The Theory of Consumer Behaviour: Property 1: Completeness. If An Individual Can Rank Any Pair of Bundles
The Theory of Consumer Behaviour: Property 1: Completeness. If An Individual Can Rank Any Pair of Bundles
Module 4
As we have illustrated, consumers’ efforts to get the most for their money
are reflected in their individual demand functions. Market-demand curves
are simply the aggregates of all individual consumer-demand curves.
Since utility is based on individual taste and preferences, each market-
demand curve reflects the aggregate market preferences of all consumers
in that market. Therefore, a market-demand curve is a powerful signal to
producers about what and how much to produce.
70
E5 Managerial Economics
Indifference curves
Let us consider some implications of these assumptions about preference
orderings. Most important, they enable us to generate a graphical
description of consumers’ preferences. An indifference curve defines the
combinations of two goods (or two bundles of goods) that give the
consumer the same level of satisfaction – they are equally preferred.
Along an indifference curve, the consumer is indifferent between
alternative combinations of goods X and Y. This is shown as the curve
labelled I, in Figure 4-1. Bundles A, B, C, and D are all equally preferred
combinations of X and Y located on the indifference curve providing the
consumer with the same level of satisfaction.
71
Module 4
Figure 4-1
I1, I2, and I3, in Figure 4-2, are index values used to denote the order of
preference that corresponds to the respective indifference curves.
Figure 4-2
72
E5 Managerial Economics
Figure 4-3
73
Module 4
Y MU x
X MU y
(2)
This willingness to exchange what we value less for what we value more
is true whether the owners of the commodities are individuals, firms, or
nations. Thus the marginal rate of substitution governs both domestic and
foreign trade.
Budget constraint
Indifference curves reflect the consumer’s personal feelings and the
relative values regarding the consumption of various combinations of any
two products. They show what combinations of X and Y the consumer is
willing to accept as equally satisfactory and they are totally independent
of the consumer’s income and market prices. Whereas indifference curves
show what the consumer is willing to do, income and market prices
determine what a consumer is able to do. In other words, the budget
constraint determines the combinations of X and Y that are affordable.
The consumer’s expenditure on X plus his or her expenditure on Y cannot
and does not exceed the consumer’s income. Assuming that the
consumer’s income is entirely spent on these two goods, we can write a
budget line relationship as follows:
Px X Py Y M
(4)
where PX and PY are the price of good X and Y, respectively, and M is the
income or the budget constraint. Suppose that the available money
income is $100, Px = $5, and PY = $10. If the entire $100 is spent on good
74
E5 Managerial Economics
M/PX=20 X
The points inside the budget line are attainable while those outside are
not. The slope of the budget line is given by –PX/PY (= the rise (M/PY
divides by the run M/PX) that represents the rate at which the X can be
exchanged for Y in the market place. In the example above, the slope
equals –1/2.
Changes in income
The consumer’s opportunity set depends on market prices and the
consumer’s income. As these parameters change, so will the consumer’s
opportunities. Let us now examine the effects on the opportunity set of
changes in income by assuming prices remain constant.
Suppose the consumer’s initial income in Figure 4-5 is M0. What happens
if M0 increases to M1 while prices remain unchanged? Recall that the
slope of the budget line is given by –PX/PY. Under the assumption that
prices remain unchanged, the increase in income will not affect the slope
of the budget line. However, the vertical and horizontal intercepts of the
budget line both increase as the consumer’s income increases, because
more of each good can be purchased at the higher income. Thus, when
income increases from M0 to M1, the budget line shifts to the right in a
parallel fashion. This reflects an increase in the consumer’s opportunity
set, because more goods are affordable after the increase in income than
before. Similarly, if income decreases to M2 from M0, the budget line
shifts toward the origin and the slope of the budget line remains
unchanged.
75
Module 4
Figure 4-5
Changes in price
Now suppose the consumer’s income remains fixed at M, but the price of
good X decreases to P1 from P0. Furthermore, suppose the price of good
Y remains unchanged. Since the slope of the budget line is given by –
PX/PY, the reduction in the price of good X changes the slope, making it
flatter than before. Since the maximum amount of good Y that can be
purchased is M/PY, a reduction in the price of good X does not change the
Y intercept of the budget line. But the maximum amount of good X that
can be purchased at the lower price (the X intercept of the budget line) is
M/PX1, which is greater than M0/PX0. Thus, the effect of a reduction in the
price of good X is to rotate the budget line anticlockwise, as in Figure 4-
6.
