CSP045
J A N UA RY 2019
Cryptocurrency
MA R G A RE T E. TA HY A R
T RE V OR I. KI VI A T
MA DI SO N J . R O BE RT S
SUI W E N L I AN G
H O W EL L J A CK SO N
Memorandum
TO:
Deputy Director of Federal Reserve Bank Operations and Payment Systems at the Federal Reserve
FROM: Director of Federal Reserve Bank Operations and Payment Systems
DATE: February 2019
RE:
Fed-Issued Digital Currency
Introduction
In light of the declining usage of cash within the United States, the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System requested that a team of staff economists brief the board on potential designs for a
Federal Reserve digital fiat currency. The economist teams have suggested two possible designs—
“Fedcoin” and “Fedcount.” There is an internal debate within the staff economists about which design
might be better for payment efficiencies and monetary policy implementation, with some also expressing
the view that no action should be taken by the Federal Reserve System at all.
Both proposals are still in their early stages, as described further below. However, given that other central
banks around the world have begun experimenting or considering experimentation with some central
bank digital currencies (CBDCs), we have been asked to evaluate the three proposals: Fedcoin, Fedcount,
and no action. To that end, I would like your help with analyzing the potential legal and policy issues that
Written by Margaret E. Tahyar, Trevor I. Kiviat, Madison J. Roberts, and Suiwen Liang of Davis, Polk and Wardwell with assistance by Howell
Jackson. Cases are developed solely as the basis for class discussion. They are not intended to serve as endorsements, sources of primary data,
legal advice, or illustrations of effective or ineffective management.
Copyright © 2019 President and Fellows of Harvard University. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used
in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without
permission. To order copies or permissions to reproduce materials visit our website at casestudies.law.harvard.edu or by mail at Harvard Law
School Case Studies Program, 1545 Massachusetts Avenue – Harvard Law School Library, 3rd Floor, Cambridge, MA 02138, or by email at
HLSCaseStudies@law.harvard.edu.
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
could arise from the policy, monetary and legal issues that could arise either from the two proposals or
from a decision that the Federal Reserve stays out of the fray. Your task is to consider any design
recommendations to guide the Federal Reserve Board forward, carefully weighed against the merits and
demerits of maintaining the status quo. Another work stream is tasked with analyzing whether the Federal
Reserve System possesses legal authority for implementing CBDC in the absence of new legislation, so for
now assume that such authority exists. You should, however, consider any policy issues related to the
institutional independence of the Federal Reserve System and the views that the congressional oversight
committee might have about decisions made by the Board of Governors with respect to CBDC and the
role of the Federal Reserve System in the political economy.
Background
Functions of Money
Sound money must fulfill three classical functions: medium of exchange, store of value, and unit of
account.
First, in order for an instrument to function as a medium of exchange, the instrument must be able to
facilitate the sale of goods and services. The seller in a transaction must accept the instrument as a means
of payment with the belief that the seller can give the instrument as a means of payment for other
transactions. 1
Second, the instrument must serve as a store of value, preserving purchasing power over time. An
instrument that is susceptible to depreciating or failing to maintain its value would not be considered
sound money. 2
Third, functioning as a unit of account requires the instrument to act as a yardstick for measuring and
comparing value across goods and services, thus informing the economic decisions of its users. 3
The Role of the Central Bank in the U.S. System
The Federal Reserve System forms the central bank of the United States. The Federal Reserve System
features “(1) a central governing Board, (2) a decentralized operating structure of 12 Federal Reserve
Banks, and (3) a combination of public and private characteristics” 4 (for more information about the
Federal Reserve System, see Appendix Item 3). The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System is
based in the nation’s capital and supervises the 12 Federal Reserve Banks. The 12 Federal Reserve Banks
“service[] financial institutions in 12 Federal Reserve districts.” 5 The Federal Reserve notes, what is
commonly called cash, are issued by the separate regional Federal Reserve Banks but printed by the U.S.
1
BANK FOR INT’L SETTLEMENTS, ANNUAL ECONOMIC R EPORT, June 2018, at 92 (2018), https://www.bis.org/publ/arpdf/ar2018e.pdf
[https://perma.cc/H4ER-SAGF]. (Hereinafter BIS ANNUAL ECONOMIC REPORT.)
2
Id. at 91.
3
Id.
4
About the Federal Reserve System, Structure of the Federal Reserve System, https://www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed/structurefederal-reserve-system.htm [https://perma.cc/V7ZF-RZM2].
5
MICHAEL S. BARR, HOWELL E. JACKSON & MARGARET E. TAHYAR, FINANCIAL REGULATION: LAW AND POLICY 939 (2d ed. 2018).
2
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Treasury. The 12 Federal Reserve Banks also “act as banker’s banks, providing a wide variety of services
such as storing currency and processing checks and electronic payments for both banking institutions and
the federal government.” 6 Directly accessing these payment services “requires a master account at the
nearest regional Federal Reserve Bank.”7 The Federal Reserve Banks only grant master accounts to banks.
The Federal Reserve System performs a number of critical roles for the U.S. economy. First, the Federal
Reserve Board is charged by Congress to “pursu[e] the goals of ‘maximum employment, stable prices, and
moderate long-term interest rates.’” 8 Second, “[t]he Federal Reserve is the primary organ responsible for
carrying out U.S. monetary policy and, for many, that is its most crucial role.” 9 Third, the Federal Reserve’s
circulation of cash, issued and delivered by the regional Federal Reserve Banks to meet domestic and
foreign demand, also generates significant revenues for the U.S. government—thanks to the U.S. dollar’s
status as the global reserve currency.
Forms of Money
Conventional Forms of Money in the U.S. Financial System
In the current U.S. financial system, money conventionally manifests in three forms: cash, commercial
bank deposits, and central bank accounts—accounts held by banks at each of the Federal Reserve Banks
through what is called a master account. As described below, the relationship between these three kinds
of money is overseen by the Federal Reserve System.
Source: Adapted from Bank for International Settlements10
6
Id.
7
Id. at 183.
8
Id. at 49.
9
Id. at 939.
10
Bank for Int’l Settlements, Central Bank Digital Currencies 5 (2018), https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d174.pdf [https://perma.cc/7FQEHYLE]. (Hereinafter CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES.)
3
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Cash consists of both metal coins minted and paper notes printed by the government. Cash represents a
liability of the central bank 11 and is “legal tender for all debts, public charges, taxes, and dues.” 12 The
Federal Reserve Banks issue and supply cash to commercial banks in their districts, which is then circulated
by commercial banks to users based on demand. Generally, anyone can access, store, and use cash. Due
to its widely recognized authenticating features (for example, watermarks and holograms on higher value
bills), payments involving cash typically do not require a trusted third party to record the transfer or verify
the authenticity of the physical notes or coins. 13 Consequently, settling transactions with cash is usually
immediate and generally does not come with transaction fees. 14
Cash also comes with costs attached for both the user, who bears the burden of storage and loss, and the
government, which bears the burden of supporting the printing, minting, and initial delivery
infrastructure. Although cash is convenient for settling smaller transactions immediately, it is
inconvenient for large transactions. Holding and transferring large quantities of cash is both burdensome
and unsafe. For these reasons, the proportion of cash in payment values has been declining in many major
economies, including the United States. 15
From the government’s perspective, cash requires an expensive infrastructure to support its circulation
and upkeep. 16 In addition to the logistics of producing, storing, and transporting physical cash to
accommodate new demand, the government has to periodically retire and replace unfit coins and notes
to maintain existing supply, further consuming resources. 17 Even with these expenses, however, the
government’s creation of cash generates significant profits for the United States government, due in part
to the U.S. dollar’s role as a reserve currency and the widespread use of $100 bills as a safe haven asset
or as the currency most valued in illicit transactions.
Money in bank deposit accounts consists of “electronically recorded deposit account liabilities on the
ledgers of commercial banks.”18 This form of money is universally available to anyone with a bank
account. 19 Money stored in deposit accounts serves as “the main means of payment between ultimate
users” 20 and “the main form of money holding of households and businesses.” 21 Its supply increases when
11
WALTER ENGERT & BEN S.C. FUNG, BANK OF CAN., CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY: MOTIVATIONS AND IMPLICATIONS 1 (2017).
12
31 U.S.C. § 5103.
13
Id. at 1.
14
BARR, JACKSON & TAHYAR, supra note 5, at 808.
15
Id.
16
Aleksander Berentsen & Fabian Schär, The Case for Central Bank Electronic Money and the Non-case for Central Bank Cryptocurrencies, 100
FED. RES. BANK OF ST. LOUIS REV. 97, 101 (2018).
17
For reference, there is an average life expectancy of 5.9 years for $1 bills, 4.2 years for $10, 3.7 years for $50, and 15 years for $100. How
Currency Gets into Circulation, FED. RES. BANK OF N.Y. (July 2013), https://www.newyorkfed.org/aboutthefed/fedpoint/fed01.html
[https://perma.cc/8CLH-WHYT].
18
Ole Bjerg, Designing New Money – The Policy Trilemma of Central Bank Digital Currency 15 (Copenhagen Bus. Sch. Working Paper, June 14,
2017), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2985381 [https://perma.cc/W7SH-L99G].
19
Id. at 14–15. As a practical matter, however, “[m]ore than 9 million U.S. households, including 15.6 million adults and 16.3 million children
are unbanked, or lack an account at an insured depository institution.” BARR, JACKSON & TAHYAR, supra note 5, at 826. There are “[a]nother
24.5 million households, comprising 51.1 million adults and 16.3 million children [who] are underbanked, meaning that although they have
bank accounts, they also obtain financial services from non-bank, alternative-financial-services providers such as check cashers or payday
lenders. Being unbanked or underbanked presents significant challenges for participating in many payment systems.” Id.
20
BIS ANNUAL ECONOMIC REPORT, supra note 1, at 93.
21
Bjerg, supra note 18, at 12.
4
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
commercial banks issue loans to borrowers or receive cash deposits and decreases when account holders
“make debt repayments or interest payments to the bank.” 22
Money in central bank accounts is recorded digitally as liabilities on each Federal Reserve Bank’s ledger.23
As discussed earlier, direct access to central bank money is currently restricted to chartered banks and
other depository institutions. Nonbank companies and individuals cannot directly access the accounts at
a Federal Reserve Bank for payments or storage. 24 Supply of central bank money grows when commercial
banks purchase government bonds or deposit funds with their Federal Reserve Banks and contracts when
commercial banks borrow on a collateralized basis from their Federal Reserve Banks. 25 Instead of
facilitating retail payments, the amounts deposited by commercial banks with the Federal Reserve Banks
enable the settlement of wholesale interbank payments. 26
Taken together, these three conventional forms of money share overlapping features while retaining key
distinctions. For instance:
•
Cash and commercial bank deposits are, in principle, accessible to anyone, unlike master
accounts, 27 which can only be opened by banks.
•
Cash and master accounts are liabilities issued by the Federal Reserve Banks, unlike commercial
bank deposits. 28
•
Commercial bank deposits and master accounts exist in digital form, unlike cash. 29
Beyond these abstract comparisons, the three forms of money share an operational infrastructure
through the Federal Reserve System’s partnership with the banking sector in circulating cash to the
public. 30 Specifically, individuals can receive cash by converting digital money stored in their bank deposits
into paper notes, most typically by a withdrawal from an ATM machine. These paper notes are purchased
by the bank from its regional Federal Reserve Bank through a deduction from the amount held in the
bank’s master account and a corresponding delivery of physical notes. 31
22
Id. at 15.
23
See id. at 14.
24
If the Fintech Charters were granted master accounts, then access would be extended beyond depository institutions. See FINTECH CHARTER
CASE STUDY 6–7.
25
See Bjerg, supra note 18, at 15.
26
BIS ANNUAL ECONOMIC REPORT, supra note 1, at 93.
27
Bjerg, supra note 18, at 15–16.
28
Id.
29
Id.
30
This institutional arrangement is not confined to the Federal Reserve System. “[I]n almost all modern-day economies, money is provided
through a joint public-private venture between the central bank and private banks, with the central bank at the system’s core.” BIS ANNUAL
ECONOMIC REPORT, supra note 1, at 93.
31
JP KONING, FEDCOIN: A CENTRAL BANK-ISSUED CRYPTOCURRENCY 25 (2016).
5
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
New Forms of Money?
Source: Adapted from Bank for International Settlements32
Cryptocurrency
Cryptocurrencies, such as Bitcoin, Ethereum, and Ripple, are a type of digital currency that rely on
cryptography to verify and secure transactions, as well as to manage the creation of new units.33 In
contrast to the conventional forms of money, and in contrast to other digital currencies (for example, ingame currencies used by certain video game franchises), cryptocurrencies generally are not backed by a
trusted institution and typically are not liabilities of any person or institution. 34
Distributed ledger technology, of which blockchain technology forms a subset, represents the
technological engine underpinning many cryptocurrencies, including Bitcoin. Distributed ledger
technology “refers to the protocols and supporting infrastructure that allow computers in different
locations to propose and validate transactions and update records in a synchronized way across a
network.” 35 As the term ledger implies, distributed ledger technology provides a means of recording
account balances or transaction history. In most other contexts, electronic transactions are recorded on
a centralized ledger. Generally, a trusted intermediary (e.g., the central bank, commercial banks, or
PayPal) manages the central ledger to “track account holders’ balances and, ultimately, vouch for a
32
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 5.
33
BARR, JACKSON & TAHYAR, supra note 5, at 835. For information on Bitcoin in particular, see Reuben Grinberg, Bitcoin: An Innovative
Alternative Digital Currency, 4 HASTINGS SCI. & TECH. L.J. 159, 160 (2011).
34
Gov. Lael Brainard, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies:
What Are We Learning? (May 15, 2018), https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20180515a.htm
[https://perma.cc/NY4Z-SJNV].
35
Morten Linnemann Bech & Rodney Garratt, Central Bank Cryptocurrencies, BIS Q. REV., Sept. 2017, at 55, 58,
https://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt1709f.pdf [https://perma.cc/4YH3-DXXV].
6
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
transaction’s authenticity.” 36 Not so with distributed ledger technology. As the name further implies, the
ledger is distributed across computers and other internet-connected devices in separate locations
globally, without the need for a trusted central authority. 37
For Bitcoin and many other cryptocurrencies, “[t]his ledger is the blockchain.” 38 Transactions are recorded
in batches, or “blocks,” with new blocks being “chained” in order to amend the existing ledger with
additional transactions. 39 This process of clearing and settlement happens around the clock—24/7/365—
and it all occurs mathematically, with minimal human intervention. Parties wishing to transact with
blockchain technology must announce their transaction “to the entire network, effectively asking network
participants to determine its authenticity.” 40 Responsibility for verifying the validity of new blocks is
shared by nodes—or computers connected to the network—through a consensus mechanism, whereby
the nodes agree to the common state of ledger usually with cryptographic tools and protocol rules. 41 For
Bitcoin’s proof-of-work consensus mechanism, network participants compete to solve cryptographic
puzzles necessary for validating a new block. As an economic incentive, the first to succeed receives newly
issued units of bitcoin. 42
A critical distinction to keep in mind is that Bitcoin is an example of a permissionless system, where each
node possesses a complete and current copy of the ledger. In principle, anyone can participate in
validating transactions in a permissionless system. In contrast, a permissioned system only allows trusted
nodes—in other words, participants approved by a central entity—to participate in updating the ledger.
A permissioned system may involve additional access controls such as verification of identity. 43
Many harbor doubts as to whether permissionless cryptocurrencies can function as sound money—much
less supplant the use of cash. For instance, Professor David Yermack argued in 2013 that Bitcoin, which
remains the most popular cryptocurrency, failed to satisfy the classical criteria of money. Although Bitcoin
enjoys some acceptance as a form of payment, “the worldwide commercial use of bitcoin remains
miniscule. . . .”44 He maintained that Bitcoin performs poorly as a unit of account since Bitcoin-based
quotes for prices of ordinary goods commonly extend to “four or five decimal places with leading zeros, a
practice rarely seen in consumer marketing and likely to confuse both sellers and buyers in the
36
Trevor I. Kiviat, Beyond Bitcoin: Issues in Regulating Blockchain Transactions, 65 DUKE L.J. 569, 578 (2015); BIS ANNUAL ECONOMIC REPORT,
supra note 1, at 96.
37
As such, this system is a “trustless” system.
38
Id.; see also SATOSHI NAKOMOTO, BITCOIN: A PEER-TO -PEER ELECTRONIC CASH SYSTEM 3 (2009), https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf
[https://perma.cc/8B5G-5RGK].
39
BANK FOR INT’L SETTLEMENTS, DISTRIBUTED LEDGER TECHNOLOGY IN PAYMENT, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT 3 (2017),
https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d157.pdf [https://perma.cc/FXS4-A2E7]. (Hereinafter DISTRIBUTED LEDGER TECHNOLOGY IN PAYMENT, CLEARING
AND SETTLEMENT).
40
Kiviat, Beyond Bitcoin, supra note 36, at 578.
41
DISTRIBUTED LEDGER TECHNOLOGY IN PAYMENT, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT, supra note 39, at 3–4.
42
Id. at 4. Bitcoin is programmed to have a finite total outstanding supply. When Bitcoin creation ceases, “the incentive to validate
transactions will likely be transaction fees.” Kiviat, Beyond Bitcoin, supra note 36, at 579–580.
43
BIS ANNUAL ECONOMIC R EPORT, supra note 1, at 96.
44
David Yermack, Is Bitcoin a Real Currency? An Economic Appraisal 2 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 19747, 2013).
7
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
marketplace.”45 Even then, his most severe reservation resided with Bitcoin’s prospects as a store of value
given, among other factors, its high volatility. 46
Since 2013, use of Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies as a medium of exchange has increased, especially
for those without access to or wishing to bypass central banks and commercial banks. Yet, adoption
remains far from widespread. 47 More problematically, persisting volatility continues to bely
cryptocurrency’s function as a stable means for storing value. To many observers, cryptocurrency’s
extreme fluctuations and growing number harken back ominously to the era of wildcat banking, when
state banks circulated their own currency that too often had dubious worth (see Appendix Item 11). 48
Central Bank Digital Currency
The advent of permissionless cryptocurrencies has catalyzed guarded interest among academics and
policymakers in CBDC. In a recent survey conducted by the Bank for International Settlements (see
Appendix Item 7), 70% of the responding central bank participants reported current or imminent
engagement with CBDC work. 49 Although a number of central banks are researching CBDC,50 few have
announced plans to implement CBDC in the next decade. 51 Despite the growing body of literature, CBDC
currently is “not a well-defined term”52 and standardization has yet to be reached in the form of an agreed
taxonomy or lexicon. Since discussions on CBDC have been mostly conceptual, it might be most helpful to
define CBDC by way of contrast: CBDC is central bank-issued digital money that is distinct from the existing
master accounts at Federal Reserve Banks. 53
Conventional forms of money
New forms of money
Bank
Master account
Privately issued
Central bank
Cash
deposits
balances
cryptocurrency
digital currency
Digital
×
✔
✔
✔
✔
Central bank-issued
×
×
✔
✔
✔
Universally accessible
×
(✔)
✔
✔
✔
✔ = existing or likely feature, (✔) = possible feature, × = not typical or possible feature
Source: Adapted from Bank for International Settlements54
45
Id. at 2–3. That said, there have been proposals to introduce a millibitcoin (mBTC), then worth $1.85, to better account for pricing of
conventional goods, Kai Sedgwick, It’s Time to Change the Way We Measure Bitcoin, BITCOIN.COM (Dec. 8, 2017),
https://news.bitcoin.com/its-time-to-change-the-way-we-measure-bitcoin/ [https://perma.cc/XB67-K7AY].
46
As discussed in footnote 42, Bitcoin’s supply is ultimately fixed. Although in theory the consensus mechanism could vote to lift this limit,
doing so would be difficult in practice. This effective limit on supply presents a further challenge to Bitcoin’s viability as a form of money.
47
CHRISTIAN BARONTINI & HENRY HOLDEN, BANK FOR INT’L SETTLEMENTS, PROCEEDING WITH CAUTION – A SURVEY ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY 14
(2019), https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap101.pdf [https://perma.cc/B3B2-H35Z].
48
Robert C. Hockett, Money’s Past Is Fintech’s Future: Wildcat Crypto, the Digital Dollar, and Citizen Central Banking (Dec. 11, 2018),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3299555 [https://perma.cc/7XBF-838X].
49
BARONTINI & HOLDEN, supra note 47, at 7.
50
Id. at 12.
51
Id. at 7.
52
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 3.
53
Id. at 4.
54
Id. at 6.
8
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
CBDC is also distinct from privately issued cryptocurrencies: CBDC would be backed by the government in
the same way that current forms of fiat currency are and may assuage concerns of volatility because
supply could be set programmatically (or algorithmically). 55 Some commentators regard a hypothetical
CBDC as superior to permissionless cryptocurrencies in two respects. First, CBDC would be a more reliable
and stable store of value. 56 Second, CBDC would likely avoid the “significant waste of resources” required
by the consensus mechanisms used by some cryptocurrencies. 57 For these reasons, a few commentators
advocate CBDC as a solution for counteracting the migration of users from conventional forms of money
to cryptocurrencies. 58 Nevertheless, no central bank has yet reported curbing the propagation of
cryptocurrency as an urgent priority. 59 More broadly, the measured pace of concrete action suggests that
central bank interest in CBDC remains tempered by caution. 60 Our own central bank has expressed its
reservations more openly, stating in May 2018 that “there is no compelling demonstrated need for a Fedissued digital currency” 61 (see Appendix Item 1).
Design Choices for Central Bank Digital Currency
Whether to introduce a CBDC and its optimal design features depend on the objectives and motivations
of the central bank. 62 Designing a CBDC would need to take into consideration the following features,
among others.
Currencies can either be token-based or account-based. If token-based, careful thought should be given
to the appropriate degree of anonymity. As with all currencies, CBDC would also require an infrastructure
to support its distribution (centralized or decentralized). As a digital currency, CBDC must also have in
place a validation scheme (centralized or decentralized) to prevent double spending or identity theft.
Finally, digital currencies can be subject to caps and/or accrue interest.
55
Brainard, supra note 34.
56
Id.
57
DONG HE ET AL., IMF, VIRTUAL C URRENCIES AND BEYOND: INITIAL CONSIDERATIONS, IMF STAFF DISCUSSION NOTE 22 n.20 (Jan. 2016) (“Mining Bitcoin is
costly, requiring computer processing power and associated energy costs. In addition, such systems involve a negative externality that
causes overinvestment in computer power.”).
58
Hockett, supra note 48. See also Itai Agur, Central Bank Digital Currencies: An Overview of Pros and Cons, in DO WE NEED CENTRAL BANK
DIGITAL CURRENCY? 113, 115 (2018) (“[O]ne incentive that central banks may have to develop a retail CBDC is to limit demand for private
cryptocurrencies.”).
59
BARONTINI & HOLDEN, supra note 47, at 14.
60
Id. at 12–13.
61
Brainard, supra note 34.
62
NOTE: While the Bank of Canada has undertaken research and experimentation with CBDCs for interbank settlement (wholesale CBDC), our
interests concern retail payments. To that end, please focus on the features that may be conducive towards a retail or general-purpose
CBDC, which may differ from those for a wholesale CBDC.
9
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Conventional forms of money
New forms of money
TokenAccountBank
Master account
Privately issued
Cash
based
based
deposits
balances
cryptocurrency
CBDC
CBDC
Tokens or accounts
T
A
A
T
T
A
Anonymity
×
×
×
✔
✔
(✔)
Decentralized distribution
×
×
✔
✔
✔
(✔)
Decentralized validation
×
(✔)
(✔)
✔
✔
✔
Capped
×
×
×
×
(✔)
(✔)
Interest-bearing
×
✔
✔
(✔)
(✔)
(✔)
✔ = existing or likely feature, (✔) = possible feature, × = not typical or possible feature
Source: Adapted from Bank for International Settlements63
Technology: Tokens or Accounts
The technological vehicle for the CBDC could be token-based, involving the transfer of an object of value
from one wallet into another, or account-based, involving the transfer of a claim recorded on one account
to another. 64 Cash and Bitcoin are examples of token-based money, whereas bank accounts and master
accounts are examples of account-based money. One distinction between tokens and accounts lies in the
method of verifying an exchange: the focus of verification for token-based money is the object
transferred—i.e., the token—and the focus of verification for account-based money is the identities of
the account holders. 65
Transfers involving tokens depend on the payee’s ability to “verify the validity of the payment object,” 66
whether in the form of a physical or digital coin. Token-based systems must control for counterfeiting and
enable the payee to validate the authenticity of the received token. 67 This implication holds true for both
physical and digital coins, as the payer could use a fake token in a transaction. Digital currencies introduce
the additional problem of double spending, where the payer uses a real digital token for more than one
transaction. Thus, policymakers for token-based systems must grapple with designing validation channels
(e.g., via a recognizable design as with paper notes or via a decentralized consensus mechanism as with
Bitcoin) for limiting counterfeit tokens and duplicate tokens. In contrast, transfers involving accounts rely
on verifying “the identity of the account holder.” 68 Account-based systems must control for identity theft
and the unauthorized transfer or withdrawal of money held within valid accounts. 69 Consequently,
policymakers for account-based systems must seek ways to validate the identity of the transacting
parties. 70
63
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 6.
64
TOMMASO MANCINI-GRIFFOLI ET AL., IMF, CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY, IMF STAFF DISCUSSION NOTE 7 (Nov. 2018).
65
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 4.
66
Id.
67
Id.
68
Id.
69
Id.
70
Id. (“Identification is needed to correctly link payers and payees and to ascertain their respective account histories.”).
10
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Anonymity
As seen with Bitcoin, token-based systems rely on verifying the authenticity of the exchanged token, not
the identities of the transacting parties. The payer “need reveal nothing to the payee beyond the
information associated with the specific coin.” 71 As such, a token-based CBDC can “be designed to provide
different degrees of anonymity”72 for its users or traceability for its transactions. 73
That said, Bitcoin and Ethereum would be more accurately characterized as granting pseudo-anonymity.
While “[t]he blockchain does not record real names or physical addresses,” the transactions of the ledger
are public and would be traceable to the owner should “the owner of the wallet become[] known.” 74 A
paper trail may be harder to follow than a digital one. 75 Cash transactions are usually anonymous to third
parties (such as banks) and the government. 76 Indeed, the anonymity of cash is an attractive quality for
many as a medium for protecting the privacy of their transaction histories. The degree to which a digital
token should be—or even could be—designed to be anonymous with respect to (i) the counterparty, (ii)
third-party validators, and (iii) the government remains an arena of lively debate.
In contrast, account-based systems generally require some knowledge of the transacting parties’
identities, such as the unique account number of the other party. 77 However, even if there was relative
counterparty anonymity—for example, where the parties only knew the other’s account numbers—thirdparty anonymity is likely absent. As discussed below, the banks operating the accounts would be “required
to have information regarding the individuals’ identities for a variety of legal reasons.”78
Degree of Centralization for Distribution and Validation
The central bank could opt to (i) directly oversee and manage the CBDC or (ii) delegate roles to other
actors, such as commercial banks.
For a token-based CBDC, the Federal Reserve Banks could directly handle the distribution of new digital
tokens to consumers and/or directly operate the validation process of digital tokens as a central validating
node. Alternatively, the Federal Reserve Banks could collaborate with private entities to accomplish these
responsibilities. For distribution, the Federal Reserve Banks could partner with commercial banks to
circulate the digital tokens to their consumers based on demand. This decentralized distribution scheme
is already used for the circulation of cash. As for validation, the Federal Reserve Banks could rely on a
network of nodes outside the Federal Reserve System, be it a permissionless network or a permissioned
network, to prevent double spending and preserve the integrity of the ledger.
71
Charles M. Kahn, Francisco Rivadeneyra & Tsz-Nga Wong, Should the Central Bank Issue E-Money? 11 (Oct. 2018),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3271654 [https://perma.cc/6KST-XJVT].
72
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 4.
73
Mancini-Griffoli et al., supra note 64, at 4.
74
Ankit Panda, Cryptocurrencies and National Security, COUNCIL ON FOREIGN RELS. (Feb. 28, 2018),
https://www.cfr.org/backgrounder/cryptocurrencies-and-national-security.
75
See Agur, supra note 58, at 115 (“An essential feature of physical cash is its anonymity.”).
76
This is less often the case with respect to the transacting counterparty, since the cash transactions typically take place in person.
77
Kahn, Rivadenyra & Wong, supra note 71, at 11.
78
Id.
11
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Although an account-based CBDC would be held by Federal Reserve Banks, the degree to which the
Federal Reserve Banks directly administer those accounts would remain a deliberate choice. A more
centralized scheme would involve the Federal Reserve Banks designing and operating the account’s
verification requirements and associated payment and customer services. Alternatively, the Federal
Reserve Banks could delegate the day-to-day responsibilities of administering the digital accounts to
private sector firms, such as commercial banks. 79
Quantitative Limits
The Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Reserve Banks could impose quantitative limits on transaction
or storage sizes for CBDC “as a way of controlling potentially undesirable implications or to steer usage in
a certain direction.” 80 For instance, a cap could be imposed on the amount of CBDC that can be stored in
a wallet or account. Alternatively, there could be a cap in the amount of CBDC a user can transact in for a
single transaction. Finally, softer limits could be imposed, where the user would be permitted to hold or
transact in an amount of CBDC beyond the limit—but with reduced anonymity.
Interest-bearing
Unlike cash, digital tokens and accounts could be designed to pay interest (positive or negative.)81 Indeed,
existing forms of account-based money, such as master accounts and commercial bank accounts, are
already interest-bearing. Importing this characteristic to digital tokens is also technically feasible. Positive
CBDC interest rates would encourage storing CBDC and converting holdings of other currencies into CBDC;
negative CBDC interest rates would encourage spending and converting holdings of CBDC into other
currencies. 82
Legal and Policy Considerations
The particular bundle of features that define a CBDC will pose important legal and policy implications for
the central bank. Provided below are a few to consider.
Concerns Related to Anti-Money Laundering, Know Your Customer, and Counter-Terrorism
Financing
The Federal Reserve Board would need to consider concerns and policies relating to laws on anti-money
laundering (AML) and counter-terrorism financing (CFT). Banks are subject to various laws that restrict
them from providing financial services that would assist with criminal activity. Such laws also require
banks to maintain customer due diligence programs for bank accounts and monitor suspicious activity,
79
See BEN DYSON & GRAHAM HODGSON, POSITIVE MONEY, DIGITAL CASH: WHY CENTRAL BANKS SHOULD START ISSUING ELECTRONIC MONEY 16–19 (2016).
80
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 4.
81
A negative interest rate means that the user pays the central bank to store its CBDC. Negative interest rates are highly controversial and
viewed by many as a confiscation of private property. Since a direct deduction would be made from the account, negative interest rates are
quite different from the erosion of inflation.
82
CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 6.
12
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
including cash transaction amounts exceeding $10,000. 83 AML and know-your-customer laws (KYC) also
apply to the Federal Reserve Banks, but current compliance is easy in practice, as only banks have direct
access to master accounts with Federal Reserve Banks.
CBDC that grants broad anonymity to users and limits traceability of transactions could become a favored
medium for illicit activities, thereby potentially raising legal and reputational concerns for the Federal
Reserve System. Cryptocurrencies have been criticized by some as a preferred medium of payment for
facilitating illegal activities. 84 A recent Europol report found that cryptocurrencies “remain the primary
payment mechanism for the payment of criminal services. . . .”85 For example, the Islamic State of Iraq
and al-Sham (ISIS), a militant terrorist organization, solicited donations in Zcash and Bitcoin in order to
finance their propaganda efforts. 86 Cryptocurrencies also figure prominently in so-called Darknet markets,
which are online marketplaces for illicit commodities and services, especially drugs. 87 A recent paper
concluded that “illegal activity accounts for a substantial proportion of the users and trading activity of
bitcoin.” 88 Such concerns caution against issuing opaque digital tokens, at least not without a key in the
government’s hands to unlock encrypted transaction information.
On the other hand, there may be legitimate demands for anonymity to safeguard privacy. Transacting
parties might seek to avoid the unwelcome nuisance of directed advertising or weightier dangers of
identity theft or personal harm. 89 Purchase history could also reveal health-related conditions and
shopping habits, which, while not unlawful, could cause embarrassment. After all, “knowledge by a third
party of the payee, amount, and time of payment for every transaction made by an individual can reveal
a great deal about the individual’s whereabouts, associations and lifestyle.” 90 The trends towards privacy
around consumer data means that users are increasingly worried about what happens to their information
after its collection, since data could be shared, sold, or lost. Indeed, the anonymity of cash remains an
attractive quality for many as a medium for protecting the privacy of their transaction histories. Even if
83
31 C.F.R. § 1010.311 (“Each financial institution . . . shall file a report of each deposit, withdrawal, exchange of currency or other payment
or transfer, by, through, or to such financial institution which involves a transaction in currency of more than $10,000. . . .”).
84
Large-denominated paper notes—which grant almost complete anonymity—are also widely used for transactions related to criminal
activities, including abroad, see Kenneth S. Rogoff, Response to Jeffrey Rogers Hummel’s Review of The Curse of Cash, 14 ECON. J. WATCH,
May 2017, at 164, 168 (“[W]hile there are many reasonable uses of the $100 bill abroad, it is indisputably popular with Russian oligarchs,
Mexican drug lords, illegal arms dealers, Latin American rebels, corrupt officials, human traffickers, etc., and of course North Korean
counterfeiters.”).
85
EUROPOL, INTERNET ORGANISED CRIME THREAT ASSESSMENT (IOCTA) 2018, at 58 (2018).
86
Id. at 53 (“Cryptocurrencies represent a source of opportunity for terrorist groups, allowing them to move funds across borders while
avoiding the regular banking scrutiny. . . . [By] the end of 2017 . . . [Islamic State] sympathisers triggered mass cryptocurrency (Bitcoin and
the more anonymous Zcash) donation campaigns in [Islamic State] affiliated websites as well as in chat environments (e.g. Telegram) to
support their cause.”).
87
Id. at 47. In 2014, the FBI and DEA shut down Silk Road, perhaps the most infamous Darknet market. Id.
88
Sean Foley, Jonathan R. Karlsen & Tālis J. Putniņš, Sex, Drugs, and Bitcoin: How Much Illegal Activity Is Financed Through Cryptocurrencies?,
OXFORD L.: OXFORD BUS. L. BLOG (Feb. 19, 2018), https://www.law.ox.ac.uk/business-law-blog/blog/2018/02/sex-drugs-and-bitcoin-howmuch-illegal-activity-financed-through [https://perma.cc/G9B6-BMPB] (“For example, approximately one-quarter of all users (25%) and
close to one-half of bitcoin transactions (44%) are associated with illegal activity. The estimated 24 million bitcoin market participants that
use bitcoin primarily for illegal purposes (as at April 2017) annually conduct around 36 million transactions, with a value of around $72
billion, and collectively hold around $8 billion worth of bitcoin. To give these numbers some context, the total market for illegal drugs in
the US and Europe is estimated to be around $100 billion and €24 billion annually.”).
89
Bech & Garratt, supra note 35, at 64.
90
DAVID CHAUM, Blind Signatures for Untraceable Payments, in ADVANCES IN CRYPTOLOGY, PROCEEDINGS OF CRYPTO 82 199, 199 (1983).
13
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
the government or company collecting the data fully aligned with the user’s interests, others—such as
foreign states or rogue hackers—could also be trying to get ahold of that information.
Monetary Policy
Provocatively, CBDC could expand the Federal Reserve’s arsenal for controlling monetary policy in two
respects. For the purposes of this briefing, please consider how CBDC’s implications for monetary policy
relate to discussions on whether consumers’ usage of currency should fall outside or within the control of
the central bank. 91 This analysis should include how the controversial nature of these policies may impact
the political economy.
