Module4 ConsumerChoiceTheory
Module4 ConsumerChoiceTheory
Module4 ConsumerChoiceTheory
Economics I
1 Completeness
If there are two consumption bundles A and B, which have (x1 , y1 ) and
(x2 , y2 ) of each of the two goods, X and Y, respectively, then, the
consumer must have: either A ≻ B or B ≻ A or A ∼ B
That is, the consumer is never in an ‘indecisive’ state and will be able
to develop some kind of preference ordering between the two bundles.
2 Transitivity
If there are three consumption bundles A, B and C which have (x1 , y1 ),
(x2 , y2 ) and (x3 , y3 ) of each of the two goods, X and Y,
respectively,then: if A ≻ B and B ≻ C then A ≻ C .
Similarly, for all the other preference relations denoted by ∼ and ≽,
this must hold true.
This axiom is important to make sure that a consumer’s preferences
are consistent.
Hence, we can see that the MUx declines from 5 to 3 and so on.
Please note that the total satisfaction on eating chocolates continues to
increase, that is, chocolate is still a ‘good’ and provides ‘positive total
utility’.
It is just its additional/marginal utility that declines.
Thus, DMU contributes to DMRS - how?
Along an IC - with the same level of utility, as consumption of good X
increases, then as per the law of DMU, the increase in utility from increased
consumption of X becomes smaller and smaller; hence, the number of units
of good Y to be sacrificed becomes smaller and smaller, to keep the utility
at the same level.
MUx
Based on this, we can prove that: MRS = MUy .
Two goods are said to be perfect complements which are consumed together
(in a certain proportion) to satisfy a given want.
These goods cannot be separately consumed. Hence, they satisfy a given
want only when consumed as a combination.
Examples: Car and oil, tea and sugar, left shoe and right shoe, etc.
In case of such goods, the consumer cares only about the total number of
combinations of consumption possible.
For example, in case of left shoe and right shoe, the consumer cares for the
number of total pairs of shoes; in case of tea and sugar, the consumer cares
for the total number of sweetened cups of tea they can have etc.
In other words, the consumer would judge a bundle based on the minimum
number of pairs they could assemble from the two commodities.
As indicated in the figure above, the two points at which the budget line intersects
the two axes are called the corresponding intercepts.
The horizontal intercept lies on the x-axis, and vertical intercept on the y-axis.
Horizontal Intercept: = PIX . It denotes the maximum possible consumption of
good X, at its given price, PX , and income, I , i.e. when the consumer spends all
their income on good X.
Likewise, Vertical Intercept: = PIY . It denotes the maximum possible consumption
of good Y, at its given prices, PY and income, I , i.e. i.e. when the consumer
spends all their income on good Y.
Dr. Divya Gupta Rational Choice Theory: Consumer Behaviour Economics I 24 / 32
Budget Constraint and Change in Income
As seen previously, the budget line is defined by: PX X + PY Y = I .
Thus, if there is any change in PX and/or PY and/or I , the budget line will change.
We first consider the effect of change in income (I ), assuming that there are no
changes in the two prices PX and PY .
If income increases from I to I1 , the budget line shifts outwards parallelly from AB
to A1 B1 (see figure below).
If the income decreases from I to I2 , the budget line shifts inwards parallelly from
AB to A2 B2 (see figure below).
The shifts in the budget line are parallel because the slope doesn’t change (Why? ).
The new budget lines will have the new intercept values as: A1 = PI1X , B1 = PI1Y ;
I2 I2
and A2 = PX
, B2 = PY
, respectively.
Suppose now the price of good Y (pepsi) decreases, with no change in the
income of consumer, and the price of good X (pizza), see figure on slide 30.
Due to this price change, the budget line rotates outwards towards vertical
axis, from AB to AD (why? - recall previous discussions).
With the new expanded budget set, if the consumer continues to consume
the initial optimal bundle E1 , it becomes sub-optimal - as the consumer can
now do much better.
Also, as per the new budget line, at E1 , the income is not exhausted.
Thus, the new optimal bundle chosen by the consumer will be E2 , where
consumption of both goods X (pizza) is decreasing and that of good Y
(pepsi) is increasing.
At E2 , the consumer’s utility is maximised by IC2 , which is the highest
possible IC for the new budget line AD.
Recall the starting point of this Based on the optimal bundles, under
discussion - we are trying to the three prices, as indicated by E1 ,
de-construct the demand curve, E2 and E3 , the quantity demanded of
which was assumed to be given. good X is, thus, X1 , X2 and X3 ,
Rational Choice Theory (or Utility respectively.
Theory) helps explain the
decision-making process that lie
behind each point on the demand
curve.
What is a demand curve? - it is the
locus/combination of optimal
decisions of the consumer, when
price of a good changes.
As shown in the figure, as price of
good X decreases from P1 to P2 and
further to P3 , the budget line of the
consumer rotates outwards from AB1
to AB2 and AB3 , respectively.
Dr. Divya Gupta Rational Choice Theory: Consumer Behaviour Economics I 31 / 32
ALL THE BEST!