Figure 4-6
M/PX0 M1/PX1 X
76
E5 Managerial Economics
Consumer equilibrium
The principal assumption upon which the theory of consumer behaviour
rests is that consumers attempt to allocate their limited money incomes to
purchase available goods and services so as to maximise their satisfaction
(utility). In other words, consumers’ indifference map provides a
diagrammatic representation of a consumer’s taste and intensity of desire
for different product combinations while the consumer’s purchasing
power (and thus ability to satisfy material wants) is reflected by the line
of attainable combinations. Putting the two together shows all the desired
product combinations on the indifference curves that are also attainable.
XE X
Note, at the point of tangency between the indifference curve and the
budget line, the slope of the indifference curve equals the slope of the
budget line, that is,
Px
MRS
Py
(5)
77
Module 4
Demonstration problem
Suppose an individual uses exactly two pats of butter on each piece of
toast. If toast costs $0.20/slice and butter costs $0.10/pat, find this
individual’s best affordable bundle if she has $12 per month to spend on
toast and butter.
Answer:
78
E5 Managerial Economics
Precisely where the new equilibrium point lies along the new budget line
after a price change depends on whether the two goods are substitutes or
complements. Recall from Module 3 that goods X and Y would be called
substitutes if an increase (decrease) in the price of X leads to an increase
(decrease) in the consumption of Y. On the other hand, they would be
called complements if an increase (decrease) in the price of good X leads
to a decrease (increase) in the consumption of good Y.
Figure 4-8 shows the case of two substitutes. A reduction in the price of
X would lead the consumer to move from point A in to a point such as B,
where less of Y is consumed than at point A.
Figure 4-8
Income changes
Indifference curve analysis also allows us to see how changes in income
affect the mix of goods purchased by consumers. When the consumer’s
income changes, the consumer will respond by changing his or her
79
Module 4
For some products the income effect is negative, meaning that if income
increases, the quantity demanded of those products actually declines. This
may happen to a product that is an inferior substitute for some superior
product. As people become richer, they tend to switch away from inferior
goods to superior substitutes. Conversely, as incomes fall (in a recession,
for example), people tend to switch back to the inferior substitutes as they
find themselves unable to afford the superior substitutes.
In Figure 4-10 we show the income effect for an inferior good. The
product on the horizontal axis, travel by train, is an inferior good, and
travel by air is a superior substitute for this particular consumer. Note that
when the consumer’s income increases and the budget line moves
outward, the quantity demanded of travel by train actually decreases
while travel by air increases. This consumer, now able to afford more air
travel, substitutes away from the inferior good and in favour of the
80
E5 Managerial Economics
For any particular product at any particular point in time, some consumers
may regard that product as a superior good while others may regard it as
an inferior good. This difference in attitude toward a particular product
stems from a difference in income levels and/or a different pattern of
tastes and preferences.
The second part of the price effect is the substitution effect. When the
price of a product falls, consumers will tend to substitute in favour of that
product because it is now cheaper relative to other substitute products that
serve the same need. Thus, when the price of a product falls, all else
being kept constant, the consumer would normally buy more of that
product, first because his or her real income has increased, and second
81
Module 4
because he or she substitutes toward that product and away from other
substitutes that are now relatively more expensive.
Demonstration problem
Suppose your product is a cyclical product, that is, sales vary directly
with the economy. How can this information be useful to you when
considering alternative products to include in your store?
Answer:
82
E5 Managerial Economics
Demonstration problem
Does running a gourmet food store involve a higher level of risk of going
out of business than running a supermarket, or vice versa, when the
economy heads for a recession?
Answer:
Corner solutions
In all the examples considered so far, the optimal consumer basket has
been interior, meaning that the consumer consumes positive amounts of
both goods. In reality, though, a given consumer will not purchase
positive amounts of all available goods. For example, not all consumers
own a car or a house. Some consumers may not spend money on tobacco
or alcohol. If the consumer cannot find any interior basket at which the
budget line will be tangent to an indifference curve, then he or she may
find an optimal basket at a corner point, that is, at a basket along an axis,
where one of the goods is not purchased at all. If an optimum occurs at a
corner point, the budget line may not be tangent to an indifference curve
at the optimal basket.
