Relational Contract Theory: Confirmations and Contradictions
Stefanos Mouzas and Keith Blois
University of Lancaster*
ABSTRACT
Scholarly work on contracts offers a valuable lens through which exchange relationships
among companies or individuals can be studied. Contracts may regulate business alliances,
strategic partnerships or collaborations among parties. The nature and form of contracts have
been investigated by a number of academic disciplines each of which has adopted a different
approach. Much of this work has been of a theoretical nature and it is often referred as
‘relational contract theory’. This paper considers two theoretical approaches to ‘relational
contracts’. The first theoretical approach to relational contracts is described as the ‘normsbased’ approach, while the second is that of a group of organizational economists and is often
referred as the ‘incomplete contracts’ approach. In comparison only a limited number of
empirical studies have been undertaken. This paper will set out the findings of these two
major streams of theoretical analysis of contracts and then contrast them with recent empirical
research into contracts described as ‘umbrella agreements’. The paper demonstrates that,
while the two theoretical streams of relational contract theory are not contradictory, there are
differences in their emphases and interpretations and that the results of empirical studies do
not always conform to those that might be expected as a result of these theoretical studies.
Keywords: Contracts; norms; relational contracts; umbrella agreements
INTRODUCTION
This paper critically examines some of the studies that contribute to our understanding of the
role of contracts in business relationships. Contracts are manifestations of legally enforceable
agreements and can be found in all sorts of business alliances, strategic partnerships or
collaborations (Heide and John, 1990; Roxenhall and Ghauri, 2004; Baker, Gibbons and
Murphy, 2008). Within a corporate world of exchange relationships, which is central to IMP
research work, understanding the nature and form of contractual arrangements is an important
issue. Such understanding allows us to look at the modes of governance that operate between
interrelated companies in business networks and, hence, to examine how contractual decisions
are reached and expressed.
The nature and form of contracts has been investigated by scholars from a number of
disciplines each of which has approached the matter in various ways and with different
emphasis (e.g. Blois, 2002; Schwartz and Scott, 2003; Harrison, 2004; Argyres and Mayer,
2007) and have provided a range of lenses through which to study exchange relationships.
Much of this work has been of a theoretical nature and it is often referred as ‘relational
contract theory’. As a theoretical movement, relational contract theory can be considered as
one attempt to take into account all the surrounding circumstances of relationships. In
*
Lancaster University Management School, Lancaster LA1 4YW, UK.
Tel: 01524-593908
E-mails: s.mouzas@lancaster.ac.uk; keith.blois@btinternet.com
2
contrast to this theoretical movement, only a limited number of empirical studies have been
undertaken.
This paper will set out the findings of two major streams of theoretical enquiry into the
analyses of contracts: a) the norms-based approach; and, b) the organizational economists’
study of incomplete contracts. It will compare these approaches with a number of empirical
studies that challenge some of the theoretical foundations of relational contracts. While these
two theoretical streams of studies are not contradictory, there are differences in their emphasis
and interpretation and that the results of empirical studies do not always conform to those that
might be expected as a result of these theoretical studies. It argues that there is a research gap
that is deeply rooted in the lack of attention to the significance of joint consent in contractual
relationships (Barnett, 1986) and that a consent-based understanding of contractual
obligations opens the door to new useful empirical insights.
The norms-based approach evolved out of the “Relational Contract Theory”1 developed by
Macneil (1974, 1975, 1985, 1987, 2001). Macneil is a law scholar who has challenged
lawyers’ traditional premise that all contracts are mere transactions. In particular he stressed
the role of norms in determining the manner in which commercial exchanges operate in
practice and introduced the concept that individual transactions lie on spectrum ranging from
‘discrete’ through to ‘relational’.
The organizational economists’ study of incomplete contracts recognizes that, absent vertical
integration, some form of contract is needed between a supplier and a customer. However,
such contracts will almost always be ‘incomplete’ because they contain some ‘third-party
unenforceable’ elements. Such elements are described by economists as the relational
elements of a contract and are those parts which help firms “circumnavigate difficulties in
formal contracting, i.e. contracting enforced by a third party, such as a court” (Baker et al.,
2002, p.40).
The ‘relational contracts’ analysed by economists do not map exactly onto the concept of
‘relationships’ as described in Macneil’s studies but they do have a common viewpoint which
is that all contracts contain a relational element. Macneil reaches this conclusion because he
asserts that even a ‘discrete exchange’ has relational elements as a contract exists within
society. Economists argue that, because it is almost impossible to write a contract which does
not include some elements which cannot be enforced by a third party, all contracts will
contain relational elements. Thus, both Macneil and economists agree that all exchanges are,
to some extent, relational.
Even though it is recognized that it is important to understand the nature and form of
contractual arrangements between firms there is a lack of empirically-based scholarly work
on this topic. This may be a result of an overemphasis on the existence of collaborative
relationships and social control mechanisms (Jap and Ganesan, 2000; Heide, Wathne and
Rokkan, 2007) for a critique see, e.g. Blois, 2003; and is a reflection of the observation that,
even where a written contract exists, frequently companies seek to avoid the use of legal
action against their suppliers and/or customers (Macaulay 1963, 2003; Smitka, 1994; Collins,
1999; Roxenhall and Ghauri, 2004). Yet, empirical investigations reveal the existence of
detailed contracts that firms use to manage their inter-firm relationships (Mayer and Argyres,
2004). Indeed, empirical research into manufacturer-retailer networks (Mouzas and Ford,
2006; Mouzas, 2006; Mouzas and Furmston, 2008) as well as into manufacturer-tomanufacturer relationships (Lacoste, 2008) shows that companies attempt to simplify and
1
Macneil has suggested (2000, p. 877) that the term Essential Contract Theory should be used rather
than Relational Contract Theory. However, this suggestion has not received support from other writers
on this topic.
3
facilitate the complex process of a business interaction by embracing a new form of contract
described as ‘umbrella agreements’.
It would seem that the manner in which elements of umbrella contracts are ‘worked out’ in
detail will, in part, be determined by the relational norms that are applicable to the situation
and Macneil’s work may provide helpful descriptions of the nature of these contractual
norms. On the other hand, organizational economists’ analyses of incomplete contracts seem
in places to reach different conclusions than the umbrella agreements approach. In particular
Mouzas (2006) has suggested that it is items such as prices and volumes that are “deferred for
the future” in umbrella agreements. In contrast, economists assume that both prices and
volumes are items that can be determined by third parties - in other words these two items
would not fall under the heading of a relational contract.
This paper argues that the specifics of relational contract theory arise from the function of a
contractual arrangement and not from fact that it is relational. The contract is per se
relational because it establishes a relation of recognition and respect among those who
decided to participate (Markovits, 2004). Based on a comparison of the two theoretical
streams inherent in the relational contracts theory and the empirical evidence regarding
umbrella agreements, the present paper suggests that there are three issues which need
consideration. First, what confirmations and contradictions that can be identified? Second,
can the apparent discrepancy between relational contract theory and empirical evidence of
umbrella agreements be explained? Third, what are the research implications?
