Where is the Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard Problem in Islamic Finance?
By Anders K. Møller
The College of Wooster
May 2013
Supervisor: Prof. Amyaz Moledina
Prepared in partial fulfillment of the requirements of ECON-299 – Alternative Financial Institutions
Møller 1
1. Introduction
Islamic finance has seen an enormous rise in popularity in recent years: Global Islamic financial
transactions and contracts are worth an estimated $1.3 trillion, a number that is growing at a rate of
between 15% and 20% per year (Pak, Islamic Finance Faces). As Haque and Mirakhor explain, it is very
important to analyze the financial structures of Islamic banking and how the profit-sharing model
overcomes financial market uncertainty, because some economists have expressed concerns that
removal of interest-based debt financing will lower investment (Haque and Mirakhor 1986, pg. iii).
However, Islamic Finance reduces the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard due to increased
information sharing. This is because Islamic banks do not charge interest, but instead share risk with the
entrepreneur. It is important to banish myths about market failures in Islamic finance if people are to
understand its true potential.
The purpose of this essay is to review the literature on how adverse selection and moral hazard
occur in Islamic finance. It begins by describing how Islamic finance overcomes the adverse selection
and moral hazard problems that might arise out of eliminating interest. It then goes on to show how
profit/loss sharing (PLS) contracts can overcome the incentive incompatibilities, which is the main
agency (principal-agency) problem faced by lenders in the Islamic finance system. This essay
demonstrates that risk-sharing, formalized and dictated in PLS contracts, reduces or eliminates agency
problems such as high monitoring costs and incentive incompatibility.
2. Overview of Riba, Adverse Selection, and Moral Hazard
Islamic finance is based on Shari’ah law and its rules governing the exchanges in the market
place. The prohibition of interest, or riba, is one of the most central principles in Islamic finance,
mandated to guard against exploitation of those who do not possess financial capital (Iqbal and
Mirakhor 2011, Pg. 41-2). Instead, Islam dictates a financial system based on mutual liability and risk
sharing. The orro er s risk lies in the opportunity cost of investing their time and energy into the
usi ess, hile the le der s risk is i the apital pro ided. This means that if a business venture is
successful, both borrower and lender share the profits; if however the venture fails, the borrower loses
their vested work and potentially their source of income, but only the lender is financially liable.
Adverse selection and moral hazard are two types of agency problems in lending.1 Armendariz
and Morduch explain adverse selection as the problem that arises when banks lack good information
about potential borrowers, and thus are unable to discriminate against risky borrowers. Lenders charge
high interest rates to compensate for the higher inherent risk in lending (Armendariz and Murdoch
2007, pg. 41-2). According to Ahmed (2002), adverse selection in Islamic finance arises before the
contract is signed because the bank has less information on the project than the borrower (Ahmed
2002, pg. 42).
1
Agency problems include lack of collateral and asymmetric information. Asymmetric (or imperfect) information,
which refers to the lack of information by one party compared to another in an economic transaction, is further
sub-divided into adverse selection and moral hazard.
Møller 2
Moral hazard refers to situatio s here the a k s risk is tied to u o ser a le hoi es ade
the borrowers, a d i ludes issues su h as shirki g a d ithholdi g of i for atio (Armendariz and
Murdoch 2007, pg. 48). Moral hazard can (generally) be categorized as either ex ante or ex post, which
relates to borrower actions before and after the loan has been disbursed, respectively. Ex ante actions
by the borrower affect the realization of returns by the lender, and typically relates to asymmetrical
information (or in simple terms, imperfect information on behalf of the lender). Ex post moral hazard
refers to diffi ulties that e erges to the le der after the loa has ee
ade a d the orro er has
i ested ; once project returns are realized, there is a risk of the borrower (agent) either running away
from the loan, or does not fully disclose profitability (Armendariz and Murdoch 2007, pg. 50). This is also
known as the enforcement problem.
3. Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection in Islamic Finance
Moral hazard and adverse selection can theoretically arise out of the inability for an Islamic bank
to charge riba. Banks utilize interest both as a compensation for higher risk as well as a screen for
removing high-risk borrowers who know their own project to have a high risk level (in which case their
business plan is more likely to fail, thus making them personally liable to the bank). Failure to screen
applicants for those who are likely to perform successfully exposes the bank to adverse selection (AlJarhi 2002, pg. 10). However, this is relatively easy to overcome from effective screening, which is a
natural component of Islamic banking (further discussed below). Other authors such as Ghannadian and
Goswami (2004) theorize there is higher ex ante and ex post moral hazard in Islamic banking loans
because debt contracts based on interest payments are more desirable for banks doing investment
transactions. As they explain, ex post asymmetrical information would make the bank unable to
accurately predict profits because there is no deterrent for the enterprise to understate returns. A
thorough audit of the fir s realized profits by the bank ex post is very costly (Ahmed 2002, pg. 44).
Because banks nonetheless can estimate the expected risk of projects ex ante, traditional banking
systems view the most effective response to be debt contracting that establishes and enforces a return
reflective of the perceived risk level (Ghannadian and Goswami 2004, pg. 744-45).
Many authors have shown that the Islamic financial system mitigates or removes these market
failures in financial transactions. Zamir Iqbal argues that the strict selection procedure that arises out of
risk sharing between lender and borrower creates allocation efficiency. Because lenders cannot charge
interest and are financially liable for the entire investment, projects are strictly chosen based on their
productivity and expected rate of return (Iqbal 1997, pg. 42). Two of the central principles of an Islamic
financial system are trust and the sanctity of contracts. According to Iqbal and Mirakhor (2011), Islam
pla es a stro g e phasis o trust a d o siders trust orthi ess a o ligator perso alit trait; It
makes clear that performing contractual obligations or promises is an important and mandatory
characteristic of a true elie er. All tra sa tio s i the arketpla e ust e ased o trust, which
fosters entrepreneurial honesty, and contractual obligations and full disclosure of information must be
upheld as a sacred duty. Both of these principles are intended to reduce risks associated with lack of
perfect information and moral hazard (Iqbal and Mirakhor 2011, pg. 42-45). Greater information seeking
and trust in Islamic financial transactions greatly diminishes the adverse selection problem.
Møller 3
Authors such as Al-Jarhi (2002) and Ahmad (2002) go further in describing how Islamic lending
reduce both adverse selection and moral hazard because they are based on PLS contracts. Traditionally,
monitoring must be implemented at ex ante, interim, and ex post transaction phases to be effective;
however, the involvement of an Islamic lender under a PLS contract turns the lender into an investment
partner which increases access to information, thus enabling them to greatly mitigate both adverse
selection and moral hazard. As Al-Jarhi e plai s, Equity finance provides the bank with access to
information necessary to practice monitoring at all intervals. (Al-Jarhi 2002, pg. 10-11). Habib Ahmad
(2002) further points out that Islamic lenders may not be willing to finance projects if insufficient
information is available, and only if the risk-adjusted rate of return is greater than the return on risk-free
investments; since the bank act as an investment partner it will seek sufficient information to effectively
assess the proje t s risk a d the appropriate profit-sharing ration, thus overcoming the adverse selection
problem. Although critics Ghannadian and Goswami view debt contract financing by banks as the most
effective system for developed nations, they suggest that a system based on equity contracts is the most
effective tool in developing countries that do not have sufficient information to assess risk structures;
risk sharing helps overcome adverse selection problem, which typically cause banks in developing
countries to have untenably high interest rates (Ghannadian and Goswami 2004, pg. 751).
Jouabar-Snoussi and Mehri (2012) in their arti le Agency Problems in Venture Capital
Contracts: Islamic Profit Sharing Ratio as a Screening Device suggest that the pro le of ad erse
selection is avoided simply by the existence of an optimal profit-sharing ratio (PSR) as part of the
profit/loss sharing contract (Jouabar-Snoussi and Mehri 2012, pg. 3-5, 25-26). The PSR can act as a
screening device for banks: assuming that an entrepreneur knows their own riskiness, it is an indicator
of high risk if he/she is willing to accept a loan above a critical ratio. Such a scenario would signal to the
bank that there is a strong possibility of agency problems with the entrepreneur. Conversely, a low-risk
entrepreneur will understand their own capacity for creating a successful enterprise and negotiate a low
PSR which ensures maximum profits for themselves. This would signal a safer investment. According to
the authors, this signaling system using the PSR can provide a tool for lenders ( hat the ter Isla i
e ture apitalists ) to help ith the o ple task of s ree i g pote tial e trepre eurs.