First, replacing cash with an interest-bearing digital currency could grant the Federal Reserve a powerful
new instrument for effectuating negative interest rates 92—which means that the user pays the central
bank to store its currency—a policy theorized to discourage users from hoarding money and stimulate
spending in the economy. Because cash has no interest rate, a central bank’s ability to cut interest rates
becomes constrained when it approaches negative interest rate territory, as people can convert their
holdings in the banking system into cash. However, if cash were to be supplanted by an interest-bearing
CBDC, the Federal Reserve could overcome this effective lower bound. 93
Second, account-based CBDCs would enable the Federal Reserve to proactively airdrop funds into the
accounts of consumers as another way of encouraging spending. 94 Some argue that such “helicopter
drops” would operate more directly and precisely than reliance on quantitative easing, interest rate
adjustments or commercial bank lending. 95 Furthermore, helicopter drops can be performed universally
on all accounts or on a selective basis, depending on the relevant situation. 96
These options would come at severe political cost, which you should account for in your briefing
preparations. First, the imposition of negative interest rates assumes a feasible path towards eliminating
cash. As a matter of practical reality, the abolition of cash and the threat of negative interest rates would
confirm the suspicions held by broad demographic swaths of the country about the Federal Reserve’s
ambitions for repressing financial autonomy (see Appendix Item 13 and Appendix Item 18). Second,
helicopter drops overtly tread into controversial decisions about redistribution—for example, decisions
91
NOTE: An economic policy division is handling the precise implications on monetary policy so no need for you to closely parse the economic
technicalities or the merits of deploying the following policies for the purposes of our briefing.
92
See Kenneth Rogoff, Dealing with Monetary Paralysis at the Zero Bound, 31 J. OF ECON. PERSPS., Summer 2017, at 47, 57–58 (2017).
93
See id.
94
Some suggest that helicopter drops could also be performed by token-based CBDC, see, e.g., Mike Bird, HSBC Says the Blockchain Could Be
Used for “Helicopter Money,” BUS. INSIDER (Nov. 9, 2015), https://www.businessinsider.com/hsbc-says-the-blockchain-could-be-used-forradical-central-bank-helicopter-money-policies-2015-11?r=UK&IR=T [https://perma.cc/7PT9-KJDZ], but this mechanism would likely be less
straightforward, see DYSON AND HODGSON, supra note 79, at 22 (“[I]t would be extremely easy for the Bank of England to make small and
regular ‘helicopter drops’ to every citizen, as a tool of monetary policies.”).
95
DYSON & HODGSON, supra note 79, at 2 & 8.
96
For example, the government could selectively use helicopter drops for lower-income households to stimulate spending and “cushion[]
their purchasing power from the effects of the downturn as well as from the temporarily negative level of the CBDC interest rate,” Michael
D. Bordo & Andrew T. Levin, Central Bank Digital Currency and the Future of Monetary Policy 3 n.10 (Hoover Institution, Econ. Working
Paper 17104, Aug. 2017); see also DYSON & HODGSON, supra note 79, at 8; MANCINI-GRIFFOLI ET AL., supra note 64, at 16 n.22 (“[Helicopter
drops] would not necessarily reach all citizens.”).
14
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
about how much money should be delivered and to whom. 97 Both actions would provoke public backlash
and reignite critiques of the democratic legitimacy and institutional independence of the Federal
Reserve. 98
Seigniorage
Seigniorage, the profit made by the central bank from its issuance of currency (a function of the currency’s
face value minus production and distribution costs), 99 forms a vital source of revenue for the Federal
Reserve System and the U.S. Treasury (that is the American taxpayer). 100 Because of its status as the
leading international reserve currency, the U.S. dollar generates substantial seigniorage revenues
compared to other national currencies. 101 Seigniorage is particularly pronounced for high-denomination
bills (namely $100 bills), which account for nearly 80% of the total value of U.S. dollars in supply 102 and
also enjoy high demand outside the United States. 103 The Federal Reserve System does not rely on
congressional appropriations, 104 which could fluctuate based on political pressures. The independent
funding of the Federal Reserve provides an additional safeguard for its institutional autonomy and
independent policymaking. 105
Seigniorage revenues would decline if demand for U.S. currency decreases. Cash’s share in payment
amounts has dropped considerably over recent years. Its decline could continue if users begin to favor
cryptocurrencies or foreign currencies over U.S. currency, whether in the form of paper notes or digital
notes. Although for now these concerns remain far from compelling, further developments in
97
MANCINI-GRIFFOLI ET AL., supra note 64, at 16 n.22 (“[T]he issue of legitimacy remains: how does the central bank decide how much to
transfer to each household given the notable and very explicit redistributional consequences? Finally, helicopter drops would continue to
be viewed as a form of monetary financing, thus undermining central bank independence.”).
98
See BARR, JACKSON & TAHYAR, supra note 5, at 49 (“The Federal Reserve Board’s power, however, remains controversial, and many critics
want the Federal Reserve Board weakened or abolished. Critics allege that the Federal Reserve Board is secretive and undemocratic. . . .”);
see also PAUL TUCKER, UNELECTED POWER: THE QUEST FOR LEGITIMACY IN CENTRAL B ANKING AND THE REGULATORY STATE (2018).
99
ENGERT & FUNG, supra note 11, at 3.
100 See Who Owns the Federal Reserve?, FAQs, FED. RES., https://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/about_14986.htm [https://perma.cc/Q8GL-
XHLR] (“[T]he Federal Reserve Banks are required by law to transfer net earnings to the U.S. Treasury, after providing for all necessary
expenses of the Federal Reserve Banks, legally required dividend payments, and maintaining a limited balance in a surplus fund.”).
101 To illustrate, the Federal Reserve Banks transferred to the U.S. Treasury $97.7 billion, $91.5 billion, $80.2 billion, and $62.2 billion
(estimated) in earnings remittances in 2015, 2016, 2017, and 2018, respectively. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Press
Release: Federal Reserve Board announces Federal Reserve Bank income and expense data and transfers to the Treasury for 2018 (Jan. 10,
2019), https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/other20190110a.htm [https://perma.cc/QPH5-8SUS].
102 Kenneth S. Rogoff, The Curse of Cash 3 & 51 (2016).
103 See Ruth Judson, Big Note, Small Note: Central Bank Digital Currency and Cash, in DO WE NEED CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY? 33, 35 (2018)
(“[T]he estimates in Judson (2016) indicate that about 70% of $100s could be held abroad, with the rest held at home.”); ROGOFF, THE CURSE
OF CASH, supra note 102, at 39 (“[F]oreign holdings . . . might explain as much as 50% of US dollar holdings.”).
104 What Does It Mean that the Federal Reserve Is “Independent Within the Government”?, FAQs, FED. RES.,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/about_12799.htm [https://perma.cc/8FYQ-JVNE] (Mar. 1, 2017) (“The Federal Reserve does not
receive funding through the congressional budgetary process.”); Who Owns the Federal Reserve?, FAQs, FED. RES.,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/about_14986.htm [https://perma.cc/3M4A-8MNM].
105 Christopher J. Waller, Independence + Accountability: Why the Fed Is a Well-Designed Central Bank, FED. RES. BANK OF ST. LOUIS REV. 293, 298
(2011) (“[A] common method for politicians to entice government agencies is to threaten to cut the agencies’ budgets. . . . To counteract
this possibility, Congress gave the Federal Reserve budget autonomy when it created the Fed in 1913. The Fed was given the power to earn
its own income and spend it without government interference.”).
15
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
stablecoins—currently mostly experimental 106—and non-U.S. CBDCs—currently mostly conceptual 107—
could provide an appealing alternative to the U.S. dollar. On the other hand, some have argued that
developing a U.S. CBDC could recover leakage of or even exceed the seigniorage from U.S. cash.108 This,
of course, hinges on the perhaps overoptimistic assumption that future demand for a U.S. CBDC would
match or exceed the existing demand for U.S. cash. Indeed, replacing cash with a CBDC that fails to appeal
to users could inadvertently hasten the decline of seigniorage.
Financial Stability
Some academics worry that a retail CBDC that resembles bank deposits could raise the costs of deposittaking for commercial banks, thereby reducing their ability to perform productive lending. Since CBDC
would be backed by the U.S. government, it would pose a safer alternative to bank deposits, which would
be guaranteed only up to the deposit insurance limit of $250,000 per depositor. 109 There is a policy
question whether it is sensible for the U.S. government to provide what would be, in effect, unlimited
insurance of deposit funds. In times of crisis, the qualities of CBDC having the “safety of physical cash but
convenience of bank deposit accounts” 110 could induce depositors to flee from depository institutions
towards the central bank, thereby weakening financial stability.111 Indeed, the traditional bank run has
been caused by depositors converting bank deposits into cash. A conversion of bank deposits into CBDC
would have a similar impact on bank balance sheets and stability. Unlike a traditional bank run, the speed
and scale would likely be unprecedented since a digital run could be triggered at the click of a button. 112
Others, however, are less worried about financial stability. Some, including Professor Morgan Ricks,
embrace the perceived structural implications of expanding the central bank’s role and causing “largescale migration from bank deposits” to the central bank (see Appendix Item 14). 113 These proponents
take the view that radical disintermediation of the private banking sector from deposit-taking would
generate more financial stability, not less. The goals of these projects also include disintermediating the
private banking sector from the lending side as well.
106 Stablecoins seek to overcome the volatility endemic among cryptocurrencies. Specifically, they are a type of cryptoasset for which the
value is pegged to the value of another asset, such as the U.S. dollar, gold, or algorithmic pricing based on circulation supply. Santiago
Fernández de Lis, Central Bank Digital Currencies: Features, Options, Pros and Cons, in DO WE NEED CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY? 46, 54
(2018).
107 BARONTINI & HOLDEN, supra note 47, at 1 (“The survey shows that, although a majority of central banks are researching CBDCs, this work is
primarily conceptual and only a few intend to issue a CBDC in the short to medium term.”).
108 See DYSON & HODGSON, supra note 79, at 11–12; see also Morgan Ricks, John Crawford & Lev Menand, A Public Option for Bank Accounts (or
Central Banking for All) 16–17 (Vanderbilt Univ. Law Sch., Research Paper No. 18-33, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3192162
[https://perma.cc/24MT-8U5Q].
109 But see MANCINI-GRIFFOLI ET AL., supra note 64, at 25 (commenting that while deposit insurance does not immunize banks from runs, it
significantly mitigates the risk).
110 DYSON & HODGSON, supra note 79, at 27.
111 CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 16.
112 Id.
113 Morgan Ricks, John Crawford & Lev Menand, A Public Option for Bank Accounts (or Central Banking for All) 2 & 17 (Vanderbilt Univ. L. Sch.,
Research Paper No. 18-33, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3192162 [https://perma.cc/7H4V-4J7Q]. While Professor Ricks and his
coauthors would prefer “more traditional nomenclature,” id. at 25–26, his FedAccount proposal is an example of a universally accessible,
accounts-based CBDC.
16
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Cybersecurity
While offering convenience and efficiencies, digitization also carries risks of cyberthreats, including
malware and fraud. 114 Cybersecurity is a significant operational risk and central banks are not immune to
hacks. 115 In fact, instituting a CBDC could elevate the profile of the central bank as a target for
cyberattacks. 116 The likelihood and severity of cyberattacks would be further exacerbated for a CBDC that
enjoys reserve currency status and is universally accessible and would open the platform to “many
participants and points of attack.” 117
Options for a U.S. Central Bank Digital Currency
The two proposed CBDCs aim to ease the convenience and costs of payment systems and enhance
monetary policy implementation. With this background in mind, please consider the three options
discussed below. Both proposed CBDCs would be issued by Federal Reserve Banks, denominated in U.S.
dollar, and convertible with other forms of money; similar to cash, both CBDCs would be deemed legal
tender. As a third option, consider whether it would be more prudent to adopt a wait-and-see approach
and stick with the existing system.
Option 1: Fedcoin
Fedcoin is a digital token built on a permissioned blockchain (“Fedchain”) 118 and issued by the Federal
Reserve Banks. Unlike permissionless cryptocurrency, like Bitcoin, the production of Fedcoin would be
managed and controlled by the Federal Reserve Banks, which would also serve as the only trusted parties
in the network. Federal Reserve Banks would possess the ability to create and destroy Fedcoin in order to
preserve a 1:1 conversion ratio between Fedcoin and the dollar. Although Federal Reserve Banks would
maintain Fedcoin’s value, approved nodes would maintain the ledger’s verification, validating new
transactions and screening out counterfeiting and double spending. These nodes would be operated by a
select group of large commercial banks approved by the Federal Reserve Banks.
Users could not directly access Fedcoin through an account at a Federal Reserve Bank, but instead must
withdraw Fedcoin from their commercial bank accounts. Once withdrawn, the Fedcoin would become
anonymous to the bank. Subsequently, Fedcoin could be stored in digital wallets provided by various
private sector firms (e.g., banks or fintech companies) certified by a Federal Reserve Bank. Anyone who
purchases and installs the requisite wallet software into a smartphone or personal computer would be
able to store and pay with Fedcoin. A user could set up as many addresses for the wallet as he or she
wishes. Once the wallet is set up, a user could engage in transactions in a similar way to Bitcoin.
114 CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 10.
115 Other Federal institutions have demonstrated vulnerability to cyberattacks. See, e.g., Jim Sciutto, OPM Government Data Breach Impacted
21.5 Million, CNN (July 10, 2015), https://www.cnn.com/2015/07/09/politics/office-of-personnel-management-data-breach-20million/index.html [https://perma.cc/XQK8-JZ99] (“Government investigators now believe that the data theft from the Office of Personnel
Management computer systems compromised sensitive personal information, including Social Security numbers, of roughly 21.5 million
people from both inside and outside the government, the government announced Thursday.”).
116 Brainard, supra note 34.
117 CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCIES, supra note 10, at 10.
118 NOTE: Among other things, Fedchain would overcome Bitcoin’s technological constraints of scalability.
17
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
As mentioned before, the nodes would be operated by large commercial banks approved by the Federal
Reserve Banks and would validate Fedcoin transactions between users. These entities would also use
Fedcoin for their own payments. As an incentive for operating these nodes, those responsible for
validation will be able to collect transaction fees. If consensus is reached by these nodes, the approved
Fedcoin transaction would be recorded on the Fedchain. Although Fedchain would be a public ledger, only
transaction amounts and party addresses would be viewable.
Option 2: Fedcount
Fedcount offers a new account-based money created and held by the Federal Reserve Banks. Unlike
master accounts, Fedcounts would be generally accessible to the nonbank public for holding electronic
money. Fedcounts would hold electronic money for all users who register with their Federal Reserve Bank.
To prevent fraud and enable instantaneous verification, registration with a Federal Reserve Bank and login
to Fedcount would require fingerprint and/or facial recognition, which is already technologically feasible
with smartphones. After successful login, users could review the account balance and transaction history
of the Fedcount but nothing else. The development of expanded interfaces for payments and other
functions would have to be provided by private sector firms, such as commercial banks. Such institutions
would administer the relevant services to make Fedcount suitable for a user’s needs in exchange for fees.
Integral functions to develop include the interfaces to initiate payments and to review more detailed
transaction summaries. Other functions would include internet coverage, periodic statements, and
customer support.
Although a commercial bank might administer Fedcounts, Fedcounts would be distinct from a deposit
account at a private bank because Fedcounts would be directly held at a Federal Reserve Bank and belong
to the account holder (i.e., the user). The relevant Fedcount administrator would only be responsible for
offering services associated with the Fedcount. Therefore, unlike with conventional bank accounts,
commercial banks providing Fedcounts would not be able to conduct lending with money housed within
Fedcounts. Moreover, money stored in Fedcount would represent a liability of the relevant Federal
Reserve Bank, not of the Fedcount administrator. Thus, according to the analysts, even if the bank
administering services to the Fedcount were to fail, the Fedcount would remain safe with the Federal
Reserve Bank.
Option 3: Neither
For the purposes of practicably advancing payment efficiencies and monetary policy implementation,
neither Fedcoin nor Fedcount would be superior to maintaining the existing infrastructure supporting
cash. It is therefore prudent to continue with the current system for the foreseeable future.
18
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Briefing Questions
Having examined the proposals, please review the materials included in the attached Appendix and
prepare to brief the director. In particular, the director is eager to know your thoughts as to the following:
1. What are the comparative strengths and weaknesses of Fedcoin and Fedcount? In what ways can
these proposals be improved?
2. What would be the likely reaction from financial sector stakeholders to these proposals? Consider the
following four examples:
•
Ames Bank is a depository institution located in Cambridge, Massachusetts. Its business
primarily consists of making loans to businesses, for which much of the funding is done through
deposit-taking.
•
BitBank is a cryptocurrency company that supports and develops wallets for Bitcoin and Bitcoinderived currencies. Its wallets do not have compatibility with other types of cryptocurrencies.
•
The Zcash Company supports and develops Zcash, which is a privacy-protecting digital currency.
Zcash features zero-knowledge proofs that allow the payee to prove the validity of a transaction
without revealing information about the transaction itself. This allows transactions to be fully
shielded from being traced within the public blockchain, thereby completely protecting the
users’ privacy.
•
Circle is a payment technology service that provides wallet services. Recently, the company also
purchased Poloniex, a prominent token exchange platform, as a step towards its goal of
becoming a trading exchange for cryptocurrencies.
3. Consider the following proposals made by our IT specialists:
•
For Fedcoin – IT specialists claim that Fedchain’s cybersecurity capabilities could be enhanced
by moving from a permissioned network of nodes to a permissionless network of nodes. They
argue that a permissionless network would offer more robust operational resilience as the
consensus mechanism could continue to operate should any node become unavailable or
compromised. What are the benefits and concerns?
•
For Fedcount – IT specialists insist that Fedcount has the technological capability of providing
more comprehensive services and greater financial inclusion for users if the Federal Reserve
assumed control over administering Fedcount’s payment and customer services. What are the
benefits and concerns?
4. Although cash is deemed legal tender, Federal law does not obligate a private business to accept cash
payments. Businesses retain discretion to accept payment in whatever form they prefer. Take for
example, bus lines that refuse pennies or convenience stores that refuse high-denominated bills.119
Other countries such as China and France take a different approach, making it generally unlawful for
payees to refuse notes and coins with the status of legal tender. What are the benefits and drawbacks
of these two approaches as applied to CBDC? How likely is the U.S. approach to change to this
119 Legal Tender Status, U.S. Dep’t of Treasury (Jan. 4, 2011), https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/faqs/currency/pages/legal-
tender.aspx [https://perma.cc/76QN-GBYN].
19
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
alternative approach? How should society weigh the payer’s right to choose between payment
methods with that of the payee’s?
5. As the readings suggest, many closely associate anonymity with privacy. Yet, the two are distinct.
Information can be private but not anonymous, such as transaction logs with personally identifying
information safeguarded by a bank; likewise, information could be anonymous but not private, such
as the sharing or disclosure of spending patterns aggregated across large numbers of users. Is this a
meaningful distinction? If so, how does it pertain to the conversation about CBDC?
6. How does CBDC, whether by its nature or by design choice, compare with the attributes of cash?
7. Circulation and usage of U.S. notes extends beyond U.S. citizenship and territoriality. On the other
hand, eligibility for master accounts with Federal Reserve Banks is limited to U.S. entities with a few
exceptions. What legal and policy considerations would be implicated if CBDC access is granted
internationally or restricted nationally? If the latter, should any controls be in place?
8. How would you rank the three options for purposes of payment efficiencies and monetary policy
implementation?
•
Would your conclusion change if the motivation for developing CBDC was instead to advance (i)
financial stability or (ii) financial inclusion (see footnote 19)? Is either financial stability or
financial inclusion a pressing objective for the Federal Reserve System?
20
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
Appendix
Speech by Governors of the Federal Reserve Board
•
Item 1: Remarks by Gov. Lael Brainard, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We
Learning? (May 15, 2018),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20180515a.htm
[https://perma.cc/4C96-79UN]. Attached.
Congressional Hearing – The Future of Money: Digital Currency, Hearing Before the Subcommittee on
Monetary Policy and Trade of the Committee on Financial Services, US House of Representatives (July
18, 2018).
•
Item 2: Transcript Excerpts of the Prepared Statement of Eswar S. Prasad. Attached.
Casebook – Michael S. Barr, Howell E. Jackson & Margaret E. Tahyar, Financial Regulation: Law and
Policy (2d ed. 2018).
•
Item 3: Excerpts of Chapters 1.2 and 9.1
IMF Publications
•
Item 4: Christine Lagarde, Managing Director, IMF, Winds of Change: The Case for New Digital
Currency (Nov. 14, 2018). Attached.
•
Item 5: Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli et al., IMF, Casting Light on Central Bank Digital Currency, IMF
Staff Discussion Note (Nov. 2018). Attached.
BIS Report
•
Item 6: Bank for International Settlements, Central Bank Digital Currencies (2018),
https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d174.pdf [https://perma.cc/E6ZB-4XHE]. Attached.
•
Item 7: Christian Barontini & Henry Holden, Bank for International Settlements, Proceeding with
Caution – A Survey on Central Bank Digital Currency (2019),
https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap101.pdf [https://perma.cc/E3Y5-PZ8K]. Attached.
Academic Articles
•
Item 8: Itai Agur, Central Bank Digital Currencies: An Overview of Pros and Cons, in Do We Need
Central Bank Digital Currency? (2018). Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 9: Aleksander Berentsen & Fabian Schär, The Case for Central Bank Electronic Money and
the Non-case for Central Bank Cryptocurrencies, 100, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Rev. 97
(2018). Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 10: Charles M. Kahn, Francisco Rivadeneyra & Tsz-Nga Wong, Should the Central Bank Issue
E-Money? (Oct. 2018), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3271654
[https://perma.cc/N8YN-CHNZ]. Not attached for reasons of copyright.
21
CRYPTOCURRENCY
CSP045
•
Item 11: Robert C. Hockett, Money’s Past Is Fintech’s Future: Wildcat Crypto, the Digital Dollar,
and Citizen Central Banking (Dec. 11, 2018),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3299555 [https://perma.cc/72HWXEXM]. Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 12: Kenneth Rogoff, Dealing with Monetary Paralysis at the Zero Bound, 31 Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Summer 2017, at 47 (2017). Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 13: Jeffrey Rogers Hummel, The War on Cash: A Review of Kenneth Rogoff’s The Curse of
Cash, 14 Econ Journal Watch, May 2017, at 138. Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 14: Morgan Ricks, John Crawford & Lev Menand, A Public Option for Bank Accounts (or
Central Banking for All) (Vanderbilt University Law School, Research Paper No. 18-33, 2018),
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3192162 [https://perma.cc/74U5-KUBF]. Not attached for reasons of
copyright.
News Articles
•
Item 15: Izabella Kaminska, When the State Takes on the Digital Float, the State Takes on the
Risk, Financial Times (Jan. 10, 2019),
https://ftalphaville.ft.com/2019/01/10/1547096400000/When-the-state-takes-on-the-digitalfloat--the-state-takes-on-the-risk/. Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 16: Nouriel Roubini, Central Bank Digital Currencies Will Destroy Cryptocurrencies, ING
Think (Nov. 19, 2018), https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/central-banks-takeover-digital-payments-no-cryptocurrencies-by-nouriel-roubini-2018-11 [https://perma.cc/DA7SS7WQ]. Not attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 17: Simon Scorer, Central Bank Digital Currency: DLT, or not DLT? That Is the Question,
Bank Underground (June 5, 2017), https://bankunderground.co.uk/2017/06/05/central-bankdigital-currency-dlt-or-not-dlt-that-is-the-question/ [https://perma.cc/UGY2-3VMG]. Not
attached for reasons of copyright.
•
Item 18: James Grant, Hostage to a Bull Market, Wall Street Journal (Sept. 9, 2016),
https://www.wsj.com/articles/hostage-to-a-bull-market-1473456611. Not attached for reasons
of copyright.
22
For release on delivery
7:00 p.m. EDT [4:00 p.m. PDT Local Time]
May 15, 2018
Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies:
What Are We Learning?
Remarks by
Lael Brainard
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Decoding Digital Currency Conference
Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
San Francisco, California
May 15, 2018
It is a pleasure to be here today. What better place to discuss digital currencies than in
San Francisco, home to so many technology innovators working on new ways to disrupt various
aspects of our daily lives? 1
Because of the transformative potential of digital currency and distributed ledger
technologies, the Federal Reserve is actively monitoring digital innovations in the financial
system. We have been keenly evaluating developments in fintech and digital currencies through
a multidisciplinary lens, combining information technology and policy analysis to study their
potential implications for payments policy, supervision and regulation, financial stability,
monetary policy, and the provision of financial services. This work draws from expertise
throughout the Federal Reserve System and benefits from engagement with our colleagues
internationally.
Cryptocurrencies
The past decade has seen a wave of important new developments in digital technologies
for payments, clearing, and settlement. Cryptocurrencies represent the leading edge of this
digital wave. And it was the advent a decade ago of Bitcoin, the first cryptocurrency, that first
gave shape to the vision of a decentralized digital currency.
At the heart of any cryptocurrency is the creation of a new type of asset--the unit of the
cryptocurrency itself--that is distinct from any traditional form of money used in routine
transactions, such as U.S. currency or checking accounts in commercial banks. A typical
cryptocurrency would not be a liability of any individual or institution. There is no trusted
institution standing behind it. This is in stark contrast to U.S. currency and reserve balances,
1
I am grateful to David Mills of the Federal Reserve Board for his assistance in preparing this text. The remarks
represent my own views, which do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal Open
Market Committee.
-2which are liabilities of the Federal Reserve Banks, and deposit accounts, which are liabilities of a
bank or another regulated depository institution backed by federal insurance up to a specific
level. And while a typical cryptocurrency may be used in payments, it is not legal tender, in
contrast to U.S. currency.
A typical cryptocurrency relies on the use of distributed ledger technology, which
provides a new way to keep ownership records and transfer ownership from one user to another,
often with little to no information about the identity of the owner. For instance, Bitcoin relies on
the blockchain, which is run by anonymous computers all over the world linked together through
a ledger of anonymized transactions. Digital currencies use automation via computer processing
power, networking via the internet, and cryptography to transfer value from one person to
another. What is innovative is that the computer code behind these transactions uses automated
checks and balances to validate the sender and receiver, and whether there is enough value in the
sender’s account to make the payment. Traditionally, this validation would be done by banks
and payment networks. Instead, with a cryptocurrency, this validation could be done by anyone
with enough computing power and resources to participate. Importantly, this technology is not
owned or managed by any entity--regulated or not--that would be responsible for its
maintenance, security, and reliability. Rather, its maintenance, security, and reliability are
handled by a decentralized developer community, which often lacks strong governance.
This combination of a new asset, which is not a liability of any individual or institution,
and a new recordkeeping and transfer technology, which is not maintained by any single
individual or institution, illustrates the powerful capabilities of today’s technologies. But there
are also serious challenges. For instance, cryptocurrencies have exhibited periods of extreme
volatility. If you purchased Bitcoin in December 2017 at a value of over $19,000, your
-3electronic claims would be worth close to half that today. 2 Indeed, Bitcoin’s value has been
known to fluctuate by one-quarter in one day alone. Such extreme fluctuations limit an asset’s
ability to fulfill two of the classic functions of money: to act as a stable store of value that
people can hold and use predictably in the future, and to serve as a meaningful unit of account
that can be used to assign a comparable value of goods and services.
In addition to losses, individual investors should be careful to understand the potential for
other risks. 3 Cryptocurrencies may raise important investor and consumer protection issues.
The lack of strong governance and questions about the applicable legal framework for some
cryptocurrencies may make consumers vulnerable to mistakes, thefts, and security breaches
without much, or any, recourse. Although the cryptographic technology may be robust to some
events, such as the fraudulent double spending of the same units of the cryptocurrency for more
than one transaction, the large number of breaches at some cryptocurrency exchanges and wallet
providers suggest that significant vulnerabilities may remain with respect to security protections
around customers’ accounts. 4 These breaches remind us that relying solely on cryptography
within the transfer technology is not enough. Ultimately, a more holistic approach to the security
of the broader cryptocurrency ecosystem, along with added layers of security on top of
cryptography, are likely to be necessary for cryptocurrencies to be widely adopted.
Some cryptocurrencies also appear quite vulnerable to money-laundering (BSA/AML, or
Bank Secrecy Act/anti-money-laundering) concerns. Since many cryptocurrencies store in their
2
See, for example, https://www.coinbase.com/charts.
Lael Brainard, “An Update on the Federal Reserve’s Financial Stability Agenda” (speech delivered at the Center
for Global Economy and Business, Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY, April 3, 2018),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20180403a.htm.
4
For example, Coincheck, a Tokyo-based cryptocurrency exchange was hacked in 2018. See
https://www.wsj.com/articles/cryptocurrency-worth-530-million-missing-from-japanese-exchange-1516988190. A
similar attack occurred back in 2014 to another Tokyo-based cryptocurrency exchange, Mt. Gox. See
https://www.wsj.com/articles/mt-gox-to-hold-news-conference-1393579356.
3
-4ledger little to no information about the identity of owners of the cryptocurrency, this essentially
mimics a bearer instrument--that is, an instrument whereby the holder of the instrument is
presumed to be its owner. Further, cryptocurrencies are easy to transfer across borders. Indeed,
a cryptocurrency that mimics a bearer instrument and provides significant anonymity in
transactions, including across borders, could raise significant concerns regarding the potential to
facilitate illicit activities and associated money laundering. For example, electronic instruments
can be easily transferred and stored in large amounts, and peer-to-peer transactions outside of the
United States could be very hard to prevent and detect. Such instruments appear to have proven
susceptible for use to convey payments to illicit actors--for example, to pay ransoms.
Overall, however, the still relatively small scale of cryptocurrencies in relation to our
broader financial system and relatively limited connections to our banking sector suggest that
they do not currently pose a threat to financial stability. 5 Of course, if cryptocurrencies were to
achieve wide-scale use, or their impact were greatly magnified through leverage, the effects
could be broader. In particular, adverse developments and shifts in sentiment could cause a
global rush to exit this market. As we have seen in other speculative activity in the past, rushfor-the-exits behavior can aggravate price fluctuations, create trading difficulties, and even
induce market breakdowns. Thus, we will continue to monitor cryptocurrencies as they evolve,
with particular vigilance for any signs of growing materiality to the broader financial system.
Central Bank Digital Currencies
Given some of the inherent issues and challenges that cryptocurrencies pose for investor
and consumer protection and the prevention of money laundering, some have advocated that
central banks should create their own digital forms of currency as more stable and reliable
5
See https://g20.org/sites/default/files/media/communique_-_fmcbg_march_2018.pdf.
-5alternatives to cryptocurrencies. After all, a central bank digital currency could overcome the
volatility risks associated with an unbacked asset with no intrinsic value by substituting a digital
instrument that is the direct liability of the central bank. Moreover, advocates suggest a central
bank would be able to develop a transfer mechanism that has robust governance.
Even though central bank digital currencies may at first glance appear to address a
number of challenges associated with the current crop of cryptocurrencies, this appeal may not
withstand closer scrutiny. 6 First, there are serious technical and operational challenges that
would need to be overcome, such as the risk of creating a global target for cyberattacks or a
ready means of money laundering. For starters, with regard to money laundering risks, unless
there is the technological capability for effective identity authentication, a central bank digital
currency would provide no improvement over physical notes and could be worse than current
noncash funds transfer systems, especially for a digital currency that could circulate worldwide.
In addition, putting a central bank currency in digital form could make it a very attractive target
for cyberattacks by giving threat actors a prominent platform on which to focus their efforts.
Any implementation would need to adequately deal with a variety of cyber threats--especially for
a reserve currency like the U.S. dollar.
Second, the issuance of central bank digital currency could have implications for retail
banking beyond payments. If a successful central bank digital currency were to become widely
used, it could become a substitute for retail banking deposits. This could restrict banks’ ability to
make loans for productive economic activities and have broader macroeconomic consequences.
Moreover, the parallel coexistence of central bank digital currency with retail banking deposits
6
See, for example, the recent joint Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures and Markets Committee
report “Central Bank Digital Currencies,” March 2018, https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d174.pdf. A Fed-issued
digital currency might have implications for the rates and terms of funding for U.S. financial institutions and even
the U.S. government as well as the transmission of monetary policy that I will not discuss here.
-6could raise the risk of runs on the banking system in times of stress and so have adverse
implications for financial stability.
Finally, there is no compelling demonstrated need for a Fed-issued digital currency.
Most consumers and businesses in the U.S. already make retail payments electronically using
debit and credit cards, payment applications, and the automated clearinghouse network.
Moreover, people are finding easy ways to make digital payments directly to other people
through a variety of mobile apps. New private-sector real-time payments solutions are beginning
to gain acceptance in the United States. And the Faster Payments Task Force has laid out a
roadmap embraced by a variety of stakeholders for a fast, ubiquitous, and secure payments
system to be in place in the United States in the next few years. 7 In short, a multiplicity of
mechanisms are likely to be available for American consumers to make payments electronically
in real time. As such, it is not obvious what additional value a Fed-issued digital currency would
provide over and above these options.
Wholesale Digital Settlement Tokens
It is important for the Fed and other central banks to continue to research these issues as
technology evolves, exploring the technical and economic possibilities and limitations of centralbank-issued digital currencies. Even though the case for a digital currency for general use may
not be compelling, opportunities for more targeted and restricted use may nonetheless prove to
have value. The private sector has been exploring a variety of ways of deploying the underlying
technologies of digital assets that are native to a particular wholesale platform, to help to
7
See https://fedpaymentsimprovement.org/faster-payments/path-to-faster-payments/.
-7facilitate finality of settlement. Such wholesale digital settlement tokens could potentially
reduce the time and costs required for wholesale financial transactions. This is being discussed,
for instance, for the use cases of interbank payments, securities settlements, and cross-border
transactions, where the introduction of a digital token native to a platform may facilitate certain
types of settlement.
Likewise, it is possible at some point in the future that a limited central bank digital
instrument that serves as a settlement asset for wholesale payment and settlement activity may
hold some promise. Several central banks have been studying this issue, and we have been
actively watching these developments. 8 We are also interested in work that decouples the
underlying distributed ledger technology from cryptocurrencies and attempts to build on the
benefits of the technology, a topic to which I now turn.
Distributed Ledger Technology
Even if cryptocurrencies prove to have a very limited role in the future, the technology
behind them is likely to live on and offer improvements in the way we transfer and record more
traditional financial assets. Distributed ledger technology could also facilitate other applications
that could improve the way we share information, validate possessions, and handle logistics.
Recall that distributed ledger technology is the mechanism for recordkeeping and transfer
of ownership that underpins cryptocurrencies. Over the past few years, the financial industry has
conducted a great deal of research and development on how to adapt the more promising aspects
of distributed ledger technology for use with more traditional financial assets. The industry has
moved a number of these projects through a series of phases, often developing more incremental
changes at first in order to gain confidence in the technology before tackling large projects with
8
For example, see Bank of Canada’s Project Jasper, https://www.bankofcanada.ca/research/digital-currencies-andfintech/fintech-experiments-and-projects/.
-8significant operational impacts. The industry is making steady progress and some projects could
be live in some form this year.
Many of the use cases focus on the areas of post-trade clearing and settlement of
securities transactions, cross-border payments solutions, and trade finance. The common thread
running through these use cases is the presence of operational “pain points” that generate
inefficiencies and delays for users. For example, post-trade reconciliation of securities
transactions can be a time-consuming and resource-intensive process that involves numerous
parties, operational steps, and message flows across the counterparties and their various agents
involved in the transactions. Distributed ledger technology has the potential to provide
synchronized, real-time views for those counterparties and agents that can speed up the process
and reduce errors.
For cross-border transactions, the process for sending payments via the existing
correspondent banking network can add time and money. Distributed ledger technology could
potentially lower the costs and time it takes funds to reach the recipient through more direct
connections, reducing the number of intermediaries required to effect the transaction.
The financial industry has been working on versions of distributed ledger technology that
help address a number of concerns, including the loose governance around the maintenance,
security, and reliability of the technology for cryptocurrencies. Most projects are organized
either as partnerships between technology and financial services firms or through consortia of
technology firms, financial firms, and other interested parties. To some degree, these alliances
may provide prototype governance arrangements for future technology deployments in financial
services. In addition, there are exchanges and clearinghouses that are actively exploring the use
of distributed ledger technology, which represent the more traditional model of multilateral
-9organization in the financial markets. Although the governance arrangements may need to
evolve over time, one thing that is clear is that strong governance arrangements will be required
to provide the coordinated operational and financial risk management for the critical clearing and
settlement operations that underpin our financial markets.
