CONSUMER EXPENDITURE AND COINTEGRATION
Carlos Robalo Marques
Banco de Portugal
Pedro Duarte Neves
Banco de Portugal and Universidade Católica Portuguesa
(July, 1998)
Abstract
In this paper we estimate the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) for the Portuguese
economy. The budget shares and real per capita income are found to be integrated of order one, I(1), but
prices seem to be better classified as I(2). This raises new problems, as it is not possible to test for
homogeneity and symmetry in a straightforward way. As cointegration is not rejected after the
imposition of homogeneity and symmetry restrictions, we conclude that the AIDS is an acceptable
characterisation of the Portuguese data on consumer expenditure.
1-Introduction
Until very recently, most empirical work on demand systems was carried out under
the explicit or implicit assumption that variables were stationary (see for instance Deaton
and Muellbauer (1980), Attfield (1991), Majunder (1992), Alley et al.(1992), Moschini
(1998)). A recent exception is Attfield (1997) which estimates the Almost Ideal Demand
System (AIDS) assuming that all the series involved are integrated of order one, I(1).
This paper estimates the AIDS model for the Portuguese economy. However as prices
are integrated of order two, I(2), we could not resort to the so called Phillips’ triangular
ECM representation (see Phillips, (1991) and Phillips (1994)) to test for homogeneity as
in Attfield (1997). So, we decided to impose homogeneity from the outset and estimate
the model accordingly. In this framework, as relative prices are I(1), one can test for
cointegration and check whether the estimated system is not spurious. A similar approach
is followed for the imposition of symmetry. The main conclusion is that the system with
1
homogeneity exhibits good cointegrating properties and sensible results for the
elasticities. When, additionally, one imposes the symmetry restrictions we find that the
cointegrating relations do not degrade. According to cointegration results one may say
that both homogeneity and symmetry are not rejected by the data and, in this sense, the
AIDS model is a cointegrating demand system.
This paper is organised as follows. In section 2 we present the model and discuss the
time series properties of the data; in section 3 we estimate the model with the
homogeneity restriction and discuss the cointegrating properties of the system; in section
4 we analyse the consequences of imposing symmetry; in section 5 we evaluate the
income and prices elasticities of the system; finally section 6 concludes.
2-The AIDS with non-stationary variables
The AIDS model, first introduced by Deaton and Muellbauer (1980), is now widely used in
the literature. The model is a set of m demand equations which relate the budget shares, wi, to
a set of prices, p1 , p2 , …, pm, and a measure of per capita real income, y, that is
w it = α i +
m
j=1
β ij p jt + γ i y t + u it
i=1, …,m
(1)
where wit is the budget share of commodity group i at time t, defined as the ratio of nominal
expenditure on commodity i, say Xit , to total nominal expenditure on all commodities, say
Xt =
m
i =1
X it ; pjt stands for the natural log of the price of the jth commodity. Real per capita
income, yt , is defined as y t = ln(X t /N t ) − lnPt* where Nt is the population at time t and
lnPt* =
m
i =1
w it p it is the so-called Stone price index (see Deaton and Muellbauer, 1980). In
system (1) two-stage budgeting is assumed so that consumers allocate expenditure among
commodity groups given an exogenously determined total expenditure.
The data analysed were drawn from Pinheiro et al. (1997) and refer to annual data
from 1958 to 1993 for the following groups of commodities: (1) food, alcoholic drink and
tobacco; (2) clothing and footwear; (3) energy products; (4) other non durable goods and (5)
services; so it is implicitly assumed that the demand for services and nondurable goods is
separable from the demand for durables.