THE PROBLEM OF PERSPECTIVE
Before reviewing the previous research and contrasting it with the empirical evidence, it is
important to bear in mind the inherent problems of using different perspectives. Thus,
although scholars may use the same terms (e.g. relational) the interpretation of the term may
differ between academic disciplines. In addition, when making a comparative analysis, we
need to understand how scholars’ ontological as well as methodological choices may vary in
terms of: a) underlying assumptions b) the purpose of the analysis c) the level of analysis that
is being used; and d) whether or not the analysis is static or dynamic (see Table I). In
comparison with other disciplines such as law or economics, business and in particular
marketing studies often (but not always, see, e.g. Sweeny, 1972) examine a transaction and/or
a relationship from the point of view of one party. Most typically the viewpoint adopted is
that of the supplier. It follows that, when comparing and/or making use of the findings of
scholars from different backgrounds, it is important to take account of the different
perspectives adopted by scholars from and within different disciplines.
Table I: The Problem of Divergent Perspectives
Ontological &
Methodological
Choices
Norms-Based
Approach
(Macneil)
Underlying Assumptions
Level of Analysis
Social Relations
matter
Explain Exchange
Behaviour
The Relationship
Incomplete
Contract Approach
(Organizational
Economists)
Transactions Costs
matter
Investigate Efficiency
of Governance Forms
The Exchange
Static vs. Dynamic
Modelling
Static
Modelling
Repeated Game
Modelling
Purpose of Analysis
Umbrella
Agreements
(Empirical Studies)
Joint Consent
matters
Explain repeated
exchanges
The Category
of Business
Dynamic
Interaction
4
As a law scholar, Macneil’s underlying assumption is that relationships matter and the prime
purpose seems to have been to challenge lawyers’ conceptualisation of contract (Macneil,
2001). Macneil therefore developed a contractual analysis that seeks to explain behaviours
within an exchange. To do this he: uses as his unit of analysis the relationship, taken as an
entity, between the contracting parties; and, examines relationships from a rather static
viewpoint focusing on behaviours to arrive at a set of ten common contractual norms. In
contrast, the underlying assumption of organizational economists is that transaction costs are
important (e.g. Klein, 1980; Tirole, 1999). Hence, the purpose of organizational economists’
analyses is to investigate the efficiency of different forms of governance. Indeed much of
their work explicitly considers what lay-people describe as the ‘make or buy problem’ (Klein
and Murphy, 1997). That is, why and how contracts within firms differ from those between
firms and the conditions, which make particular contractual forms the more efficient. As such
their level of analysis is the exchange and not the relationship or firm per se. For this reason,
organizational economists’ perspective often moves on to a higher aggregation, namely that
of society. In terms of the static/dynamic divide, their analysis is rather dynamic as it is most
frequently based in repeated game-theoretic models over time. In comparison to the two
theoretical approaches to relational contracts, the underlying assumption of empirical studies
regarding umbrella agreements is that joint consent matters. The implication of such a
consent-based view (Barnett, 1986) is that the contractual surplus, i.e. the joint gain, from the
exchange is maximized only if a contract involves an ‘actual meeting of minds’ (Kronman
and Posner, 1979). A deal that is not based on a genuine agreement is, therefore, not
sustainable. Over time, this ‘actual meeting of minds’ becomes, however, a rather enigmatic
task because of the prevalence of information asymmetries (Akerlof, 1970) and the
multiplicity of unforeseen contingencies (Maskin and Tirole, 1999). For this reason, the
purpose of the umbrella agreements’ analysis is to investigate repeated exchanges between
contracting parties. The level of analysis thus shifts towards the ‘category of business’ e.g.
product or service category and the modelling becomes dynamic as contracting parties
continuously interact with each other.
INTELLECTUAL ORIGINS AND PREVIOUS RESEARCH
Relational Contract Theory: The Norms-Based Approach
While there are many others, especially Macaulay (1963, 2003), who have made substantive
contributions to this school of thought, the norms-based approach to contract is most strongly
associated with the work of Macneil. The role of norms in determining the manner in which
commercial exchanges operate in practice has been central to Macneil’s work. A particularly
important aspect of his analysis is the setting out of the way in which the applicable common
contract norms alter depending upon where an exchange lies on the spectrum running from
discrete (which Macneil believes to be a theoretical construct) to relational exchange.
Macneil has argued that the manner in which contracts operate is determined by the
applicable common contract norms and his work has primarily been to develop a detailed
interpretation of the meanings of these norms. He, however, provides few insights into the
factors that determine where on the discrete/relational spectrum an exchange might be
expected to lie.
Building on the work of Macaulay (1963), Macneil developed a set of norms that determine
“the behavior that does occur in relations, must occur if relations are to continue, and hence
ought to occur so long as their continuance is valued” (Macneil, 1980, p. 64). Yet, given the
variety of forms of exchange which do exist it is necessary to consider how widely applicable
is Macneil’s theory. It is first necessary to determine what Macneil means by the term
‘contract’ which he defines as “no more and no less than the relations among parties to the
process of projecting exchange into the future” (1980, p. 4). This opinion is shared by other
5
legal scholars (e.g. Macaulay, 1963) and by scholars in other disciplines. Quite simply, in
Macneil’s view, where an exchange occurs a contract exists and therefore a contract is present
in all business to business exchanges. Indeed, Whitford suggests that “because Macneil sees
exchange occurring almost everywhere, his theory (viz. relational contract theory), becomes
in effect a general theory of the social order” (Whitford, 1985, p. 252). Furthermore, Macneil
recognizes that contracts vary widely in the depth of the relationship to which they are
applied. Thus, he states that “[n]evertheless, some contracts, called here ‘contractual
relations’ are far more relational than others. They lie towards one end of a relational
spectrum of contractual behaviour, opposite from the non-relational end where the discrete
transaction is found.” (Macneil, 1983, p.342).
Initially Macneil developed nine norms or principles “of right action binding upon the
members of a group and serving to guide, control, or regulate proper and acceptable
behaviour” (Macneil, 1980, p.38). He later (1983) developed a tenth and changed the label
applied to one of the original nine. He argues that these ten norms constitute an abstract
summary of the wide variety of specific norms that can be found in the many different forms
of contracts that do exist in a modern society.
These ten common contract norms are:
(1) Role integrity.
(2) Reciprocity.
(3) Implementation of planning.
(4) Effectuation of consent.
(5) Contractual solidarity.
(6) The linking norms: restitution; reliance; and expectation.
(7) Creation and restraint of power.
(8) Flexibility.
(9) Proprietary of means.
(10) Harmonization of the social matrix.
Macneil’s view is that the importance given to these common contract norms varies according
to where an interaction lies on the contractual spectrum ranging from relational to discrete
and indeed that some of these norms are transformed according to where they lie. To
emphasize this distorting effect Macneil introduces new terms. In the case of discrete
exchanges he suggests that two of the common norms, ‘implementation of planning’ and
‘effectuation of consent’ are greatly magnified and merged into a norm that he labels:
enhancing discreteness and presentiation. By creating this term he is seeking to emphasize
that an exchange can only be purely discrete if it is 100 per cent planned; 100 per cent
consented to; and “separated from all else between the participants at the same time and
before and after” (Macneil, 1980, p.60). He is however careful to add that even if much
diminished in importance, the other eight common norms are still present.