In addition, the industry continues to make progress on the ability of distributed ledger
technology to handle the very large volumes of transactions that take place both in financial
markets and in retail payments every day. As I highlighted in 2016, this technical challenge of
achieving the necessary scale and through put is an important hurdle. 9 Much of this challenge
has been tied to the time it takes to achieve “consensus” on a distributed ledger. Consensus is
the process by which new transactions are broadcast to all the participants, or nodes, in the
network and each node accepts those new transactions as valid additions to the ledger. The
initial consensus method used by Bitcoin, called “proof of work,” is designed to deal with the
lack of information and trust among the users of the network by providing tools and incentives to
overcome this problem. But it is a highly resource-intensive process that limits the number of
transactions that can be processed each second. The proof of work consensus model represents a
tradeoff between operational efficiency and scalability, on the one hand, and the ability to
operate without sufficient trust or information about the entities in the network, on the other
hand.
Fundamentally, however, the financial industry does not operate as a trustless network.
Rather, the industry has long specialized in the collection and analysis of information about
9
Lael Brainard, “The Use of Distributed Ledger Technologies in Payment, Clearing, and Settlement” (speech
delivered at the Institute of International Finance Blockchain Roundtable, Washington, DC, April 14, 2016),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20160414a.htm; and Lael Brainard, “Distributed Ledger
Technology: Implications for Payments, Clearing, and Settlement” (speech delivered at the Institute of International
Finance Annual Meeting Panel on Blockchain, Washington, DC, October 7, 2016),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20161007a.htm.
- 10 customers and counterparties as a core part of banking operations. Even allowing for the
inevitable imperfect information that may result, it would seem natural for the financial industry
to be able to leverage institutional information and trust in ways that allow for more efficient
methods to achieve consensus than proof of work. Consequently, the industry and the academic
community have focused a great deal of attention on various consensus methods that can provide
greater scalability either by leveraging trust, which relaxes some operational and incentive
constraints, or possibly by devising methods without trust that are much less resource intensive.
Some of the technology firms working with the financial industry are taking different approaches
in this fast-moving arena.
Another important challenge for the industry has been leveraging distributed ledger
technology while preserving the confidentiality of transactional information. At its core,
distributed ledger technology is a shared ledger across multiple nodes in a network, likely
representing multiple firms and legal entities. Ownership records and transactions flows from
accounts on such a ledger are typically copied and stored on all the nodes in the network. The
financial industry, however, must develop distributed ledgers that adhere to laws, regulations,
and policies that protect important information of the parties and their customers. Clearly, a
model where every entity on the network can see everyone else’s account holdings and
transactions history will not satisfy broad industry confidentiality requirements. In addition,
stored data that may be protected cryptographically today may not be protected as the technology
continues to advance, which adds even more difficulty and urgency to the work on
confidentiality.
The industry has been working to develop approaches to preserve confidentiality so that
only the authorized parties relevant to a transaction can see the details recorded on the ledger.
- 11 Some of these approaches involve encrypting data on the ledger so that the ledgers can still be
copied across all the nodes in the network, but an entity cannot look at any element of that ledger
except for transactions in which it has been involved. Other approaches include so-called zeroknowledge proofs or ring signatures that allow entities to validate transactions without seeing
confidential information. Still others are looking at platforms that connect multiple ledgers
rather than having one single ledger that is copied across all nodes in the network. While
questions remain about the usefulness and viability of each of these approaches, it is important to
underscore that preserving confidentiality is an important area of research.
Finally, perhaps the biggest potential benefit for payments, clearing, and settlement of
distributed ledger technology may be resiliency. Distributed ledger technology may enable a
network to continue to operate even if some of the nodes on the network are compromised
because of the ability of the other nodes in the network to pick up the slack and continue
processing transactions. One challenge going forward will be to understand the implications that
the confidentiality tools and different approaches to consensus under consideration may have on
the resilience of the distributed ledger. Given that resiliency is a key potential benefit of
distributed ledger technology over existing platforms, it is critical to understand the trade-offs
between resiliency and a consensus method that focuses on operational speed, or between
resilience and confidentiality.
Conclusion
It is an exciting time for the financial sector as digital innovations are challenging
conventional thinking about currency, money, and payments. Cryptocurrencies are strikingly
innovative but also pose challenges associated with speculative dynamics, investor and consumer
protections, and money-laundering risks. Although central bank digital currencies may be able
- 12 to overcome some of the particular vulnerabilities that cryptocurrencies face, they too have
significant challenges related to cybersecurity, money laundering, and the retail financial system.
Even so, digital tokens for wholesale payments and some aspects of distributed ledger
technology--the key technologies underlying cryptocurrencies--may hold promise for
strengthening traditional financial instruments and markets. I have highlighted a few key areas
where the technology is advancing to deal with some important policy, business, and operational
challenges. The Federal Reserve is dedicated to continuing to monitor industry developments
and conduct research in these vital areas. I remain optimistic that the financial sector will find
valuable ways to employ distributed ledger technology in the area of payments, clearing, and
settlement in coming years.
THE FUTURE OF MONEY:
DIGITAL CURRENCY
HEARING
BEFORE THE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON MONETARY
POLICY AND TRADE
OF THE
COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES
U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION
JULY 18, 2018
Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services
Serial No. 115–111
(
U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE
WASHINGTON
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
31–510 PDF
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00001
Fmt 5011
:
2018
Sfmt 5011
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES
JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman
PATRICK T. MCHENRY, North Carolina,
Vice Chairman
PETER T. KING, New York
EDWARD R. ROYCE, California
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico
BILL POSEY, Florida
BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri
BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan
SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin
STEVE STIVERS, Ohio
RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois
DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida
ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina
ANN WAGNER, Missouri
ANDY BARR, Kentucky
KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania
LUKE MESSER, Indiana
SCOTT TIPTON, Colorado
ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas
BRUCE POLIQUIN, Maine
MIA LOVE, Utah
FRENCH HILL, Arkansas
TOM EMMER, Minnesota
LEE M. ZELDIN, New York
DAVID A. TROTT, Michigan
BARRY LOUDERMILK, Georgia
ALEXANDER X. MOONEY, West Virginia
THOMAS MACARTHUR, New Jersey
WARREN DAVIDSON, Ohio
TED BUDD, North Carolina
DAVID KUSTOFF, Tennessee
CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York
TREY HOLLINGSWORTH, Indiana
MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking
Member
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
NYDIA M. VELÁZQUEZ, New York
BRAD SHERMAN, California
GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York
MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts
WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri
STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts
DAVID SCOTT, Georgia
AL GREEN, Texas
EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri
GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin
KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota
ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado
JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut
BILL FOSTER, Illinois
DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan
JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland
KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona
JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio
DENNY HECK, Washington
JUAN VARGAS, California
JOSH GOTTHEIMER, New Jersey
VICENTE GONZALEZ, Texas
CHARLIE CRIST, Florida
RUBEN KIHUEN, Nevada
SHANNON MCGAHN, Staff Director
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
(II)
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 5904
Sfmt 5904
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
SUBCOMMITTEE
ON
MONETARY POLICY
AND
TRADE
ANDY BARR, Kentucky, Chairman
ROGER WILLIAMS, Texas, Vice Chairman
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan
ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina
MIA LOVE, Utah
FRENCH HILL, Arkansas
TOM EMMER, Minnesota
ALEXANDER X. MOONEY, West Virginia
WARREN DAVIDSON, Ohio
CLAUDIA TENNEY, New York
TREY HOLLINGSWORTH, Indiana
GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin, Ranking Member
GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York
BILL FOSTER, Illinois
BRAD SHERMAN, California
AL GREEN, Texas
DENNY HECK, Washington
DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan
JUAN VARGAS, California
CHARLIE CRIST, Florida
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
(III)
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 5904
Sfmt 5904
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 5904
Sfmt 5904
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
CONTENTS
Page
Hearing held on:
July 18, 2018 .....................................................................................................
Appendix:
July 18, 2018 .....................................................................................................
1
23
WITNESSES
WEDNESDAY, JULY 18, 2018
Garratt, Rodney J., Maxwell C. and Mary Pellish Chair, Professor of Economics, University of California Santa Barbara ......................................................
Michel, Norbert J., Director, Center for Data Analysis, The Heritage Foundation ........................................................................................................................
Pollock, Alex J., Distinguished Senior Fellow, R Street Institute .......................
Prasad,
Eswar
S.,
Tolani
Senior
Professor
of
Trade
Policy,
Cornell University ................................................................................................
5
7
10
9
APPENDIX
Prepared statements:
Garratt, Rodney J. ............................................................................................
Michel, Norbert J. .............................................................................................
Pollock, Alex J. .................................................................................................
Prasad, Eswar S. ..............................................................................................
24
30
39
44
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
(V)
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 5904
Sfmt 5904
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
APPENDIX
July 18, 2018
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
(23)
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 6601
Sfmt 6601
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 6601
Sfmt 6601
Insert offset folio 21 here 31510.021
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
44
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00067
Fmt 6601
Sfmt 6601
Insert offset folio 38 here 31510.038
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
61
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
62
VerDate Sep 11 2014
07:37 Nov 15, 2018
Jkt 000000
PO 00000
Frm 00068
Fmt 6601
Sfmt 6011
Insert offset folio 39 here 31510.039
nshattuck on FSR297 with DISTILLER
Æ
G:\GPO PRINTING\DOCS\115TH HEARINGS - 2ND SESSION 2018\2018-07-18 MPT DIGIT
CHAPTER 1.2
THE HISTORY OF U.S. FINANCIAL
REGULATION: A THEMATIC
OVERVIEW
CONTENTS
I.
INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................ 34
II.
THE FIRST AND SECOND BANKS OF THE UNITED STATES (1790–1863) .......... 34
A. The First Bank of the United States ...................................................... 34
B. The Second Bank of the United States .................................................. 36
C. Jackson’s War Against the Second Bank ............................................... 37
D. The Free Banking Era ............................................................................ 38
III.
THE RISE OF NATIONAL BANKS (1863–1914) .................................................. 39
A. Uniform National Currency.................................................................... 40
B. The Dual Banking System ...................................................................... 40
C. Unit Banks and Correspondent Banking............................................... 41
D. Interbank Deposits in the Reserve Structure ........................................ 42
IV.
THE CREATION OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM (1907–1933) .................. 44
A. The Panic of 1907 .................................................................................... 44
B. Functions of the Federal Reserve System .............................................. 47
C. The Early Federal Reserve System ........................................................ 48
V.
THE NEW DEAL AND ITS LEGACY (1933–1960s) ............................................. 49
A. Enhancing Transparency in Securities Markets and Separating
Banking from Securities ......................................................................... 50
1. The Securities Act of 1933 and the Exchange Act of 1934 ............. 50
2. The Banking Act of 1933 .................................................................. 51
B. Stabilizing the Banking System Through Deposit Insurance............... 51
VI.
A TREND TOWARDS DEREGULATION (1970s–2000s) ....................................... 53
A. Deregulation of Depository Institutions ................................................ 54
B. Loosening of Geographic Restrictions .................................................... 55
C. Re-Regulation of Banks and Thrifts ....................................................... 56
D. The Erosion of the Glass-Steagall Act.................................................... 57
E. Securitization and the New Models of Intermediation ......................... 58
F. The Commodity Futures Modernization Act ......................................... 59
VII. THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ITS AFTERMATH .................................................. 59
A. The Financial Crisis ................................................................................ 59
B. The Dodd-Frank Act ............................................................................... 64
C. Contending Visions of the Financial Crisis ........................................... 65
D. Changed Political Climate ...................................................................... 72
33
44
INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL REGULATION
IV.
PART I
THE CREATION OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
(1907–1933)
Since the demise of the Second Bank, the United States had changed from
an agricultural economy to a developing industrial economy. Unlike all other
developed nations at the time, however, the United States had not established a
lender of last resort. The Federal Reserve System evolved over time. The Panic
of 1907 created a strong impetus for reform, and after long and
contentious debates, Congress enacted the Federal Reserve Act in 1913. As you
will see, the hybrid structure of the Federal Reserve System involved
compromises between competing factions, echoing the earlier debates around the
First and Second Banks. These compromises were revisited in the wake of the
Federal Reserve’s failures in the Great Depression, resulting in significant
reforms enacted in 1935. As you read this material, consider the extent to which
debates at the time of the Federal Reserve System’s founding remain relevant
more than a century later.
A.
THE PANIC OF 1907
The Panic of 1907, even more so than the string of panics that had preceded
it, demonstrated that the U.S. financial system was inherently fragile. The panic
began among trust companies that were not regulated as banks but made loans
and offered demand deposits.
Jon R. Moen & Ellis W. Tallman, The Panic of 1907
FED. RESERVE HISTORY (Dec. 4, 2015)
The Panic of 1907 was the first worldwide financial crisis of the twentieth century. It
transformed a recession into a contraction surpassed in severity only by the Great
Depression. . . .
The central role of New York City trust companies distinguishes the Panic of 1907 from
earlier panics. Trust companies were state-chartered intermediaries that competed with
banks for deposits. . . . [T]hey held a low percentage of cash reserves relative to deposits,
around 5 percent, compared with 25 percent for national banks. Because trust-company
deposit accounts were demandable in cash, trusts were just as susceptible to runs on
deposits as were banks. . . .
[T]rusts were large and important to the financial system. Trust companies loaned large
sums directly in New York equity markets, including New York Stock Exchange [(NYSE)]
brokers. Trusts did not require collateral for these loans, which had to be repaid by the
end of the business day. Brokers used these loans to purchase securities for themselves
or their clients and then used these securities as collateral for a call loan—an overnight
loan that facilitated stock purchases—from a nationally chartered bank. The proceeds of
the call loan were used to pay back the initial loan from the trust company. Trusts were a
necessary part of this process, because the law prohibited nationally chartered
commercial banks from making uncollateralized loans or guaranteeing the payment of
checks written by brokers on accounts without sufficient funds. The extra liquidity
provided by trusts supported new daily transactions on the floor of the exchange. Runs
on trust company deposits, however, short-circuited their role as the initial liquidity
provider to the stock market. . . .
The parallels between the crises in 1907 and 2008 are striking. During 2007–09, the
financial crisis was centered on investment banks, institutions without direct access to
CH. 1.2
THE HISTORY OF U.S. FINANCIAL REGULATION: A THEMATIC OVERVIEW
the Federal Reserve System. In 1907, widespread depositor withdrawals occurred at New
York City trust companies—intermediaries outside the New York Clearing House, the
effective lender of last resort. In effect, both financial crises started outside the large
banks serving as payments centers. Yet the crises created havoc within markets and
among banks that were central to the payments system. Both crises challenged the
existing mechanisms used to alleviate crises.
The trust companies in 1907 were like the shadow banks in the financial crisis of 2007–
09. Short-term lending during the recent crisis came largely from some shadow banks
(hedge funds and money market mutual funds) to fund other shadow banks
(investment banks). As key liquidity providers for repurchase agreements, these shadow
banks were the “depositors” providing funds for overnight lending to allow investment
banks to finance the asset-backed security market, just as uncollateralized loans
(overdrafts) by trust companies allowed brokers to purchase stock. Both the trusts and
the shadow banks faced runs by their depositors and had to withdraw lending in shortterm credit markets.
The Panic of 1907 was initially prompted by market rumor regarding the
financial health of an established banking institution. The rumor caused banks
around the country to hoard cash and call in their own deposits with other banks,
as they feared a bank run. Widespread public distrust ensued, leading to a
general demand for deposits, which the banks could not meet, and currency
began to disappear from circulation. LUDWIG BENDIX, THE ALDRICH PLAN IN THE
LIGHT OF MODERN BANKING 23 (1912).
In the midst of the panic, J. Pierpont Morgan, namesake of the firm J.P.
Morgan, stepped in and personally pledged his own money to prop up the
banking system.
Simultaneously, Morgan brought in other bankers and
institutions to do the same. In a famous finale to this rescue, Morgan gathered
the other financiers in his lavish library and held them there until they agreed to
provide the funds necessary to stave off collapse. The Treasury also contributed
tens of millions of dollars, but Morgan received the lion’s share of credit for
saving the day. Morgan’s involvement quite understandably raised concerns
about leaving the fate of the burgeoning financial system in the hands of one
private individual. See RON CHERNOW, THE HOUSE OF MORGAN: AN AMERICAN
BANKING DYNASTY AND THE RISE OF MODERN FINANCE 126–28 (1990); see also
PETER CONTI-BROWN, THE POWER AND INDEPENDENCE OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE
17 (2016); GARY B. GORTON, MISUNDERSTANDING FINANCIAL CRISES: WHY WE
DON’T SEE THEM COMING 142–43 (2012).
After the Panic of 1907, many supported reforms that could reduce the
banking system’s susceptibility to panics as a result of seasonal demands.
Consensus for reform did not, however, coalesce in favor of creating a central
bank until years afterwards. The period between 1907 and 1913 was marked by
vigorous debate. Proponents of decentralized local government, reprising the
local power ideals of Jeffersonian and Jacksonian democracy, set themselves
against proponents of a strong national government modeled more closely on the
Hamiltonian tradition. Before the creation of a single national currency,
members of the camp in favor of decentralized local government, led by William
Jennings Bryan, favored reforms that would expand the U.S. monetary supply by
allowing banks to issue private currency backed not by specie or government
45
46
INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL REGULATION
PART I
securities but by the assets they held, such as loans and discounted notes.
Members of the opposing camp, including a German émigré banker named Paul
Warburg and, later, Senator Nelson Aldrich, favored the creation of a central
bank. Warburg arrived in New York in 1902 and, reared in the efficiently
synchronized world of German banking, acutely perceived with an outsider’s eye
the flaws in the banking system that myopic Americans had missed:
Warburg stressed that a central bank was a requisite for developing
deeper, more liquid credit markets. Even in a second tongue,
Warburg waxed poetic over the centralized credit systems of Europe,
where “the credit of the whole nation—that is, the farmer, merchant
and manufacturer . . . becomes available as a means of exchange.”
Warburg wanted Americans to see that their system was weakened
by its lack of unity. He vividly compared its banks to the infantry in
a disorganized platoon.
“Instead of sending an army,” he
admonished, “we send each soldier to fight alone.”
LOWENSTEIN, AMERICA’S BANK: THE EPIC STRUGGLE TO CREATE THE FEDERAL
RESERVE, at 55–56.
In the wake of the Panic of 1907, Congress established a commission to
study the banking systems of Europe and the United States. Eventually, Aldrich
and a small number of others who went on to lead the central banking movement
held a secret summit on Jekyll Island in 1910, developing a plan, which came to
be called the Aldrich Plan, setting out their vision for a U.S. central bank. The
Aldrich Plan remained a closely guarded secret, however, even as the Jekyll
Island group began to unfold their designs in the face of intense opposition to the
idea of a central bank. See id. at 107–23.
The election of progressive Democrat Woodrow Wilson in 1912 sparked new
impetus for reform. Fearing political repercussions from rural voters reflexively
opposed to concentrated financial power in any form, however, Wilson avoided
publicly supporting the establishment of a central bank during his 1912
presidential campaign but privately signaled he would be receptive. Id.; see also
CONTI-BROWN, THE POWER AND INDEPENDENCE OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE;
ALLAN H. MELTZER, A HISTORY OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE (2002); JOHN H. WOOD,
CENTRAL BANKING IN A DEMOCRACY: THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND ITS
ALTERNATIVES (2015); RICHARD H. TIMBERLAKE, THE ORIGINS OF CENTRAL
BANKING IN THE UNITED STATES 6 (1978).
As President, Wilson favored a strong, publicly run central bank based in
Washington. Large banks favored a privately run system based on the Bank of
England and British clearinghouse model, while those in the Jeffersonian
tradition wanted to disperse power away from Washington.
Ultimately,
Congress enacted a compromise. Then-representative Carter Glass, a Democrat
from Virginia, favored a decentralized system of private reserve banks. In a
compromise that became the Federal Reserve Act, Wilson accepted a
hybrid public-private structure with a publicly appointed Board of
Governors based in Washington that supervised 12 privately owned Federal
Reserve Banks, each corresponding to a geographically apportioned district. A
version of this compromise still exists today. The uneasy balance between
decentralized authority focused on local interests and intermittent crises
CH. 1.2
THE HISTORY OF U.S. FINANCIAL REGULATION: A THEMATIC OVERVIEW
requiring central action in Washington continues to define the Federal Reserve
System, though it resulted in especially deleterious friction in the Federal
Reserve Board’s early decades.
See CONTI-BROWN, THE POWER AND
INDEPENDENCE OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE.
B.
FUNCTIONS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
The Federal Reserve Act addressed two major deficiencies in the banking
system that the Panic of 1907 exposed: the lack of an elastic currency supply and
the absence of a lender of last resort.
During panics, banks faced with a shortage of cash had no way to expand the
money supply. Issuing more national banknotes to serve as an emergency
currency was not an option because banknotes had to be backed by a
corresponding value of Treasury bonds. Additional national banknotes could
therefore only be issued through an increase in Treasury bonds deposited with
the Comptroller of Currency. In times of panic, that was not an option because
banks did not have enough money to purchase more Treasury bonds, let alone
pay their depositors. In essence, national banknotes were not an elastic currency
because their volume could not expand with rising need during a crisis.
The Federal Reserve Act solved this problem by creating Federal Reserve
notes, legal tender whose supply the Federal Reserve System could increase or
decrease as needed. The Federal Reserve Banks were authorized to discount
short-term commercial and agricultural paper for their member banks against
the proceeds of which Federal Reserve notes could be issued and put in
circulation. Then, as the discounted paper was paid off, the Federal Reserve
notes would be withdrawn from circulation. In this way, the Federal Reserve
could control the amount of Federal Reserve notes in circulation and, thus, the
elasticity of the money supply.
As the Panic of 1907 demonstrated, the U.S. banking system lacked an
adequate lender of last resort that could provide discretionary liquidity to banks
in times of crisis. As you will learn in Chapter 9.1, the Federal Reserve Act
allowed the Federal Reserve System to serve as a lender of last resort by
replenishing member banks’ reserves when banks experienced liquidity
shortfalls and could not obtain funds elsewhere. When the banking system was
unstable, Federal Reserve Banks could now stand ready to inject funds into
fundamentally solvent banks experiencing temporary liquidity problems. By
doing so, the Federal Reserve System could help these banks avoid forced asset
sales to meet their obligations and also discourage depositors from running on a
bank due to concerns over a bank’s liquidity. Aldrich and his allies hoped
that this lender of last resort function would mitigate the risk of bank failure
and contagion.
The concept of the lender of last resort dates back to 1797, when it was first
suggested by Sir Francis Baring that the Bank of England should be the “dernier
resort.” SIR FRANCIS BARING, OBSERVATIONS ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF THE
BANK OF ENGLAND AND ON THE PAPER CIRCULATION OF THE COUNTRY 22
(Augustus M. Kelley ed., 1967). In reality, however, the Bank of England did not
consistently provide liquidity in times of crisis, nor did it embrace its role as
lender of last resort until the mid-19th Century. Thomas M. Humphrey & Robert
47
48
INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL REGULATION
PART I
E. Keleher, The Lender of Last Resort: A Historical Perspective, 4 CATO J. 275,
299–300 (1984).
The Bank of England was persuaded to adopt the role of lender of last resort
by Walter Bagehot. Id. at 291–305. Bagehot argued that, in times of panic, the
Bank of England should lend freely in accordance with two rules. First, the loans
should only be made at high rates of interest, known as penalty rates. Second,
the Bank of England should make loans against all collateral that
was considered good, commonly pledged, and easily convertible during
ordinary times, so as not to exacerbate the panic. WALTER BAGEHOT, LOMBARD
STREET: A DESCRIPTION OF THE MONEY MARKET, ch. 7 ¶¶ 57–60 (Henry S. King &
Co. 1873).
C.
THE EARLY FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
The Federal Reserve System started operations in November 1914, just after
the beginning of World War I. Contending with a more or less constant power
struggle between the regional Federal Reserve Banks and the Board in
Washington, the Federal Reserve System, by tightening credit during the Stock
Market Crash of 1929, worsened the Great Depression and contributed to the
failure of many banks between 1929 and 1933. See LIAQUAT AHAMED, LORDS OF
FINANCE: THE BANKERS WHO BROKE THE WORLD 501–02 (2009); see also BEN S.
BERNANKE, ESSAYS ON THE GREAT DEPRESSION (2000); MILTON FRIEDMAN &
ANNA J. SCHWARTZ, THE GREAT CONTRACTION, 1929–1933 (1969).
Twenty years after the passage of the Federal Reserve Act, the Banking Act
of 1935 altered the Federal Reserve System’s structure and governance. The Act
was the brainchild of Marriner S. Eccles, special assistant to the Secretary of the
Treasury. See CONTI-BROWN, THE POWER AND INDEPENDENCE OF THE FEDERAL
RESERVE. Eccles’s goal was to make the Washington-based Federal Reserve
Board the true center of national banking policy and to abolish the Reserve
Banks, which were dominated by regional banking interests. Whereas in 1913,
limiting federal power was a principal concern, in 1935, Eccles’s principal focus
was increasing the power of the Washington-based Federal Reserve Board. Id;
see also LOWENSTEIN, AMERICA’S BANK: THE EPIC STRUGGLE TO CREATE THE
FEDERAL RESERVE. Eccles’s vision was partially embodied in the Banking Act of
1935. The act strengthened the Federal Reserve Board and prevented the
Federal Reserve Banks from undermining a national interest rate and monetary
policy; the Federal Reserve Banks, however, were permitted to participate in the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), through which the Federal Reserve
System sets monetary policy. According to one account, the Federal Reserve
System was transformed from “private banks running a private banking policy
with public benefits to a public central bank in the modern sense of the word.”
CONTI-BROWN, THE POWER AND INDEPENDENCE OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE, at 31.
———————
1. The Federal Reserve Board’s Evolving Role. The Federal Reserve
Board’s role in financial regulation has continued to expand. For instance, in the
Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 (BHCA), Congress gave the Federal Reserve
Board supervisory and regulatory power over bank holding companies (BHCs).
We will discuss BHCs in Chapter 6.1. Twenty years later, amidst high inflation
CH. 1.2
THE HISTORY OF U.S. FINANCIAL REGULATION: A THEMATIC OVERVIEW
and unemployment, Congress charged the Federal Reserve Board with pursuing
the goals of “maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term
interest rates.”
12 U.S.C. § 225a (1977) (2012).
After the Financial
Crisis, Congress put the Federal Reserve Board in charge of supervising
financial companies that are deemed systemically important. See, e.g., DoddFrank Act § 113.
The Federal Reserve Board’s power, however, remains controversial, and many
critics want the Federal Reserve Board weakened or even abolished. Critics
allege that the Federal Reserve Board is secretive and undemocratic, and they
argue that the Federal Reserve Board’s response to the Financial Crisis exceeded
its statutory powers. See, e.g., RON PAUL, END THE FED (2009); see also
ROTHBARD, THE CASE AGAINST THE FED. You will learn about the Federal
Reserve Board in Chapter 9.1.
———————
V.
THE NEW DEAL AND ITS LEGACY (1933–1960s)
Following the end of World War I and into the 1920s, the United States
enjoyed unprecedented prosperity. Some 20 million shareholders took advantage
of post-war prosperity and invested in the stock market, fueling its spectacular
growth. This growth, combined with a flow of loose credit, fueled risky and
speculative activities. Groups of wealthy investors traded large pools of stocks to
manipulate prices and enjoy speculative windfalls. Commercial banks used
depositors’ funds, which at the time were uninsured, to make speculative loans.
Small investors acquired stock beyond their means from brokers who required
only a small down payment, or margin, while loaning the remaining price of the
stock. Fueling the fire, securities regulation was either vastly inadequate or
nonexistent. Although many states attempted to regulate the securities markets
at a local level through Blue Sky laws, brokers and dealers found it easy to evade
this state regulation.
When stock prices began to decline in September 1929, brokers started
demanding repayment of their loans. Many investors lacked sufficient cash to
satisfy their obligations, and they resorted to selling their stock. These fire sales
further depressed prices, creating a vicious cycle that soon collapsed, bringing
the country’s financial system to disaster. On October 24, 1929, dubbed Black
Thursday, a selling frenzy resulted in record one-day stock market losses that
totaled $9 billion. The following Tuesday, October 29, the market traded 16
million shares, and by November stocks shed some $26 billion in value. The
losses did not end there:
Between September 1, 1929, and July 1, 1932, the value of all stocks
listed on the [NYSE] shrank from a total of nearly $90 billion to just
under $16 billion—a loss of 83 percent. In a comparable period,
bonds listed on the [NYSE] declined from a value of $49 billion to $31
billion. . . . Nor did these figures, staggering as they were, fully
gauge the extent of the 1929–1932 stock market crash. During the
post-World War I decade, approximately $50 billion of new securities
were sold in the United States. Approximately half or $25 billion
would prove near or totally valueless. Leading “blue-chip” securities,
including General Electric, Sears, Roebuck, and U.S. Steel common
49
CHAPTER 9.1
LENDER OF LAST RESORT
CONTENTS
I.
INTRODUCTION .............................................................................................. 935
II.
HISTORY ........................................................................................................ 936
A. The Bank of England ............................................................................ 936
B. The United States Without a Lender of Last Resort ........................... 938
C. Today’s Federal Reserve ....................................................................... 939
III.
TRADITIONAL LENDER OF LAST RESORT ....................................................... 939
A. Open Market Operations ...................................................................... 941
B. The Discount Window ........................................................................... 942
C. The Problem of Stigma and the Early Financial Crisis ...................... 944
IV.
FEDERAL RESERVE EMERGENCY LENDING: SECTION 13(3) .......................... 947
A. The History of Section 13(3) ................................................................. 948
B. Aftermath and Reform .......................................................................... 951
C. The Lender of Last Resort Debate ....................................................... 953
1. Central Bank Independence ........................................................... 953
2. Criticisms of the Federal Reserve .................................................. 955
3. The Future of Lender of Last Resort .............................................. 957
V.
THE FEDERAL RESERVE AS THE INTERNATIONAL LENDER OF
LAST RESORT? ............................................................................................... 959
I.
INTRODUCTION
In this Chapter, we take a closer look at the central bank and its function as
the lender of last resort. In the United States, the Federal Reserve System plays
this role. Deposit insurance and the lender of last resort are often discussed as
complementary since they both protect against runs, but the lender of last resort
is a 19th Century idea and older than deposit insurance plans, which only
developed in the early 20th Century.
Years of contentious debate accompanied the creation of the Federal Reserve
System at the beginning of the 20th Century and, later, the controversy over
whether the Federal Reserve used its lender of last resort authority aggressively
enough during the 1930s. During the intervening decades of relative financial
stability in the United States, however, intellectual and political interest in the
function of the lender of last resort waned. As Professor Peter Conti-Brown
writes, until roughly the early 1960s, “Central banking was in the hinterland;
fiscal policy—the stuff of taxes and budgets and spending and deficits—was at
935
936
LENDER OF LAST RESORT AND RESOLUTION
PART IX
the core.” PETER CONTI-BROWN, THE POWER AND INDEPENDENCE OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE ix (2016).
This lack of attention changed abruptly with the Financial Crisis, when
many central banks, including the Federal Reserve, made heavy and creative use
of their lender of last resort powers to avert a global financial catastrophe.
Earlier crises had prompted assertive but incremental action. For example, after
Thailand’s sharp devaluation of the baht in July 1997, central banks established
currency swap lines to facilitate foreign exchange and alleviate the market
disruption that became known as the Asian financial crisis. The Financial Crisis
pushed the Federal Reserve and other lenders of last resort to act far more
aggressively. In a highly volatile market, a financial conglomerate might remain
solvent while in desperate need of liquidity, but it might already have crossed the
brink. Many categorical distinctions—insolvency versus illiquidity; banking
versus non-banking activities; systemic versus idiosyncratic risks—
collapsed under the weight of overwhelming uncertainty. Clear-eyed theory
often gave way to more nuanced and fraught experimentation as the Federal
Reserve Board and other policy-makers struggled to understand and respond to
the Financial Crisis.
We begin with a history of the lender of last resort, starting with the Bank of
England. We then discuss the traditional lender of last resort power in the
United States, as well as the extraordinary use of the lender of last resort powers
during the Financial Crisis. The Financial Crisis emergency lending sparked
a vigorous academic and political debate over the proper role of the lender of
last resort, which we will try to capture. The Chapter concludes with an
examination of whether the Federal Reserve has become a truly international
lender of last resort.
II.
A.
HISTORY
THE BANK OF ENGLAND
The Bank of England has served as the model for other central bank lenders
of last resort. It was granted a corporate charter in 1694 as a private company
after a crushing naval defeat and the threat of French invasion required the
English crown to rebuild its navy. The English crown had neither funds nor good
credit, so it needed another means to get a loan. In order to entice subscribers
for the large loan, the crown agreed to grant prospective lenders a bank charter.
ANDREAS M. ANDREADÉS, HISTORY OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND 54–59 (4th ed.
2013). The charter granted the Bank of England’s private shareholders limited
liability protection, which at the time was an innovative idea, especially in
banking. Id. at 83.
The Bank of England was initially the government’s preferred bank, holding
its balances and lending it money. CHARLES GOODHART, THE EVOLUTION OF
CENTRAL BANKS 5 (3d ed. 1981).
It was also empowered to issue
banknotes against the government’s debt and deal in bills of exchange and
gold or silver bullion. ANDREAS M. ANDREADÉS, HISTORY OF THE BANK OF
ENGLAND, at 73. Its charter had to be renewed every 20 years and its powers
expanded or contracted according to the politics of the time. The 20-year charter,
CH. 9.1
LENDER OF LAST RESORT
a common feature historically, and private ownership were to be repeated in the
earliest, ultimately doomed, attempts to establish a central bank in the United
States. See Chapter 1.2. In 1844, the Bank Charter Act granted the Bank of
England a monopoly, with certain exceptions, on issuing banknotes, and these
notes were declared legal tender. Thomas M. Humphrey & Robert E. Keleher,
The Lender of Last Resort: A Historical Perspective, 4 CATO J. 275, 289–97
(Spring/Summer 1984); see also ANDREADÉS, HISTORY OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND,
at 188–89, 200–01, 288–91.
It is unclear when the Bank of England first acted as a lender of last resort.
The concept of the lender of last resort was first suggested by Sir Francis Baring
in 1797, when he wrote that the Bank of England was the “dernier ressort.” SIR
FRANCIS BARING, OBSERVATIONS ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF THE BANK OF
ENGLAND AND ON THE PAPER CIRCULATION OF THE COUNTRY 22 (Augustus M.
Kelley 1967); see also Humphrey & Keleher, The Lender of Last Resort: A
Historical Perspective, at 282. Baring was not describing a self-conscious role the
bank was performing, but rather the brute fact that the Bank of England was the
last one left after every other lender had turned down a request for a loan.
Richard S. Grossman & Hugh Rockoff, Fighting the Last War: Economists on
the Lender of Last Resort, in CENTRAL BANKS AT A CROSSROADS: WHAT CAN
WE LEARN FROM HISTORY?, 231, 245 (Michael D. Bordo et al. eds., 2016). The
Bank of England maintained the official stance that it was “no more bound to
support commercial credit than any other bankers are” and did not consistently
provide liquidity in times of crisis. David Kynaston, TILL TIME’S LAST SAND: A
HISTORY OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND 1694–2013, at 152 (2017). The Bank of
England’s role in the financial system was nonetheless widely acknowledged by
the mid-19th Century, and an 1848 Parliamentary report observed that “the Bank
[was subject to] the duty of a consideration of the public interest, not indeed
enacted or defined by law, but which Parliament in its various transactions with
the Bank has always recognized and which the Bank has never disclaimed.” Id.
In response to the inconsistent policies of the Bank of England when
confronting panics during the 19th Century, Walter Bagehot wrote LOMBARD
STREET: A DESCRIPTION OF THE MONEY MARKET. Although the Bank of England
had sometimes supplied some liquidity to help alleviate panics, it had not
developed a consistent policy. Building on the earlier, seminal work of Henry
Thornton, Bagehot’s book was a landmark, at once sophisticated and accessible,
arguing persuasively that the Bank of England’s actions during an earlier panic
in 1825 defined the exemplary lender of last resort. See HENRY THORNTON, AN
ENQUIRY INTO THE NATURE AND EFFECTS OF THE PAPER CREDIT OF GREAT
BRITAIN (1802); Humphrey & Keleher, The Lender of Last Resort: A Historical
Perspective, at 297–305.
