Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

CBFL Rep 2301 RPhang AAzzutti

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 56

Banking, Finance and Technology Conference

NUS Faculty of Law


18th – 19th May 2023

Collection of Selected Presentation Summaries

Compiled by:

Rachel Phang
Research Associate
CBFL, NUS Law

Alessio Azzutti
Research Associate
CBFL, NUS Law

[CBFL-Rep-2301]
July 2023

This collection is based on the proceedings of the Banking, Finance and Technology
Conference organised by the Centre for Banking & Finance Law, and held on 18th – 19th May
2023. The views expressed in this report reflect the authors’ personal opinions and do not
necessarily reflect the policies or views of the Centre for Banking & Finance Law.
Centre for Banking & Finance Law
Faculty of Law
National University of Singapore
Eu Tong Sen Building
469G Bukit Timah Road
Singapore 259776
Tel: (65) 6601 3878
Fax: (65) 6779 0979
Email: cbfl@nus.edu.sg

http://law.nus.edu.sg/cbfl/

The Centre for Banking & Finance Law (CBFL) at the Faculty of Law, National University of
Singapore, focuses broadly on legal and regulatory issues relating to banking and financial
services. It aims to produce research and host events of scholarly value to academics as well as
of policy relevance to the banking and financial services community. In particular, CBFL seeks
to engage local and international bankers, lawyers, regulators and academics in regular
exchanges of ideas and knowledge so as to contribute towards the development of law and
regulation in this area, as well as to promote a robust and stable financial sector in Singapore,
the region and globally.

2
Table of Contents

I. The Nature of Property in Cryptoassets


Mr Timothy Chan (National University of Singapore).................................................. 4
II. The Regulation of Crypto-Lending
Dr Alexandros Seretakis (Trinity College Dublin) ........................................................ 9
III. Insolvency of Crypto-Asset Service Providers: Legal Problems and Regulatory
Responses
Mr Ilya Kokorin (Leiden University) .......................................................................... 12
IV. A Framework for the Interoperability of CBDCs
Dr Kosmas Kaprinis (Binance/IE University) ............................................................. 16
V. Regulating DeFi and On-Chain CeFi: Centralisation Points as Regulatory Hooks
Dr Ann Sofie Cloots (University of Cambridge) ......................................................... 20
VI. A Multi-Layered Framework of AI Governance in China’s Finance Sector
Ms Jinghe Fan (University of Oxford) and Dr Xin Zhang (University of International
Business and Economics) ............................................................................................ 25
VII. Financial Regulation and the Advent of Digital Reporting: The End of Rule-Use
as We Know It?
Dr Andromachi Georgosouli (Queen Mary University of London) ............................ 31
VIII. Challenges Posed by the Second Generation of Digital Technologies to Financial
Regulatory Strategies
Dr Teresa Rodríguez de las Heras Ballell (Universidad Carlos III de Madrid)........... 35
IX. AI in Credit Lending and Enforcement Decision-Making by Banks: Accuracy,
Risk, Data and Consumer Protection
Dr Jeannie Marie Paterson (University of Melbourne)................................................ 42
X. At the Crossroads Where Robo-advisers Stand
Mr Selwyn Lim (Syfe) ................................................................................................. 48
XI. Payment Fraud and Consumer Protection
Dr Sandra Booysen (National University of Singapore) ............................................. 53

3
I. The Nature of Property in Cryptoassets1

Mr Timothy Chan
(National University of Singapore)

Most courts2 and commentators3 agree that cryptoassets are property. However, in order
to develop that conclusion further, two important questions must be answered. First, why
should cryptoassets be regarded as property? And second, how do property rules operate when
it comes to cryptoassets? This presentation explores how we should approach the second
question. As it proceeds on the basis that cryptoassets are property, it will not explore why they
should be regarded as property.4 It focuses on the mechanics rather than the justification of
property in cryptoassets, which are important for various private law aspects of property in
cryptoassets in both the contexts of two-party and three-party disputes.

It may be helpful to begin with a brief recap of how blockchain transactions are
executed.5 The blockchain is a decentralised ledger maintained by nodes which keep track of
user balances and validate transactions for crypto rewards (‘mining’). To send 1 BTC to B, for
example, A sends an instruction to the network. The first node to receive the instruction verifies
that (i) A’s balance is sufficient; and A’s signature is valid. The transaction then enters a pool
of pending transactions where it awaits inclusion within a new ‘block’. Once done, the answer
forms part of the blockchain and the transaction is ‘confirmed’. Importantly, nodes do not
undertake an obligation to validate any particular transactions—mining is a self-interested
process designed to earn Bitcoin rewards and the process is fundamentally extra-contractual.

What is the ‘thing’ or ‘res’ that is the subject-matter of property rights in cryptoassets,
considering that neither a physical ‘thing’ nor a contractual counterparty can be identified? One
option, proposed by David Fox6 and the Law Commission,7 conceives of the res as a ‘data
string’ or ‘data structure’, which should be treated as an exception to the rule that information

1
This summary is based on a forthcoming paper, which may be cited as Timothy Chan ‘The Nature of Property
in Cryptoassets’ (2023) Legal Studies (forthcoming), https://doi.org/10.1017/lst.2022.53.
2
See, e.g., CLM v CLN [2022] 5 SLR 273; Janesh s/o Rajkumar v Unknown Person (“CHEFPIERRE”) [2022]
SGHC 264; Piroozzadeh v Persons Unknown and ors [2023] EWHC 1024 (Ch); Re Gatecoin Limited [2023]
HKCFI 91.
3
See, e.g., Michael Bridge et al. (eds) The Law of Personal Property (London: Sweet and Maxwell, 3rd edn,
2022), para 8-050; D Fox ‘Cryptocurrencies in the common law of property’ in D Fox and S Green (eds)
Cryptocurrencies in Public and Private Law (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2019); Kelvin FK Low and Ernie
GS Teo ‘Bitcoins and other cryptocurrencies as property?’ (2017) 9(2) Law, Innovation and Technology 235.
4
For some comments, see Timothy Chan and Kelvin FK Low ‘DeFi Common Sense: Crypto-backed Lending in
Janesh s/o Rajkumar v Unknown Person (“CHEFPIERRE”)’ (2023) Modern Law Review (forthcoming), 5–9,
https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2230.12804.
5
See Chan (n 1) 3–5 and the references cited there.
6
David Fox ‘Digital assets as transactional power’ (2022) 1 Journal of International Banking and Financial Law
3.
7
Law Commission Consultation Paper on Digital Assets Law Com No 256, 28 July 2022, ch 10.
T. CHAN

is not property,8 insofar as it has the particular functionality of allowing the user to effect
transactions on a blockchain network. But some difficulties should be noted.9 First, it is not
clear how such ‘data’ can be identified in different accounting systems (while it might be
possible in unspent transaction output (UTXO)-based systems such as Bitcoin, it seems
difficult in account-based systems, such as Ethereum). More importantly, framing data as the
res seems inconsistent with the idea of proprietary exclusion, since the data has to be publicly
available on the blockchain. And third, it is hard to explain why, after a cryptoasset is ‘spent’,
it ceases to be property. On another view, proposed by Kelvin Low and Ernie Teo, the res is a
legal right of cryptoasset holders to have their cryptoassets ‘locked to their chosen public
bitcoin address on the blockchain’.10 But what is the legal basis for this right? As there is no
contractual or statutory basis, it must be a claim that the courts should recognise a new right,
as they did with common law copyright in the 18th century.11 Even then, the corresponding duty
must be a duty of non-interference, which seems better analysed as an incident of property
rather than an item of property itself.12

Perhaps the better approach is to return to first principles. Most Commonwealth


property scholars agree that property is about some combination of exclusionary control and a
power of alienation.13 What is the ‘thing’ that cryptoasset users seek to exclude others from by
protecting their private keys, and ‘transfer’ through blockchain transactions? I suggest that it
is a factual ‘transactional ability’—an ability to effect a blockchain transaction (with the
specific assets held at that public address) that will be recognised as valid under the relevant
consensus algorithm.14 It may seem unusual to regard an essentially factual ability as an item
of property. But there is in fact precedent for this: goodwill, defined as the ‘benefit and
advantage of the good name, reputation, and connection of a business’,15 is recognised as a
type of property,16 albeit an unusual one. A state of reputation is essentially a state of factual
recognition (or consensus), and the proposed ‘transactional ability’ is precisely an ability to
change a state of consensus on the blockchain network. This conception accommodates various

8
Your Response v Datateam [2014] EWCA Civ 281.
9
See Chan (n 1) 9–10.
10
See Low and Teo (n 3).
11
In Millar v Taylor (1769) 4 Burr 2301. See Kelvin FK Low, ‘Cryptoassets and the Renaissance of the Tertium
Quid?’ in Chris Bevan (ed), Edward Elgar Handbook on Property Law and Theory (forthcoming),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4382599.
12
See Chan (n 1) at 11–12.
13
See, e.g., Bridge et al. (n 3) para 1-006.
14
See Chan (n 1) 6–9.
15
Commissioners of Inland Revenue v Muller and Co’s Margarine Ltd [1901] AC 217 at 223–224.
16
See, e.g., Harrods Ltd v Harrovian School Ltd [1996] RPC 697 at 711 per Millett LJ; Spalding (AG) and Bros
v AW Gamage Ltd (1915) 32 RPC 273 (HL) at 284 per Lord Parker; Star Industrial v Yap Kwee Kor [1976] FSR
256 (PC) at 269 per Lord Diplock.

5
T. CHAN

types of cryptoassets, both first- and second-layer, and explains various practical aspects of
property in cryptoassets, such as what happens when a private key is irretrievably lost.17

Another key issue is the characterisation of blockchain transactions: do such


transactions amount to true legal ‘transfers’, or are they events by which the original asset
(conceptualised as a transactional ability or otherwise) is extinguished, and a new asset created
(which we may call a ‘res-creating’ event)? If the latter, which is generally thought to be the
case with bank transfers,18 then traditional rules of title transfer such as nemo dat probably
would not apply.19 This led the UK Jurisdiction Taskforce to the unpalatable conclusion that
where cryptoassets are stolen, nemo dat would not apply.20 Factually, at least, whether an event
is ‘res-transferring’ or ‘res-creating’ depends on the ‘thing’ being transferred. On Fox’s ‘data
centric’ view and the present view that the res is a transactional ability, the relevant ‘function’
or ‘ability’ is rendered ‘spent’ and extinguished upon each blockchain transaction. On Low’s
view that the res is a ‘right to a registry entry’, no such issues arise—the right is a legal
construct, so whether it is ‘transferred’ need not take reference from the factual mechanism of
the transaction. I argue, however, that whether a true ‘transfer’ has occurred should be treated
as a normative rather than a factual question.21 The best analogy is with chattels which go
through a process of manufacture, where the suggested test is whether the raw materials and
the product are economically identical.22 This ‘economic identity’ test is suitable for the context
of intangibles because they cannot be physically enjoyed; importantly, it also explains why
bank transfers are new items of property, since each bank account is governed by different sets
of terms and conditions with the counterparty bank. In the crypto context, there is no
counterparty and each transactional ability is economically identical. I suggest this provides a
strong basis to regard blockchain transactions as true ‘transfers’, rather than ‘res-creating’
events.

I argue that the foregoing analysis provides principled grounds for extending to
cryptoassets existing rules of title transfer which presently apply to chattels. There are two
important similarities between the two. First, and most importantly, blockchain transactions as
true ‘transfers’ are different from bank transfers, where nemo dat does not apply. Second,
control of cryptoassets via a private key is programmed to be both rivalrous and transferable.

17
See Chan (n 1) 8.
18
R v Preddy [1996] AC 815.
19
Cf Trustee of the Property of FC Jones and Sons v Jones [1997] Ch 159; Ben McFarlane and Robert Stevens
‘The nature of equitable property’ (2010) 4 Journal of Equity 1 at 22; Lionel Smith ‘Simplifying claims to traceable
proceeds’ (2009) 125 LQR 338 at 347.
20
UK Jurisdictional Taskforce Legal Statement on Cryptoassets and Smart Contracts, November 2019, para 47.
21
See Chan (n 1) 12–17.
22
Duncan Webb ‘Title and transformation: who owns manufactured goods?’ (2000) Journal of Business Law 513
at 523.

6
T. CHAN

As Fox has pointed out,23 this makes such control functionally similar to the possession of
tangible assets. A transfer of legal title to cryptoassets therefore probably requires both an
intention to transfer and some proxy to delivery (a transfer of the private key itself or, more
commonly, a blockchain transaction).24 Further, where a party purports to transfer a cryptoasset
to which he does not have legal title, nemo dat (which is a rule of general application to all
legal transfers) should apply.25

These rules provide a starting point for resolving proprietary disputes over cryptoassets.
For example, in Jones v Persons Unknown,26 the claimant sent around 89.6 BTC to fraudsters’
accounts which was subsequently traced to Huobi wallets. On the claimant’s application for
summary judgment, the court held Huobi a constructive trustee of that BTC. However, it was
far from clear how the court reached that conclusion, and in particular why Huobi was said to
have obtained legal title to the BTC. In fact, Clause 5(i) of Huobi’s ‘Platform User Agreement’
stated that ‘title to the Digital Assets shall remain with you [the customer] and not transfer to
us.’27 What then was Huobi holding on trust? Perhaps the better analysis was that legal title
remained with the fraudsters, but was subject to a constructive trust in favour of Jones, who
could then enforce the fraudsters’ rights against Huobi under the Vandepitte procedure.28
Another recent example is provided by the interlocutory proprietary injunction granted in the
Chefpierre case, which involved a DeFi arrangement for a loan of 45 ETH granted subject to
some sort of quasi-security over a Bored Ape Yacht Club NFT. 29 In such cases, the question
of title is inextricably tied up with the characterisation of the security arrangement. Here, the
courts ‘take account of the language used by the parties in order to decide what rights and
obligations are created by the agreement, so long as the agreement is internally consistent, and
there is no evidence of a sham’.30 The focus remains, therefore, on the intentions of the parties,
although the subsequent question of characterising the arrangement presents particular
difficulties in the DeFi context.31

23
See Fox (n 3).
24
See Chan (n 1) 17; see also Fox(n 3) para 6.49; Hin Liu, ‘Transferring legal title to a digital asset’ (2023) 5
JIBFL 317.
25
See Chan (n 1) 18; see also Fox (n 3) para 6.48.
26
[2022] EWHC 2543 (Comm).
27
Terms dated 22 February 2021 and last updated on 22 June 2022, https://www.huobi.com/support/en-
us/detail/360000298561.
28
See Timothy Chan and Kelvin FK Low ‘Post-Scam Crypto Recovery: Final Clarity or Deceptive Simplicity?’
(2023) LQR (forthcoming), SSRN preprint, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4394820.
29
Janesh s/o Rajkumar v Unknown Person (“CHEFPIERRE”) [2022] SGHC 264.
30
Louise Gullifer, Goode and Gullifer on Legal Problems of Credit and Security (Sweet & Maxwell, 6th ed,
2017), para 1-36.
31
For further discussion, see Timothy Chan and Kelvin FK Low ‘DeFi Common Sense: Crypto-backed Lending
in Janesh s/o Rajkumar v Unknown Person (“CHEFPIERRE”)’ (2023) Modern Law Review (forthcoming),
https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2230.12804.

7
T. CHAN

To properly resolve proprietary disputes over cryptoassets, we must figure out what
title rules apply, and why they apply. My core argument here is that there is good reason for
traditional rules to be applied by analogy, and I have sought to demonstrate the relevance of
these rules to practical decisions. This space continues to develop rapidly and remains one to
watch.

8
II. The Regulation of Crypto-Lending

Dr Alexandros Seretakis1
(Trinity College Dublin)

Summary of the Presentation Delivered at the CBFL Banking, Finance and Technology
Conference, 18-19 May 2023, NUS Law. The Presentation is based on the paper “How
Should Crypto-Lending Be Regulated under EU Law?” jointly authored with Professor
Emilios Avgouleas, University of Edinburgh.