4. Ex Post Moral hazard: Incentive Incompatibilities
The most challenging source of moral hazard in an Islamic financial transaction occurs ex post of
a bank lending capital to an entrepreneur or a corporation (borrower) due to conflicts of interest. If
there is a conflict of interest between the management and some or all of the shareholders of a firm,
moral hazard arises when the agent (management) omits from sharing certain information with the
owners (principal) hi h ould ha e ee utilized to ser e the pri iple s est i terest. This is known as
the incentive incompatibility (Haque and Mirakhor 1986, pg.4-5), and is commonly referred to as the
principal-agent problem in investment banking (although principal-agent problem is a broad term
which means the same as agency problem ). As mentioned above, Islamic equity financing of firms is
based on profit-sharing contracts where risk is shared between lenders and borrowers i.e. Islamic banks,
and entrepreneurs and firms respectively (Haque and Mirakhor 1986, pg. iii). When a principal (lender)
enters into contract with an agent (entrepreneur), they may for example have different attitudes
towards entrepreneurial risk and thus have conflicting incentives. Moreover, given an unequal
Møller 4
distribution of information about profit and company activities, the principal cannot perfectly monitor
the agent. Given that the optimal cost of monitoring constitutes a high cost to the principal, less
monitoring will take place and the agent may be disposed towards hiding the true risk level of an action.
This issue can be easier understood given a relatively simple example. If Islamic bank A
(principal) lends X amount to an entrepreneur who is the CEO of a start-up (firm B), the profits of the
venture will be a function of X; i.e. P = f(x). The principal receives a pre-determined portion of profits
equal to Z, and the agent (CEO) retains the remainder P – Z. If, for example, the e trepre eur s retai ed
profits are a relatively small component of their wealth, they might well be risk-prone and willing to
e pa d fir B s operatio s i spite of so e set of i here t risks. Let us assu e that the a k is ore
risk-averse than the agent, and would not go along with any high-risk investments by the firm. If the
agent is party to information about the risks expansion and chooses to withhold it from bank A, then
he/she is exposing the principal to moral hazard. This example illustrates how there might be conflicts of
interest between the shareholders (in this case, bank A is a major stakeholder in firm B) and the
management, which is a source of moral hazard in Islamic financing of corporations. This is also known
as an agency cost to bank A.
This scenario fails, however, to take into account the re-alignment of interests that occur in a
PLS contract. Haque and Mirakhor show that this type of moral hazard can be disseminated by creating
optimized individual contracts. As the poi t out, he age
osts are redu ed, the e efits are
shared by both the agent and the principal, therefore, [they] both have a common interest in defining a
monitoring and incentive scheme that yields outcomes as close as possible to ones that would be
produced if information monitoring were costless (Haque and Mirakhor 1986, pg. 6). Both the principal
and the agent thus create a contract that details transparent rules governing investment and profit
decisions by the firm. Haque and Mirakhor go on to explain that since the principal has a vested interest
i the su ess of the age t s fir , the disti tio et een lender and entrepreneur diminishes. In effect,
the profit-sharing system eli i ates the fi ed ost of apital fro the fir s profit al ulatio s, a d thus
[ ]oth the o ers of the fir a d the le ders to a fir [ e o e] residual i o e ear ers. In other
words, both principal and agent have converging interests in achieving success for the firm because they
both profit accordingly (Haque and Mirakhor 1986, pg. 18). This improves cooperation between the
shareholders and thus increases effort, reducing the risk of the enterprise. Moreover, if the firm faces
financial difficulties the principal may well inject more equity to keep it afloat. They will do so as long as
the marginal investment costs are lower than the rate of return (Moledina, lecture on 4-22-2013). This is
yet another way in which a PLS reduces the risk of a firm.