Walter Bagehot, Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market
57–60 (1873)
And with the Bank of England, as with other Banks in the same case, these advances, if
they are to be made at all, should be made so as if possible to obtain the object for which
they are made. The end is to stay the panic; and the advances should, if possible, stay the
panic. And for this purpose there are two rules:
937
938
LENDER OF LAST RESORT AND RESOLUTION
PART IX
First, That these loans should only be made at a very high rate of interest. This will
operate as a heavy fine on unreasonable timidity, and will prevent the greatest number of
applications by persons who do not require it. The rate should be raised early in the
panic, so that the fine may be paid early; that no one may borrow out of idle precaution
without paying well for it; that the Banking reserve may be protected as far as possible.
Secondly. That at this rate these advances should be made on all good banking securities,
and as largely as the public ask for them. The reason is plain. The object is to stay
alarm, and nothing therefore should be done to cause alarm. But the way to cause alarm
is to refuse someone who has good security to offer. . . . If it is known that the Bank of
England is freely advancing on what in ordinary times is reckoned a good security—on
what is then commonly pledged and easily convertible—the alarm of the solvent
merchants and bankers will be stayed. But if securities, really good and usually
convertible, are refused by the Bank, the alarm will not abate, the other loans made will
fail in obtaining their end, and the panic will become worse and worse.
. . . The only safe plan for the Bank is the brave plan, to lend in a panic on every kind of
current security, or every sort on which money is ordinarily and usually lent. This policy
may not save the Bank; but if it do not, nothing will save it.
For an excellent review that places Bagehot’s book in context, see Peter
Conti-Brown, Misreading Walter Bagehot: What Lombard Street Really Means for
Central Banking¸ NEW RAMBLER (Dec. 14, 2015).
Bagehot’s dictum, the name by which the modern interpretation of his
argument is commonly known, asserts that, in times of panic, the Bank of
England should lend freely against what is considered to be good collateral in
normal times at high interest rates. Modern articulations of Bagehot’s dictum
also include the condition that central banks should lend only to solvent
borrowers, a point that would have been implicit when Bagehot wrote but, as we
discuss later, has additional relevance today. The actions of the Bank of England
reduced the number of 19th Century banking panics in England, especially as
compared to the United States, which, after the first and second Banks of the
United States’ charters lapsed, did not have a central bank to serve as a lender of
last resort. See Chapter 1.2.
B.
THE UNITED STATES WITHOUT A LENDER OF LAST RESORT
At the turn of the 20th Century, the United States was the only developed
economy without a lender of last resort. In the absence of a central bank, private
clearinghouses stepped in to fill that role. In 1853, certain New York banks
joined together to form the New York Clearing House Association. During
banking panics, when New York banks became illiquid, the New York Clearing
House issued clearinghouse certificates against the banknotes of its members.
Member banks paid interest on the certificates and accepted them as payment,
relieving other member banks of the need to settle their transactions in
greenbacks or specie. This allowed those other banks to use the greenbacks or
specie to satisfy deposit withdrawals, making a collapse less likely. The New
York Clearing House served as an ad hoc lender of last resort, injecting liquidity
into the New York banks by converting banknotes that had ceased to function as
money into clearinghouse certificates that were widely accepted as money, and
thus avoiding or mitigating a contraction in the supply of money even during a
CH. 9.1
LENDER OF LAST RESORT
panic. See NEW YORK CLEARING HOUSE ASSOCIATION RECORDS, 1868–1950;
JOHN H. WOOD, CENTRAL BANKING IN A DEMOCRACY: THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND
ITS ALTERNATIVES 56–60 (2015). Similar systems developed elsewhere, notably
in New England under the Suffolk Bank System. The Suffolk Bank of Boston
issued notes in exchange for specie or local banknotes, creating a kind of regional
currency between 1824 and 1858. GARY WALTON & HUGH ROCKOFF, HISTORY OF
THE AMERICAN ECONOMY 215 (2005); C.J. Maloney, Life Without the Fed: The
Suffolk System, MISES INST. (Jan. 5, 2011); see also ROGER LOWENSTEIN,
AMERICA’S BANK: THE EPIC STRUGGLE TO CREATE THE FEDERAL RESERVE (2015).
The weakness of the clearinghouse system was that its solutions were local and
the certificates worked only in the city where they were issued. LOWENSTEIN,
AMERICA’S BANK, at 41.
As discussed in Chapter 1.2, the severity of the Panic of 1907 was the
turning point for the development of a central bank to serve as a lender of last
resort in the United States. To address the deficiencies in the banking system
that were exposed in that crisis, the Federal Reserve Act was passed in 1913.
C.
TODAY’S FEDERAL RESERVE
Today’s Federal Reserve System retains 12 Federal Reserve Banks that
service financial institutions in 12 Federal Reserve districts. These reserve
banks act as banker’s banks, providing a wide variety of services such as storing
currency and processing checks and electronic payments for both banking
institutions and the federal government. The Federal Reserve Banks are
overseen by a seven-person Board of Governors based in Washington. Each of
these Governors is appointed by the President of the United States and serves a
14-year term. The Chairman of the Board of Governors is appointed from among
its members for a four-year term. For a more thorough exploration of the
governing structure of the Federal Reserve, see BD. OF THE FED. RESERVE SYS.,
THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM: PURPOSES & FUNCTIONS 1–13 (2005).
We discussed the Federal Reserve’s supervisory authority with respect to
bank holding companies (BHCs) and its role in supervising systemic non-bank
financial companies in Chapters 6.1 and 6.3, as well as its role in the payments
system and check clearing in Chapter 7.2. The Federal Reserve is the primary
organ responsible for carrying out U.S. monetary policy and, for many, that is its
most crucial role.
III.
TRADITIONAL LENDER OF LAST RESORT
As lender of last resort, each of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks can replenish
banks’ liquidity, on a collateralized basis, when they experience shortfalls and
cannot obtain funds elsewhere. See Kathryn Judge, Three Discount Windows, 99
CORNELL L. REV. 795 (2014). When the banking system is stable, private
commercial banks can overcome liquidity shortfalls by borrowing from one
another in the interbank lending market. When the banking system is unstable,
however, banks may hesitate to lend to one another because they are unable to
determine which institutions are solvent or sufficiently liquid to withstand a run
by their depositors or other short-term creditors. By standing ready to inject
funds into fundamentally solvent banks experiencing temporary liquidity
939
940
LENDER OF LAST RESORT AND RESOLUTION
PART IX
problems, the lender of last resort helps these banks avoid forced asset sales to
meet their obligations. It also discourages depositors from running on a bank
due to concerns over a bank’s liquidity position, which in turn mitigates the risk
of bank failure and contagion.
The purpose of the lender of last resort, at least in theory, is only to provide
temporary fully secured liquidity to solvent banks and not to provide capital to
rescue banks from insolvency.
A collateralized liquidity injection is
distinguishable in theory from a bailout, in which insolvent banks receive equity
or equity-like infusions of capital, the impact of which is to shield the bank’s
long- and short-term creditors from losses. Those losses are then redistributed to
third parties, like taxpayers, the rationale being that the social costs of the
bailout are lower than the social costs of letting the bank fail. See Randall D.
Guynn, Are Bailouts Inevitable?, 29 YALE J. ON REG. 121, 125–29 (2012).
This section focuses on the Federal Reserve’s traditional lender of last resort
function. It begins with an examination of open market operations. While open
market operations are often discussed as a distinct function from the lender of
last resort, it makes sense to begin the discussion there for two reasons. First,
open market operations are the Federal Reserve’s primary tool for regulating
liquidity in the banking system. Second, allegations that the Federal Reserve
abused its lender of last resort power during the Financial Crisis have sparked
efforts to restrain not only the lender of last resort power, but also the Federal
Reserve’s open market operations function. The Federal Reserve has vigorously
resisted these efforts to curb its most powerful monetary policy tool. This section
concludes by looking at the Federal Reserve’s bilateral lending facility, the
discount window, which has historically carried out what most would recognize
as the lender of last resort power.
———————
1. The Federal Reserve’s Informational Role. Professor Kathryn Judge
draws a distinction between a liquidity shortage caused by an exogenous shock,
such as the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, and a persistent liquidity
shortage of the sort that culminated in the Financial Crisis. Persistent liquidity
shortages, Judge argues, are symptoms of deeper market dysfunction that the
infusion of liquidity alone may be insufficient to alleviate. She proposes a
broader understanding of the role of the lender of last resort in today’s financial
system, in which the Federal Reserve exercises its authority as lender of last
resort not only to provide liquidity, but also to collect, synthesize, and
disseminate the information necessary to neutralize the crippling uncertainty
that may otherwise trigger a contagious panic:
[C]ontinually pumping new liquidity into a financial system in the
midst of a persistent liquidity shortage may increase the fragility of
the system and, on its own, is unlikely to resolve the deeper problems
causing those liquidity shortages to persist. . . [W]hen facing
persistent liquidity shortages, the [Federal Reserve Board] should
instead use the leverage it enjoys by virtue of controlling access to
liquidity to improve its understanding of the ailments causing the
market dysfunction to persist and to help address those underlying
issues. It should also use the information to further policies that can
CH. 9.1
LENDER OF LAST RESORT
help to counter those underlying issues. . . . Providing credible
information and working with other policymakers to ensure the
overall financial system is sufficiently capitalized are thus among the
issues that the [Federal Reserve Board] should prioritize when facing
persistent liquidity shortages.
Kathryn Judge, The First Year: The Role of a Modern Lender of Last Resort, 116
COLUM. L. REV. 843, 843 (2016). The traditional prudential view differs in
important respects; regulators in the past strove to keep prudential information
secret in order to ward off bank runs. The 2009 stress tests began to change that
view, as the transparency of the stress tests served to reduce market uncertainty.
———————
A.
OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS
The Federal Reserve’s primary tool for regulating liquidity in the banking
system is the use of open market operations. To expand or contract the money
supply, the Federal Reserve purchases or sells U.S. Treasuries on the open
market. The broker-dealers that transact directly with the Federal Reserve are
known as primary dealers. Dietrich Domanski, Richhild Moessner & William
Nelson, Central Banks as Lenders of Last Resort: Experiences During the 2007–
2010 Crisis and Lessons for the Future 51 (Bank for Int’l Settlements, Working
Paper No. 79, 2014). You will recall that, even during the Glass-Steagall Act era,
commercial banks were affiliated with primary dealers that underwrote and
dealt in U.S. government securities. If the Federal Reserve wants to increase
liquidity (i.e., the money supply), it will cause one of the Federal Reserve Banks
to purchase U.S. Treasuries from a primary dealer. To pay for the purchase, the
Federal Reserve Bank credits the account of the primary dealer and debits its
own account in an equal amount.
In effect, the U.S. Treasuries purchased by a Federal Reserve Bank
conducting open market operations are paid for using newly created money. As a
result, the amount of money circulating in the banking system is increased. This
expansion in the money supply, in turn, allows banks to lend to one another and
to the economy more freely. Interbank lending is measured by reference to the
Federal Funds Rate, which is the rate that banks charge one another for
overnight loans on balances held at a Federal Reserve Bank. A lower Federal
Funds Rate reflects a decrease in the cost of lending to the economy, typically
resulting in an expansion of the supply of both money and credit through a
mechanism generally known as the money multiplier. JAMES R. KEARL,
ECONOMICS AND PUBLIC POLICY: AN ANALYTICAL APPROACH 422–27, 792 (6th ed.
2011). Conversely, the sale of government securities will have the opposite effect
of contracting the money supply, as well as the supply of money and credit
throughout the banking system. The Federal Reserve’s course in open market
operations is determined by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), which
is composed of all seven members of the Board of Governors, the President of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and an annually rotating group of Presidents
from four other Federal Reserve Banks. 12 U.S.C. § 263 (2012).
The Federal Reserve undertook aggressive open market operations to
increase liquidity during and after past crises. For example, aggressive open
941
942
LENDER OF LAST RESORT AND RESOLUTION
PART IX
market operations were key in mitigating broad financial market instability
during the 1987 stock market crash. Mark Carlson, A Brief History of the 1987
Stock Market Crash with a Discussion of the Federal Reserve Response (FEDS
Working Paper No. 2007–13, 2007). The Federal Funds Rate remained close to
0% for several years until December 2015, meaning that banks could effectively
lend to each other interest-free. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.,
Selected Interest Rates (Weekly) (Apr. 6, 2015).
Despite the role that open market operations play in improving bank
liquidity, it is important to remember that the primary purpose of open market
operations is not to regulate the health of banks, but rather to expand or contract
the money supply, adjust interest rates, and either stimulate or tamp down the
availability of credit.
B.
THE DISCOUNT WINDOW
The fact that a lender of last resort stands ready to exchange cash for illiquid
assets during periods of scarce liquidity has many salutary effects. The existence
of the lender of last resort discourages depositors from participating in a run.
Paul Tucker, The Lender of Last Resort and Modern Central Banking: Principles
and Reconstruction (Bank for Int’l Settlements, Working Paper No. 79b, 2014)
[hereinafter Tucker, Lender of Last Resort]. In the event that a run does occur,
central bank liquidity helps an institution with liquidity difficulties avoid asset
fire-sales and insolvency. A central bank is in the best position to act as a lender
of last resort for several reasons. Central banks often act as prudential
supervisors. This regulatory role positions them to assess banks’ health and
avoid lending to an insolvent institution. Judge, Three Discount Windows, at
808. In a world of fiat currency, central banks possess the ability to print or
otherwise create central bank money. Id. at 807. Their ability to make
emergency loans is not constrained by a lack of money, and they have no
incentive to hoard liquid assets in times of financial instability. Id. at 808.
Central banks with power to expand the money supply are, uniquely, indifferent
to liquidity risk.
In normal times, the Federal Reserve provides collateralized loans through
its bilateral lending facility, the discount window. The interest rate on discount
window loans, known as the discount rate, is set by Federal Reserve Banks in
each district, subject to approval by the Board of Governors. Normally, only
depository institutions are permitted to access the discount window. 12 C.F.R.
§ 201.1(b) (2017).
Discount window loans contain terms designed to mitigate problems of
adverse selection and moral hazard. Banks seeking to tap the discount window
must post collateral at the window in exchange for a loan of cash. Judge, Three
Discount Windows, at 797. A broad range of high-quality collateral is acceptable,
including loans and securities. William Nelson, Lessons from Lender of Last
Resort Actions During the Crisis: The Federal Reserve Experience 78 (Bank for
Int’l Settlements, Working Paper No. 79d, 2014). If a bank borrower turns out to
be insolvent, the Federal Reserve can then sell that collateral for cash to satisfy
the bank’s secured obligation. Furthermore, discount window loans come with a
haircut, meaning that bank borrowers post collateral that has a higher value
than the cash they receive in return. This overcollateralization further protects
CH. 9.1
LENDER OF LAST RESORT
the Federal Reserve against loss. There is no known instance of a Federal
Reserve Bank suffering a loss on a secured loan from the discount window.
In addition to these safeguards, all discount window loans carry interest
rates higher than those prevailing in the market to discourage banks from using
the facility. This above-market rate for federal funds varies depending on the
soundness of the banks taking out the loan. Banks in good condition can borrow
from the Federal Reserve’s standing lending facility at 100 basis points above the
targeted Federal Funds Rate. These loans are called primary credit discount
loans, and the interest rate on these loans is called the primary rate. Weaker
banks that do not qualify for primary discount loans must take a secondary
credit discount loan, which usually carries an interest rate 50 basis points higher
than the primary rate. The Federal Reserve exercises greater oversight over
institutions that take out secondary credit discount loans. Id. If a bank is
“critically undercapitalized” under the prompt corrective action regime, which we
explored in Chapter 2.5, the Federal Reserve can only extend a loan to that
institution if it matures in five days or less. 12 C.F.R. § 201.5. Finally, the
Federal Reserve offers seasonal credit to small banks that have deposit
withdrawals that spike in certain seasons, requiring greater reserves. The
interest rates on these loans are typically below the primary rate.
———————
1. The Monetary Policy Toolkit. Open market operations and the discount
window are among the most important of the Federal Reserve’s tools, but they
are not the only instruments of monetary policy. Federal regulations require
banks to maintain minimum reserve balances at Federal Reserve Banks and,
like commercial banks, Federal Reserve Banks pay interest on these deposits.
The power to adjust the interest rates paid to commercial banks on their
required and excess Federal Reserve Bank balances is one of the Federal
Reserve’s conventional monetary policy tools. Lowering interest rates on excess
balances incentivizes banks to put these funds to use elsewhere, i.e., by making
commercial loans instead. Forward guidance is another conventional monetary
policy tool; by issuing policy statements that express a commitment to
maintaining low interest rates, the Federal Reserve can promote confidence in
the availability of credit in the future and thereby encourage economic growth.
2. Unconventional Monetary Policy Tools. During the period of low
interest rates and economic inertia that followed the Financial Crisis, the
effectiveness of conventional monetary policy tools was constrained by what is
known as the zero lower bound problem; further reduction may be impossible
when interest rates are already at or near 0%. In theory, reserves might carry a
negative interest rate, charging banks for maintaining excess reserves. Some
central banks, including the European Central Bank and the Bank of Japan,
have ventured into negative interest rate territory. The possibility of the Federal
Reserve following the same course remains a subject of academic debate, but the
Federal Reserve did begin using other unconventional tools more extensively and
creatively after the Financial Crisis to expand the money supply in an effort to
stimulate growth. Most prominently, the Federal Reserve launched the first in a
series of quantitative easing programs in 2008. Like open market operations,
quantitative easing involves the purchase of assets from market participants by
943
944
LENDER OF LAST RESORT AND RESOLUTION
PART IX
Federal Reserve Banks to increase the amount of liquidity in the financial
system. It is considered unconventional in that the assets purchased include not
only U.S. Treasuries but also other types of securities, such as mortgage-backed
securities issued by government sponsored enterprises. The Federal Reserve has
also experimented with the use of overnight reverse repurchase transactions
with money market mutual funds (MMFs) as an alternative to purchasing U.S.
Treasuries from primary dealers in open market operations to influence the
Federal Funds Rate.
3. Shrinking the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet. Quantitative easing
resulted in a massive expansion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet, which
grew from less than $900 billion early in 2008 to more than $4.5 trillion at its
peak in 2015 and has remained close to that size for years afterwards. See Bd. of
Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., Credit and Liquidity Programs and the
Balance Sheet: Recent Balance Sheet Trends (last updated Mar. 9, 2018) (select
the “Total Assets of the Federal Reserve” chart). In September 2017, the FOMC
stated that it “will initiate [a] balance sheet normalization program,” using
Federal Reserve parlance to announce its plans to reduce the size of the balance
sheet over time. Just as quantitative easing supported financial stability and
economic growth, there are concerns that the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
reduction may disrupt markets if it proceeds too quickly or too far. Former
Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke supports a prudent course of action,
arguing for the benefits of keeping a large balance sheet, such as better
transmission of monetary policy, an increased supply of safe assets available to
market participants and a greater ability for the Federal Reserve to provide
liquidity during a crisis. Furthermore, he argues that the process of reduction
should be “passive and predictable,” with the Federal Reserve declining to reinvest the proceeds of assets once they mature but not proactively selling assets
off. See Ben S. Bernanke, Shrinking the Fed’s Balance Sheet, BROOKINGS INST.:
BEN BERNANKE’S BLOG (Jan. 26, 2017), Calling for more aggressive moves,
James Bullard, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, argues that
the large balance sheet reflects a monetary policy that is distorting markets and
that reducing its size more quickly would “allow for more balance-sheet ‘policy
space’ in the future” in case of a recession. James Bullard, A Case for Shrinking
the Fed’s Balance Sheet, THE REGIONAL ECONOMIST (Second Quarter 2017). One
commentator summarizes the market’s initial reaction to the FOMC’s
announcement of balance sheet normalization: “For now, markets will continue
to treat the Fed's normalization as the equivalent of watching paint dry: a slow,
uneventful and relatively predictable process. Whether such expectations are
validated over the longer term, however, is far from clear.” Mohamed A.
El-Erian, Opinion, The Next Step in the Federal Reserve’s Beautiful
Normalization, BLOOMBERG VIEW (Sept. 20, 2017).
———————
C.
THE PROBLEM OF STIGMA AND THE EARLY FINANCIAL CRISIS
The discount window was rarely used before the Financial Crisis, primarily
due to the problem of stigma. Banks are hesitant to tap the discount window for
fear of projecting weakness, and only the most troubled banks would do so. This
AS PREPARED FOR DELIVERY
Winds of Change: The Case for New Digital Currency
By Christine Lagarde, IMF Managing Director
Singapore Fintech Festival, November 14, 2018
Introduction
Distinguished guests, ladies and gentlemen—good morning and thank you for the
opportunity to participate in this important event.
In Singapore, it is often windy. Winds here bring change, and opportunity. Historically, they
blew ships to its port. These resupplied while waiting for the Monsoon to pass, for the
seasons to change.
“Change is the only constant,” wrote the ancient Greek philosopher, Heraclitus of Ephesus.
Singapore knows this. You know this. It is the true spirit of the Fintech Festival—opening
doors to new digital futures; hoisting sails to the winds of change.
And yet change can appear daunting, destabilizing, even threatening. This is especially true
for technological change, which disrupts our habits, jobs, and social interactions.
The key is to harness the benefits while managing the risks.
When it comes to fintech, Singapore has shown exceptional vision—think of its regulatory
sandbox where new ideas can be tested. Think of its Fintech Innovation Lab, and its
collaboration with major central banks on cross-border payments.
In this context, I would like to do three things this morning:
•
First, frame the issue in terms of the changing nature of money and the fintech
revolution.
•
Second, evaluate the role for central banks in this new financial landscape—
especially in providing digital currency.
•
Third, look at some downsides, and consider how they can be minimized.
1. The changing nature of money and the fintech revolution
Let me begin with the big issue on the table today—the changing nature of money.
When commerce was local, centered around the town square, money in the form of tokens—
metal coins—was sufficient. And it was efficient.
2
The exchange of coins from one hand to another settled transactions. So long as the coins
were valid—determined by glancing, scratching, or even biting into them—it did not matter
which hands held them.
But as commerce moved to ships, like those that passed through Singapore, and covered
increasingly greater distances, carrying coins became expensive, risky, and cumbersome.
Chinese paper money—introduced in the 9th century—helped, but not enough. Innovation
produced bills of exchange—pieces of paper allowing merchants with a bank account in their
home city to draw money from a bank at their destination.
The Arabs called these Sakks, the origin of our word “check” today. These checks, and the
banks that went along with them, spread around the world, spearheaded by the Italian
bankers and merchants of the Renaissance. Other examples are the Chinese Shansi and
Indian Hundi bills.
Suddenly, it mattered whom you dealt with. Was this Persian merchant the rightful owner of
that bill? Was the bill trustworthy? Was that Shanxi bank going to accept it? Trust became
essential—and the state became the guarantor of that trust, by offering liquidity backstops,
and supervision.
Why is this brief tour of history relevant? Because the fintech revolution questions the two
forms of money we just discussed—coins and commercial bank deposits. And it questions
the role of the state in providing money.
We are at a historic turning point. You—young and bold entrepreneurs gathered here today—
are not just inventing services; you are potentially reinventing history. And we are all in the
process of adapting.
A new wind is blowing, that of digitalization. In this new world, we meet anywhere, any
time. The town square is back—virtually, on our smartphones. We exchange information,
services, even emojis, instantly… peer to peer, person to person.
We float through a world of information, where data is the “new gold”—despite growing
concerns over privacy, and cyber-security. A world in which millennials are reinventing how
our economy works, phone in hand.
And this is key: money itself is changing. We expect it to become more convenient and userfriendly, perhaps even less serious-looking.
We expect it to be integrated with social media, readily available for online and person-toperson use, including micro-payments. And of course, we expect it to be cheap and safe,
protected against criminals and prying eyes.
What role will remain for cash in this digital world? Already signs in store windows read
“cash not accepted.” Not just in Scandinavia, the poster child of a cashless world. In various
3
other countries too, demand for cash is decreasing—as shown in recent IMF work. And in
ten, twenty, thirty years, who will still be exchanging pieces of paper?
Bank deposits too are feeling pressure from new forms of money.
Think of the new specialized payment providers that offer e-money—from AliPay and
WeChat in China, to PayTM in India, to M-Pesa in Kenya. These forms of money are
designed with the digital economy in mind. They respond to what people demand, and what
the economy requires.
Even cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin, Ethereum, and Ripple are vying for a spot in the
cashless world, constantly reinventing themselves in the hope of offering more stable value,
and quicker, cheaper settlement.
2. A case for Central Bank Digital Currencies
Let me now turn to my second issue: the role of the state—of central banks—in this new
monetary landscape.
Some suggest the state should back down.
Providers of e-money argue that they are less risky than banks, because they do not lend
money. Instead, they hold client funds in custodian accounts, and simply settle payments
within their networks.
For their part, cryptocurrencies seek to anchor trust in technology. So long as they are
transparent—and if you are tech savvy—you might trust their services.
Still, I am not entirely convinced. Proper regulation of these entities will remain a pillar of
trust.
Should we go further? Beyond regulation, should the state remain an active player in the
market for money? Should it fill the void left by the retreat of cash?
Let me be more specific: should central banks issue a new digital form of money? A statebacked token, or perhaps an account held directly at the central bank, available to people and
firms for retail payments? True, your deposits in commercial banks are already digital. But a
digital currency would be a liability of the state, like cash today, not of a private firm.
This is not science fiction. Various central banks around the world are seriously considering
these ideas, including Canada, China, Sweden, and Uruguay. They are embracing change and
new thinking—as indeed is the IMF.
4
Today, we are releasing a new paper 1 on the pros and cons of central bank digital currency—
or “digital currency” for short [link, hold up copy of paper]. It focuses on domestic, not
cross-border effects of digital currency. The paper is available on the IMF website.
I believe we should consider the possibility to issue digital currency. There may be a role for
the state to supply money to the digital economy.
This currency could satisfy public policy goals, such as (i) financial inclusion, and (ii)
security and consumer protection; and to provide what the private sector cannot: (iii) privacy
in payments.
a) Financial inclusion
Let me start with financial inclusion, where digital currency offers great promise, through its
ability to reach people and businesses in remote and marginalized regions. We know that
banks are not exactly rushing to serve poor and rural populations.
This is critical, because cash might no longer be an option here. If the majority of people
adopt digital forms of money, the infrastructure for cash would degrade, leaving those in the
periphery behind.
What about subsidizing cash usage in those areas? But that means that economic life in the
periphery would become disconnected from the center.
Of course, offering a digital currency is not necessarily the only answer. There may be scope
for governments to encourage private sector solutions, by providing funding, or improving
infrastructure.
b) Security and consumer protection
The second benefit of digital currency relates to security and consumer protection. This is
really a David versus Goliath argument. In the old days, coins and paper notes may have
checked the dominant positions of the large, global payment firms—banks, clearinghouses,
and network operators. Simply by offering a low cost and widely available alternative.
Without cash, too much power could fall into the hands of a small number of outsized private
payment providers. Payments, after all, naturally lean toward monopolies—the more people
you serve, the cheaper and more useful the service.
For a start, private firms may under-invest in security to the extent they do not measure the
full cost to society of a payment failure. Resilience may also suffer—with only a few links in
the payment chain, the system may stop working if one of these links breaks. Think about a
cyber-attack, a glitch, bankruptcy, or a firm’s withdrawal from the local market.
1
IMF Staff Discussion Note entitled “Casting Light on Central Bank Digital Currency,” published today on our
website.
5
Regulation may not be able to fully redress these downsides. A digital currency could offer
advantages, as a backup means of payment. And it could boost competition by offering a
low-cost and efficient alternative—as did its grandfather, the old reliable paper note.
c) Privacy
The third benefit of digital currency I would like to highlight lies in the privacy domain.
Cash, of course, allows for anonymous payments. We reach for cash to protect our privacy
for legitimate reasons: to avoid exposure to hacking and customer profiling, for instance.
Consider a simple example. Imagine that people purchasing beer and frozen pizza have
higher mortgage defaults than citizens purchasing organic broccoli and spring water. What
can you do if you have a craving for beer and pizza but do not want your credit score to
drop? Today, you pull out cash. And tomorrow? Would a privately-owned payment system
push you to the broccoli aisle?
Would central banks jump to the rescue and offer a fully anonymous digital currency?
Certainly not. Doing so would be a bonanza for criminals.
3. Downsides of Bank Digital Currencies
This brings me to my third area—the potential downsides of digital currency. The obvious
ones are risks to financial integrity and financial stability. But I would also like to highlight
risks of stifling innovation—the last thing you want.
My main point will be that we should face these risks creatively. How might we attenuate
them by designing digital currency in new and innovative ways? Technology offers a very
wide canvas to do so.
a) Risks to financial integrity
Let’s return to the tradeoff between privacy and financial integrity. Could we find a middle
ground?
Central banks might design digital currency so that users’ identities would be authenticated
through customer due diligence procedures and transactions recorded. But identities would
not be disclosed to third parties or governments unless required by law. So when I purchase
my pizza and beer, the supermarket, its bank, and marketers would not know who I am. The
state might not either, at least by default.
Anti-money laundering and terrorist financing controls would nevertheless run in the
background. If a suspicion arose it would be possible to lift the veil of anonymity and
investigate.
6
This setup would be good for users, bad for criminals, and better for the state, relative to
cash. Of course, challenges remain. My goal, at this point, is to encourage exploration.
b) Risks to financial stability
The second risk relates to financial stability. Digital currencies could exacerbate the pressure
on bank deposits we discussed earlier.
If digital currencies are sufficiently similar to commercial bank deposits—because they are
very safe, can be held without limit, allow for payments of any amount, perhaps even offer
interest—then why hold a bank account at all?
But banks are not passive bystanders. They can compete with higher interest rates and better
services.
What about the risk of bank runs? It exists. But consider that people run when they believe
that cash withdraws are honored on a first-come-first-serve basis—the early bird gets the
worm. Digital currency, instead, because it can be distributed much more easily than cash,
could reassure even the person left lying on the couch!
In addition, if depositors are running to foreign assets, they will also shun the digital
currency. And in many countries, there are already liquid and safe assets to run toward—
think of mutual funds that only hold government bonds. So, the jury is still out on whether
digital currencies would really upset financial stability.
c) Risks to innovation
If digital currency became too popular, it might ironically stifle innovation. Where is your
role if the central bank offers a full-service solution, from digital wallet, to token, to back-end
settlement services?
What if, instead, central banks entered a partnership with the private sector—banks and other
financial institutions—and said: you interface with the customer, you store their wealth, you
offer interest, advice, loans. But when it comes time to transact, we take over.
This partnership could take various forms. Banks and other financial firms, including
startups, could manage the digital currency. Much like banks which currently distribute cash.
Or, individuals could hold regular deposits with financial firms, but transactions would
ultimately get settled in digital currency between firms. Similar to what happens today, but in
a split second. All nearly for free. And anytime.
7
The advantage is clear. Your payment would be immediate, safe, cheap, and potentially
semi-anonymous. As you wanted. And central banks would retain a sure footing in payments.
In addition, they would offer a more level playing field for competition, and a platform for
innovation. Meanwhile your bank, or fellow entrepreneurs, would have ensured a friendly
user experience based on the latest technologies.
Putting it another way: the central bank focuses on its comparative advantage—back-end
settlement—and financial institutions and start-ups are free to focus on what they do best—
client interface and innovation. This is public-private partnership at its best.
Conclusion
Let me conclude. I have tried to evaluate the case this morning for digital currency.
The case is based on new and evolving requirements for money, as well as essential public
policy objectives. My message is that while the case for digital currency is not universal, we
should investigate it further, seriously, carefully, and creatively.
More fundamentally, the case is about change—being open to change, embracing change,
shaping change.
Technology will change, and so must we. Lest we remain the last leaf on a dead branch, the
others having decided to fly with the wind.
In the world of Fintech, we need to harness change so it is fair, safe, efficient, and dynamic.
That was the goal of the Bali Fintech Agenda launched by the IMF and World Bank last
October.
When the winds of change pick up, what will guide us in our journey? The captains sailing
through the Straits of Singapore followed the North Star.
And today? Tomorrow?
I suggest we follow a girl. A young girl. A fearless girl. [show picture of statue]. If you are
lucky, you might be able to meet her in person in New York’s financial district.
She is bold. She is brave. She is confident. She faces forward, toward the future, with grit and
determination—a future she herself is going to shape, with eyes wide open, eagerly, steadily.
I hear her say: Let us sail ahead. I am not afraid. (pause) I, am not afraid.
Thank you.
Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli, Maria Soledad Martinez
Peria, Itai Agur, Anil Ari, John Kiff, Adina Popescu,
and Celine Rochon
With contributions from Fabio Comelli, Federico Grinberg,
Ashraf Khan, and Kristel Poh
DISCLAIMER: Staff Discussion Notes (SDNs) showcase policy-related analysis and research being
developed by IMF staff members and are published to elicit comments and to encourage debate. The
views expressed in Staff Discussion Notes are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the
views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.
SDN/18/08
Casting Light on Central Bank
Digital Currency
November 2018
IMF ST A F F D ISC U SSIO N N O T E
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Casting Light on Central Bank Digital Currency 1
Authorized for distribution by Tobias Adrian, Martin Muhleisen, and Maurice Obstfeld
DISCLAIMER: Staff Discussion Notes (SDNs) showcase policy-related analysis and research
being developed by IMF staff members and are published to elicit comments and to encourage
debate. The views expressed in Staff Discussion Notes are those of the author(s) and do not
necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.
JEL Classification Numbers:
E51, E58, E52
Keywords:
money, central bank digital currencies, monetary policy
Authors’ E-mail Address:
TManciniGriffoli@imf.org; MMartinezPeria@imf.org;
iagur@imf.org; aari@imf.org; jkiff@imf.org;
apopescu@imf.org; crochon@imf.org
1
Paper prepared by an IMF Staff team from MCM, RES, SPR, and LEG, led by Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli (MCM) and
Maria Soledad Martinez Peria (RES) under the guidance of Dong He (MCM), Giovanni Dell’Ariccia (RES), and Vikram
Haksar (SPR). Comments are gratefully acknowledged by seminar participants at the IMF and Inter-American
Development Bank, as well as by IMF reviewing divisions, and separately by Tobias Adrian, Jihad Alwazir, Tamim
Bayoumi, Pelin Berkmen, Luis Brandao Marques, Jess Cheng, Chris Colford, Ulric Eriksson von Allmen, Gaston Gelos,
Masaru Itatani, Nigel Jenkinson, Tanai Khiaonarong, Darryl King, Amina Lahreche, Ross Leckow, Rodolfo Maino,
Fabiana Melo, Aditya Narain, Maurice Obstfeld, Luca Ricci, James Roaf, Herve Tourpe, Romain Veyrune, and
Froukelien Wendt. Karen Lee (MCM) provided excellent research assistance. We are grateful to Shanti Karunaratne,
Danica Owczar, and Wifianni Wirsatyo (MCM) and Gabriela Maciel (RES) for outstanding administrative assistance.
We are indebted to Joe Procopio (COM) for copyediting the document.
2
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
CONTENTS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY __________________________________________________________________________ 4
I. INTRODUCTION _______________________________________________________________________________ 6
II. BASICS OF CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY ___________________________________________ 7
III. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK TO COMPARE DIFFERENT FORMS OF MONEY ___________ 9
IV. IS THERE A ROLE FOR CBDC? USER PERSPECTIVE_________________________________________ 14
V. IS THERE A ROLE FOR CBDC? CENTRAL BANK PERSPECTIVE______________________________ 15
Social Criteria for Money ________________________________________________________ 15
Would CBDC Undermine Financial Integrity? ____________________________________ 20
Would CBDC Undermine Financial Stability and Banking Intermediation? _______ 21
Would Monetary Policy Transmission Remain Effective? ________________________ 25
VI. CENTRAL BANK RESEARCH AND EXPERIMENTS __________________________________________ 27
VII. CONCLUSION ______________________________________________________________________________ 30
REFERENCES ____________________________________________________________________________________ 32
APPENDIX ______________________________________________________________________________________ 38
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
3
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Digitalization is reshaping economic activity, shrinking the role of cash, and spurring new digital
forms of money. Central banks have been pondering whether and how to adapt. One possibility is
central bank digital currency (CBDC)—a widely accessible digital form of fiat money that could be
legal tender. While several central banks have studied the adoption of CBDC and have undertaken
pilots, many have not actively explored it and remain skeptical.