The last few years have seen the exponential growth of crypto lending, with lenders
such as Celsius and BlockFi, and DeFi protocols such as MakerDAO and Compound
dominating the space.2 Nonetheless, the failures of Celsius Network and Voyager have alarmed
policymakers, alerting them to the importance of crypto lenders for crypto markets and the
fragility of their business model. Moreover, the spectacular collapse of FTX created contagion
across the industry and had a spillover effect on crypto lenders, with major firms such as
Genesis and BlockFi suspending withdrawals of customer funds and filing for bankruptcy. 3

Crypto lenders, such as Celsius and Voyager, sought to provide a solution to two
distinct problems facing crypto holders: lack of liquidity and market purchasing power.4 Crypto
holders face a liquidity problem, since crypto is not widely accepted as a medium of exchange.
As a result, holders of crypto who want to monetise their holdings must convert them into fiat
currency.5 Moreover, the opportunities to earn handsome returns on crypto holdings, such as
staking, are only available to the holders of big portfolios.6 Crypto lenders engage in secured
lending by allowing holders to deposit their assets and borrow fiat currency or other digital
assets using their crypto holdings as collateral. Moreover, users can also earn rewards on these
assets at rates that are more favourable than those offered by traditional intermediaries or other

1
Assistant Professor of Law in Capital Markets and Financial Services and Fellow (elected 2023) Trinity College
Dublin.
2
Leeor Shimron, ‘Exploding Past $10 Billion, Interest Income and Lending are Bitcoin’s First Killer Apps’ Forbes
(26 May 2020), https://www.forbes.com/sites/leeorshimron/2020/05/26/exploding-past-10b-interest-income-and-
lending-are-bitcoins-first-killer-apps/.
3
Laurence Fletcher and Joshua Oliver, ‘Hedge Funds Left With Billions Stranded on FTX’ The Financial Times
(22 November 2022), https://www.ft.com/content/125630d9-a967-439f-bc23-efec0b4cdeca; Stephanie Findlay et
al., ‘Crypto Broker Genesis Puts Lending Unit Into Chapter 11 Bankruptcy’ The Financial Times (20 January
2023), https://www.ft.com/content/c040bc6c-08be-48dd-8af9-3b11b8b67c99. More than $900 million in
customer funds remain frozen in Genesis’s bankruptcy. See Ken Sweet, ‘Crypto Firms Acted Like Banks, then
Collapsed Like Dominoes’ Associated Press (23 January 2023), https://apnews.com/article/cryptocurrency-
technology-financial-services-bankruptcy-bitcoin-f7d97ff9cc12afc1fd845648b5f13ea7.
4
In re CELSIUS NETWORK LLC, et al., Declaration of Alex Mashinsky, Chief Executive Officer of Celsius
Network LLC, In Support of Chapter 11 Petitions and First Day Motions, p. 2.
5
Ibid.
6
Ibid.
A. SERETAKIS

crypto platforms. Crypto lenders are in essence performing credit intermediation outside the
regular banking system. As a result, they form part of the so-called shadow banking system.

The key financial stability threat of crypto lending comes from the excessive volatility
of crypto currency markets and the fact that lots of crypto assets like NFTs—non fungible
tokens7—are very complex and very difficult to value, making it is very difficult to obtain
sufficient collateral to secure the loan.8 So, leverage within the system remains uncontrolled.
It makes lenders vulnerable to suspicions of bankruptcy, thus triggering market panic
(depositor runs), which may result in lenders facing the risk of illiquidity.

The activities of crypto lenders, which involve the taking of deposits in crypto-assets
and the granting of crypto loans, resemble the activities of credit institutions. As a result,
prudential regulation should be extended to crypto lenders. Crypto lenders are currently not
captured by banking regulation. In the US, numerous state regulators and the Securities and
Exchange Commission (SEC) have taken the view that the interest-bearing accounts offered
by crypto lenders are unregistered securities. For instance, in February 2022, the SEC charged
BlockFi, a major crypto lender, with failing to register the offers and sales of its retail crypto
lending product.9 US regulators seek to regulate crypto lenders and protect the public against
their risks via securities law. Nevertheless, securities regulation is not suitable for tackling the
risks posed by crypto lending. Instead, it may exaggerate financial instability. Securities
regulation is based on disclosure.10 In the event of a market panic, market players do not act to
rationally and it is unlikely that they will stop “running” in the face of more information.

Even though crypto lending is a form of narrow banking and the usual rationales for
prudential regulation, namely, fractional reserve and depositor protection, may not apply, the
risks created by the crypto lending industry are important enough to justify the full panoply of
prudential regulation. As the Celsius and Voyager debacles demonstrated, crypto lenders face
the risk of investor runs, which can lead to their demise triggering a cascade of failures in
crypto markets. Moreover, taking a functional approach, regulation should not distinguish

7
According to Makavor and Schoar, NFTs are “a unique piece of data stored on a blockchain. The data can be
associated with a particular digital or physical asset or a license to use the asset for a specified purpose.” See Igor
Makavo and Antoinette Schoar, ‘Cryptocurrencies and Decentralized Finance (DeFi)’ (April 2022) NBER
Working Paper 30006, 26.
8
Collateral made up of crypto assets can be very volatile and can quickly lose value. For instance, Sam Bankman-
Fried in a letter to staff argued that the value of collateral held by FTX fell from $60 billion to $8 billion. Nikhilesh
De, ‘Bankman-Fried Apologizes to FTX Employees, Details Amount of Leverage in Internal Letter’ (CoinDesk,
23 November 2022), https://www.coindesk.com/business/2022/11/22/bankman-fried-apologizes-to-ftx-employe
es-details-amount-of-leverage-in-internal-letter/.
9
In the Matter of BlockFi Lending LLC, SEC Order, https://www.sec.gov/litigation/admin/2022/33-11029.pdf.
10
John C Coffee Jr, ‘Market Failure and the Economic Case for a Mandatory Disclosure System’ (1984) 70(4)
Virginia Law Review 717; Paul G Mahoney, ‘Mandatory Disclosure as a Solution to Agency Problems’ (1995) 62
University of Chicago Law Review 1047; Paul Mahoney, ‘The Economics of Securities Regulation: A Survey’
(2021) Virginia Law and Economics Research Paper No. 2021-14.

10
A. SERETAKIS

between the two types of intermediaries, namely the mainstream lending institutions and crypto
lenders. Cranston, Avgouleas et al. define prudential regulation as the thick and complex web
of rules employed to (a) keep financial institutions safe and a going concern, and failing that,
(b) to assist their resolution and/or restructuring, and (c) to augment the resilience of financial
systems to withstand shocks.11 Prudential regulatory tools include capital requirements,
liquidity requirements,12 corporate governance and remuneration rules, lender of last resort
facilities and deposit insurance.

The application of prudential rules—excluding lender of last resort and deposit


insurance arrangements in order not to heighten moral hazard—would have averted the recent
collapses of Voyager and Celsius. Adequate capital reserves would ensure the stability of the
crypto lending operators and reduce the risk of bankruptcy. The balance sheet hole would have
been covered. Prudential regulation would have also prevented concentration of balance sheets
on a single asset class. Moreover, liquidity requirements would have required crypto lenders to
hold some of their assets in liquid form ensuring thus that they had enough funds to repay users
and avert the run. Corporate governance standards and remuneration rules would have
guaranteed effective risk management and prevented excessive risk-taking. For instance,
Celsius’s collapse can be in part attributed to the losses suffered from erroneous and risky asset
deployment decisions, such as investments in long-term and illiquid assets. To avoid giving
false assurances to crypto lending users, crypto lenders should not benefit from deposit
insurance schemes or lender of last resort facilities. The application of deposit insurance and
lender of last resort facilities to crypto lenders would create moral hazard and extend implicit
government guarantees to crypto lenders.13 Crypto lenders would thus become another
category of too-big-to fail institutions.

11
Ross Cranston et al., Principles of Banking Law (Oxford University Press 2018) 31.
12
Liquidity requirements are composed of the Liquidity Coverage Ratio and the Net Stable Funding Ratio. The
Liquidity Coverage Ratio seeks to ensure that institutions have enough liquid assets to withstand a 30-day stress
period. The Net Stable Funding Ratio forces institutions to finance long-term assets with long-term liabilities. See
Clemens Bonner and Paul Hilbers, ‘Global Liquidity Regulation – Why Did It Take So Long?’ (2015) 455 DNB
Working Paper January 2015, https://www.dnb.nl/media/wkjpo4kj/working-paper-455.pdf.
13
On how deposit insurance creates moral hazard, see Charles W Calomiris, ‘Is Deposit Insurance Necessary? A
Historical Perspective’ (1990) 50(2) The Journal of Economic History 283; Stanley Fischer, ‘On the Need for an
International Lender of Last Resort’ (1999) 13(4) Journal of Economic Perspectives 85.

11
III. Insolvency of Crypto-Asset Service Providers: Legal Problems and Regulatory
Responses

Mr Ilya Kokorin1
(Leiden University)

Insolvencies of crypto-asset service providers (CASPs or crypto firms) are not new.
Perhaps the most well-known example is the collapse of the Japanese crypto exchange Mt.Gox
in 2014. While customers of Mt.Gox are still waiting to get compensation, crypto markets have
experienced a major downturn since the spring of 2022—the so called “crypto winter”. By
some estimates, from May 2022, over US$1.8 trillion of crypto value dissolved.2 Last year, we
witnessed collapses of some major market players, including Three Arrows Capital, Voyager,
Celsius, FTX, Alameda and BlockFi. Crypto failures continued in 2023 (e.g., Genesis, Bittrex
Inc). These domino-like crashes highlight the interconnectedness of market participants (e.g.,
crypto lenders, crypto hedge funds, crypto exchanges), integrated nature of many crypto
enterprises, multi-layered group structures behind a recognised brand name, and frequent
disregard of corporate formalities. Ultimately, insolvencies of CASPs emphasise the
importance of both private and public law for the protection of stakeholders, especially
consumers and crypto investors.

Insolvency is the ultimate litmus test that may reveal the (in)adequacy of regulation and
test the application of various rules and doctrines from different areas of law, including
property, contract, insolvency and financial law. It brings to light complex legal problems and
exposes the vulnerabilities of the existing business models. In this presentation, I examine the
most common legal problems that arise in crypto bankruptcies and explore regulatory
responses to them.

The first part of the presentation outlines some general observations concerning the
current wave of crypto failures. It highlights the major role of intermediaries in crypto markets
and summarises the main causes of CASPs’ insolvencies. Interestingly, despite the promises
of disintermediation, famously proclaimed in the Bitcoin White Paper,3 the present-day reality
is that a significant share of crypto-assets remains in the hands of centralised entities. This
creates single points of failure. Such failure could be caused by a variety of non-exclusive and
frequently overlapping events and reasons, including hacks (Mt.Gox, Gatecoin, Cryptopia),
unsustainable business models resulting in negative net interest margin (Celsius), overreliance
or overinvestment in a particular asset like a stablecoin (Three Arrows Capital), large exposure

1
PhD candidate at the Department of Financial Law, Leiden University, the Netherlands.
2
Giulio Cornelli et al., ‘Crypto shocks and retail losses’, BIS Bulletin, No. 69 (20 February 2023),
https://www.bis.org/publ/bisbull69.pdf.
3
Satoshi Nakamoto, ‘Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System’, https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf.
I. KOKORIN

and industry contagion (Voyager, BlockFi, Genesis), as well as regulatory issues and/or likely
mismanagement or even fraud (Bittrex Inc, FTX/Alameda).

Insolvency means that there are insufficient assets to fully satisfy creditors’ claims. This
is why “who should get what in insolvency” becomes a crucial and heavily-litigated question.
An answer to this question in many cases depends on whether customers of a failed CASP are
general unsecured creditors or whether they can exercise in rem (property rights) over
deposited crypto-assets. As demonstrated by a line of cases from civil and common law
jurisdictions, the existence of such in rem rights depends on individual facts of the case and on
applicable (property) law—and specifically whether this law recognises the concept of trusts
or otherwise permits preservation of property rights over commingled fungible assets.4 In some
of the most recent cases, courts in common law jurisdiction paid particular attention to the
Terms & Conditions or Terms of Use of crypto platforms.5 In one of them, the court even
concluded that the “issue of ownership of the assets in [accounts] is a contract law issue.” 6 Be
it as it may, even if a contract with a CASP explicitly states that “Title to your Digital Assets
shall at all times remain with you and shall not transfer to CASP”, this does not guarantee full
protection of customers’ assets and rights. For instance, if a CASP (in violation of a contractual
undertaking) disposes of (or re-uses) customers’ crypto-assets—as was likely the case with
FTX7—the return of such assets may be difficult, if not impossible.

In order to promote legal certainty, protect consumers and crypto investors, ensure
market integrity, and preserve financial stability, while at the same time supporting innovation
and the development of new technologies—regulation is necessary. But what type of
regulation? The second part of this presentation summary is devoted to the issue of regulation.
One can regulate the relations around crypto-assets through private law instruments (e.g.,
Article 12 of the Uniform Commercial Code, UNIDROIT Digital Assets and Private Law
Principles) or via rules of a public (administrative) law nature (e.g., EU Markets in Crypto-
assets Regulation or MiCA, EU Transfer of Funds Regulation, Japanese Payment Services Act,
Swiss “Blockchain Act”). Public law aims to establish the rules of the game for market
participants and for crypto markets. In this paper, I look at one example of such law—MiCA.

4
See In re MtGox, Tokyo District Court, 5 August 2015, Reference No. 25541521; In re Bitgrail, Court of
Florence, 21 January 2019, Bankruptcy Docket Nos. 178/2018 and 205/2018, Decision No. 17/2019; Ruscoe &
Moore v. Cryptopia Limited (in liquidation) [2020] NZHC 728.
5
See In re Celsius Network LLC et al., Case No. 22-10964 (MG) (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 4 January 2023); Re Gatecoin
Ltd (in liquidation) [2023] HKCFI 914; HCCW 18/2019 (31 March 2023).
6
See In re Celsius Network LLC et al., Case No. 22-10964 (MG) (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 4 January 2023).
7
See CFTC v. Samuel Bankman-Fried et al., Amended Complaint for Injunctive and Other Equitable Relief, Case
No. 1:22-cv-10503-PKC, 21 December 2022; SEC v. Samuel Bankman-Fried, Complaint, Civil Action No. 22-
cv-10501, 13 December 2022.

13
I. KOKORIN

On 24 September 2020, the European Commission adopted a Digital Finance Package


with the goal of boosting Europe’s competitiveness and innovation in the financial sector, and
making the European Union (EU) a global standard-setter.8 The Digital Finance Package
contained a number of legislative proposals, including the Proposal for a Regulation on
Markets in Crypto-assets.9 MiCA is truly ambitious, both in length (with more than 140
articles) and scope. It constitutes the largest piece of supranational legislation targeting crypto-
assets, which seeks to integrate them into the modern financial system.

MiCA was approved by the European Parliament on 20 April 2023 and will be
applicable in 2024.10 It will apply to crypto-assets, which are defined as “digital representation
of a value or of a right that is able to be transferred and stored electronically using distributed
ledger technology or similar technology.”11 Thus, it will cover all major types of crypto-assets
(i.e. cryptocurrencies, stablecoins, utility tokens). However, it excludes tokens that qualify as
securities (e.g., tokenised shares or bonds). These “blockchain-wrapped” financial instruments
and services around them fall within the scope of the long-standing financial regulation,
including instruments like MiFID II12 and the Prospectus Regulation.13 MiCA also does not
extend to unique non-fungible tokens (NFTs), central bank digital currencies (CBDCs), and
lending and borrowing of crypto-assets.

MiCA introduces detailed rules on issuance, offering to the public, admission to trading
of crypto-assets and provision of certain services like exchange and custody of crypto-assets.14
For example, it stipulates that CASPs that hold crypto-assets belonging to clients should ensure
that those crypto-assets are not used for their own account.15 In theory, this should prevent an
FTX-like scenario involving a re-use of customers’ crypto-assets. In addition, MiCA obliges
CASPs to “make adequate arrangements to safeguard the ownership rights of clients”,16 and
provides for different types of segregation arrangements which must be employed by CASPs

8
European Commission, ‘Digital finance package’, https://finance.ec.europa.eu/publications/digital-finance-
package_en.
9
Proposal for a Regulation on Markets in Crypto-assets, and amending Directive (EU) 2019/1937, COM(2020)
593 final, https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX:52020PC0593. Other instruments from
the Digital Finance Package include the Digital Operational Resilience Act (DORA) and the DLT Pilot Regime
Regulation.
10
MiCA, text adopted by the European Parliament, https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/TA-9-2023-
0117_EN.html.
11
MiCA, Article 3(1)(5).
12
Directive 2014/65/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 May 2014 on markets in financial
instruments.
13
Regulation (EU) 2017/1129 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14 June 2017 on the prospectus
to be published when securities are offered to the public or admitted to trading on a regulated market.
14
For a concise overview of MiCA, see Patrick Hansen, ‘The EU’s new MiCA framework for crypto-assets – the
one regulation to rule them all’ (20 April 2023), https://paddihansen.substack.com/p/the-eus-mica-framework?
utm_source=direct&utm_campaign=post&utm_medium=web.
15
MiCA, Recital 83.
16
MiCA, Article 70(1).