In the case of those exchanges that are more relational, he suggests that five norms have the
greatest significance. Two of these (role integrity and proprietary of means) are identical to
two of the common contractual norms. The other three are based on a combination of a
number of the other eight common norms. They are:
(1) Preservation of the relation. This norm is primarily an intensification and
expansion of the norms of contractual solidarity and flexibility.
(2) Harmonization of relational conflict. This norm is mainly a combination of
elements of the norms of flexibility and harmonization of the social matrix.
(3) Supra-contractual norm. This norm is mostly derived from the norm of
harmonization of the social matrix.
6
The essence of Macneil’s approach is perhaps well summarized by Kimel (a writer who is not
particularly sympathetic to Macneil’s views) who comments that empirical research has
identified “how parties to certain types of contract do not see the contract to which they are
party as a conclusive list of fixed rights and obligations, but rather as a starting point for renegotiation and adjustment when circumstances change or difficulties arise; parties in practice
not insisting on their contractual rights and not taking too seriously the option of litigation,
but rather exhibiting the ongoing willingness to make the necessary adjustments in order to
continue to co-operate” (2007, p.250). The extent and the nature of any ‘re-negotiation and
adjustment’ which occurs being determined by the norms established in that business context.
Although it has been commented that “we are all relationalists now” (Scott, 2000, p.852),
Macneil’s work is still subject to substantial challenges not least from practicing2 as well as
academic lawyers. ‘Relationalists’ are arguing that as long as contract theory fails to adopt a
relational paradigm “it is bound to remain out of touch with reality and riddled with fiction,
and thus fail to explain precisely what it sets out to explain” (Kimel, 2007, p.250). However,
some scholars (e.g. Bernstein, 1992) still reject the relationalists’ approach. Others, for
example Kimel (2007), argue that their acceptance that ‘relationalism’ exists does not mean
that they assume that traditional contracts have no value or role. Indeed, Kimel introduced
into his argument recognition of the fact that relationships do not suddenly ‘occur’ but
develop over time arguing that the continuing existence of traditional contract law is “What
often enables parties to contracts to develop co-operative relationships that go over and above
the bare terms of the contract – indeed, what often enable potentially3relational contracts to
develop into truly relational ones” (Kimel, 2007, p.247). Thus Kimel’s view is that legal
contracts of the traditional kind provide an essential background “in order for the potential
encapsulated in potentially relational contracts to be realised” (2007, p.254).
Relational Contract Theory: The Incomplete Contract Approach
In recent years an increasing number of organizational economists have been analysing the
wide variety of forms of governance which firms can be observed to utilize. This activity has
arisen in recognition of the fact that “[e]ven brief inspection of the existing governance
structures in industries such as pharmaceuticals, biotechnology, medical devices, airlines, and
telecommunications shows that firms have invented far more ways to work together than
organizational economics has so far expressed (not to mention evaluated)” (Baker et al.,
2008). There are two strands of this work which are pertinent to this paper. First, there have
been a substantial number of studies of incomplete contracts but the majority of these studies
have been entirely theoretical. Second, there have been several studies which have
investigated the conditions under which relational contracts, as compared with the ‘make’
solution, can be more efficient. Most of these studies have incorporated formal models.
Incomplete Contracts: Economists’ traditional approach to the ‘make or buy’ problem has
been to compare the efficiency of alternative forms of governance and to recognize that under
any form of governance, other than ‘make’, that a contract (though not necessarily a written
one) will exist between the two parties. It is accepted that while with regard to some elements
of an exchange, such as: price; quantities; payment terms; etc., it is possible for a contract to
be certain but that there are two reasons why “complete, fully contingent, costlessly
enforceable contracts are not possible” (Klein, 1980, p.356). First, a large number of possible
contingencies exist and it may be costly or impracticable to specify in advance responses to
2
See Baird Textile Holdings Limited and Marks & Spencer plc. (2001) para. 16 for a legal dispute
where senior English judges rejected an attempt to make use of a “relationalist” argument.
3
Italics in original.
7
all of them. Second, transaction costs such as: unforeseen contingencies; the cost of writing
contracts; the cost of enforcing contracts; and, the cost of renegotiating contracts (Tirole,
1986; 1999) may make it very expensive or effectively unfeasible to measure some types of
contractual performance. Examples are the quality of promotional activity undertaken by a
franchisee or the commitment of a supplier, which is being paid on a cost-plus basis, to keep
costs low. Third, information asymmetries exist (Akerlof, 1970).
However, some economists accept that “there is another possible remedy when contracts are
imperfect: leave the governance structure alone, but move to ‘relational contracting’”
(Gibbons, 2005, p. 236). A ‘relational contract’ being one which, while it contains some
elements which can be enforced by a third party, contains substantive elements where third
parties “are unable to verify whether contractual obligations have been met” (Brown et al.,
2004, p.747). Indeed, relational contracts often include informal agreements and are
frequently based upon unwritten codes of conduct. For economists the difficulty of relational
contracts is that they create a situation which is indeterminate in that it cannot be established
how the relational elements of the contract will, in the case of a dispute, be interpreted. So,
on the one hand the benefit of relational contracts is that they allow “the parties to utilize their
detailed knowledge of their specific situation and to adapt to new information as it becomes
available.” (Gibbons, 2005, p.236) but, on the other hand for the very same reasons, they
cannot be enforced by a third party. It is because of this that it has been observed that:
“Traders are very much concerned about the identity of their trading partners if third party
enforcement is ruled out” (Brown et al., 2004, p.748).
Economists contend is that relational contracts are, within limits, ‘self-enforcing’ because
both parties have an incentive not renege for, as Levin commented: “reneging would bias
future trade terms against the deviator or even end the relationship” (2003, p.836). In
addition any transactor who reneges would suffer from a loss of reputation and it has been
argued that the value of each transactor’s reputation can be thought of as delineating what
Klein and Nevin call “the self-enforcing range of the contractual relationship” (Klein &
Nevin, 1997, p.417). Klein and Nevin (1997) suggest that a supplier will give a high level of
service if the difference between the expected discounted profit that they could earn from
supplying a low level of service and the expected discounted profit that could be earned from
supplying a high level of service is less than the value of the damage that could be done to the
supplier’s reputation by a dissatisfied customer. These two profit levels, associated with
differing levels of service, thus define the extent of “the self-enforcing range” and indicate the
amount that market conditions can change without occasioning non-performance. This
indicates that, as long as market conditions leave the transactor operating in manner which
enables them to achieve a level of profit within this range, the contract will be selfenforceable.
