The Medium Run
The Medium Run
The Medium Run
BLANCHARD
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
89
90 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1997
Continental
Spainf
0.30-
0.40 Canada
r " / \~~/ %.
/
0.35 v Un
UnitedKingdom
. I I I I
Source: Author's calculations, based on data from the Organisationfor Economic Co-operation and Development's data
diskette OECD Business Sector Data Base, 1997/1.
a. Sample periodends in 1996 for Canada,Germany,and the United States;for all othercountries,in 1995.
b. All income is ascribed to either capital or labor, so that capital income includes profits, interest paid by firms, and profit
taxes.
Olivier J. Blanchard 91
1. Two semantic issues arise here. First, as my definitionof a labor supply shift
indicates, I do not take "labor supply" necessarilyto mean competitivelabor supply,
but rather (and more generally), the relation between the wage and unemployment
implied by wage-setting in the labor market. Other researchershave variously called
this the wage curve, the wage-settingrelation,or the pseudo-labor-supply
curve. Second,
in order not to have labor supply and labor demandshift along a steady-stategrowth
path, I look at the wage adjustedfor total factor productivity.Thus a slowdown in
productivitygrowththat is not fully reflectedin a parallelslowdown of real wages-at
a given rateof unemployment-shows up as a laborsupply shift.
2. Again, by "labor demand" I do not necessarilymeancompetitivelabordemand,
but rather,the relationbetween the real wage and employmentthat emerges from the
employmentand pricing decisions of firms. This is sometimes called the price-setting
relationor the pseudo-labor-demand curve.
92 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
technologies that use less labor and more capital, thus decreasing the
marginal product of labor at a given ratio of labor to capital. It is
difficult to distinguish empirically between these two explanations on
the basis of aggregate evidence; to the extent that it speaks, this evi-
dence weakly favors the second. Whatever the cause, the effect of this
adverse shift in labor demand has been to increase unemployment fur-
ther, while at the same time increasing capital shares.
By contrast, the "Anglo-Saxon" countries appear to have been
largely shielded from both the adverse labor supply shifts of the 1970s
and the labor demand shifts of the 1980s and 1990s. This accounts for
the differences from the Continental countries in the evolution of un-
employment and of capital shares.
While it is true that the macroeconomic literature has not typically
focused on medium-run evolutions, this is not the first attempt to ex-
plore such issues. Michael Bruno and Jeffrey Sachs told the first half
of the story, showing how the failure of wages to adjust to lower
productivity growth and other adverse shocks could explain the rise in
unemployment in the 1970s.3 The present paper can be seen as an
update, emphasizing the role of labor demand shifts since the mid-
1980s. One of the purposes of the project led by Jacques Dreze and
Charles Bean in the 1980s was to identify the role of capital accumu-
lation in the rise of European unemployment, a theme closely related
to that discussed here.4 More recently, Edmund Phelps has argued that
the rise in European unemployment is best understood as a "structural
slump" distinct from business cycle fluctuations.5 Finally, the present
paper is closely related to the recent work of Ricardo Caballero and
Mohamad Hammour.6 Their analysis of the effects of specificity and
labor market institutions on capital accumulation and unemployment-
in particular, their explanation of "jobless growth" in France-can be
seen as providing some of the microeconomic foundations for the shifts
that I take instead as primitives.
The paper is organized as follows. With an eye on the evolution of
capital shares, the first section documents the evolution of capital,
employment, and wage and profit rates since 1970 in fourteen member
y = y(zn, k),
y = y(fi, k),
where fi zn.
Under the further assumption that the marginal product of labor is
equal to the wage, the following relation holds:
where aris the profit rate (that is, profit divided by the capital stock in
volume) and wv- w/z is the wage rate per efficiency unit. Furthermore,
g' is greater than zero: an increase in the ratio of labor to capital both
increases the profit rate and decreases the wage, and by implication,
increases the ratio of the profit rate to the wage. If, for example, the
production function exhibits a constant elasticity of substitution (CES),
the relation specified in equation 1 is log linear, with coefficient equal
to 1/U, where u is the elasticity of substitution between capital and
labor.
A simple exercise following from this is to examine empirically the
relation between the left- and right-hand sides of equation 1. One can
then ask: what is the implied elasticity of substitution between capital
and labor? Can an elasticity different from one explain the evolution of
capital shares in Continental countries in the 1980s? Or was there a
shift in the relation between the factor price and the factor quantity
ratios during that period?
I perform this exercise for fourteen OECD countries. For most of
the analysis below, I divide these into two groups: the first includes
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, It-
aly, the Netherlands, Spain, and Sweden; the second includes Canada,
the United Kingdom, and the United States. I refer to these, with some
license, as the Continental and the Anglo-Saxon countries, respec-
tively. Assignment to one or other of these two groups is based on the
96 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
evolution of capital shares. Typically, the period covered runs from the
late 1960s to 1995, depending on data availability.7
Throughout the paper, the main data source is the OECD data set for
the business sector in each country.8 Value added is net of indirect taxes
and is allocated either as labor income or as capital income.9 Labor
income includes the imputed income of self-employed individuals,
based on the average wage in the business sector; capital income in-
cludes the residual income of the self-employed. Employment is mea-
sured as the number of workers, without adjustment for hours worked
(so that given the decline in hours per worker, employment growth
typically is overstated and productivity growth understated). I make
one modification to the data. The OECD data are adjusted for the
number of unpaid family workers, who must be deducted from total
private employment because their output is not measured. When this
adjustment does not start at the beginning of the sample, I extend it to
earlier years, assuming a ratio of unpaid family workers to total em-
ployment equal to that in the first year for which it is available. '0
Under the assumption that labor is paid its marginal product, one
can construct the series for Harrod-neutral technological progress, z,
by constructing the Solow residual for each year, dividing it by the
contemporaneous share of labor, and integrating it over time. Then one
can construct labor in efficiency units by multiplying employment by
the constructed z, and the wage in efficiency units by dividing the real
product wage (the wage divided by the deflator for business sector GDP)
by z.
Figure 2 plots the evolution of average factor price ratios and average
factor quantity ratios for the Continental and Anglo-Saxon countries.