14
I. KOKORIN

offering custody services.17 To the extent that segregation helps to identify customers’ crypto-
assets and ensure that these assets are not commingled with the assets of a CASP (and,
therefore, are less likely to be re-used), they promote protection of clients’ (property) rights.

To conclude, the recent wave of crypto bankruptcies exposed a plethora of risks


characterising the activities of crypto-asset service providers. Failures of large crypto firms like
Celsius and FTX also emphasised the urgency of regulation. Such regulation is necessary to
protect consumers and investors, but also to help crypto businesses, as they often struggle with
legal uncertainty. MiCA—a new ground-breaking law harmonising the regulation of crypto
firms and crypto-asset services in the European Union—can prevent or at least reduce the
damaging effects of crypto insolvencies. That said, given the global nature of crypto-assets and
services provided by CASPs registered all over the world, a global response may be required.18

17
MiCA, Article 75.
18
See FSB, Regulation, ‘Supervision and Oversight of Crypto-Asset Activities and Markets: Consultative
document’ (11 October 2022), https://www.fsb.org/wp-content/uploads/P111022-3.pdf; IOSCO, ‘Policy
Recommendations for Crypto and Digital Asset Markets: Consultation Report’ (May 2023), https://www.iosco.org
/library/pubdocs/pdf/IOSCOPD734.pdf.

15
IV. A Framework for the Interoperability of CBDCs

Dr Kosmas Kaprinis
(Binance/IE University)

The exploration of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) has accelerated rapidly in
recent years. While each central bank has different motivations for exploring CBDC systems
at the domestic front, the potential for improved cross-border payments through CBDC
arrangements is perceived as a common goal across jurisdictions. In the context of CBDCs,
interoperability refers to the ability of different CBDC systems to interact with each other,
allowing financial institutions and retail customers to transfer money between different CBDC
networks. The interoperability of CBDCs has raised several legal issues that need to be
addressed before practical cross-border arrangements are established.

As a brief overview, CBDC is defined as central bank money in a digital format,


denominated in the national unit of account, and is a direct liability of the central bank. Retail
CBDCs are designed for individuals and businesses to hold and utilise in their everyday
transactions. Wholesale CBDCs are held by eligible financial institutions and used for the
settlement of interbank payments. There are a number of well-recognised policy choices faced
by CBDCs at the domestic level. These include: whether the CBDC should be architected on
an ‘account’ or ‘token’ model; whether the CBDC should be accessible to retail users or
restricted to wholesale users; and whether the central bank should pay interest on CBDC
holdings. It is projected that the CBDC ecosystem would comprise similar elements and
functions as traditional payment systems. In this respect, financial service providers will likely
maintain their intermediary role in CBDC distribution, compliance, and CBDC wallet
provision.

In the sciences, interoperability refers to the technical and business compatibility that
enables a system to be used in conjunction with other systems. In CBDCs, interoperability
enables financial institutions from various CBDC systems to conduct cross-system payments
without the need to engage in multiple systems simultaneously. The concept of interoperability
is interpreted from a different angle for each financial market participant: for retail users (or
wholesale) users, interoperability is perceived as a state of seamlessness, where transactions
between platforms occur with minimal costs; for financial service providers, it is perceived as
a business environment that would diminish hurdles to entry in new markets; for regulators,
interoperability would reduce operational risks of operators and promote the efficiency of the
financial sector. In this regard, an international CBDC system will need to “compete” with
other payment schemes on user experience and regulatory efficiency if it is to be widely
adopted.
K. KAPRINIS

In the CBDC pilots that have been conducted internationally, three broad models have
emerged in terms of interoperability:

• The compatible model—refers to individual/domestic CBDC systems that use common


standards to communicate, reducing the operational burden on financial institutions
while participating in multiple systems. For example, if a national CBDC system allows
for direct access, a foreign bank could directly access the system to facilitate a cross-
border payment using the domestic CBDC of that jurisdiction. In this regard, the
compatible model does not link different CBDC systems, though it has the potential to
improve efficiency of payment processing.

• The interlinked model—refers to the process of connecting different CBDC systems


using standardised technical protocols, which not only enable foreign banks to process
payments but also assist in ensuring compliance, facilitating foreign currency provision,
and settling transactions. As in the first case, these common arrangements would allow
participants in the interlinked CBDC systems to transact with each other without the
need to become a direct participant in each of them.

• The single system model—refers to CBDC systems that use a single common technical
infrastructure. This model is not about connecting separate systems, but rather
establishing a common platform to achieve interoperability between CBDCs.

There is no universal model that can be applied to all cases when it comes to accessing and
ensuring interoperability among different CBDC systems. For example, while compatibility
might be the least costly form of interoperability, it may not achieve similar efficiency benefits
to interlinking or a single system. The majority of the pilots for multi-CBDC interoperability
have adopted option 3 of a single, shared settlement system.

According to the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), approximately 28% of the
central banks surveyed are considering the possibility of creating multi-CBDC arrangements
to achieve interoperability among different CBDC systems. Singapore has been at the forefront
of research and testing in the field of CBDC interoperability. Indicatively, in November 2018,
the Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS), the Bank of Canada (BoC), and the Bank of
England (BoE) released an early report evaluating different approaches to improve cross-
border payments and settlements. Following this, MAS and BoC connected their experimental
domestic payment networks, known as Project Jasper and Project Ubin, and in May 2019, they
announced a successful trial of cross-border and cross-currency payments using CBDCs.
Presently, Singapore, along with South Africa and Australia, is participating in cross-border
CBDC testing.

17
K. KAPRINIS

From a policy perspective, we identify three important policy priorities for policy
makers: (i) international governance arrangements on CBDC design and infrastructure, (ii)
interoperability of CBDCs that is robust to operational risks, and (iii) maximising the potential
of CBDC arrangements for enhancing inclusive growth globally. Our hypothesis is that the
divergent (and not sufficiently harmonised) legal domestic frameworks can pose challenges to
the above goals. This is attributed to the fact that interoperability is not viewed as a technical
process, but part of a wider strategy of sovereign states to exert influence over global finance.

From a legal perspective, the primary legal concern is the issue of jurisdiction.
Specifically, the transaction processing, settlement, and clearing of CBDCs involve the transfer
of assets across borders. National regulators have the responsibility of overseeing the
operations of a domestic CBDC, but cross-border operations involve multiple jurisdictions,
each with its own set of regulations. Currently, such transfers adhere to conditions specified by
cross-border payment systems such as SWIFT and TARGET2, with established international
standards and arbitration procedures. Similarly, for CBDC systems to be interoperable, they
must ensure that their transactions are legally enforceable across different jurisdictions.
Secondly, interoperability requires establishing effective know your customer (KYC) and anti-
money laundering (AML) procedures across different CBDC systems. Ensuring that all
participants in the interconnected CBDC networks comply with KYC and AML requirements
is vital to prevent money laundering, terrorist financing, and other illicit activities.
Interoperability increases the attack surface for cyber threats and fraud attempts. Implementing
robust cybersecurity measures, including encryption, authentication protocols, and fraud
detection systems, is necessary to mitigate compliance risks related to cybersecurity and fraud
prevention. Additionally, ensuring consumer protection in an interoperable CBDC
environment is crucial. Clear rules and mechanisms should be in place to address issues such
as unauthorised transactions, disputes, refunds, and customer support across different CBDC
systems. Finally, the legal consequences of interoperability also encompass matters of privacy
and data protection. When different CBDC systems interact with each other, they must
exchange transaction data, personal information, and other sensitive data, which can raise
concerns regarding data privacy.

It is widely agreed that CBDCs could play an important role in addressing long-standing
challenges in the cross-border payments market It is crucial to avoid creating fragmented
systems that hinder interoperability and resemble isolated entities. Instead, CBDCs should
serve as inclusive platforms supporting global financial inclusion and fostering innovation in
the financial markets. In this respect, the interoperability of CBDCs poses several real legal
implications that need to be worked out for the above goals to be achieved.

18
K. KAPRINIS

Broader international coordination on domestic designs would be beneficial to lower


barriers to cross-border compatibility and could serve as a launching pad for interoperability.
International organisations such as the BIS, International Monetary Fund, and the Financial
Action Task Force should play a critical role in developing common understanding and
approaches for cross-border CBDCs. Even jurisdictions not planning to issue a CBDC ought
to be involved in this work as they will still be part of this new regime. Finally, given the
constant changes in the payments market, a cross-border CBDC system should also be flexible
enough to interoperate with future payment services arrangements.

Bibliography

“Proceeding with Caution — A Survey on Central Bank Digital Currency,” Bank for
International Settlements, January 2020. Source: www.bis.org/publ/othp33.pdf

“Central Bank Digital Currency: The Quest for Minimally Invasive Technology,” Raphael
Auer and Rainer Boehme, BIS Working Papers, June 2021. Source:
www.bis.org/publ/work948.htm

“Project Jasper and Project Ubin: Cross-border Interoperability Prototype for Payments and
Settlements Using Central Bank Digital Currency,” Bank of Canada, Monetary
Authority of Singapore, 2019. Source: www.bankofcanada.ca/wp-
content/uploads/2019/05/Project-Jasper-and-Project-Ubin-Cross-border-
Interoperability-Prototype-for-Payments-and-Settlements-using-Central-Bank-Digital-
Currency.pdf

“Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features,” International
Monetary Fund, October 2020. Source: www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-
Papers/Issues/2020/10/13/Central-Bank-Digital-Currencies-49843

“Central Bank Digital Currencies: The Quest for Legitimacy and Efficiency in the Digital
Age,” European Central Bank, February 2020. Source:
www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/ecb.cbdcquestforlegitimacyandefficiency202002~f
2e7a67016.en.pdf

“Report on the Cross-border Retail Payments,” Committee on Payments and Market


Infrastructures and the World Bank Group, January 2021. Source:
www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d200.pdf

“Cross-border Retail Payments,” Financial Action Task Force, June 2020. Source: www.fatf-
gafi.org/media/fatf/documents/reports/Cross-Border-Retail-Payments.pdf

19
V. Regulating DeFi and On-Chain CeFi: Centralisation Points as Regulatory Hooks

Dr Ann Sofie Cloots


(University of Cambridge)

1. Introduction

Decentralised Finance (DeFi) has raised concerns among regulators, lawmakers and
policymakers. Whereas regulation of centralised finance (CeFi) to a large extent relies on
centralised intermediaries as legal hooks, DeFi is designed to reduce or bypass the reliance on
such centralised intermediaries. The fear is that this undermines the ability to regulate
decentralised financial infrastructure and the actors involved. This presentation summary
shows why that fear is at least partially misplaced.

In a recent paper,1 we propose a framework to assess the factual decentralisation of


DeFi. A systematic analysis of DeFi’s architecture shows various potential centralised ‘hooks’
on the different layers of DeFi’s technology stack. These ‘hooks’, or centralisation vectors,
can, and very likely will, be relied upon by lawmakers and regulators considering a legal
framework for DeFi.

The proposed systematic analysis of DeFi requires sufficient understanding of the


technological architecture of DeFi, from the blockchain (settlement) layer to the application
layer.

Within this technology stack, various endogenous centralisation vectors can be


identified at each layer. Moreover, a higher layer inherits centralisation concerns of a lower
layer. For example, if a permissionless blockchain has centralised elements, this centralisation
will be inherited by any protocol or application built on top of it.

In addition to centralisation vectors that are endogenous to one layer of the DeFi stack
or are inherited from a lower layer, other centralisation vectors arise from interactions between
the blockchain and the off-chain world.

1
Katrin Schuler, Ann Sofie Cloots, and Fabian Schär, ‘On Defi and On-Chain CeFi: How (Not) to Regulate
Decentralized Finance’ (2023) SSRN preprint, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4422473.
A.N. CLOOTS

For a legal analysis of DeFi, the first step is to locate a particular project in the DeFi
stack. The second step is to scrutinise the project for endogenous centralisation vectors and the
third step is to assess centralisation inheritance from a lower layer. Finally, centralisation
vectors from a lateral layer or interaction with off-chain centralised entities need to be assessed.
The aim is to identify centralisation vectors that distinguish genuine DeFi from on-chain CeFi
when considering an adequate legal response.

Below we briefly assess the centralisation vectors at the three layers of the DeFi stack:
(1) the settlement (blockchain) layer, (2) the asset and protocol layer and (3) the application
and aggregator layer.

2. Settlement Layer (Blockchain Layer)

We analyse the capacity of users to directly join the network and exchange data with
other network participants. Restrictions or special privileges can be used to exclude certain
participants or transactions from the network, creating centralisation vectors that suggest one
is dealing with on-chain CeFi rather than genuine DeFi.

Second, we assess the ability of participants to mathematically verify the authenticity


and integrity of a transaction. Decentralisation in this respect may help achieve the regulatory
goals of reducing information asymmetry in financial markets. Transparency of on-chain
transaction data and execution logic could reduce the need for statutory disclosure obligations
at the settlement layer. However, there may be various types of restrictions to this ability, which

21
A.N. CLOOTS

can be either explicit (off-chain computations by a third party) or implicit (the verification is
prohibitively expensive for most average users).

The last and arguably most complex design aspect for a blockchain is reaching
consensus over the current state. We assess different consensus models and their trade-offs,
including the risks of frontrunning-like behaviour through MEV.2 From a legal perspective, it
is important to note that consensus models are designed to reach an agreement on the current
state and discourage nodes from including invalid transactions. They are not designed to
exclude unlawful transactions. Compliance with sanctions law (or other rules) can be enforced
through on- and off-ramps or other centralised entities rather than through consensus-relevant
nodes (such as miners or consensus-relevant nodes).

For regulators assessing whether and how to regulate this settlement layer, there are
three important points to consider. First, if such legal obligations impose a degree of
centralisation on the settlement layer (which is highly likely), in practice, this will undermine
the possibility of DeFi, as DeFi requires a decentralised and independent settlement layer.
Second, the settlement layer is not only used for DeFi but also for a variety of other
applications. Regulating the settlement layer as a way to regulate DeFi will also affect all non-
financial transactions on that layer. Third, there are other means to indirectly regulate, namely
by regulating on- and off-ramps or scrutinising upper layers in the DeFi stack.

3. Asset and Protocol Layer

The asset and protocol layers are arguably the core element of the DeFi ecosystem
where most of the ‘action’ happens. Both are smart contract-based and therefore have similar
centralisation vectors and legal considerations.

Assets (or tokens) use standardised smart contract interfaces to keep track of balances
and allow the transfer of funds. Protocols use smart contracts to recreate a wide array of
financial market infrastructure, such as exchanges, lending markets, derivatives, and asset
management services.

From a legal perspective, there have been proposals to regulate asset issuers as well as
identify persons who control the asset’s or protocol’s smart contracts to place legal hooks. This
assumes a level of centralisation at the asset or protocol layer or even, as one OECD report
suggests, a need to recentralise DeFi to get “some comfort from a regulatory and supervisory
standpoint, without necessarily completely undermining decentralisation”.3 It is difficult to see

2
Maximum Extractable Value.
3
OECD, ‘Why Decentralised Finance (DeFi) Matters and the Policy Implications’ (19 January 2022),
https://www.oecd.org/daf/fin/financial-markets/Why-Decentralised-Finance-DeFi-Matters-and-the-Policy-
Implications.pdf.

22
A.N. CLOOTS

how this can be achieved, however, as it is technically impossible to introduce centralisation


vectors ex post into a genuinely decentralised protocol. Moreover, this may not be desirable,
as it undermines the potential benefits of genuine decentralisation.