The ‘efficiency’ of alternative forms of governance: There is a change in tone when
Economists switch from discussing why relational contracts arise and what they typically
cover to determining their impact on the efficiency of different forms of governance. These
studies rely heavily on the Transaction Cost Analysis to investigate the forms of
governance categorized as ‘hybrids’ by Williamson (1985). Formal models are used to
analyse the efficiency issue and this requires the setting out of, usually rigorous, assumptions
so that mathematical analyses can be used. For example, states that his main assumptions are:
“that parties are risk neutral, that they have symmetric information, that they do not
renegotiate contracts, that all variables are contractible, but that writing contract involves
costs that rise with the number of contractual terms” (2006, p.290). Economists’ analyses
thus provide a series of results which are tightly constrained by their assumptions and which,
as Shavell, commented require that their conclusions “be applied with caution to the actual
world of contracts and judicial practice” (2006, p.292, fn.5).
8
It is not therefore easy to make clear concise statements about the relative efficiency of
relational contracts. A case in point being Baker et al. who conclude: “The preceding section
characterized upstream actions and total surplus under four alternative governance structures.
In a given environment, the efficient organizational form maximizes the total surplus. For
some parameter values, relational employment will be the efficient organizational form; for
others, relational outsourcing will dominate; for still other parameters, neither relational
outsourcing nor employment will be feasible and spot outsourcing or spot employment will
dominate” (2002, p.58). Yet, one senses that several of the investigators feel that relational
contracts are, in those cases where ‘make’ is not the preferred option, overall beneficial. Thus
they often use terms other than ‘efficiency’ to describe the benefits of relational contracting
and they make comments such as: “relational contracts can encourage useful4 actions” (Baker
et al., 2002, p.41); “[w]e also show that the seeds for a successful4 long-term relation are
planted at the very beginning of the relationship” (Brown et al., 2004, p.748); Gibbons
comments that Klein’s studies “emphasize that successful4 transactions between3 firms often
achieve adaptation by using relationships” (2005, p.209); “The literature on vertical supply
contracting suggests that adaptability4 is a key feature of successful long-tem relationships”
(Levin, 2003, p.837); and, that: “it is not surprising that that relational contracts can1 help
parties remedy imperfect formal contracts -a theoretical statement-” (Gibbons, 2005, p.237)
Indeed, given Shavell’s argument that: “the interpretation of contracts is in the interest of
contracting parties” (2006, p.289) particularly because this will improve otherwise imperfect
contracts, there would seem to be an acceptance that relational contracting is not without
benefits.
There is also in these economists’ comments a presumption that long-term relationships bring
benefits over short-term ones. This becomes evident in the discussion of the factors which
may discourage reneging where great emphasis is placed on the need to recognize the risks
associate with reneging. Indeed Brown et al. argue that “[t]he parties can create higher gains
from trade due to relation-specific investments if they stay together than if they separate”
(2004, p.749).
Thus, economists use the word ‘relational’ in a specific manner. The implication is that it
refers to situations where there is an expectancy that both parties will benefit from its
continuance. This position does not make any presumption about the need for commitment
and trust to exist between the parties and is no more than a rational calculation of cost
minimizing and benefit maximising. In other words it assumes that the prime interest of a
firm is the creation of value for itself and that the co-operation needed to create an exchange
“does not require commitment to the goal of the other party and indeed may, within
prudential limits, be inimical to it” (Campbell and Harris, 1993, p.181).
THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Empirical research into manufacturer-retailer networks shows that companies attempt to
simplify and facilitate the complex process of a business interaction by embracing a new form
of contract known as ‘umbrella agreements’ (Mouzas, 2006; Mouzas and Ford, 2006; Mouzas
and Furmston, 2008)5 whose nature and form constitutes a paradigm shift. Firms arrange
umbrella agreements to achieve improved interaction with each other and thus retreat from
4
5
Italics added.
These studies are based on empirical investigations of contemporary contractual arrangements in the
United Kingdom and Germany. The investigations comprise umbrella agreements between firms such
as fast-moving consumer goods companies, pharmaceutical companies, service providers and grocery
retailer completed during the years 2002-2006.
9
inflexible contractual arrangements. Because umbrella agreements are contracts that define
established rules and principles that can be used in all future agreements they create a
framework for continuing negotiation and exchange, companies are thereby better able to
maximise their joint gains. Umbrella agreements are not concerned with immediate
contractual decisions and are in fact ‘framework contracts’ that provide a set of clauses which
regulate the conclusion of future contracts. For this reason, umbrella agreements are contracts
that do not predetermine future selection processes. Instead, they create the framework within
which future selection processes may take place (Crone, 1993). This does not imply that
umbrella agreements are necessarily long-term business contracts. What differentiates
umbrella agreements from other contractual agreements is, therefore, not the time horizon of
the contractual arrangement but its function; and the function of an umbrella agreement is to
supply clauses that can be used in a defined set of transactions.
The parties to an umbrella agreement are usually not required to specify new terms in their
future transactions nor are they required to refer to the pre-existence of an umbrella
agreement. The advantage for buyers is that if they need a particular product or service, they
only need to specify the quantity and price or arrange continuous stock replenishment. It
must be emphasized that the buyer has no obligation to buy a specified amount of goods or to
accept future offers. However, the buyer (e.g. a grocery retail chain) may agree with the
seller (e.g. a manufacturer) that successive orders will be met. The advantage for sellers is
that they gain a source of incremental business and that they only need to deliver according to
the needs of their customers. For this reason, umbrella agreements are often encountered in
regular, stable and established business relationships such as manufacturer-retailer
relationships, manufacturer-supplier relationships, agency relationships (e.g. service providers
in banking, consulting, technology or advertising) as well as in business-to-business cooperations, strategic partnerships and alliances (Mouzas and Furmston, 2008). In these
established relationships, contracting parties acknowledge and recognize their
interdependence and seek to articulate the basic norms that could pave the way toward a
jointly decided action. This effort to create a framework requires multiple levels of
managerial interface and inter-firm negotiation. The managerial interface between
manufacturers and retailers, for example, involves key account management, purchasing or
category management, while inter-firm negotiations are usually conducted in the shape of
institutionalized forms of repeated annual trade negotiations.
In drafting umbrella agreements, purchasing managers and key account managers draw on the
expertise of other experts or staff departments, such as the legal, marketing or production
departments. Termination clauses or exit scenarios are usually inserted as pre-packaged
‘boilerplates’ carefully drafted with the help of corporate lawyers (Christou, 2002).
Theoretically, in regular and established business relationships, contracting parties are driven
by the common objective to maintain and develop their existing exchange relationship. In this
way, both parties recognize the value of their business relationship and acknowledge their
determination to create joint gains through repeated exchanges. In reality, however, umbrella
agreements do not constitute any obligation to buy or sell anything. For example, during the
annual negotiations of umbrella agreements between manufacturers and retailers, contracting
parties may agree on the listing of products or services e.g. shelf space and on the umbrella
terms e.g. trade allowances which are the fees to obtain distribution (Sullivan, 1997; VillasBoas and Zhao, 2005). Subsequent orders (future contracts), however, will be determined by
the consumer demand expressed as consumer off-takes. Of course, manufacturers may
underwrite heavy media advertising and intensive promotional spending at the point of sale
for favourable shelf space and thereby pay less in trade allowances. But even expensive
consumer advertising and promotion activities cannot fully guarantee consumer off-takes
(sales to final consumers) and thus they cannot secure subsequent orders (future contracts).