This discussion note proposes a conceptual framework to assess the case for CBDC adoption from
the perspective of users and central banks. It abstracts from cross-border considerations by
assuming that CBDC is for domestic use only. This note discusses possible CBDC designs, and
explores potential benefits and costs, with a focus on the impact on monetary policy, financial
stability, and integrity. This note also surveys research and pilot studies on CBDC by central banks
around the world. The main takeaways are as follows:
•
The impact of CBDC introduction will hinge on its design and country-specific characteristics.
Critical features will be anonymity (the traceability of transactions), security, transaction limits,
and interest earned. The role of cash and commercial bank deposits in payments will also
matter.
•
CBDC could strengthen the benefits and reduce some of the costs and risks to the payment
system and could help encourage financial inclusion. However, demand will not necessarily be
very high and will depend on the attractiveness of alternative forms of money. Moreover, there
are other payment solutions to help central banks more fully achieve their goals relative to
money. CBDC will have to contend with operational risks arising from disruptions and
cyberattacks.
•
Token-based CBDC—with payments that involve the transfer of an object (namely, a digital
token)—could extend some of the attributes of cash to the digital world. CBDC could provide
varying degrees of anonymity and immediate settlement. It could thus curtail the development
of private forms of anonymous payment but could increase risks to financial integrity. Design
features such as size limits on payments in, and holdings of, CBDC would reduce but not
eliminate these concerns.
•
Account-based CBDC—with payments through the transfer of claims recorded on an account—
could increase risks to financial intermediation. It would raise funding costs for deposit-taking
institutions and facilitate bank runs during periods of distress. Again, careful design and
accompanying policies should reduce, but not eliminate, these risks.
•
CBDC is unlikely to affect monetary policy transmission significantly, although operations may
need adaptation. Transmission could strengthen if CBDC spurs greater financial inclusion.
Interest-bearing CBDC would eliminate the effective lower bound on interest rate policy, but
only with constraints on the use of cash.
4
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
•
Overall, it is too early to draw firm conclusions on the net benefits of CBDC. Central banks
should consider their specific country circumstances, paying careful attention to the risks and
relative merits of alternative solutions. Further analysis of technological feasibility and
operational costs is needed.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
5
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
I. INTRODUCTION
1.
The impact of digitalization is widespread and profound. It is changing the nature of
jobs, education, commerce, innovation, and product life cycles. Demographics are accelerating these
developments. Millennials now outnumber baby boomers (Tilford 2018) and are steering the
economy toward their world—one in which digital platforms are central, and nearly second nature.
2.
Payments, and more fundamentally money, are also undergoing tremendous change. 2
Technology, new employment arrangements, and the growing decentralized service economy, as
well as evolving social attitudes, are driving efforts to build new and more decentralized forms of
money. These offer peer-to-peer transactions, micropayments, and easy-to-use interfaces integrated
with social networks. Payments are increasingly being diverted toward privately run solutions. Even
cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin, Ethereum, and Ripple—still early in their development cycle—offer
competing forms of money.
3.
Deep and pressing questions arise. Is there a role for cash, or a cash-like form of money, in
the digital world? Should central banks offer new forms of money? If so, what are the implications
for monetary policy and financial intermediation, stability, and integrity?
4.
Central banks are taking these questions seriously. Several are actively investigating the
possibility of a central bank digital currency (CBDC). This new central bank liability would be a widely
accessible digital form of fiat money, intended as legal tender. One day, it could fully replace
physical cash. CBDC seems to be a natural next step in the evolution of official coinage (from metalbased money, to metal-backed banknotes, to physical fiat money).
5.
This note offers a conceptual framework to evaluate the case for CBDC. The approach
aims to answer a simple question: Does CBDC offer benefits? On the demand side, would it satisfy
end user needs better than other forms of money? And on the supply side, would issuing CBDC
allow central banks to more effectively satisfy public policy goals, including financial inclusion,
operational efficiency, financial stability, monetary policy effectiveness, and financial integrity? In
short, is CBDC a desirable form of money given existing and rapidly evolving alternatives? Although
its adoption appears more promising in some circumstances than in others, a final decision requires
careful evaluation of country-specific circumstances, including a review of technological feasibility
and costs. These factors are beyond the scope of this note.
6.
This note includes a summary of pilot projects and analyses from central banks
exploring the possibility of issuing CBDC. The analysis is based on publicly issued materials and
discussions with staff members at central banks and technology providers around the world.
7.
This note contributes to a growing body of literature on CBDC. Others have already
explored this topic, including international organizations such as the Bank for International
Settlements3 and several central banks (Bank of Canada, People’s Bank of China, Bank of England,
2
See He and others (2017) for a discussion of the impact of financial technology on financial services.
3
See the report produced by the Bank for International Settlements Committee on Payments and Market
Infrastructures (CPMI 2018).
6
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Bank of Finland, Norges Bank, Danmarks Nationalbank, Sveriges Riksbank), 4 as well as academics
and policymakers (Raskin and Yermack 2016; Rogoff 2016; Bordo and Levin 2018; He 2018; He and
Khan 2018; Kahn, Rivadeneyra, and Wong 2018). Those analyses discuss the pros and cons of CBDC
adoption and, in some cases, make policy recommendations. Relative to those studies, this note
makes several contributions. First, it introduces a conceptual framework to evaluate the desirability
of CBDC. In doing so, it emphasizes the perspective of users and their preferences for different
features of money, in addition to the goals of central banks. Second, it considers policy responses to
CBDC adoption to mitigate ensuing risks. Third, it offers a one-stop reference on views and ongoing
and future plans of some central banks from around the world regarding CBDC.
8.
The remainder of the note is organized in six sections. Section II covers the basics of
CDBC. Section III lays out a conceptual framework to compare different forms of money from the
standpoint of end users and the central bank. Section IV puts the approach to use, evaluating
whether there might be a role for CBDC from the perspective of users. Section V considers that
question from the viewpoint of central banks, and in so doing explores different options for
designing CBDC. Part of this section is devoted to gauging the impact of CBDC on financial integrity,
financial stability, and monetary policy transmission. Section VI offers an overview of central bank
investigations, and the last section concludes and raises questions for future research on how CBDC
might affect cross-border payments.
II. BASICS OF CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
9.
CBDC is a new form of money, issued digitally by the central bank and intended to
serve as legal tender. 5 It would differ, however, from other forms of money typically issued by
central banks: cash and reserve balances. CBDC designed for retail payments would be widely
available. In contrast reserves are available only to selected institutions, mostly banks with accounts
at the central bank. 6 Clearly, CBDC is not intended to have a physical form like cash. But as cash, it
would be widely accessible to a country’s residents—and potentially to individuals and organizations
abroad. 7 CBDC could be used as easily for person-to-person, person-to-business, and business-tobusiness transactions of any amount, a notable improvement over cash. 8 Reserves, by contrast,
settle wholesale interbank payments only.
4
Fung and Halaburda (2016); Bech and Garratt (2017); Engert and Fung (2017); Davoodalhosseini (2018); Yifei (2018);
Carney (2018); Kumhof and Noone (2018); Grym and others (2017); Norges Bank (2018); Gürtler and others (2017);
and Sveriges Riksbank (2017).
5
Change in legislation may be needed for CBDC to be legal tender. The definition of legal tender—usually applied to
banknotes and coins issued by central banks—varies slightly across jurisdictions. For instance, a creditor is not
obligated to accept payment in legal tender in all jurisdictions. See He and others (2016) for details.
6
Reserves can be interpreted as a wholesale form of CBDC used exclusively for interbank payments.
7
The cross-border implications of CBDC are not considered here, but some important questions are put forth in the
concluding section for future work.
8
Person to person transactions are deliberately defined as person to person and not peer to peer. The first suggests
that payments can be made seamlessly between individuals, such as when splitting a dinner bill. The second,
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
7
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
10.
CBDC could be account- or token-based, the former involving the transfer of a claim
on an account and the latter of a token between wallets. 9 A transaction in account-based CBDC
would resemble today’s transactions between commercial bank depositors, except accounts would
be held with the central bank. A payer would log in to an account at the central bank—for example,
through a web page or an app on a handheld device—and request a transfer of funds to a
recipient’s account, also at the central bank (Figure 1). The central bank would ensure settlement by
updating a master ledger, but only after verification of the payer’s authority to use the account,
sufficient funds, and authenticity of the payee’s account. The exchange of information would
therefore be substantial.
Figure 1. Account- and Token-Based CBDC, Basic Mechanics
Source: IMF staff
11.
Transacting in token-based CBDC would involve more steps than exchanging cash but
would offer the convenience of not having to meet in person. Unlike cash—the prime example
of a traditional token-based form of money—CBDC tokens would be too complex to be
distinguished from counterfeits by parties to the transaction. Settling a transaction using tokenbased CBDC would require external verification of the tokens. As a result, transactions might not be
entirely anonymous, like cash. The extent of anonymity would depend on whether wallets are
registered and transaction information is recorded.
however, is often used to denote payments in cryptocurrency for which transaction parties, or “peers,” are also
involved in settlement.
9
The distinction between accounts (intangible property) and tokens (tangible property) is emphasized in Kahn and
Roberds (2009). See also Kahn, Rivadeneyra, and Wong (2018) for a discussion of different forms of token-based
CBDC.
8
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
12.
Verification of the tokens and settlement could be centralized or decentralized,
depending on the technology used. Decentralized settlement is possible via the use of distributed
ledger technology (DLT). However, although the technology is evolving, it currently falls short in
scalability, energy efficiency, and payment finality (He and others 2017). DLT could be used over a
closed (“permissioned”) network managed by the central bank. But there are other types of
centralized settlement technology that may prove more efficient. These would check the validity of
the tokens’ serial numbers, then reassign numbers once tokens change wallets to avoid the risk of
double spending.
III. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK TO COMPARE
DIFFERENT FORMS OF MONEY
13.
The conceptual framework in this discussion note is geared toward tackling one key
question: Does CBDC offer net benefits? We explore two sides to benefits. First, on the demand
side, to what extent might CBDC satisfy end users’ need for money, and would it do so better than
other forms of money? Second, on the supply side, would CBDC allow central banks to more fully
achieve their public policy goals and overcome specific market failures? In answering these
questions and to assess the net benefits of CBDC, we also explore some potential costs and tradeoffs associated with its adoption. We refrain, however, from assessing technical implementation
costs and feasibility.
14.
The case for CBDC hinges on whether it strengthens the functions of money for users
and central banks. In economics, money is seen as having three functions: a unit of account, a
means of payment, and a store of value. As a unit of account, money serves as a measuring stick
ideally linked to the same basket of goods over time. As a means of payment, it facilitates
transactions. As a secure store of value, it provides refuge from various sources of risk defined
further below. 10
15.
Users will seek a form of money that maximizes private benefits and minimizes
associated costs and risks. 11 Related criteria are listed below (Figure 2). Emphasis is placed on the
means of payment and store of value functions of money, for which criteria are more diverse. The
relative weight of each criterion below will vary by country and user.
10
These three properties are not entirely independent. If money is not a store of value, it will certainly not offer a
satisfactory means of payment and will consequently not be a satisfactory unit of account. Money offers substantial
efficiency gains by helping coordinate the specification of financial contracts. See He and others (2016) for a
discussion of money versus “currency,” a term used for money issued by governments as legal tender.
11
Kahn, Rivadeneyra, and Wong (2018) adopt a similar approach—“convenience, costs, and safety”—in their phrasing.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
9
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Figure 2. User Criteria to Judge Different Forms of Money
Maximize
benefits
Means of payment
Store of value
• Liquidity: Payment on demand
• Returns: Nominal interest payments 12
• Scalability: Payment of any size (no limits)
• Acceptance: Person to person, person to
business, business to business to and from
any device; no network limitation
• Extra services: Preferential access to other
financial services (loans, advice, etc.)
Minimize
costs
• Transaction: Ease of use; fees
Minimize
risks
• Settlement: Lag between agreeing to a
transaction and actual receipt of funds
• Disclosure: Degree of anonymity
• Theft: Ability to reverse fraudulent transactions,
exposure to fraud/cyber risk
• Loss: Ability to claim ownership or recover
access if lost
• Default: of the money issuer
16.
One important criterion stands out: the ability to make anonymous transactions.
Regarding money, anonymity covers the extent to which identity and transactions are, or can be,
disclosed to transaction parties, third parties, and the government. There are legitimate reasons
people may prefer at least some degree of anonymity—potentially when it comes to everyone
except the government, and regarding the government unless a court order unlocks encrypted
transaction information. It is a way to avoid customer profiling—commercial use of personal
information, for example, to charge higher mortgage rates to people who purchase alcohol. Another
advantage of anonymity is limiting exposure to hacking. Moreover, anonymity is often associated
with privacy—widely recognized as a human right (as stated in the Universal Declaration of Human
Rights [Article 12] and elsewhere).
17.
On the supply side, central banks play a pivotal role and ensure that money delivers on
its three functions. For central banks, this role means two things. First, because they are
accountable to the public, central banks must design the money they issue—and regulate private
forms of money—in a way that satisfies the user needs stated earlier. Second, because they are
public policy institutions, they must ensure that money also meets important social criteria
(illustrated in Figure 3 and discussed in Box 1):
•
12
As a unit of account, money is an important public good that requires price stability in all
economic circumstances. The design of money can favor or interfere with this goal. For instance,
because cash pays no interest, central banks find it difficult to offer deeply negative interest
rates following sharp recessions (more on this later).
Bordo and Levin (2018) argue that for money to be a secure store of value, it must offer risk-free returns.
10
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
•
As a means of payment, money must be universally available and verifiable as well as efficient,
while ensuring appropriate consumer protection and minimal cost to taxpayers.
•
As a store of value, money must be as secure as possible, but it must also allow for efficient
allocation of resources.
18.
In addition, central banks will prefer forms of money that support, or at least do not
undermine, three other public policy goals: financial integrity, financial stability, and
monetary policy effectiveness. 13 In turn, each of these further supports the three functions of
money. Financial integrity covers, among other things, anti–money laundering and combating the
financing of terrorism (AML/CFT) rules, including customer due diligence measures and additional
measures aimed at fighting corruption and fostering good governance.
Figure 3. The Central Bank’s Criteria to Evaluate Different Forms of Money
Box 1. The Birth of Central Banking—a Quest for Efficient, Low-Cost, and Safe Money
There is a fascinating historical account of the birth of central banking in Europe in Kahn, Quinn, and
Roberds (2014). Coins were the predominant form of money in medieval times and during the early
Renaissance. Although they were a relatively efficient means of payment and allowed immediate
settlement, transportation costs grew substantially as commerce spread geographically. Bills of exchange
were introduced to decrease these costs; merchants could purchase bills drawn on the foreign banks
where they intended to do business. However, bills carried substantial counterparty risk, as debtor banks
often did not pay. The Bank of Amsterdam was established in 1609 to reduce the risks inherent in bills of
13
Other goals of central banks regarding CBDC include measures to stem the loss of seigniorage from the growth of
new forms of private money. CBDC would in fact preserve seigniorage and possibly increase it if the central bank’s
balance sheet grew, depending on whether CBDC earned interest. However, because seigniorage is small in many
countries, we do not entertain this line of argument further.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
11
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
exchange, following earlier (though smaller-scale and private) models, such as the Taula de Canvi in
Barcelona (1401), Banco di San Giorgio in Genoa (1408), and Banco di Rialto in Venice (1587). The Bank
of Amsterdam stood ready to pay high-quality Dutch guilders against the receipt of bills. In 1683, it
offered account balances to settle bills of exchange on its books, and soon thereafter suspended the
right of coin withdrawals entirely, thereby shifting the unit of account from commodity money to its
liabilities, as in a system with metal-backed banknotes. At its peak in the mid-1700s, yearly turnover
through the accounts at the Bank of Amsterdam was more than 2.5 times Dutch GDP.
This evolution highlights ongoing efforts to establish increasingly efficient, secure, and lower-cost forms
of money. The Bank of Amsterdam first reduced the risks and costs of payments by offering immediate
and final settlement. Then it did more by offering liquidity backstops to merchant banks that were
funded with bills of exchange. Without this backstop, merchant banks would have faced a trade-off.
They either had to offer a secure store of value by storing the cash received for their bills of exchange or
efficiently allocate funds by lending the cash. This would expose them and their creditors to the liquidity
risk associated with maturity mismatches. The Bank of Amsterdam’s innovation underscores the role of
the state in enhancing the safety of private payment systems without contravening their efficiency. Bank
supervision, lender of last resort functions, and deposit insurance do much the same today.
19.
The last leg of the conceptual framework is to determine competitors to CBDC. These
fall into four categories, but will vary by country: cash, commercial bank deposits, narrow finance,
and cryptocurrencies. All except cash are evolving and rapidly gaining market share.
20.
Commercial bank deposits are going through notable improvements. Payments have
traditionally been facilitated by debit card networks. Today, two continuing transformations are
notable, especially in advanced economies. The first stems from “wrapper” technology, such as
Venmo in the United States, which allows transactions to take place between mobile devices
(bypassing expensive point-of-sale terminals) and adds a layer of security. 14 The other is centralbank-provided fast-payment solutions (“fast payments”). 15 These allow payments of any size and
type (person to person, person to business, business to business) to be settled instantaneously by
the central bank in reserve money through a dedicated platform running continuously at negligible
cost. 16
14
Touchless technology also facilitates debit card transactions. There is wrapper technology, such as PayPal, for
credit card transactions as well, but credit-based transactions lie outside the scope of this note.
15
The largest-scale project is the European Central Bank’s Target Instant Payment Settlement service, to be
introduced in November 2018. There are already other similar initiatives, such as Hong Kong SAR’s Faster Payments
introduced in August 2018, Sweden’s Swish, Denmark’s Straksclearing, and Australia’s New Payments Platform. Other
so-called fast or instant payment solutions are also being rolled out exclusively by commercial banks (see CPMI
2016).
16
Fast payments can be thought of as a form of CBDC offered through a public-private partnership, because they
allow people to settle in central bank reserves at will, at any time, through banks (resembling the proposal in Bordo
and Levin 2018). The central bank, then, offers the means of payment function of money and banks the store of value
function. Together, they offer money’s three functions. From a technological standpoint, fast payments would
however differ, even if account-based. Fast-payment engines are optimized for interoperability with real-time gross
12
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
21.
“Narrow finance solutions” is a term introduced in this discussion note to capture the
various new forms of private money backed one for one by central bank liabilities, either cash
or reserves. These offer stable nominal value, security, liquidity, and potentially close to a risk-free
rate of return. The parallel here is with currency boards (such as in Hong Kong SAR) or metal-backed
banknote systems (such as the gold standard). Two versions of narrow finance solutions are relevant.
The first is stored value facilities 17 such as AliPay and WePay in China, PayTM in India, M-Pesa in
Kenya, and Bitt.com in the Caribbean. These provide private e-money to users against funds received
and placed in custodian accounts. Transactions occur between electronic wallets installed on
handheld devices, can be of any size (although they are usually not large), and are centrally cleared,
but are restricted to participants in the same network. However, holding these forms of money
entails some risk. 18 Nonetheless, this segment is gaining widespread and very rapid acceptance. The
second version of narrow finance solutions—narrow banks—is only beginning to materialize. It
covers institutions that invest client funds only in highly liquid and safe government assets—such as
excess reserves at the central bank—and do not lend. However, they allow payments in their
liabilities through debit cards or privately issued digital money. 19
22.
Cryptocurrencies are different along many dimensions and struggle to fully satisfy the
functions of money, in part because of erratic valuations. Examples include Bitcoin, Ethereum,
and Ripple. These currencies are not the liability of any institution and are not backed by assets.
Their value is usually volatile, because most have rigid issuance rules. Some new cryptocurrencies
attempt to stabilize their value by controlling issuance according to a function of price deviations
from a fiat currency or commodity (as in an exchange rate peg). Examples are Basecoin and
Stablecoin. 20 In all cases, transactions are settled in a decentralized fashion, using distributed ledger
technology.
settlement systems (in which banks keep liquidity and borrow funds to settle intraday payments) and, by extension,
with private banks. This integration would not be necessary for account-based CBDC.
17
The terms “stored value facilities” and “e-money” are taken from the Monetary Authority of Singapore (2017); emoney is defined as “electronically stored monetary value in a payment account that can be used to purchase goods
or services, or to transfer funds to another individual.”
18
These depend on whether the stored value facility has access to the funds in the custodian account and whether it
can invest them in illiquid assets and the degree to which e-money issuance can exceed reserves. Both of these
examples invite the question of why users would choose to exchange or forgo a safe and liquid asset like cash or a
government bond for another provided by a private intermediary. The answer lies in the ease with which users can
initiate payments on private platforms, and potentially access other services. Note that new players—such as large
tech firms, including Amazon, Apple, Google, and Facebook—may well enter this space. They could offer e-money to
purchase their goods at a discount, in exchange for valuable information.
19
See Ali (2018) for instance for a solution based on privately issued digital money. Note that firms in the narrow
finance category do not create money, unlike fractional reserve banks. In a world of CBDC alone, only the central
bank could create money. Today most money creation is “outsourced” to commercial banks, which create deposits
when they extend credit. The process of money creation nonetheless responds to interest rates set by central banks.
20
See, however, Eichengreen (2018) for doubts about the ability to maintain a peg, short of full backing by fiat
currency as in the narrow finance example (referred to as a currency board).
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
13
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
IV. IS THERE A ROLE FOR CBDC? USER PERSPECTIVE
23.
Competing forms of money can be ranked according to the criteria described earlier.
The evaluation is presented visually in Figure A1.1 of Appendix I, in the form of “spider charts,” and
explanations are provided in the subsequent Table A1.1. Higher scores are captured by points
farther from the center. The more attractive the form of money, the larger the surface covered by
the spider chart. All monies were deemed liquid, so that criterion was left aside.
•
Cash is not an especially attractive means of payment given its high transaction costs (the need
to meet in person and withdraw cash, which may be difficult in remote locations), vulnerability
to theft, and lack of returns in the form of interest. However, cash offers immediate settlement,
no default or cyber risk, and—importantly—full anonymity, a potentially attractive feature to
users.
•
Cryptocurrencies are the least attractive option, receiving a low score in settlement speed
because of current technological limitations (which may eventually be overcome). Their main
advantage is anonymity.
•
Private e-money provided by stored value facilities scores high on several fronts. It offers
widespread acceptance, low transaction costs via user-friendly interfaces designed by customercentric firms, and full-service bundling with other financial as well as social services. Narrow
banks could further reduce default risk—and possibly enhance scalability by offering largervalue payments, although potentially lower ease of use, depending on design.
•
Commercial bank deposits, as they were traditionally structured, offered average value. On the
positive side, they provided security from theft and loss, and integration with additional services,
while on the negative side there was limited acceptance (cumbersome peer-to-peer payments
requiring checks or wire transfers) and scalability (floors on debit card payments). However,
recent reforms and innovations, including fast payments, have improved the attractiveness of
commercial bank deposits considerably. Deposits with fast payment are completely scalable and
are widely accepted, without network limits, have no settlement risk, and offer limited default
risk where deposit insurance is available. 21 Transaction costs (fees and ease of use) are minimal.
24.
CBDC would not strictly dominate any of these alternative forms of money. As evident
in Figure A1.1, CBDC would closely compete with evolving commercial bank deposits and e-money.
CBDC stands out only when it comes to anonymity and default risk. There are two sets of features:
fixed features, for which the central bank does not have discretion, and flexible features.
•
Fixed design features: CBDC would be on par with fast-payment solutions regarding acceptance
(person to person, person to business, business to business without network restrictions),
settlement risk, and transaction cost (to the extent that mobile interfaces are well designed—no
small feat). CBDC would probably be superior regarding default risk, although in many
jurisdictions only marginally. Instead, CBDC would score poorly in terms of offering additional
21
Insurance limits nonetheless should ensure that funds earmarked for payments—not all those held as savings—are
protected. Households—large firms to a lesser degree—have the option of splitting deposits across accounts.
14
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
services (although banks could provide the front-end applications to manage CBDC and could
cross-sell services).
•
Flexible design features: CBDC could offer competitive interest returns, protection from theft and
loss, scalability, and anonymity, though not all at once as these features depend on one another.
As discussed earlier, anonymity could be provided to different degrees: relative to transaction
parties, third parties, and/or the government. But the greater the anonymity, the harder it is to
reverse fraudulent transactions (risk of theft) and claim ownership (risk of loss). And central
banks may be prepared to offer full anonymity only with strict and low limits on CBDC holdings,
thus undermining scalability. Finally, CBDC could offer interest. If it paid the policy rate, it would
be as attractive as narrow finance solutions, although commercial banks could still offer higher
rates on deposits (and recoup profits by charging higher lending rates—more on this later).
25.
In summary, demand for CBDC will depend on its design. It may not be high in more
advanced economies, except as a cash replacement, but could be very attractive elsewhere.
Commercial bank deposits with fast payments, and to some extent narrow banking solutions, will
rival CBDC and could be superior in some areas. CBDC could excel only regarding anonymity,
although at some cost to scalability and security. As such, it would compete mostly with cash, by
allowing small-value transactions with at least some degree of anonymity. Someday CBDC may,
indeed, be introduced as a replacement for paper bills, which will become increasingly anachronistic
as economic activity grows ever more digital. However, in jurisdictions with limited banking
penetration and unreliable settlement platforms, CBDC may be more attractive to users, especially in
the absence of stored value facilities.
V. IS THERE A ROLE FOR CBDC? CENTRAL BANK
PERSPECTIVE
26.
This section gauges whether central banks could benefit from CBDC to more fully
achieve public policy goals. These include satisfying the social dimensions of money’s three
functions, as well as financial integrity, financial stability, and monetary policy effectiveness.
Social Criteria for Money
27.
CBDC is unlikely to offer near-term assurance of price stability in all economic
circumstances—as needed to bolster the unit of account function of money. The global
financial crisis starkly illustrated that interest rate policy can be constrained by the presence of cash.
Policy rates cannot be brought significantly below zero without risking a massive shift into cash,
which ensures zero returns (see Dell’Ariccia and others (2017) for a full discussion and Habermeier
and others (2013) for an overview of unconventional monetary policy). However, cash is unlikely to
go away anytime soon, for political reasons. Only over the longer term, if CBDC is adopted widely,
would cash be eliminated, much as happened with metal coinage. In that scenario, policy rates could
go deep into negative territory. But this would happen only to the extent that CBDC also charged
negative rates and did not replace cash as a means to circumvent policy. In the interim, other
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
15
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
measures have been proposed to allow for deeply negative policy rates, but with questionable
feasibility and without necessarily requiring CBDC. 22
28.
CBDC could help ensure equal access to a means of payment for all citizens, thereby
favoring financial inclusion. But other solutions also exist and may be more efficient. Much
depends on the barriers to financial inclusion. For one, cash may be difficult to obtain and use in
underpopulated and rural areas. As a majority of the population shifts to digital forms of money, the
infrastructure for cash (such as distribution networks, counting machines, and armored services) may
deteriorate, and businesses may resist dealing with it. As in other cases of negative externalities,
government intervention may be warranted. One approach may involve subsidizing the provision of
cash in underserved areas. CBDC may not be a viable solution if access to technology is limited. If
the problem is instead the supply of bank accounts—which banks deem unprofitable or require
unaffordable or nonexistent technology—the question is whether the private sector can offer
alternative solutions. M-Pesa in Kenya and PayTM in India are examples of successful initiatives,
although with some state support in the case of M-Pesa (from the UK Department for International
Development). Alternatively, the government could subsidize the deployment of bank branches.
Or—short of direct intervention—it could facilitate the development of online banking and
communication infrastructure in rural areas and reduce the cost of bank-intermediated small-value
transactions by deploying fast payments. Where these solutions are not feasible, CBDC could
provide an alternative. If, however, barriers to financial inclusion stem from an aversion to
formalization, neither CBDC nor other initiatives would prove satisfactory.
29.
CBDC may instead help reduce costs associated with the provision of cash, thereby
ensuring an efficient means of payment from a public policy perspective. Issuing and managing
cash are expensive. Hasan, De Renzis, Schmiedel (2013) estimate the cost to be 0.5 percent of GDP
for the euro area, similar to the cost in Canada (Kosse and others 2017) and Uruguay (Alvez,
Lluberas, and Ponce 2018). Costs fall mostly on banks, firms, and households. Although introducing
and maintaining CBDC would probably entail substantial fixed costs, marginal operational costs
would likely be low, despite the need for customer service. On this basis alone, the business case to
adopt CBDC would probably be better for larger jurisdictions able to absorb the fixed costs.
30.
CBDC would not help resolve the tension central banks face between offering a secure
store of value and promoting financial intermediation. Narrow finance solutions offer a liquid
and secure store of value at the cost of financial intermediation. This is because payments must be
entirely prefunded, as explained earlier. Fractional reserve banks, however, pool the liquidity buffers
households and firms maintain to respond to payment shocks. And because not all shocks
materialize at once (at least not most of the time), they can lend a portion of the funds, keeping only
22
Cash could be prohibited altogether as argued in Rogoff (2014), made costly to hold as suggested in Bordo and
Levin (2018), or made to depreciate against CBDC, which would become the sole legal tender, as in Agarwal and
Kimball (2015). Note that if CBDC were not interest bearing, the effective lower bound could bind at even higher
rates of interest, as CBDC could be stored more cheaply than cash. CBDC has also been touted as a means to
implement aggressive monetary stimulus known as a “helicopter drop” by crediting CBDC accounts or wallets
holding CBDC tokens. However, doing so would not necessarily reach all citizens. Moreover, the issue of legitimacy
remains: how does the central bank decide how much to transfer to each household given the notable and very
explicit redistributional consequences? Finally, helicopter drops would continue to be viewed as a form of monetary
financing, thus undermining central bank independence.
16
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
a fraction in highly liquid and safe assets. Even though central banks should be concerned if narrow
banking solutions grow substantially, CBDC would not help reverse the trend. CBDC is also, after all,
a form of money that requires full prefunding. Instead, fast payments would help fractional reserve
banks offer money that competes with that offered by stored value facilities and other narrow
finance solutions.
31.
Other potential benefits of CBDC must be seen against the backdrop of a reduction in
the use of cash. The trend is already evident in some countries and is expected to become more
widespread. Sweden is probably the most striking example. 23 In other countries, cash in circulation
as a share of GDP has actually increased in the past decade, as documented in Bech and others
(2018). However, a second look reveals that such movements are largely cyclical and can be partly
explained by low interest rates. As shown in Box 2, the preference for cash has mostly been
decreasing or has remained unchanged except in reserve currency countries (Switzerland and the
United States). In addition, the demand for cash is likely to diminish as older generations give way to
more technology-adept generations. Merchants and banks in both advanced and developing
economies are also trying to discourage cash transactions, given the related costs.
23
Cash in circulation as a share of GDP is currently half its value 10 years ago, representing merely 6 percent of
central bank liabilities and 2 percent of the money supply.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
17
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Box 2. A Closer Look at the Demand for Cash
In many countries, currency in circulation has increased significantly in the past decade (Figure 4a). 24
However, much of that increase seems cyclical, because it can be explained in good part by lower
interest rates, higher uncertainty, and economic recoveries. 25 Figure 4b shows that in selected countries
the unexplained (residual) component of cash in circulation—loosely associated with preferences—has
often decreased or remained stable. Only in Switzerland and the United States has this component
increased markedly over the past decade, in part thanks to those countries’ reserve currency status.
However, cash still accounts for a large share of transaction volumes, though not of value, even in
advanced economies. The use of cash is subject to habit, increases with age, and decreases with
education and income. It is generally lowest in countries with the most developed payment systems. 26
Figure 4a. Cash in Circulation
(as percent of GDP)
Source: IFS, Haver
24
See also Bech and others (2018) and Jobst and Stix (2017).
25
The baseline is a regression of the log of real cash in circulation on deposit rates and the log of real GDP. Results
are robust to inclusion of the log of stock prices (to capture wealth effects), different measures of uncertainty
(Chicago Board Options Exchange Volatility Index and uncertainty indices), and country-by-country and panel
estimates.
26
For related analysis, see Flannigan and Parsons (2018); Arango-Arango and others (2018); Esselink and Hernández
(2017); Wakamori and Welte (2017); Bagnall, Bounie, and Huynh (2016); Krüger (2016); Bennet, Schuh, and Schwartz
(2014); and Sisak (2011). For example, the cash share of payments is 82 percent by volume in Austria (63 percent by
value), but 46 percent in the United States (23 percent by value).
18
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Figure 4b. Growth of Real Cash Balances
(in percent, annualized growth rates)
Sources: Staff calculations
32.
As the use of cash wanes, there is greater concern about the security of the payment
system if it is dominated by private firms. But there are solutions other than CBDC. Private
issuers of money, including rapidly growing stored value facilities, may not internalize the social cost
of systemic disruptions from cyberattacks or negligence, and thus may not adequately invest in
security (to the extent that users remain oblivious to these risks and do not require sufficient
safeguards). Central banks would be more prone to do so, but that does not mean that the risk of
cyberattacks would disappear. Moreover, CBDC could offer a backup solution if disruptions in the
digital infrastructure materialize, unless there are large-scale natural disasters and power outages.
(Cash is similarly at risk since its infrastructure also requires electricity.) Another solution is to deploy
fast payments, which also give central banks control over an essential piece of the payment
architecture. Finally, adequate regulation should also bolster the security of money, even if privately
provided.
33.
The disappearance of cash could also pose risks to consumer protection. Again, CBDC
can help, but so would fast payments and regulation. Modern payment systems are often
operated by a few commercial banks and by even fewer clearinghouses and messaging services.
Payment systems tend to become natural monopolies. This reflects strong network externalities (the
value of using a given payment network is greater the larger the user community), decreasing
average costs (savings from netting transactions over a large user base), high fixed development
and maintenance costs, and significant gains from aggregating data, which—to an individual—is
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
19
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
worth little. However, private monopolistic providers will tend to offer inadequate and expensive
services and could take unfair advantage of data. The prevalence of cash as an attractive and lowcost competitor may have limited the monopoly power of private monies. In the future, if antitrust
regulation and data protection prove insufficient, CBDC could serve that same purpose. However, so
too could the deployment of low-cost fast payments.
34.
In summary, while central banks could benefit from CBDC to more fully satisfy some
of the social criteria of money, in many countries there are also other solutions. CBDC may be
a way to reduce the cost to society associated with the use of cash. Financial inclusion may also
benefit, if private sector solutions and policy efforts do not bear fruit. However, CBDC will not
support efficient allocation of resources. It could, under some circumstances, help central banks
bolster the security of payment systems and consumer protection. But regulation and, where
possible, fast-payment platforms should offer compelling alternatives.
Can CBDC Balance Privacy and Financial Integrity Concerns?
35.
In designing money, national authorities already face a trade-off between satisfying
legitimate user preferences for privacy and mitigating risks to financial integrity. Cash protects
privacy because it is anonymous: no account is necessary, and there is no record of transactions.
However, it also facilitates criminal financial transactions such as money laundering, financing of
terrorism, corruption, and tax evasion. Most of the cash in circulation is in the top two largest
denominations, often associated with illicit payments or store of value. 27
36.
Recent discussions on the trade-off between financial integrity and privacy for cash
could prove useful for CBDC design. Eliminating cash would undermine privacy. Moreover, it is
unlikely to improve financial integrity since illicit transactions would presumably migrate to another
form of money (McAndrews 2017). Ironically, those seeking anonymity for legitimate purposes
might even adopt the parallel money, contributing to its liquidity and attractiveness for criminal use.
This pattern may be visible in the adoption of cryptocurrencies. Proposals to do away with highdenomination bills seem more appealing (Rogoff 2016 and references therein). Remaining smalldenomination bills could in part satisfy legitimate preferences for privacy but would pose risks for
illicit transactions.
37.
Depending on its design, CBDC can strengthen or undermine financial integrity.
Financial integrity could be strengthened if authorities impose strict limits on the size of
transactions. Alternatively, CBDC can be designed to facilitate effective identity authentication and
tracking of payments and transfers. Identities would be authenticated through customer due
diligence procedures, and transactions recorded. But unless required by law, users’ information
could be protected from disclosure to third parties and governments, while criminals could be
deterred by the risk of investigation and prosecution. Although promising on paper, these solutions
would have to be further evaluated, and questions answered. For instance, Would users trust the
safeguards established to protect their privacy? Would central banks be held responsible for
27
Judson (2017); sample includes Australia, Brazil, Canada, the euro area, Hong Kong SAR, India, Japan, Mexico,
Singapore, South Arabia, South Korea, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, Russia, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
See also Europol (2015).