Smart contract upgradeability: opt-in versus opt-out

To distinguish genuine DeFi from on-chain CeFi, we assess different types of


centralisation vectors depending on the type of smart contract set-up (static, parametric or
proxy contracts). A rough analogy is to see static contracts as ‘opt-in’ for users, while
parametric and proxy contracts are ‘opt-out’.

Smart contracts are functions that contain a condition that will be verified when
someone ‘calls’ (relies on) this function. These conditions can introduce centralisation vectors,
for example by imposing blacklists used for sanctions compliance) or whitelists.4 In such cases,
the functions are restricted: there is a gatekeeper that can exercise centralised control over who
can interact with or change the smart contracts.

Some of these restricted functions may allow their controllers to effectively expropriate
users. A straightforward example is when the functions allow the controller to unilaterally
adjust user balances on an asset or protocol level without the holder's private keys. A further
concern in terms of decentralisation is any emergency stop functions.

Governance: account-based versus token-based

We explore the governance and control structures behind these restricted functions.

First, we analyse account-based governance: setups in which the right to execute a


restricted function is given to one or multiple account-holders. The holders of these so-called
admin keys can exclusively call (execute) restricted functions.

Second, we assess token-based governance: a setup in which voting rights are tied to
governance tokens.

Finally, we explore lateral centralisation that undermines genuine DeFi, through


‘oracles’ and ‘bridges’.

4
Sanctions law compliance has led several crypto companies to resort to blacklisting sanctioned addresses.
Compliance with sanctions imposed against individuals requires KYC, which can be enforced through crypto-fiat
on- and off-ramps. However, when sanctions target a blockchain address rather than the individual who controls
it, the address can be blacklisted by centralised exchanges and protocols with blacklist functions.

23
A.N. CLOOTS

4. Application and Aggregation Layer

Next, we assess the off-chain layers of DeFi. They provide graphical user interfaces (a
website or app through which people interact with the underlying smart contracts, also called
‘front-ends’). The applications are non-custodial.5

From a legal perspective, a DeFi project’s activities on the front-end layer could be
subjected to rules such as those on misleading advertisement or financial promotions. Other
obligations that have been considered include audit requirements and governance standards.6

From a competition law viewpoint, the open technical interface to the on-chain DeFi
infrastructure holds promise. Meanwhile, the potential abuse of dominant position by
applications that garner substantial user traction raise centralisation concerns (for example, by
bundling a popular wallet app with other services). Apps may also accept kick-backs from
protocols.

5. Conclusion

Most of what is commonly referred to as DeFi today has severe centralisation vectors.

Centralised financial services that run on a blockchain should not be referred to as DeFi.
Instead, we propose the term on-chain CeFi and argue that these centralised service providers
can and should be regulated in line with their non-blockchain-based counter-parts. The two
categories have different risk profiles and require distinct regulatory approaches.

While there is a certain grey area today, we argue that there will be a diversion toward
the two extremes: projects will either become fully decentralised (genuine DeFi), acting as
neutral infrastructure with no regulatory hooks, or they retain centralised elements (on-chain
CeFi) and the corresponding hooks, through which they can and will be regulated.

5
Otherwise they are purely centralised finance and outside of the scope of the analysis.
6
HM Treasury, ‘Future Financial Services Regulatory Regime for Cryptoassets. Consultation
and Call for Evidence’ (February 2023), https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/file/1133404/TR_Privacy_edits_Future_financial_services_regulatory_regime_for_cry
ptoassets_vP.pdf.

24
VI. A Multi-Layered Framework of AI Governance in China’s Finance Sector

Ms Jinghe Fan (University of Oxford) and Dr Xin Zhang (University of International


Business and Economics)

Artificial intelligence (AI) plays a central role in changing financial services around the
1
globe. In recent decades, AI has not only created new business models, like upgrading
programme trading and developing robo-advisers, but also transformed the methods of
fulfilling compliance duties and assisting risks assessment in credit lending, etc.2

In 2017, China released the Next Generation Artificial Intelligence Development Plan
(‘AIDP’) which outlines China’s overarching policy objectives of AI development strategy. As
a highly incentivised ‘wish list’,3 the AIDP indicates the importance of developing AI as one
of the driving forces for multiple sectors which entail finances. The People’s Bank of China
has also called for applying AI steadily and properly promoting ‘the deep integration of
artificial intelligence technology with the financial business’ in the FinTech Development Plan
(2019-2021). Against this backdrop, the market size of AI-powered financial products has been
anticipated to constantly expanding.4

Despite the potential of facilitating transactions, enhancing market efficiency, and


improving customer experience,5 the expanding application of AI in financial services could
also bring about a myriad of risks. These risks could be basically classified into three categories
based on the underlying reasons. The first type of risk—endogenous risks from AI
technologies—is predominantly affected by the technical features of developing and using AI.6
A straightforward example would be that the use of non-traditional data and novel models (e.g.,
Machine Learning) could exacerbate the opacity of AI systems and further create challenges
of explainability. Also, the multiple stages of developing AI may increase the number of actors
involved in the supply chain and obscure the responsibility allocation.7 The second category of

1
Florian Ostmann and Cosmina Dorobantu, ‘AI in Financial Services’ (The Alan Turing Institute 2021) 5
https://www.turing.ac.uk/news/publications/ai-financial-services.
2
Richard Hay and Sophia Le Vesconte, ‘Financial Regulation’, Artificial Intelligence Law and Regulation (2022)
292.
3
Huw Roberts et al., ‘The Chinese Approach to Artificial Intelligence: An Analysis of Policy, Ethics, and
Regulation’ (2021) 36 AI & Society 59, 61.
4
See iResearch, ‘Research Report on the Development of AI+ Finance Industry in China in 2022’ (2022),
https://www.iresearch.com.cn/Detail/report?id=4101&isfree=0. The market size of AI-powered financial services
is anticipated to reach 66 billion CNY for core products and 1562 billion CNY for related industries in 2026. The
core products refer to products that include technologies such as computer vision, speech recognition machine
learning, knowledge graph, natural language processing, and other core technologies of AI. Related industries
refer to the procurement of relevant software and hardware products that are associated with achieving the
objective of AI application.
5
OECD, OECD Business and Finance Outlook 2021: AI in Business and Finance (OECD 2021)
https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/finance-and-investment/oecd-business-and-finance-outlook-2021_ba682899-en.
6
Xin Zhang and Qi Gao, ‘Types of Risks and Regulatory Measures Pertaining to the Application of Artificial
Intelligence in Finance’ (2022) 6 China Banking 67, 67.
7
Ostmann and Dorobantu (n 1) 21.
J. FAN & X. ZHANG

risks arises from societies even without the innovation of AI technology. These risks could be
named inherent risks from societies.8 The complexities of AI systems could further entrench
the risks that are not restricted to specific industries, such as fairness, privacy, freedom of
expression, competition, etc. The final category entails those risks from specific domains,
which are unique to one sector in which AI is applied. For instance, the usage of similar AI
strategies could arguably exacerbate the risks of procyclicality.9 Responsible AI in the financial
sector also pays attention to consumer protection, aiming to prevent financial losses caused by
the mismatch between products and customer needs.10

These categories are neither exhaustive nor fully delineated. Some challenges brought
about by AI could fall into multiple categories. Nevertheless, this classification could provide
a lens through which we could zoom in on how legislative developments respond to AI-related
challenges and explore the promises and uncertainties that are involved.11

1. Legislative Trends in AI in China’s Financial Sector

To address these risks, China is dedicated to a three-step development of AI governance


framework according to the AIDP.12 The FinTech Development Plan (2019-2022) also set up
the objective of stipulating clear and comprehensive regulations including both universal
standards and targeted requirements. Since then, a burgeoning field of regulations at various
levels has arisen within both the technology and financial sectors.

This work intends to provide an overview of the expanding field of legislation since
2017. It could be observed that the year 2021 may possibly mark the beginning of the expansion
of the AI governance landscape. Before 2021, AI in financial services is predominantly
regulated under the existing legislative framework of finances. A few domain-specific rules

8
Zhang and Gao (n 6) 67–68.
9
Ekaterina Svetlova, ‘AI Ethics and Systemic Risks in Finance’ (2022) 2 AI and Ethics 713.
10
Ostmann and Dorobantu (n 1) 38.
11
It is worth noting that it is beyond the scope of this short summary to completely examine the enforcement in
AI-powered financial services. This work will primarily focus on responses to AI challenges in the financial sector
from legislations.
12
As per the AIDP, initial ethical norms, policies and regulations should have been created in some areas of AI by
2020. By 2025, China expects to initially establish laws, regulations, ethical norms, and policy systems related to
AI. Further upgrades and a comprehensive system of these levels of regulations are intended to be completed by
2030.

26
J. FAN & X. ZHANG

clarified the requirements of using AI in specific financial services, such as robo-adviser and
online loaning by commercial banks.13

Since 2021, multiple landmark legislations have been promulgated as part of the efforts
to strengthen general AI governance. Having regard to the infrastructure level which provides
the foundational elements of developing AI, China’s data governance regime has gradually
come into shape.14

On the level of AI technologies and application, a series of horizontal legislations (or


drafts) which applies to all sectors has been gradually promulgated since 2021, in accordance
with several core areas of AI technologies, such as algorithmic recommendations services,15
deep synthesis services,16 and generative AI services (for public consultation).17 These
departmental rules are designed to substantiate service providers’ accountability over
algorithms. For example, the Internet Information Services Algorithmic Recommendation
Management Provisions (‘IISARMP’) confirms that algorithmic recommendation service
providers shall fulfil their primary responsibility of ensuring algorithmic security, technology
ethics review, information security, and lawfulness by regularly examining and verifying
algorithmic mechanisms, models, data, and applications.18 Individual rights and special
protection for specific groups are also reiterated.19 In soft law, it is worth noting that ethical

13
In light of robo-advisers, for instance, as per the 2018 Guiding Opinions on Regulating the Asset Management
Business of Financial Institutions (‘Guiding Opinions on Asset Management’), Paragraph 23 connects to the
general duties of asset management, including the suitability obligations and information disclosure, while also
calling for more stringent requirements of transparency, internal monitoring, and accountability due to the
deployment of AI. The Interim Measures for the Administration of Internet Loans of Commercial Banks (2020)
Article 22 also mandates commercial banks to integrate human intervention into the automatic approval of risk
models that are used for loaning.
14
Both the Personal Information Protection Law and the Data Security Law have been enacted in 2021.
Regulatory systems of data protection and utilisation that are neutral and specific to finances have both been
initially formulated through both hard and soft law. For example, within the financial sector, the Banking and
Insurance Regulatory Commission issued Guidelines on Data Governance for Banking Financial Institutions
(hard law) in 2018 and the People’s Bank of China issued the Personal Financial Information Protection
Technical Specification (soft law) in 2020.
15
Internet Information Service Algorithmic Recommendation Management Provisions (promulgated on 16
November 2021, took effect from 1 March 2022)
16
Provisions on the Administration of Deep Synthesis of Internet-based Information Services (promulgated on 3
November 2022, took effect from 10 January 2023).
17
Public Comments Requested on Administrative Measures for Generative AI Services (released on 11 April
2023).
18
According to the IISARMP Article 2, the use of algorithmic recommendation technology as mentioned in the
previous Paragraph refers to the use of generative or synthetic type, personalised recommendation type, ranking
and selection type, search filter type, dispatching and decision-making type, and other such algorithmic
technologies to provide information to users. The scope of application is relatively broad and may cover some AI-
powered financial services that are related to information recommendation.
19
In the IISARM, individuals who might be affected by the algorithm recommendation services have the right to
be informed (Art 16), right to opt-out of customisation based on individual characteristics (Art 17), right to delete
personal characteristics in recommendation (Art 17), access to portal for complaints (Art 22). Specific groups
include minors, elders, workers, and consumers.

27
J. FAN & X. ZHANG

principles of AI governance have been elaborated.20 Arguably, due to the broad scope of
application, general AI regulations in China may have the potential to provide certain
safeguards against AI-related risks in financial services if the AI technologies fall within the
scope of respective legislations.

In the financial sector, soft law measures, such as industry standards, have been
particularly developed. Some glimmers are shown in the Evaluation Specification of Artificial
Intelligence Algorithm in Financial Application (JR/T 0221-2021) which provides for a unified
framework of pre-emptive measures to integrate four core aspects of responsible AI—safety,
explainability, accuracy, and performance (robustness) into the whole lifecycle of preparing,
building, and applying AI models.

2. Legislative Responses to Certain AI-Related Risks and Areas of Concern

As illustrated above, this work intends to examine how the current multi-level
regulatory framework responds to three types of AI-related risks by using examples of risks in
each category.

Among the endogenous risks from AI technologies, extended AI supply chains could
exacerbate the complexities of governance. The development of AI systems may rely on off-
the-shelf tools, pre-existing models, or software that were developed externally and not
specifically for the purpose of financial services.21 However, the present regulations in the
financial sector (e.g., the Guiding Opinions of Asset Management paragraph 23) concentrate
on financial institutions, who usually play the role of deployers of AI when there are third-
party developers.22 This may not necessarily give clear guidance on how multiple players in
the AI supply chain could detect and mitigate risks proactively and pre-emptively. The
excessive reliance on deployers is also reflected in the general AI rules, like the IISARMP.23
In this regard, it remains to be seen how the Evaluation Specification of Artificial Intelligence
Algorithm in Financial Application could be implemented to give clearer instructions for

20
See the Opinions on Strengthening Governance over Ethics in Science and Technology (2022) and the Ethical
Norms for New Generation Artificial Intelligence (2021). Some principles include advancing human welfare,
promoting fairness and justice, protecting of privacy and security, assuring controllability and worthiness, and
strengthening accountability.
21
Ostmann and Dorobantu (n 1) 23.
22
For example, regarding issues of robo-advisers, financial institutions can either develop robo-adviser software
themselves or purchase such from third-party technology companies. In general, they play the role of deploying
AI systems in financial services.
23
IISARMP Article 2 states that the regulation applies to those who use algorithm recommendation technology
to provide internet information services.

28
J. FAN & X. ZHANG

promoting responsible AI at different stages, combining concrete and unique requirements


from different financial services.24

Moving to inherent risks from societies, bias, in reality, may creep into each domain of
AI application. AI in insurance and credit lending may make worries of inequality more
prominent if an individual’s risks profile cannot be precisely established.25 Though the
principle of fairness has been stressed in the multi-layered legislative framework of AI
governance,26 there may still be some uncertainties during implementation that are worth
further addressing. From the outset, the provisions related to non-discrimination are too general
without providing clearer definitions of discrimination and legal standards for direct or indirect
discrimination.27 The absence of comprehensive non-discrimination rules would further
impede the promotion of fairness in AI-powered financial services. Moreover, as a principle,
fairness could have been listed as a dimension distinguished from security, robustness, and
privacy, and fully elaborated in industry standards such as the Evaluation Specification of
Artificial Intelligence Algorithm in Financial Application. Both aspects need to be facilitated
by legislators, regulators, the industry, and public participation.

Domain-specific risks in the financial sector would be another source of AI-related


challenges. Supervision over AI needs to strike a balance between redressing macro-prudential
supervision and financial consumer protection.28 Taking the provisions of transparency related
to AI as an example, it remains unclear whether this balance has been successfully struck.
When providing services like robo-advisers, financial institutions are mandated to report the
main parameters of AI models and the main logic of asset allocation to the regulators in order
to strengthen supervision.29 However, the main logic of asset allocation need not be
demonstrated to consumers. The inherent weaknesses of AI algorithms and the risks of using
AI in financial services, which should be mandatorily disclosed, are not further explained. The

24
Insights could also be borrowed from the Provisions on the Administration of Deep Synthesis of Internet-Based
Information Services and the Administrative Measures for Generative AI services (Draft) which incorporate
entities who develop or provide technical support to AI services within the scope of application.
25
Lin Lin and Christopher C Chen, ‘The Promise and Perils of InsurTech’ (2020) Singapore Journal of Legal
Studies 115, 125.
26
In the context of AI governance, the principle of fairness has been cited non-exhaustively in the Personal
Information Protection Law Article 24, IISARMP Article 21, Ethical Norms for New Generation Artificial
Intelligence Article 13, etc. Discrimination has also been prohibited according to Law on the Protection of
Women’s Rights and Interests, the Law on Protection of Disabled Persons, the Labour Law, the Employment
Promotion Law, etc.
27
Bin Wang, ‘China’s Anti-Discrimination Law Legislation: Difficulties and Future’ in Xiaonan Liu and Liwan
Wang (eds), Equality and Anti-Discrimination (Brill 2021) 88 https://brill.com/view/book/edcoll/9789004421
011/BP000004.xml.
28
See Hui Huang ‘The Logics and Path of China's Financial Regulatory Structure Reform: International
Experiences and Local Choice’ The Jurist (2019) 124. It is suggested that if AI algorithms start following similar
strategies in lending for banks or in robo-advisers for consumers, markets may be overheated in the upturn and
undervalued in the downturn and face more risks of instability.
29
See the Guiding Opinions on Asset Management Paragraph 23.