10
Table II: Umbrella Agreement as a Framework of Agreed Norms
Type of Contract Norm
Product/Service Category
Examples of Umbrella Clauses
Laundry and Cleaning Products
Property Rights
Supplier ensures that no third person has obtained property
rights
Parties have the right to obtain competitive offers at any time
It is agreed to establish an Electronic Data Interchange
Mutual notification regarding all future capital investment and
R&D
All information exchanged is confidential and shall not to be
available to third parties without written consent of the other
party
Subcontracting is only possible upon consent
The obligation to remedy deficiencies applies also to services
obtained from subcontractors
Parties bear no liability for damages occurred as a result of
war, political unrest, strikes, lockouts, and governmental
Interventions
Annual Renegotiation/ Quarterly Business Reviews
Payment in 30 days; delivery cost is paid by the supplier.
Each party has the right to terminate the agreement giving one
year’s prior notice
Volume and Prices to be agreed / Unilateral price
determination
Unless it is of major importance, invalidity of one or more
clauses will not have any effect on the agreement as a whole
International Chapter of Commerce
Indefinite Agreement/ Annual Agreement
London
Exclusivity
Information Flow
Notification Requirements
Confidentiality
Subcontracting
Liability
Force Majeure
Renegotiation
Terms of Payment
Termination Rights
Volume / Prices
Saving Clause
Arbitration/ Mediation
Duration
Legal Venue
Umbrella clauses between firms usually start with the description of the scope of business by
defining product categories or the range of services exchanged (see Table II). Then they move
on to circumscribe a framework of norms such as property rights, exclusivity issues,
information flow, notification requirements, confidentiality, renegotiation, terms of payment,
as well as termination rights according to which voluntary and informed exchange may take
place.
As umbrella agreements usually do not specify prices or volumes, the conclusion of further
specific contracts is always made under the aegis of the pre-agreed umbrella clauses which
guide the conclusion of further contracts. For example, contracting parties in manufacturerretailer networks might agree to appoint a manufacturer as ‘category captain’ which is
equivalent to the status of ‘preferred supplier’ in other industries. According such an umbrella
agreement, the retailer will work exclusively with the appointed manufacturer (category
captain) in optimizing the planograms of the retailer’s shelf space which display the allocation
of shelf space. In a similar way, contracting parties may draft an umbrella agreement for the
exclusive production and distribution of own labels (retailer brands). In this case, the
consumer goods manufacturer will produce the retailer’s own labels, and the umbrella
agreement will specify all relevant norms that regulate future business. The umbrella
agreement, however, will not specify any volumes or prices as these are variables to be agreed
in the future. Therefore, the primary concern of umbrella agreements is not with immediate
contracts or with concrete transactions but rather with contract rules that guide the creation of
11
joint gains. This function of umbrella agreements contributes to the achievement of joint
consent over time. By not predetermining any prices and volumes, umbrella agreements cope
with the existence of barriers to a final and complete agreement, such as unforeseen
contingencies or asymmetries of information between the contracting parties. Empirical
evidence, suggests that contractual arrangements that are not based on a genuine consent are
usually not sustainable over time because they fail to maximize the value that can be created
through potential exchange processes (Kronman and Posner, 1979; Sebenius, 1992). In
contrast, umbrella agreements allow the re-adjustment of joint consent over time in such a
way that the contractual surplus, i.e. the value created from the exchange, is maximized,
though the maximization of value creation does not imply anything about how value is being
appropriated by the contracting parties (Lepak, Smith and Taylor, 2007).
Because consent matters, contracting parties in umbrella agreements regard the exchange of
information as a major step toward managing the increasing data flow from the consumer’s
decision, up to merchandising and production planning. Such information exchange tightens
the connectivity between retailers and manufacturers and contributes to a reduction in
handling and administrative costs. Some business contracts especially those that require
substantial capital investments e.g. in the construction industry might include a number of
immediate contractual decisions leaving some of the terms open. In these particular cases, it
seems to be more appropriate to view the agreed contracts as open-terms agreements (Gergen,
1992). Contracting parties with a strong bargaining position may include umbrella clauses
that confer powers to them to determine prices unilaterally. Similarly, in asymmetric
relationships contracting parties with strong bargaining power may insert umbrella clauses
that restrict the retailers’ ability to revoke orders after manufacturers’ production start
(Mouzas and Ford, 2007). The empirical evidence shows that some umbrella agreements may
restrict or confer powers on parties to vary their initial position or renegotiate some of their
own duties. For example, umbrella agreements may confer discretionary powers on retailers
to have a continuous stock replenishment according to consumer off-takes or discretionary
powers to manufacturers to deliver according to a Vendor Managed Inventory system.
Furthermore, umbrella agreements between contracting parties show a variety of notification
and termination procedures. In established and continuing business relationships, umbrella
agreements may include, for example, that the agreement is indefinite or that unless otherwise
agreed, the cooperation between the parties is terminated at the end of a calendar year, giving
one year’s prior notice.
CONTRASTING THEORY AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Both streams of relational contract theory provide an interesting contribution to an academic
discussion of the nature of contractual relationships and provide a number of conceptual tools
that have been adopted and used in management studies (Dwyer, Schurr and Oh, 1987; Poppo
and Zenger, 2002; Harrison, 2004; Taylor and Plambeck, 2007). The norms-based approach
to relational contracts provides a panoply of important relational norms and demonstrates the
embeddedness of contractual parties in continuing exchange relationships. Similarly,
organizational economists’ incomplete contract approach provides elegant mathematical
models of repeated interactions and sheds significant light on governance forms. There are,
indeed, clear indications that these two approaches are converging (Poppo and Zenger, 2002).
For example, the economists’ observation that ‘relational contracts’ may include informal
agreements based upon unwritten codes of conduct leads to the question of whether or not
such unwritten codes are the same as norms? Before moving on to contrast these theoretical
insights and the available empirical evidence, is worth examining some inherent
contradictions and problems.