Let’s consider again our consumer who chooses between just two goods,
food and clothing. If the consumer’s indifference map is as illustrated in
Figure 4-12, no indifference curve is tangent to his or her budget line. At
any interior basket on the budget line, such as basket B, the slope of the
indifference curve is steeper (more negative) than the slope of the budget
line. This means that MRS > PX/PY. In this case, our consumer is willing
to exchange more Y for an additional unit of X than he or she has to,
based on the market. This is true not only at basket B, but at all baskets on
the budget line. The consumer would continue to substitute X for Y,
moving along the budget line until he or she reaches the corner point
basket C. At basket C the slope of the indifference curve I2 is still steeper
than the slope of the budget line; he or she would like to substitute more
X for Y if that were possible. But no further substitution is possible
because no more X can be purchased beyond basket C. Therefore the
optimal choice for this consumer is basket C, because that basket gives
the consumer the highest utility possible on the budget line.
83
Module 4
Figure 4-12
CX
84
E5 Managerial Economics
85
Module 4
If such strong conclusions can be drawn from such a simple model, then
why do governments spend billions of dollars to provide subsidised
housing, instead of just making cash grants? One political reason is that
earmarking the subsidy for housing guarantees that resources used will
put roofs over people’s heads rather than being spent in frivolous or illicit
ways. An economic reason the likelihood of the consumer finding
housing is less under cash subsidy than voucher. This is the case because
the landlord may perceive the risk of non-payment to be greater when the
entire rental payment is made by the tenants themselves than when a
portion of it is guaranteed by the government.
86
E5 Managerial Economics
Individual demand
Recall from Module 3 that a market demand curve is a relationship that
tells how much of a good the market as a whole wants to purchase at
various prices. Suppose we want to generate a demand schedule for a
good, X, not for the market as a whole but for only a single consumer.
Holding income, preferences, and the prices of all other goods constant,
how will a change in the price of shelter affect the amount X the
consumer buys? To answer this question, we begin with this consumer’s
indifference map, with X on the horizontal axis and the composite good Y
on the vertical axis, Figure 4-16(a). The consumer initially is in
equilibrium at point A, where income is fixed at M, and prices are PXA
and PYA. But when the price of good X falls to the lower level, indicated
by PXB (PXB < PXA ), the consumer reaches a new equilibrium at point B.
The important thing to notice is that the only change that caused the
consumer to move from A to B was a change in the price of good X;
income and the price of good Y are held constant in the diagram. When
the price of good X is PXA the consumer consumes XA units of good X;
when the price falls to PXB, the consumption of X increases to XB.
The panel (b) in Figure 4-16 shows this relationship between the price of
good X and the quantity consumed of good X. This consumer’s demand
curve for good X indicates that, holding other things constant, when the
price of good X is PXA the consumer will purchase XA units of X; when
the price of good X is PXB, the consumer will purchase XB units of X.
87
Module 4
Figure 4-16
The line connecting point A to point B in panel (b) represents the demand
curve for our consumer. An individual consumer’s demand curve is like
the market demand curve in that it tells the quantities the consumer will
buy at various prices.
Market demand
The market demand curve is the horizontal summation of individual
demand curves and indicates the total quantity all consumers in the
market would purchase at each possible price. This concept is illustrated
graphically in Figures 4-17(a) and 4-17(b). The curves D1 and D2
represent the individual demand curves of two hypothetical consumers:
Individual 1 and Individual 2. When the price is $500, Individual 1 and
Individual 2 buy 0 units. Thus, at the market level, 0 units are sold when
the price is $500, and this is one point on the market demand curve
(labeled DM in Figure 4-17(b)). When the price is $400, Individual 1 buys
50 units (point A) and Individual 2 buys 0 units (point B). Thus, at the
market level 50 units are sold when the price is $400, and this is another
point (point A + B) on the market demand curve. When the price of good
is $200, Individual 1 buys 150 units and Individual 2 buys 80 units; thus,
at the market level, 230 units are sold when the price is $200.