The averages are constructed with 1980 relative GDPs, using purchas-
ing power parity exchange rates, and each ratio is normalized to equal
1.0 in each country in 1970. This figure makes two points. In the
Continental countries, the period up to the early 1980s was character-
ized both by a decrease in the profit rate relative to the wage rate (in
efficiency units) and by a decrease in labor (in efficiency units) relative
to capital. Since that time, however, the profit rate has improved rela-
tive to the wage, while the ratio of labor to capital has continued to
decrease, albeit more slowly. This is what lies behind the increase in
the capital share. By contrast, in the Anglo-Saxon countries, the evo-
lutions of the factor price and factor quantity ratios show little or no
trend, and the movements appear to reflect business cycle fluctuations
rather than medium-run evolutions.
Next, I take a more formal econometric approach, although still in
the spirit of data description. Let pratioi, ln(wi,/i-,) be the log of the
factor price ratio and qratioi, ln(fii,/ki,)be the log of the factor quantity
ratio, where i is the country and t is time. One can then run the following
panel regression:
(2) pratioi, = y(qratioi,) + xi + x, + Ei,,
where xi and x, are coefficients on country and time dummies, respec-
tively.
The results for both Continental and Anglo-Saxon countries are re-
ported in table 1 and figure 3. Table 1 gives the estimated coefficient y
and the significance level associated with the test that all the coefficients
on the time dummies are equal to zero. Figure 3 plots the time series
of estimated coefficients on the time dummies (normalized so that the
value in 1970 is equal to zero), along with two-standard-error bands.
98 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
Figure 2. Factor Price and Factor Quantity Ratios across Three Decades,
Continentaland Anglo-SaxonCountriesa
Continental
Index,1970= 1
0.90 0.90
0.80 0.80 -
0.70 0.70 -
Anglo-Saxon
Profit/wage Labor/capital
1.05-
1.20-
1.00
1.10
0.95-
0.90
1.00
l l l l l l
Continental
0.4
0.2
0.0
0 L* * <~~~~~~~~~00
-0.2
Anglo-Saxon
0.4
0.2 VZ<
0.0 7
L I I I I I I I
11. Another source of bias is measurement error in capital, which affects capital and
the profit rate-computed as profit divided by capital-in opposite directions. To the
extent that this measurement error is highly serially correlated (as is likely), the problem
will not be solved by using those instruments; indeed, it is not easy to solve.
102 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 2:1997
12. When there are costs of adjusting labor or factor proportions, as in the previous
interpretation, this ratio has to be redefined to include marginal costs of adjustment in
addition to the wage. The specifics are better left to the formal model below.
13. Some simple algebra may help here. Let pLbe the ratio of price (P) to marginal
cost (MC): P = pLMC.If firms take the wage as given, marginal cost is given by the
wage divided by the marginal product of labor (MP): MC = WIMP. Putting the two
relations together gives P = pLWIMP;or, defining the real wage as w = WIP, p. =
MPIw, which is my definition of the markup.
14. Phelps (1994).
Olivier J. Blanchard 103
led firms to develop or adopt new technologies that were biased against
labor. Indeed, the distinction between movements along an isoquant
(choices among existing technologies) and shifts in the isoquant (de-
velopment and adoption of new technologies) is probably much sharper
in economists' models than in reality.
TRADE AND COMPOSITION EFFECTS. A fourth interpretation dismisses
the shifts in the relation between factor prices and factor quantities as
reflecting composition effects. A particularly strong statement along
these lines is the factor price equalization theorem. Simply put, to the
extent that trade leads to factor price equalization, one should not expect
any relation between the ratio of aggregate factor quantities and the
ratio of factor prices in a country. Thus what I have called shifts in that
relation may merely capture the effects of the world factor quantity
ratio on domestic factor price ratios-although the difference between
factor price evolutions in the Continental and in the Anglo-Saxon coun-
tries would appear to be prima facie evidence against the hypothesis of
factor price equalization.
One way to explore the relative importance of composition effects is
to look at more disaggregated evidence within each country. Under the
factor price equalization theorem, the relation between factor prices and
factor quantities should hold for each firm but disappear at the aggregate
level, because of the composition effects induced by trade. I have
started looking at sectoral evidence in France, at roughly the two-digit
(by Standard Industrial Classification) level of disaggregation, and find
that the increase in the share holds in nearly all tradable sectors. Unless
composition effects are only at work at a lower level of disaggregation,
this suggests that the factor price equalization theorem is not the main
source of the evolutions described above.
17. Caballero and Hammour (1998) build a richer model, with explicit putty clay
Olivier J. Blanchard 105
The Model
The basic structure of the model is a set of demand and supply
equations for labor and for capital. The two demand relations are de-
rived from costs of changing capital and costs of changing factor pro-
portions. Capital accumulation depends on current and expected future
marginal profits; adjustment in factor proportions, on the relation be-
tween current and expected marginal revenue products and wages. On
the supply side, the wage is an increasing function of employment,
while the interest rate is assumed independent of capital accumulation.
The specific assumptions are as follows.
The economy is composed of monopolistically competitive firms.
The reason for introducing monopolistic competition is to be able to
trace the effects of markup changes, taking these as a stand-in for shifts
in the distribution of rents in the economy.
Each firm uses one unit of capital, which it combines with variable
amounts of labor to produce output. The production function of a firm
is given by"8
The capital stock is thus equal to the number of firms in the economy,
and changes in the capital stock correspond to the entry and exit deci-
sions of firms. A continuing firm makes only one decision at any point
in time: how much labor to employ. Note that n is both employment in
a given firm and the ratio of labor to capital for the economy as a whole.
This separation between capital accumulation decisions and factor pro-
portion decisions is inessential; but keeping these decisions sharply
distinct is helpful for the discussion of adjustment of capital and labor
below.
As noted, each firm is monopolistically competitive in the goods
market. The demand for its good is given, in inverse form, by
technology and explicit bargaining in the labor market. This allows them to relate
macroeconomic outcomes to institutional changes in the structure of bargaining, un-
employment benefit rules, and so on. In this paper, I take a number of shortcuts that
keep the model simpler but, admittedly, poorer.
18. Harrod-neutral technological progress can be introduced straightforwardly; all
that is needed is to measure labor and wages in efficiency units. For notational simplicity,
I leave it out at this stage but reintroduce it when I look at actual economies.
106 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
P= 0y ? y K 1,
ly\
where p is the price charged by the firm relative to the price level, y is
average output, and y is the inverse of the elasticity of demand. It
follows from this constant elasticity specification that the markup of
price over marginal cost charged by a firm will be equal to pL
1/(1 - y).