12
The norms-based approach to relational contracts has been criticised for over-emphasizing the
importance of contextual variables and thus is considered less relevant to practice (Schanze,
1991; Eisenberg, 2002; McKendrick, 2002). One reason for this is that relational contracts
are not recognized as legal categories in common law countries such as USA, Australia or
England (e.g. see Endnote 2; Schwartz, 1992; Eisenberg, 2002). In civil law jurisdictions,
such as those encountered in continental Europe, some types of ‘relational’ contracts
recognize the legal term ‘Dauerschuldverhaeltnisse’ (long-term contractual obligations). Such
long-term contractual obligations include tenancy and leasing agreements, licence
agreements, distribution agreements as well as management or knowledge transfer
agreements. These long-term agreements require that contracting parties show mutual respect
to their counterparts’ interests, especially with regard to the principle of good faith (Flohr and
Klapperich, 2002). However, the “length of time during which performance is likely to
occur should not be regarded as significant for the purpose of the analysis of contractual
relationships” (Collins, 1999: p.142). For this reason, courts in common law countries, such
as United Kingdom, argue that the ‘length of time’ during which performance has occurred
does not by itself create an implied contract between the parties. If, for example, two parties
had chosen to work together for decades without any written agreement, the ‘length of time’
of their co-operation would not be regarded as significant factor by the courts. The well
known case of Baird versus Marks & Spencer6 illustrates this (Blois, 2003; Harrisson, 2004;
Mellahi, Jackson and Sparks, 2002; Mouzas and Furmston, 2008). Despite the valuable
contribution of the norms-based approach to relational contracts in challenging the premise
that all relationships are merely transactions, it can be posited that all relationships have
discrete and relational components (Blois, 2002) and that a relationship hides behind even the
simplest discrete transaction. For this reason, Eisenberg (2002) emphasized the inadequacy
of relational contract theory by making the cogent argument that all general principles of
contracts should be responsive to both relational and discrete relationships. In a similar way,
McKendrick (2002) rejects the claim for relational transactions being a separate category and
suggests that it is largely left to the related parties to include in their contracts clauses such as:
‘force majeure’; ‘hardship’; or ‘third-party intervener’ clauses which deal with particular
contextual eventualities. While this critique of relational contract theory reminds us that the
specifics of a relational contract derive from the particular function of the contractual
arrangement and not from the fact that a contract is relational, it must be noted that a contract
per se is relational as it establishes a relation of recognition and respect among those who
participate (Markovits, 2004).
The organizational economists’ incomplete contract approach to relational contracts avoids
the above critique because it shifts the unit of analysis from the relationship to the exchange.
The economists’ underlying assumption that transaction costs matter along with their analysis
of governance forms in terms of the ‘make or buy’ decision postulate alternative forms for
conducting transactions: markets and hierarchies. These alternatives provide a simple but
strong contingency model for investigating the governance structures under which
organisations can most efficiently conduct transactions. The problem with these alternatives
is that they do not contribute conceptually to the identification of any distinctive properties of
contractual relationships (Collins, 2005). Transaction cost analysis is useful but it has a
number of intrinsic weaknesses that make it problematic for the purpose of researching
contracts. First, the transaction cost by itself is not adequate for exploring the process of
contracting and therefore, because it is limited to efficiency as the dominant motivation
behind a firm’s transactions, it is not sufficient for explaining complex inter-firm exchanges.
Secondly, the underlying assumption that transaction costs are important neglects other
6
See Baird v. Marks & Spencer plc, [2001]. It can be argued that the relationship between the two
parties was asymmetrical. Marks & Spencer deliberately avoided a long-term commitment and Baird
deliberately avoided exercising pressure for a contractual commitment.
13
human and socio-cultural aspects of business relationships. The critique of transaction cost
theories is now well rehearsed (Ghoshal and Moran, 1996).
The use of repeated game modelling where, although the output from one analysis is the input
for the next one, is not a dynamic analysis but is a form of repeated and deterministic
analysis. This explains the contradiction between the economists’ results and the studies of
umbrella agreements for under an umbrella agreement future behaviours while strongly
influenced by previous events are not predetermined by them. This means that while the
economists’ analyses would assume that both prices and volumes are items that can be
determined by third parties - in other words these two items would not fall under the heading
of a relational contract. Whereas these items are “deferred for the future” Mouzas (2006) in
umbrella agreements, are not certain and cannot be contractually specified.
It appears that that the manner in which incomplete contracts are ‘worked out’ in detail will,
in part, be determined by implicit or explicit relational norms that are applicable to the
particular situations or contexts, e.g. industry standards or common use. Although Macneil’s
work provides helpful descriptions of the nature of these contractual norms, organizational
economists do not make use of the Macneil’s taxonomy of contract norms. Notwithstanding
the significant scholarly work on the importance of conventions and norms (Buchanan, 1975,
1978; Young, 1993) work on contracts has paid less attention to the relevance of contract
norms for the contracting process.
As a result of the implicit norms in common usage, a variety of forms of contract between
individuals as well as between firms have evolved over time. Norms are important because
they create a structure for business interaction and guide the conclusion of exchanges (Nee,
1998). Without the existence of norms, contracting parties would face tremendous difficulties
when interacting with each other and, thereby, the possibility of exchange would be severely
constrained (Casson, 1982; Choi, 1993; Loasby, 2000). In this respect, the empirical
evidence of the use of umbrella agreements draws attention to two intriguing aspects. Firstly,
umbrella agreements as new contract forms transform implicit norms, which are embedded in
customs and business practices into explicit, basic rules and principles for business interaction
(Mouzas, 2006; Mouzas and Ford 2006). Umbrella agreements are therefore contractual
manifestations which codify the parties’ knowledge about efficient ways to interact and,
hence, become “knowledge repositories” (Mayer and Argyres, 2004, p.405). The empirical
evidence that the primary concern of umbrella agreements is with the exchange of
information between contracting parties is supported by studies of strategic alliance contracts
that demonstrate that repeated exchange among firms forming alliances deepens inter-partner
communication and leads to a tacit development of contractual provisions for troubleshooting
(Reuer and Arino, 2007). Secondly, the function of an umbrella agreement is not to
predetermine contractual decisions but to provide an agreed framework in which contractual
decisions can be made. This functional particularity is crucial for understanding how
contracting parties deal with barriers to complete and final contract and how they arrive to a
joint consent. One of the enduring puzzles in understanding contract problems refers to the
question why there is ever disagreement? For example, contracting parties may have a)
divergent expectations, b) they may hold asymmetric information, c) they may be uncertain
about the structure of their interaction with others or whether a deal is possible and d) they
might have locked themselves in other irreversible commitments (Farber and Bazerman,
1987). Scholarly work on contracts has rather obscured the difference between contractual
decisions and the framework in which contractual decisions are made (compare e.g. Macneil,
1987b).
14
CONCLUSIONS
There is a degree of convergence in the approaches of law scholars and of economists to the
issues of relational contracting. However, the extent of this convergence must not, as it easily
can be, exaggerated because although scholars in these separate disciplines often use similar
or identical terms there are fundamental differences in their assumptions regarding levels of
analysis, etc. In part the convergence that has occurred has arisen in response to the implicit
challenge of the observation that: “reasonably clever businessmen and lawyers cope with
problems scholars might consider intractable” (Goldberg and Erikson, 1987, p.369). The use
of umbrella agreements is one example of the way in which managers have sought to find
solutions to the difficulties they encounter in managing their interactions with other
organizations. On the one hand is their reluctance to rely on contract law with its costliness
and especially, when disputes arise, its adversarial nature but on the other hand their desire for
a degree of certainty as to the consequences of any predictable behaviour by those
organizations with whom they interact.
