Econometrics Lecture 1: Introduction
Econometrics Lecture 1: Introduction
Econometrics Lecture 1: Introduction
Lecture 1: Introduction
WHAT IS ECONOMETRICS?
• the subject deserves to be studied in its own right for the following
reasons:
• Economic theory makes statements or hypotheses that are mostly
qualitative in nature (the law of demand), the law does not provide
any numerical measure of the relationship. This is the job of the
econometrician.
• The main concern of mathematical economics is to express economic
theory in mathematical form without regard to measurability or
empirical verification of the theory. Econometrics is mainly
interested in the empirical verification of economic theory.
• Economic statistics is mainly concerned with collecting, processing,
and presenting economic data in the form of charts and tables. It
does not go any further. The one who does that is the
econometrician.
METHODOLOGY OF ECONOMETRICS
• The estimated regression line is shown in Figure I.3. The regression line fits
the data quite well. The slope coefficient (i.e., the MPC) was about 0.70, an
increase in real income of 1 dollar led, on average, to an increase of about 70
cents in real consumption.
6. Hypothesis Testing
• That is to find out whether the estimates obtained in, Eq. (I.3.3) are in
accord with the expectations of the theory that is being tested. Keynes
expected the MPC to be positive but less than 1. In our example we found the
MPC to be about 0.70. But before we accept this finding as confirmation of
Keynesian consumption theory, we must enquire whether this estimate is
sufficiently below unity. In other words, is 0.70 statistically less than 1? If it
is, it may support Keynes’ theory.
• Such confirmation or refutation of economic theories on the basis of sample
evidence is based on a branch of statistical theory known as statistical
inference (hypothesis testing).
7. Forecasting or Prediction
• To illustrate, suppose we want to predict the mean consumption
expenditure for 1997. The GDP value for 1997 was 7269.8 billion dollars
consumption would be:
• which gives X = 7197, approximately. That is, an income level of about 7197
(billion) dollars, given an MPC of about 0.70, will produce an expenditure
of about 4900 billion dollars. As these calculations suggest, an estimated
model may be used for control, or policy, purposes. By appropriate fiscal
and monetary policy mix, the government can manipulate the control
variable X to produce the desired level of the target variable Y.
• Figure I.4 summarizes the anatomy of classical econometric modeling.
• Choosing among Competing Models
• When a governmental agency (e.g., the U.S. Department of Commerce)
collects economic data, such as that shown in Table I.1, it does not
necessarily have any economic theory in mind. How then does one know that
the data really support the Keynesian theory of consumption? Is it because
the Keynesian consumption function (i.e., the regression line) shown in
Figure I.3 is extremely close to the actual data points? Is it possible that
another consumption model (theory) might equally fit the data as well? For
example, Milton Friedman has developed a model of consumption, called
the permanent income hypothesis. Robert Hall has also developed a model of
consumption, called the life-cycle permanent income hypothesis. Could one
or both of these models also fit the data in Table I.1?
• In short, the question facing a researcher in practice is how to choose
among competing hypotheses or models of a given phenomenon, such as the
consumption–income relationship.
• The eight-step classical econometric methodology discussed above is neutral
in the sense that it can be used to test any of these rival hypotheses. Is it
possible to develop a methodology that is comprehensive enough to include
competing hypotheses? This is an involved and controversial topic.