Exchange Rate Predictability Rossi
Exchange Rate Predictability Rossi
Exchange Rate Predictability Rossi
Abstract
The main goal of this article is to provide an answer to the question: “Does any-
thing forecast exchange rates, and if so, which variables?”. It is well known that
exchange rate ‡uctuations are very di¢ cult to predict using economic models, and
that a random walk forecasts exchange rates better than any economic model (the
Meese and Rogo¤ puzzle). However, the recent literature has identi…ed a series of fun-
damentals/methodologies that claim to have resolved the puzzle. This article provides
a critical review of the recent literature on exchange rate forecasting and illustrates
the new methodologies and fundamentals that have been recently proposed in an up-
to-date, thorough empirical analysis. Overall, our analysis of the literature and the
data suggests that the answer to the question: "Are exchange rates predictable?" is,
"It depends" –on the choice of predictor, forecast horizon, sample period, model, and
forecast evaluation method. Predictability is most apparent when one or more of the
following hold: the predictors are Taylor rule or net foreign assets, the model is lin-
ear, and a small number of parameters are estimated. The toughest benchmark is the
random walk without drift.
Keywords: Exchange Rates, Forecasting, Instability, Forecast Evaluation
Acknowledgments: I thank D. Ferraro for assistance in collecting the data used
in this paper, Janet Currie and four anonymous referees for their generous and useful
comments, and Greg Ganics for assistance in proofreading.
J.E.L. Codes: F3, C5
Barbara Rossi (ICREA-UPF, Barcelona GSE, CREI). Mailing address: Universitat Pompeu Fabra-
CREI, Carrer Ramon Trias Fargas, 25-27, Mercè Rodoreda bldg., 08005 Barcelona SPAIN. Tel.: +34-93-
542-1655; e-mail: barbara.rossi@upf.edu
Et (st+h st ) = ft ; t = 1; 2; :::; T;
where T is the total size of the available sample and h is the forecast horizon.
The model’s performance is typically evaluated relative to that of a benchmark model.
Let the benchmark model be the random walk without drift:
Et (st+h st ) = 0:
In fact, we will argue in Section 6 that the random walk without drift is the appropriate
benchmark for the analysis.
The predictive ability of the fundamental can be evaluated according to in-sample …t or
out-of-sample forecast performance. In-sample …t is typically evaluated by estimating over
the full sample,
! 1 !
X
T X
T
bT = ft2 ft (st+h st ) ;
t=1 t=1
and calculating a t-test on : if the fundamental contains relevant information, then should
be di¤erent from zero. The latter is known as an in-sample (traditional) Granger-causality
test. If the test rejects, it signals that the predictor contains useful information for explaining
exchange rate ‡uctuations over the full sample. However, this does not necessarily mean that
the predictor contains useful information to predict exchange rate ‡uctuations in real-time.
To assess the latter, it is common to turn to forecasting.
To evaluate the models’ out-of-sample forecasting ability, the sample is split into two
parts: the in-sample portion, consisting of observations from 1 to R, and the out-of-sample
1 X f
T
2
RM SF Ef " :
P t=R t+hjt
1
PT 2
The model forecasts better than the random walk if RM SF Ef < RM SF Erw P t=R "rw
t+hjt :
To judge whether the model forecasts signi…cantly better, one typically tests whether RM SF Ef
RM SF Erw is equal to zero against the alternative that the di¤erence is negative, i.e. using
a t-test. Several methods to compute the standard errors and other available test statistics
are discussed in Section 6.
where st ln (St ), = 0 and = 1; and h is the horizon. Similarly, covered interest rate
parity (CIRP) predicts exchange rates according to: Et (st+h st ) = + (Ft st ), where
Ft denotes the h-period ahead forward rate at time t.12
The empirical evidence is not favorable to UIRP. Meese and Rogo¤ (1988) use eq. (1) to
forecast real exchange rates out-of-sample using real interest rate di¤erentials, and compare
its performance with the random walk, …nding that the latter forecasts better. Similarly,
Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005) and Alquist and Chinn (2008) …nd that, although for
some countries UIRP forecasts better than the random walk at long horizons, its performance
is never signi…cantly better. Slightly more positive …ndings have been reported by Clark and
West (2006) at short-horizons, and Molodtsova and Papell (2009) for some countries.13 In-
sample empirical evidence is not favorable to UIRP either. The consensus is that, typically,
11
See Lewis (1995) for a discussion of UIRP without perfect foresight.
12
CIRP states that the spread between forward and spot exchange rates equals the nominal interest
di¤erential between two countries, and was developed by Keynes (1923).
