Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1/ 23
Fertility 生育
Political Economy of Welfare and Gender Inequal-
ity (PEWGI), 2024-2 Graduate Institute of National Development, NTU Instructor: Dr. Ijin Hong Do employed women have more children? Or the opposite? 就業女性是否有更多孩子?或者相反? Index • Fertility in a PE perspective • The reversal of the relationship between female LM participa- tion and fertility • Women and the LM • The impact of family policies 家庭政策 on fertility in indus- trialised countries • A review of empirical evidence • Thinking exercise Fertility • As women have moved into the paid workforce over the 19 century, fertility rates 生育率 have plummeted • Average OECD fertility dropped from 2.4 children per women (1970) to less than 1.7 (2000). • Female labour force participation rate rose from 45% to 65%+ • A ‘giant X’ figure • A fact of the modern world, reflect- ing women’s opportunity costs 機會成本 , the decline of the gender division of labour 性別分工 with stronger bar- gaining power 議價能力 of women? The reversal of the relationship between female labor force participation and fertility Policy effects? • Childcare spending 托兒服務支出 has less bearing on fertility levels than ex- pected (r=.13). • This depends on labour market struc- tures: In countries with highly flexible LMs, affordable day care services are avail- able in the market, and women can rela- tively easily find jobs (US, NZ) For LMs with specific investments in human capital, limited effect. • AT, DE, IT have traditionally had generous subsidies for families with children with low fertility rates – women more likely to take time off work for care reasons, also due to the fact they are more costly to their em- ployers Two macro-level variables • Publicly provided day • Because of employers’ statisti- care helps reduce the cal discrimination, women shift problem because it short- their career investment to- wards (more general skills) ens career interruptions occupations with high job flex- and gives women more ibility flexibility in balancing • when jobs are in short supply, work and career the desire of women to have ac- tive careers forces them to have fewer children • The state needs to subsidize jobs that are highly flexible in terms of hours and careers inter- ruptions Women and the LM • 1. Demand for female labour • Firms get lower returns on human capital investment in service sector jobs, which are less about labor productivity. • Difference between general skills vs. specific skills • In Liberal Market Economies (LME) 自由市場經濟 , deindustrialization happened relatively quickly, and LMs are relatively unprotected. Firms delocalize to relocate manufacturing operations overseas in pursuit of cheaper labor. Deregulated LMs allow wages and prices to drop quickly. • In Coordinated Market Economies (CME) 協調的市場經濟 , long-term, spe- cific investments in human capital, and neocorporatist wage-setting systems allow manufacturing to retain a larger share of the overall pri- vate sector economy, and personal and social service expansion has been slower (Iversen, 2005) • LMEs cluster 聚類 at one end (smaller cir- cle), exhibiting low price levels and a high share of RWHR employment. • The opposite patters are observed for CMEs (larger circle) • 2. Divorce risk • Compared to a 14.6% divorce rate in OECD countries in 1970, nearly one in two marriages ended in divorce in 2005. • Unable to rely on marriage as an insurance against poverty, more women in high-divorce societies will “self-insure” by earning an in- come on their own • Divorce and female labor force participation: 0.9 correlation! • As the outside options of women improve, the bargaining space in- side of the marriage shrinks, so the exit option from unhappy mar- riages becomes viable • 3. Demonstration effects • Why women try so hard to enter the workforce in countries where the demand for female labor is low and where divorce is relatively hard and rare? • In IRE, IT, JP, POR, ESP, KR women seem to be responding to hostile LMs not by giving up on career prospects and settling for a traditional motherhood role, but by trying even harder at the expense of child- birth lower fertility • Influenced by the opportunities they observe women having in other countries? • Fertility among developed nations might be positively related to ease of employment and career advancement for women. Findings - Occupation or sector of employment makes little difference for men, whereas for women if is quite important Among 1,000 women in the public sector 公共部門 , an estimated 70 more children than among 1,000 women in the private sector is expected (ceteris paribus)
- For men, a negative effect of public
sector employment is expected on their number of children (though it is not significant)
(Using fertility among senior managers as
the reference group, the other black bars show estimated fertility rates among women in different occupations relative to men in those occupations) LMs and fertility in US, JP, DE, SWE
• Lower fertility rates for specific-skills economies?
