common-law
prohibition on contracts without intent to deliver? Congress ended this
uncertainty three years later, by declaring that federal law in this area
preempted state law. The Futures Trading Practices Act of 1992 pro-
vided that derivatives were not subject to “any State or local law that
prohibits or regulates gaming or the operation of ‘bucket shops.’ ”30 The
new derivatives had cleared the last legal hurdle.
Some government officials were uncomfortable with allowing un-
fettered derivatives trading. In 1994, on the same day that Procter
& Gamble announced it had lost $157 million in swaps, the House
Banking Committee held hearings on the topic. The purchaser of a
derivative is “entering into a gamble,” worried Representative Henry
Gonzalez of Texas, the committee chair. “I picture it as an inverted
pyramid where the apex is a basic nominal value and then derived up
to this tremendous base are offshoots of all these formidable definitions
and forms of derivatives.” As Gonzalez saw the new market, participants
were not profiting “in the usual financial term of things, but by out and
out gambling.” He foresaw “the possibility of a giant, global, electronic
Ponzi” that one day would come crashing down. The financier George
Soros shared Gonzalez’s concern. “Some of those instruments appear to
be specifically designed to enable institutional investors to take gambles
which they would not otherwise be permitted to take,” he explained.
“For example, some bond funds have invested in synthetic bond issues
which carry a tenfold or twentyfold multiple of the normal risk within
defined limits. And some other instruments offer exceptional returns
because they carry the seeds of a total wipeout.” If a meltdown were
to occur, Soros noted, “the regulatory authorities may find themselves
obliged to step in to preserve the integrity of the system. It is in that
326 Speculation
light that the authorities have both the right and an obligation to su-
pervise and regulate derivative instruments.”31
Within the Clinton administration, the leading voice in favor of reg-
ulation was the Washington lawyer Brooksley Born, who was chair of
the CFTC between 1996 and 1999. Born repeatedly urged greater gov-
ernment oversight of the ballooning derivatives market, particularly the
idea of requiring buyers and sellers of derivatives to make disclosures of
their financial positions so their counterparties would be able to evalu-
ate their creditworthiness. “No reporting requirements are imposed
on most OTC derivatives market participants,” she observed shortly
after the collapse of Long Term Capital Management, in a speech that
would look quite prescient a decade later. “This lack of basic informa-
tion about the positions held by OTC derivatives users and about the
nature and extent of their exposures potentially allows OTC derivatives
market participants to take positions that may threaten our regulatory
markets or, indeed, our economy without the knowledge of any fed-
eral regulatory authority.”32 But Born’s view was not shared by senior
government economic officials, including Treasury Secretary Robert
Rubin and Federal Reserve Chair Alan Greenspan, who believed that
market participants already had every incentive to evaluate their coun-
terparties’ creditworthiness. “Individuals who lend money to others,”
Greenspan responded, “have a very important interest in getting that
money back.”33
Instead, the Clinton administration went in the opposite direction.
The President’s Working Group on Financial Markets, made up of
Greenspan, Lawrence Summers (Rubin’s successor as Treasury secretary),
William Rainer (Born’s successor as CFTC chair), and Arthur Levitt
(the chair of the Securities and Exchange Commission), concluded
31 Risks That Hedge Funds Pose to the Banking System: Hearing Before the Committee
on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs (Washington, D.C.: Government
Printing Office, 1994), 14, 38.
32 Richard B. Schmitt, “The Born Prophecy,” ABA Journal, May 2009, 50–55;
Brooksley Born, “The Lessons of Long-Term Capital Management L.P.” (Oct.
15, 1998), http://www.cftc.gov/opa/speeches/opaborn-37.htm. “OTC” stands
for “over the counter”—that is, not traded on an exchange.
33 Greenspan quoted in Sebastian Mallaby, More Money Than God: Hedge Funds
and the Making of a New Elite (New York: Penguin, 2010), 245.
327
328 Speculation
mortgage market, the lending might well have tapered off sooner, so
the crisis might not have been as severe. And when the housing bubble
burst, the firms facing insolvency were not just the banks that held
mortgage loans. Equally imperiled were a host of other institutions that
held derivatives linked to those loans, derivatives that had not existed
in previous housing bubbles. Speculation in derivatives thus may have
made the crisis more pervasive than it would otherwise have been.
After the crisis, some urged the prohibition of derivatives that are
used primarily for speculation (in the sense that they are bought and
sold because market participants have different expectations about the
future) rather than for some other purpose such as hedging. As the title
of one such effort put it, trading in such derivatives was simply “gam-
bling by another name.”37 “Financial products are socially beneficial
when they help people insure risks,” reasoned one pair of authors, “but
when those same products are used for gambling they can instead be
socially detrimental.” After earlier market downturns, critics had like-
wise urged that new financial products should be banned. Defenders
of the market had always responded by pointing out how difficult it
would be to distinguish the harmful transactions from the beneficial
ones. The most recent crisis once again elicited these arguments. Would
it even be possible for government officials to distinguish trading moti-
vated by hedging from trading motivated by differences in beliefs about
the future? Were purely speculative traders necessary to make a market
for traders wishing to hedge, in the same way that insurance would
be impossible to buy without the existence of insurance companies?