13
Molodtsova and Papell (2009) estimate UIRP with unrestricted coe¢ cients (both constant and slope) as
well as without a constant and with an estimated slope. In the latter case, they only …nd marginal evidence
where = 0 and = 1:
The out-of-sample empirical evidence is not favorable to PPP either: Cheung, Chinn and
Pascual (2005) …nd that, although PPP forecasts better than the random walk at the longest
horizons, its performance is never signi…cantly better; at shorter horizons, it is signi…cantly
worse than the random walk. Whether PPP holds in-sample is also debated. In particular,
two stylized facts emerge from Rogo¤ (1996). First, nominal exchange rates tend toward
purchasing power parity in the long run, although the speed of convergence is remarkably
slow. Second, short run deviations from PPP are substantially large. As Rogo¤ (1996) notes,
deviations from PPP can be attributed to transitory disturbances in the presence of nominal
price stickiness; thus, they should be short-lived (i.e., 1–2 years), while, in the data, half-
life deviations from PPP range between three to …ve years.15 Rogo¤ (1996, p. 647) called
this empirical inconsistency the “PPP puzzle.” Possible concerns and explanations include:
underestimation of the uncertainty around point estimates (Cheung and Lai, 2000, Kilian
of predictive ability for Australia and Canada; in the former case, they …nd strong evidence in favor of Japan
and Switzerland, as well as marginal evidence in favor of Australia and Canada.
14
Possible explanations include: the presence of a time-varying risk premium (Fama, 1984; Backus, Foresi
and Telmer, 2001); estimation biases (Bekaert and Hodrick, 2001); imprecise standard errors (Baillie and
Bollerslev, 2000, Rossi, 2007a); and small samples (Chinn and Meredith, 2004, who …nd positive evidence in
longer samples, and Chen and Tsang, 2011, who pool information from the whole term structure).
15
The half-life measures how many time periods it takes for the e¤ects of a shock to PPP to decrease by
50%.
10
mt pt = it+1 + yt :
Assuming that a similar equation holds for the foreign country (mt pt = it+1 + yt ,
where for simplicity of notation we assumed that the coe¢ cients are symmetric and asterisks
denote foreign country variables) and taking the di¤erence between the two gives the relative
money demand equation: mt mt (pt pt ) = it+1 it+1 + (yt yt ). One approach
(valid if prices and exchange rates are completely ‡exible) is to assume that PPP holds at
every point in time, and substitute it in the relative money demand equation to get the
"‡exible price version of the monetary model":18
In the presence of sticky price adjustment, either the relative price level or in‡ation di¤eren-
tials are included as regressors to obtain the "sticky price version of the monetary model":
11
Note that in the case of (5) the nominal exchange rate may depend on real variables. In
some studies, the real price of non-tradeables is included instead of productivity di¤erentials.
19
Sometimes in‡ation di¤erentials are used instead of prices (Cheung, Chinn and Pascual, 2005) and
coe¢ cients left unrestricted.
20
MacDonald and Taylor (1993), Husted and MacDonald (1998), Groen (2000, 2002), Mark and Sul (2001)
…nd cointegration between exchange rates and monetary fundamentals, while Sarantis (1994) does not. Rossi
(2006) rejects that the coe¢ cients of the monetary model are both constant and equal to zero, suggesting
time-varying predictive ability.
21
At longer horizons, Chinn and Meese’s (1995) results are slightly more positive, although statistically
signi…cant only for the Yen/US dollar exchange rate among the …ve currencies they consider.
22
Chinn and Meese (1995) consider eq. (3); Alquist and Chinn (2008) consider the sticky price monetary
model (eq. 4) with di¤erentials of money, real GDP, interest and in‡ation rates.
23
They …nd evidence only for two countries among the twelve they consider.
12
where bt is the stock of home assets held by home and bt is the stock of foreign assets held by
home, and the unobservable term Et (st+1 st ) is approximated by zero. Several measures
of balances have been used in the literature as broad proxies: cumulated trade balance
di¤erentials, cumulated current account balance di¤erentials, and government debt. Meese
and Rogo¤ (1983a,b) …nd that, even after augmenting the monetary model by a measure of
trade balance di¤erentials, the model still does not forecast better than the random walk, a
…nding con…rmed by Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005).25
Summary of Empirical Findings
Overall, the empirical evidence based on the traditional predictors is not favorable to
the economic models. While the out-of-sample forecasting ability of the economic predictors
occasionally outperforms that of a random walk in some studies for some countries/time
periods, it de…nitely does not systematically do so. More importantly, with a few exceptions,
their predictive ability is not signi…cantly better than that of a random walk at short horizons.
The main exception is the work by Clark and West (2006) regarding the out-of-sample
predictive ability of UIRP; the next sections will investigate the reasons why their …nding
is di¤erent from the rest of the literature. At longer horizons, there is more evidence of
predictive ability in favor of the monetary model, although the …nding is contentious. At
the same time, some predictors (i.e. interest rate di¤erentials) show signi…cant in-sample …t,
although with coe¢ cient signs that are inconsistent with economic theory.
24
Wright (2008) also includes productivity di¤erentials among his predictors. See Section 4 for a discussion.
25
Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005) estimate a model where exchange rate ‡uctuations are functions of
the government debt relative to GDP, the real interest rate, the net foreign asset position, the (log of the)
terms of trade, the (log) price level di¤erential and the relative price of non-tradeables.