20
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
compliance failures, even if customer due diligence procedures were outsourced? And to what
extent could authorities benefit from the ability to scrutinize transaction information for illicit activity
in real time? On the other hand, CBDC offering full anonymity and large-value transactions would
undermine financial integrity relative to cash and current noncash fund transfer systems. Whatever
design is chosen, it should accommodate the implementation of effective AML/CFT measures.
Would CBDC Undermine Financial Stability and Banking Intermediation?
38.
CBDC could affect financial stability and banking intermediation if it competes with
bank deposits. Hence, in what follows we assume CBDC with characteristics similar to those of bank
deposits: traceability and protection from loss or theft. In a world of diverse consumers, it is
reasonable to assume that some will prefer and adopt CBDC.
39.
Two hypothetical scenarios are considered. The first is a tranquil period following the
introduction of CBDC. Questions arise such as how banks will respond, what will happen to bank
intermediation and funding, and how central banks might react. The second scenario assumes a
period of systemic financial stress in a world with CBDC. The key question in this case is what
happens to run risk—the potential for a significant shift of deposits from banks to CBDC.
Scenario 1: Risk of Disintermediation in Tranquil Times
40.
Banks will likely react to the introduction of CBDC, but their ability to defend their
business model depends on market power. As some depositors leave banks in favor of CBDC,
banks could increase deposit interest rates to make them more attractive.28 But the higher deposit
rates would reduce banks’ interest margins. As a result, banks would attempt to increase lending
rates, though at the cost of loan demand. 29 The greater banks’ market power, the less demand for
credit would contract and the more effectively banks could respond to CBDC by preserving profits
(see Box 3).
Box 3. Banks’ Response to CBDC—Higher Rates on Deposits and Lending 30
The introduction of CBDC draws deposits away from banks, leading to an upward shift in the deposit
supply curve (Figure 5a). Banks counteract some of the impact on their deposit bases by raising deposit
interest rates (Figure 5b). Moreover, banks pass part of this deposit rate hike on to their loan interest
rates. When banks have more market power in lending (also reflected in the steepness of the demand
curve for deposits), they can better insulate their profits by passing the deposit rate hike on to loan
28
Banks could also respond by providing more and better complementary financial services.
29
In addition, central banks could lower policy rates to counter the tighter financial conditions stemming from banks’
higher lending rates, so that the banks’ response to CBDC would be less contractionary for the economy. Moreover,
the net impact of CBDC adoption on interest rates will depend on how the central banks introduce the CBDC, where
an injection of CBDC via the sale of government bonds could, under specific circumstances, lead to lower rates
(Barrdear and Kumhof 2016).
30
This discussion of the reaction of banks to CBDC adoption is based on a model by Agur and others (forthcoming)
assuming an oligopolistic market structure in lending markets.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
21
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
rates. Banks with little market power adjust more aggressively in quantity, exhibiting a larger contraction
in deposit and loan volume.
Figure 5a. Introduction of CBDC
Bank
deposit
rate
Deposit
supply
with CBDC
Account-like
CBDC shifts
up deposit
supply
𝑟2∗
𝑟1∗
Deposit
supply
Deposit
demand
𝐷1∗
𝐷2∗
Source: IMF staff
Quantity of bank deposits
Figure 5b. Effects of CBDC and market power in lending
Bank
deposit
rate
∗
𝑟2𝑏
Deposit
supply
with CBDC
More market power in
lending reduces extent of
disintermediation due to
CBDC. Instead, deposit
rates adjust more.
Deposit
supply
∗
𝑟2𝑎
Deposit demand,
low market power
in lending
𝑟1∗
Deposit demand,
high market power
in lending
Source: IMF staff
22
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
∗
𝐷2𝑎
∗
𝐷2𝑏
𝐷1∗
Quantity of bank deposits
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
41.
Banks could try to replace the deposits that shift to CBDC with other forms of funding.
Potential alternatives are commercial paper, bonds, and equity. All are market (wholesale) types of
funding. There are three likely implications to such a shift.
42.
First, bank funding would become more expensive. Deposit insurance and implicit
government guarantees allow banks to fund themselves with deposits at lower cost than with other
instruments. 31 Hence, switching away from deposits could result in lower bank profits or higher
lending rates to preserve margins. The magnitude of the effect may not be enormous, though, given
that most of the value of deposits in most banking systems is uninsured.
43.
Second, the introduction of CBDC may affect market discipline in the banking sector.
Discipline stems from banks facing higher costs of funding or a drop in deposits as they take more
risks (Berger 1991). However, insured depositors do not impose discipline on banks since they do
not bear the consequences of the risks they undertake. Following the introduction of CBDC, market
discipline could decline (increase) if banks lose more (fewer) uninsured than insured depositors. If
market discipline diminishes, banks could take on more risk.
44.
Third, bank funding may become less stable. Retail depositors are more stable sources of
funding than wholesale depositors (see Huang and Ratnovski 2011; Gertler, Kiyotaki, and Prestipino
2016). If more (fewer) retail depositors prefer CBDC to wholesale depositors, bank funding could
become more (less) volatile. In that case, banks might have to hold more liquid assets to meet
regulatory requirements or cut back on lending.
45.
The extent of disintermediation will be greater among banks in more direct
competition with CBDC. CBDC would likely be in greater competition with retail than with
wholesale deposits, which require larger-value payments. Thus, banks with a larger share of retail
deposits will face tougher competition following the introduction of CBDC and may not be able to
raise lending rates to preserve profits. Greater presence of nonbank loan providers would add to
competitive pressure on banks.
46.
In the event of disintermediation, central banks can respond in several ways, although
some are not especially palatable over the medium term and would imply a dramatic step
away from central banks’ typical mandates. The central bank could limit the decline in bank
deposits and lending by setting limits on individual CBDC holdings or discouraging (such as through
fees) convertibility from bank deposits to CBDC. In addition, the central bank could lend the funds
diverted from deposits back to banks. This would allow banks to keep lending, although the central
bank could require more capital or collateral, with possible implications for the cost and volume of
31
Ueda and di Mauro (2013) estimate that government guarantees have reduced bank funding costs between 60
and 80 basis points in recent decades. Other studies quantify the impact of government guarantees on bank funding
costs by analyzing funding cost differentials for banks deemed too big to fail (Tsesmelidakis and Merton 2013;
Acharya, Anginer, and Warburton 2016; Kelly, Lustig, and van Nieuwerburgh 2016; Kroszner 2016).
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
23
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
lending. Moreover, the central bank’s balance sheet would grow, it would systematically take on
credit risk, and it would have to decide how to allocate funds across banks. 32
47.
At the margin, central banks could help maintain the ties between customers and
banks by allowing banks to manage CBDC. As discussed earlier, banks could offer wallets to hold
and make transactions in CDBC and could offer customer support.
Scenario 2: Run Risk in Times of Systemic Financial Stress
48.
CBDC may facilitate a generalized run on banks by offering a readily available, safe,
and liquid alternative to deposits. 33 But in many cases, this effect will be muted. First, the
introduction of CBDC would not facilitate idiosyncratic runs from one bank to another. Such
movement can already take place electronically at the click of a button. Second, if a banking crisis
coincides with a more general economic (currency or sovereign) crisis, funds will be withdrawn from
all local assets, including CBDC. 34 Third, even short of a general crisis, CBDC is unlikely to matter
much if very safe and liquid alternatives already exist. These include reserves-only narrow banks or
Treasury-only mutual funds 35 or, in some cases, state banks with healthy balance sheets or explicit
and credible state guarantees. 36
49.
In some cases, CBDC could even help the central bank ease liquidity pressures and thus
contain bank runs. 37 The provision of extensive liquidity support is pervasive during banking crises.
For example, central banks provided liquidity assistance to banks in almost 96 percent of the 151
crisis episodes studied by Laeven and Valencia (2018). Liquidity can be provided by increasing
32
A situation in which the central bank does not recycle deposits back to banks, but instead takes on the direct role
of maturity transformation and intermediation, would mean an even larger departure from the central bank mandate
and could give rise to a sovereign–central bank nexus, if the monetary authority is pressured to lend to the
government.
33
Bank run models, such as Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and Goldstein and Pauzner (2005) and references therein,
emphasize information asymmetries regarding liquidity mismatches on banks’ balance sheets, and liquidity needs of
depositors, as the driving forces behind runs. Depositors may also run because of concerns about solvency rather
than illiquidity (Calomiris and Gorton 1991).
34
In more general economic crises, depositors may also fear losses in real terms because of high inflation and
currency depreciation and may thus attempt to hold foreign assets, leading to capital outflows. In fact, almost 30
percent of banking crises coincide with currency and/or sovereign crises (Laeven and Valencia 2018). Emerging
market and developing economies are more susceptible to these twin or triple crises (Caprio and Klingebiel 1996;
Laeven and Valencia 2018). Advanced economies are not immune to these episodes as is evident in the recent
European sovereign debt crisis (IMF 2011; Brown, Evangelou, and Stix 2017; Sibert 2013).
35 Schmidt, Timmermann, and Wermers (2016) document runs from money market mutual funds following the
collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008, showing that while most prime money market mutual funds experienced
outflows, those invested in Treasury bills observed strong inflows “as investors sought the liquidity of the U.S.
government market as part of a flight-to-safety.”
36
Barajas and Steiner (2000), focusing on depositor behavior in Colombia, and Mondschean and Opiela (1999),
considering Poland, find that state banks are perceived as safer and have an advantage in attracting deposits relative
to private banks. However, a large number of studies, focusing on a diverse set of countries, do not offer
corroborating evidence (Adler and Cerutti 2015; Hasan, Jackowicz, Kowalewski, and Kozlowski. 2013; Semenova 2007;
Das and Ghosh 2004; Ungan and Caner 2004; Hori, Ito, and Murata 2009).
37
The absence of a lender of last resort has been associated with US banking panics in the pre–Federal Reserve era
(Calomiris 2008; Gorton and Tallman 2016).
24
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
reserves (to replace funding) and cash (to allow banks to meet deposit withdrawals). Having CBDC
will not affect the central bank’s ability to increase reserves, since this can already take place
electronically. But in geographically vast countries where transporting cash to bank branches and
ATMs might be a costly and time-consuming endeavor, CBDC could also facilitate the process of
providing liquidity to banks and resolve runs faster. 38
50.
Even if the introduction of CBDC increased the risk of systemic bank runs, deposit
insurance could alleviate the effects. Liquidity provision needs are smaller in countries with
deposit insurance before a banking crisis. 39 Countries adopting CBDC should, therefore, have a
deposit insurance scheme to lower the probability of runs. 40 The effectiveness of such schemes in
mitigating runs, though, will depend on the credibility of the fiscal backstop and the extent of
coverage.
Would Monetary Policy Transmission Remain Effective?
51.
The introduction of CBDC is unlikely to significantly affect the main channels of
monetary policy transmission under plausible CBDC designs. 41 The channels are fourfold:
•
The basic interest rate channel may be the most affected and could strengthen. Changes in
policy interest rates induce households and firms to rebalance investment and consumption
between the future and the present, especially if these are exposed to interest-sensitive
borrowing and saving instruments. To the extent that CBDC increases financial inclusion—thus
access precisely to such instruments—monetary policy transmission could strengthen (Mehrotra
and Nadhanael 2016). Gains would be most evident if CBDC were interest bearing.
•
The bank lending channel could also strengthen. Through this channel, policy interest rates and
their expectation affect bank balance sheets and profits—ultimately their creditworthiness and
thus their nondeposit funding cost and lending rates. 42 This channel would strengthen if CBDC
increased the share of banks’ wholesale funding, as argued earlier.
38
For similar reasons, central banks should not impose aggregate limits on CBDC in circulation. These could induce
price distortions as a result of scarcity premiums. These limits could also accelerate runs as there is an attempt to
purchase CBDC before others do and the aggregate limit is reached. Note also that the trigger for a run could
become more unpredictable; when the run is to CBDC rather than to cash it will be harder for depositors to observe
the signal of others’ liquidity needs or information about the bank as there will be no lining up outside branches.
39
In the Laeven and Valencia (2018) sample of crises, median peak liquidity provision was 15.3 percent in countries
with deposit insurance; it was 22.4 percent of deposits for countries without it. In addition, there is evidence that
uninsured wholesale depositors are more predisposed to runs (Covitz, Liang, and Suarez 2013).
40
In fact, some runs, such as the case of the run on Northern Rock in the United Kingdom in 2007, have been
associated with gaps in deposit insurance coverage for small depositors (Goodhart 2011).
41
Similar conclusions are suggested in Meaning and others (2018) and in CPMI (2018). Another unexplored, though
interesting, channel is the potential for CBDC to facilitate the resetting of prices and thus weaken transmission. A
more remote option requiring attention is for CBDC to allow for interest rates to differ across individuals or regions.
42
See Bernanke (2007) and references therein for a full description of the bank lending channel. Older versions of
this channel, originating in a period with higher reserve requirements and credit market segmentation, suggested
that a higher supply of reserves increased deposits—loanable funds—and hence bank lending.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
25
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
•
The credit channel is unlikely to be affected much. This channel is related to the one above;
policy rates affect asset prices and collateral values of borrowers, thus their creditworthiness and
costs of borrowing. 43 However, CBDC should not markedly impinge on these effects.
•
Likewise, the exchange rate channel—through which changes in policy rates bring about
rebalancing between foreign and domestic assets, and a commensurate variation in the
exchange rate affecting exports and imports—is unlikely to be affected.
52.
This relatively benign view depends on the expectation that central banks would
remain in a position to affect market interest rates relevant to the channels above. First, central
banks should be able to affect term spreads through communication as before, such as by releasing
and discussing their interest rate projections. Second, central banks should be able to retain control
of interest rates on reserves. As long as banks demand reserve balances to pay each other—
ultimately, as long as banks intermediate payments—the central bank should be able to set their
marginal price. 44 This is key, since the price of reserves determines the opportunity cost for banks to
lend funds to each other, and by extension the rates set in the much larger money markets. In turn,
these affect rates on riskless, and ultimately risky, assets. Clearly, the presence of banks across these
markets, as well as arbitrage and lack of market segmentation, is key to transmission. CBDC,
however, is not expected to markedly affect any of these conditions under most design scenarios.
53.
One scenario, however, would significantly test the standard transmission channels,
but could be resolved with a change in operating framework. If banks were no longer involved
in intermediating payments, having lost the business to CBDC (or stored value facilities, depending
on how these are regulated), demand for reserves would disappear. This scenario resembles the
“cashless world” considered by Woodford (2000). In this world, though, monetary policy has the
means to remain effective. Woodford argues that “perfect control over overnight rates would still be
possible, through adjustments of the rate paid on central bank balances.” In the digital world, the
insight translates into paying interest on CBDC. Doing so would put a floor on interest rates if CBDC
is provided without limit. Indeed, no one with access to CBDC would lend at a rate below that
offered by CBDC, which would remain the safest and most liquid asset available. This is akin to
controlling monetary policy by paying interest on reserves when these are in excess of what is
demanded by the banking sector for precautionary purposes (referred to as a “floor system”).
43
It could weaken if fintech innovations, beyond just CBDC, reduce information asymmetries inherent in the markups
charged to borrowers.
44
Some adjustments may nevertheless be necessary to central banks’ operating frameworks. CBDC is likely to
displace cash, but could also partially drain reserves from commercial banks if customers withdraw deposits to hold
CBDC. To the extent that banks need the reserves for precautionary purposes, central banks would still be able to
replenish these by engaging in liquidity-injecting open market operations. Ultimately, demand for precautionary
reserves might actually decrease, because CBDC could attenuate the variance of payment shocks (unlike cash, CBDC
does not require lumpy withdrawals from costly visits to ATMs) or increase their predictability. But even if the shape
and position of the demand curve for reserves change, central banks should be able to adapt their supply of reserves
to stabilize interest rates. In the interim, movements between deposits and CBDC could be volatile and require more
frequent liquidity-injecting open market operations—perhaps on a fixed-rate full allotment basis—to stabilize
interest rates. A floor system could also be considered to stabilize interest rates, since the demand for liquidity does
not need to be accurately forecast.
26
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
VI. CENTRAL BANK RESEARCH AND EXPERIMENTS
54.
Several central banks, in both advanced and emerging market and developing
economies, are considering the pros and cons of issuing CBDC. Table 1 summarizes the
jurisdictions in which central banks are (or have been) actively exploring CBDC for retail use based on
publicly available information.
Table 1. Jurisdictions Where Retail CBDCs Are Being Actively Explored 4546
Australia (on hold)
Bahamas
Brazil
Canada
China (and here)
Curaçao and Sint Maarten
Eastern Caribbean
Ecuador (pilot complete)
Denmark (rejected)
Israel
Norway (ongoing)
Philippines
Sweden
United Kingdom (on hold)
Uruguay (and here)(pilot)
Sources: Central banks or various news sources per hyperlinks above. (Information
has not been verified through official channels.)
55.
Some sovereigns have issued, or may issue, retail digital currencies, though these are
not CBDC because they are not issued by central banks as their liability. For example, the
Marshall Islands has discussed launching the SOV, a crypto asset that will become legal tender along
with the US dollar, with the apparent intention to raise funds for the government. Likewise,
Venezuela is planning to issue the petro, a commodity-backed crypto asset.
56.
Central banks are considering CBDC for two main reasons: Declining use of cash in
advanced economies and financial inclusion in emerging market and developing economies.
These and other objectives mentioned by central banks are summarized in Table 2. None of the
central banks surveyed cite seigniorage preservation or monetary policy effectiveness at the zero
45
“Active” means central banks that have convened projects to seriously explore CBDC or that have undertaken
pilots. Some central banks have publicly indicated that they are investigating CBDC but have provided little to no
detail. These include central banks in Bahrain, Barbados, Egypt, the Euro Area (and rejected), Hong Kong SAR, India,
Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Korea (and rejected), Lebanon, New Zealand (on hold), Russia, and Switzerland.
46
There is doubt about Senegal’s and Tunisia’s CBDC, which appear to be fiat-collateralized crypto assets. In the case
of Senegal’s e-CFA e-currency, the only connection to the central bank seems to be that the e-currency complies
with the e-money regulations of the Banque Centrale des Etats de l’Afrique de l’Ouest. In Tunisia, the post office has
been operating an e-dinar digital money wallet since 2000, and in 2016 it partnered with Monetas and DigitUs to
offer a crypto-powered payment app, but there has been no central bank involvement.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
27
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
lower bound as rationales for CBDC adoption, with papers by the Bank of Canada emphatically
denying the latter. 47 The main rationale for advanced economies seems to be countering the growth
of private forms of money (operational risk and monopoly distortions) and reducing costs
associated with managing cash (cost efficiency). For example, Sweden points to increasing payment
system single-point-of-failure risk associated with diminishing cash usage. In emerging market
economies, the main interest in CBDC seems to be fostering financial inclusion by reaching out to
the unbanked segments of the population. Only China cites monopoly distortions as a justification.
Cost efficiency is also behind China’s investigations, Ecuador’s CBDC issuance (launched in early
2015 though shut down in early 2018), and Uruguay’s six-month trial. 48 Some developing economy
central banks have also mentioned reducing the costs and risks associated with the distribution of
physical cash.
Table 2. Rationales for Exploring CBDCs via Publicly Available Information
Diminishing Cash Usage
Monopoly
Distortions
Operational
Risks
Cost
Efficiency
Bahamas
Financial
Inclusion
X
Canada
X
China
X
X
X
X
CBCS
X
X
X
ECCB
X
X
X
Ecuador
Countering derisking
X
Norway
X
Senegal
Sweden
Other
X
X
X
Tunisia
Uruguay
X
X
X
Monetary policy was not cited as a rationale by any of the central banks surveyed. It was not possible
to ascertain the rationales, based on publicly available information, for Australia, Bahrain, Denmark, the
European Union, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Jamaica, South Korea, and Switzerland.
Sources: Central banks or various news sources (as indicated in italics) per hyperlinks in Table 1.
Information has not been verified through official channels.
Note: CBCS = Central Bank of Curaçao and Sint Maarten; ECCB = Eastern Caribbean Central Bank.
47
Engert and Fung (2017) conclude that “reducing the effective lower bound does not provide a compelling
motivation to issue CBDC.”
48
Ecuador’s main rationale was to avoid the costs of managing physical dollars in its fully dollarized economy.
However, user acceptance was very low, seemingly because of lack of trust in the central bank (White 2018).
28
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
57.
Some central banks are reportedly no longer pursuing CBDC. Factors cited include small
benefits for central banks and potential disintermediation and bank run risks (Australia, Denmark,
European Central Bank, New Zealand, Switzerland).
58.
In terms of design, most central banks seem to be contemplating forms of accountbased CBDC, though with various levels of anonymity; some token-based solutions also exist.
The Eastern Caribbean Central Bank and the People’s Bank of China could offer both account- and
token-based CBDC, with accounts managed by commercial banks and/or other licensed financial
institutions. The People’s Bank of China is also considering fully anonymous token-based wallets,
albeit with low payment limits. However, other central banks seem to be shying away from such
solutions because they would not meet Financial Action Task Force requirements. 49 Most central
banks are considering anonymous CBDC when it comes to transacting parties and third parties but
not in the case of the government. This is the situation of the People’s Bank of China. (Wallets with
greater anonymity, however, would have lower payment limits.) Protecting users against risks of
theft and loss was considered important to many of the central banks mentioned.
59.
A number of central banks surveyed indicated that CBDC should be available 24 hours
a day, 7 days a week, to mimic the accessibility of cash. In this regard, Canada, China, and
Sweden are looking into CBDC with offline capability. This would be offered by preloading tokens
onto a wallet while online, then validating transactions via encrypted messaging to point-of-sale
terminals, similarly to cash cards. In all cases, central banks are considering limits to such
transactions. Functionality could be temporarily available during electricity or infrastructure
breakdowns but still be susceptible to catastrophic events. 50 Even cash is not particularly resilient in
such circumstances, as its distribution and use require electricity (to operate automated teller
machines, vending machines, and other cash dispensers), and cash can be destroyed easily in a
catastrophe.
60.
None of the central banks surveyed are seriously considering interest-bearing CBDC.
Central banks appear to be concerned with financial intermediation, lending contraction, and
heightened bank balance sheet volatility. Some, such as the Reserve Bank of New Zealand and
Uruguay simply assert on principle that CBDC should be fungible. Central banks contemplating
token-based CBDC suggest that paying interest would present a technical challenge, though not an
insurmountable one. Others raise the hurdle of tracking interest payments for tax purposes.
However, Sweden’s proposed CBDC, the e-krona, will have the built-in ability to pay interest if the
central bank decides to do so.
61.
The central banks surveyed are studying ways of managing and funding CBDC
infrastructure. Although marginal costs of managing physical cash are likely higher than those of
49
The Financial Action Task Force is an independent intergovernmental body that develops and promotes policies to
protect the global financial system against money laundering, terrorism financing, and the financing of proliferation
of weapons of mass destruction. It has set out recommendations for customer due diligence (for instance, identity
verification) implementation, record keeping, and suspicious transaction reporting requirements for financial
institutions and designated nonfinancial businesses and professions.
50
A recurrence of the 1859 Carrington Event could knock out communications and power for up to a year and render
digital money useless.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
29
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
CBDC, the high up-front fixed costs may favor CBDC adoption in larger economies. Some central
banks are exploring the option of building and maintaining CBDC in-house, but most are planning
to outsource these onerous tasks, despite the risks involved. Some central banks are contemplating
cost-sharing mechanisms. For example, China may make third-party wallet providers bear part of the
development costs in return for keeping a cut of any fees charged and benefiting from cross-selling
opportunities. The Uruguay pilot appears similar. China is also thinking about charging fees on large
transactions, just as for large cash withdrawals.
62.
Various central banks surveyed plan to outsource CBDC development, though under
close supervision. For example, the Uruguay CBDC pilot turned to the Roberto Giori Company to
develop digital notes, IN Switch Solutions for wallets, and Redpagos for “storefront” operations
(cashing e-pesos in and out). Tunisia used Monetas for digital notes and DigitUS for wallets, but
developed the user interface itself (according to The Tunisian Post). Senegal used eCurrency Mint for
the notes, while the Banque Régionale de Marchés provided the wallets and user interface. 51
63.
Central banks are for the most part focused on CBDC applications for the domestic
economy. Only Canada and China mentioned cross-border issues, but more as complications than
opportunities. Canada seemed focused on accessibility by tourists. China cited cross-border capital
management. Other projects focus more on intermediating wholesale payments across borders,
such as a joint project between the Bank of Canada, the Monetary Authority of Singapore, and the
Bank of England.
VII. CONCLUSION
64.
CBDC could be the next milestone in the evolution of money. The history of money
suggests that, while the basic functions of money might not change, the form does evolve in
response to user needs. Digitalization of many aspects of economic activity is prompting central
banks to seriously consider the introduction of CBDC.
65.
CBDC is a digital form of existing fiat money, issued by the central bank and intended
as legal tender. It would potentially be available for all types of payments and could be
implemented with a variety of technologies.
66.
This discussion note introduces a three-step conceptual framework to assess CBDC’s
potential to create value both for end users and for central banks. The first step is to identify
the criteria with which users evaluate different forms of money. The second step involves
establishing the public policy goals of central banks with respect to money. The third step lays out
the competitive landscape, comprising existing and evolving forms of money.
67.
Overall, the note finds no universal case for CBDC adoption as yet. From the
perspective of end user needs, it finds that demand for CBDC will depend on the
attractiveness of alternative forms of money. In advanced economies, there may be scope for the
adoption of CBDC as a potential replacement for cash for small-value, pseudo-anonymous
51
The International Telecommunications Union is working on standardized terms and conditions for the design of
digital fiat currencies, including currencies issued by central banks and managed by private entities.
30
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
transactions. But in countries with limited banking sector penetration and inefficient settlement
technology, demand for CBDC may well be greater.
68.
From a central bank perspective, the case for CBDC is likely to differ from country to
country. CBDC may reduce the costs to society that are associated with the use of cash. Moreover,
CBDC may improve financial inclusion in cases of unsuccessful private sector solutions and policy
efforts. It could also help central banks bolster the security of, and trust in, the payment system and
protect consumers where regulation does not adequately contain private monopolies. But
regulation and, where possible, novel payment solutions could offer compelling alternatives to a
CBDC.
69.
For countries that decide to introduce CBDC, appropriate design and policies should
help mitigate ensuing risks. Monetary policy transmission is unlikely to be significantly affected
and may even benefit from greater financial inclusion. Moreover, though it will not eliminate illicit
activity, CBDC may in some situations enhance financial integrity. However, it also entails risks for
financial integrity if badly designed. In addition, although CBDC could increase the cost of funding
for deposit-taking institutions and intensify run risk in some jurisdictions, design choices and
policies can help ease such concerns. Nevertheless, operational and reputational risks arising from
malfunctions of the digital infrastructure or cyberattacks are likely to remain as challenges.
70.
Looking ahead, the cross-border implications of CBDC raise a multitude of new
questions that merit investigation. For instance, from a practical standpoint, how would tourists
be able to make payments in a foreign country that has adopted CBDC? Should foreigners have
access to CBDC? To what extent would this complicate know-your-customer and AML/CFT
compliance, and could standardized information be requested across countries? Would access to
CBDC in a reserve currency (such as e-dollars) facilitate currency substitution in countries that have
weak institutions? And to what extent might safe-haven flows be encouraged, potentially draining
resources from countries that face banking, sovereign, or currency crises? Finally, if CBDC were used
for cross-border transactions, how might central banks be required to cooperate? Would they
absorb some of the functions of correspondent banks and thus take on additional liquidity, credit,
and foreign exchange rate risk—or might tokens be created for cross-border payments among
particular central banks, commercial banks, or firms? Research on CBDC should proceed resolutely
given that the questions to be explored are deep and difficult and have far-reaching implications.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
31
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
REFERENCES
Acharya, V., D. Anginer, and A. Warburton. 2016. “The End of Market Discipline? Investor
Expectations of Implicit Government Guarantees.” https://ssrn.com/abstract=1961656 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1961656.
Adler, G., and E. Cerutti. 2015 "Are Foreign Banks a Safe Haven? Evidence from Past Banking Crises."
IMF Working Paper 15/43, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Agarwal, R., and M. Kimball. 2015. “Breaking through the Zero Lower Bound.” IMF Working Paper
15/224, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Agur, I., A. Ari, and G. Dell’Ariccia. Forthcoming. "Central Bank Digital Currencies: Design Tradeoffs
and Implications." IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Ali, R. 2018 "Cellular Structure for a Digital Fiat Currency." MIT Digital Currency Initiative.
https://dci.mit.edu/digital-fiat-currency.
Alvez, M., R. Lluberas, and J. Ponce. 2018. "The Cost of Using Cash and Checks in Uruguay."
Unpublished.
Arango-Arango, C., Y. Bouhdaoui, D. Bounie, M. Eschelbach, and L. Hernandez. 2018. "Cash Remains
Top-of-Wallet! International Evidence from Payment Diaries." Economic Modelling 69 (January): 38–
48.
Bennett, B. S. Schuh, and S. Schwartz. 2014. "The 2012 Diary of Consumer Payment Choice." Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston Research Data Report.
Bagnall, J., D. Bounie, and K. Huynh. 2016. "Consumer Cash Usage and Management: A CrossCountry Comparison with Diary Survey Data." International Journal of Central Banking 12 (4): 1–61.
Barajas, A., and R. Steiner. 2000. "Depositor Behavior and Market Discipline in Colombia." IMF
Working Paper 00/214, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Barrdear, J. and M. Kumhof. 2016. “The Macroeconomics of Central Bank Issued Digital Currencies.”
Bank of England Working Paper 605, Bank of England, London.
Bech, M. L., U. Faruqui, F. Ougaard, and C. Picillo. 2018. "Payments Are A-Changin’ but Cash Still
Rules." BIS Quarterly Review (March):67–80.
Bech, M. L., and R. Garratt. 2017. “Central Bank Cryptocurrencies.” BIS Quarterly Review. September.
Berger, A. 1991. “Market Discipline in Banking.” In Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and
Competition. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
32
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Bernanke, B. 2007. "Inflation Expectations and Inflation Forecasting." Speech delivered at the
Monetary Economics Workshop of the National Bureau of Economic Research Summer Institute,
Cambridge, MA.
Bordo, M., and A. Levin. 2018. "Central Bank Digital Currency and the Future of Monetary Policy."
Monetary Policy and Payments 3:143–78.
Brown, M., I. Evangelou, and H. Stix. 2017. “Banking Crises-Bail-ins and Money Holdings.” Central
Bank of Cyprus Working Paper 2017-2.
Calomiris, C. 2008. “Testimony before the Committee on Oversight and Government Reform.” US
House of Representatives, December 9.
———, and G. Gorton. 1991. "The Origins of Banking Panics: Models, Facts, and Bank Regulation."
Financial Markets and Financial Crises. University of Chicago Press.
Caprio, G. Jr., and D. Klingebiel. 1996. "Bank Insolvencies: Cross-Country Experience." World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper Series 1620, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Carney, Mark. 2018. "The Future of Money." Speech at the inaugural Scottish Economics Conference,
Edinburgh University, March 2.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (CPMI). 2016. “Fast Payments—Enhancing the
Speed and Availability of Retail Payments.” CPMI Report 154, Basel.
———. 2018. “Central Bank Digital Currencies.” CPMI Report 174, Basel.
Covitz, D., N. Liang, and G. Suarez. 2013. "The Evolution of a Financial Crisis: Collapse of the AssetBacked Commercial Paper Market." Journal of Finance 68 (3): 815–48.
Das, A., and S. Ghosh. 2004. "Market Discipline in the Indian Banking Sector: An Empirical
Exploration." https://econwpa.ub.uni-muenchen.de/econ-wp/fin/papers/0410/0410020.pdf.
Dell'Ariccia, G., V. Haksar, T. Mancini-Griffoli, K. Eckhold, S. Gray, F. Han, G. H. Hong, E. Lundback, H.
Oura, H. Poirson, P. Rabanal, and D. Sandri. 2017. "Negative Interest Rate Policies—Initial
Experiences and Assessments." IMF Policy Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Diamond, D., and P. Dybvig. 1983. “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity.” Journal of Political
Economy 91 (3): 401–19.
Eichengreen, B. 2018. "Why 'Stable Coins' Are No Answer to Bitcoin's Instability." Project Syndicate,
September 11. https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/stable-coins-unviablecryptocurrencies-by-barry-eichengreen-2018-09.
Engert, W., and B. Fung. 2017. "Central Bank Digital Currency: Motivations and Implications." Bank of
Canada Staff Discussion Paper 2017-16, Ottawa.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
33
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Esselink, H., and L. Hernández. 2017. "The Use of Cash by Households in the Euro Area." Occasional
Paper Series 201, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
Europol. 2015. “Why Cash Is King? A Strategic Report on the Use of Cash by Criminal Groups as a
Facilitator for Money Laundering.” https://www.europol.europa.eu/publications-documents/whycash-still-king-strategic-report-use-of-cash-criminal-groups-facilitator-for-money-laundering.
Financial Action Task Force (FATF). 2015. “Money Laundering through the Physical Transportation of
Cash.” Paris.
Flannigan, G., and S. Parsons. 2018. "High-Denomination Banknotes in Circulation: A Cross-Country
Analysis." Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin, March.
Fung, B., and H. Halaburda. 2016. “Central Bank Digital Currencies: A Framework for Assessing Why
and How.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper 2016–22, Ottawa.
Gertler, M., N. Kiyotaki, and A. Prestipino. 2017. "A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics."
International Finance Discussion Paper 1219, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC.
Goldstein, I., and A. Pauzner. 2005. "Demand–Deposit Contracts and the Probability of Bank Runs"
Journal of Finance 60 (3): 1293–327.
Goodhart, C. 2011. "The Macro-Prudential Authority: Powers, Scope and Accountability." Market
Trends 2011-2, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
Gorton, G., and E. Tallman. 2016. "How Did Pre-Fed Banking Panics End?" NBER Working Paper
22036, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Grym, A., P. Heikkinen, K. Kauko, and K. Takala. 2017. “Central Bank Digital Currency.” Bank of Finland
Economics Review 5.
Gürtler, K., S. Nielsen, K. Rasmussen, and M. Spange. 2017. “Central Bank Digital Currency in
Denmark,” Analysis 28, Danmarks National Bank.
Habermeier, K., L. Jacome, T. Mancini-Griffoli, C. Baba, T. Bayoumi, J. Chen, G. Dell’Ariccia, S. Gray, M.
Ismael, T. Mondino, A. Pescatori, T. S. Sedik, S. Sgherri, H. Tanimoto, K. Ueda, N. Valckx, and F.
Valencia. 2013. "Unconventional Monetary Policies—Recent Experiences and Prospects." IMF Policy
Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Hasan, I., T. De Renzis, and H. Schmiedel. 2013. “Retail Payments and the Real Economy.” European
Central Bank Working Paper 1572, Frankfurt.
Hasan, I., K. Jackowicz, O. Kowalewski, and L. Kozlowski. 2013. “Market Disciplines during Crisis:
Evidence from Bank Depositors in Transition Countries.” Journal of Banking and Finance 37 (12):
5436–51.
34
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
He, D. 2018. “Monetary Policy in the Digital Age.” Finance and Development 55 (2).
He, D., K. Habermeier, R. Leckow, V. Haksar, Y. Almeida, M. Kashima, N. Kyriakos-Saad, H. Oura, T.
Saadi Sedik, N. Stetsenko, and C. Verdugo-Yepes. 2016. “Virtual Currencies and Beyond: Initial
Considerations.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 16/03, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
He D., and A. Khan. 2018. “Central Bank Digital Currencies.” In Global Financial Stability Report,
Chapter 1, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, April.
He, D., R. Leckow, V. Haksar, T. Mancini-Griffoli, N. Jenkinson, M. Kashima, T. Khiaonarong, C.
Rochon, and H. Tourpe. 2017. "Fintech and Financial Services: Initial Considerations." IMF Staff
Discussion Note 17/05, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Hori, M., Y. Ito, and K. Murata. 2009. "Do Depositors Respond Rationally to Bank Risks? Evidence
from Japanese Banks during Crises." Pacific Economic Review 14 (5): 581–92.
