WorldDevelopmentVol. 26, No. 6, pp. 1033-1047, 1998
Pergamon
0 1998 Elsevier Science Ltd
All rights reserved. Printed in Great Britain
0305-750x/98 $19.00+0.00
PII: SO305750X(98)00025-4
Corporate
Finance in Developing Countries:
New Evidence for India*
COBHAM zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSR
DAVID
University of St Andrews, St Andrews, UK
and
RAMESH SUBRAMANIAM
Asian Development Bank, M anila, Philippines
Summary. Recent work by Singh and Hamid (1992, Corporate Financial Structures in
Developing Countties) and Singh (1995, Corporate Financial Patterns in Industrializing Economies:
A Comparative International Study) has suggested that large firms in a number of developing
countries, including India, use much more external finance in general, and equity finance in
particular, than those in developed countries. However, the contrast is in part a product of
methodological differences, and India is much less different from countries such as France and
Italy. The Singh results are not due merely to bias arising from the focus on the largest
companies, since the rest of the Indian corporate sector also issues large amounts of equity, via
informal networks rather than organized stock exchanges. The importance of such issues suggests
the need for further research before policy conclusions can be drawn. 0 1998 Elsevier Science
Ltd. All rights reserved
Key words -
Asia, India, corporate financing, firm-size effects, equity markets
1. INTRODUCTION
There is a considerable general literature on
finance and economic growth, and much recent
work has emphasized the importance of the
linkages between the real and financial sectors.’
The capital structure of firms in developing
countries had attracted little systematic attention,
however, before the pioneering study for the
International Finance Corporation by Singh and
Hamid (1992), which examined the financial
structure of large firms in a sample of nine
developing countries, found that external finance
in general and equity finance in particular were
much more important for these firms than had
been previously thought.
Singh and Hamid (1992) analyzed data on the
50 largest manufacturing
companies listed on
stock exchanges in India, South Korea, Pakistan,
Jordan, Thailand, Mexico, Malaysia, Turkey and
Zimbabwe over 1980-88.2 Their basic method is
to calculate the “net assets” of firms, equal to
total assets minus current liabilities, and then to
consider the sources of finance internal
finance (retained profits, net of depreciation),
equity and long-term debt (bond issues plus
long-term bank loans) - as a proportion of the
growth of net assets. They found, first, that these
companies seemed to use much more external
finance than companies in developed countries
and, second, that they also made much more use
of equity finance than companies in developed
countries. More detailed work was undertaken
by Singh (1995) in a study designed partly to
check the robustness of these results. The new
data set covered 100 companies where possible, a
slightly longer time period (19SO-90), and an
*We would like to thank seminar participants at the
University of St Andrews and the Royal Economic
Society Conference (Swansea, 1996) for comments,
Ganga Darbha, Subir Gokarn, K. J. Joseph, R.
Nagaraj, Manoj Panda and M. H. Suryanarayana for
help with data sources, and Gustav Ranis, Cherian
Samuel, Ajit Singh and anonymous referees for helpful
suggestions and comments. Subramaniam would like to
gratefully acknowledge financial support from the May
and Stanley Smith Trust at the University of St
Andrews and the hospitality of Yale University
Economic Growth Center where a previous version of
this paper was written. The views expressed here are
those of the authors, and not of the organizations with
which they are affiliated. Final revision accepted:
January 12, 1998.
1033
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
1034
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
major independent
contribution
to economic
Table 1. Top listed companies in manufacturing mean
propotiion of internal and external finance of corporate
growth (% ), Singhs (1995) results
Source/country
Internal
finance
Equity
Long-term
debt
Korea
Pakistan
Jordan
Thailand
Mexico
India
Turkey
Malaysia
Zimbabwe
Brazil
19.5
74.0
66.3
27.7
24.4
40.5
15.3
35.6
58.0
56.4
49.6
1.7
22.1
N.A.
66.6
19.6
65.1
46.6
38.8
36.0
30.9
24.3
11.6
N.A.
9.0
39.9
19.6
17.8
3.2
7.7
ALL
38.8
39.3
20.8
Source: Singh (1995), extracted from Table C-5.
extra country
(Brazil).
The key results,
as
exemplified
by Table 1, confirmed
the earlier
findings:
although
there is considerable
(and
statistically significant) variation across countries,
the
mean
proportion
of internal
finance
(retained profits after tax as a percentage
of the
growth of “net assets”) was 38.8%, while issues
of equity finance provided 39.3% and long-term
debt
provided
20.8%.
For
some
countries
(notably Korea, Turkey and Mexico) the use of
internal finance was much lower and that of
equity finance much higher.
These results provide a sharp contrast with
recent research on the net sources of finance for
the non-financial
corporate
sector in developed
countries, e.g. by Mayer (1988, 1990, 1994) and
Corbett and Jenkinson (1994) which has shown
that issues of securities (equity and bonds) do
not provide large amounts
of finance in any
country
considered,
and have often been a
negative source of finance in net terms in the
United
States
and
the
United
Kingdom.
Moreover, the “pecking-order”
theory of finance
1984)
that
firms
prefer
internal
(Myers,
financing to external and within the external
category prefer debt to equity, which has been
used to explain the latter findings, should, if
anything,
hold more strongly
for developing
countries where information
imperfections
are
often more significant, companies
are typically
younger and less well-established,
and capital
markets are too small to benefit from the economies of scale found in the larger developed
country securities markets.
The Singh-Hamid
results are also at odds with
development
economists’ conventional
view that
stock markets cannot be expected
to make a
growth (see, for example, Fry, 1988, p. 291; Fry,
199.5, p. 344; see also Nagaraj, 1996; Samuel,
1996) although in recent years some observers
(e.g. Atje and Jovanovic, 1993; Atkin and Glen,
1992) have taken a more positive view of stock
market development.
Singh (1995) himself has
rejected the suggestion that developing countries
are simply repeating the historical experience of
the United States (in which equity finance was
originally important but has become much less so
since the 1930s) and has put forward an explanation of his findings which relates to the specific
circumstances
of the period
and countries
concerned.
He stresses the active role taken by
governments
in pushing the development
of their
stock markets through activities which include
privatization,
financial liberalization,
and a range
of specific measures affecting both the supply of
and the demand for securities.
He emphasizes
the drop in the relative cost of equity capital
over the 1980s which resulted from a large rise in
share prices (and the associated
rise in priceearnings ratios) and a rise in real interest rates,
the former related internally to financial liberalization
and governmental
support
for stock
markets and externally to the awakening interest
of developed
country institutional
investors in
emerging markets, and the latter resulting largely
from internal
financial liberalization,
together
perhaps with some international
influence.
The main implication
of this explanation
is
that the high level of external equity financing in
developing countries over the 1980s is likely to
turn out to be a passing phenomenon
resulting
on the one hand from the ending of conventional
financial repression
in these countries (together
perhaps
with the introduction
of some new
distortions
intended
to produce
structural
changes
that are unlikely
to become
selfsustaining
in the absence
of governmental
support),
and on the other hand from periodspecific
developments
in the
international
environment
facing developing countries.