29
J. FAN & X. ZHANG

gap between the information reported to regulators and to the public also exists in general AI
rules. As per the IISARMP Article 24, a service provider30 with public opinion properties and
social mobilisation capacity shall report to regulators a wide range of information through the
Internet Information Services Algorithm Filing System,31 while the information demonstrated
to the public through the filing system is relatively restricted.32 How precisely these types of
information should be disclosed is completely subject to the discretion of algorithm service
providers. It should be noted that reducing information asymmetry between deployers of AI
and consumers, and between regulators and consumers, could have paramount implications for
individuals, and also be beneficial in promoting polycentric governance by enhancing public
oversight and leveraging the efficiency of supervision.

3. Conclusion

AI governance in China’s financial sector has gradually transformed from legislative


plans to multi-layered concrete rules in both hard and soft law, general AI regulations, and
specific provisions in the financial sector that could complement each other. The current
legislative framework represents a clear step forward to the objective set up by the AIDP to
initially establish a legal system of AI by 2025. It is, however, also a point of departure for us
to devote more efforts to examining how distinct AI-related risks and challenges arise and
could be redressed, in order to ultimately formulate a coherent, efficient, and holistic regulatory
framework in the AI-powered financial sector, which is envisioned to be established by 2030.

30
If providers of AI-related financial services use the information recommendation technologies that fall within
the scope of IISARMP, they will also be subject to the IISARMP.
31
According to the User Manual for Internet Information Service Algorithm Filing System (2022), the information
that needs to be disclosed to the system includes but is not restricted to (1) basic properties of algorithms:
categories, name, algorithm security self-assessment report; (2) detailed properties of algorithms: data that is used;
intended purposes; methods of demonstration; (3) algorithm data: including biometric characteristics or not;
including personal identification or not; (4) algorithm models: sources of training data; description of open-source
training datasets; self-made datasets and sources. See Cyberspace Administration of China, ‘Internet Information
Service Algorithm Filing System’, https://beian.cac.gov.cn/#/index.
32
According to the IISARM Article 16, individuals could be informed about the basic principles, the purpose and
intention, and the main operation mechanisms, etc. of their algorithmic recommendation services.

30
VII. Financial Regulation and the Advent of Digital Reporting: The End of Rule-Use
as We Know It?

Dr Andromachi Georgosouli
(Queen Mary University of London)

The UK and other countries around the world are shifting to a new digital economy.
This shift is powered by big data, advanced analytics and artificial intelligence (AI) and goes
hand-in-hand with fundamental changes in the design of the legal framework that supports the
regulation of economic activity. As technology penetrates the sphere of regulation, it
transforms how regulators gather information, how they monitor compliance, and how they
impose sanctions. Furthermore, it gradually changes how regulators draft rules and how they
use them in their interaction with the regulated industry. The impact of technology on the use
of rules as instruments of social organisation and control has received growing attention in
recent legal scholarship. 1 The intersection of artificial intelligence, technology and the law in
financial markets has also been researched extensively.2 The implications of re-writing
reporting requirements into code to enable machine-readability and machine-executability and,
in particular, the merits of a system of data-driven financial governance with little or no reliance
on human interpretation has escaped systematic examination. This presentation summary seeks
to address this gap in the literature making special reference to the digitalisation of reporting
requirements that is currently in progress around the globe. It provides a more balanced
assessment of what digital regulatory reporting can actually do for us and of the minimum
requirements for its effectiveness.

Regulatory technology (Regtech) has a huge potential but also comes with risks, which
we do not fully understand at present. To be sure, the future ahead of us need not be dystopian.
However, we need to refrain from the naïve view of a problem-free data-driven future in which
machines will take care of everything. The digitalisation of reporting requirements in the field
of financial regulation is an exemplary case in point. The chief purpose of reporting
requirements is to increase transparency, promote market discipline and help financial
regulators detect and respond to emerging risks. However, the existing reporting processes are

1
See notably Aaron Wright and Primavera De Filippi, ‘Decentralized Blockchain Technology and the Rise of Lex
Cryptographia’ (2015) SSRN preprint, https://ssrn.com/abstract=2580664; Anthony J Casey and Anthony Niblett,
‘The Death of Rules and Standards’ (2017) 92(4) Indiana Law Journal 1401.
2
The scholarship focuses primarily on Financial Technology (FinTech), technology governance, and competition
law issues associated with sandboxes for FinTech experimentation. See Eva Micheler and Anna Whaley,
‘Regulatory Technology: Replacing law with computer code’ (2020) 21(2) European Business Organisation Law
Review 349; Saule T Omarova, ‘Technology v. Technocracy: Fintech as a Regulatory Challenge’ (2020) 6 Journal
of Financial Regulation 75; Rory Van Loo, ‘Making Innovation More Competitive: The Case of Fintech’ (2018)
65 UCLA Law Review 232; in parallel to this literature, a more theoretical discourse examines the advent of
algorithmic regulation, and the impact of technology on legal concepts and doctrines. See Roger Brownsword,
Eloise Scotford and Karen Yeung (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Law, Regulation and Technology (OUP 2017);
Martin Lodge and Karen Yeung (eds), Algorithmic Regulation (OUP 2019); and Mireille Hildebrandt, ‘Law as
information in the era of data-driven agency’ (2016) 79(1) MLR 1.
A. GEORGOSOULI

complex, time consuming and expensive for the financial industry. At the same time, delays in
reporting and data of poor quality often compromises the effectiveness of financial regulators
and their overall responsiveness to risks in the delivery of their mandate. These concerns have
become powerful drivers of a series of Digital Regulatory Reporting (‘DRR’) initiatives. From
the side of the financial industry, the International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA)
is a leading champion of digitalisation and is currently running an industry-wide DRR initiative
for the trade reporting requirements under the European Market Infrastructure Regulation
(EMIR) as well as the reporting requirements of the US Commodity Futures Trading
Commission (CFTC). Financial regulators around the world have also launched a series of
DRR initiatives. For example, in the UK, there are pilots and projects run by the Financial
Conduct Authority (FCA) and the Bank of England in collaboration with leading members of
the industry. In the EU, there are similar initiatives run by the European Commission and by
the European Supervisory Authorities (ESAs). There is also a variety of international projects.
Notable examples include, the G-20 TechSprint initiative and the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS) Innovation Hub’s Project Ellipse.

DRR is a machine-readable and machine-executable system of automatic reporting, and


it is a conspicuous case of innovation in the field of Regtech. If fully developed and
successfully implemented, it will enable the industry to interpret and implement reporting rules
consistently via a common machine-readable code thanks to -inter alia- a standardized data
model. The DRR will cut the time and cost of data reporting and processing, and will reduce
mistakes, ambiguities and inconsistencies. At the same time, DRR is set to improve the
monitoring and oversight capabilities of financial regulators. Specifically, it is anticipated that,
thanks to digitalisation and further technological advancements, financial regulators will be
able to access a larger pool of data and, as a result, to make more accurate predictions. They
will be better able to detect emerging risks and intervene earlier and in a more targeted fashion.
Financial regulators will also be able to pull data themselves instead of requiring members of
the industry to submit data, hence, obviating the need for extra oversight.3

Despite the fact that the digitalisation of reporting requirements is currently at the stage
of experimentation, there are plans to expand digitalisation beyond reporting. DRR enthusiasts
claim that the digitalisation project will revolutionise how we use rules, with some of them
going as far as to argue for a future of rule-use without humans, as everything—from the
engineering of code-based micro-directives to the execution of those micro-directives for
compliance purposes—will be machine-driven. There is no doubt that there are benefits to be

3
On the distinction between the “push” and the “pull” model of reporting, see Bank of England, ‘Transforming
Data Collection from the UK Financial Sector’ (Discussion Paper, January 2020) 42–5,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/paper/2020/transforming-data-collection-from-the-uk-financial-
sector.pdf?la=en&hash=6E6132B4F7AF681CCB425B0171B4CF43D82E7779.

32
A. GEORGOSOULI

gained from digitalisation; however, the view that DRR will dramatically change how we use
rules as we know it is not entirely persuasive.

I provide three arguments to support my thesis.4 The first draws attention to the limited
translatability of regulatory content into code. To make rules machine-executable, one must
make them machine-readable. Machines deal in black and white. As a result, it is necessary to
use unambiguous language to facilitate machine-readability and machine-executability, but
here lies a problem: While coding is possible, there is an increased risk of loss of meaning.
Most probably, it is not too difficult to turn highly technical standards into their digital
equivalent compared to vague regulatory stipulations (e.g., the requirement to treat customers
fairly). However, even technical standards come with a marginal degree of ambiguity.
Furthermore, they need to be read in conjunction with more open-ended rules in order to apply
correctly. The second argument concerns the limited capabilities of machines in making
determinations (e.g., with regard to what sort of data needs to be reported) given the existing
and foreseeable development of the relevant technology. Machines can retrieve factual
information, match past legal facts, enlist similarities and differences, rank data in terms of
relevance, and use statistical modelling to output compliance scores in impressive speed.
However, machines cannot engage in normative reasoning equally well especially when
compared to humans. This is due to their constrained capacity to root their determinations on
principled-judgments according to public criteria that are open to intelligible scrutiny and
contestation. Finally, the third argument refers to an indispensable aspect of rule-use, namely,
that of human interpretation, which is deliberative in nature and crucial for the legitimacy of
financial regulation. Contrary to received wisdom, regulatory law is not there just for the sole
purpose of communicating to regulatees what they may or may not do a predictable fashion.
Over and above communicating stipulations, prescriptions and the regulators’ expectations,
regulatory law embeds interpretive processes of constructive deliberation whose function is to
legitimise the regulator’s highly consequential decisions. Undoubtedly, interpretation is a
burdensome task. It is also true that humans err and that they often exhibit predictable and
irrational behaviour. However, they remain moral agents capable of self-reflection, of holding
each other accountable, and of taking responsibility for their acts and omissions.

To conclude, the digitalisation of reporting requirements will be beneficial if carefully


designed, but it will not dramatically change how we use rules. Even though any projection
about the future is bound to be an imprecise science, there are reasons to believe that digital
reporting will most likely become an extension of the existing regulatory practice.5 From this,

4
For a more detailed discussion see Andromachi Georgosouli, ‘Metarules, judgment and the algorithmic future
of financial regulation in the UK’ (winter 2023) Oxford Journal of Legal Studies (forthcoming).
5
Martin Lodge and Andrea Mennicken, ‘Reflecting on Public Service Regulation by Algorithm’ in Martin Lodge
and Karen Yeung (eds), Algorithmic Regulation (OUP 2019) 178, 180.

33
A. GEORGOSOULI

it follows that the real challenge is not how to move to a system of data-driven governance with
little or no reliance on human interpretation—but how to design rulebooks which will help their
human users take advantage of their own general intelligence, and of the specialist intelligence
of machines.6

6
On the distinction between “specialist” and “general” intelligence see Margaret Boden, Artificial Intelligence, A
Very Short Introduction (OUP 2018) 18.

34
VIII. Challenges Posed by the Second Generation of Digital Technologies to Financial
Regulatory Strategies

Dr Teresa Rodríguez de las Heras Ballell


(Universidad Carlos III de Madrid)

1. Introduction: The Context

The financial sector, traditionally receptive and permeable to technological advances,


is not oblivious to the extraordinary opportunities provided by the second generation of digital
technologies (AI, platforms, DLT, big data, augmented and immersive reality, IoT). There is
increasing penetration of digital technologies in financial markets, in adoption rates1 among
users, expanding presence of fintech firms,2 and the growing use of fintech solutions3 by
incumbents.4 The increasingly popular term “Fintech” captures the accelerated transformation
of contemporary financial markets driven and enabled by technology, and encapsulates its
multifarious potential impact on services, market structures, and business models.5

1
See EY, ‘EY Fintech Adoption Index 2017, The Rapid Emergence of Fintech’ (2017) 5-7 and 12,
https://assets.ey.com/content/dam/ey-sites/ey-com/en_gl/topics/banking-and-capital-markets/ey-fintech-adoptio
n-index-2017.pdf, showing a global fintech adoption of 33 percent compared to the 16 percent rate in 2015; the
adoption increases up to 46 percent across five emerging markets (Brazil, China, India, Mexico and South Africa),
whereas the adoption rates are disparate in European countries. Among the twenty countries studied, the highest
percentage in a European country corresponds to the United Kingdom with 42 percent, followed by Spain with
37 percent. Other European countries surveyed, except Germany, are at or below the threshold of 30 percent. The
report pivots on a definition of fintech that includes not only early-stage start-ups and new entrants, but also scale-
ups, maturing firms and even non-financial services firms).
22
See A Fraile Carmona et al., Competition issues in the Area of Financial Technology (FinTech) (2018) Policy
Dep’t for Econ., Sci. and Quality of Life Policies, European Parliament, 32, https://www.europarl.europa.eu/
RegData/etudes/IDAN/2019/631061/IPOL_IDA(2019)631061_EN.pdf, illustrating the size of the fintech market
in number of fintech-labelled technologies, according to the Crunchbase database that provides 4,359 companies
in 2018 classified as fintech. The authors refine the overall number of fintech-labelled companies, adjusting the
figure to 3,852. Upon the adjustment, the report identifies that the European Union contributes to the global fintech
sector with 1,020 fintech companies.
3
Fintech is not only describing an ecosystem of innovative startups invading the financial markets with
groundbreaking technological solutions to revolutionise the delivery of financial services; it also comprises
incumbent firms that adopt advanced technological strategies to effectively compete and innovate. Bernardo
Nicoletti, The Future of Fintech: Integrating Finance and Technology in Financial Services (Springer 2017) 13.
4
Traditional commercial banks indicated increasing adoption of machine learning techniques to increase
efficiency. Institute of International Finance, ‘Machine Learning in Credit Risk’, August 2019, 2nd Edition
Summary Report, 2, https://www.iif.com/Portals/0/Files/content/Research/iif_mlcr_2nd_8_15_19.pdf. That
strategy would provide signs that incumbents are reacting to fintech challenges by the implementation of
technology-driven solutions. Ibid. In addition, PwC’s 2018 Digital Banking Consumer Survey does also stress the
need for traditional banks to reconsider how they sell and provide their services and how they interact with their
customers. See PwC Financial Services, PWC’S 2018 Digital Banking Consumer Survey: Mobile users set the
agenda (2018), https://www.pwc.com/il/he/bankim/assets/2018/PwC%202018%20Digital%20Banking%20Cons
umer%20Survey.pdf. The incorporation of digital technologies—namely, as highlighted by the report, mobile-
based services and products—is crucial.
5
See generally Capgemini et al., ‘World FinTech Report 2018’ (2018), https://www.capgemini.com/wp-
content/uploads/2018/02/world-fintech-report-wftr-2018.pdf (spotting and describing the potential impact of
emerging technologies in the provision of customer-oriented financial services—artificial intelligences, data
analytics, robotics, distributed ledger technologies, biometrics, platforms, internet of things and sensors,
augmented reality, chatbots, etc.).
T. RODRÍGUEZ DE LAS HERAS BALLELL

Fintech is not, indeed, a single, global phenomenon. It comprises a vast complexity of


multifaceted, evolving groups of solutions, applications, and uses based on technology-
intensive strategies. Consequently, the expansive use of digital technologies crosscuts the
entire financial market and impacts the structure of the market, the market actors, the provision
of services, the type of products, and the relationships with the clients and the supervising
authorities. Such a transversality of fintech effects reveals the severity and the extent of the
impact on financial regulatory strategies and supervision models.