Each firm faces costs of adjusting its ratio of labor to capital; equiv-
alently, its employment level. Rather than explicitly allowing for a
putty clay structure of technology, I assume that each firm faces costs
of adjusting factor proportions. Specifically, I assume the cost of ad-
justinig n to be given by (c/2)(dn/dt)2, where c is a parameter.
Each firm faces a constant probability of death 8, a real interest rate
r, and a real wage (in terms of the price level) w. Under these assump-
tions, at any point in time, the firm chooses employment so as to
maximize its value, given (for time 0) by
v e ( ) LT-(2)(d)2 dt,
where
7rT p y- w n.
The first order conditions and the symmetry condition that all firms
must charge the same price, so that p = 1, are then given by
dn I
dt c
dq =
(r + 8)q -T,,
dt
= (ii)f,(n, 1) -w.
the long run, the marginal product of labor must be equal to the real
wage times the miarkup(equivalently, the marginal revenue product of
labor must be equal to the real wage). Denoting steady-state values by
a star,
dK
(5) Pk 1 + hd
V Pk,
where v is the value of the firm, defined above. If firms could freely
choose their initial factor proportions, the model would yield a distri-
bution of factor proportions across firms, with the proportion depending
on time of entry. To avoid such heterogeneity, I assume that new firms
enter with the same ratio of labor to capital as existing firms. This keeps
the model tractable; but it also eliminates the entry and exit of firms as
a candidate channel for change in aggregate factor proportions over
time. 19
The value of a new firm must be equal to the price of the machine
needed to produce its goods. From the definition of v above, v is char-
acterized by
19. One of the contributions of Caballero and Hammour's (1998) model is that it
keeps track of the distribution of firms and its implications, for example, for wage
bargaining.
108 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
Entry takes place (equivalently, the capital stock increases) when the
value of an existing firm is greater than one. In steady state, dvldt =
dnldt = dK/dt = 0, so that the previous equations imply that
(6) w = * (r + 8) = (r + 8).
(7) w =0 (0 )
where ,Bis the elasticity of the wage with respect to employment and 0
is a multiplicative constant. And I assume r to be exogenous. This is a
strong assumption. In combination with equation 6, it implies that the
long-run supply curve of capital is infinitely elastic and the profit rate
always returns to the same value: r + 6.
crease in the capital share, I also examine the case where a is equal to
2.0.
The probability of death for firms (8)-equivalently, the depreciation
rate-is equal to 0.1 and the real interest rate (r) is equal to 0.05. The
initial value of y is 0, corresponding to the case of perfect competition;
this implies a value for the markup ([t) of 1.0.
The value for c is equal to 4.0. In a world in which production was
strictly putty clay, only the newly installed capital stock-roughly
10 percent of the total each year-would embody the new desired factor
proportions. This would imply a mean lag of adjustment of 4.5 years.
In the present case, my chosen value of c implies that firms each year
close roughly 17 percent of the gap between desired and actual factor
proportions. This, in turn, implies a mean lag of 4.8 years.
The value for h is equal to 10.0. This implies an elasticity of invest-
ment with respect to the relative price of capital (pk) of 1.0. Empirical
evidence on the relation of investment to Tobin's q yields lower elas-
ticities, and thus higher implied values for h. But as discussed in that
literature, these estimates of h are likely to be biased upward. The
instrumental variable approach used by Jason Cummins, Kevin Hassett,
and Glenn Hubbard yields an elasticity of about 0.7.20
I normalize the labor force to be equal to 1.0. I choose 0 equal to
0.35, which implies zero unemployment in the initial steady state. The
elasticity of the wage with respect to employment ,Bis equal to 1.0. For
an average unemployment rate of 10 percent, this corresponds to an
elasticity of roughly 0. 1, which is close to the estimates of David
Blanchflower and Andrew Oswald for a number of countries. My work
with Lawrence Katz suggests that the elasticity is, in fact, lower in the
short run and higher in the long run; I ignore those dynamics here.22
These parameters and their implications for steady-state values of
output and other variables are presented in table 2.
0.13
6 1
-:=1 0.35
0.122
Profit/wage Labor/capital
0.40 / 1.00
0.98-
0.36
-
0.32 ~~~~~~~0.96
Capitalshare Unemploymentrate
0.30 /--0.08- -
0.28 0.06
0.26 0.04
0.24 0.02
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time(quarters) Time(quarters)
Source:Author'scalculations,as describedin text.
a. Graphsshow simulateddynamic effects of a 10 percent increase in the parameter0; the increase occurs in quarter5. Solid
line results when elasticity of substitutionis set to one; dashed line, when elasticity is set to two. All other parameterstake the
values given in table 2.
112 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
return to its initial value. This implies that the wage must also return
to its initial value. Given the unit elasticity of the wage with respect to
employment, both employment and capital decrease by 10 percent. The
capital share returns to its initial value, and the unemployment rate
increases to 10 percent.
In summary, adverse labor supply shifts can generate both an in-
crease in unemployment over time and the kind of movement in the
capital share that has been observed in the Continental countries-
namely, an initial decrease followed, in the medium run, by a more
than full recovery. But to the extent that unemployment puts pressure
on the wage to return to its initial value, the medium-run increase in
the capital share is quite small. In the simulation corresponding to a =
2.0, the capital share never rises much above its initial level.
INCREASE IN THE MARKUP. Figure 5 shows the effects of an unex-
pected, permanent, increase in the markup: a 10 percentage point in-
crease in w.23 Recall that the markup acts like a tax on labor. Thus in
response to an increase in the markup, firms decrease employment over
time. This leads to an increase in unemployment, and higher unem-
ployment, in turn, leads to a decrease in the wage. As a result of both
of these effects, the capital share increases. Thus in the medium run,
the markup shift leads to both an increase in the capital share and an
increase in unemployment.
The decrease in the wage, in turn, leads to an increase in the profit
rate. Thus a second mechanism comes into play: the entry of firms in
response to the higher profit rate. Unemployment, after its initial in-
crease, starts to fall; the rise in the number of firms dominates the
decrease in the ratio of labor to capital in each individual firm.