13
for all countries, whereas for the US = 0, and vt+1 is the monetary policy shock. That is,
using asterisks to denote foreign country variables:
By taking the di¤erence of the two equations, using UIRP and re-de…ning the coe¢ cients,
one obtains the speci…cation in Molodtsova and Papell (2009):
which they refer to as the “asymmetric” Taylor rule. They also consider imposing the
coe¢ cient to be the same and excluding the real exchange rate, a speci…cation they refer
14
Both the in-sample and the out-of-sample empirical evidence are mostly favorable to
Taylor-rule fundamentals, although with exceptions. Regarding the in-sample evidence,
Chinn (2008) estimates the Taylor model in-sample and …nds that the coe¢ cient signs are
not consistent with theory, and that the choice of the gap measure is not innocuous.26
Regarding the out-of-sample evidence, Molodtsova and Papell (2009) show that eq. (8)
forecasts exchange rates out-of-sample signi…cantly better than the random walk for several
countries, although the performance depends on the exact speci…cation.27 Molodtsova et al.
(2010), Giacomini and Rossi (2010) and Inoue and Rossi (2012) also …nd strong empirical
evidence in favor of Taylor-rule fundamentals. On the other hand, Rogo¤ and Stavrakeva
(2008) …nd that the empirical evidence in favor of Taylor-rule fundamentals is not robust.
Taylor rules are generally deemed to be a good description of monetary policy in the past
three decades, but monetary policy may have changed during the recent 2007 …nancial crisis.
Molodtsova and Papell (2012) study exchange rate forecasting during the …nancial crisis by
including indicators of …nancial stress in the Taylor rule, such as the Libor-OIS/Euribor-
OIS di¤erential, the Bloomberg and OECD …nancial condition indices, and the TED spread
di¤erential. Adrian et al. (2011) use instead measures of liquidity such as funding liq-
uidity aggregates of US …nancial intermediaries measured by stocks of US dollar …nancial
commercial paper and overnight repos. Both the latter papers …nd positive evidence.28
15
16
17
0
Et (st+h st ) = 0 + 1 ft+h ; (9)
where the future, realized values of the fundamental ft+h are used. We refer to (9) as the
"single-equation, contemporaneous, realized fundamental model". The actual, rather than the
forecasted, value of the fundamentals is used as a predictor by Meese and Rogo¤ (1983a,b,
1988) to make sure that the lack of predictability of exchange rates is not due to poor
forecasts of the fundamentals. The parameters are estimated either by simple OLS or by
GMM (to deal with the endogeneity of the predictors). Meese and Rogo¤ (1983b) calibrate
the parameter in a grid to explore the robustness of their results to possible inconsistencies
in the parameter estimates. Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005) forecast exchange rates
using eq. (9) either by using calibrated parameter values (based on economic theory)32 or by
estimating eq. (9) via OLS (ignoring endogeneity issues). Similarly, Bacchetta, van Wincoop
and Beutler (2010) and Ferraro et al. (2011), among others, estimate eq. (9).33
To evaluate actual, ex-ante predictability of the fundamental, one might consider the
following models. The "single-equation, contemporaneous, forecasted fundamental" model
is:
0
Et (st+h st ) = 0 + 1 Et ft+h (10)
where Et ft+h is estimated based on information available up to time t, and the endogeneity
of the fundamentals requires instrumental variable estimation. Eq. (10) has been considered
by Meese and Rogo¤ (1983a) and Chinn and Meese (1995). In the "single-equation, lagged
fundamental model":
0
Et (st+h st ) = 0 + 1 ft ; (11)
32
For example, for PPP, they forecast future st+h st simply by using pt+h pt+h .
33
Ferraro et al. (2011) argue that the fundamental that they use (the rate of growth of commodity prices)
can be considered essentially exogenous; thus, they can consistently estimate the parameters by OLS.
18
19
P
h
0
Et (st+h st ) st+j = 0 + 1 (st ft ) (12)
j=1
To help intuition, consider the monetary model, eq. (3). Note that by substituting the
UIRP and PPP conditions in the relative money demand equation, we have: mt mt st
= (Et st+h st ) + (yt yt ), which leads to the popular approach of Mark (1995), where
Et st+h st = + [(mt mt ) (yt yt ) st ] : As long as < 1; exchange rates revert
back to their fundamental value ft (mt mt ) (yt yt ) over time. Thus, predictive
ability should be stronger at longer horizons. The cointegration vector parameter ( ) can
be calibrated – as in Mark (1995),36 Chinn and Meese (1995), Abhyankar et al. (2005),
Berkowitz and Giorgianni (2001) and Kilian (1999) –or estimated (typically by Stock and
Watson’s (1993) DOLS), either over the full-sample or recursively –as in Alquist and Chinn
(2008), Chinn and Moore (2012) and Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005).37
Positive evidence in favor of the ECM model at long horizons has been found by Mark
(1995), whereas Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005) and Alquist and Chinn (2008) …nd no
predictive ability. Note that the former calibrates the cointegration parameters whereas
the latter estimate them. On the other hand, using exactly the same ECM speci…cation,
Kilian (1999) and Groen (1999) …nd no predictive ability for the monetary model at long
horizons, whereas Rossi (2005a) does. We will investigate in detail the reasons behind the
disagreement over the predictive ability of the monetary model at long horizons in Sections
5.1, 6.4 and 6.5.38
20
0
st = t ft + ut ; (13)
t =G t 1 + K + Avt ;
where the parameter t changes over time according to an autoregressive process, K and
A are constants, and ut and vt are unforecastable shocks.43 The "random walk coe¢ cient
time-varying parameter" model (Stock and Watson, 1998) imposes G = I and K = 0:
39
Including Chinn (1991) and Chinn and Meese (1995) for the monetary model; Diebold and Nason (1990)
for univariate models; Mizrach (1992) for locally weighted regression model across several currencies; Qi and
Wu (2003) and Rapach and Wohar (2006).