This explanation is attractive, if not yet wholly
persuasive.
Before it can be firmly accepted
more research will be needed in a number of
areas; time alone will generate relevant data to
test whether the phenomenon
is a transitional
one or a continuing
one. In the meantime
a
number of other useful points can be made. In
this paper, we take one particular country, India,
from the Singh-Hamid
sample and examine it in
more detail. In Table 1 India is shown as having
had a near-average
level of internal finance but
less equity and more debt finance than the
sample as a whole. However, in the early 1990s
CORPORATE
FINANCE
IN DEVELOPING
equity issues on the Indian stock exchanges
continued to increase sharply, so that for the
later period to which most of our results refer,
India is likely to have been near to or above the
mean of Singh’s sample. We first examine the
net sources and Singh-Hamid
methodologies
and show that the contrast is at least in part the
product of methodological
differences.
We
provide some net sources of finance data for
India, which suggest that, although markedly
different from that in the Anglo-Saxon countries,
the structure of corporate finance in India was
not that far from that found in “Mediterranean”
countries such as France and Italy. We then
investigate, again with respect to India, the possibility that the Singh-Hamid
work is samplespecific in that the large firms on which their
analysis focuses are not representative of the
private corporate sector as a whole. Our analysis
of firm-level data from two samples of Indian
firms suggests that small firms there make as
much or more use of equity finance than large
firms, while comparable firm-level data for the
United Kingdom produce the opposite result.
We rationalize these results by arguing that the
nature of equity financing is different when firms
are not listed on stock exchanges and are issuing
equity through channels which involve less information asymmetry and less separation of ownership and control.
Section 2 examines the differences in methodology between Singh-Hamid and the studies of
developed countries by Mayer and his associates.
Section 3 presents aggregate data for India
compiled according to the net sources of finance
methodology and compares India on that basis
with the developed countries that have been
studied in this way. Section 4 analyzes firm-level
cumulative data in order to investigate whether
in the case of India the Singh-Hamid
results
suffer from a large-firm bias, and Section 5
concludes and draws out the implications for
policy.
COUNTRIES
1035
2. METHODOLOGICAL
ISSUES
The net sources methodology can be understood most easily in terms of a simplified sources
and uses of funds table, as in Corbett and
Jenkinson
(1994). The gross sources are
presented as follows in Table 2. The gross
of finance
involves
sources
methodology
considering each of the individual sources of
funds in relation to the total sources. Partly
because the total sources of finance are used to
acquire financial as well as physical assets, the
preferred net sources methodology subtracts
Items 7 to 10 from the corresponding sources
(see Table 3). The various net sources are then
considered in relation to total net sources, which
is equal to physical investment (gross fixed
capital formation plus increase in stocks).
The Singh-Hamid methodology uses balance
sheet (stock) data rather than sources and uses
(flow) data, but takes changes in the stocks so
that in principle there should be no difference.3
It then subtracts depreciation (Item 14) from
both internal finance (retained profits) and
capital formation, and derives an aggregate
(Item 15) for the change in net assets equal to
the change in total assets minus current liabilities, as in Table 4. The sources of finance are
then regrouped as (“net”) internal, external
(equity) and external/long-term
debt ( = longterm bank loans plus bond issues), and each of
these is considered in relation to the total of net
assets. To be precise, their ratios are given by:
(a) internal finance of growth; (b) external
finance of growth (long term debt); and (c)
external finance of growth (equity): 1 -internal
finance of growth-external
finance of growth
(long-term debt), where RP stands for Retained
Profits, NA for Net Assets and LTD for Long
Term Debt. p and m are the first and last years,
respectively, in the period covered.
Thus, the net sources methodology treats
depreciation as a part of internal financing, looks
at the net contribution from each source, and
Table 2. Gross sources methodology
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQP
Gross uses
Gross sources
1. Internal
2.
3.
4.
5.
Bank loans and advances
New equity issues
Bond issues
Trade credit received
6. Total sources
Identity:
1+2+3+4+5
= 6 = 7+8+9+10+11+12
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
= 13
Cash and bank deposits
Equity purchases
Bond purchases
Trade credit given
Gross fixed capital formation
Increase in stocks
Total uses
WORLD
1036
DEVELOPMENT
Table 3. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJ
Net sources methodology
Net uses
Net sources
1.
2-7.
3-8.
4-9.
5-10.
Internal
Net bank finance
Net equity finance
Net bond finance
Net Trade Credit
Total net sources
( = 6 - 7 - 8 -9 - 10)
Identity: 1+(2-7)+(3-8)+(4-9)+(5-lo)=
expresses the sources of finance as proportions
of physical investment (including variations in
stocks), while the Singh-Hamid
methodology
nets depreciation out from both the sources (in
the form of internal finance) and the uses of
finance, takes the main contributions gross, and
expresses the sources of finance as proportions
of the change in fixed assets net of current liabilities. Therefore both the numerators and the
denominators differ between these three presentations of the sources of corporate finance. In
particular, inspection shows that the total (gross)
sources of finance, Item 6, must be.greater than
total net sources or physical investment, Items
11+ 12 (hence the larger figure for the internal
finance ratio in the net sources presentation).
Similarly, total gross sources must be greater
than total net assets, Item 15. The latter aggregate can in principle be greater or smaller than
total net sources/physical investment, depending
on the respective magnitudes of (i) firms’ acquisitions of financial assets, (ii) the change in firms’
current liabilities, and (iii) depreciation; but in
practice the depreciation item is likely to be
much larger than the net change in financial
assets minus current liabilities,4 so that Item 15 is
generally smaller than Items 11+12. This,
together with the fact that equity is taken gross
rather than net, explains why equity looks more
important in the Singh-Hamid
methodology.
Similarly, internal finance appears smaller in the
Physical
investment
11+12
Singh-Hamid
methodology partly because the
denominator is larger and partly because it is
considered net of depreciation. Singh (1995)
provides some data for a sample of UK manufacturing companies using his own methodology,
which show equity finance as considerably more
important for UK companies than appears from
the net sources methodology: for the average
in his sample
internal
finance
company
accounted for 56.7% of the growth of net assets,
equity finance for 16.6% and long-term debt for
26.6%. There is still a marked contrast, however,
between these figures and the Singh-Hamid
results for developing countries.
The differences between these methodologies
are not arbitrary. Singh-Hamid used a methodology which dates back at least to Singh and
Whittington (1968) and is designed to answer
questions about the growth of individual firms,
while the net sources methodology is designed to
investigate how the corporate sector finances its
physical investment. The latter is less subject to
international
differences in the treatment of
depreciation
(Mayer,
1990; Corbett
and
Jenkinson, 1994). It is also less vulnerable to
differences in the reporting of data that affect
the gross sources methodology (Corbett and
Jenkinson, 1994; Corbett and Jenkinson, 1997).’
In addition, a wider range of countries have been
examined on this basis, so that more comparators are available: in particular, studies on this
Table 4. Singh- Hamid methodology
Sources
1-14.