In the long run, the implication of free entry and a given interest rate
is that the profit rate must return to its original value. Thus to a first
approximation, the wage also must return to its initial value, as must
unemployment; the effect on employment of a lower ratio of labor to
capital in each firm is offset by a larger number of firms, a larger capital
stock.24 The capital share, however, remains permanently higher, as
the ratio of labor to capital is lower at any given wage rate.
23. Rotembergand Woodford(1991, 1998) draw attentionto the role that changes
in markupsplay in business cycle fluctuations.This paperdrawsattentionalso to their
potentialmedium-runimplications.
24. "To a firstapproximation"meansthat the resultholds for small changes in the
OlivierJ. Blanchard 113
Profitrate Wagerate
0.165- -- 0?35?h0
0.160 - Jr 0.345
0.155 - 0.340 -
0.150 0.335 -
=2x
Profit/wage,, - Labor/capital
1.0
0.47-
0.49i -< . ..
0.45-
0.43 0.
Capitalshare ,-
0.38 -
0.36 -
o
0.02
0.32-
0.00
0.30 Unemploymentrate
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time(quarters) Time(quarters)
Source:Author'scalculations,as describedin text.
a. Graphsshow simulated dynamic effects of a 10 percent increase in the markup(the parameterp); the increase occurs in
quarter5. Solid line results when elasticity of substitutionis set to one; dashed line, when elasticity is set to two. All other
parameterstake the values given in table 2.
114 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
While the markup in the model comes from monopoly power in the
goods market, any change in the distribution of rents that leads to an
increase in iL will have similar effects. Consider, for example, an in-
crease in V. coming from a decrease in featherbedding practices. The
dynamics will be identical to those shown in figure 5.25 At a given
wage, firms want to reduce employment, and they do so over time. This
leads to an increase in unemployment, but also a higher profit rate and
a higher capital share. Over time, the increase in the profit rate leads
to entry of firms and capital accumulation, and consequently unem-
ployment decreases until it has returned roughly to its initial level. By
this time, the profit rate has returned to its normal level, but the capital
share remains high.
In summary, in the short and medium runs increases in the markup
lead to an increase in unemployment and an increase in the capital
share. Unemployment does eventually return to its initial value but, as
the simulation shows, this takes a very long time. Thus upward markup
shifts-or, more generally, shifts in the distribution of rents from work-
ers to firms-appear potentially able to explain the evolutions in the
Continental countries since the early 1980s.
BIASED TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE. I formalize the effects of biased
technological change as an increase in the coefficient on capital (a) in
the production function given by equation 8. In the Cobb-Douglas case,
this takes the simple form of an increase in the exponent for capital and
a corresponding decrease in the exponent for labor. This formalization
captures the idea that new technologies save on labor, and has the
advantage that the bias is well defined even in the Cobb-Douglas case.26
Figure 6 shows the effects of a 10 percentage point increase in the
0.170 F 1 0.35
0.16 0.34 -
0.15 03
Profit/wage Labor/capital
0.50 ~~~~ -
~~~~~0.80
0.45 0.70
Capitalshare
0.45 0.06
0.40 - - 0.04 - -
0.35 - 0.02 -
0.30 0.00
Unemploymentrate
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time(quarters) Time(quarters)
The next step is to see whether and how the model can explain
observed evolutions in specific countries. It would be overambitious
and space-consuming to analyze each country individually in this paper.
Therefore I present the results for one country-France-and then sum-
marize the results for the others.
(9) ln w = ln 0 - u,
where u is the unemployment rate and w-is, again, the wage in efficiency
units. I first construct the series for the wage in efficiency units.28 I
then construct the series for (log) labor supply shifts as ln 0 -lnii +
3u. Finally, I normalize this series to equal zero in 1970.
By constructing labor supply shifts in this way, I do not mean to
imply that the "true" labor supply relation has the form of equation 9.
As mentioned above, the true labor supply or wage relation has richer
dynamics-from overlapping wage-setting to hysteresis-and includes
many other variables. Thus the labor supply shifts that I construct are
combinations of these dynamic effects and movements in these other
variables. The best way to think about equation 9 and these labor supply
shifts is as giving the distance of the wage from that which, in the
absence of other shifts, would allow the economy to return to its 1970
unemployment rate.
Figure 7 shows labor supply shifts in France for three values of 3:
1.0 (the value that I use above and again in the simulations below),
0.5, and 1.5. All three series show a large increase in the early 1970s,
with the wage increasing much faster than measured total factor pro-
ductivity; a peak at around 15 percent (for the intermediate case) in the
early 1980s; and a subsequent decline. In 1996, the value of labor
supply shifts stands between 1 and 10 percent, depending on the value
of P. Put another way, French wages in efficiency units are lower today
than they were in 1970; but they would be too high if unemployment
decreased, subjecting them to upward pressure. How high is "too high"
depends on the assumed value of ,3, the effect of unemployment on the
wage.
Relating these labor supply shifts to specific changes in the economic
environment and in labor market institutions must wait for another
paper. But based on the large amount of research on European unem-
ployment, I do not think that there is any great mystery about what lies
28. RobertHall has shown that if the markupis differentfromone, the computation
of total factorproductivitygrowthmust be modifiedto take accountof the effect of the
markupon the shares; see, for example, Hall (1990). The results reportedhere are
derivedunderthe assumptionthatthe averagemarkupduringthe periodis equalto 1.0.
I have carriedout the same exercise underthe assumptionthat the average markupis
equal to 1.2, with very similarresults.
/
(tolt/~~~ 2- '9
00
- -~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~E7
1 I
I- '-
- /~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C
/,momQo O 00
; o2/
iii
oY, o o o
Olivier J. Blanchard 119
where
ln 0i, = A ln + (1 - X) ln i,
envelope computations. For example, a decrease in the labor share from 0.7 to 0.6
implies an increasein the markupof roughly 15 percent.
31. For a detailed discussion of this and other issues in the constructionof the
markup,see Rotembergand Woodford(1998).
Olivier J. Blanchard 121
AlternativeadjustmentCoStSb
0.10_
0.50 -
0.00
-0.50
large negative values beginning in the mid- 1970s and then turns positive
in the mid- 1980s. But the other two graphs show that the initial decrease
is largely spurious, coming from the slow adjustment of firms away
from labor in the face of the wage push. For X equal to 0.8, the markup
shows a small decline in the late 1970s and a large increase since the
late 1980s. For A equal to 0.9, the increase only starts in 1990. Note
that in all three cases, the value of the markup shift is large and positive
at the end of the period; the value of A affects only the timing of the
increase.