To assess the adequacy of regulation and devise a fit-for-purpose regulatory response,


a multi-layered regulatory strategy is proposed in this presentation summary (at Part 2).
Financial digital innovation (fintech) is stratified in three layers: the structural layer, the
material layer, and the personal layer—each of which identifies and analyses the impact of
digital innovation on a financial-market dimension. Thus, this paper devises and develops a
multi-layered regulatory response to face fintech challenges.

2. The Layers of Financial Digital Innovation Theory

The “layers of digital financial innovation” theory is based on the idea that the impact
of digital technology on financial markets penetrates all of its layers and thus, produces specific
effects and poses singular challenges at each layer. Dismembering or disassembling the digital
impact in different layers provides a better structured framework to classify new models, new
products or services, and new operators, identify and assess the resultant risks, where they arise,
and detect which traditional components of the regulatory and supervisory schemes could more
likely be affected.

Structural layer: architecture, structures and models

The first visible impact of digital technology is on financial market architecture:


particularly, market structure and business models. The architecture of financial markets is
being reshaped under new structures. It is therefore described as the structural layer of the
fintech challenge.

Digital innovation has contributed to the development of two structural models in the
market, which interestingly reflect two diametrically opposed architectures: platforms and
distributed ledgers. On one hand, as the digital economy has transformed into a platform
economy, platform-based models have populated the financial sector.6 The expansion of

6
The continuous growth of crowdfunding platforms and other alternative finance platforms illustrates this
statement. See e.g., The Cambridge Centre for Alternative Finance, ‘Shifting Paradigms: The 4th European
Alternative Finance Benchmarking Report’ (2019), https://www.crowdfundinsider.com/wp-content/uploads/20
19/04/CCAF-4th-european-alternative-finance-benchmarking-industry-report-shifting-paradigms-April-
2019.pdf. According to this report, in 2017, the alternative finance volume from across Europe grew by 36 percent,
while the Asia-Pacific region and the Americas experienced a 4-year average annual growth rate of 145 percent

36
T. RODRÍGUEZ DE LAS HERAS BALLELL

crowdfunding, aggregators, multilateral trading systems, and other sharing-inspired financial


models—including social trading and copy trading—has been substantially facilitated and
accelerated by platform models.7 Platforms offer self-regulated, multilateral, centralised, and
trustworthy models for the provision of financial services.8 On the other hand, platforms
concurrently coexist and compete with decentralised schemes operating on distributed ledger
technologies (DLT). Unlike platforms, the use of DLT relies on decentralised schemes,
distributed trust, and peer-to-peer (P2P) operations.9

The structural layer has a two-fold impact on regulatory strategies and practices.

First, it dilutes the classical distinction between markets and financial service providers,
insofar as the use (primarily) of platforms to provide financial services assimilates its structure
and operation to genuine markets.10 As the boundaries among markets (exchanges and
exchange-like models), traditional financial intermediaries, and new services providers are
blurring, the classical regulatory and supervisory schemes seem unsuited, or at least too
simplified, to embrace hybrid models. The emergence and flourishing of Multilateral Trading
Facilities represents an illustrative example of how these firm-market figures require a hybrid
regulatory approach.11 Despite the value of this suitable precedent, the contemporary

and 89 percent respectively. Ibid 22–23. In numbers of operating crowdfunding platforms, as per the data provided
by Massolution, in 2014 the threshold of 1,250 platforms active in the world had been reached. Massolution, ‘The
Crowdfunding Industry Report’ (2015) 2015CF 82, https://www.smv.gob.pe/Biblioteca/temp/catalogacion/
C8789.pdf. Without specifying which fintech are based on platforms, Deloitte also reports growing data in fintech.
See Deloitte, ‘Fintech by the Numbers: Incumbents, Startups, Investors Adapt to Maturing Ecosystem’ (2017) 7,
https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/us/Documents/financial-services/us-dcfs-fintech-by-the-
numbers-web.pdf.
7
See generally Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European
Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, Online Platforms and the Digital Single
Market Opportunities and Challenges for Europe (25 May 2016) COM (2016) 288 final, 2, https://eur-
lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?qid=1590005545023&uri=CELEX:52016DC0288.
8
Teresa Rodríguez de las Heras Ballell, The Legal Anatomy of Electronic Platforms: A Prior Study to Assess the
Need of a Law of Platforms in the EU, 3 ITALIAN L.J. 149 (2017); see generally Teresa Rodríguez de las Heras
Ballell, El régimen jurídico de los Mercados Electrónicos Cerrados (e-marketplaces) [The Juridical Regime of
the Closed Electronic Markets (E-Marketplaces)] (2006) 56–58, 210–29, describing platforms as closed, self-
regulated environments and explaining the functions and role of platform operators as regulators, supervisors, and
trust-generators.
9
Distinctive features of DLT-based schemes are based on the structural and operational characteristics of
distributed ledger technologies as explained by scholars and experts Aaron Wright and Primavera De Filippi in
Decentralized Blockchain Technology and the Rise of Lex Cryptographia (2015), SSRN preprint,
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2580664.
10
Ruben Lee, What is an Exchange? The Automation, Management, and Regulation of Financial Markets (Oxford
University Press 1998) 117–39, defining and describing trading platforms as alternative trading systems to
traditional exchanges.
11
Jan De Bel, ‘Automated Trading Systems and the Concept of an “Exchange” in an International Context.
Proprietary Systems: A Regulatory Headache!’ (1993) 14 U. PA. J. INT’L BUS. L. 169, 208; Jonathan R Macey
and Maureen O’Hara, Regulating Exchanges and Alternative Trading Systems: A Law and Economics Perspective
(1999) 28 J. LEGAL STUD. 17.

37
T. RODRÍGUEZ DE LAS HERAS BALLELL

multiplication of hybrid models12 and their proliferation in the fintech sector invite dynamic
solutions to deal with architectural transformation on a large scale. In the context of a digital
economy that has evolved into a platform economy, market-like models compete with
traditional exchanges,13 platform operators act as new intermediaries, and platforms serve as
support for the provision of new services and the running of innovative business activities (e.g.,
aggregators, social trading, copy trading, and trading platforms).

Second, these new structures do not fit into the current regulatory framework, as they
relocate the regulation/supervision focus. Under platform models, new players come to the
financial fore: platform operators. As platform operators are not—in some business models—
direct providers of financial services, but mere enablers for platform users to interact and carry
out financial-like activities, it is reasonable to wonder how the financial market regulations
should address platform operators. Are platform operators new financial intermediaries or
instead, simply intermediary service providers (digital intermediaries) facilitating the delivery
of financial services? The regulatory response to crowdfunding platforms, for instance,
illustrates a genuine financial-operator-based regulatory strategy. However, other platforms
(such as social trading, aggregators, and copy trading) have not attracted the same regulatory
attention and might not deserve an equivalent response.

Contrarily, DLT-based models pose a completely different challenge to regulators.


These models operate on a decentralised and disintermediated basis. In the absence of an
identifiable central operator, the traditional operator-based regulatory strategy does not work.
Although the ecosystem of DLT-based models comprises a variety of variants—from
permissioned to permissionless—the regulator faces the question of how to regulate a
decentralised structure

Material layer: services, products and instruments

The second angle of digital impact is on the nature and attributes of financial products
and services and, therefore, on the perimeters of financial activity. The activity layer represents
the second layer of the fintech challenge.

Technology applications to products and services can transform the characteristics of


financial activities and enable the configuration of new products and services. Accordingly, the
applicable legal regime might need to be reconsidered to some extent.

Several examples may serve as illustrations:

12
Thomas W Malone, ‘Modeling Coordination in Organizations and Markets’ (1987) 33 MGMT. SCI. 1317;
Thomas W Malone et al., ‘Electronic Mkt. and Electronic Hierarchies’ (1987) 30 COMM. OF THE ACM 484.
13
See generally Martin Bichler, The Future of e-Markets. Multidimensional Market Mechanisms (Cambridge
University Press 2001).

38
T. RODRÍGUEZ DE LAS HERAS BALLELL

First, the application of artificial intelligence (AI) throughout the value chain (front-
office, middle-office, and back-office)14 and along the entire array of financial services. Among
them, robo-advisers provide customised, low-cost, highly efficient algorithm-driven financial
advice. Considering their level of automation, can robo-advisers be legally treated as human
financial advisers? Can liability rules and regulatory requirements be applied to robo-advice,
or exclusively to the development of the software and the establishment of the pre-conditions
of the programme? Thus, robo-advisers represent another expression of fintech that might
require regulatory attention. On one hand, the advent of robo-advisers entails the emergence of
new actors in the financial markets. Robo-advising solutions can be provided by fintech start-
ups, technological companies, or traditional financial institutions. In the two former cases, it
implies the irruption of new actors competing with incumbents (fintech companies and bigtech
firms). On the other hand, the automation of financial advice also poses a conceptual challenge.
The existing rules for human-centric financial advice have to be applied to an algorithm-driven
system. To a certain extent, that implies a shift of the regulatory focus from a human activity
to an automated process. In fact, the spotlight changes from behavioural aspects of human
conduct to the design and the operation of an algorithm-driven system.

Second, P2P payments enable the completion of payments between users. The
decentralised network enables users to complete payments. Should payment services rules be
applied there? And if so, to whom?

Third, if insurance companies incorporate big data to foresee the likelihood of the
covered risks, and adjust the insurance fees accordingly (“dynamic insurance”), would the duty
to notify a change in risk be relevant?

Finally, as a result of a burgeoning trend towards the tokenisation of assets, values, and
services, the market is receiving digital assets and customised tokens with an uncertain and
intricate legal characterisation. In conjunction with DLT, tokenisation unleashes opportunities
for asset management, fund raising, investing, and other financial services.

These examples reveal that the technological impact on the activity layer may affect
four groups of attributes of products, services, and activities in the financial markets. Insofar
as algorithm-driven solutions enable highly automated tasks and processes and increasingly
autonomous decision-making, technology impacts the procedural attributes of the activity,
infusing celerity, automation, and autonomy. The facilitation of P2P schemes for the provision
of financial—or quasi-financial—services represents the impact on structural attributes. A

14
Chatbots, virtual assistants, credit scoring, KYC/AML applications or smart contracts exemplify varied
possibilities for the use of AI in all financial sectors. Ana Fernández, Inteligencia Artificial en los Servicios
Financieros (29 March 2019) Boletín Económico 2/2019, 3–4. These prospective applications show today
different levels of maturity in the market. Ibid, Diagram 1, 3.

39
T. RODRÍGUEZ DE LAS HERAS BALLELL

widespread use of big data along the successive stages of the activity process affects the
attributes related to the magnitude, scale, and scope of the activity.15 Interestingly, such a scale
shift is not a mere incremental change, but a radical transformation likely to redefine the
information asymmetries and reshape the traditional schemes to allocate duties and liabilities.

Finally, the possibilities and the extent of tokenisation touch the very core of the legal
categorisation of financial instruments by challenging the current demarcation for financial
supervision and regulation.

Personal layer: From disintermediation to reintermediation

Digital technology has not only reconfigured the profile of incumbents, but has also
triggered the emergence of new players competing with incumbents. Fintech has then put in
motion a cycle of disintermediation and reintermediation.16 The entry of crowdfunding
platforms in the credit market, the emergence of aggregators and comparators in the insurance
and the banking sector, or the increasing competition of bigtech companies providing techfin
solutions in payments are some examples of the transformation of the financial intermediation
arena. These examples reveal a circular process of removing intermediaries in certain areas,
followed by the emergence of new intermediaries in others.

New market players have become protagonists with the proliferation of platform
models. Platform operators are not necessarily financial intermediaries or financial service
providers, who can indeed become platform users. In particular, sharing-based platform models
have raised concerns about the genuine role of platform operators and consequently, the
applicable legal regime. The recent Court of Justice decisions on the Uber Spain Case 17 in
2017, the Uber France Case18 in 2018, and, lately, the Airbnb Ireland Case19 in 2019 have
contributed with a case study to the debate.20 Likewise, burgeoning fintech models give rise to
new players: aggregators, comparators, robo-advisers, and recommenders.

15
According to the European Commission Communication, the term “big data” refers to “large amounts of
different types of data produced with high velocity from a high number of various types of sources,” whose
processing requires new tools and methods, such as powerful processors, software and algorithms. Hence, the
disruptive character of big data pivots on three “Vs”: velocity, volume, and variety. Communication from the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the
Committee of the Regions, Towards a Thriving Data-Driven Economy (2 July 2014) COM (2014) 442 final, 4,
https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?qid=1590006916232&uri=CELEX:52014DC0442.
16
See Shaun French and Andrew Leyshon, ‘The New, New Financial System? Towards a Conceptualization of
Financial Reintermediation’ (2004) 11(2) Rev. of Int’l Political Econ. 263.
17
See generally Case C-434/15, Asociación Profesional Elite Taxi v. Uber Systems Spain SL, 2017 E.C.R. 981.
18
Case C-320/16, Uber France SAS v. Nalib Bensalem, 2018 E.C.R. 221.
19
Case C-390/18, Airbnb Ireland, 2019 E.C.R. 1112.
20
In the three cases described above, the European Court of Justice has been asked about the role of platform
operators—Airbnb and Uber—in the rental industry and the urban transport sector, respectively. The Court held
that Uber is not a mere digital intermediary-information society services provider. Rather, Uber operates as a
genuine transport service provider, insofar as it exercises certain control over the quality of the service, the drivers,

40
T. RODRÍGUEZ DE LAS HERAS BALLELL

Thus, the “layers of digital financial innovation” theory has been formulated in an
attempt to understand the true impact of this disruption on financial regulation and to dissect
its implications. In accordance with this original theory, this paper explains how challenges are
located on three layers of financial markets: structures and architectures; market players; and
products, services and activities.

The observation of each layer reveals diverse consequences of the fintech impact and
announces different challenges. The “layers of digital financial innovation” theory aspires to
serve as a theoretical and analytical framework to understand prospective technological
advances and to ensure that regulation is well-equipped to face future challenges.

and the cars. The Court also held that by determining the maximum fare, Uber exerts decisive influence over the
conditions under which drivers provide their services. Accordingly, Uber is not subjected to the legal regime
applicable to intermediary service providers, but instead, to the regime applicable to transport service providers.
However, the Court held under the same analysis that Airbnb has neither control nor decisive influence on the
rental transactions conducted between the users within its platform. Consequently, Airbnb is not treated as a real
estate agent, but as a mere digital intermediary instead. The diverse legal treatment entails different legal
obligations as well as liability regimes.