88
E5 Managerial Economics
Figure 4-17
89
Module 4
Attribute Rating
B 2,800 7 6 1.16
C 3,200 5 9 0.55
What determines how far along each ray the buyer could go and how
much of each product the buyer can purchase depends on the buyer’s
budget (budget constraint). In the case of an indivisible purchase, such as
purchase of a car or a notebook computer – the products that are, on the
one hand, available only in discrete units and, on the other hand, the price
of which are large in relation to the consumer’s income – the consumer is
expected to stop at purchasing just one unit of the product: one car and
one notebook computer. This, of course, implicitly assumes the buyer’s
budget is large enough to permit the purchase of all three brands despite
the price differences.
Following this logic, the efficiency frontier, which is the outer boundary
of the attainable combinations of attributes, is obtained. It is called
‘efficient’ because only combinations on this frontier allow the consumer
to maximise utility. This frontier consists of the points joining the limit
points – points A, B, and C – on each product ray. Each point is found by
first dividing the buyer’s income by the price of the respective product in
order to determine the number of the units of the product, and then
multiplying the outcome by the attribute content of each unit. The point
depicted along each ray shows the maximum intake of the two attributes
that can be obtained by consuming each notebook.
90
E5 Managerial Economics
91
Module 4
Module summary
The utility approach to consumer behaviour is grounded upon
psychological principles, and is best explained in terms of utility.
Conceptually, utility can be measured in cardinal units, as in Module 2, or
ordinal approach, as discussed in this module, in which case the
Summary consumer is able to rank products in order of preference. Consumer
equilibrium is reached when the marginal utility per dollar is the same for
all products, or when the slope of the indifference curve and the slope of
the budget line are the same. The consumer’s demand curve for a
particular product is directly related to the marginal utility of that product.
The downward sloping demand curve is due to the law of diminishing
marginal utility. In general, the individual’s demand curve consists of two
effects, the substitution effect and the income effect. The income effect
may be positive or negative depending on the taste and preferences of the
consumer. Changes in the consumer’s income will change the quantity
demanded at a given price level. The quantity demanded of normal goods
will move in the same direction as income, whereas the quantity
demanded of inferior goods will move in the opposite direction to
income.
92
E5 Managerial Economics
Assignment
1. A consumer has an income of $50. He can choose any combination of
product X and product Y for consumption. If price of X (Px) is $5
and price of Y (Py) is $2.50, draw the budget line of the consumer.
Find the market rate of substitution. What is the maximum quantity of
Y that he can purchase? If the income goes up to $75, then how will
the budget line change? Find the maximum quantity of Y that he can
Assignment purchase with the new budget.
2. A consumer can choose any combination of apples and oranges. A,
B, and C are three different points on his indifference curve. If he
moves from A to B he gives up two oranges for one apple. If he
moves from B to C then he gives up one orange for one apple. Do the
consumer’s preferences comply with the diminishing marginal rate of
substitution? Explain.
93
Module 4
Assessment
1. Consider the problem in question 2. If the price of apples is $0.50 per
unit and the price of oranges is $0.25 per unit, then with an income of
$10 at which point (among points A, B, and C) will he maximise his
welfare? Explain. If welfare is not maximised at any of these points,
Assessment then explain how he should change his consumption.
2. Prices of food and clothing are currently $10 per unit and $25 per unit
respectively. With an income of $500, find the market rate of
substitution. Suppose that the consumer’s preference shows that
marginal rate of substitution at some point is two units of food for
one unit of clothing. Given that the consumer’s indifference curve
shows a diminishing marginal rate of substitution, how should the
consumer adjust his consumption to maximise utility given the
budget constraint?
94
E5 Managerial Economics
Assessment answers
1. Market rate of substitution = 0.5/0.25 = 2, MRS at A = 2
At A the consumer maximises welfare.
95
Module 4
References
Baumol, W. J. (1967). Business Behavior, Value and Growth, Rev. Ed.
New York: Harcourt Brace Johanovich.
Besanko, D., & Braeutigam, R. (2002). Microeconomics: An Integrated
References Approach. New York: Wiley & Sons.
Douglas, J. E. (1992). Managerial Economics: Analysis and Strategy.
Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Lancaster, K. (1971). Consumer Demand: A New Approach. New York:
Columbia University.
Pindyck, R. S., & Rubinfeld, D. (2001). Microeconomics, 5th Edition.
Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
96