The two graphs in the lower panel of figure 8 correspond to different
values of cr: 1.0 (the benchmark) and 2.0. In both cases, A is set equal
to 0.8. The higher value of cr yields a more pronounced decline in the
1980s and a smaller value of the shift at the end of the period.
The series for the markup shifts is derived under the assumption that
the production function is time invariant (up to Harrod-neutral techno-
logical progress); in particular, ln(1 - a) is constant in equation 10.
But these shifts could equally have been called technological bias shifts,
corresponding to changes in the coefficient a, with ji remaining con-
stant. Equation 10 makes clear that if one looks only at labor demand,
changes in ln ji and changes in - ln(1 - a) are observationally equiv-
alent. Thus one could equally interpret figure 8 as showing technolog-
ical bias in favor of capital-an increase in a-since the mid-1980s. I
discuss below whether and how one can use other evidence to distin-
guish between the two explanations.
SHIFTS IN USER COST. To construct the time series for shifts in the
cost of capital (r + 8), I use the depreciation ("scrapping") rate from
OECD data for 8. I construct r in three different ways. Figure 9 presents
the resulting user cost series for France.
In the series that I use for simulations below, I construct r as equal
to the long nominal interest rate minus the average rate of inflation over
the previous five years. This is labeled "bonds, method 1" in figure 9.
The second series uses the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate
over the previous year, and is labeled "bonds, method 2." The third
series, "bonds and equity," constructs the required rate of return as a
weighted average of the real interest rate on bonds-which, in turn, is
constructed as the nominal interest rate minus a five-year average of
inflation-and of the required rate of return on equity-which itself is
constructed as the sum of the ratio of dividends to prices plus a five-
ol~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
Eu
Cu
- -~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~4
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-1
00 ~~~0&
001
Cu~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Cu ~~~~~~
G.0~~~~~~~~~~~
o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-
0 2
Cu~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~,0
;z~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~*
00~
124 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 2:1997
year average of past output growth (an admittedly rough proxy for the
expected rate of growth of dividends). The weights are 0.7 on bond
finance and 0.3 on equity finance.
All three series show a low user cost in the 1970s, a peak associated
with disinflation in the early 1980s, and another peak in the early 1990s,
associated with German reunification and the "Franc fort" policy. The
user cost using one year of lagged inflation rather than a five-year
average is higher during most of the 1980s and a little higher at the end
of the series. The user cost assuming bond and equity finance shows
little trend and finishes lower than the other two series. This is because
the steady decrease in the ratio of dividends to prices and in the growth
rate over the past fifteen years imply a steady decrease in the estimated
required rate of return on equity over that period.32
32. I have so far ignoredthe trenddecline in the relative price of capital, which is
absentfromthe modelabove but is empiricallyrelevantfor a numberof OECDcountries.
In France, however, this factor is not very important.The relative price of investment
goods has decreasedby only 6 percentsince 1970.
Olivier J. Blanchard 125
Profitrate Wagerate
0.15 03
0.14-
0.36
0.13-
0.12 0.3
Profit/wage Labor/capital
0.45 - 0.95
0.40 0.90
0.35 -0.85 -
0.30 0.80
Capitalshare Unemploymentrate
0.36 -0.08 -
0.06-
0.32-
0.04-
-
0.28 - 0.02
Profitrate Wagerate
0.18 - 0.37
0.16 -0.36
0.14 0.35
0.12 --=10.34'v
Profit/wage lo ratal
0.50
0.40 09
0.85-
0.30
Capitalshare Unemploymentrate
0.35 0.10
0.25 0.00
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
Source:Author'scalculations(see figure 1).
a. Graphsshow the paths that variablesfollow in response to the constructedlabor supply and user cost shifts that occurredin
France over the sample period. The constructionof the time series of these shifts is described in the text and in the notes to
figures 7 and 9; the user cost series is constructedusing long bond rates deflatedby the inflationrate over the previous five years.
Solid line results when elasticity of substitution(a) is set to one; dashed line, when elasticity is set to two. All other parameters
take the values given in table 2.
Olivier J. Blanchard 127
33. The fit between the actualevolutions in figure 10 and the simulatedevolutions
in figure 12 is clearly very good. This, however, is largelyby construction.Recall that
the series for the laborsupply and demandshifts are constructedso as to makethe labor
supplyandthe labordemandrelationsfit exactly. If the model hadno internaldynamics,
the overall fit would be perfect. To the extent that the model determinesthe dynamics
of capital accumulationand factorproportionsendogenously,the fit can still turnout to
be poor. Table3 below, which reportsthe simulationresultsfor each of the otherthirteen
countries in the sample, shows that predictedunemploymentcan differ substantially
from actualunemployment.
34. I was unableto solve the model for Spain and the United Kingdom,apparently
because of large negative real interestrates in the mid-1970s. The simulationsreported
for these countriesassume a constantuser cost.
128 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1997
Figure 12. SimulatedEffects of HistoricalLabor Supply and Demand and User Cost
Shifts, France, 1970-96a
Profitrate Wagerate
0.16 03
0.36-
0.14
0.35
0.12 - 103
cT2
Profit/wage Labor/capital
0.45 0.96
0.40 0.92 7/
0.35 /0.88
Capitalshare Unemploymentrate
0.35 -- 0.10
0.30 0.05 -
l~ ~~~
l I
0.25 -0.00
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
Source:Author'scalculations(see figure 1).
a. Graphsshow the paths that variablesfollow in response to the constructedlabor supply, labor demand,and user cost shifts
that occurredin Franceover the sample period. The constructionof the time series of these shifts is described in the text and in
the notes to figures 7, 8, and 9. Solid line results when elasticity of substitution(a) is set to one; dashed line, when elasticity is set
to two. All otherparameterstake the values given in table 2.
Olivier J. Blanchard 129
Table 3. Labor Supply and Demand Shifts and Implied and Actual Unemployment
Rate Changes, 1970-95a
Percentage points
1970-81 1981-95
Change in Change in
and demand shifts, it is useful to recall that over a period of five to ten
years, the effect of 1 percent adverse shift in labor supply is to increase
the unemployment rate by about 0.8 percentage points. Over the same
period, a 1 percent adverse shift in labor demand increases the unem-
ployment rate by about 0.4 percentage point. Table 3 suggests a number
of conclusions.