• Results of the multi- level analysis 多層次分析 The impact of family policies 家庭政策 on fertility in industrialised countries • Public policies 公共政策 have an undeniable effect on families • They regulate conditions of employment • They define eligibility to welfare benefits • They provide education and health services • They define the rights and responsibilities of parents • Public policies shape family life in defining rights, responsibilities, opportunities, constraints • They encourage some types of family structures over others, and provide incentives or disincentives to cohabit, marry, divorce, to have children within or outside the wedlock • The social policy fertility question is complex. • These links depend on the type of policies, the level of benefits, the conditions of eligibility, the income and opportunity sets of individuals, and the norms, stigma and sanctions associated with the receipt of benefits. Theoretical framework • Variants of rational choice theory 理性選擇理論 , including the new home economics theory, were used to study the policy-fertility relationship. • According to the neoclassic economic theory of fertility, the decision to have a child is subject to an economically rational decision (a utility maximization process), and is a function of the economic cost and benefits of children, subject to an income constraint and to individuals’ preferences for children (as opposed to other goods). • A reduction in the cost of children (as a result of public subsidy) or an in- crease of income (as a result of transfer payments) is expected to increase the demand for children (Becker 1981) • Family policies s.a. child and family cash allowances, tax relief for children, subsidies to childcare, and maternity and parental leave bene- fits are expected to have a positive impact on fertility by reducing the direct or indirect (opportunity) cost of children or by increasing individu- als’ income. 5 assumptions • Although this economic model is very influential in the literature, it is also reliant on 5 strong assumptions: 1. An increase in income increase in demand for children (however, the increase might be in increased quality of children, for example, their education) 2. Decisions are made based on full information (however, imperfect information is more likely, for example regarding the perceived cost of children) 3. Having a child, marrying, divorcing treated like an economically rational decision (however, decisions are often ‘appropriate’, ‘adequate’, rather than ‘rational’) 4. Preferences for children are taken for granted (however, policies might also in- fluence the formation of preferences, as well as factors such as peers, neigh- bors, habits, traditions, and publicity) (Becker 1996) 5. Preferences regarding children are treated as homogenous among household members (instead, preferences may differ among household members) (Rasul 2022). Empirical evidence • Family cash benefits 家庭現金福利 fertility (O) • Ex. Gauthier and Hatzius (1997) find that a 25% increase in family al- lowances results in an increase of the total fertility rate (TFR) of 0.07 children per woman • But, policies might have differential effects per birth order (ex. Second child or third child rather than the first child) • Results are complec and depend on policy design as well (e.g. level of bene- fits, eligibility criteria) • Work-related policies fertility (~) • Effect of parental and maternity leave policies 育嬰假和產假政策 seen in CAN (Hyatt & Milne 1991), not in AT (Hoem et al. 2001) • Childcare cost and availability 托兒費用和可用性 : positive effect in a multicountry analysis (Del Boca et al. 2003); no statistically significant impact in NOR, FIN (Ronsen 2004), DE (Hank & Kreyenfeld 2003), SWE (Andersen et al. 2004) Are family policies effective? • The measurement of policies is a challenge: need to consider eli- gibility criteria, benefit caps, employer-provided benefits… • People’s preferences might follow the channels of (1) reduction of children costs (2) increase in family incomes (3) increase in the preference of children. But, concomitant variations and links between policies, wages, and female labor force participation make the picture more complex • Need to take into account social and economic differences across families • Results of empirical analyses need to take into account the mag- nitude of the impact of policies and the differential impact by birth order • Castles (2003) Take away lesson from this class • -- Glossary • Family policies 家庭政策 • Family cash benefits 家庭現金 • Liberal Market Economies 福利 (LME) 自由市場經濟 • Parental and maternity • Coordinated Market leave policies 育嬰假和產假政策 Economies (CME) 協調的市場經濟 • Childcare cost and avail- • Cluster 聚類 ability 托兒費用和可用性 : • Rational choice theory 理性選 擇理論 Next time: Gender and political preference 性 別和政治偏好 (10/14) What do men and women vote? 男人和女人投票什麼 ? Thinking exercise Political Economy of Welfare and Gender Inequality (PEWGI), 2024-2 Graduate Institute of National Development, NTU Instructor: Dr. Ijin Hong