Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Product Differentiation
Product differentiation plays an even more crucial role in monopolistically competitive industries. Why?
many producers. Hence, product differentiation is the only way monopolistically competitive firms can acquire some market power.
Then, how do firms in the same industrysuch as fast-food vendors, or chocolate companies differentiate their products? Is the difference mainly in the minds of consumers or in the products themselves?
2
Product Differentiation
There are three important forms of product differentiation: Differentiation by style or type Differentiation by location Dry cleaner near home vs. Cheaper dry-cleaner far away Differentiation by quality Ordinary vs. high quality products
Product Differentiation
Whatever form it takes, however, there are two important features of industries with differentiated products:
Competition
the same market, so entry by more producers reduces the quantity each existing producer sells at any given price.
Value
Economics in Action:
Case: Any Color, So Long as Its Black Fords strategy was to offer just one style of car, which maximized his economies of scale but made no concessions to differences in taste Model T
Alfred P. Sloan of GM challenged this strategy by offering a range of car types, differentiated by quality and price Chevrolet, Cadillac, Buick
By the 1930s the verdict was clear: Customers preferred a range of styles!
5
Because each firm is offering a distinct product, it is in a way like a monopolist: it faces a downward-sloping demand curve and has some market powerthe ability within limits to determine the price of its product. However, unlike a pure monopolist, a monopolistically competitive firm does face competition: the amount of its product it can sell depends on the prices and products offered by other firms in the industry.
6
Understanding Monopolistic Competition: The Monopolistically Competitive Firm in the Short Run
The following figure shows two possible situations that a typical firm in a monopolistically competitive industry might face in the short run.
In each case the firm looks like any monopolist: it faces a downward-sloping demand curve, which implies a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve. We assume that every firm has an upward-sloping marginal cost curve but that it also faces some fixed costs, so that its average total cost curve is U-shaped.
7
The firm in panel (a) can be profitable for some output levels: the levels at which its ATC, lies below its demand curve, DP. The profit-maximizing output level is QP, the output at which marginal revenue, MRP, is equal to marginal cost. The firm charges price PP and earns a profit, represented by the area of the shaded rectangle.
The firm above can never be profitable because the ATC lies above its demand curve, DU. The best that it can do if it produces at all is to produce output QU and charge PU. This generates a loss, indicated by the area of the shaded rectangle. Any other output level 8 results in a greater loss.
Entry and Exit into the Industry Shift the Demand Curve of Each Firm
Entry will occur in the long run when existing firms are profitable. In panel (a), entry causes each firms demand curve and marginal revenue curve to shift to the left. The firm receives a lower price for every unit it sells, and its profit falls. Entry will cease when remaining firms make zero profit.
Exit will occur in the long run when existing firms are unprofitable. In panel (b), exit out of the industry shifts each remaining firms demand curve and marginal revenue curve to the right. The firm receives a higher price for every unit it sells, and profit 10 rises. Exit will cease when the remaining firms make zero profit.
If existing firms are profitable, entry will occur and shift each firms demand curve leftward. If existing firms are unprofitable, each firms demand curve shifts rightward as some firms exit the industry. In long-run zero profit equilibrium, the demand curve of each firm is tangent to its average total cost curve at its profitmaximizing output level: at the profit-maximizing output level, 11 QMC, price, PMC, equals average total cost, ATCMC.
12
Panel (a) shows the situation of the typical firm in long-run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive industry. The firm operates at the minimum-cost output QC , sells at the competitive market price PC , and makes zero profit. It is indifferent to selling another unit of output because PC is equal to its marginal cost, MCC . Panel (b) shows the situation of the typical firm in long-run equilibrium in a monopolistically competitive industry. At QMC it makes zero profit because its price, PMC, just equals average total cost. At QMC the firm would like to sell another unit at price PMC, since PMC exceeds marginal cost, MCMC. But it is unwilling to lower price to make more sales. It therefore operates to the left of the minimum-cost output and has excess 13 capacity.
14
15
Advertising is not a waste of resources when it gives consumers useful information about products. Either consumers are irrational, or expensive advertising communicates that the firm's products are of high quality.
16
Brand Names
Some firms create brand names.
A brand name is a name owned by a particular firm that distinguishes its products from those of other firms. As with advertising, the social value of brand names can be ambiguous.
The names convey real information when they assure consumers of the quality of a product.
17