Huang, R., and L. Ratnovski. 2011. "The Dark Side of Bank Wholesale Funding." Journal of Financial
Intermediation 20 (2): 248–63.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2011. “Euro Area Policies: 2011 Article IV Consultation—Staff
Report; Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the
Executive Director for Member Countries.” IMF Country Report 11/184, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
Jobst, C., and H. Stix. 2017. “Doomed to Disappear: The Surprising Return of Cash across Time and
across Countries.” CEPR Discussion Paper 12327, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Judson, R. 2017. "The Death of Cash? Not So Fast: Demand for U.S. Currency at Home and Abroad,
1990–2016." Paper presented at the 3rd International Cash Conference, Deutsche Bundesbank, April.
Kahn, C., S. Quinn, and W. Roberds. 2014. “Central Banks and Payment Systems: The Evolving Tradeoff between Cost and Risk.” Paper presented at the Norges Bank Conference on the Uses of Central
Banks: Lessons from History, June 5–6.
Kahn, C. M., F. Rivadeneyra, and T.-N. Wong. 2018. “Should the Central Bank Issue e-Money?”
Unpublished.
Kahn, C., and W. Roberds. 2009. “Why Pay? An Introduction to Payments Economics.” Journal of
Financial Intermediation 18 (1): 1–23.
Kelly, B., H. Lustig, and S. van Nieuwerburgh. 2016. “Too-Systemic-to-Fail: What Option Markets
Imply about Sector-Wide Government Guarantees.” American Economic Review 106 (6): 1278–319.
Kosse, A., H. Chen, M.-H. Felt, V. D. Jiongo, K. Nield, and A. Welte. 2017. “The Costs of Point-of-Sale
Payments in Canada.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper 2017-4, Ottawa.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
35
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Kroszner, R. 2016. “A Review of Bank Funding Cost Differentials.” Journal of Financial Services
Research 49 (2): 151–74.
Krüger, M. 2016. “Pros and Cons of Cash: The State of the Debate.” In 2016, Cash on Trial, edited by
C. Beer, E. Gnan, and U. Birchler. SUERF Conference Proceedings 2016/1, SUERF—The European
Money and Finance Forum, Vienna, 45–67.
Kumhof, M., and C. Noone. 2018. "Central Bank Digital Currencies—Design Principles and Balance
Sheet Implications." Bank of England Staff Working Paper 725, London.
Laeven, L., and F. Valencia. 2018. "Systemic Banking Crises Revisited." IMF Working Paper 18/206,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
McAndrews, J. 2017. “The Case for Cash.” ADBI Working Paper 679, Asian Development Bank
Institute, Manila.
Meaning, J., B. Dyson, J. Barker, and E. Clayton. 2018. "Broadening Narrow Money: Monetary Policy
with a Central Bank Digital Currency." Bank of England Staff Working Paper 724, London.
Mehrotra, A., and G. Nadhanael. 2016. "Financial Inclusion and Monetary Policy in Emerging Asia." In
Financial Inclusion in Asia, edited by S. Gopalan and T. Kikuchi. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 93–127.
Davoodalhosseini, S. 2018. "Central Bank Digital Currency and Monetary Policy." Bank of Canada
Staff Working Paper 2018-36, Ottawa.
Mondschean, T., and T. Opiela. 1999. "Bank Time Deposit Rates and Market Discipline in Poland: The
Impact of State Ownership and Deposit Insurance Reform." Journal of Financial Services Research 15
(3): 179–96.
Monetary Authority of Singapore. 2017. “Consultation Paper on Proposed Payment Services Bill.”
http://www.mas.gov.sg/News-and-Publications/Consultation-Paper/2017/Consultation-Paper-onProposed-Payment-Services-Bill.aspx.
Norges Bank. 2018. "Central Bank Digital Currencies." Norges Bank Paper 1, Oslo.
Raskin, M., and D. Yermack. 2016. “Digital Currencies, Decentralized Ledgers, and the Future of
Central Banking.” NBER Working Paper 22238, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,
MA.
Rogoff, K. 2014. "Costs and Benefits to Phasing Out Paper Currency." NBER Working Paper 20126,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
———. 2016. The Curse of Cash. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Schmidt, L., A. Timmermann, and R. Wermers. 2016. "Runs on Money Market Mutual Funds."
American Economic Review 106 (9): 2625–57.
36
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Semenova, M. 2007. "How Depositors Discipline Banks: The Case of Russia." Economics Education
and Research Consortium Working Paper Series 07-02e, Kiev.
Sibert, A. 2013. “Deposit Insurance after Iceland and Cyprus.” VoxEU.org, April 2.
https://voxeu.org/article/deposit-insurance-after-iceland-and-cyprus.
Sisak, B. 2011. "What Drives Cash Demand? Transactional and Residual Cash Demand in Selected
Countries." Magyar Nemzeti Bank Working Paper 10, Budapest.
Sveriges Riksbank. 2017. The Riksbank’s e-krona Project Report 1." September.
https://www.riksbank.se/globalassets/media/rapporter/ekrona/2017/rapport_ekrona_uppdaterad_170920_eng.pdf.
Tilford, C. 2018. "The Millennial Moment.” In Charts, Financial Times, June 6.
https://www.ft.com/content/f81ac17a-68ae-11e8-b6eb-4acfcfb08c11.
Tsesmelidakis, Z., and R. Merton. 2013. "The Value of Implicit Guarantees."
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2231317 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2231317.
Ueda, K., and W. di Mauro. 2013. "Quantifying Structural Subsidy Values for Systemically Important
Financial Institutions." Journal of Banking and Finance 37 (10): 3830–42.
Ungan, A., and S. Caner. 2004. “Depositor Behaviour and Market Discipline in Turkey.”
https://ssrn.com/abstract=495122.
Wakamori, N., and A. Welte. 2017. "Why Do Shoppers Use Cash? Evidence from Shopping Diary
Data." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 49 (1): 115–69.
White. 2018. “The World’s First Central Bank Electronic Money Has Come—And Gone: Ecuador,
2014–2018.” Cato Institute, Washington, DC.
Woodford, M. 2000. "Monetary Policy in a World without Money." NBER Working Paper 7853,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Yifei, F. 2018. "Some Considerations about Central Bank Digital Currency." YICAI News Service,
January 25. https://www.yicai.com/news/5395409.html.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
37
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
APPENDIX
Figure A1.1. Attractiveness to Users of Different Forms of Money
Cash
Cryptocurrencies
Private e-money (by stored value facilities)
Traditional bank deposits
Improved bank deposits (fast payments & other)
CBDC
38
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
CASTING LIGHT ON CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY
Table A1.1. Scores by Criteria
Cash
Traditional bank
Cryptocurrencies*
deposits
Private e-money
Bank deposits with
(by stored value
fast payment
facilities)
Scalability
M: not for
M: not for small-
L: not for large
M: could be
H: all transactions
large-value
or micro-value
payments
expanded to
possible
transactions
transactions
large-value
transactions
Extra services
Interest returns
Acceptance
Settlement risk
L: none
H: access to all
L: limited services
H: integration
H: like bank
bank services
through
with social and
deposits
exchanges
financial services
L: none
L: usually none,
L: zero
M: interest,
yielding
though below
though could be
policy rate
offered
M: interest
M: limits to
L: only person to
L: only few
M: person to
H: like stored value
change; some
business and
retailers accept
business, business
facilities but no
merchants
business to
to business,
network limit
reject
business, point-
person to person,
of-sale terminals
but only within
needed
network
H: none;
M: some delay
M: lags; struggle
M: like bank
H: instantaneous in
immediate
to establish
deposits
central bank
settlement
finality for some
money (reserves)
Theft & loss
M: hard to
M: can reverse
L: hard to recover/
M: like bank
M: like bank
risk
recover/
transaction &
claim due to
deposits
deposits
claim; no
claim ownership
anonymity
H: none, a
M: deposit
H: to the extent
M: no deposit
M: like bank
central bank
insurance
code is solid, not a
insurance, though
deposits
liability
some safeguards
L: high energy
H: very easy to
H: very easy to use,
requirements
use, cheap
cheap
H: full anonymity
L: not anonymous
L: not anonymous
cyber risk
Default risk
liability
Transaction
L: need to
costs
physically
M: service fees
meet
Anonymity
H: full
costs
anonymity
L: not anonymous
Note: Scores are H (high), M (medium), and L (low) to the extent the corresponding criteria are desirable
for the end user. For instance, a high mark for transaction costs means that costs are low and thus
attractive to users. *Rapidly evolving technological advances could improve scores.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
39
Committee on
Payments and Market
Infrastructures
Markets Committee
Central bank
digital currencies
March 2018
This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org).
©
Bank for International Settlements 2018. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or
translated provided the source is stated.
ISBN 978-92-9259-142-7 (print)
ISBN 978-92-9259-143-4 (online)
Foreword
The history of central banking began with payment services. Since then payment-related innovation has
always been an integral part of central banking. Modern examples include the establishment of systems
allowing for immediate interbank gross settlement and the recent increased emphasis on faster retail
payment systems. Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) represent another such potential innovation.
This joint report by the Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures and the Markets Committee
provides an initial analysis of CBDCs. It offers a high-level overview of their implications for payments,
monetary policy and financial stability. The analysis of the committees reflects initial thinking in this rapidly
evolving area and is a starting point for further discussion and research. It also highlights that the issuance
of a CBDC requires careful consideration.
The Committees thank Klaus Löber (European Central Bank) and Aerdt Houben (Netherlands Bank)
and the two Committee working groups for their efforts in preparing this report.
Benoît Cœuré
Chair, Committee on Payments and
Market Infrastructures
Central bank digital currencies
Jacqueline Loh
Chair, Markets Committee
iii
Contents
Foreword ...............................................................................................................................................................................................iii
Executive summary ........................................................................................................................................................................... 1
1.
Introduction ...................................................................................................................................................................... 3
2.
Taxonomy........................................................................................................................................................................... 3
2.1
The money flower .................................................................................................................................................. 4
2.2
Design features ....................................................................................................................................................... 5
3.
Payment aspects.............................................................................................................................................................. 7
3.1
General purpose CBDC ........................................................................................................................................ 7
3.2
Wholesale only CBDC ........................................................................................................................................... 8
3.3
Other considerations ............................................................................................................................................ 9
3.4
Key feasibility and operational challenges .................................................................................................. 9
4.
Monetary policy aspects ............................................................................................................................................ 10
4.1
Desirability for monetary policy ..................................................................................................................... 10
4.2
Implications for monetary policy implementation and interest rates ............................................ 12
5.
Financial intermediation, financial stability and cross-border aspects .................................................... 14
5.1
Role of the central bank .................................................................................................................................... 14
5.2
Banks business models, financial intermediation and markets ......................................................... 15
5.3
Financial stability .................................................................................................................................................. 16
5.4
Cross-border and global dimensions .......................................................................................................... 17
References .......................................................................................................................................................................................... 19
Annex A: Principles of monetary policy implementation ................................................................................................ 21
Annex B: Flow-of-funds representation ................................................................................................................................. 24
Annex C: The impact of CBDC on seigniorage .................................................................................................................... 26
Annex D: Members of the working groups ........................................................................................................................... 27
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures ............................................................................................. 27
Markets Committee ............................................................................................................................................................... 28
Central bank digital currencies
v
Executive summary
Interest in central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) has risen in recent years. The Committee on Payments
and Market Infrastructures and the Markets Committee recently completed work on CBDCs, analysing their
potential implications for payment systems, monetary policy implementation and transmission as well as
for the structure and stability of the financial system.
Key highlights of the work are:
CBDC is potentially a new form of digital central bank money that can be distinguished from reserves
or settlement balances held by commercial banks at central banks. There are various design choices
for a CBDC, including: access (widely vs restricted); degree of anonymity (ranging from complete to
none); operational availability (ranging from current opening hours to 24 hours a day and seven days
a week); and interest bearing characteristics (yes or no).
Many forms of CBDC are possible, with different implications for payment systems, monetary policy
transmission as well as the structure and stability of the financial system. Two main CBDC variants are
analysed in this report: a wholesale and a general purpose one. The wholesale variant would limit
access to a predefined group of users, while the general purpose one would be widely accessible.
CBDC raises old questions about the role of central bank money, the scope of direct access to central
bank liabilities and the structure of financial intermediation. Traditionally, central banks have, for
various reasons, tended to limit access to (digital) account-based forms of central bank money to
banks and, in some instances, to certain other financial or public institutions. By contrast, physical
central bank money, ie cash, is widely accessible. This approach has, in general, served the public and
the financial system well, setting a high bar for changing the current monetary and financial structure.
Wholesale CBDCs, combined with the use of distributed ledger technology, may enhance settlement
efficiency for transactions involving securities and derivatives. Currently proposed implementations
for wholesale payments – designed to comply with existing central bank system requirements relating
to capacity, efficiency and robustness – look broadly similar to, and not clearly superior to, existing
infrastructures. While future proofs of concept may rely on different system designs, more
experimentation and experience would be required before central banks can usefully and safely
implement new technologies supporting a wholesale CBDC variant.
In part because cash is rapidly disappearing in their jurisdiction, some central banks are analysing a
CBDC that could be made widely available to the general public and serve as an alternative safe,
robust and convenient payment instrument. In circumstances where the traditional approach to the
provision of central bank money – in physical form to the general public and in digital form to banks
– was altered by the disappearance of cash, the provision of CBDC could bring substantial benefits.
However, analysing whether these goals could also be achieved by other means is advisable, as CBDCs
raise important questions and challenges that would need to be addressed. Most importantly, while
situations differ, the benefits of a widely accessible CBDC may be limited if fast (even instant) and
efficient private retail payment products are already in place or in development.
Although a general purpose CBDC might be an alternative to cash in some situations, a central bank
introducing such a CBDC would have to ensure the fulfilment of anti-money laundering and counter
terrorism financing (AML/CFT) requirements, as well as satisfy the public policy requirements of other
supervisory and tax regimes. Furthermore, in some jurisdictions central banks may lack the legal
authority to issue a CBDC, and ensuring the robust design and operation of such a system could prove
to be challenging. An anonymous general purpose CBDC would raise further concerns and challenges.
Although it is unlikely that such a CBDC would be considered, it would not necessarily be limited to
retail payments and it could become widely used globally, including for illegal transactions. That said,
compared with the current situation, a non-anonymous CBDC could allow for digital records and
traces, which could improve the application of rules aimed at AML/CFT.
Central bank digital currencies
1
Issuance of a CBDC would probably not alter the basic mechanics of monetary policy implementation,
including central banks’ use of open market operations. CBDC introduces a new type of central bank
money whose demand – like cash – would need to be accommodated. CBDC would also not
necessarily affect the discretion that central banks have in choosing their monetary policy
implementation techniques (eg reliance on purchases of securities or credit operations with banks) as
well as the maturity, liquidity and credit risk of their assets. However, if flows into CBDC were to
become large and not associated with offsetting declines in physical banknotes, as could be the case
in times of financial stress, challenges could arise (such as a need to broaden the assets that the central
bank can hold or take on as collateral).
CBDC could enrich the options offered by the central bank’s monetary policy toolkit, eg by allowing
for a strengthening of pass-through of policy rate changes to other interest rates or addressing the
zero lower bound (or the even lower, effective bound) on interest rates. It is not clear, however, that
the current pass-through is anything but adequate. Furthermore, other more conventional tools and
policies can to some extent achieve similar outcomes without introducing new risks and challenges
(such as implementing negative interest rates on public holdings of a general purpose CBDC). And
some of these gains might not arise without discontinuing higher denomination banknotes, which –
although helping with AML/CFT requirements – would by itself entail some costs.
Implications are more pronounced for monetary policy transmission and financial markets, especially
if a CBDC was to be designed as, or de facto became, an attractive asset. As a liquid and creditworthy
asset, a wholesale variant available to institutional investors that would be akin to interest-bearing
central bank reserves or reverse repo facilities, yet widely tradeable, could function as a safe asset
comparable in nature to short maturity government bills. A general purpose variant could compete
with guaranteed bank deposits, with implications for the pricing and composition of banks’ funding.
The introduction of a CBDC would raise fundamental issues that go far beyond payment systems and
monetary policy transmission and implementation. A general purpose CBDC could give rise to higher
instability of commercial bank deposit funding. Even if designed primarily with payment purposes in
mind, in periods of stress a flight towards the central bank may occur on a fast and large scale,
challenging commercial banks and the central bank to manage such situations. Introducing a CBDC
could result in a wider presence of central banks in financial systems. This, in turn, could mean a
greater role for central banks in allocating economic resources, which could entail overall economic
losses should such entities be less efficient than the private sector in allocating resources. It could
move central banks into uncharted territory and could also lead to greater political interference.
For currencies that are widely used in cross-border transactions, all the considerations outlined above
would apply with added force, especially during times of generalised flight to safety. The introduction
of a CBDC in one jurisdiction could adversely affect others. Central banks that have introduced or are
seeking to introduce a CBDC should consider cross-border issues where relevant.
Any steps towards the possible launch of a CBDC should be subject to careful and thorough
consideration. Further research on the possible effects on interest rates, the structure of
intermediation, financial stability and financial supervision is warranted. The effects on movements in
exchange rates and other asset prices remain largely unknown and also deserve further exploration.
More generally, central banks and other authorities should continue their broad monitoring of digital
innovations, keep reviewing how their own operations could be affected and continue to engage with
each other closely. This includes monitoring the emergence of private digital tokens that are neither
the liability of any individual or institution nor backed by any authority. At this time, the general
judgment is that their volatile valuations, and inadequate investor and consumer protection, make
them unsafe to rely on as a common means of payment, a stable store of value or a unit of account.
2
Central bank digital currencies
1.
Introduction
Some central banks have started to consider whether they might, at some stage in the future, issue digital
currencies of their own. While providing greater access to digital forms of central bank liabilities is not an
entirely new idea (eg Tobin (1985)), the recent debate has been motivated by a number of factors. These
include: (i) interest in technological innovations for the financial sector; (ii) the emergence of new entrants
into payment services and intermediation; (iii) declining use of cash in a few countries; and (iv) increasing
attention to so-called private digital tokens. In response to the growing interest of central banks, the
private sector and the public at large, the Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (CPMI) and
the Markets Committee (MC) conducted complementary studies on the implications of issuing a central
bank digital currency (CBDC).
This consolidated report is an early contribution to this topic, providing a conceptual analysis of the
potential effect of CBDC in three core central banking areas: payments, monetary policy implementation
and financial stability. The committees’ work in this area builds on previous work they conducted on the
role of central bank money, digital currencies, fast payments, access to central bank services and monetary
policy implementation.1 It is complemented by an exploration of possible effects on the structure of the
financial system and for financial stability.
CBDC raises questions about the role of central bank money, direct access to central bank liabilities
and the structure of financial intermediation. Traditionally, central banks have, for various reasons, tended
to limit access to (digital) account-based central bank money to banks and, in some instances, to certain
other financial or public institutions.2 By contrast, physical central bank money (ie cash) is widely accessible.
In some jurisdictions, however, the use of cash is decreasing, with the possibility of its complete
disappearance, implying that the public would no longer have wide access to central bank money. Since
the traditional approach has, in general, served the public and the financial system well, the bar for
changing the current monetary and financial structure is high.
The report is organised as follows. Section 2 introduces a taxonomy of CBDC, provides an overview
of key design features and describes two variants: a wholesale and a general purpose variant. The two are
used as reference cases to analyse the payment system implications in Section 3, as well as the impact on
monetary policy implementation and transmission in Section 4. Section 5 discusses the broader
implications for the financial system, financial stability risks and cross-border issues.
2.
Taxonomy
CBDC is not a well-defined term. It is used to refer to a number of concepts. However, it is envisioned by
most to be a new form of central bank money. That is, a central bank liability, denominated in an existing
unit of account, which serves both as a medium of exchange and a store of value. This would be an
innovation for general purpose users but not for wholesale entities. Central banks already provide digital
money in the form of reserves or settlement account balances held by commercial banks and certain other
financial institutions at the central bank. This mix of new and already existing forms of central bank money
makes it challenging to precisely define what a CBDC is. In fact, for purposes of analysing what may change,
1
See also CPSS (2003), CPMI (2012), CPMI (2014), CPMI (2015) and CPMI (2016a, 2016b).
2
In the early days of central banking, it was fairly common to offer accounts not just to banks but also to non-banks (see eg
Reichsbank (1926) and Bank of England (1963)). However, starting in the 20th century, central banks have tended to
progressively restrict access by non-banks. In recent years, access has been granted to some critical financial market
infrastructures (FMIs), such as central counterparties (CCPs), mainly for financial stability purposes. Moreover, some central
banks have provided access to liquidity-absorbing instruments, such as central bank bills and reverse repos, to a broader set
of counterparties than banks.
Central bank digital currencies
3
it is easier to define a CBDC by highlighting what it is not: a CBDC is a digital form of central bank money
that is different from balances in traditional reserve or settlement accounts.3
2.1
The money flower
To get greater clarity, it is useful to put CBDC in the context of other types of money. Graph 1 presents a
taxonomy of money in the form of a Venn-diagram referred to as the money flower (Bech and Garratt
(2017)). The version here focuses on the combinations of four key properties: issuer (central bank or other);
form (digital or physical); accessibility (widely or restricted); and technology (token- or account-based).4
Money is typically based on one of two basic technologies: tokens of stored value or accounts (Green (2008)
and Mersch (2017a)). Cash and many digital currencies are token-based, whereas balances in reserve
accounts and most forms of commercial bank money are account-based.
A key distinction between token- and account-based money is the form of verification needed when
it is exchanged (Kahn and Roberds (2009)). Token-based money (or payment systems) rely critically on the
ability of the payee to verify the validity of the payment object. With cash the worry is counterfeiting, while
in the digital world the worry is whether the token or “coin” is genuine or not (electronic counterfeiting)
and whether it has already been spent.5 By contrast, systems based on account money depend
fundamentally on the ability to verify the identity of the account holder. A key concern is identity theft,
which allows perpetrators to transfer or withdraw money from accounts without permission.6 Identification
is needed to correctly link payers and payees and to ascertain their respective account histories.
Digital central bank money is at the centre of the money flower. The taxonomy distinguishes between
three forms of CBDCs (the dark grey shaded area). Two forms are token-based and the other is accountbased. The two token-based versions differ first and foremost by who has access, which, in turn, depends
on the potential use of the CBDC. One is a widely available payment instrument that is primarily targeted
at retail transactions but also available for much broader use.7 The other is a restricted-access digital
settlement token for wholesale payment and settlement transactions. Below they are referred to as (central
bank) general purpose token and (central bank) wholesale token.
The account-based version envisages the central bank providing general purpose accounts to all
agents in the jurisdiction. While the scale would be of a different magnitude, the technology to do so is
arguably currently available. The novelty would be the decision to implement such accounts.
3
Reserves and settlement accounts are available in most jurisdictions to “monetary policy counterparties”, ie financial institutions
that are directly relevant for monetary policy implementation, such as deposit-taking entities, which are generally already
granted access to central bank deposit and lending facilities. In some jurisdictions, account holders may comprise a broader
group and include non-monetary counterparties (eg treasury, foreign central banks or certain financial markets infrastructures
(FMIs)). Some central banks are considering widening access. CBDC would further expand access to digital central bank money
but not to central bank lending facilities.
4
Accessibility distinguishes between money that is available everywhere to everyone and money that is restricted to certain
agents or jurisdictions.
5
Double-spending is a potential problem for digital tokens. There is a risk that a payer could try to use the “same” token on two
different transactions.
6
The incident that occurred in February 2016 at the central bank of Bangladesh is an example of false verification based on
compromised credentials. CPMI (2017b) presents a strategy to counter fraud in wholesale payment systems. In general,
safeguarding against unauthorised access or tampering of account histories is of utmost importance. If someone maliciously
breaks into the trusted intermediary hosting all the account balances, they can in principle tamper or modify any account
balances at will. CPMI and IOSCO (2016) provides guidance on cyber-resilience for financial market infrastructures.
7
It is common to divide payments into retail and wholesale segments. Retail payments are relatively low-value transactions, in
the form of, for example, cheques, credit transfers, direct debits and card payments. By contrast, wholesale payments are largevalue and high-priority transactions, such as interbank transfers. The distinction might become less relevant in a world with
CBDCs. In fact, depending on its design, a widely available CBDC could also be used for wholesale transactions.
4
Central bank digital currencies
The money flower: a taxonomy of money
Graph 1
Notes: The Venn-diagram illustrates the four key properties of money: issuer (central bank or not); form (digital or physical); accessibility
(widely or restricted) and technology (account-based or token-based). CB = central bank, CBDC = central bank digital currency (excluding
digital central bank money already available to monetary counterparties and some non-monetary counterparties). Private digital tokens
(general purpose) include crypto-assets and currencies, such as bitcoin and ethereum. Bank deposits are not widely accessible in all
jurisdictions. For examples of how other forms of money may fit in the diagram, please refer to the source.
Source: Based on Bech and Garratt (2017).
2.2
Design features
In addition to the four core properties highlighted above, there are other design features that will
determine how a CBDC may serve as a means of payment and a store of value. These choices will have
implications for payments, monetary policy and financial stability. The most important CBDC design
options identified to date are listed below. Table 1 provides a comparison of properties across existing
and potential new forms of central bank money.
Availability. Currently, access to digital central bank money is limited to central bank operating hours,
traditionally less than 24 hours a day and usually five days a week.8 CBDCs could be available 24 hours a
day and seven days a week or only during certain specified times (such as the operating hours of largevalue payment systems). CBDC could be available permanently or for a limited duration (eg it could be
created, issued and redeemed on an intraday basis).
8
The introduction of faster or instant payment systems in an increasing number of jurisdictions has led a number of central
banks to reconsider the time during which access to digital central bank money is available, with some moving toward
availability 24 hours a day seven days a week for central bank money settlement of fast retail payments (see CPMI (2016b) and
Bech et al (2017)).
Central bank digital currencies
5
Key design features of central bank money
Table 1
Existing central bank
money
Central bank digital currencies
Cash
Reserves and
settlement
balances
24/7 availability
()
()
Anonymity vis-à-vis central bank
()
()
Peer-to-peer transfer
()
()
Interest-bearing
()
()
()
()
Limits or caps
()
()
()
General purpose
token
accounts
Wholesale
only token
= existing or likely feature, () = possible feature, = not typical or possible feature.
Anonymity. Token-based CBDC can, in principle, be designed to provide different degrees of
anonymity in a way that is similar to private digital tokens. 9 A key decision for society is the degree of
anonymity vis-à-vis the central bank, balancing, among other things, concerns relating to money
laundering, financing of terrorism and privacy.
Transfer mechanism.10 The transfer of cash is conducted on a peer-to-peer basis, while central bank
deposits are transferred through the central bank, which acts as an intermediary. CBDC may be transferred
either on a peer-to-peer basis or through an intermediary, which could be the central bank, a commercial
bank or a third-party agent.
Interest-bearing. As with other forms of digital central bank liabilities, it is technically feasible to pay
interest (positive or negative) on both token- and account-based CBDCs. The interest rate on CBDC can
be set equal to an existing policy rate or be set at a different level to either encourage or discourage
demand for CBDC.11 Both non-interest bearing and interest bearing accounts could be used for retail or
wholesale payment transactions. The payment of (positive) interest would likely enhance the attractiveness
of an instrument that also serves as a store of value.
Limits or caps. Different forms of quantitative limits or caps on the use or holdings of CBDC are often
mentioned as a way of controlling potentially undesirable implications or to steer usage in a certain
direction. For example, limits or caps could make a CBDC less useful for wholesale rather than retail
payments. At present, such limits or caps on holdings/use are most easily envisioned in non-anonymous
account-based systems.12
9
For example, bitcoin allows transactions to be (pseudo) anonymous. While all bitcoin transactions are publicly recorded using
the payer’s and the payee’s public addresses, very much like e-mail addresses, these addresses do not necessarily reveal the
true identity of users. A person sending bitcoin to a public address thus need not reveal his/her true identity to the recipient
(counterparty anonymity) or to other users (one form of third-party anonymity). Recent innovations may allow even more
anonymity than in the original bitcoin design.
10
Bech and Garratt (2017) focus on the transfer mechanism (centralised or decentralised) rather than on the token- or accountbased technology. Money is either exchanged in a decentralised manner known as peer-to-peer (ie transactions occur directly
between the payer and the payee without the need for a central intermediary) or in a centralised manner relying on the services
of one or more third parties. Tokens are often transferred peer-to-peer.
11
Moreover, rates could be differentiated. For example, if accounts were linked to individual persons or entities, the CBDC rate
could vary by counterparty, amount held in the account or some other characteristic, in a way that is similar to the current
central bank practice of extensive use of differentiated interest rates on deposits held by non-monetary counterparties.
12
The proper functioning of the payment system, however, implies one-to-one convertibility of CBDC with respect to reserves
and banknotes (Fung and Halaburda (2016)). Not facilitating one-to-one convertibility would lead to an exchange rate between
different types of central bank money, breaking the unity of the currency. However, some have proposed allowing this unity to
break under certain circumstances. For example, Agarwal and Kimball (2015) propose abandoning one-to-one convertibility as
a way of allowing a floating exchange rate between cash and commercial bank deposits and thus eliminating the effective
lower bound. Abandoning convertibility between CBDC and reserves would similarly lead to a floating exchange rate between
CBDC and commercial bank deposits.
6
Central bank digital currencies
The different combinations of features mean that there are many potential CBDC variants. The two
variants analysed below – one with restricted access for wholesale payments and one with wide access for
general purposes (either token- or account-based) – are presented for conceptual clarity purposes only;
they are by no means exhaustive.
3.
Payment aspects
The introduction of a general purpose or a wholesale only CBDC could bring a number of potential benefits
to payment, clearing and settlement systems, but it could also pose several risks and challenges. In
deciding the case for CBDCs, central banks should compare them with existing or enhanced payment,
clearing and settlement solutions. And they would need to consider the impacts on other parts of their
remit – most importantly monetary policy and financial stability (analysed in the next two sections).
3.1
General purpose CBDC
One rationale for introducing CBDC in a jurisdiction could be to provide a safe, central bank instrument,
especially should the use of cash decline significantly. Over the past decades, technological developments
have significantly improved the convenience and efficiency of digital forms of private sector payment
instruments compared with central bank paper money (ie banknotes). In Sweden, these developments
have led to an absolute decline in the amount of cash in circulation. The Riksbank is investigating whether
an e-krona would provide the general public with continued access to central bank money and increase
the resilience of the payment system (Skingsley (2016) and Sveriges Riksbank (2017)).13
While specifics will vary according to a country’s circumstances and economic conditions, these
payment-related motivations for issuing CBDC appear at this time not to be compelling for most
jurisdictions. The growing use of electronic means of payment has generally not yet resulted in a
substantial reduction in the demand for cash (Graph 2).14 The rationale for considering a central bank
replacement for, or supplement to, cash thus may appear less compelling (CPMI (2017a)). The efficiency
gains for retail payment purposes may also be less material. In many countries, current retail payment
solutions are convenient, efficient and reliable, and have earned public trust and confidence over time.
Going forward, technology will likely offer even more opportunities to enhance convenience, increase
safety, lower overall costs and further improve resilience. A number of jurisdictions have already adopted
or are in the process of addressing public demand for faster and more convenient approaches to payments
that are also compatible with new digital and mobile technologies. Some are already providing real-time
or near real-time settlement and close to 24/7 availability. One exception is perhaps cross-border retail
payments, which are generally slower, less transparent and more expensive than domestic retail payments
(CPMI (2018)).
Some argue that CBDC could also reinforce the resilience of a country’s retail payment systems. They
argue that should payments in private sector infrastructures be disrupted due, say, to technical problems
or because a bank providing credit transfers was under stress, households and businesses could still make
digital payments via CBDC, something especially important if cash had (largely) disappeared. On a related
note, CBDC could reduce the concentration of liquidity and credit risk in payment systems (Dyson and
Hodgson (2016)). However, one could, of course, also achieve operational resilience through the diversity
afforded by multiple payment systems, although this could be difficult to achieve given the network effects
and economies of scale present in payment systems. In addition, continued availability and use of physical
currency could help ensure even greater resilience by providing an instrument that is more immune to
disruptions to electric power and telecommunication networks resulting from natural or man-made
13
Cash use has declined to the point where a growing number of merchants no longer accept cash and most bank branches have
eliminated cash processing (Skingsley (2016)).
14
Unfortunately, internationally comparable data are not available on the actual use of cash, only for cash in circulation.
Central bank digital currencies
7
disasters. Having said that, in those jurisdictions where the general public is abandoning cash, this is not
an alternative.
Card payments and cash demand, change 2007–161
As a percentage of GDP
1
Graph 2
The start of an arrow represents 2007 data while the end represent 2016
Source: Bech et al (2018).
In this context, one could also consider the implications of not issuing CBDC. One is the potential for
private digital tokens to more widely displace central bank money in transactions. Retail customers could
face more credit and liquidity risks, relative to central bank liabilities, from exposure to either private issuers
of digital tokens or from a lack of issuer. At this time, their volatile valuations and inadequate investor and
consumer protection make private digital tokens unsafe to rely on as a common means of payment and a
stable store of value or unit of account. Overall, while carefully monitoring the development and potential
uses of new technologies, central banks are likely to continue to emphasise the need for improving the
efficiency and speed of private systems.
3.2
Wholesale-only CBDC
In terms of wholesale markets, the main argument made is that settlement systems for financial
transactions could be made more efficient – in terms of operational costs and use of collateral and liquidity
– and more secure by using wholesale CBDC. Introducing a wholesale CBDC that is comparable to
traditional central bank reserves into interbank payment systems could potentially improve efficiency and
risk management in settlement (see CPMI (2017a)). If complemented by direct participation of non-banks
in the settlement process, gains could further increase, including through facilitating the use of new
technologies for asset transfers, authentication, record-keeping, data management and risk management.
Payments and (cash legs of) securities transactions settled in CBDC, instead of through facilities hosted by
commercial banks or other service providers, could help reduce counterparty credit and liquidity risks in
the financial system. It could also help central banks monitor financial activity.
To meet evolving needs from financial markets and to ensure an overall stable and sound financial
system, a number of central banks have been conducting experiments involving CBDC and its related
underlying technology (in particular DLT). Early experimentation, however, has not shown significant
benefits for wholesale payments. The design of an infrastructure using such new technology would look
similar to the one currently in place in terms of legal, operational and security requirements. Doubts remain
regarding the maturity of the technology and the size of efficiency gains associated with the use of DLT.
Moreover, changes could imply expanded – direct or indirect – access to a central bank account with new
counterparties, which could be difficult to control. That said, technologies and related possible designs are
evolving quickly and central banks will need to continually assess whether introducing CBDC (potentially
incrementally) in this area could be useful.
8
Central bank digital currencies
3.3
Other considerations
In addition to more efficient and safer payments and settlement systems, CBDC could come with additional
benefits. Given that a CBDC can allow for digital records and traces, it could improve the application of
rules aimed at anti-money laundering and countering the financing of terrorism (AML/CFT), and possibly
help reduce informal economic activities. These gains may, however, be small in that the formal payment
system, especially if there were to be a traceable CBDC, would not necessarily be the main conduit for illicit
transactions and informal economic activities.
There are also costs. Commercial banks could lose a valuable interface with their consumers given
that in some CBDC designs the “know-your-customer” function could fall to the central bank. Central
banks would have to take on a much larger role in this field, with associated costs. Central banks could
also be called upon to provide information to tax and other authorities (eg for judicial matters). Moreover,
they would have to manage privacy and anonymity issues stemming from the insights obtained from
private transactions. More generally, central banks might have to deal with many requests and customers,
including some now excluded, for which they are not necessarily well equipped (although some of these
challenges may be mitigated or avoided by careful design).
Another argument is that a CBDC could improve financial inclusion. In some countries, a sizable
portion of the population does not participate in the formal financial system and could thus miss out on
associated benefits. A CBDC, however, does not necessarily alleviate all the constraints to access; for some
segments of the population, barriers to the use of any digital currency may be large, and the preference
for trusted alternatives, such as cash, is strong. In addition, a CBDC may allow for better real-time data on
economic activity but such gains are already largely achievable with existing payments data. A more
persuasive argument is that a CBDC may help to maintain a direct link between central banks and citizens
(especially where cash use is diminishing), which could help foster the public’s understanding of central
banks’ roles and need for independence (Mersch (2017b)).