The model does a decent job of explaining unemployment evolutions
across countries and across subperiods. The cross-country correlation
between predicted and actual changes in unemployment is 0.60 for the
first subperiod and 0.36 (excluding Canada, 0.65) for the second
subperiod.
130 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
35. The OECD is not to blame, as its data on the price of investmentgoods are
consistent with those publishedby Canada.Accordingto StatisticsCanada,the price of
producer'sdurableequipmentrelative to the GDP deflatorhas decreasedfrom 100 in
1970 to 33.8 in 1995 (comparedwith 62.9 in the UnitedStates, accordingto the Bureau
of EconomicAnalysis). Partof the problemappearsto be the OECD's use of an implicit
price deflator for Canada, but a chain index for the United States. Canadahas now
introduceda chain index and its evolution is much closer to that of the United States. I
could not, however, use this new index in my simulations,as it only goes back to 1981.
Olivier J. Blanchard 131
Leaving aside such problems and puzzles, table 3 suggests that the
increase in unemployment in the Continental countries is typically ex-
plained by adverse labor supply shifts in the first subperiod and adverse
labor demand shifts in the second. Just as has been seen for France,
these later adverse labor demand shocks also explain the increase in
capital shares. It is interesting to note that the model suggests that labor
demand shifts have played a more limited role in Germany than in
France: most of the decrease and later recovery of capital shares in
Germany is accounted for simply by the dynamic response of factor
proportions to factor prices.
Table 4. Regressing Factor Quantity Ratios on Current and Lagged Wage Rates,
1961-95a
Coefficient on wages
Sum p valuesb
Panel and Time t -3 to t -I to Lagged Time
estimator dummies Current t-I t-2 t -9 t -9 wages dummies
Continental
OLS No -0.14 -0.51 -0.31 -1.31 -2.27 0.00 ...
OLS Yes -0.74 -0.35 -0.30 -1.09 -2.47 0.00 0.00
IVC No -0.51 -0.44 -0.44 -1.40 -2.79 0.00 ...
IVC Yes -0.87 -0.37 -0.32 -1.13 -2.69 0.00 0.00
Anglo-Saxon
OLS No -1.19 -0.49 -0.16 -0.10 -1.94 0.00 ...
OLS Yes -1.09 -0.34 -0.32 -0.20 -1.95 0.00 0.09
IVC No -1.30 -0.47 -0.16 -0.03 -1.96 0.00
IVC Yes -1.37 -0.33 -0.60 0.79 -1.51 0.00 0.05
Source: Author's regressions (see table I).
a. The dependent variable is the log factor quantity ratio, In (filk)j,, where ht is labor in efficiency units and k is the capital
stock in country i and year t. Independent variables include current and lagged values of the log wage per efficiency unit,
In wi,,in addition to country and time fixed effects. Equation estimated is ( 12) in the text. Samples are as described in notes
to table I.
b. Probability of obtaining these data given that all lagged wage or time dummy coefficients are zero. Covariance matrix
is Newey-West corrected.
c. Estimated using constructed labor supply shifts (see figure 7), lagged zero to nine years, as instruments for wages in
efficiency units.
k is capital; wviis the wage per efficiency unit of labor; xi and xt are
country and time fixed effects, respectively; and +(L) is a lag polyno-
mial. As is well known, this log-log specification does not hold exactly,
except in the Cobb-Douglas case-this is why the estimation above
relied instead on a log-log relation between factor price and factor
quantity ratios, which holds for the CES case-and must be thought of
as a log approximation. Under that interpretation, the sum of estimated
coefficients on current and lagged wages, 4(1), is approximately equal
to the ratio of the elasticity of substitution to the share of capital, u/a.
This fact is useful for interpreting the results below.
The results of this estimation are reported in table 4 and figure 13.
Table 4 presents four sets of results for each group. Two are obtained by
ordinary least squares, with and without time dummies. The other two are
obtained using instrumental variables, with and without time dummies.
For the present purposes, the labor supply shifts constructed earlier are
natural instruments.37The regression results yield two conclusions.
37. Another issue arises from the fact that business cycles generate a correlation
Olivier J. Blanchard 133
Figure 13. Time Variationin Factor Quantity Ratios, Controllingfor Wage Rates,
Continentaland Anglo-SaxonCountries,1963-95a
Log index, 1970= 0
Continental
0.0
{).1
-0.1I > wages
h ~~~~~~~~~~~lagged
-0.2
-0.3
Anglo-Saxon
0.1
Withlagged wages
0.0
-0.1I
-0.2
Withoutlagged wages
-0.3
I I ~~~I ~ ~I ~ ~I ~ I
First, there is evidence of long lags in labor demand. While the best
lag length varies across specifications, the results suggest that up to
nine years are needed to capture the dynamics of adjustment. If one
takes the average capital share to equal 0.35, the sum of coefficients
on current and lagged wages implies an elasticity of substitution a little
under 1.0, which is unable to yield a significant medium-run increase
in the capital share in response to adverse labor supply shifts.
Second, even allowing for lags, time dummies remain highly signif-
icant for the Continental countries, but are only marginally so for the
Anglo-Saxon countries. More information is given in figure 13, which
plots the series of time fixed effects estimated by instrumental variables,
for each group. For comparison, it also plots the series of time effects
from a regression that allows only for current wages-and country
dummies. For the Anglo-Saxon countries, the shifts are small, whether
or not one allows for lags in labor demand. For the Continental coun-
tries, allowing for lags reduces the size of shifts in the 1970s but does
not otherwise change the general shape of the shifts: there is still a large
unexplained adverse shift in labor demand increasing from the early
1980s to the present.
between the ratio of labor (in efficiency units) to capital and the wage (in efficiency
units), due either to deviations of the marginalproductfrom the wage or to mismea-
surementof total factorproductivity.A demand-drivenboom is typicallyassociatedwith
high measuredtotalfactorproductivitygrowth.Highmeasuredproductivitygrowthleads
to a large increase in labor measuredin efficiency units (fi) and a large decrease in the
wage per efficiency unit (w). In orderto alleviate some of the business cycle effects, I
have tried using only values of the labor supply shifts lagged by three or more years.
The resultingpatternof estimatedcoefficients is typically nonsensical.
