Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Introduction
The capital asset pricing model that assists the security have different expected return because they have different beta however they exists an alternative model of asset pricing that was developed by Stephen Ross it is known as arbitrage pricing model. Arbitrage pricing theory (APT) is an equilibrium model of security prices, as is the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). It makes different assumptions than the CAPM does. APT assumes that security returns are generated by a factor model but does not identify the factors. An arbitrage portfolio includes long and short positions in securities. it must have a net market value of zero, no sensitivity to any factor, and a positive excepted return. Investors will invest in arbitrage portfolios, provided they exist, driving up the prices of the securities held in long positions until all arbitrage possibilities have been eliminated. When all arbitrage possibilities have been eliminated, the equilibrium expected returns on a security will be a linear function of its sensitivities to the factors a factor-risk premiums is the equilibrium to the factors and no sensitivity to any other factor APT does not specify the number or identify of the factors that affect excepted returns or the magnitudes or signs of the risk premiums. Most research into factors has focused on indicators of aggregate economic activity, inflation and interest rates
1.
It is based on Unrealistic Assumptions Difficult to find risk free assets Equality of lending and borrowing rates
2. 3.
It is difficult to test the validity of CAPM BETAS do not remain stable over time.
4. Under APT investors borrows and lend at risk free rate. 5. There is no market friction such as transaction cost or restriction on short selling. 6. Investors agree on the number and identify of the factors that are important symbolically in pricing asset.
Principle
Arbitrage is the process of earning profit by taking advantage of differential pricing for the some physical asset or security. As widely applied investment tactic, arbitrage typically entails the sale of security at a relatively high price and the simultaneous purchase of the same security at a relatively low price. Arbitrage is critical element of modern, efficient security markets. Because arbitrage profits are by definition riskless all investors are motivated to tale advantage of then whenever they are discovered. Granted some investors are greater resources and are more inclined to engage in arbitrage than others. It only takes a few of these active investors to exploit arbitrage than others. It only takes few of these active investors to exploit arbitrage situations and by their buying and selling actions, eliminates these profit opportunities. The nature of arbitrage is clear when discussing different prices for an individual security. However almost arbitrage opportunity involve similar securities or portfolios. The similarity can be defined in many ways for example in the exposure to pervasive factor that affect security prices.
of the macroeconomic factors as the mispriced asset. The arbitrageur creates the portfolio by identifying x correctly priced assets (one per factor plus one) and then weighting the assets such that portfolio beta per factor is the same as for the mispriced asset. When the investor is long the asset and short the portfolio (or vice versa) he has created a position which has a positive expected return (the difference between asset return and portfolio return) and which has a net-zero exposure to any macroeconomic factor and is therefore risk free (other than for firm specific risk). The arbitrageur is thus in a position to make a risk-free profit: Where today's price is too low: The implication is that at the end of the period the portfolio would have appreciated at the rate implied by the APT, whereas the mispriced asset would have appreciated at more than this rate. The arbitrageur could therefore: Today: 1 short sells the portfolio 2 buy the mispriced asset with the proceeds. At the end of the period: 1 sells the mispriced asset 2 use the proceeds to buy back the portfolio 3 pocket the difference.
Factor model
Single-factor models
Before using the notion of absence of arbitrage to provide pricing relations, We need a basis for the generation of stock returns. Within the context of The APT, this basis is given by the assumption that the population of stockreturns are generated by a factor model. The simplest factor model, given below, is a one-factor model: ri = i + i F + i E(i) = 0. (3.1) In equation 3.1, the returns on stock i are related to two main components: 1. The first of these is a component that involves the factor F. This factor is posited to affect all stock returns, although with differing sensitivities. The sensitivity of stock is return to F is i. Stocks that have small values for this parameter will react only slightly as F changes, whereas when i is large, variations in F cause very large movements in the return on stocki. As a concrete example, think of F as the return on a market index (e.g.the S&P-500 or the FTSE-100), the variations in which cause variations in individual stock returns. Hence, this term causes movements in individual stock returns that are related. If two stocks have positive sensitivities to the factor, both will tend to move in the same direction. 2. The second term in the factor model is a random shock to returns, which is assumed to be uncorrelated across different stocks. We have denoted this term i and call it the idiosyncratic return component for stock i. An important property of the idiosyncratic component is that it is also assumed to be uncorrelated with F, the common factor in
stock returns. In statistical terms we can write the conditions on the idiosyncratic component as follows: Cov(i, j) = 0 i j Cov(i, F) = 0 i An example of such an idiosyncratic stock return might be the unexpected departure of a firms CEO or an unexpected legal action brought against the company in question. The partition of returns implied by equation 3.1 implies that all common variation in stock returns is generated by movements in F (i.e. the correlation between the returns on stocks i and j derives solely from F). Asthe idiosyncratic components are ncorrelated across assets they do not bring about covariation in stock price movements.