2
Table 1 presents the results of the ADF tests for unit roots in the commodity shares,
wit, log of prices, pit, log of real per capita income, yt , and relative prices
Table 1
Unit root tests1
w1
w2
w3
w4
w5
ADF(0)=-0.67
ADF(0)=-1.07
ADF(0)=-0.02
ADF(1)=-2.91*
ADF(0)=0.88
No constant
No constant
No constant
No constant
No constant
Y
p1
p2
p3
p4
ADF(1)=-2.80
ADF(1)=-1.06
ADF(0)=-3.15
ADF(0)=-4.22*
ADF(1)=-1.25
With trend
With trend
With trend
With trend
With trend
p5
p15
p25
p35
p45
ADF(0)=-1.54
ADF(0)=-1.25
ADF(0)=-1.22
ADF(0)=-0.90
ADF(0)=-2.61
With trend
No constant
No constant
No constant
With trend
(pi5t=pit-p5t). According to the tests performed we may conclude that a unit root in wit
(i=1,…,4) and yt cannot be rejected2. Of course, by construction, budget shares are bounded
and so, in the long run, one would expect them to be stationary. However, for the sample data,
the wi display the characteristics of I(1) variables and so we treat them accordingly (see
Graph No.1). As the first differences of prices do not exhibit mean reversion (see Graphs
No.2 and No. 3) we decided to entertain the possibility of prices being I(2). For these
variables we performed the ADF test resorting to the so-called Dickey-Pantula strategy (see
Dickey and Pantula 1987). As can be seen from the table, the null hypotheses of two unit
1
ADF(k) is the Augmented Dickey- Fuller test statistic based on the t-statistics to test the hypothesis
the model
H 0 : γ = 0 in
∆y t = α + βt + γy t −1 + δ1 ∆y t −1 + ... + δ k ∆y t −k + ε t . The test was carried out following a
“general to specific strategy”, in which k was set so that the regression did not exhibit serial correlation in the
residuals. If during the simplification process, it happened that
constant” case, if
α and β were both non-significant, we have the “no
β is non-significant we have the “no trend” case and if α and β were both significant we have the
“with trend” case. The critical values for 36 observations and a 5% test are: -1.95 (no constant), -2.94 (no trend) and
–3.54 (with trend). The figures with an asteristic (*) are significant at least at 5 per cent.
For the price variables, for which the Dickey-Pantula strategy was followed, the estimated model was
∆2 y t = α + βt + γ 1 y t −1 + γ 2 ∆y t −1 + µ1 ∆2 y t −1 ... + µ k ∆2 y t −k + ε t
and the figures in the table refer to the t-statistics of
2
γ 2 (after imposing γ 1
= 0 ).
An exception, according to the ADF test result is w4. However by looking at the corresponding figure (see Graph
No.1) it is easy to recognise that w4 is not stationary.
3
roots cannot be rejected (only p3 seems to be an exception appearing as I(1)). In turn, relative
prices pi5 (i=1,…,4) appear to be I(1) (see also Graphs No. 4 and No.5). As it will be
discussed below this turns out to be a very important result.
3-Testing for homogeneity
Let us consider system (1). Consumer theory imposes homogeneity of degree zero in
prices and nominal income for consumer demand equations. In the AIDS model the
homogeneity restriction on each share equation implies that
m
j=1
m
As
i =1
β ij = 0
i = 1,2,..., m
(2)
w it = 1 only m-1 of the shares can be independently explained/estimated. For
this reason the equation for the commodity group “(5)-services” is omitted in the estimation.
Testing for homogeneity would be straightforward if the variables were stationary or
integrated of order one. In the first case one would resort to he classical F test. In the second
case one could proceed by resorting to the so called Phillips triangular representation (see
Phillips 1991 and 1994) as in Attfield (1997), or through the use of the fully modified
Phillips-Hansen estimator (see Phillips and Hansen, 1990, Hansen (1992) and Phillips 1995).
To see how this could easily be accomplished let us reparameterize model (1) in the following
way:
w it = α i +
m -1
j=1
β ij p j5t + µ i p 5 t + γ i y t + u it
Notice that in equation (3) p j5 t = p jt − p 5 t (j=1,…,4) and
i=1, …,m-1
µi =
m
j=1
(3)
β ij . So, testing for
homogeneity amounts to testing µ i = 0 (i=1,…,m-1) using the corresponding t-statistics.
However as p5t is I(2) none of those approaches is applicable.