These conclusions are in line with recent studies in the USA that demonstrate the capability of
firms to learn how to sustain repeated exchanges through contractual arrangements (Schwartz
and Scott, 2007; Argyres and Mayer, 2007; Argyres, Bercovitz and Mayer, 2007). For many
companies, the need to sustain repeated exchanges through various contract forms is
increasingly important because a great deal of their business activity appears to be occurring
via strategic partnerships, alliances or other forms of inter-organizational arrangements that
are regulated through contracts (Reuer and Arino, 2007); yet there has been relatively little
study of these contract forms in their real life context. Umbrella agreements as new
contractual forms build upon bases of consent that pre-exist as norms or common practice and
transform them into an applicable framework for managing business relationships (Mouzas
and Ford, 2006). Joint consent is a significant aspect that deserves more research attention; A
consent-based understanding of contractual obligations (Barnett, 1986) may stimulate further
empirical work that delivers new insights about how actors manage their interactions with
their counterparts. Understanding the role of joint consent in contractual arrangements
requires a fundamental insight into the significance of property rights or entitlements which
specify the substance of rights that actors may possess, acquire or transfer in their interactions
with other actors (Coase, 1960, Demsetz 1966). The importance of joint consent draws
attention to the significance of inter-cognitive articulation as well as its manifestation in
contract provisions. Further empirical work should be responsive to the recent calls for more
attention to the specific provisions that managers incorporate into contracts (Poppo and
Zenger, 2002; Reuer and 2007; Furlotti, 2007) rather than adopting a theoretical norms-based
or incomplete contract approach.
When conducting further empirical work on business contracts, it is important to be clear
about our ontological and methodological choices. Also, it is necessary to be cautious about
the underlying assumptions, the level and purpose of analysis, as well as with the choice of
model. This study demonstrates the inherent problems of using divergent perspectives in
contract research. The confirmations and contradictions of the two major streams of
theoretical analysis of contracts as well as their contrast with the recent empirical research
has, hopefully, provided a platform for the study of contemporary contract forms.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, G. (1970) “The market for lemons: Qualitative uncertainty and the market
mechanism”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol 84 No 3, pp. 488-501.
Argyres, N. and Mayer, K.J. (2007) “Contract design as a firm capability: An Integration of
learning and transaction cost perspectives”, Academy of Management Review, Vol
32 No 4, pp. 1060–1077.
15
Argyres, N., Bercovitz, J. and Mayer K.J. (2007) “Complementarity and Evolution of
Contractual Provisions: An Empirical Study of IT Services Contracts”, Organization
Science, Vol 18 No 1, pp. 3-19.
Baird Textile Holdings Limited and Marks & Spencer plc. (2001) EWCA CIV 274 (Court of
Appeal [Civil] Division).
Baker, G., Gibbons, R. and Murphy K.J. (2008) “Strategic Alliances: Bridges Between
‘Islands of Conscious Power’ ”. Forthcoming in Journal of the Japanese and
International Economies.
Baker, G., Gibbons, R. and Murphy, K.J. (2002) “Relational contracts and the theory of the
firm”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol 117 No 1, pp.39-84.
Barnett, R.E. (1986) ‘A Consent Theory of Contract’, Columbia Law Review, Vol 86 No 2,
pp. 269-321.
Bazerman, M.H. and Gillespie, J.J. (1999) “Betting on the future: The Virtues of Contingent
Contracts”, Harvard Business Review, Vol 77 No 7, pp.155-161.
Bernstein, L. (1992) “Opting out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual
Relations in the Diamond Industry”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol 21, pp.
115- 157.
Blois, K. (2002) “Business to Business Exchanges: A Rich Descriptive Apparatus
Derived From Macneil’s and Menger’s Analyses”. Journal of Management
Studies, Vol 39 No 4, pp. 523-551
Blois, K. (2003) “B2B “relationships”: A Social Construction of Reality? A Study of Marks
and Spencer and one of its major suppliers”, Marketing Theory, Vol 3 No 1, pp. 7995.
Brown, M., Falk, A. and Fehr, E. (2004) “Relational Contracts and the Nature of Market
Transactions”, Econometrica, Vol 72 No 3, pp.747-780.
Buchanan, J.M. (1975) ‘A Contractarian Paradigm for Applying Economic Theory’,
American Economic Review, Vol 65 No 2, pp. 225-230.
Campbell, D. and Harris, D. (1993) ‘Flexibility in Long-term Contractual Relationships: The
Role of Cooperation’, Journal of Law and Society, Vol 20 No 2, pp. 166-191.
Casson, M. (1982) The entrepreneur: An economic theory. Martin Robertson: Oxford.
Choi, Y.B. (1993) Paradigms and conventions: Uncertainty, decision-making and
entrepreneurship. University of Michigan Press: Ann Arbor.
Christou, R. (2002) Boilerplate Clauses: Practical Issues, Sweet and Maxwell: London.
Coase, R. (1960) “The Problem of Social Cost”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol 3,
pp.1-44
Collins, H. (1999) Regulating Contracts, Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Collins, H. (2005) “The weakest Link: Legal Aspects of Network Architecture of Supply
Chains”, International Conference: Contractual Networks: Legal Issues of
Multilateral Cooperation. Paper Fribourg (Switzerland).
Crone, von H. (1993) Rahmenverträge.Vertragsrecht-Systemtheorie-Oekonomie.
Schulthess Polygraphischer Verlag: Zürich.
Demsetz, H. (1966) “Some Aspects of Property Rights”, Journal of Law and Economics,
Vol 9, pp.61-70.
Eisenberg, M.A. (2002). “Relational Contracts”, in Beatson, J. and Friedmann, D. (Eds.),
Good Faith and Fault in Contract law, Clarendon Press: Oxford, pp. 291-304.
Flohr, E and Klapperich, J. (2003) Dauerschuldverhaeltnisse nach der Schuldreform
Verlag fuer Rechts-und Anwaltspraxis: Duesseldorf.
Furlotti, M. (2007) “There is more to contracts than incompleteness: a review and assessment
of empirical research on inter-firm contract design”, Journal of Managerial
Governance, Vol 11, pp.61–99.
Ghoshal S. and Moran P. (1996) “Bad for Practice: A Critique of the Transaction Cost
Theory”, Academy of Management Review, Vol 21 No 1, pp. 13-47.
Gibbons, R. (2005) “Four formal(izable) theories of the firm?” Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, Vol 58, pp. 200-245.
16
Goldberg, V. and Erikson, J. (1987) “Quantity and price adjustment in long-term contracts”
Journal of Law and Economics, Vol 30, pp.369-398.
Harrison, D. (2004) “Is a Long-term Relationship an Implied Contract? Two Views of
Relationship Disengagement”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol 41 No 1, 107125.
Heide, J.B. and John, G. (1990) “Alliances in Industrial Purchasing: The Determinants of
Joint Action in Buyer- Supplier Relationships”, Journal of Marketing Research,
Vol 27 No 1, pp. 24-36.
Heide, J.B., Wathne, K.H, and Rokkan, A.I. (2007) “Interfirm Monitoring, Social Contracts,
and Relationship Outcomes”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol 44 No 3, pp.425433.
Jap, S. and Ganesan, S. (2000) “Control Mechanisms and the Relationship Life Cycle:
Implications for Safeguarding Specific Investments and Developing
Commitment”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol 37 No 2, pp. 227-245.
Kimel, D. (2007) “The Choice of Paradigm for Theory of Contract: Reflections on the
Relational Model”, Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, Vol 27 No 2, pp. 233-255.