40
Meese and Rose (1991) …nd signi…cant in-sample and out-of-sample predictability in the non-linear
monetary model. Satchell and Timmermann (1995) show that, although the squared forecast errors of
nonlinear models are higher than those of the random walk, non-linear models correctly predict a large
proportion of the sign of exchange rate changes for several countries.
41
Taylor and Peel (2000) and Kilian and Taylor (2003) are examples of in-sample estimation of non-linear
models and out-of-sample forecasting, respectively, in the case of real exchange rate models.
42
The di¤erence between BMA and forecast combinations is that BMA estimates the weights in the forecast
combination using Bayesian methods, whereas forecast combinations typically use equal weights or weights
estimated with frequentist methods.
43
Wol¤ (1987) estimated the TVP model using the Kalman …lter.
21
A (L) Yt = ut ; (14)
where A (L) = I A1 L ::: Ap Lp and L is the lag operator. A special version of VARs are
Bayesian VARs (BVARs), that is VARs estimated with a large number of variables imposing
some Bayesian shrinkage for the parameters, which otherwise would be very imprecisely
estimated in the small samples typically available to researchers. Meese and Rogo¤ (1983a,b)
…nd that VARs with monetary fundamentals do not improve over the random walk. The
BVARs with a large number of exchange rates in Carriero, Kapetanios and Marcellino (2009)
outperform the random walk even at short horizons. Note that the BVAR considered by
44
although the former did not test their signi…cance and the latter …nds signi…cant evidence for one country
out of three. Cheung and Erlandsson (2005) …nd in-sample empirical evidence in favor of a Markov Switching
model for exchange rates.
45
Although Chinn (2009) and Giannone (2009) debate their conclusion.
22
where 't is the factor extracted from the explanatory variables Xt , (Xt = 't +ui;t , where the
explanatory variables are a panel of exchange rates), i denotes the country, and the number
of countries considered is large.46 Engel, Mark and West (2009) …nd that, in some cases,
the factor model improves forecasts at long horizons but does not improve short-horizon
forecasts.47
(c) VECMs. The single-equation ECM model, eq. (12), is a simpli…cation of the tradi-
tional "multi-equation VECM model":
0
st+1 = 0 + 1 (st ft ) + 2 (L) st 1 + 3 (L) ft 1 (16)
where the short run dynamics is eliminated, and 1 L. The empirical evidence on
VECMs is mixed: some papers …nd positive evidence (i.e. MacDonald and Taylor, 1993,
for the monetary model; Clarida and Taylor, 1997, for forward rates) while others are more
negative (Rapach and Wohar, 2002, and Diebold, Gardeazabal and Yilmaz, 1994).48 Overall,
the literature suggests that single-equation ECM speci…cations are preferable to VECMs
because the short-run dynamics of exchange rates is di¢ cult to estimate (cfr. Cheung,
Chinn and Pascual, 2005, p.1156)
(d) Multivariate time-varying parameter models. Multivariate models can also
have time-varying parameters: a multivariate version of the time-varying parameter model
(13) has been used in Canova (1993).49 Due to the complexity, these models are estimated
by Bayesian methods. The empirical evidence shows that multivariate TVP models may
provide forecast improvements over the random walk (see Canova, 1993, for the multivariate
46
Eq. (15) may include additional control variables, such the deviation of Taylor rules, monetary or PPP
fundamentals from the current exchange rate of the country.
47
They also consider the alternative speci…cation: Et si;t+h = i0 Et 't+h .
48
Diebold, Gardeazabal and Yilmaz (1994) reconcile their negative …nding with the fact that powerful
cointegration tests reject cointegration. See also Baillie and Bollerslev (1989, 1994) for in-sample tests of
cointegration among exchange rates.
49
More in detail, Canova’s (1993) model is: Bt (L) Yt = ut , where ut j=t N (0; V ), =t is the information
set, and B t = GB t 1 + K + Avt ; where B t is the vector containing all the parameters in Bt (L) and
vt (0; t ).
23
where the error term contains both an individual, time-invariant component, an aggregate,
time variant component, and an individual, time variant component.50 Mark and Sul (2001),
Groen (2005), Engel, Mark and West (2007) and Cerra and Saxena (2010) impose a known
cointegrating parameter .51 Rapach and Wohar (2004) estimate the cointegrating parame-
ters recursively, but unfortunately do not compare the models’ forecasts with the random
walk. The "panel, contemporaneous realized fundamental model" used by Cerra and Saxena
(2010) is: Et si;t+h = fi;t+h , where fi;t+h is the actual, realized value of the fundamen-
tal. The "panel, lagged fundamental model" used by Adrian, Etula and Shin (2011) is:
Et si;t+h = fi;t , where fi;t is the lagged value of the fundamental.