The Johansen approach is also not suitable as the AIDS model is derived under the
assumptions underlying the consumer demand theory and these do not conform with the
4
hypotheses underlying the Johansen approach, namely, that all the variables are endogenous
and generated by a VAR3.
Share equations in (1) or (3) are unlikely to hold in each and every period, and are
best seen as defining long run “equilibrium” budget shares. In this sense we may say that
system (1) is data consistent if every equation exhibits cointegration (otherwise the
regressions would be spurious). So, a way of testing the homogeneity restrictions consists in
estimating system (3) after imposing µ i = 0 in each equation and then testing for
cointegration. If cointegration for each equation is not rejected then we may conclude that
homogeneity is not inconsistent with empirical evidence. Notice that after imposing µ i = 0
in each equation, all the remaining variables in system (3) are I(1) and so the standard
cointegrating analysis applies. In particular, the potential endogeneity of the real expenditure
variable yt , discussed, for instance, in Attfield (1991), is not an issue as the estimators are
super-consistent in case of cointegration
Table 2 presents the results of the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, PhillipsOuliaris (1990), Z α , statistic and Shin (1994) cointegration test for the 4 equations estimated
by OLS, after setting µ i = 0 , so that homogeneity is imposed. The lack of power of the
cointegration tests is well known. That is why we decided to compute two cointegration tests
in which the null hypothesis is the absence of cointegration, i.e., the ADF and the Z α tests
and a cointegration test where the null hypothesis is cointegration, i.e., the Shin test. Both the
ADF and Z α tests were computed because the first is one of the most used cointegration tests
and the second because it is generally more powerful than the ADF test, specially in moderate
sample sizes or when the regressors are exogenous (see for instance Haug (1996)). In general,
one tends to favour the cointegration tests that postulate cointegration as the null hypothesis.
After all, the economic theory, basically, posits long run equilibrium relationships and so, a
null hypothesis of cointegration is more in line with economic theory than the reverse. In this
case, the economic theory will only be rejected if there is strong evidence against it, otherwise
we would take the risk of rejecting a good theory just because the test has not enough power
or because data are not enough informative.
According to the tables constructed by Engle and Yoo (1987) the ADF critical values
for a model with five variables and 50 observations is –4.15 (for a 5% test). As the critical
values increase about 0.20 points for each additional variable, the critical value for a model
3
In a recent paper Pesaran and Shin (1997) estimate the AIDS model through a general VAR model, the main
difference to the Johansen approach being the way the cointegrating relations are identified. Treating prices as
endogenous, however, is not a reasonable assumption and for this reason, this approach has not been adopted in
our study.
5
with six variables must be close to –4.35 for a 5% test and to –4.05 for a 10% test. According
to these critical values, non-cointegration would be rejected for equations w1, w2 and w4 for a
5% test. For the w3 equation, the null hypothesis would be rejected for a 20% test.
As we said the Z α test is generally more powerful than the ADF test. For a sample
size of 50 observations with five explanatory variables, Haug (1992) gives 5% critical value
for Z α of –33.49 and of –30.48 for a 10% critical value (demeaned statistics). So according
to the Z α test the null of no cointegration is rejected for equations w3 (at 5%), w2 and w4 (at
10%) and w1 (at 20%).
Table 2
Cointegration tests for AIDS with homogeneity4
w1
w2
w3
w4
ADF(2)=-4.55
ADF(0)=-4.97
ADF(1)=-3.70
ADF(0)=-4.50
Z α (m = 3)
-27.42
-32.95
-35.15
-32.74
SHIN(m=3)
0.056
0.045
0.135
0.114
ADF(k)
A similar conclusion may be drawn from the Shin cointegration test. According to
Shin’s tables the critical value for a model with 5 explanatory variables is 0.097 for a 5%
test and 0.158 for a 1% test. The null hypothesis of cointegration is not rejected for any
equation. For the first two equations is not rejected for a 20% test and for equations w4
and w3 cointegration is not rejected at 2.5% and 1% respectively. Additionally the
analysis of graph No.6 suggests that the residuals of the four equations are stationary. We
may then conclude that system (3) represents a cointegrating demand system in the
almost ideal form of Deaton and Muellbauer (1980). As the system was estimated with
homogeneity imposed ( µ i = 0 , i=1, …, m-1) we may say that homogeneity in the AIDS
model is not rejected by the data.