Olivier J. Blanchard 135
A value of 4 equal to zero implies that the change in the share is due
to markup changes. A value of 4 equal to one implies that the change
in the share is due to biased technological progress.
Estimating equation 14 requires the specification of z, the technolog-
ical level.39 I assume that ln z;, (for country i at time t) is equal to a
country-specific quadratic trend, f,(t), plus a stationary component, Ei,.
If one assumes that -a, the underlying constant value of a under HI, is
equal to the mean value of the share in the sample, one can construct
the time series for the dependent variable, X1 [ln(ylk) - (1 --a)
ln(nlk)], and the first right-hand-side variable, X2 -- [(a-- o)
ln(nlk)], and run the following panel regression:
40. The results are very similar if only the Continentalcountriesare used. The test
has little power for the Anglo-Saxon countries, because their shares do not vary very
much.
138 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
Conclusions
41. Those who have read an early version of the presentpaper(Blanchard, 1996)
may note the absence of a theme developed there: the relation between inflation and
markups.My initial work showed a strongtime-seriesrelationbetween the increaseof
the measuredmarkupand the decrease in inflation. Now that I have adjustedthe con-
structionof markupsto take into account lags of adjustmentof factor proportions,the
relationremainsbut is weaker. And when time effects are allowed in panel regressions
of factorprices on factorquantities,domestic inflationfor each countryis only margin-
ally significant. For these reasons, I have left the explorationof a potential relation
between markupsand inflationto furtherwork.
42. See, for example, Jackman,Layard,and Nickell (1996).
140 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
demand for labor is an infinitely elastic function of the real wage rate;
the labor demand curve shifts down with an increase in the rate of
interest, the rate of capital taxation, the depreciation rate, and the Cobb-
Douglas share of capital. The steady-state properties are that adverse
or upward shifts in labor supply have no effect on real wages but do
increase the "unemployment rate." Adverse or downward shifts in
labor demand are fully reflected in a lower real wage and also produce
a steady-state change in the unemployment rate.
Blanchard uses the model to simulate the impact of different shocks
to the system. He suggests that Continental countries suffered from a
series of adverse labor supply shifts in the 1970s. These would clearly
lead to increases in the unemployment rate. (Be warned that the un-
employment rate is a mixture of voluntary unemployment, efficiency
wage and wait unemployment, and classical unemployment, but no real
cyclical unemployment of the Keynesian variety.) Blanchard's model
also shows that these shocks lead to a decrease in capital shares, al-
though I am not convinced that this result is robust to changing the
modeling dynamics.
The new piece of the story concerns the last decade. Since the early
1980s, according to Blanchard, continental Europe has suffered a num-
ber of adverse labor demand shocks. There is some question in his mind
as to whether these represented biased technological change or shifts in
the markup, although his econometrics leads him to the conclusion that
they are likely to have been biased technological change, which in-
creased the Cobb-Douglas coefficient on capital. As for the Anglo-
Saxon world, Blanchard writes: "By contrast, the 'Anglo-Saxon' coun-
tries appear to have been largely shielded from both the adverse labor
supply shifts of the 1970s and the labor demand shifts of the 1980s and
1990s. This accounts for the differences from the Continental countries
in the evolution of unemployment and of capital shares."
I conclude by reflecting on which of the explanations for these phe-
nomena seem plausible and consistent with the cross-section of human
experience. To do so, I round up both the usual suspects and those
chosen by Blanchard. The augmented list of suspects comprises the
business cycle, the cost of capital, markups and market power, inter-
national trade, biased technological change, and labor market rigidities.
On the issue of the business cycle, profits and profit rates are highly
cyclical. This is probably a good part of the recent profits surge in the
146 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
Saxon countries are actually a subset of those with relatively free labor
markets; his Continental countries are high on the list of those with
major labor market rigidities. For example, consider the following
OECD ratings. Ranked on unemployment protection-using an inverse
French grading scale, where 1 affords the least employment protection
(the United States) and 20 affords the most (Italy)-the three Anglo-
Saxon countries have an average score 3.7, while France, Germany,
Italy, and Spain average 16.5. On the labor standards rating (a scale
from 0 to 7), the Anglo-Saxon countries average 0.7, while these four
Continental countries average 6.5. In terms of unemployment insur-
ance, these four Continental countries have a generosity rate (replace-
ment rate times maximum duration) of 180 percent-years, while the
Anglo-Saxon countries average 79 percent-years, a difference of almost
2 1/2 times. ' It would therefore be more plausible to classify the Anglo-
Saxon countries as the "FreeLabs" (those with largely free labor mar-
kets) and the Continental countries as the "RegLabs" (those with heav-
ily regulated labor markets).
This distinction would resolve half of the distributional puzzle, that
concerning the labor market, but the profit puzzle remains unsolved.
Unless the elasticity of substitution of capital for labor is greater than
one, there is no simple and robust story about why the RegLabs would
experience increasing profit rates or capital shares while these were
relatively stable in the FreeLabs. There may be lots of unemployment
in Europe, but there is still much work to be done by future Brookings
Panels on this fascinating and important issue.
employees and customers, and the natural rate is driven up. One can
call this markup increase, such as Blanchard talks about, but I am
talking about markup increases that are induced by the elevation of real
interest rates. Second, there is obviously a physical capital channel
from real interest rates to labor demand, which may operate only very
gradually.
The other suspect shock is hard to get a handle on, although the
paper makes some strides toward doing so. This shock is the new or
intensified labor-saving bias in technical change that set in around the
end of the 1970s. A slowdown of the marginal productivity of labor
coupled with a speed-up of the marginal productivity of capital (relative
to the old bias of technical progress) that leaves growth in total factor
productivity unchanged will slow labor demand at any given capital
stock, but at first the wage curve will not slow in tandem. Thus the
natural rate will be gradually pushed up.
In Blanchard's computations, the labor demand shifts from 1981 are
indeed adverse in almost all of the OECD countries studied, and they
are fairly large. (Interestingly, for reasons that I do not understand,
there tend to be some positive labor demand shifts in the 1970s; so, the
net change is even larger.) I am very pleased to see that the consensus
view, into which I have put a lot of effort, comes out quite well here.
Nevertheless, in places Blanchard seems to want to cast doubt on some
of these ideas.