Were hedgers actually distinct entities from speculators, or did hedgers
330 Speculation
38 Posner and Weyl, “An FDA for Financial Innovation,” 1308; Darrell Duffie,
“Challenges to a Policy Treatment of Speculative Trading Motivated by
Differences in Beliefs,” Journal of Legal Studies 43 (2014): S173–82; Ing-Haw
Cheng and Wei Xiong, “Why Do Hedgers Trade So Much?,” Journal of Legal
Studies 43 (2014): S183–207.
331
q i n de x
331
332
332 Index
Catchings, Waddill, 196–7 credit default swaps, 235, of the late 1830s, 13,
caveat emptor, 247–53, 266–7 319, 328 23, 283
Chambers, Charles, 177 Crèvecoeur, Hector St. of 1907, 110, 144
Chase, Salmon, 7, 54 John de, 30 of 1929–33, 164–217
Chevalier, Michel, 7–8 Crissinger, Daniel, 167 of 2007–10, 233,
Chiarella v. United States, 275 Curtin, Andrew, 6 235–40, 307–30
Chicago Board of Trade Curtis, Ezra, 286 Edwards, J.R., 173
agrarian opposition to, Custer, George, 72 efficient market hypothesis,
83–5, 105–37 313–5
campaign against bucket Dana, Francis, 48 Egan, Martin, 170
shops of, 96–103 Dane, Nathan, 250 Eliot, Robert, 124
formation of, 66 Danforth, Charles, 81–2 Ely, Richard, 112, 227
self-regulation by, 91–2, 178 Danforth, George, 254–5 Emergency Home Finance Act
speculation on, 56–8, Davis, C. Wood, 113, 126 of 1970, 234–5
76–7, 81–2 Dean, Arthur, 189, 205 Emerson, Ralph Waldo, 28–9
Christie, C.C., 96 Defoe, Daniel, 62 Emery, Henry Crosby, 131–2
Citron, Robert, 318 Deming, William, 207 Ernst, Daniel, 201
Civil War, speculation during, Denison, Edward, 162–3 Erskine, Thomas, 16
6–7, 52–4, 165 Denslow, Van Buren, 133
Clark, John Bates, 144 Depository Institutions Federal Home Loan Bank Act
Clark, R.C., 120 Deregulation and of 1932, 234
Clews, Henry, 141, 257 Monetary Control Act of Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Clinton, Bill, 308, 320 1980, 237 Corporation, 235
Cobbett, William, 15 depressions. See economic Federal National
Cochran, John, 195 downturns Mortgage Association,
Cohen, Benjamin, 188, 201 deregulation, 307–30 234–5
collateralized debt obligations, derivatives, 316–20, 324–9 Fessenden, William, 54
235, 238 Dew, Thomas, 13 Fidler, Isaac, 8
Commodity Futures Dewey, T. Henry, 78 Financial Crisis Inquiry
Modernization Act of Dickson, Frederick, 97 Commission, 309
2000, 309, 323, 327 Dirks v. S.E.C., 276 Findley, William, 26
Commodity Futures Trading Disney, John, 40 Fisher, Irving, 166
Commission, 324–26 Dix, John, 28 Fitch, Walter, 118
Conant, Charles, 112, 144 Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, Fletcher, Duncan, 180
Cone, Solomon, 125 239–40, 323, 328 Flexner, Bernard, 193
Connely, E.F., 215 Dolley, Joseph, 138–40, Flint, Walter, 157
Cook, Donald, 145–9, 153–4 Florida land boom, 218–24
265, 269 Dos Passos, John, 73 Flynn, John T., 171, 213
Cook, William, 255 Douglas, Michael, 277 Foote, Ira, 56–9
Cooley, Thomas, 80 Douglas, William O., 183, 190, Forbes, Allan, 174
Cooper, Thomas, 249 201–2, 204 Foss, H.A., 123
Corbet, Thomas, 32 Drummond, Thomas, 70 Foster, Benjamin, 13
Corcoran, Thomas, 188, 201 du Pont, Alfred, 184 Foster, George, 14
Cotton Futures Act of Duff, E.A., 118 Frank, Jerome, 190,
1914, 134–5 Dunlap, M.L., 83–4 200, 202–4
Coulson, Barbara, 307 Dwight, Timothy, 23 Frankfurter, Felix, 188–9,
Counselman, Charles, 121 192, 193
Couzens, James, 168 Eccles, Marriner, 296 Frazer v. Gervais, 247
Cowan, Edgar, 53–4 Eckles, A.H., 212 Frederick, J. George, 176
Cowdin, J. Cheever, 271–2 economic downturns Freeman, Milton, 201, 268
Coxe, Tench, 20 of 1792, 13, 23, 35, 43, French, D.E., 225
crashes. See economic 45, 165 Freneau, Philip, 18
downturns of 1819, 13, 23 Friedman, Elisha, 297
333
Index 333
334 Index
Index 335