The empirical evidence suggests that panel ECMs are quite successful for the monetary
model (see Mark and Sul, 2001; Groen, 2005; Engel, Mark and West, 2007; and Cerra and
Saxena, 2010) and for funding liquidity fundamentals (Adrian, Etula and Shin, 2011). They
are less successful for PPP fundamentals (Mark and Sul, 2001).
50 1
Pt
Its forecasts are: h (fi;t si;t ) + i + t j=1 j , where i is the individual, time-invariant component
and t is the aggregate, time-variant component.
51
In particular, Groen (2005) imposes knowledge on the number of cointegrating vectors as well as the
parameters of the common cointegrating vector, and only re-estimates the intercept and the coe¢ cients of
short-run dynamics.
24
25
26
27
5.4 Frequency
Existing studies in the literature also di¤er with respect to the frequency of the data they
consider, ranging from low frequency, yearly data, to quarterly, monthly, and even weekly,
daily or very high-frequency data (such as those available at 30-minute intervals). There
is clearly a trade-o¤ between the frequency of the data and the span of the data, as lower
frequency data (which are perhaps more informative regarding long-run trends in the data)
are by construction available only for shorter samples.56 Typically, studies interested in the
long-term forecastability of exchange rates focus on quarterly data (i.e. Mark, 1995). There
are no striking discrepancies between empirical results of studies that focus on monthly data
55
For example, Meese and Rogo¤ (1983a,b) consider also the trade-weighted exchange rate.
56
E.g. longer spans of data have been considered by Rapach and Wohar (2002) at the price of restricting
attention to yearly frequencies and a smaller sample. See also Taylor (2002) on using longer span of data
for the analyzing real exchange rates.
28
29
30
Et st+h st = 0
An alternative benchmark is the random walk with drift ("RWWD"), according to which
exchange rate changes are predictable but independent of other macroeconomic variables:
Et st+h st = 6= 0.
It is important to note that the e¢ cient market hypothesis does not imply that exchange
rate changes should be unpredictable. That is, the Meese and Rogo¤ (1983a,b) …nding that
the random walk provides the best prediction of exchange rates should not be interpreted
as a validation of the e¢ cient market hypothesis. The e¢ cient market hypothesis means
that bilateral exchange rate is the market’s best guess of the relative, fundamental value of
two currencies based on all available information at that time. The e¢ cient market hypoth-
esis does not mean that exchange rates (like any asset prices) are unrelated to economic
fundamentals, nor that exchange rates should ‡uctuate randomly around their past values.
Consistently, across papers, the random walk is used as the benchmark. Typically, when
the random walk with drift forecasts are reported, they are worse than those of the random
walk without drift. This may explain some puzzling results in the literature. For example,
among papers that study non-linear models, Meese and Rose (1991) found more empirical
evidence in favor of the nonlinear model, whereas Chinn (1991) and Chinn and Meese (1995)
61
When not speci…ed otherwise, random walk means the random walk without drift.
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
7.2 Methodology
We present empirical results using a few of the most used predictors and successful method-
ologies. Regarding the predictors, we consider interest rate di¤erentials, price di¤erentials,
money and output di¤erentials, Taylor rule fundamentals and measures of external imbalance
such as the current account and the trade balance.75
Regarding the models, …rst we consider the performance of selected traditional single-
equation linear models (UIRP, eq. 1; PPP, eq. 2, and monetary) as well as Taylor-rule
fundamentals (eq. 8) and portfolio balance models (eq. 6).76 The monetary model is
73
While we collected data also for Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Hong Kong,
Mexico, Peru, Portugal, Russia, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand and Turkey, the sample sizes of either the
exchange rate or the fundamentals were severely limited, or potentially severely a¤ected by measurement
error. These countries were discarded from the analysis.
74
For quarterly data, the …lter is 1=3+1=3L+1=3L2 ; for monthly data it is (1=12)+(1=12) L+:::+(1=12) L11 .
Empirical results based on seasonally unadjusted data are qualitatively similar.
75
The analysis will focus on monthly data when possible, given that both monthly and quarterly data
have the same span but the former provides larger sample sizes.
76
Unfortunately, net foreign assets data are available only at the annual frequency, so an analysis with the
40
41
42
43
44
8 Conclusions
To conclude, our analysis of the literature review has uncovered several stylized facts, which
lead to …ve main conclusions.
45
46
95
For example, monetary fundamentals at long horizons.