41
IX. AI in Credit Lending and Enforcement Decision-Making by Banks: Accuracy,
Risk, Data and Consumer Protection

Dr Jeannie Marie Paterson


(University of Melbourne)

1. Overview

Artificial intelligence (AI) offers opportunities for improving efficiency, cost and
inclusion in consumer credit, including in informing the credit scores and credit assessments
that influence a lenders’ decision to lend. Equally, standards for ethical, responsible, and
trustworthy AI have a particularly important role to play in consumer credit transactions, which
are characterised by an inequality of bargaining power and information asymmetries. 1 This
presentation summary agrees with recommendations for greater transparency and
accountability in the use of AI generally, and particularly in lending decisions. The paper also
argues that the design of policy and regulation to address concerns about the risks of harm to
consumers from the use of AI in making lending decisions should recognise the complexities
of practice, technology and existing law in this field. Concerns about bias and financial
inclusion in AI credit rating and assessment should be addressed with clarity in objectives and
precision in proposed interventions. Moreover, the value of responsible lending, that is, lending
in ways that do not cause undue financial hardship, should be recognised. This approach does
not stifle innovation but rather, by promoting genuinely responsible AI, supports the
trustworthiness of AI in consumer credit decision making.2

2. AI in Lending

Fintech and open banking initiatives

The growing capacity of the cluster of data-driven technologies commonly grouped


under the title of AI, such as machine learning, neural networks, and natural language
processing, is transforming established financial services. AI is being used in fraud detection,
cybersecurity, marketing, and onboarding new clients.3 New consumer-facing AI-informed
services are also being made available, such as through chatbots for seamless consumer-lender
interfaces, robo-advisers,4 and personalised budgeting tools.5 Governments have supported

1
Jeannie Ma Paterson and Yvette Maker, ‘Artificial Intelligence and Consumer Protection’ in Ernest Lim and
Phillip Morgan (eds), The Cambridge Handbook of Private Law and Artificial Intelligence (Cambridge University
Press, 2023), http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3973179.
2
See AI Singapore, https://aisingapore.org/.
3
Bank of England and Financial Conduct Authority, ‘Machine Learning in UK Financial Services’ (Report,
October 2019) 8.
4
Jeannie M Paterson, ‘Making robo-advisers careful? Duties of care in providing automated financial advice to
consumers’ (2023) Law and Financial Markets Review 1-18, doi:10.1080/17521440.2023.2196027.
5
Jeannie M Paterson, Tim Miller, and Henrietta Lyons, ‘Demystifying Consumer-Facing Fintech: Accountability
for Automated Advice Tools’ (April 11, 2023). Zofia Bednarz and Monika Zalnieriute (eds), Money, Power and
J. M. PATERSON

developments in financial AI to improve market competition and consumer wellbeing,


including through open banking initiatives6 and regulatory sandboxes.7

Big data and AI in lending to consumers

Accompanying these developments has been considerable interest in using the


combination of big data and AI for lending decisions. AI in lending decisions, supported by
open banking, is touted for its potential to provide more consistent, efficient and fine-grained
assessments 8 and make credit available to a wider number of borrowers.9 Concerns have also
been raised about the risk of AI in credit scoring and assessments to give rise to inaccuracy and
bias. These concerns have prompted statutory and soft law interventions. Notably, the proposed
EU AI Act places the use of AI for making decisions about lending in the high-risk category
of uses, which would be subject to robust requirements of transparency, testing and
monitoring.10 Other jurisdictions stress the need for AI used in decision-making for access to
public and private goods to meet the demands of codes of AI ethics or responsible AI
frameworks.11 In the US, the Equal Credit Opportunity Act (regulation B) prohibits lenders
from discriminating against borrowers on the basis of protected attributes, such as age, colour,
religion, national origin, sex, marital status, or age, including in decisions made by
algorithms.12

AI: From Automated Banks to Automated States (Cambridge University Press,


2023), https://ssrn.com/abstract=4414789.
6
Douglas W Arner, Ross P Buckley, and Dirk A Zetzsche, ‘Open Banking, Open Data and Open Finance: Lessons
from the European Union’ in Linda Jeng (ed), Open Banking (Oxford University Press 2021), Chapter 8, UNSW
Law Research Paper No. 21-69, University of Hong Kong Faculty of Law Research Paper No. 2021/49,
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3961235; Christoph Frei, ‘Open Banking: Opportunities and Risks’ (January 3, 2023)
in Thomas Walker, Elaheh Nikbakht, and Maher Kooli (eds), The Fintech Disruption: How Financial Innovation
Is Transforming the Banking Industry (Palgrave Macmillan 2023) 167–190,
https://ssrn.com/abstract=4316760 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4316760
7
Douglas W Arner et al., ‘Sustainability, FinTech and Financial Inclusion’ (2020) 21 European Business
Organization Law Review 27, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s40804-020-00183-y
8
Ross P Buckley and Natalia Jevglevskaja, ‘Australia’s Consumer Data-Sharing Regime: A World-Leading
Reform’ (January 1, 2022) University of New South Wales Law Journal, forthcoming, UNSW Law Research
Paper No. 22-2, https://ssrn.com/abstract=4042404.
9
See e.g., Dirk Zetzsche et al., ‘From FinTech to TechFin: The Regulatory Challenges of Data-Driven Finance’
(2017) 14 European Banking Institute Working Paper Series 2017 – no. 6.
10
Gerald Spindler, ‘Algorithms, Credit Scoring, and the New Proposals of the EU for an AI Act and on a Consumer
Credit Directive’ in Martin Ebers and Susana Navas (eds), Law and Financial Markets Review (Cambridge
University Press 2023).
11
See e.g., soft-law instruments established in Singapore (https://aisingapore.org/); in the US (https://www.ni
st.gov/artificial-intelligence); and at the supranational level (https://www.oecd.org/digital/artifici al-intelligence/).
12
Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, ‘§ 1002.1 Authority, Scope, and Purpose’, https://www.consumerfinanc
e.gov/rules-policy/regulations/1002/1/.

43
J. M. PATERSON

3. AI and Data in Consumer Credit

AI in credit assessments and credit scores

The decision about whether to lend to a consumer is usually described as credit


assessment or credit under-writing. Credit assessments are influenced by a number of
considerations, including prudential requirements, the lender’s risk profile, financial
modelling, regulatory requirements and the borrower’s credit score/report. Credit scoring,
usually performed by a third-party ratings agency, involves calculating a score about the way
in which a consumer has previously managed credit on the basis of data gathered from lenders,
and in some jurisdictions, sources such as utilities.13

Lenders have long used statistical credit risk modelling to determine who gets a loan,
and many of these credit assessment processes have been automated using computer software.
Lenders may also use insights from AI to refine lending decisions. 14 These techniques may
allow new insights from the data available about borrowers that is not captured in existing
financial modelling.

Data in lending decisions

The use of AI in decision-making about lending is primarily fuelled by the increased


availability of consumer data, was well as improved computer processing power. One of the
most significant initiatives is open banking, with market-led adoption in Singapore, supported
by the Monetary Authority of Singapore,15 and mandatory schemes in Australia16 and the UK.17
Before open banking, lenders might look at borrowers’ data, but would do this via the practice
of screen scraping.18 Open banking enables consumers to direct the transfer of this data without
giving access to their accounts to prospective lenders.

4. Risks of AI in Consumer Credit Assessments

AI inaccuracy and opacity

13
Nydia Remolina, ‘The Role of Financial Regulators in the Governance of Algorithmic Credit Scoring’ (15
March 2022) SMU Centre for AI & Data Governance Research Paper No. 2/2022, 7.
14
Matthew Bruckner, ‘Preventing Predation & Encouraging Innovation in Fintech Lending’, 72 Consumer Fin.
L. Q. Rep. 370, 371 (2019), who gives the examples of Lenddo and Zest.
15
Joe Jelinek, ‘The state of Open Banking in APAC today’ The Payers (20 January 2023), https://the
paypers.com/expert-opinion/the-state-of-open-banking-in-apac-today--1259954/. See also Leong, Emma and
Jodi Gardner, ‘Open Banking in the UK and Singapore: Open Possibilities for Enhancing Financial Inclusion’
(2021) 5 Journal of Business Law.
16
Australian Banking Association, ‘What is Open Banking?’, https://www.ausbanking.org.au/priorities/open-
banking/.
17
Open Banking, https://www.openbanking.org.uk/.
18
Natalia Jevglevskaja and Ross P Buckley, ‘Screen Scraping of Bank Customer Data: A Lamentable Practice’
(2023) UNSW Law Research Paper No. 23-3, https://ssrn.com/abstract=4382528 .

44
J. M. PATERSON

Where the use of AI in credit scoring or assessment relies on large data sets and complex
neural networks, the accuracy of and reasons for decisions become particularly hard to
ascertain.19 Responsible AI principles and some regulatory regimes require lenders to give
explanations of why borrowers are denied credit,20 so called explainable AI.21 It is unclear how
effective these processes are in the face of complex machine learning algorithms and low
borrower financial literacy.22

AI bias and discrimination

A key concern about the use of AI in lending decisions is bias in training data leading
to discrimination in outcomes.23 The risk arises because any data-driven decision may replicate
and amplify previous bias in lending.24 Typically, and in some places in compliance with the
law, a lender automating a lending decision or using the insights would not directly include
protected attributes. The concern about bias nonetheless remains. Machine learning algorithms
may find the proxies in the data for protected attributes to replicate and amplify that bias.25
Discrimination in credit rating or assessments can be difficult to identify, especially where the
decision is based on very large data and uses complex machine learning algorithms or neural
networks. Accordingly, most of the proposed regulatory responses to responsible or ethical AI
require robust systems for monitoring the inputs and design of AI systems and oversight and
review for the outputs.26

Thin data and financial exclusion

Greater financial inclusion is another commonly cited aim of AI in credit rankings and
assessment, as well as in open banking. Certainly, improving the credit assessment process
should reduce the cost of lending to many consumers, thus making credit more readily

19
Matthew Bruckner, ‘Regulating Fintech Lending’ (2018) 37 Banking & Fin. Services Pol’y Rep. 1,3; Mikella
Hurley and Julius Adebayo, ‘Credit Scoring in the Era of Big Data’ (2016) 18(1) Yale Journal of Law and
Technology 148, 153.
20
See e.g., US Equal Credit Opportunity Act Regulation B; see also Consumer Financial Protection Bureau,
‘Consumer Financial Protection Circular 2022-03, https://www.consumerfinance.gov/compliance/circulars/
circular-2022-03-adverse-action-notification-requirements-in-connection-with-credit-decisions-based-on-
complex-algorithms/.
21
Tim Miller, ‘Explainable AI is Dead, Long Live Explainable AI! Hypothesis-driven Decision Support using
Evaluative AI’ (2023) FAccT 2023, https://arxiv.org/abs/2302.12389.
22
Jeannie M Paterson, ‘Misleading AI: Regulatory Strategies for Transparency in Information Intermediary Tools
for Consumer Decision-Making’ (2023) Loyola Consumer Law Review, https://ssrn.com/abstract=4422456.
23
Matthew Bruckner, ‘Preventing Predation & Encouraging Innovation in Fintech Lending’ (2019) 72 Consumer
Fin. L. Q. Rep. 370, 378 (2019); Holli Sargeant, ‘Algorithmic Decision-making in Financial Services: Economic
and Normative Outcomes in Consumer Credit’ (2022) AI Ethics, https://doi.org/10.1007/s43681-022-00236-7.
24 See Sargeant (n 23).
25
See Matthew Bruckner, ‘The Promise and Perils of Algorithmic Lenders’ Use of Big Data’ (2018) 93 Chi. Kent
L. Rev. 3, 25-27.
26
See e.g., the approach taken by the US Federal Trade Commission, https://www.ftc.gov/business-
guidance/blog/2020/04/using-artificial-intelligence-and-algorithms.

45
J. M. PATERSON

available. But some prospective borrowers may miss out on these gains by being found less
credit worthy. Others will not benefit from the advances because they were not benefiting from
mainstream or even fringe lending in the first place.27 Indeed, data scientists speak about
‘noise’ arising from these kinds of ‘thin’ data sets, which means the outcomes simply do not
reflect the creditworthiness of the excluded individuals because there is not enough data to
form an accurate prediction about them.28 Measures to remove bias based on protected
attributes, or proxies for them, in the loan decision will therefore not address financial
exclusion.

5. AI Responsible Lending

Responsible lending

Not all differential treatment is discrimination—it is legitimate for lenders to refuse to


lend to borrowers who are unable to be likely to repay the loan. In some jurisdictions, lenders
have a legal obligation to consider the ability of the borrower to repay without undue
hardship,29 and lending in the face of indicators of overcommitment may amount to
unconscionable or unfair dealing.30 People who cannot get access to credit may struggle with
full participation in society, with limited access to items like transport, consumer goods and
housing. However, consumers who are overcommitted in borrowing risk the profound social
and economic devastation of financial hardship or bankruptcy.31 AI models used in credit
scoring and assessment should be tested not only for discriminatory bias, but also the
sustainability of loans made. Moreover, the benefits of AI in lending, if verified, might usefully
be extended to the other field that affects consumers, namely, enforcement decisions. Much
like its use in financial fraud detection, AI might be used to identify the key indicators and
patterns of default and provide more fine-grained basis for enforcing a loan, or even early
proactive intervention.

Predatory lending

A related unaddressed concern about the use of AI in credit scoring or credit assessment
is the potential for it to facilitate predatory lending by unscrupulous lenders. These concerns

27
Mikella Hurley and Julius Adebayo, ‘Credit Scoring in the Era of Big Data’ (2016) 18(1) Yale Journal of Law
and Technology 148, 156.
28
Laura Blattner and Scott Nelson, ‘How Costly is Noise? Data and Disparities in Consumer Credit’ (2021)
https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2105.07554; Bruckner, Matthew, ‘The Promise and Perils of Algorithmic Lenders’
(2018) Use of Big Data, 93 Chi. Kent L. Rev. 3, 18-19.
29
See Jeannie M Paterson and Nicola Howell, ‘Everyday Consumer Credit Overview of Australian Law
Regulating Consumer Home Loans, Credit Cards and Car Loans: Background Paper 4’ (2018) The Royal
Commission into Misconduct in the Banking, Superannuation and Financial Services Industry, Australia.
30
See e.g., Stubbings v Jams 2 [2022] HCA 6.
31
See also Emma Leong, ‘Regulating Borrower Hardship in Australia, Singapore, and Hong Kong: Payment
Holidays During COVID-19 and Beyond’ (2022) Journal of Consumer Policy.

46
J. M. PATERSON

mean that the accountability mechanisms for AI decision-making in lending should require
lenders to review and monitor lending outcomes not only for bias in the loans refused, but also
overcommitment in the loans that are made.

6. Take Away Points

1. AI and big data may be used in credit scoring and credit assessment, and potentially
enforcement decisions;

2. The use of AI in making lending decisions has the potential to improve outcomes for
lenders and borrowers;

3. The kinds of data used in AI decision-making about credit, and in particular the use of
data that is not directly related financial factors (i.e. social media), should be reviewed;

4. Systems for accountability for AI are imperative in guarding against inaccuracy,


discrimination and overcommitment in AI-informed credit scoring or assessments;

5. Improving financial inclusion through the combination of AI and big data requires
deliberate intervention;

6. It may be possible to use AI for predatory lending and this risk requires regulatory
vigilance;

7. Best practice guidelines for the use of AI in credit should be developed;

8. Responsible AI should include a commitment to responsible lending.

47
X. At the Crossroads Where Robo-advisers Stand

Mr Selwyn Lim
(Syfe)

1. Introduction

Robo-advisers set out to empower the individual retail investor and to provide
investment options beyond conventional bank deposits, insurance policies, and self-selected
stocks. The business thesis was that unlike human advisers, robo-advisers:

• are always available;

• help the investor avoid decision paralysis;

• are transparent and without conflict; and

• can scale at close to zero marginal cost.

To that end, the hundreds of thousands of users in Singapore who today use the services
of a robo-adviser to help them to save and invest better are testament to the gap that existed in
the market previously.

Robo-advisers do not exist in a vacuum. They arose to serve a perceived need of the
retail investor for empowered investing, and so the state and regulation of the industry must
continually evolve to keep pace with the context in which it exists. This presentation summary
explores the development of the robo-advisory industry hitherto, the regulatory regime that
governs the industry, the crossroads where it now stands in the face of stagnant regulation in
the context of the above trends, and posits the future of the industry having regard to the twelve
or so robo-advisers in the Singapore market today and their plans for the future. How should
regulation respond?

2. Regulation of Robo-Advisers

From a regulatory standpoint, the Monetary Authority of Singapore (‘MAS’) ought to


be lauded for encouraging the development in Singapore of this most recent wave of growth in
the fintech industry that started in the mid-2010s, and continues to develop now with electronic
payments and decentralised finance. By determining quickly that regulation is technology-
neutral and that the new fintech business models could be regulated under existing laws—the
MAS issued the Guidelines on Provision of Digital Advisory Services (‘Guidelines’) that
provided clarity on how prevailing rules operate to apply to digital advisers—the robo-advisory
industry was able to rapidly take off and carve out a new segment in the investment
intermediary space dominated hitherto by traditional brokerages, banks, insurers, mutual fund
asset managers and independent (human) financial advisers.
S. LIM

There were three aspects of regulation that were unique in driving this development:

• First, the MAS typically required that retail fund management companies need a five-
year track record of managing funds for retail investors, and manage total assets of at
least S$1 billion, before they would be granted a licence to operate in Singapore. The
Guidelines offered a concession—the MAS would licence robo-advisers to operate if
they limit portfolios offered to retail clients to comprise only collective investment
schemes (‘CIS’) that are in substance excluded investment products (i.e. simple
products such as shares and deposits).

• Second, a robo-adviser should only operate client-facing tools that are fully automated,
to avoid undue influence on the advisory and portfolio construction process or the
client’s investment decision.