4
In the table ADF(k) stands for the ADF test with k lags in the first differences of the residuals of the cointegrating
regressions; k was identified following a “general to specific strategy” so that the residuals from the ADF regression
do not exhibit serial correlation in the residuals;
Z α (m=3) stands for the Phillips-Ouliaris cointegration test with m
representing the number of lag windows used to compute the test; The Shin cointegration test is computed from the
residuals of a cointegrating regression including lags and leads of the first differences of the regressors; because of a
degrees-of-freedom problem we only added to the cointegrating regression the current first differences of the
regressors; we suspect that this could have biased the results of the computed Shin test against the null of
cointegration; as in
Z α test, m stands for the number of lag windows used to compute the test.
6
4-Testing for homogeneity and symmetry
In addition to homogeneity restrictions consumer theory also imposes the so called
symmetry restrictions, i.e.,
β ij = β ji
for all i,j
(4)
These are cross-equation restrictions and so it is no longer possible to estimate the
system by ordinary least squares. Either one uses a non-linear least squares estimation
procedure or the well known SURE (seemingly unrelated regression equations) approach. The
four static structural equations have been estimated through the use of the restricted SURE
estimation approach, with the cross-equation restrictions imposed, using Microfit 4.05.
Asymptotically the estimators will be super-consistent in case of cointegration.
The restricted residuals of each equation where used to test for cointegration. Using
restricted rather than unrestricted residuals (as in section 3) affects both size and power of
conventional cointegration statistics. In general, size will be reduced and power increased at
conventional critical values, provided the restrictions are empirically satisfied. It is difficult to
know, without Monte Carlo simulation, exactly what critical values to use when testing the
restricted residuals. Intuition suggests that since there are 4 equations, 5 explanatory variables
and 6 symmetry restrictions, critical values associated with a cointegrating relationship with 4
explanatory variables are probably a reasonable approximation. Notwithstanding we decide to
carry out our analysis as if no restrictions were imposed, i.e., resorting to the critical values
used in the previous section for a regression with 5 regressors. Of course these are expected to
be conservative tests, in the sense of acting against cointegration6.
The results of the cointegration tests are in table 3. As it can be seen the new results
support the existence of cointegration. According to the ADF test the null of no cointegration
is rejected for all equations (at 5% for the w1 and w3 equations and at 10% for the w2 and w4
equations). The same conclusion holds for the Z α test, even though in case of the w1
equation the null is only rejected for a 20% test. According to the Shin cointegration test the
5
We also estimated the model using the LNSYSTEM routine of RATS 4.3, but the estimates for the parameters were
exactly the same.
6
In rigour, we do not know the true critical values, as the residuals were not obtained using OLS. Additionally one
must note another potential limitation of the analysis carried out in this section. Cointegration is analysed equation by
equation, but one should probably carry out a global cointegration test taking into account the fact that we are
estimating a system with cross-equations restrictions. However, such a test, to our knowledge, has not yet been
developed in the context of the consumer demand theory.
7
null of cointegration is not rejected for any equation and the results for the w3 equation are
even superior to the non-symmetry case (the same holds for the ADF test). In addition to
cointegration tests, the analysis of Graph No. 7 also suggests that the residuals of the four
equations are stationary.
Table 3
Cointegration tests for AIDS with homogeneity and symmetry
w1
w2
w3
w4
ADF(2)=-4.69
ADF(0)=-4.00
ADF(1)=-4.37
ADF(0)=-4.27
Z α (m = 3)
-29.99
-37.32
-34.90
-30.83
SHIN(m=3)
0.056
0.063
0.097
0.116
ADF(k)
In short, cointegration holds for the AIDS model with homogeneity and symmetry
imposed and, in this sense, this model is an acceptable characterisation of the Portuguese data
on consumer expenditure.