Klein, B. (1980) “Transaction Cost Determinants of ‘Unfair’ Contractual Arrangements”,
American Economic Review, Vol 70, No 2, pp. 356-362.
Klein, B. and Murphy, K.M. (1997) “Vertical Integration as a Self-Enforcing Contractual
Arrangement”, American Economic Review, Vol 87 No 2, pp. 415-420.
Kronman, A.T. and Posner, R.A. (1979). The Economics of Contract Law, Little, Brown
and Co.: Boston.
Levin, J. (2003) “Relational incentive contracts”, American Economic Review, Vol 93 No3,
pp.835-857.
Loasby, B.J. (2000) “Market Institutions and Economic Evolution”, Journal of Evolutionary
Economics, Vol 10 No 3, pp. 297-309.
Macaulay, S. (1963) “Non-contractual relationships in business: A preliminary study”.
American Sociological Review, Vol 28, pp. 55-69.
Macaulay, S. (2003). ‘The Real and the Paper Deal: Empirical Pictures of Relationships,
Complexity and the Urge for Transparent Simple Rules’, in Campbell, D., Collins, H.
and Wightman, J. (Eds.), Implicit Dimensions of Contract: Discrete, Relational
and Network Contracts, Hart Publishing: Oxford. pp. 51-102.
Macneil, I.R. (1974) “Restatement (Second) of Contracts and Presentiation”, Virginia
Law Review, Vol 60 No 4, pp. 589-610.
Macneil, I.R. (1975) “A Primer of Contract Planning”, Southern California Law Review
Vol 48, pp.627-704.
Macneil, I. R. (1980) The New Social Contract, Yale University Press: New Haven, CT.
Macneil, I.R. (1983) “Values in contract: internal and external”, Northwestern University
Law Review, Vol 78, pp.340-418.
Macneil, I. R. (1985) “Relational Contract: What we do and do not know”, Wisconsin Law
Review, pp.483-525.
Macneil, I.R. (1987a) “Barriers to the Idea of Relational Contracts”, in Nicklisch, F. (Ed.),
The Complex Long-term Contract, CF Mueller Juristisher Verlag: Heidelberg, pp.
31-46.
Macneil, I.R. (1987b) “Relational contract theory as sociology: a reply to Professors Limberg
and de Vos”, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol 143,
pp.272-90.
Macneil, I.R. (2000). ‘Relational Contract Theory: Challenges and Queries’. Northwestern
University Law Review, 94,.877-907.
Markovits, D. (2004) “Contract and collaboration”, The Yale Law Journal, Vol 113,
pp.1417-1518.
Maskin, E. and Tirole, T. (1999) “Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts”, The
Review of Economic Studies, Vol 66 No 1, pp. 83-114, Special Issue: Contracts.
17
Mayer, K.J. and Argyres, N. (2004) “Learning to Contract: Evidence from the Personal
Computer Industry”, Organization Science, Vol 15 No 4, pp. 394-410.
McKendrick, E. (2002) ‘The Regulation of Long-term Contracts in English law’, in J.
Beatson and D. Friedmann (Eds.), Good Faith and Fault in Contract Law: pp. 305333. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Mellahi, K., Jackson, P. and Sparks, L. (2002) “An exploratory study into failure in successful
organizations: the case of Marks and Spencer”. British Journal of Management,
Vol 13, No 1, pp. 15–30.
Mouzas, S. (2006) “Negotiating Umbrella Agreements”, The Negotiation Journal, Vol 22
No 3, pp. 279-301.
Mouzas, S. and Ford, D. (2006) “Managing Relationships in Showery Weather: The Role of
Umbrella Agreements”, Journal of Business Research,Vol 59, pp. 1248-1256.
Mouzas, S., and Ford, D. (2007). “Contracts in Asymmetric Relationships”, The IMP
Journal, Issue 3: (March).
Mouzas, S., and Furmston, M. (2008) “From Contract to Umbrella Agreement“, Cambridge
Law Journal, Vol 67 No 1, pp. 37 -50.
Nee, V. (1998) “Norms and Networks in Economic and Organizational Performance”,
American Economic Review, Vol 88 No 2, pp. 85-89.
Poppo L. and Zenger, T. (2002) “Do Formal Contracts and Relational Covernance Function
as Substitutes or Complements?”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol 23, pp. 707724.
Reuer, J.J. and Arino, A. (2007) “Strategic Alliance Contracts: Dimensions and Determinants
of Contractual Provision”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol 28, pp.303-330.
Roxenhall, T. and Ghauri, P. (2004) “The Use of written contract in long-lasting business
relationships”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol 33 No 3, pp. 261-268.
Schanze, E. (1991) “Symbiotic Contracts: Exploring Long-term Agency Structures between
Contract and Corporation”, in Joergens, C. (Ed.), Franchising and the law:
Theoretical and Comparative Approaches in Europe and the United States, pp.
67-104, Baden-Baden.
Schwartz, A. (1992) “Relational contracts in courts: An analysis of incomplete agreements
and judicial strategies”. Journal of Legal Studies Vol 21 No 2, pp. 271–318.
Schwartz, A. and Scott, R. (2003) “Contract theory and the limits of Contract Law”, The
Yale Law Journal, Vol 113, pp.541-619.
Schwartz, A. and Scott, R.E. (2007) ‘‘Pre-Contractual Liability and Preliminary Agreements’’
Harvard Law Review, Vol 120 No3, 661-707.
Scott, R.E. (2000) “The Case for Formalism in Relational Contract” Northwestern
University Law Review, Vol 94, pp. 847-862.
Sebenius, J.K. (1992). ‘Negotiation analysis: A characterization and review’. Management
Science, 38:3, 18-38.
Shavell, S. (2006) “On the Writing and Interpretation of Contracts” Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization, Vol 22 No 2, pp. 289-314.
Sullivan, M. W. (1997) “Slotting allowances and the market for new products”, Journal of
Law & Economics, Vol 40 No 2, pp. 461–493.
Sweeney, D.J. (1972). “Marketing: management technology or social process?” Journal of
Marketing, Vol 36 No 4, pp.3-10.
Taylor, T.A. and Plambeck, E. (2007) “Supply Chain Relationships and Contracts: The
Impact of Repeated Interaction on Capacity Investment and Procurement”,
Management Science, Vol 53 No 10, pp. 1577-1593.
Tirole, J. (1999) “Incomplete Contracts: Where do we stand?”, Econometrica, Vol 67 No 4,
pp. 741-781
Villas-Boas, J.M. and Zhao, Y. (2005) “Retailers, manufacturers, and individual consumers:
Modelling the supply side in the ketchup marketplace”, Journal of Marketing
Research, Vol 42 No 1, pp. 83–95.
Whitford (1985) “Ian Macneil’s contribution to contracts scholarship”, Wisconsin Law
Review, pp.545-560.
18
Williamson, O.E., (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press,
New York.
Young, H.P. (1993) “The Evolution of Conventions”, Econometrica, Vol 61 No 1, pp. 57-84.