2a.
3.
4.
of finance
Changes
Internal finance (net of depreciation)
Bank loans, long term
Equity issues
Bond issues
Identity:
in net assets
7-2b.
Cash and bank deposits - short term bank loans
8.
Equity purchases
9.
Bond purchases
10-5.
Net trade credit liabilities
11-14.
Net fixed capital formation
12.
Increase in stocks
15.
Change in net assets
(l-14)+2a+3+4=(7-2b)+8+9+(10-5)+(11-14)+12=
15
CORPORATE
FINANCE
IN DEVELOPING
basis now exist for a range of countries other
than the United States and the United Kingdom.
For these reasons, and because our interest is in
the relationships between investment, growth
and the financial system as a whole, we choose to
use the net sources methodology where possible
(although for the samples of firms we examine in
Section 4 data limitations mean that we can
consider only the gross sources of finance).
3. AGGREGATE
DATA FOR INDIA
Table 5 provides data, at the aggregate level,
on the gross (panel (a)) and net (panel (b))
sources of finance for India. Data are also
presented separately for two periods: 1980-81 to
1986-87 corresponds to the pre-liberalization
period in financial markets, and 1987-88 to
1992-93 approximately pertains to the liberalization period. It should also be noted that the
figures in the table are period ratios (as in
Corbett and Jenkinson, 1994) in that they show
the contribution of each source of finance over
the entire period.
The figures presented in Table 5 suggest that
market finance in India was rather less important
on this basis than on Singh’s figures. For the
whole period market finance in Table 5 is given
as 17-18% in either gross or net terms. This
figure can be contrasted with Singh’s (1995)
figures of 19.6% of net asset growth financed by
equity and 39.9% financed by long-term debt
(which includes long-term bank loans as well as
bonds) in 1980-90 (a period which excludes the
two years 1991 and 1992 when equity issues were
exceptionally high), as given in Table 1. The
share of internal finance for the Indian corporate
Table 5. Gross and net sources
of finance
Gross sources of finance as 5% of total identified
Internal
Market finance (equity issues+bonds)
Bank lending
Other
(b) Net sources of finance as % of physical investment
Internal
Market finance
Bank lending
Other
Notes:
See Appendix
(equity issues+bonds)
1037
sector is about 37.8% of gross finance and 42.0%
of physical investment. Bank lending accounts
for 31.2% of gross sources and (in net terms) for
28.8% of physical investment. The gross finance
ratios decline marginally for retentions
and
“Other” sources between the two sub-periods,
whereas for market finance and bank lending the
ratios increase. All the net finance ratios, with
the exception of the “Other” category, increase
between the sub-periods (which may reflect
mainly an improvement in the coverage of the
data); in proportional terms the rise in market
finance is particularly large. Examination of the
data on a year-by-year basis shows that the
pattern of important internal finance, substantial
bank borrowing and moderate recourse to the
capital markets is a consistent one over time,
although there is some increase in securities
issues in the early 1990s.
The Indian figures can also be compared with
the figures for other developed
countries
produced by Mayer (1990) and Corbett and
Jenkinson (1994), as in Table 6. This table distinguishes between three sets of countries: those
which Corbett and Jenkinson (1994) call “high
internal finance” countries - the United States,
the United Kingdom and Germany, designated
as Group A; the others for which data are available Japan, France, Italy, Canada and
Finland, designated Group B; and a subset of the
latter - France, Italy and Finland - which arc
designated as Group C. Group C thus excludes
Japan, which may be regarded as zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihg
sui generis, and
Canada which is in some ways closer to the high
internal finance countries; Group C is therefore
perhaps more representative of those developed
countries which lie between the two polar groups
to which most attention has so far been paid.
Type/source
(4
COUNTRIES
for the Indian corporate sector
1980-81 to
1992-93
1980-81 to
1986-87
1987-88 to
1992-93
37.8
18.4
31.2
12.6
38.5
15.3
29.3
16.9
37.4
20.2
32.3
10.1
42.0
16.9
28.8
12.3
33.1
10.4
22.6
33.9
49.7
22.5
34.0
-6.2
sources
A for a general description
of the Indian Flow-of-Funds
table. Sources: National Income
Bank of India’s Annual Reports and Reports on Currency and Finance. “Other” is the sum of
trade credit and reported and unreported
residual categories (see the text and Appendix A).
Statistics and Reserve
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
1038
Table 6. International comparisons zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQ
Source
Gross sources of finance
Internal
Equity
Market finance
Bank loans
Net sources of finance
Internal
Equity
Market finance
Bank loans
Group A
Group B
Group C
India
60.4 to
-4.9 to
3.1 to
14.7 to
62.7
7.0
9.3
23.3
38.5 to
3.9 to
7.4 to
12.8 to
54.2
11.9
18.0
41.5
38.5 to
5.6 to
7.4 to
27.2 to
44.1
10.8
13.2
41.5
37.4 to 38.5
N.A.
15.3 to 20.2
29.3 to 32.3
80.6 to
- 10.4 to
- 6.9 to
11.0 to
97.3
0.9
8.3
19.5
51.9 to
-0.1 to
2.7 to
15.2 to
76.4
8.2
11.0
37.3
51.9 to
-0.1 to
2.7 to
27.7 to
64.4
8.2
9.8
37.3
33.1 to 49.7
N.A.
10.4 to 22.5
22.6 to 34.0
Group A - high internal finance countries: US, UK and Germany; Group B - low internal finance countries:
Canada, Finland, France, Italy and Japan; Group C - Finland, France and Italy.
Notes: Data for US, UK, Germany and Japan pertain to 1970-89 and are taken from Corbett and Jenkinson
(1994, Table 3). These are period ratios. Data for Canada, Finland, France and Italy pertain to 1970-85 and are
taken from Mayer (1990, Table 12.3). These are averages of annual ratios. Data for India pertain to 1980-92 and
are as explained in the notes to Table 2.
The
table
gives
the
range
(minimum
to
maximum) for each group of countries or, for
India, across the two subperiods.
Examination
of Table 6 reveals that, although
India is clearly very different
from the high
internal finance countries of Group A, it is not
so different from the Group C countries.
The
gross finance ratios for India are within or close
to the ranges for Group C. The Indian net ratios
for internal finance and market finance are lower
and higher respectively than those for Group C.
Both
of
these
differences
are,
however,
consistent with the fact that Indian firms use a
smaller proportion
of their gross sources of
finance to acquire financial (rather than physical)
assets. On this basis it seems reasonable
to
conclude that the Indian private corporate sector
is not financed in a way that is very different
from the non-polar
developed
countries;
in
particular,
India has much in common
with
France and Italy.”
The macro evidence presented
in Table 5 is
based on the whole non-financial
corporate
sector. Thus it includes firms in all size-groups,
ranging from the small to the very large. In order
to test for any size effects, to see if the behavior
of large firms is much different
from that of
smaller firms, we need disaggregated
data. We
shall therefore analyze cumulative balance sheet
and income and expenditure data for a sample of
firms in India from the Reserve Bank of India
(RBI) and Industrial
Credit and Investments
Corporation
of India (ICICI) data sets. We also
examine some samples of United Kingdom firms
from
the
Business
Monitor
surveys
as a
comparison. Appendix A presents a discussion of
the nature of these data sets. We provide our
results in terms of finance and investment ratios
(both annual and period)
and tests for size
effects in the next section.