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
Molodtsova and Papell (2012) L lag fund. ; y gap ,F CI Q (real t) 1992Q4-2012Q1 EU
Qi and Wu (2003) NL ECM neural net. m,y ,i M 1973:3-1997:7 JP,UK,CA,GER
Rapach and Wohar (2006) NL univ. ESTAR s M 1980:1-1994:12 UK,GER,FR,JP
Rime, Sarno and Sojli (2010) L ECM order ‡ows D 2004:2-2005:2 UK,EU,JP
Rogo¤ and Stavrakeva (2008) L ECM (m,y);( ; y gap );nxa Q 1973:1-2005:4 18 countries
Rossi (2005a) L ECM m,y Q 1973Q3-1998Q2 GER,JP
Rossi (2006) L/NL lag fund. TVP y , m,i M 1973:3-1998:12 CA,FR,GER,IT,JP
Rossi and Sekhposyan (2011) L lag fund. m, u, y , i, CP M 1975:9-2008:9 SWI,UK,CA,JP,GER
Schinasi and Swami (1987) L contemp. TVP-AR m,y ,i,T B M 1973:3-1980:3 UK,GER,JP
West, Edison and Cho (1993) L/NL univ. GARCH/NP s W 1973:3-1989:9 CA,FR,GER,JP,UK
Wol¤ (1987) L contemp. TVP-AR m,y; i, M 1973:3-1984:4 GER,JP,UK
Wu and Wang (2009) L lag fund. semi-param. ( ; y gap ; q);(m; y) M varies by country 12 countries
Multiple Eqs. Models
Canova (1993) L TVP-VAR i W 1979 to 1987 FR,SWI,GER,UK,JP
Clarida et al. (2003) NL VECM-MS F W 1979:1-1998:52 FR,GER,JP,UK
Clarida and Taylor (1997) L VECM F W 1977:1-1993:52 UK,GER,JP
61
Molodtsova and Papell (2012) RW roll(26) 1 q. 2007Q1 CW Yes
Qi and Wu (2003) roll(.75T) 1,6,12 mo. (iter) 1990:1 DMW No
Rapach and Wohar (2006) 1 to 3 mo. DMW,PIT No
Rime, Sarno and Sojli (2010) 1 day 2004:6 utility-based Yes
Rogo¤ and Stavrakeva (2008) varies various Mostly no
Rossi (2005a) 1-12qrs. DMW Yes, based on GC-robust tests; somewhat, based on TVP models
Rossi (2006) RW roll,rec 1 mo. D M W ,E N C N E W Yes (for some countries)
Rossi and Sekhposyan (2011) RW roll 1-12mo. varies DMW No
Schinasi and Swami (1987) 15 mo. 1980:4 MSFE,MAE Yes (but no statistical signi…cance analysis)
West, Edison and Cho (1993) utility-based Yes
Wol¤ (1987) RW rec 1-24 mo. (iter) 1981:7 MSFE,MAE Somewhat (only for one country)
Wu and Wang (2009) RW roll(200) 1-12 mo. (iter) interval,GW Yes
Multiple Eqs. Models
Canova (1993) RW 1-52 w. (iter) 1986 Theil Yes
Clarida et al. (2003) RW 4-52 w. 1996:1 DMW Yes
Clarida and Taylor (1997) RW rec 1-12 mo. 1977:1 MSFE,MAE Yes
62
Models in Quarterly Data
Int. Rate Di¤. CPI Di¤. TB Di¤. Output Di¤. CA Di¤.
Country Start End N.Obs. Start End N.Obs. Start End N.Obs. Start End N.Obs. Start End N.Obs.
Australia 1969:04 2011:02 167 1957:02 2011:02 217 1973:02 2010:04 151 1959:04 2011:02 207 1973:02 2010:04 151
Austria 1967:02 1998:04 127 1957:02 2011:02 217 1973:02 2011:01 152 1988:02 2011:01 092 1973:02 2011:01 152
Belgium 1957:02 1998:04 167 1957:02 2011:02 217 2002:02 2011:01 036 1980:02 2011:02 125 2002:02 2011:01 036
Canada 1975:02 2011:02 145 1957:02 2011:02 217 1973:02 2011:01 152 1961:02 2011:02 201 1973:02 2011:01 152
Denmark 1972:02 2011:02 155 1980:02 2011:02 125 1975:02 2011:01 144 1991:02 2011:02 081 1975:02 2011:01 144
Finland 1978:02 2011:02 133 1960:02 2011:02 205 1975:02 2011:01 144 1975:02 2011:02 145 1975:02 2011:01 144
France 1957:02 1999:01 168 1990:02 2011:02 085 1975:02 2010:04 143 1957:02 2011:02 217 1975:02 2010:04 143
Germany 1957:02 2011:02 217 1957:02 2011:02 217 1973:02 2011:01 152 1991:02 2011:02 081 1973:02 2011:01 152
Greece 1998:02 1999:03 006 1959:02 2011:02 209 1976:02 2011:01 135 2000:02 2011:01 044 1976:02 2011:01 135
Ireland 1973:02 2011:02 147 1969:02 2011:02 169 1981:02 2011:01 120 1997:02 2011:01 056 1981:02 2011:01 120
Italy 1971:02 2011:02 161 1957:02 2011:02 217 1973:02 2011:01 152 1981:02 2011:02 121 1973:02 2011:01 152
Japan 1957:02 2011:02 217 2000:02 2011:02 045 1977:02 2011:01 136 1980:02 2011:02 125 1977:02 2011:01 136