• Third, the MAS required governance and supervision arrangements to be put in place
to oversee algorithms used by the robo-adviser. There was to be no fault or bias in the
algorithms that could lead to clients suffering a detriment when using the robo-adviser’s
platform to select investments.

Collectively, the above regulatory policies allowed the existing laws governing
financial intermediary supervision under the Securities and Futures Act 2001 (‘SFA’) and the
Financial Advisers Act 2001 (‘FAA’) to remain intact in regulating the robo-advisory industry,
with the touch of overlay regulation arising under the Guidelines.

This means that in practice, robo-advisers who construct portfolios in which their
clients may invest (and handle clients’ moneys in relation to the portfolio management) will be
licensed to carry on fund management activity under the SFA, because they are regarded as
managing a portfolio of securities for their clients. The robo-adviser retains discretion as to the
portfolio composition and its ongoing management. This is referred to as a discretionary
portfolio management service. At the same time, there is an expectation that the robo-adviser
is providing financial advice because its client is reasonably expected to rely on the robo-
adviser when making an investment decision. For this reason, a robo-adviser also holds an
exempt financial adviser status under the FAA.

3. Growth of Robo-Advisers

The robo-advisory industry has grown rapidly in the five years since the MAS issued
the Guidelines. It is estimated that there is now over S$4 billion in assets under management
held by investors in Singapore, much of it for the benefit of the retail investor.

Much of this growth for robo-advisers was catalysed by two trends. First, a significant
pick-up of interest in investing driven by the Covid-19 pandemic, when people fortunate

49
S. LIM

enough to remain employed found themselves with more time and money during lockdown.
Second, the growth of financial commentary in social media, which served to educate the retail
public on investing in ways that were relatable and accessible.

But the industry is at a crossroad. The investing boom during the Covid-19 years has
wilted in a rising interest rate environment which has had the effect of depressing asset prices.
The retail investor has also grown increasingly sophisticated with the barrage of financial
commentary and information that is now easily accessible—they may now prefer investing
without advice, human or digital. Cryptocurrencies and other asset classes (such as private
markets) also offer competition for the investing dollar.

These are not necessarily negative trends for the robo-advisory industry. They bring
about opportunities that could be tapped upon too—but this author submits that the regulatory
framework may need to be refined to allow the industry to continue to flourish.

4. How Should Regulation Respond?

Looking back at the three aspects of regulation examined above, it is submitted that
robo-advisers and the retail investor have both matured over the last decade, and it is time to
bring regulation for robo-advisers into greater parity with the rest of the financial industry.

(a) Expanding regulation

The premise for much of the consumer protection purpose of regulation examined
above—thereby requiring robo-advisers to only construct portfolios of simple products and to
minimise human interaction with the user—may no longer hold true. It would be a more level
playing field for robo-advisers to compete with traditional capital markets intermediaries,
provided that they are able to meet the requirements of existing regulation. Given that
regulation is meant to be technology-neutral, it follows also that robo-advisers ought not to be
denied the benefits of utilising human advisers as a complement to a digital service. Robo-
advisers should also be allowed to construct portfolios which provide investors with more
options, rather than being limited to portfolios comprising CIS that constitute excluded
investment products.

(b) Clarify statutory duty for robo-advisers

It is generally accepted that a robo-adviser which is dual-regulated as a fund manager


and a financial adviser is likely subject to a duty under section 36(1) of the FAA to have a
reasonable basis for making an investment recommendation to a client. In other words, the
robo-adviser is required to ensure that its investment recommendation is suitable for the client,
having due consideration to the client’s investment objectives, financial situation and particular
needs.

50
S. LIM

Section 36 of the FAA sets out the basis for statutory liability for a financial adviser
recommending unsuitable products. It requires that for a client to make out a claim for damages
where a recommendation was made without a reasonable basis, the client must show reliance
on the recommendation, and that it is reasonable, having regard to the recommendation and all
other relevant circumstances, for that client to have purchased the investment in reliance on
the recommendation.

Section 36 was enacted at a time when robo-advisers did not exist. The MAS has itself,
in the Investigation Report on the Sale and Marketing of Structured Notes Linked to Lehman
Brothers, noted that “(i) whether an investor bringing an action against a financial adviser can
prove that there was reliance; (ii) whether such reliance was reasonable; and (iii) to what extent,
if any, the recommendation could be shown to have affected the investor’s actual decision to
invest is a matter that would need to be established by each investor based on the specific facts
and circumstances at the time of purchase. Establishing such a case in law would depend,
among other things, on the oral and documentary evidence as to what transpired between the
client and the representative of his [financial adviser] and what documents the client signed as
part of the transaction process”.

In this regard, it is submitted that it is particularly difficult to establish the reliance


element in the context of a robo-advisory service. In a fully automated digital process where
there is no human interaction between a robo-adviser and its client, and where clients may be
told (via a digital prompt) that an investment is unsuitable for them but they choose to
nevertheless to proceed with the investment, it can be difficult for a robo-adviser to accept that
a client has solely relied on its recommendation when making a losing investment, or for a
client to admit that he had in fact self-selected the losing investment on the platform without
any real intention to rely on the advice dispensed on the platform. The line between whether a
platform is providing full, partial, product-only or execution-only advice, and whether an
investor’s insistence to proceed even in the face of a risk warning on the platform amounts to
non-reliance and acceptance of the risk, therefore becomes blurred.

There is also the technical point as to whether the reference to “investment product” in
section 36 includes a discretionary portfolio managed by a fund manager. (“Investment
product” as defined in the FAA technically would not capture such a discretionary portfolio.)

Accordingly, existing regulation on the duty of financial advisers to recommend


suitable products presents an ambiguity in its application to robo-advisers. It is submitted that
it would be more ideal for both robo-advisers and their clients to understand at the outset what
their respective duties are when interacting with each other through a digital platform. The law
can find a balance between the principles of caveat emptor and caveat venditor in determining
the extent to which financial regulation should intervene to protect the interests of an investor

51
S. LIM

transacting via a digital platform, if the platform and algorithms were otherwise properly
designed.

Notably, some of the difficulty here could be resolved if robo-advisers start


complementing their services with human advisers. In such event, the element of human
interaction and possible undue influence that comes with it could perhaps justify a presumption
of reliance by an investor as to ground a claim under section 36.

52
XI. Payment Fraud and Consumer Protection

Dr Sandra Booysen
(National University of Singapore)

Payment fraud (or payment scams) can take different forms, including forgery of the
drawer’s signature on a cheque, the unauthorised use of a payment card (most commonly in
‘card not present’ transactions), and by tricking an account holder into making a payment from
his/her bank account through a fraudulent misrepresentation. Cases from the last category are
mostly examples of ‘authorised push payment’ (APP) scams.1 They are considered ‘authorised’
payments because the payment instruction emanates from the bank account holder who is
entitled to make payments from the account, and they are ‘push’ payments because the payment
instruction is received by the paying bank before it enters the relevant payment system.2

APP scams have become a significant category of payment fraud in many jurisdictions,
for which reason they are receiving growing attention from governments, regulators, and
consumer welfare groups. They are also giving rise to a notable number of disputes that are
being litigated in the courts. It seems clear that the worrying rise in APP scams is closely
aligned with the increase in electronic or digital methods of payment. In other words, as
payment preferences have evolved and moved away from cheques to online and mobile
payments, the tactics of fraudsters have similarly evolved. Electronic payments are harder to
forge than paper-based payments, thus prompting fraudsters into soliciting payments by deceit
instead. Because of the attention that APP fraud is currently receiving, the focus here is on APP
fraud.

A forged signature is no signature, both at common law and under the Bills of Exchange
Act, section 24. A bank that pays on a forged signature does so without the customer’s authority
which means that there is a breach of mandate and the bank is not entitled to debit its customers
account with the payment. This position is subject to qualification, for example the customer
may be estopped from denying his/her signature.3 The position may also be modified by
legislation, such as the Payment Services Regulations 2017 in the UK; by soft law codes, such
as the MAS E-payments User Protection Guidelines; and by contract terms which shift the risk
of forgery onto the customer, an example of which is the verification and conclusive evidence
clause.4

1
See, e.g., Tidal Energy Ltd v Bank of Scotland plc [2014] EWCA Civ 1107, discussed in Sandra Booysen ‘Trade
Practices, Contract Doctrine and Consumer Protection’ (2021) LMCLQ 316.
2
By contrast, cheque and card payments are ‘pull’ payments because the paying bank receives the payment
instruction only after it has been routed through the relevant payment system.
3
See, e.g., Greenwood v Martins Bank [1933] AC 5.
4
See Major Shipping & Trading Inc v Standard Chartered Bank (Singapore) Ltd [2018] SGHC 4. See also Sandra
Booysen ‘Consumer Protection and the Court’s Role in Shaping the Bank-Customer Contract’ (2019) 135 LQR
437.
S. BOOYSEN

The distinguishing feature about authorised scam payments is that the paying bank has
prima facie authority to make the payment, and ordinarily a bank must process payment
instructions promptly. For this reason, the risk of APP scams falls on the customer. It is well-
established, however, that banks owe their customers an implied duty of care in rendering their
services. A similar duty may also be owed in tort. In some jurisdictions (e.g., the UK and Hong
Kong), there is a statutory duty on service providers to render their services with care. As
regards its scope, the bank’s duty of care has been recognised as applying where the bank
executes payment instructions. In this context, the duty goes by the label of the Quincecare
duty.5 The duty ordinarily requires a bank not to pay and make inquiries when it suspects, or
should reasonably suspect, that the customer is being defrauded. The standard expected is that
of the reasonable bank.6 Two relatively recent cases have highlighted the difficulty that a bank
may face should it need to make inquiries. In Singularis,7 company monies were
misappropriated by the controlling shareholder who was also dominant in running the
company. In JP Morgan Chase v Nigeria,8 the payment instruction was given by a senior figure
in the government of Nigeria at the time. The claim was brought by a successor government
which alleged that the payment instruction was given fraudulently and therefore it triggered
the bank’s Quincecare duty. Both scenarios highlight the difficulties banks may face once their
suspicions have been aroused by a payment instruction. Unlike cases such as Lipkin Gorman,
there is no obviously independent person whom the bank can reliably contact to confirm or
dispel their concerns.

Although the recognition of the Quincecare duty has been challenged as unwarranted
and inconsistent with the bank’s duty to execute mandates promptly,9 it has been confirmed in
the UK by the Court of Appeal,10 and more recently in the Supreme Court.11 It has also been
recognised by the Singapore Court of Appeal.12 The existence of the duty is backed by
considerable precedent. These cases, however, involved examples of an agent abusing his/her
authority (internal fraud).13 The scope of the Quincecare duty in the context of APP scams,
which involves fraud by a third party (external fraud), was until recently, untested.

5
[1992] 4 All ER 363. See also Lipkin Gorman v Karpnale & Co [1989] 1 WLR 1340, issue not raised on appeal,
[1991] 2 AC 548.
6
Hsu Ann Mei Amy v OCBC [2011] 2 SLR 178, [24].
7
Singularis Holdings Ltd (in Official Liquidation) v Daiwa Capital Markets Europe Ltd [2020] AC 1189.
8
[2019] EWHC 347 (Comm); on appeal, [2019] EWCA 1641. For the subsequent factual findings on fraud see,
The Federal Republic of Nigeria v JPMorgan Chase Bank, NA [2022] EWHC 1447 (Comm).
9
See, e.g., Peter Watts, ‘The Quincecare Duty: Misconceived and Misdelivered’ (2020) JBL 402; Peter Watts,
‘Playing the Quincecare Card’ (2022) 138 LQR 530.
10
Lipkin Gorman (n 5).
11
Singularis (n 7).
12
Hsu Ann Mei Amy (n 6); Yogambikai Nagarajah v Indian Overseas Bank [1996] 2 SLR(R) 774.
13
For a recent case from Hong Kong raising interesting issues in the context of internal fraud, see PT Asuransi
Tugu Pratama Indonesia TBK v Citibank NA [2023] HKCFA 3.

54
S. BOOYSEN

The question recently came before the English courts in Philipp v Barclays Bank Ltd.14
The Philipps fell victim to an APP scam which saw them transfer £700,000 to accounts in the
UAE. They sued their bank for not taking a number of steps to protect them from the scam
(before, during and after they made the payments), based on the Quincecare duty. The High
Court gave summary judgment to the bank on the basis that the Quincecare duty does not apply
where the payment instruction emanates from the customer as a result of a third party’s fraud
(i.e. external fraud). It is limited to cases where an agent of the customer abuses his/her
authority and misappropriates monies from the customer’s account (internal fraud). The court’s
reasoning reflects a concern about the difficult position that banks are in with conflicting duties,
on the one hand to pay promptly, and on the other hand, not to pay where fraud should
reasonably be suspected. The Court of Appeal unanimously overturned the summary judgment
against the customer. It pointed out that the articulation of the duty in the salient cases (e.g.,
Quincecare and Lipkin Gorman) did not restrict the duty to cases of internal fraud, 15 although
the facts in those cases did involve internal fraud. The court was also sceptical of claims that
the duty was unworkable in the modern payment environment. The court rightly reasoned that
the duty was calibrated to take account of the general duty to process payment instructions
promptly. The everyday push payments made by customers will ordinarily not trigger the duty.

The recognition of the Quincecare duty in the APP scam context is supported. It is only
in a limited range of circumstances that the Quincecare duty will be triggered. It is well-
established that banks do not have to be detectives or be overly suspicious. But they should not
be entitled to turn a blind eye if transactions are objectively suspicious. An additional reason
in support of recognising the duty in this context is policy. APP scams are growing at an
alarming rate, and are a menace to society. Customers do not have the bargaining power to
insert terms in their account contracts to require banks to reduce the risk. There are many
measures which banks can take to warn, detect, and intervene to reduce the risk to customers.
Indeed, they already take a variety of measures, and are expected to do so by regulatory and
soft law measures.16 The common law should also respond to the problem, by recognising the
duty in external fraud cases. Philipp and the scope of the Quincecare duty is now before the
Supreme Court. The questions of law which have been raised are (1) whether Quincecare is
limited to cases of internal fraud, and if so, (2) whether it should be extended to external fraud

14
[2022] EWCA Civ 318. See also Sandra Booysen ‘Authorised Payment Scams and the Bank’s Duty of Care’
(2022) LMCLQ 349.
15
Cf Singularis (n 7) para 55, although this decision must be seen in context. The bank’s duty of care was not in
issue, and the articulation of the duty sufficed for the facts of the case.
16
See, e.g., MAS E-Payments User Protection Guidelines (Singapore); Contingent Reimbursement Model Code
for Authorised Push Payment Scams (UK). See also Sandra Booysen ‘Tackling Payment Scams: A Comparative
Review’ (2019) ABLU 1.

55
S. BOOYSEN

or whether an analogous duty should be recognised in such cases. The Supreme Court’s answer
to these important questions is eagerly anticipated.

The bank’s duty of care to non-customers has also been considered by the courts
recently. Such a duty can arise in tort if the elements of a duty of care are satisfied.17 In this
context, the duty would typically be based on an assumption of responsibility. However, the
common law is generally cautious of imposing a duty of care for pure economic loss outside
of a contractual relationship. This point is illustrated by Customs & Excise v Barclays Bank
Ltd, where a bank overlooked a freezing order in favour of a customer’s creditor, and paid most
of the monies away. The House of Lords considered that the bank did not owe a duty of care
to the creditor as there was no voluntary assumption of responsibility; nor did policy
considerations favour the recognition of such a duty. The recent case of Royal Bank of Scotland
v JP SPC 4,18 is consistent with this approach. An investment fund sued RBS after fund monies,
held in an account with RBS, were misappropriated by the account holder. The Privy Council
held that a duty of care in tort would be owed if the bank had a ‘special level of control over
the source of danger’ or if it assumed responsibility to protect the fund from the danger of
misappropriation by the account holder.19 On the facts, the Privy Council advised that RBS did
not owe the investors a duty of care in tort.

17
Famously recognised in Hedley Byrne & Co Ltd v Heller & Partners Ltd [1964] 1 AC 465.
18
Royal Bank of Scotland International Ltd v JP SPC 4 (Isle of Man) [2022] UKPC 18.
19
Ibid, 83.

56

You might also like