4. FIRM-LEVEL
RESULTS FOR INDIA AND
THE UNITED KINGDOM
(a) Results zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVU
for firms in the RBI sample
We begin our analysis with the Reserve Bank
of India cumulative firm-level data set. Table 7
presents
the averages of the annual ratios of
sources to total finance and of total finance to
physical investment
for these firms. In terms of
size-wise comparisons
between large and small
firms, a number of differences
are found. The
most striking difference between large and small
firms is that internal finance is higher and bank
loans are lower for large firms than for small. In
addition, the annual ratios (not presented
here)
show that the ratios are much more variable for
the small than for the large firms, and in some
years bank finance is even more important than
internal finance for the small firms. For the large
firms, on the other hand, internal
finance is
consistently above 40%. The denominator
(total
identified
sources of financing)
in the ratios
presented in Table 7 is the sum of the sources in
the first three rows (internal, equity and total
borrowings).
The next two rows present the two
most important
elements
of total borrowings:
debentures
and loans. Large firms make more
use of bond finance than small firms, but small
firms make slightly more use of equity finance.
CORPORATE FINANCE IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
103Y
Table 7. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Averages of annual ratios of (gross) sources of finance to total identified sources of finance and of total
finance to investment for Reserve Bank of India data, 1981- 90
Source
All firms
Large firms
Small firms
Internal
Equity
Total borrowings”
Debentures
Bank loans
0.437
0.071
0.491
0.123
0.167
0.469
0.072
0.459
0.137
0.139
0.348
0.078
0.590
0.070
0.260
Total finance
1.111
1.149
1.004
to investment
t-test for large vs small firms comparison”
4.60
0.13
-3.89
2.91
- 4.55
(14) p
(18)~
(17)~
(18) p
(16) p
=
=
=
=
=
0.0004
0.8987
0.0012
0.0093
0.0003
2.63 (18) p = 0.0168
“Debentures,
bank loans and other borrowings
(from financial institutions)
add up to total borrowings.
The RBI
tables provide only debentures
and bank loans, but not the residual category.
hDegrees of freedom are given in parentheses;
a negative value for the t-ratio implies that the small firms group
has a higher mean for the concerned finance ratio.
Our preference is for the MCJ net sources
methodology, but as stated above the RBI data
do not allow us to calculate the net figures.
However, we include in the last row of Table 4
the ratio of total identified (gross) sources of
finance to net physical investment.’ These figures
show that the large firms invest considerably
more in financial assets than the smaller firms.
Table 7 also presents the results of a set of
f-tests of the hypotheses that the means of the
ratios of each source of financing (over the
10 years, from 1981 to 1990) are equal between
large and small firms. The variables (internal
ratios for large and small firms, for example) are
assumed to have unequal variances in calculating
the t-ratios.8 Ideally we would have liked to use a
cross-section, preferably a panel, of firm-level
data in order to test whether the distributions of
the finance and investment ratios are different
between the various categories of firms, but such
individual-level data are not available. Instead,
we carry out a more limited test which is the only
thing possible given the data: we examine
whether the average ratios for each source of
finance are different between the large and small
groups of firms over the period under consideration. The degrees of freedom for the t-tests are
provided in parenthesis in each cell. It can be
seen from Table 7 that this hypothesis is rejected
for each source of finance except for equity.’
Thus, there is a significant (probability values
are also provided in Table 7) size difference
between large and small firms in terms of
internal, debentures and bank loans as sources of
financing. The negative t-test values, for total
borrowings and bank loans, imply that small
firms (the latter group in the framework of the
tests) have higher ratios in these categories than
large firms. In other words, this test suggests that
large firms use more internal finance and bond
finance, but smaller firms use more bank loans.
Smaller firms also use marginally more equity
finance, but the difference is not significant.
Below we provide some plausible explanations
for this observed size difference in the behavior
of firms. The next section presents the results for
the ICICI sample.
(b) zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPO
Results for firmsin the ICKY sample
Table 8 presents the averages of the annual
finance ratios for the whole sample of firms as
well as the different size subsamples in the ICICI
data set. In column 1, for the whole sample,
internal financing is the dominant source at 38%,
followed by trade credits at 17%. Equity
financing contributes
a small 4% to total
finances, while debentures and bank loans contribute 10% each. Thus, the pooled ICICI sample
does not look much different from the pooled
RBI sample in terms of the relative importance
of the various sources, though both internal and
equity financing are higher in the RBI than zyxwvutsrqpo
in
the ICICI sample. The ratio of total finance to
investment presented in the last row is well
above unity; this must reflect some combination
of incompleteness in the data and firms’ acquisitions of financial rather than physical assets. The
remaining columns in the table provide the
averages of annual finance ratios for firms in the
four different size groups.
While the average ratios presented in Table 8
for the ICICI data show similar size-source
patterns as in the RBI data, with larger firms
using more internal finance and bond finance
and smaller firms using more equity finance, the
r-test results presented in Table 9 show that not
all the size-source differences are statistically
significant. In addition, as can be seen from
Table 8, there is no consistent size pattern for
bank financing (with firms in S2 and S4 reporting
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
1040
Table 8. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Averages of annual ratios of (gross) sources of finance to total sources of finance for industrial credit and
investment corporation of India data, 1982- 90,
by size groups (Sl, S2, S3 and S4)”
All firmsh
Sl
s2
s3
s4
Internal
Equity
Bonds
Bank borrowings
Trade credit
0.378
0.040
0.099
0.099
0.166
0.217
0.110
0.023
0.052
0.214
0.273
0.063
0.057
0.095
0.240
0.392
0.045
0.088
0.058
0.169
0.363
0.040
0.156
0.093
0.136
Total finance to investment
1.462
1.609
1.729
1.582
1.459
Source
“Sl - firms with gross hxed assets (end of a financial year) below Rs. 5 Crores; S2 - firms with GFA between
Rs. 5 Crores and Rs. 20 Crores; S3 - firms with GFA between Rs. 20 Crores and Rs. 50 Crores; S4 - firms with
GFA above Rs. 50 Crores; 1 Crore = 10 million.
bData pertain to 1980-92. The sample has 417 public limited companies for 1980-88 and 620 public limited
companies for 1989-92. The other sources are: bank borrowings for working capital (O.OSl), unsecured loans and
deposits (O.OSS), deferred credit (O.OOS), other borrowings (0.03) and other current liabilities (0.046),
approximately.
a higher ratio for bank borrowings than firms in
the other two groups). The column for internal
finance in Table 9 shows that there is no significant difference between Sl firms and those in S2
and S4. Firms in S3 use more internal finance
than those in Sl. Firms in S3 and S4 use more
internal sources than firms in S2 and there is no
significant difference between S3 and S4 firms.‘”
For equity financing (Table 9, column 2) there is
no significant size effect in any of the pairwise
comparisons, with the exception of Sl versus S4
where Sl firms report a significantly higher ratio
for this source than the largest (S4) firms. On the
other hand, there is a significant positive
relationship between size and bond financing as
can be seen from column 3 of Table 9. In line
with the bank finance ratios in the last column of
Table 8, only in the last pair is there a significant
Table 9.