In regard to the real interest rate hypothesis, in figure 9 Blanchard
uses a time series for France that depicts the real rate as having by 1986
returned all the way to its low levels of the late 1970s. If those data
were correct, the rise of real rates would be short-lived and one could
hardly ascribe any durable part of the rise of unemployment from 1980
onward to real interest rates. I think this peculiar series ("bonds,
method 1") is the result of Blanchard weighing distant inflation rates,
including the very high rates around 1980-82, as heavily as more recent
ones when calculating the real interest rate from the nominal interest
rate. (Lest there should be any doubt about the apparent importance of
the real rate, if one juxtaposes the graph of the evolution of the unem-
ployment rate in the United Kingdom and that of the world real interest
rate from the 1960s to recent times, it is difficult not to be impressed
by the fit.)
At another level, Blanchard pays close attention to the phenomenon
152 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
otherwise likely to lie down on the job or worse. Thus on this account,
the educational broadening in the American and British labor forces,
taken alone, must have raised labor's share and lowered the natural
rate. This development was not so strong in the Continental countries;
in Italy, for example, the differentials in unemployment rates between
educational groups are not so pronounced, or even go the wrong way.
It may also be true that desk jobs do not need as much physical capital
per worker as do production line jobs.
Fourth, the greater number of American workers with some educa-
tional credentials certainly increases the wage bill in the economy, since
the employer will pay these an educated worker's wage on the prospect
of recovering the cost when their wider knowledge and greater versa-
tility are needed. But the eventual payoff from their greater "promise,"
which justifies the wage premium, may be a long time in coming.
Although wages go up, productivity may increase only much later, after
the introduction of a new technology, a reorganization of the workforce,
or entry into a new market-that is, when the workers' knowledge and
versatility are really needed. On this account, then, labor's share may
grow for some time, as the fraction of the labor force that is paid on its
promise keeps rising. The fact that capital's share does not rise in the
United States and the United Kingdom therefore is not evidence that
the influence of world real interest rates on capitals share is absent or
weak.
To conclude, I do find this paper quite stimulating. In the end,
though, it leaves me wiser but in the same place.
References
Acemoglu, Daron. 1997. "Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills'?
Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality." Unpublished paper. Mas-
sachusetts Institute of Technology (August).
Blanchard, Olivier J. 1996. "Notes on Profit Shares in the OECD." Unpub-
lished paper. Massachusetts Institute of Technology (December).
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Lawrence F. Katz. 1997. "What We Know and Do
Not Know About the Natural Rate of Unemployment." Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11(1): 51-72.
Blanchflower, David G., and Andrew J. Oswald. 1994. The Wage Curve. MIT
Press.
Bruno, Michael, and Jeffrey D. Sachs. 1985. The Economics of Worldwide
Stagfiation. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Caballero, Ricardo J., and Mohamad L. Hammour. 1998. "Incomplete Con-
tracts, Factor Proportions, and Unemployment." Carnegie-Rochester Con-
ference Series on Public Policy 48 (forthcoming).
Cette, Gilbert, and Selma Mahfouz. 1996. "Le partage primaire du revenu: un
constat descriptif sur longue periode." Economie et Statistique (6-7):
165-89.
Cummins, Jason G., Kevin A. Hassett, and R. Glenn Hubbard. 1994. "A
Reconsideration of Investment Behavior Using Tax Reforms as Natural Ex-
periments." BPEA, 2:1994, 1-74.
Dickens, William T. 1995. "Do Labor Rents Justify Strategic Trade and In-
dustrial Policy?" Working Paper 5137. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research (May).
Dougherty, Chrys, and Dale W. Jorgenson. 1996. "International Comparisons
of the Sources of Economic Growth." American Economic Review, Papers
and Proceedings 86(2): 25-29.
Dreze, Jacques H., and Charles R. Bean, editors. 1990. Europe's Unemploy-
ment Problem. MIT Press.
Fortin, Nicole M., and Thomas Lemieux. 1997. "Institutional Changes and
Rising Wage Inequality: Is There a Linkage?" Journal of Economic Per-
spectives 11(2): 75-96.
Hall, Robert E. 1990. "Invariance Properties of Solow's Productivity Resid-
ual." In Growth, Productivity, Unemployment, edited by Peter Diamond.
MIT Press.
Hammermesh, Daniel S. 1993. Labor Demand. Princeton University Press.
Houthakker, H. S. 1956. "The Pareto Distribution and the Cobb-Douglas
Production Function in Activity Analysis." Review of Economic Studies
23(1): 27-31.
Jackman, Richard, Richard Layard, and Stephen Nickell. 1996. "Combatting
158 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1997
Unemployment: Is Flexibility Enough?" Paper prepared for the conference
"Interactions between Structural Reform, Macroeconomic Policies and Eco-
nomic Performance." Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Devel-
opment, Paris, January 18-19.
Johnson, George. 1990. "Work Rules, Featherbedding, and Pareto-optimal
Union-Management Bargaining." Journal of Labor Economics 8(1, part 2):
S237-59.
Laffargue, Jean Pierre, and Anne Saint-Martin. 1997. "Une simulation retro-
spective d'un modele WS-PS pour la France de 1974 'a 1993." Unpublished
paper. Paris: Cepremap and Eureqa (August).
Layard, Richard, Stephen Nickell, and Richard Jackman. 1991. Unemploy-
ment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market. Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Nickell, Stephen. 1997. "Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe
versus North America." Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(3): 55-74.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1994. Structural Slumps: The Modern Equilibrium Theory
of Unemployment, Interest, and Assets. Harvard University Press.
Phelps, Edmund S., and Gylfi Zoega. 1996. "The Incidence of Increased
Unemployment in the Group of Seven, 1970-1994." Centro Studi Paper
115. Rome: Centro Studi Confindustria (September).
Poterba, James M. 1998. "Recent Developments in Corporate Profitability:
Patterns and Explanations." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Pub-
lic Policy 48 (forthcoming).
Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. 1991. "Markups and the Busi-
ness Cycle." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991, edited by Olivier J.
Blanchard and Stanley Fischer. MIT Press.
. 1998. "The Cyclical Behavior of Prices and Costs." In Handbook of
Macroeconomics, edited by John Taylor and Michael Woodford. Amster-
dam: North-Holland (forthcoming).
Zeira, Joseph. Forthcoming. "Workers, Machines, and Economic Growth."
Quarterly Journal of Economics.