---------------------------------------
Multi-factor models
A generalisation of the structure presented in equation 3.1 posits k factors or sources of common variation in stock returns. ri = i + 1iF1 + 2iF2 + .... + kiFk + i E(i) = 0. (3.2) Again the idiosyncratic component is assumed uncorrelated across stocks and with all of the factors. Further, well assume that each of the factors has a mean of zero. These factors can be thought of as representing news on economic conditions, financial conditions or political events. Note that this assumption implies that the expected return on asset i is just given by the constant in equation 3.2 (i.e. E(ri) = i). Each stock has a complement of factor sensitivities or factor betas, which determine how sensitive the return on the stock in question is to variations in each of the factors.
9
A pertinent question to ask at this point is how do we determine the return on a portfolio of assets given the k-factor structure assumed? The answer is surprisingly simple: the factor sensitivities for a portfolio of assets are calculable as the portfolio weighted averages of the individual factor sensitivities. The following example will demonstrate the point. Example The returns on stocks X, Y, and Z are determined by the following two-factor model: rX = 0.05 + F1 0.5F2 + X rY = 0.03 + 0.75 F1 + 0.5F2 + Y rz = 0.04 + 0.25 F1 0.3F2 + z Given the factor sensitivities in the prior three equations, we wish to derive the factor structure followed by an equally weighted portfolio of the three assets (i.e. a portfolio with one-third of the weights on each of the assets). Following the result mentioned above, all we need to do is form a weighted average of the stock sensitivities on the individual assets. Subscripting the coefficients for the equally weighted portfolio with a p we have: p = 1 3 (0.05 + 0.03 + 0.04) = 0.04 1p = 1 3 (1 + 0.75 0.25) = 0.5 2p = 1 3 (0.5 + 0.5 0.3) = 0.1; and hence; the factor representation for the portfolio return can be written as: rp = 0.04 + 0.5F1 0.1F2 + p where the final term is the idiosyncratic component in the portfolio return.
10
Arbitrage portfolio
According to APT, an investor will explore the possibility of forming an arbitrage portfolio in order to increase the expected return of his or her current portfolio without increasing its risk. Just what is an arbitrage portfolio? There are three characteristic of an arbitrage portfolio ;1. It does not require any additional funds from the investor. If Xi denotes change in
the investors holding of security I, this requirement of a three security arbitrage portfolio written as X1+ X2+X3 =0
2. It has no sensitivity to any factor because the sensitive of a portfolio factor is just
a weighted average of the sensitivities of the securities in it ie to that factor, this requirement of a three security arbitrage portfolio is one factor can be written as B1X1 +b2X2+ b3X3 =0
3. It has a positive expected return. Mathematically this third and last thing for a
11
Implementation of APT
The implementation of APT involves three steps: 1. Identify the factors 2. Estimate factor loadings of assets 3. Estimate factor premia. 1. Factors. Since the theory itself does not specify the factors, we have to construct the factors empirically: (a) Using macroeconomic variables: changes in GDP growth changes in T-bill yield (proxy for expected inflation) changes in yield spread between T-bonds and T-bills changes in default premium on corporate bonds changes in oil prices (proxy for price level)
12
(b) Using statistical analysis factor analysis: estimate covariance of asset returns extract factors from the covariance matrix (c) Data mining: Explore different portfolios to find those whose returns can be used as factors. 15.407 Lecture Notes Fall 2003 c_Jiang Wang Chapter 12 Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) 12-15 2. Factor Loadings. Given the factors, we can regress past asset returns on the factors to estimate factor loadings (bik): rit = ri +bi1 f1t + +biK fKt +uit. 3. Factor Premia. Given the factor loading of individual assets, we can construct factor portfolios.