Type
Sl vs s2
Sl vs s4
s2 vs s3
s2 vs s4
s3 vs s4
(c)
Results for firms
Internal
Equity
- 0.64 (7)
0.5440
- 1.98 (7)
p = 0.0877
- 1.66 (7)
p = 0.1399
-4.25 (13)
p = 0.0009
-3.52 (14)
p = 0.0034
1.01 (14)
p = 0.3298
1.28 (9)
0.2334
1.82 (7)
p=o.1122
2.00 (7)
p = 0.0855
1.00 (12)
p = 0.3364
1.43 (9)
p = 0.1876
0.47 (12)
p = 0.6497
p =
in the UK business monitor
survey
The period ratioI presented in Table 10
suggest that large UK firms use more internal
and equity finance, with smaller firms using more
bonds, bank borrowings and trade credit. The
t-ratios presented in the same table show,
however, that only the differences in equity and
trade credit are statistically significant. The net
equity-investment
t-ratio indicates that large
firms use significantly more equity than smaller
firms, but the gross equity-finance t-ratio is only
T-test results for comparisons of annual finance ratios across firms
S4), ICICI data set, 1982-9p
p =
Sl vs s3
difference. Finally, firms in S2 use more trade
credits than larger firms, but there is no significant difference in any of the other comparisons.”
-2.27 (12)
0.0423
-4.05 (11)
p = 0.0019
-4.65 (7)
p = 0.0023
- 1.62 (14)
p = 0.1285
-3.26 (9)
p =
p = 0.0099
-2.23 (10)
p = 0.0499
in different
size groups (Sl,
S2, S3 and
Bank borrowings
Trade credit
-1.21 (11)
0.2523
-0.24 (10)
p = 0.8121
- 1.79 (11)
p = 0.1004
1.16 (8)
p = 0.2789
0.06 (9)
p = 0.9534
- 2.05 (14)
p = 0.0601
-0.47 (10)
p = 0.6492
0.86 (8)
p = 0.4141
1.48 (9)
p = 0.1732
2.28 (13)
p = 0.0399
3.18 (14)
p = 0.0066
1.19 (14)
p = 0.2543
p =
“Degrees of freedom are given in parentheses. A negative value for the c-ratio implies that the latter group of
firms in a pair (such as Sl vs S3) has a higher mean for the concerned ratio.
Table 10. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Period ratios of (gross) .sources to total sources of finance and (net) sources to phy sical investment for business monitor -
company finance -
data, United
5
Kingdom, 1982- 90
Large
Source
Finance
firms
Small firms
Investment
Finance
All firms
Investment
Finance
t-tests for large vs
small firms comparison”
0.49
0.61
0.34
0.64
0.44
0.62
1.09 (13)
p = 0.2951
Equity
0.12
0.10
0.06
- 0.02
0.10
21
Investment
Finance
Internal
[
0.07
Bonds
0.08
0.12
0.11
0.22
0.09
0.14
Bank borrowings
0.11
0.07
0.13
0.11
0.11
0.08
Trade credit
0.20
0.10
0.36
0.01
0.25
0.07
1.61 (14)
p = 0.1286
-0.23 (16)
p = 0.8195
-0.64 (14)
p = 0.5308
- 1.82 (16)
p = 0.0876
Investment
0.48 (18)
p = 0.6359
1.98 (11)
p = 0.0730
-0.91 (11)
p = 0.3810
-0.90 (12)
p = 0.3401
1.13 (10)
p = 0.2854
f
G
2
g
2
Q
2
8
2
Sample: 2000 largest industrial and commercial
“Degrees of freedom are given in parentheses.
concerned ratio.
companies;
A negative
1 in 300 other registered companies in the United Kingdom, randomly chosen (see Appendix
value for the t-ratio implies that the latter group of firms (small firms here) has a higher
A).
mean
for the
$
R
v1
1042
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
tions set out in Section 2 of the paper. These
results can be rationalized
only by recognizing
that the type of equity financing undertaken
by
the smaller Indian firms must be of a different
nature from that which implicitly underlies the
orthodox
economic
literature
on corporate
financing in developed countries. That literature
deals essentially with the case of an already-listed
firm choosing between issuing equity or bonds or
obtaining funds in some other way. But all of the
smaller, and many of the larger, firms in our
samples are likely to be unlisted firms.lJ In the
RBI sample, for example,
the mean paid-up
capital of a small firm is about Rs. 0.16 crores
and that of a large firm is about Rs. 0.84 crores,
which are well below the Rs. 3 crores requirement for listing.
(d) zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Discussion of the micro-data results
For these firms, most of the equity issued is
likely to be sold to existing owner/directors
of
The evidence
presented
in the last three
the firms or to members of their family networks,
subsections suggests that in the United Kingdom
rather than to unknown members of the public.15
large firms use equity finance more than small
In that case, the agency costs (increased
scope
firms, while the Indian samples of data show the
for managerial discretion) associated with equity
opposite.
To summarize
the results
of the
issues are minimal, and issuing equity does not
(admittedly
limited)
test we carried
out in
give an adverse signal: equity finance is therefore
Sections 4a and 4b: (i) large firms in the RBI
more attractive
to both the firms and their
sample seem to use more internal finance and
financiers.
bonds than smaller firms, while the latter report
At this point it is worth drawing attention to
higher bank loans and total borrowings than the
the only comparable
work on a developing
former;
(ii) there seems to be no significant
country, by Cho (1995) who collected data on
difference between the equity ratios; (iii) large
gross and net sources of finance for Korea. Cho
firms in the ICICI seem to use more internal
used three sets of data, covering respectively the
finance and bonds than smaller firms (three of
whole of the corporate sector (including governthe pair-wise comparisons
for internal ratios are
ment-owned
firms), the private manufacturing
statistically significant), while the latter make use
sector, and a sample of around 400 companies
of more trade credit; (iv) the smallest group of
which were listed on the stock exchange by the
firms seems to have a significantly higher ratio
end of the 1980s. Korea is a more extreme case
for equity financing than the largest group of
in Singh’s (1995) analysis, which reports 19.5%
firms.
of net asset growth as coming from internal
The UK findings and results (i) and (iii) for
finance, 30.9% from long term debt, and 49.6%
the Indian firms are, in broad terms at least,
from
equity finance. Cho found, however, that on
consistent
with theoretical
expectations:
larger
the Mayer-type methodology
equity finance was
firms have a higher average age and thus have
much
less
important:
12.8%
in
gross terms and
longer and better reputations
than smaller firms,
16.4% in net terms for the whole corporate
which enables
them to finance growth from
sector: 7.7% gross for the manufacturing
sector
greater retentions and to access the bond market
and 9.8% gross for the firm sample (for both of
more easily, at lower cost; smaller firms, on the
the latter a separate net term for equity is not
other hand, have a lower average age (and/or
available).