New Zealand 1985:02 2011:02 105 1957:02 2011:02 217 1980:02 2011:01 124 1987:03 2011:01 095 1980:02 2011:01 124
Portugal 1981:02 2000:01 076 1960:02 2011:02 205 1975:02 2011:01 144 1995:02 2011:02 065 1975:02 2011:01 144
63
UK 1.00 1.01 0.58 1.00 1.00 1.01 0.54 0.70 0.61 1.01 0.58 0.89 0.20 1.01 0.55 0.61 1.00 1.00 0.49 0.10 0.20 1.03 0.57 0.29
h=4 Years h=4 Years h=4 Years h=4 Years h=4 Years h=4 Years
Australia n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.21 1.00 0.52 0.29 0.57 1.01 0.57 0.93 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.05 1.03 0.60 0.86
Austria 0.53 1.00 0.53 0.67 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.00 1.05 0.59 0.11
Belgium 1.00 1.01 0.53 0.50 0.47 1.01 0.58 0.97 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.89 1.00 0.51 0.49 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Canada 0.43 1.01 0.53 0.36 0.28 1.00 0.52 0.40 1.00 1.00 0.53 0.73 0.50 1.00 0.51 0.38 0.12 0.99 0.48 0.00 0.00 1.03 0.57 0.65
Denmark 0.71 1.00 0.52 0.43 0.72 1.00 0.51 0.44 1.00 1.02 0.57 0.70 0.29 1.02 0.57 0.71 1.00 1.01 0.49 0.36 0.26 1.04 0.59 0.59
Finland 0.31 1.01 0.55 0.78 0.83 1.00 0.55 0.84 0.55 1.01 0.55 0.50 0.79 1.01 0.54 0.66 0.10 1.02 0.51 0.46 0.00 1.09 0.65 0.77
France 1.00 1.02 0.57 0.76 0.53 1.04 0.61 0.78 0.21 1.02 0.55 0.73 0.51 1.01 0.55 0.80 0.23 n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.00 1.21 0.65 n.a.
Germany 0.82 1.01 0.54 0.60 0.04 1.01 0.54 0.69 0.22 1.01 0.54 0.53 0.48 1.01 0.56 0.86 0.40 1.01 0.49 0.28 0.01 1.11 0.61 0.60
Greece 0.77 1.01 0.53 0.49 0.22 1.00 0.49 0.03 0.43 1.00 0.49 0.04 0.78 1.00 0.51 0.16 0.21 1.00 0.50 0.01 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Ireland 1.00 1.02 0.56 0.85 0.40 1.01 0.56 0.83 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.04 1.03 0.57 0.45 0.00 1.11 0.71 0.52
Italy 1.00 1.02 0.56 0.70 0.04 1.00 0.51 0.36 0.35 1.04 0.62 0.97 0.31 1.03 0.59 0.80 0.02 1.01 0.50 0.33 0.00 1.06 0.56 0.42
Japan 0.64 1.01 0.55 0.85 0.22 1.02 0.57 0.64 0.13 1.01 0.52 0.36 0.39 1.01 0.53 0.80 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.00 1.09 0.61 0.22
New Zealand 0.64 1.01 0.55 0.71 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.22 1.01 0.54 0.72 0.89 1.00 0.52 0.28 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.02 1.06 0.63 0.90
Portugal 1.00 1.02 0.58 0.84 0.00 1.01 0.53 0.47 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.00 1.12 0.55 0.20 0.00 1.06 0.59 0.28
Spain 0.70 1.02 0.55 0.61 0.05 1.00 0.53 0.63 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.00 1.00 0.45 0.05 0.00 1.06 0.58 0.41
64
U.K. 1.01 0.55 0.75 1.00 0.52 0.53
h=4 Years
Australia 1.35 0.70 0.31 1.00 0.48 0.18
Austria n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Belgium n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Canada 1.34 0.70 1.00 1.00 0.53 0.84
Denmark 1.49 0.76 1.00 1.01 0.55 0.83
Finland 1.84 0.80 0.00 1.01 0.55 0.87
France 1.72 0.78 1.00 1.00 0.54 0.79
Germany 1.75 0.76 1.00 1.00 0.52 0.50
Greece 1.14 0.60 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a.
Ireland n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Italy 1.11 0.55 0.00 1.00 0.54 0.73
Japan 1.79 0.74 0.50 1.00 0.52 0.59
New Zealand 1.52 0.69 1.00 1.00 0.49 0.27
Portugal n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Spain n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Note to Table 1. The table reports the name of the model "Model", the fundamental
predictors used in the model ("ft ") and the mnemonics used to refer to these fundamentals
in Table 2.
Note to Table 2, Panel A. "L" denotes linear model and "NL" denotes non-linear model.