5-Analysing income and price elasticities
This section reports income and price elasticities for the AIDS model both with and
without symmetry restrictions imposed. In the first case (model without symmetry
restrictions), elasticities were computed using the so called dynamic OLS estimator, that is the
OLS estimator on the triangular representation of the AIDS model in which the first
differences of the regressors were added to system (3) (with µ i = 0 ), i.e.,
w it = α i +
m -1
j=1
β ij p j5t + γ i y t +
m -1
j=1
δ ij ∆p j5t + λ i ∆y t + ε it
i=1,…,m-1
(5)
In rigour this system is expected to include lags and leads of the first differences of
the regressors, but the small number of observations prevented us from including them. It is
known that the MLE estimators of β ij and γ i parameters reduce to the GLS estimators.
Because regressors pj5t and yt are I(1) it can be shown that simple OLS on (5) gives an
asymptotically equivalent estimator of parameters β ij and γ i (Stock and Watson, 1993).
These estimators are also asymptotically efficient (Saikkonen, 1991). In the second case
8
(model with both homogeneity and symmetry restrictions), elasticities were computed
estimating system (5) using the SURE technique.
Table 4 presents income and uncompensated own-price elasticities for the AIDS
model, computed at sample means7. The imposition of symmetry produces some considerable
changes for food, clothing and energy. The economic reasonability of some elasticities seems
to be deteriorated after the imposition of symmetry. This is the case of food, for instance.
Food has an income elasticity slightly larger than one after the imposition of symmetry,
whereas the imposition of homogeneity only was compatible with the usual classification of
Table 4
Elasticities
Model with homogeneity
Model with homogeneity
and symmetry
Commodities
Income
Own-price
Income
Own-price
Elasticity
elasticity
elasticity
elasticity
Food
0.907
-0.310
1.049
-0.390
Clothing
0.857
-0.820
0.689
-0.625
Energy
0.822
-0.453
1.180
-0.282
Other goods
1.197
-0.977
1.205
-0.965
Services
1.069
-0.770
0.982
-0.835
this good as a necessity. The demand for food is relatively price inelastic. Clothing is a
necessity. The income elasticity of energy is either close to 0.8, with homogeneity imposed,
or to 1.2, in the system with symmetry imposed; energy is relatively price inelastic. Other
goods are a luxury and display the larger own-price elasticity, close to –1. Finally, the income
elasticity of services is close to one and the respective own-price elasticity is close to –0.8.
6. Concluding remarks
This paper uses the AIDS to analyse the allocation of consumption amongst different
types of goods in Portugal, over the period 1958-1993. In contrast with most previous
application of the Almost Ideal model, this paper takes into account the non-stationary
properties of the data. The statistical analysis of the series indicates that budget shares and
7
One should note that as the budget shares are I(1) they do not have a constant mean. In spite of this we decided to
compute the elasticities in the usual way.
9
real per capita income are I(1), whereas prices are I(2). This result prevented us from testing
the imposition of homogeneity resorting to the Phillips’ triangular representation (Attfield,
1997).
As relative prices are I(1), homogeneity was imposed from the outset. As
cointegration was not rejected, we concluded that the AIDS with imposition of homogeneity
is a data consistent model. Imposition of symmetry involves cross-equation restrictions and
therefore critical values for cointegration are not known. The comparison with some
‘conservative’ critical values indicated that cointegration is not rejected in the symmetric
AIDS. This model is, in this way, an acceptable characterisation of the Portuguese data on
consumer expenditure.