Moreover,
if Cho’s figures for the
they are growing faster) which reduces
their
latter two sets of data are compared with the low
ability to access the stock market for long term
internal finance countries referred to in Section 3
funds or to use retained profits (which are lower
above, Korea looks broadly similar to them
relative to their investment).
(though the similarity is less marked for the
Results (ii) and (iv) for the Indian firms, which
whole corporate sector). In addition, Cho is able
show either no significant difference between the
equity-finance
ratios (for the RBI firms) or a
to divide zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSR
his second and third sets of data so as
negative relationship
between size and equityto compare large and small firms, domestic and
finance ratios (for the ICICI firms), are not
export firms, heavy and light industry, and other
consistent, however. with the theoretical expectapairs. The main finding there is that large firms
marginally significant. The gross trade creditfinance t-ratio is significant, implying that small
firms use more of this source than large firms.
For bank borrowings and bonds, the differences
are not statistically significant.” The trade credit
difference
disappears
in net terms (last row in
Table lo), implying that smaller firms give, as
well as receive, more trade credit than larger
firms. The next section compares the evidence
from this data set with the results from the
Indian micro data sets and attempts to explore
the possible reasons for the difference between
the behavior of Indian firms and that of their UK
counterparts
in terms of the relative importance
they assign to the various sources of financing.
CORPORATE FINANCE IN DEVELOPING
use more internal finance and more bond finance
than small firms, but there is also some tendency
for small firms to use more equity finance. Thus
in a number of respects Cho’s findings for Korea
parallel our findings for India.16
5. CONCLUSIONS
In this paper we have presented sector and
firm-level data on the sources of finance for non
financial Indian firms, in an attempt to put the
Singh and Hamid (1992) and Singh (1995)
findings in context. Singh himself has argued that
his results reflect period and country specific
circumstances, rather than generic characteristics
of developing countries. While we find his
explanation attractive at the level of the firms
concerned, we think it is difficult to assess at this
point in time. Instead we have produced data for
India directly comparable to that most widely
used to analyze the financial systems of
developed countries. We have shown that Singh’s
methodology naturally finds a greater role for
equity finance than the Mayer type methodology,
and that the structure of corporate finance in
India is not that much different from what
economists
might expect, once the specific
characteristics of the economy are taken into
account. Indeed, we would suggest that, when
allowance is made for the lower rate of acquisition of financial assets by firms, India is broadly
comparable to those developed countries such as
France and Italy which have relatively small
stock markets (with little or no market for
corporate control), large sectors of medium and
small-sized companies, and a banking system
which lends substantial amounts to companies
but does not have very close ties with firms and
cannot exert the influence and control over them
typical of Japanese banks.”
COUNTRIES
1043
At the same time we have shown that Singh’s
results cannot be ascribed merely to sample
selection bias arising from the focus on the
largest firms, since the rest of the Indian
corporate sector issues large amounts of equity.
It is clear, however, that these equity issues are
undertaken in large part by non-listed firms and
in that case they do not have the same characteristics as the equity issues by large listed firms
which are the typical focus of analysis in the
corporate financing literature. Thus, the question
of the social gains from investment in the establishment and development
of formal stock
markets is rather more complex than some
writers have suggested. For large firms where the
ownership of capital is already dispersed, at least
in part (even if there are some large stable
shareholdings), so that information asymmetries
and agency costs are already and inevitably
substantial, and where at the same time the
capital needs of the firms are significant, then the
development and improvement of stock markets
may be beneficial in improving the supply of
finance. But for the mass of small and mediumsized firms which, because their ownership is not
dispersed,
benefit
from lower information
asymmetries and lower agency costs, it may be
better to encourage equity finance of the existing
form, that is, through informal networks of
family, friends and business contacts. If incentives are to be given for firms to obtain or
investors to provide equity finance, these incentives should apply to both sorts of firms. At the
very least, there should be no extra incentive to
firms to move from the second category to the
first, other than the increased need for capital as
firms expand. Before more definite policy conclusions are drawn, however, there is clearly a need
for a rigorous firm-level analysis of the financing
behavior of a representative sample of firms.
Such an attempt will be made in our future work.
NOTES
1. For example, Gertler (1988) reviews the literature
on the linkages between the financial system and the
real economy, including the impact of macroeconomic
policies. Sundararajan
(1987) finds that the high debtequity ratios in Korean firms in the 1960s and 1970s
weakened the effectiveness of interest rate policies.
2. For some countries,
data on less than 50 such
companies
were available,
and in some countries
a
shorter time period had to be used.
3. In practice
it may
increases
in own capital
be difficult
which arise
to distinguish
from valuation
changes
equity.
4.
from
Particularly
those
which
in countries
arise
from
new issues
where takeovers
of
are rare.
5. The net sources methodology
is also less vulnerable to the valuation problems that affect international
comparisons
of leverage (see, for example, Rajan and
Zingales, 1995).
6. More reliable data for these two countries can be
found in Cobham and Serre (1996) and Cobham et al.
(1996) who put forward the idea of a “Meditteranean”
model to characterize
these two countries.
but the
conclusions are unaltered.
1044
WORLD
DEVELOPMENT
7. We can also calculate ratios of the gross sources to
physical investment.
For cumulative
ratios such as the
gross average of the annual ratios (or period ratios),
the ratio of Total Gross Sources of Finance to Physical
Investment is all that is needed to calculate the Gross
Sources of Finance
to Investment
ratios, since the
latter are scaled up versions of the former, where the
scaling factor is the Total Finance to Physical Investment ratio. We have not therefore
presented
these
additional ratios here.
8. Let x and y be two variables. The (t-test) statistic
for testing the equality of the means of these two
variables, p1 = A, when the variances of x and y, err and
gY, are unknown and cr, # o,, is given by:
s, st
-+r rl1 41
The result is distributed as Student’s t with v degrees
of freedom, where v is given by the closest integer to
(&I,)’
-+1<+1
(&I$
9,+1
See Hoe1 (1984, pp. 140-161) for an introduction
explanation of the calculation of these tests.
and
9. The t-ratio in the last cell of the last column of
Table 7 suggests that there is a significant difference in
the ratio of total sources of finance to investment
between small and large firms. We can also test for
differences
in the ratios of each source (gross, in this
data set) to investment,
and this would yield different
results insofar as the year-to-year
movements
of total
sources and investment
are different. The results for
these tests (not reported
here) are broadly similar to
those in Table 7, except for the ratios of total borrowings to investment, which are not significantly different
between small and large firms.
10. These results are the opposite
of Singh and
Hamid’s
(1992) finding of a negative
relationship
between size and internal financing of growth. They
report that the smallest 25% of the firms financed
about half their growth through savings while for the
largest 25%’ of the firms the ratio was less than a third.