Abalkhail and Presley (2002) similarly discuss how a comprehensive contract can reduce
asymmetric information between the agent and the principle to overcome the principal-agent problem.
They explain that contracts a e for ulated to i flue e the age t s eha ior through either
influencing the management, which is a monitoring approach where the investor becomes more
involved, and/or provide incentives and involve the entrepreneur s capital which is an outcome-based
approach (Abalkhail and Presley 2002, pg. 121-23). Such approaches will streamline the interests of the
principal and the agent, which maximizes the efficiency of the firm. They therefore both stand to gain
Møller 5
from overcoming the moral hazard problem and write a contract that stipulates full information and
incentive compatibility (Abalkhail and Presley 2002, pg. 12).
5. Concluding Remarks
It can be seen from the arguments highlighted above that the PLS contracts in Islamic banking
allows the principal (the bank) to overcome both adverse selection and moral hazard problems. The
latter includes ex ante moral hazard (asymmetrical information) in addition to ex post (principal-agent
problem). Baldwin et. al. provide an excellent overview of the benefits of a PLS contract in relation to
agency problems (Baldwin et. al. 2002). A PLS agreement creates a partnership between the principal
(bank) and the agent (loaner) that is the equivalent of a venture capital partnership in conventional
banking: this reduces asymmetrical information between agent and principal, which gives a stronger
vetting process for loan granting that in return reduces the risk of each venture. It moreover aligns the
effort incentives, so that the principal-agent problem is overcome (which furthermore reduces risk).
Lastly, in some cases the principal may use their venture capital status as a shareholder in the firm to
hire new management with valuable expertise in the market; this, yet again, reduces the probability that
the enterprise will fail.
Although a well-designed PLS contract can solve the main agency problem facing lending by
Islamic banks as shown by authors such as Haque and Mirakhor (1986) and Abalkhail and Presley (2002),
only general lessons about the specific design of such the contract have been drawn. More research is
needed into how PLS contract will be designed, and how it fits into the wider picture of Islamic finance
in general as well as conventional banking. Such studies might well enhance the global interest in Islamic
financial institutions.
Møller 6
Bibliography
Abalkhail, M., & Presley, J. R. (2002). How informal risk capital investors manage asymmetric
information in profit/loss-sharing contracts. Islamic Banking and Finance, New Perspectives On ProfitSharing And Risk.
Ahmed, H. (2002). Incentive-compatible Profit-sharing Contracts: A Theoretical Treatment, published in
Iqbal and Llyewellyn, 40-56.
Al-Jarhi, M. A. (2002). Islamic finance: an efficient and equitable option. Islamic research and training
institute, Islamic development Bank.
Armendáriz, Beatriz, and Jonathan Morduch. The economics of microfinance. MIT press, 2007.
Baldwin, K., Dar, H. A., & Presley, J. R. (2002). On determining moral hazard and adverse selection in the
Islamic firm. Theoretical Foundations of Islamic Economics, 145.
Ghannadian, F. F., & Goswami, G. (2004). Developing economy banking: the case of Islamic banks.
International Journal of Social Economics, 31(8), 740-752.
Iqbal, Z. (1997). Islamic financial systems. Finance and Development, 34, 42-45.
Iqbal, Z., & Mirakhor, A. (2011). An introduction to Islamic finance: theory and practice (Vol. 687). Wiley.
Jouaber-Snoussi, K., & Mehri, M. (2012, April). A Theory of Profit Sharing Ratio Under Adverse Selection:
The Case of Islamic Venture Capital. In 29th International Conference of the French Finance Association
(AFFI).
Moledina, Amyaz (2013). Alternative Financial Institutions, 4/22/2013. The College of Wooster.
Pak, Jennifer. "Islamic Finance Faces Growth Challenges." BBC News. BBC, 12 May 2012. Web. 30 Apr.
2013. <http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-20405292>.
Ul Haque, N., & Mirakhor, A. (1986). Optimal Profit-sharing Contracts and Investment in an interest-free
Islamic Economy.