7- References
Alley A.G., Ferguson D. G., Stewart K. G., 1992, “An almost ideal demand system
for alcoholic beverages in British Columbia”, Empirical Economics, 17, 401-418;
Attfield, C. L. F., 1991, “Estimation and testing when explanatory variables are
endogenous: an application to a demand system” Journal of Econometrics 48, 395-408;
Attfield, C. L. F., 1997, “Estimating a cointegrating demand system”, European
Economic Review, 41, 61-73;
Deaton, A., Muellbauer, J., 1980, “An almost ideal demand system”, American
Economic Review 70, 312-326;
Dickey, Pantula, 1987, “Determining the order of differencing in autoregressive
processes”, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 5, No 4, 455-461;
Engle R. F., Yoo, B. S., 1987, “Forecasting and testing in co-integrated systems”,
Journal of Econometrics, 35, 143-159;
Hansen, B. E., 1992, “Tests for parameter instability in regressions with I(1)
processes”, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 10, No 3, 321-335;
Haug, A. A., 1992, “Critical values for the Z α -Phillips-Ouliaris test for
cointegration”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 54, 473-480.
Haug, A. A., 1996, “Tests for cointegration, a Monte Carlo comparison”, Journal of
Econometrics, 71, 89-115;
Majunder, A., 1992, “Measuring income responses: a log quadratic demand model for
consumers in India”, Empirical Economics, 17, 315-321;
10
Moschini, G., 1998, “The semiflexible almost ideal demand system”, European
Economic Review, 42, 349-364;
Pesaran, M. H., Shin Y., 1997, “Long-run structural modelling”, manuscript,
http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/faculty/pesaran/
Phillips, P. C. B., 1991, “Optimal inference in cointegrated systems”, Econometrica
59, 283-306;
Phillips, P. C. B., 1994, “Some exact distribution theory for maximum likelihood
estimators of cointegrating coefficients in error correction models”, Econometrica 62, 7393;
Phillips, P. C. B., 1995, “Fully modified least squares and vector autoregression”,
Econometrica, Vol.63, No 5, 1023-1078;
Phillips, P. C. B., Hansen, B. E., 1990, “Statistical inference in instrumental variables
regression with I(1) processes”, Review of Economic Studies, 57, 99-125;
Pinheiro et al., 1997, “Historical series for the Portuguese economy”, Banco de
Portugal;
Saikkonen, P., 1991, “Asymptotically efficient estimation of cointegration
regressions”, Econometric Theory, 7, 1-21;
Shin, Y., 1994, “A residual-based test of the null of cointegration against the
alternative of no cointegration”, Econometric Theory, 10,91-115;
Stock, J. H., Watson M.W., 1993, “ A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors in
higher order integrated systems”, Econometrica Vol.61, No. 4, 783-820;
11
Graph No.1
.375
.14
w1
.35
w2
.12
.325
.1
.3
1960
.03
1970
1980
1990
1960
.13
w3
.025
.12
.02
.11
.015
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
w4
.1
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
Graph No.2
.8
w5
y
.45
.6
.425
.4
.4
.2
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
dy
dp1
.025
.2
0
.1
-.025
0
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
12
Graph No.3
.4
dp2
dp3
.4
.3
.2
.2
.1
0
0
-.1
1960
.2
1970
1980
1990
1960
dp4
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
1980
1990
dp5
.2
.1
.1
0
-.1
0
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
Graph No.4
.2
p25
p15
0
.1
0
-.2
-.1
-.4
1960
1970
1980
1960
1990
p35
.4
p45
0
.2
-.25
-.5
0
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
1970
13
Graph No.5
.1
dp15
dp25
.2
.05
.1
0
0
-.05
-.1
-.2
-.1
1960
.3
1970
1980
1990
1960
dp35
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
dp45
.2
.05
.1
0
0
-.05
-.1
-.1
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
Graph No.6
Residuals from cointegrating regressions
Model with homogeneity
.02
resw1
resw2
.01
.01
0
0
-.01
-.02
-.01
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
resw3
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
resw4
.005
0025
0
0
-.005
0025
-.01
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
14
Graph No.7
Residuals from cointegrating regressions
Model with homogeneity and symmetry
.02
resw1
resw2
.01
.01
0
0
-.01
-.02
-.01
1960
.005
1970
1980
1990
resw3
1960
.005
1970
1980
1990
1970
1980
1990
resw4
0025
0
0
-.005
0025
-.01
1960
1970
1980
1990
1960
15