11. While the patterns
revealed
in the t-tests for
investment ratios are broadly similar to those for the
gross finance ratios discussed so far, there are some
differences:
in terms of internal
finance ratios, the
largest firms do not necessarily have a higher internal
finance to investment ratio than the smaller ones, and
in terms of equity financing, there is no significant size
difference across the firms (whereas for finance ratios,
the smallest firms had a higher mean ratio than the
largest firms). Also, the investment
t-ratios do not
reveal any consistent pattern in the proportion
of total
finances
invested by firms in the different
groups.
These investment
ratios are not presented
here since
they are not based on net sources of financing.
12. See Appendix A for a precise definition of period
ratios.
Period ratios are presented
here since the
sample size has remained
the same in the UK data,
whereas in the RBI and ICICI data sets, there have
been changes in the sample size across the years.
13. Singh and Whittingtons
(1968) study of UK
companies,
covering 1948-60, did not find any significant relationship
between
size and other corporate
characteristics.
A later study by Kumar (1984) on large
UK quoted
companies,
covering
1972-76,
found a
positive relationship
between size and long-term debt.
On differences
in equity financing,
see also Hughes
(1994) who examined the Business Monitor data used
here in more detail for 1987-89.
14. The rules for listing of securities of a company on
stock exchanges
laid down by the Department
of
Economic Affairs, Ministry of Finance of the Government of India, stipulate that the following criteria will
apply: (i) the minimum
issued capital of a company
shall be Rs. 3 crores. and (ii)
\ , the minimum oublic offer
of equity capital shall not be less than Rs. 1.8 crores. In
addition, the Securities Contracts
(Regulation)
Rules,
1957, have additional
restrictions
on the percentage
of
issued capital apportioned
for public offer, based on
whether a company is an established or a new one. On
this and other laws pertaining
to the regulation
of
capital issues, see “Capital Issues, SEBI and Listing” by
Chandratre
et ul. (1992).
15. Very broad estimates on the stock-holding
pattern
are
as
follows:
controlling
management/family:
25-30%;
institutions
(public sector inst&tion,
mutual
funds etc): 35-45s:
uublic (free tloat): 35-400/o. See
George (1994). In the unlisted small’ tirm case, the
family/management
fraction is likely to be substantially
higher,
because
there
are
no outside
(public)
shareholders.
16. Findings reported
by Sak (1995) on the various
sources
of external
finance
for Turkish
firms also
suggest that bank credit was a much more important
source of finance than equity.
17. India has had “lead bank” systems since the
1960s but these institutions
and the context in which
they operate
are very different
from those of the
Japanese main bank system (see Bhatt, 1994).
1045 zyxwvutsr
CORPORATE FINANCE IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
REFERENCES
Atje, R. and Jovanovic, B. (1993) Stock markets and
Kumar, M. S. (1984) Growth, Acquisition and Investdevelopment. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
European
Economic
Review
37,
ment. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
632- 640.
Mayer, C. (1988) New issues in corporate finance.
Atkin, M. and Glen, J. (1992) Comparing corporate
European Economic Review 32, 1167- 1189.
capital structures around the globe. The International
Mayer, C. (1990) Financial systems, corporate finance
Executive 34(5), 369- 387.
and economic development. In Asy mmetric InformaBhatt, V. (1994) The lead bank system in India. In The
tion, Corporate Finance and Investment, ed. R.
Japanese M ain Bank System: Its Relevance for
Hubbard. National Bureau of Economic Research,
Developing and Transfoming Economies, ed. M. Abki
Cambridge, MA.
and H. Patrick. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Mayer, C. (1994) Stock markets, financial institutions
Chandratre, K. R., Israni, S. D., Acharya, B. S. and
and corporate performance. In Capital M arkets and
Sethuraman, K. (1992) Capital Issues, SEBI and
Corporate Governance, ed. N. Dimsdale and M.
Prevezer. Clarendon Press, Oxford.
Listing with Guidelines, Clarifications, Circulars, Rules
etc. Bharat Publishing House. New Delhi.
Myers, S. (1984) The capital structure puzzle. Journal
of Finance 39, 575- 592.
Cho, Y.-D. (1995) FLancial ‘factors and corporate
Nagaraj, R. (1996) India’s capital market growth:
investment: A microeconomic analysis of Korean
Trends, explanations and evidence. Mimeo, Indira
manufacturing firms. D.Phil. thesis, University of
Gandhi
Institute
of Development
Research,
Oxford.
Bombay.
Cobham, D., Cosci, S. and Mattesini, F. (1996) The
Rajan, R. and Zingales, L. (1995) What do we know
Italian financial system: Neither bank-based nor
about capital structure? Some evidence from intermarket-based. Mimeo, University of St Andrews, St
national data. Journal of Finance 50, 1421- 1460.
Andrews, UK.
Reserve Bank of India (various years) Annual Reports.
Cobham, D. and Serre, J.-M. (1996) A characterization
Reserve Bank of India, New Dehli.
of the French financial system. Mimeo, University of
Reserve Bank of India (various years) Report on
St Andrews, St Andrews, UK.
Currency and Finance. Reserve Bank of India, New
Corbett, J. and Jenkinson, T. (1994) The financing of
Dehli.
industry, 1970-89: An international comparison.
Sak, G. (1995) Istanbul stock exchange and the
CEPR Discussion Paper no 958, CEPR, Oxford.
corporate sector: Reflections on the Turkish experiCorbett, J. and Jenkinson, T. (1997) How is investment
ence in financial liberalization.
In Economic
financed? A study of Germany, Japan, UK and US.
Research Forum for the Arab Countries, Iran and
Manchester School.
Turkey, Development of Financial M arkets in the
Fry, M. (1988) M oney, Interest and Bunking in
Arab Countries, Iran and Turkey, Cairo.
Economic Development. Johns Hopkins University
Samuel, C. (1996) The stockmarket as a source of
Press, Baltimore, MD.
finance: A comparison of U.S. and Indian firms.
Fry, M. (1995) M oney, Interest and Banking in
Policy Research Working Paper 1592, The World
Economic Development, 2nd edn. Johns Hopkins
Bank, Washington, DC.
University Press, Baltimore, UK.
Singh, A. (1995) Corporate financial patterns in indusGeorge, P. L. (1994) The Handbook of Emerging
trializing economies: A comparative international
M arkets: A County-by-Country Guide to the W orld’s
study. International Finance Corporation Technical
Fastest Growing Economies.
Probus Publishing,
Paper No. 2, IFC Washington, DC.
London.
Singh, A. and Hamid, J. (1992) Corporate financial
Gertler, M. (1988) Financial structure and aggregate
structures in developing countries. International
economic activity. Joumul of M oney, Credit and
Finance Corporation Technical Paper No.1, IFC,
Banking.
Washington, DC.