Michael berry, Edwin Burmeister and Marjorie McElroy identify five factor .three correspond closely to the last three identified by Chen, Roll, and Ross and the other two
13
are the growth rate in aggregate sales in the economy and the rate of return on the S &P 500 Finally, .consider the five factors used by Salomon Brothers (now Salomon Barney) in their fundamental factor model. Only one factor, inflation, is the same as the factors identified by the others. The remaining factors are as follows: 1. Growth rate in gross national product. 2. Rate of interest 3. Rate of change in oil prices 4. Rate of growth in defense spending It is interesting to note that the three sets of factors have common characteristics, first contain some indication of aggregate economic activity (industrial production. aggregator sales and GDP) second, they include inflation. Third, they contain some type of interest rate factor (either spreads or a rate itself) because stock prices are equal to the discounted value of future dividends, the factors make intuitive sense. Further dividends are related to aggregate economic activity and the discount rate used to determine present value is related to inflation and interest rates
14
4.the relationship should be theoretically justifiable on economic grounds Chen, Roll and Ross (1986) identified the following macro-economic factors as significant in explaining security returns: surprises in inflation; surprises in GNP as indicted by an industrial production index; surprises in investor confidence due to changes in default premium in corporate bonds surprise shifts in the yield curve. As a practical matter, indices or spot or futures market prices may be used in place of macroeconomic factors, which are reported at low frequency (e.g. monthly) and often with significant estimation errors. Market indices are sometimes derived by means of factor analysis. More direct "indices" that might be used are: short term interest rates; the difference in long-term and short-term interest rates;a diversified stock index such as the S&P 500 or NYSE Composite Index;oil pricesgold or other precious metal prices Currency exchange rates.
market line represents a single-factor model of the asset price, where beta is exposed to changes in value of the market.
2. The APT can be seen as a "supply-side" model, since its beta coefficients reflect
the sensitivity of the underlying asset to economic factors On the other side, the capital asset pricing model is considered a "demand side" model. Its results, although similar to those of the APT, arise from a maximization problem of each investor's utility function, and from the resulting market equilibrium (investors are considered to be the "consumers" of the assets).
3. Under APT investors do not look at expected returns and standard deviation
while in the case of CAPM investors look at the expected return and accompanying risk measured by standard deviation.
4. Under APT risk return analysis is not the basis while in the case of CAPM risk
5. APT is based on the return generated by factor models, while in the case of
Empirical evidence
The APT has been empirically tested two different approaches. in the first approach, the technique of factor analysis (a statistical technique) is applied to stock returns to discover the basic factors. These are then examined to see whether they correspond to some economic or behavioral variables. Empirical studies done so far suggest that there is hardly any consistency in terms of:
1. The number of basic factors.
2. The interpretation that may be put on these factors (typically the factors identified
3.
In the second approach, factors are specified a priori, rather than extracted by analyzing stock returns. The classical work of Roll and Ross, typifies this approach. They employ four factors:
1.
Industrial production
2. Inflation rate.
3. Term structure of interest rates 4. Default risk premiums.
Sensitivity to unanticipated changes in these factors provides explanations for differences in excepted returns among stocks in their study.
17
Conclusion
The APT gives us a straightforward, alternative view of the world from the CAPM. The CAPM implies that the only factor that is important in generating expected returns is the market return and, further, that expected stock returns are linear in the return on the market. The APT allows there to be k sources of systematic risk in the economy. Some may reflect macroeconomic factors, like inflation, and interest rate risk, whereas others may reflect characteristics specific to a firms industry or sector. Empirical research has indicated that some of the well-known empirical problems with the CAPM are driven by the fact that the APT is really the proper model of expected return generation.
18
Bibliography Security analysis and portfolio management Punithavathty pandian Fundamentals of investments. William F.Sharpe Gorden J. Alexzander Jeffery V. Bailey.
19
www. Google.com
20