Mnemonics for the predictors are as in Table 1. If a paper considers several models at
the same time, their predictors are separated by a semicolon; for example, a paper that
considers both UIRP and the monetary model with interest rates will be characterized by:
i; (m; ; y; i). In addition, "SP " denotes stock prices; "q" denotes the real exchange rate;
"CP " denotes commodity prices (either oil price or the commodity price); "D" denotes the
dividend yield; "CA" denotes the current account; "T B" denotes the trade balance; "s" is
the lagged exchange rate; "F CI" denotes Financial Condition Indices; "r" denotes the real
interest rate; "u" denotes unemployment; a " " before a variable denotes the …rst di¤erence
of that variable. Note that Cheung et al. (2005) also consider the model with productivity
(m; y; i; z) as well as a model with net foreign assets (p; r; b; terms of trade, net foreign assets
and the relative price of non-tradeables). "Calibr. coe¤." means calibrated coe¢ cients;
"estim. coe¤." denotes estimated coe¢ cients; "calibr. coint." means calibrated values for
the cointegration vector; "estim. coint." denotes estimated cointegration vector; "di¤."
means that the model is estimated with variables in di¤erences; "semi-param." means that
the model is estimated with semi-parametric methods; "contemp." denotes contemporaneous
predictors; "lag fund." denotes lagged fundamentals; "real. fund." means that the model uses
ex-post, realized values of the contemporaneous fundamentals for prediction; "univ." denotes
a univariate model (with possible lags of exchange rates and no fundamentals); "ECM"
denotes Error Correction Model; "NP" denotes non-parametric; "LWR" denotes locally
weighted regression; "MS" denotes Markov Switching model; "neural net." denotes neural
network model. Canova’s (1993) model includes stochastic volatility; in Cheung, Chinn and
Pascual (2005), the contemporaneous fundamental model is estimated with OLS whereas
the cointegrating vector in the ECM model is estimated via the Johansen procedure; Wright
(2008) also includes the ratio of the current account to output among the regressors; in Adrian
et al. (2011), the repo- and commercial paper variables (here labeled "repo;comm.paper")
are detrended over the full sample.
Note to Table 2, Panel B. "Freq." denotes the frequency of the data: "Y" for yearly,
65
66
67
-2 0
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-4
-6
-8 -5
-10
-12
-14 -10
1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Time Time
MonECM for Switzerland at h=1 months MonECM for Germany at h=1 months
4 4
2
2
0
0
-2
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-2
-4
-4
-6
-6
-8
-8
-10
-10 -12
2003.5 2004 2004.5 2005 2005.5 2006 2006.5 2007 2007.5 2008 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Time Time
MonECM for Japan at h=1 months MonECM for U.K. at h=1 months
5 4
0 0
-2
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-5 -4
-6
-10 -8
-10
-15 -12
1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Time Time
68
8
2
6
0
4
-2
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
2
0 -4
-2
-6
-4
-8
-6
-10
-8
-10 -12
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Time Time
MonECM for Switzerland at h=48 months MonECM for Germany at h=48 months
4 5
2 0
0 -5
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-2 -10
-4 -15
-6 -20
-8 -25
2007 2007.5 2008 2008.5 2009 2009.5 2010 2010.5 2011 2011.5 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Time Time
-2 0
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-4
-6
-8
-5
-10
-12
-14
-16 -10
1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Time Time
69
4
10
2
5
Inoue-Rossi test
Inoue-Rossi test
0
-2
-5
-4
-10
-6
-8 -15
50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220
R R
MonECM for Switzerland at h=1 months MonECM for Germany at h=1 months
10 5
5 0
0 -5
Inoue-Rossi test
Inoue-Rossi test
-5 -10
-10 -15
-15 -20
20 40 60 80 100 120 140 0 50 100 150 200 250 300
R R
MonECM for Japan at h=1 months MonECM for U.K. at h=1 months
16 10
14
5
12
0
10
Inoue-Rossi test
8
Inoue-Rossi test
-5
-10
4
2 -15
-20
-2
-4 -25
50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 0 50 100 150 200 250
R R
70
5 0
0 -5
Inoue-Rossi test
Inoue-Rossi test
-5 -10
-10 -15
-15 -20
-20 -25
50 100 150 200 250 300 350 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180
R R
MonECM for Switzerland at h=48 months MonECM for Germany at h=48 months
5 5
0
0
-5
-5
Inoue-Rossi test
-10
-15
-15
-20
-20
-25
-25 -30
20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220
R R
MonECM for Japan at h=48 months MonECM for U.K. at h=48 months
5 5
-5
0
-10
Inoue-Rossi test
Inoue-Rossi test
-15
-20
-5
-25
-30
-35 -10
50 100 150 200 250 300 350 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220
R R
71
MonECM for Germany at h=48 months MonECM for Germany at h=48 months
10 5
5
0
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
0
-5
-5
-10
-10
-15 -15
1985 1990 1995 2000 1985 1990 1995 2000
Time (R=50) Time (R=70)
MonECM for Germany at h=48 months MonECM for Germany at h=48 months
5 5
0 0
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-5 -5
-10 -10
-15 -15
-20 -20
1985 1990 1995 2000 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000
Time (R=100) Time (R=120)
72
MonECM for Japan at h=48 months MonECM for Japan at h=48 months
5 5
0 0
-5
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-5
-10
-10
-15
-15
-20
-25 -20
-30 -25
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Time (R=50) Time (R=70)
MonECM for Japan at h=48 months MonECM for Japan at h=48 months
5 5
0 0
Fluctuation test
Fluctuation test
-5 -5
-10 -10
-15 -15
-20 -20
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Time (R=100) Time (R=120)
73
1
UIRP
0.9 PPP
Monetary
0.8 Taylor-rule
Monetary Panel
P-value of CW Test at h=48
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
P-value of C W Test at h=1
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
P-value of GC-robust Test at h=1
74