Hoel, P. G. (1984) Introduction to M athematical StatisSingh, A. and Whittington, G. (1968) Growth, Profitatics, 5th edn. John Wiley and Sons, New York.
bility and Valuation. Cambridge University Press,
Hughes, A. (1994) The “problems” of finance for
Cambridge, UK.
smaller businesses. In Capital M arkets and Corporate
Sundararaian. V. (1987) The debt-eauitv ratio of firms
Governance, ed. N. Dimsdale and M. Prevezer.
and the effectiveness of interest rate policy: Analysis
Clarendon Press, Oxford.
with a dynamic model of saving, investment, and
Industrial Credit and Investments Corporation, India
growth in Korea. International M onetary Fund Staff
(various years) Financial Performance, Companies
- ICICI portfolio. ICICI, New Dehli.
Papers 34(2), 261- 310.
II
I
I
*
,
1046
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
APPEN ‘DIX A
MACRO-LEVEL DATA FOR INDIA AND
does not add up to total physical investment, as
it should, most likely as a result of incomplete
FIRM-LEVEL SAMPLE DATA FOR INDIA
data. Therefore we defined a residual equal to
AND THE UNITED KINGDOM zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIH
investment - (internalfnet
bank
physical
finance+net
market finance).
The “other”
category in panel (b) of Table 5 refers to this
(a) Flow-of-funds data for India
residual source of finance. Of this ratio, 12.3% is
accounted for by the data reported in the Report
Data on internal finance and investment for
India are taken from National Accounts Statistics on Currency and Finance, and only 0.1% is not
reported for the whole period. For 1980-86,
and the data on the other sources of finance are
derived from a financial flows table in the
however, only 12.3% is reported and 21.4% is
not reported, and the corresponding figures for
Reserve Bank of Indias Report on Currency and
1987-92 are 12% reported and -18.2% not
Finance. The flow of funds table for India does
reported.
not provide data for equity and bond issues
The period ratios presented are given by:
separately, hence the gross figures reported in
the paper (Table 5) are for corporate securities
(equity+bonds = “market finance”) and the net
figures are for issues of corporate securities
minus acquisitions of all (corporate and public
where I : denotes the amount of finance of type
sector) securities.
The broad categories of financial claims j, say internal or equity, in year t (measured in
presented in the flow-of-funds tables are: (i) current prices of year t), Z, denotes total finance
in period t (that is, the sum of the different types
Currency; (ii) Deposits bank and other
deposits; (iii) Investments in all forms of securiof finance in each year) and P, denotes the price
ties; (iv) Loans and advances; (v) Small savings;
index in year t - here, the GDP deflator, with
(vi) Provident funds; (vii) Life funds; (viii)
1990 as the base year. For physical investment
Compulsory deposits; (ix) Trade credit/debt; (x) ratios, It was replaced by physical investment in
Foreign claims not elsewhere classified; and (xi) year t.
Other items not elsewhere classified. It should be
noted that for the Indian non-financial private
sector, both the sources and uses column in the
(b) Cumulative firm- level data
flow-of-funds tables were nil for categories (v),
(vi), (vii) and (viii). This could be a reason for
We use three different (published) sources of
the presence of large residuals in the data (see
cumulative
firm-level data. The Report on
Currency and Finance published by the Reserve
below).
Paid-up capital does not include forfeited
Bank of India (RBI) provides a database, with
the sample size varying over the years (upward
shares which are added to reserves and surplus.
Borrowings of the private non-financial sector
of 1650 firms), for two size-groups (large and
are from the organized as well as from the
small, based on the amount of paid-up capital).
unorganized
sectors. Trade dues and other
The cumulative balance sheet data presented in
the RBI reports cover a sample of varying sizes
current liabilities include: sundry credit, liabilities
to subsidiary and holding companies, interest on
from 1975 to 1976 until the latest available year,
loans and unclaimed dividends, deposits from
1990-91. The most recent Report on Currency
customers, agents etc., and others. Loans and
and Finance (1993- 94) actually provides cumulaadvances include loans to subsidiary companies,
tive balance sheet data for 1991-93, but only for
companies under the same group and holding
large companies. 1990-91 is the latest year for
companies.
which data for both small and large firms are
Net sources of finance are defined as follows:
available. The average number of large firms
bank finance = (sources of loans and advances
(each with a paid-up capital greater than Rs. 1
-uses
of loans and advances)+(sources
of crore) is 580, and the average number of small
currency and deposits -uses of currency and
firms (each with a paid-up capital greater than
deposits. Market finance and the “other”
Rs. 5 lakhs but less than Rs. 1 crore) is 1,300.
categories are obtained by netting out the uses
New firms get added to the sample each year.
from the corresponding sources. The sum of These data cover the main sources of finance for
these three and the internal sources, however,
firms, but do not cover the firms’ acquisitions of
CORPORATE FINANCE IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
1047
financial assets, so that only an approximation of size varies in each of these groups across the
the MCI gross sources presentation is possible.
years. The average numbers of firms in the
The
Industrial
Credit
and
Investments
groups are: 85 in Sl, 175 in S2, 90 in S3 and
Corporation
of India (ICICI)
maintains
a about 65 in S4. We utilize these data to study the
database on a sample of firms of various sizes relationship
between size and the relative
(based on gross fixed assets). We use these data
importance of each source of financing.
(taken from various issues of the report zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHG
Financial
In the United Kingdom, the Business M onitor
Pet$ormance of Companies, ICKY Portfolio) for
surveys (MA3) on Company Finance provide a
1980-92. This database provides all the balance
consistent source of data from our point of view
sheet information, in aggregative form, for a for 1982-90. The data are divided into two
sample of 417 firms for 1980-88 and 620 firms
strata: the large firms group is comprised of the
2,000 largest firms, and the small firms group is a
for 1988-92. The firms in this sample accounted
sample (just over 1,000 firms) consisting of 1 in
for about 45% of the total paid-up capital and
300 of all the other Great Britain registered
about 53% of the gross value added in the
companies
which file accounts selected at
Indian private corporate sector as a whole for
random. For large firms, size is measured using
1990-91. Like the RBI data set, however, the
capital employed, the cut-off being three million
ICICI data set does not allow us to calculate the
GB pounds or more. Capital employed is defined
net sources of financing. The cumulative balance
as the sum of all items which finance net assets
sheets of the ICICI data are also presented for
(such as shareholders’ interest, minority sharefour different size groups, based on gross fixed
holders’ interest), deferred taxation, long-term
assets at the end of each financial year, and for
loans (including debentures and mortgages) plus
profit and loss making firms separately. Firms
are classified into: Size 1 (Sl) - gross fixed bank loans and overdrafts, short-term loans and
indebtedness to directors and group members,
assets below Rs. 5 crores, Size 2 (S2) - gross
fixed assets between Rs. 5 crores and Rs. 20 less amounts due from group members. This
data set provides detailed information on both
crores, Size 3 (S3) - gross fixed assets between
sources and uses of funds, enabling us to
Rs. 20 crores and Rs. 50 crores and Size 4 (S4)
calculate net sources of funds for our analysis.
- gross fixed assets above Rs. 50 crores. The
average firm size in S4 is about 200 times as We present ratios for both gross and net sources.
large as the average firm size in Sl. The sample