3.4
Key feasibility and operational challenges
Even if CBDCs were deemed desirable, initial exploration and experimentation have identified a number
of legal, technical and operational issues that central banks and other relevant parties must consider before
an instrument can be deemed suitable for wide-scale use.
In some countries, there are legal considerations. Not all central banks have the authority to issue
digital currencies and expand account access, and issuance may require legislative changes, which might
not be feasible, at least in the short term. Other questions include whether a CBDC is “legal tender” (ie a
legally recognised payment instrument to fulfil financial obligations) and whether existing laws pertaining
to transfers of value and finality are applicable.15
Central banks would also have to take account of AML/CFT concerns and requirements if they were
to issue CBDC. Issuing a CBDC that does not adequately comply with these and other supervisory and tax
regimes would not be advisable. To date, it is not clear how AML/CFT requirements can be implemented
practically for anonymous forms of CBDC. Forms of CBDC that can be easily transferred across borders or
used offshore are especially likely to present significant challenges in this respect. As such, the reputational
risk to the central bank from a general purpose CBDC must be considered.
The use of central bank and commercial bank deposits typically provides some level of privacy (for
individual banks and agents, respectively), while the use of cash provides anonymity to all users. The
appropriate degree of privacy, as also judged by society, is a challenge in a digital environment. For CBDC,
15
Existing laws are typically written broadly for direct physical transfer or for a central entity (“banks”) to accept instructions and
modify a ledger. In a CBDC based on DLT, multiple entities could modify a set of distributed ledgers. Other legal issues, such
as the timing of the discharge of obligations and liability for errors and unauthorised payments, may also be relevant.
Central bank digital currencies
9
the appropriate degree of privacy of the currency would need to be considered carefully, which could
entail difficult public policy design choices for a central bank.
Cyber-security is currently one of the most important operational challenges for central bank systems
and the financial industry more generally. Cyber-threats, such as malware, and fraud are risks for nearly
every payment, clearing and settlement system. They pose, however, a particular challenge for a general
purpose CBDC, which is open to many participants and points of attack. Moreover, the potential effect of
fraud could be more significant because of the ease with which large amounts could be transferred
electronically. Robust mitigation methods of cyber-risk would therefore be a prerequisite for CBDC
issuance.
More generally, the robustness of possible new technologies in ensuring a sound risk management
framework is uncertain. Because central bank services are essential to the smooth functioning of an
economy, very robust requirements for reliability, scalability, throughput and resilience are necessities.
Central banks therefore typically have very rigorous operational requirements for their systems and
services. Some of the proposed technologies for issuing and managing CBDC (such as DLT) are still
relatively untested, and even the private sector is in the early phase of developing and applying DLT for
commercial use.16 Many questions surrounding operational risk management and governance need to be
answered before deployment can be envisioned. This may especially be the case for countries at earlier
stages of financial infrastructure development.
4.
Monetary policy aspects
The consequences of CBDC issuance for the implementation and transmission of monetary policy are
directly related to how wide access to CBDC is and whether it is attractively remunerated. Monetary policy
arguments for issuing CBDC include potential strengthening of the pass-through of the policy rate to
money markets and deposit rates, and helping to alleviate the zero (or effective) lower bound constraint.
These arguments should be considered carefully. It is not clear that the pass-through of the policy rate
needs strengthening and introducing a CBDC may also bring new risks to monetary policy. In addition,
existing tools can, in many cases, achieve the same objectives. Since digital central bank money is already
available to monetary counterparties and some non-monetary counterparties, as discussed in other
sections, this section refers only to the monetary policy aspects introduced by wider access to CBDC.17
4.1
Desirability for monetary policy
Wider digital access to the central bank may strengthen the pass-through of the policy rate to money and
lending markets. Monetary policy implications are likely more pronounced if CBDC emerges as an
attractive asset to hold. The crucial design features that determine the extent to which CBDC may function
as such include the rules regulating its access by different types of agent, its availability beyond intraday
use and whether it is interest-bearing, and at what rate (Box A). Only if it combines these choices, would
it be a new and liquid central bank liability likely to have an impact on the channels of transmission of
policy rates to the money market and beyond.
16
Any CBDC need not necessarily be implemented using some form of DLT; theoretically more traditional centralised technologies
may suffice. The pros and cons of using DLT in general, eg as regard to scalability, confidentiality and resilience, is an area of
ongoing research that is outside the scope of this report.
17
Besides the fact that digital central bank money is already provided to monetary counterparties, and merely changing the
technology behind the provision of funds is thus of limited significance, there are three reasons for this delineation. First, while
central banks may need to adjust the quantity of money provided to monetary counterparties to control short-term interest
rates, the demand for central bank money held by non-monetary counterparties (eg treasury, foreign central banks or certain
FMIs) is more typically just accommodated. Second, there may be good reasons for central banks to provide digital central
bank money on different terms (remuneration, settlement hours, individual quantitative limits and anonymity) to (various)
monetary and non-monetary counterparties. Third, while monetary counterparties have some access to intraday and overnight
credit (ie reserve balances may turn negative), non-monetary counterparties typically do not. Similarly, CBDC balances may not
turn negative.
10
Central bank digital currencies
Box A
Features of CBDC, demand and the degree of substitution with other financial assets
The way in which access to CBDC is granted implies that substitution effects will affect different types of financial asset.
CBDC accessible to individuals and designed as a non-interest bearing, retail payment instrument might primarily
substitute for cash (eg token-based CBDC) and commercial bank deposits (eg account-based CBDC). CBDC that pays
interest and is readily transferable would likely be attractive to professional financial market participants (eg cash pools
and asset managers). It may substitute for money market instruments, such as government bills, reverse repos, central
bank bills and FX swaps, and be a liquid and credit risk-free asset facilitating final settlement. CBDC accessible to nonresidents may substitute for internationally-used banknotes, bank deposits and international reserve assets.
Substitution may theoretically be limited by imposing individual quantitative limits in normal times, eg access could
be conditional upon a commercial bank account to which payments are redirected in case this upper limit is surpassed,
to try to curb demand.
Substitution effects will be importantly influenced by whether a CBDC is non-remunerated (as is cash), whether
it pays interest at an unchangeable or adjustable rate and whether that rate might possibly move with the policy rate,
and, if so, at a spread that is constant or varying. Moreover, rates could be differentiated. A substantially lower interest
rate on CBDC holdings exceeding, say, the amount covered by deposit insurance schemes would reduce their
attractiveness in normal times.
These and other design features will influence the demand for CBDC. If designed with limited attractiveness, the
substitution effects in normal times may be moderate, and so will be the effects on monetary policy transmission (as
well as any structural effects on the financial system). Of course, in times of stress, central banks are unlikely to want
to directly control the quantity of CBDC because they would want to maintain one-to-one convertibility with respect
to reserves and banknotes.
Even if purposefully designed to be primarily a payment vehicle, CBDC may still end up functioning like a store
of value in unforeseen ways under certain circumstances. In times of financial stress, domestic (retail) investors are
likely to consider CBDC attractive relative to bank deposits, with many possible side effects, including for financial
stability (see section 5). And, if granted access, residents in high-inflation countries may turn to CBDC issued by a lowinflation country (as they do nowadays with cash).
An application of overall quantitative limits to CBDC may potentially disrupt payment systems, giving rise to an exchange rate between
different types of central bank money. Such issues may not occur in the case of individual quantitative limits. However, the aggregate of
individual limits could in theory produce a binding overall limit in certain situations. The one-to-one convertibility between CBDC,
banknotes and reserves means that the central bank can only control their joint quantity. While the central bank can, in principle, steer the
overall quantity of central bank money outstanding through liquidity-injecting and liquidity-absorbing open market operations, the holders
of central bank money jointly determine its composition, as they are free to convert one type of liability into another. Commercial banks face
a similar issue in not being able to directly control the quantity of their retail deposits. This illustrates that means of payment cannot be
directly quantitatively controlled but are rather indirectly influenced by their design features and adjustments in other items. Central banks
already face this issue in the provision of banknotes, reserves and deposits for a relatively small number of non-monetary counterparties (see
Annex A). Traditionally, central banks passively and elastically accommodate the demand for banknotes and deposits held by non-monetary
counterparties to steer the quantity of reserves. This is a necessary condition for implementing monetary policy and it would apply with equal
force to CBDC.
In particular, a CBDC attractively remunerated compared with other interest rates could affect
holdings by institutional investors of other liquid, low-risk instruments (such as short-term government
bills and repos backed by sovereign collateral).18 If institutional investors could hold such an instrument
without limits, the interest rate on it would help establish a hard floor under money market rates, which is
arguably useful.19
An interest-bearing general purpose variant could also make pass-through more direct. If households
considered a CBDC to be an alternative to commercial bank deposits, banks would have less scope for
independently setting the interest rate on retail deposits. For example, banks would find it harder not to
18
Note also that this refers to the general collateral (cash-driven) segment of repo markets, not to the “specials” (collateraldriven) segment.
19
Duffie and Krishnamurthy (2016), who do not explicitly mention CBDC as a possible instrument, argue that the dispersion of
rates that is related to imperfect pass-through signals a social cost.
Central bank digital currencies
11
increase deposit rates in tandem when the central bank was raising the CBDC rate. As such, a change in
the policy rate could be more directly transmitted to bank depositors (possibly with an intermediation
margin, given costs and credit risks). To the extent that an attractively remunerated CBDC reduced currency
substitution, which is a possibility in some countries, pass-through more generally could be enhanced,
including with respect to domestic prices.
In principle, negative rates on central bank liabilities could provide the monetary stimulus needed in
extreme circumstances. Proponents have suggested that issuance of CBDC could serve to alleviate the
zero lower bound if it came along with a reduced desire for cash holdings (eg Goodfriend (2016) and
Dyson and Hodgson (2016)). Relatedly, some argue that having a substitute for cash in the form of
(interest-bearing) CBDC makes the discontinuation of higher denomination banknotes easier to achieve
(Rogoff (2016) and Bordo and Levin (2017)). 20
There are, however, important caveats and counter-arguments. The degree to which key market rates
move in conjunction with the policy rate appears satisfactory for most central banks. Whether the passthrough to money markets, for example, is impeded in material ways is not clear (Potter (2017)). Moreover,
it is not clear whether one should expect bank deposit rates to respond immediately to policy rate changes.
The spreads between the policy rate and retail rates represent compensations for various risks and
transaction costs, including for services that are implicitly cross-subsidised (commercial banks provide a
broader range of services to retail investors than any CBDC would). More generally, retail depositors tend
to be less price-sensitive than wholesale investors. And, the stickiness of retail deposits allows commercial
banks to perform more easily their maturity, credit risk and liquidity transformation roles in the economy.
In practice, the lack of a one-to-one response to policy rate hikes and cuts does not represent a
challenge as long as central banks have appropriate control over financial conditions. Banks take into
consideration a wider range of factors than simply the policy rate in the pricing of their retail deposits,
including longer-term rates that encompass credit and liquidity risk premia (ie they look at the relevant
investment opportunities). That said, the presence of an attractive CBDC would put pressure on
commercial banks to raise their retail deposit rates to avoid losing retail funding. At the same time, some
doubt that additional tools would strengthen the central bank’s ability to achieve its objectives (eg Bindseil
(2016)). Moreover, even if pass-through warrants strengthening, there are other conventional tools, such
as central bank bills, time deposits and standing reverse repo facilities (Box B) that can accomplish the
same objective.
Box B
Central bank bills, time deposits and standing repo facilities as alternatives to CBDC
Strengthening the pass-through of the policy rate to money market rates also could be achieved by the central bank
supplying liquidity-absorbing instruments to non-bank money market participants. The latter includes reverse repo
facilities, time deposits and central bank bills. Central banks have significant expertise and experience in the use of
such tools. Considering the pros and cons of these alternatives, there are two key differences between offering
liquidity-absorbing instruments and CBDC to money market participants:
CBDC can be used as intraday liquidity by its holders, whereas liquidity-absorbing instruments cannot achieve
the same, or can do so only imperfectly. At the moment, there is no other short-term money market instrument
featuring the liquidity and creditworthiness of CBDC. The central bank would thus use its comparative advantage
as a liquidity provider when issuing CBDC.
Although the quantity of CBDC can be influenced by its design features, it cannot be fully controlled. By contrast,
liquidity-absorbing instruments can be auctioned off in fixed quantities.
While a CBDC could carry a negative rate, this may not address effectively the zero lower bound if
higher denomination banknotes were not simultaneously abolished (eg Pfister (2017)). More generally,
considering political economy consequences, it is uncertain how deeply negative rates may work in
20
12
Also, some have argued that CBDC could enhance the effectiveness of quantitative easing, given that monetary counterparties
would no longer have to intermediate when the central bank conducted asset purchases (eg bonds would be swapped for riskfree CBDC) instead of dealing in credit-risky commercial bank deposits, possibly strengthening any portfolio rebalancing effects.
Central bank digital currencies
practice, (McAndrews (2017)). Finally, weaker demand for cash does not imply the need for a CBDC. In fact,
monetary policy can still remain effective even without cash (Woodford (2000)). On balance, it is not clear
that there is a strong basis at this time to issue a CBDC for the purpose of enhancing the efficacy of
monetary policy transmission.
4.2
Implications for monetary policy implementation and interest rates
The presence of CBDC would have a limited impact on monetary policy implementation – that is, how
central banks use their balance sheets to control short-term interest rates (for a review see Annex A). While
a central bank would need to accommodate demand for CBDC, flows into CBDC would drain the amount
of reserves in the system in exactly the same way as flows into banknotes and central bank deposits held
by non-monetary counterparties (eg the treasury, foreign central banks or financial market infrastructures
(FMIs)) currently do. In a corridor system, all flows in and out of CBDC need to be compensated through
liquidity-injecting and liquidity-absorbing open market operations (OMOs) to keep the desired amount of
reserves.21 In a floor system, only when CBDC inflows drained reserves to the point where they became
scarce would the central bank need to undertake additional liquidity-injecting OMOs.
Therefore CBDC does not alter the basic “mechanics” of monetary policy implementation (see further
Annex B for a flow-of-funds representation). Demand for CBDC would just be another factor to consider
for policy responses to be consistent with continued control over short-term interest rates. There are two
practical implications, though. First, depending on the degree of substitution, a larger balance sheet may
be needed to implement monetary policy, as agents substitute physical cash, commercial bank deposits
and other safe assets for CBDC. Second, the overall volatility of autonomous factors could be affected,
which, in turn, may affect their predictability.22
While likely requiring larger balance sheets, central banks would still have discretion in choosing the
assets they hold to accommodate the demand for CBDC, just as they have for banknotes. Theoretically,
assets can be made up of outright holdings of any kind or collateralised lending to monetary
counterparties on any terms and conditions. 23 Subject to the overall supply of various types of asset and
changes thereof, the additional duration, liquidity and credit risk stemming from accommodating the
demand for CBDC is thus determined by the central bank itself, as is the case with banknotes.
Demand for CBDC may be volatile on a daily basis, as inflows and outflows result from payments
between CBDC and non-CBDC holders. Whether this leads to higher overall volatility depends on the
correlations with other factors.24 If volatility proves particularly high, central banks can be forced to operate
through a floor system. Whether the quality of liquidity forecasting is hampered depends on the
predictability of daily flows in and out of CBDC.
The overall effects of CBDC on the (term) structure of interest rates are very hard to predict and will
depend on many factors. To attract demand, short-term government paper and overnight repos with
treasury collateral might have to provide some yield pickup with respect to a wholesale-oriented
21
Under a corridor system, the (marginal) CBDC remuneration rate should not exceed the policy rate. Otherwise, monetary
counterparties would have an incentive to trade their excess overnight funds with CBDC holders instead of trading them among
themselves. Monetary counterparties with temporary liquidity deficits would need to bid up overnight rates, causing shortterm interest rates to exceed the policy rate. Under a floor system, the marginal CBDC rate should not exceed the rate of
remuneration of reserves placed at the central bank’s deposit facility.
22
CBDCs are considered an autonomous factor for monetary policy implementation for two reasons. First, from the viewpoint of
the day-to-day steering of the central bank’s balance sheet to control short-term interest rates, daily fluctuations in the demand
for CBDC are an exogenous factor, even though CBDC would be an endogenous factor within the broader monetary policy
framework. Second, even if CBDC was introduced, the amount of digital central bank money held by monetary counterparties
(reserves) would still be crucial for control over short-term interest rates.
23
As central bank credit to monetary counterparties is collateralised, a widening of collateral eligibility may be necessary to
accommodate banks’ increased recourse to credit facilities to compensate for the loss of funding due to CBDC inflows (Annex
B).
24
In the case of a corridor system, this may necessitate more frequent liquidity-injecting and liquidity-absorbing OMOs, higher
reserve requirements with averaging provisions or wider tolerance bands around reserve targets to steer liquidity conditions.
Central bank digital currencies
13
remunerated CBDC. This means that the short end of the sovereign yield curve may end up above the
CBDC rate. Contrary to the hard floor that the wholesale CBDC variant may put under money market rates,
the general purpose variant is likely to put only a soft floor under retail deposit rates given the lower price
sensitivity of retail depositors and switching costs.
At the same time, depending on the specific assets held to accommodate the issued CBDC, central
banks would probably need to engage in various kinds of maturity, liquidity and credit risk transformation.
How these two forces balance out in terms of various interest rates across assets classes and maturities is
difficult to predict. More generally, the implications of a CBDC relative to other instruments are likely to
depend on each jurisdiction’s specific operating environment. Also, since operating environments may
change in the future, monetary policy cost-benefit analyses related to CBDC may need to be revisited
periodically.
5.
Financial intermediation, financial stability and cross-border aspects
Whether or not to introduce a CBDC depends on an assessment of many fundamental issues that go
beyond the impact on the payment system and monetary policy transmission and implementation. In this
section, topics warranting further investigation are explored.
5.1
Role of the central bank
A fundamental matter raised by CBDC issuance relates to the appropriate roles – in financial intermediation
and the economy at large – of private financial market participants, governments and central banks. With
CBDCs, there could be a larger role for central banks in financial intermediation. As the demand for CBDC
grows, and if holdings of cash do not decline in lockstep, central banks might need to acquire (or accept
as collateral) additional sovereign claims and, depending on size, private assets (eg securitised mortgages,
exchange-traded funds and others). If demand becomes very large, central banks may need to hold less
liquid and riskier securities, thereby influencing the prices of such securities and potentially affecting
market functioning. Central banks may also need to provide substantial maturity, liquidity and credit risk
transformation at times to both banks and markets. Since central banks could assume more important
roles, they could have a larger impact on lending and financial conditions.
Given that all this could challenge the two-tier banking system, structural implications need to be
understood better before CBDC issuance can take place. A greater role for central banks in credit allocation
entails overall economic losses if central banks are less efficient than the private sector at resource
allocation (eg as it impedes the efficient use of decentralised knowledge in society (Hayek (1945)). It is
doubtful, for example, that, from the perspective of an efficient allocation of credit, a centralised approach
involving outright holdings of corporate securities would be preferred to a decentralised approach based
on banks and other private actors granting loans to corporations and investing in securities. From an
infrastructure perspective, central banks would have to decide on the design of the appropriate
technology, create the required infrastructure and governance and manage this new form of money. This
could lead to large operational demands and associated (upfront) costs, with the possible creation of new
risks.
There could also be changes to market liquidity and interlinkages. If the demand for CBDC exceeded
the decline in the demand for cash and/or reserves, larger outright holdings of CBDC could hamper market
functioning if they reduced the free-floating share of outstanding bonds. While a CBDC would by itself be
very liquid, it could result in reduced liquidity and increased “specialness” in collateral (repo) markets. The
depth of repo and short-term government bill markets could decline as demand was redirected to
wholesale market use of CBDC. While the central bank could step in on the demand side of these markets,
it would need to broaden its holdings to match its increasing liabilities. This expanded role of central banks
in wholesale markets could also reduce interbank activity and the price discovery role of these markets.
14
Central bank digital currencies
Coordination issues between the central bank and the government debt management office might
occur and central banks’ operations could become more challenging (Greenwood et al (2014)). By having
to passively accommodate the demand for CBDC, the central bank could potentially introduce volatile
demand for government debt. Related questions include which part of the public sector is best suited to
issue a country’s short-term public debt and determine the maturity profile of the consolidated public
debt. If CBDC replaced a large portion of bank deposits, central bank demand for government securities
could be large, which might then affect sovereign debt markets. More broadly, a larger balance sheet
could present challenges as it reduced the role of the market in price setting. Such a reduction could lead
to allocative distortions and tie up higher-quality assets. This could, in turn, adversely affect the functioning
of collateral markets. All of this would have implications for financial stability.
Depending on design, central banks’ seigniorage income could also be affected (see Annex C).
Relatedly, if CBDC was interest bearing, the central bank would be directly exposed to stakeholders that
might at times exert pressures to raise interest rates. Applying differentiated rates (eg by amount held or
counterparty) could also be necessary for effective monetary policy implementation but this might prove
to be technically difficult (eg on token-based CBDC). It could also lead to arbitrage as well as being
controversial (eg a CBDC rate for households below the rate of remuneration on excess reserve balances).
5.2
Banks business models, financial intermediation and markets
The issuance of CBDC would have implications for the structure of payment markets. To the extent that a
CBDC would further open up payments to non-banks, commercial banks would stand to see their
payment-related income streams eroded by increased competition. Private sector FMIs, such as securities
settlement systems and possibly central counterparties for securities trades, might be affected by the
issuance of wholesale CBDC.25 While such developments may be far off – because of the many legal,
technical and market coordination challenges involved – market participants and authorities would need
to be alert, as indirect or unintended consequences might occur.
A general purpose CBDC could have a large impact on financial intermediation patterns. The
consequence of a larger central bank balance sheet could be a withdrawal of funding to commercial banks.
For example, a flow of retail deposits into a CBDC could lead to a loss of low-cost and stable funding for
banks, with the size of such a loss in normal times depending on the convenience and costs of the CBDC.
Banks could try to prevent a loss of deposits by raising interest rates or seek funding to replace such
outflows, eg through wholesale funds and term deposits, which would likely be more costly.26 This could
lead some banks to raise spreads and increase transaction fees in order to maintain profitability.
Depending on existing market structures, including the importance of retail versus wholesale funding,
banks might have to shrink their balance sheets, with possible adverse consequences.27
Commercial banks’ business models would also have to adapt. Services that are currently crosssubsidised by deposits would need to become viable on a stand-alone basis. The contours of institutions
undertaking the liquidity, credit risk and maturity transformation no longer performed by banks are not
clear. If liquidity in financial markets were to decline and credit and term spreads were to rise, there could
25
New applications of technology could allow participants to interact directly with a synchronised securities ledger to add, verify
and report transactions, with activity to be accelerated, at least theoretically, to real-time settlement. In such a vision, central
counterparties might no longer be necessary to guarantee trades between execution and settlement. A wholesale CBDC might
be considered by some central banks to be part of their toolkit to improve settlements. Nonetheless, many legal, technical and
market coordination challenges would need to be addressed first. Multilateral coordination and governance over such
arrangements would also likely be necessary. And regulatory authorities would insist on prudent management.
26
Furthermore, alternative means of funding are subject to uncertainties. First, the issuance of bonds by banks is contingent upon
placement with investors, which may face some obstacles during times of market stress. Second, any increase in refinancing
via the central bank is usually limited by the amount of assets that can be pledged as collateral with the central bank. Third,
regulatory constraints may further limit the options available to compensate for the loss of deposits.
27
Annex B contains a flow-of-funds analysis illustrating stylised static balance sheet adjustments of key sectors of the economy
upon the introduction of an interest-bearing and widely accessible CBDC.
Central bank digital currencies
15
be adverse repercussions for the economy.28 More generally, the implications of a shrinkage of commercial
bank balance sheets and activity are very hard to assess and require further analysis.
A CBDC attracting significant demand as an asset to hold, may also change the structure and
functioning of funding markets, affecting banks and corporations. Issuers of money market instruments
and borrowers in repo markets would see more competition because a CBDC would substitute for such
claims. Those who issue claims bought by the central bank to accommodate demand for CBDC would
gain. Overall, there might also be a collateral upgrade for private balance sheets if central banks end up
holding some less liquid and lower-rated assets to accommodate the issuance of CBDC.
5.3
Financial stability
Issuance of CBDC raises questions that are similar to those relating to narrow banking or full-reserve
money, as analysed by several academics and critics of current monetary systems. Proponents claim that
narrow banking could make the overall financial system safer because it limits the scope for commercial
banks’ operations. Although narrow banking raises many questions in its own right, the introduction of a
CBDC does not necessarily entail the same restrictions.29 While difficult to anticipate, the possibility that
banks could try to offset the higher cost of funding by engaging in riskier forms of lending to restore
profitability could create financial stability risks. While such risks would have to be compared with those
associated with other (unconventional) monetary policy tools, and combined with the potential adverse
economic impact of reduced lending (Stevens (2017)), there could be more, rather than less, financial
stability risk.
In terms of wholesale markets, some (eg Greenwood et al (2016)) argue that the provision of a safe
and ultra-liquid asset may help reduce rollover risks and excessive maturity transformation, potentially
improving financial stability. However, whether a CBDC leads to these benefits relative to other tools is
uncertain (Box C).
Arguably, the most significant and plausible financial stability risk of a general purpose CBDC is that
it can facilitate a flight away from private financial institutions and markets towards the central bank. Faced
with systemic financial stress, households and other agents in both advanced and emerging market
economies tend to suddenly shift their deposits towards financial institutions perceived to be safer and/or
into government securities. Of course, agents could always flee towards the central bank by holding more
cash. But a CBDC could allow for “digital runs” towards the central bank with unprecedented speed and
scale. Even in the presence of deposit insurance, the stability of retail funding could weaken because a
risk-free CBDC provides a very safe alternative.
Depending on the context, the shift in deposits could be large in times of stress. A crucial element in
such system-wide shifts is the stronger sensitivity of depositors to the actions of others. The more other
depositors run from weaker banks, the greater the incentive to run oneself. If CBDC were available, the
incentives to run could be sharper and more pervasive than today, as the CBDC would be the favoured
destination, especially if deposits were not insured in the first place or deposit insurance was (made more)
limited.30 Whereas weaker banks could experience a run, even stronger banks could face withdrawals in
the presence of CBDC.
28
There are also questions in terms of microprudential regulation and supervision. Would, for example, regulatory requirements,
such as capital and liquidity adequacy, and supervision of banks, need to be adapted?
29
Narrow banking and CBDC differ in two ways. First, under CBDC residents hold direct claims on the central bank, whereas under
narrow banking residents hold commercial bank money that is fully backed by central bank reserves or sovereign claims.
Second, CBDC could coexist with commercial bank money, whereas narrow banking proposals envision no private money
creation. Benes and Kumhof (2012) and Cochrane (2014), which represent examples of recent calls for narrow banking, also
review historical precedents, such as the Chicago Plan of the 1930s. Bacchetta (2017) critically reviews such a proposal in the
case of Switzerland.
30
Although with a lower stock of demand deposits commercial banks might be less prone to retail runs, runs in recent times have
been initiated by other (wholesale) creditors, which would become more important.
16
Central bank digital currencies
It would be difficult to stem runs under such conditions, even when providing large lender of last
resort facilities. Changes in the interest rate that applies to CBDC are unlikely to succeed when agents seek
safety at almost any price. Imposing quantitative limits, difficult at any time owing to various forms of
evasion, could create price deviations between types of central bank money (“discounts”), negating the
principle of money being exchangeable at par and hampering the conduct of monetary policy.
Box C
CBDC, rollover risk and financial stability
A secular rise of institutional cash pools and a stronger desire among investors for secured forms of financing have
increased the demand for highly liquid and safe instruments, which cannot be met by bank deposits (Pozsar (2011)).
This has led to a “near-money premium” in wholesale markets, ie yields on short-term, liquid instruments that are
significantly lower compared with those of slightly longer tenors or higher credit risk. This, in turn, can incentivise
agents to fund longer-term assets with short-term liabilities (eg repo or commercial paper), with associated rollover
risks that could adversely affect financial stability.
Central banks may have a role in reducing these risks by providing non-banks with an attractive money-type
instrument. As argued by some (eg Stein (2012)), the augmented supply of safe assets may force market participants
to scale back their funding of longer-term assets with short-term wholesale borrowing. If less liquid and riskier money
market instruments (eg commercial paper) lost some of their near-money premium, the incentives faced by issuers
for maturity, liquidity and credit risk transformation could be weakened. Whether a CBDC would materially reduce
rollover risks, however, is uncertain. Moreover, increased issuance of short-term debt by the government can also
reduce the near-money premium, with possibly associated benefits. Moreover, central banks have other conventional
tools at their disposal that could serve a similar purpose (Box B).
The term “institutional cash pool” refers to large, centrally managed, short-term cash balances of global non-financial corporations and
institutional investors, such as asset managers, securities lenders and pension funds. See eg Greenwood et al (2016) or Carlson et al (2016)
for further analysis. Another way the near-money premium expresses itself is when short-term government bills and short-term repos with
sovereign collateral trade significantly below the overnight index swap (OIS) rate and the policy rate. For example, long positions in
government bonds financed mostly in repo markets (leveraged fixed income strategies employed by hedge funds) could be unwound as collateral
chains between institutional investors and money market funds are disintermediated (Pozsar (2011) and Singh (2016)).
5.4
Cross-border and global dimensions
For currencies widely used in cross-border transactions, many of the considerations outlined above would
apply with added force. In normal times, there would be many complications should non-residents be
allowed to hold and transact in CBDC. Distinctions between residents and non-residents and domestic and
foreign transactions could become largely symbolic. For example, it could be more difficult to apply
AML/CFT requirements because of a lack of formal powers over intermediaries involved in token-based
CBDC distribution. Similarly, if foreign banks and FMIs (and even other central banks) were able to
purchase, receive or otherwise hold “domestic” CBDC, legal and operational issues could arise. For
example, a foreign entity could use the domestic CBDC to back or otherwise provide the functional
equivalent of “offshore” accounts and payment services denominated in the domestic currency. Further,
the more anonymous the instrument and the more decentralised the transfer mechanism was, the greater
the opportunity for cross-border activity, arbitrage and concealed transactions would be, with related
reputational risks for the central bank. A CBDC available cross-border could, in some economies, increase
substitution away from the domestic currency, which could make monetary aggregates unstable and alter
the choice of monetary instruments.
Even during normal times, CBDC could come with first-mover advantages and economies of scale and
other externalities. In terms of market share, if CBDCs were introduced by jurisdictions with international
currencies, they could reinforce existing costs and benefits, including externalities. Similarly, CBDC could
change the nature of global liquidity and safe asset provision. Also, and especially if introduced in a sudden
and unexpected manner, CBDC could, in some situations, lead to large capital movements and related
exchange rate and other asset price effects. In addition, countries might face challenges in preparing for
Central bank digital currencies
17
what would happen if other central banks were to introduce CBDC. More generally, disturbances could
easily occur.
The cross-border and global dimensions of CBDCs available to non-residents could be especially
pronounced during times of generalised flight to safety. Under such conditions, exchanging a CBDC for
an international currency could potentially enable faster deleveraging in capital markets. If CBDCs
accelerated flights from risk, deleveraging pressures could manifest themselves in the form of tight
funding conditions and sharp movements in foreign exchange markets.
18
Central bank digital currencies
References
Agarwal, R and M Kimball (2015): “Breaking through the zero lower bound”, IMF Working Papers, no
WP/15/224.
Bacchetta, P (2017): “The sovereign money initiative in Switzerland: an economic assessment”, CEPR
Discussion Papers, no 12349.
Bank of England (1963): “Origin of the branches.”
/media/boe/files/quarterly-bulletin/1963/branches-of-the-boe.pdf.
https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-
Bech, M and R Garratt (2017): “Central bank cryptocurrencies”, BIS Quarterly Review, September,
pp 55–70.
Bech, M, Y Shimizu and P Wong (2017): “The quest for speed in payments”, BIS Quarterly Review, March,
pp 57–67.
Bech, M, U Faruqui, F Ougaard, and C Picillo (2018): “Payments are a-changin’ – but cash still rules”, BIS
Quarterly Review, March, pp 67-80.
Benes, J and
no WP/12/2012.
M
Kumhof
(2012):
“The
Chicago
Plan
revisited”,
IMF
Working
Papers,
Bindseil, U (2014): “Monetary policy operations and the financial system”, Oxford University Press.
——— (2016): ”Evaluating monetary policy operational frameworks”, paper presented at the Economic
Policy Symposium at Jackson Hole.
Bordo, M and A Levin (2017): “Central bank digital currency and the future of monetary policy”, NBER
Working Papers, no 23711.
Carlson, M, B Duygan-Bump, F Natalucci, B Nelson, M Ochoa, J Stein and S Van den Heuvel (2016): “The
demand for short-term, safe assets and financial stability: some evidence and implications for central bank
policies”, International Journal of Central Banking, vol 12, no 4, December, pp 307–333.
Cochrane, J (2014): “Toward a run-free financial system”, University of Chicago, working paper.
Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems (CPSS) (2003): The role of central bank money in payment
systems, August.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (CPMI) (2014): Non-banks in retail payments,
September.
–––– (2012): Innovations in retail payments, May.
–––– (2015): Digital currencies, November.
–––– (2016a): A glossary of terms used in payments and settlement systems, October.
–––– (2016b): Fast payments – Enhancing the speed and availability of retail payments, November.
–––– (2017a): Distributed ledger technology in payment, clearing and settlement: An analytical framework,
February.
–––– (2017b): Discussion note - Reducing the risk of wholesale payments fraud related to endpoint security
- consultative document, September.
–––– (2017c): Statistics on payment, clearing and settlement systems in the CPMI countries - Figures for 2016
(preliminary version), October.
–––– (2018): Cross-border retail payments, March.
CPMI and International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) (2016): Guidance on cyber
resilience for financial market infrastructures, June.
Central bank digital currencies
19
Duffie, D and A Krishnamurthy (2016): “Adapting to changes in the financial market landscape”, paper
presented at the Economic Policy Symposium at Jackson Hole.
Dyson, B and G Hodgson (2016): “Digital cash: why central banks should start issuing electronic money”,
Positive Money.
Fung, B. and H. Halaburda (2016): “Central Bank Digital Currencies: A Framework for Assessing Why and
How.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper No. 2016-22.
Goodfriend, M (2016): “The case for unencumbering interest rate policy at the zero bound”, paper
presented at the Economic Policy Symposium at Jackson Hole.
Green, E (2008): “Some challenges for research in payment systems” in The Future of Payment Systems, eds
A Haldane, S Millards and V Saporta, Routhledge, Milton Park.
Greenwood, R, S Hanson, J Rudolph and L Summers (2014): “Government debt management at the zero
lower bound”, Hutchins Centre on Fiscal & Monetary Policy at Brookings, Working Papers, no 5.
Greenwood, R, S Hanson and J Stein (2016): “The Federal Reserve’s balance sheet as a financial-stability
tool”, paper presented at the Economic Policy Symposium at Jackson Hole.
Hayek, F (1945): “The
vol 35, no 4, pp 519–30.
use
of
knowledge
in
society”,
American
Economic
Review,
Kahn C and W Roberds (2009): “Why pay? An introduction to payments economics”, Journal of Financial
Intermediation 18(3), January, pp 1–23.
McAndrews, J (2017): “The case for cash”, ADBI working paper, no 679.
Mersch, Y (2017a): “Digital base money: an assessment from the ECB’s perspective”, speech at the Bank of
Finland, 16 January.
——— (2017b): “Why Europe still needs cash”, Contribution for Project Syndicate.
Pfister, C (2017): “Monetary policy and digital currencies: much ado about nothing?” Bank of France,
Working Papers, no 642.
Potter, S (2017): “Money markets at crossroads: policy implementation in times of structural change”,
remarks at the University of California, Los Angeles.
Pozsar, Z (2011): “Institutional cash pools and the Triffin dilemma of the US banking system”, IMF Working
Papers, no WP/11/90.
Reichsbank (1926): Die Reichsbank, 1901–1925, Druckerei der Reichsbank.
Rogoff, K (2016): The curse of cash, Princeton University Press.
Singh, M (2016): Collateral and financial plumbing, Risk Book, 2nd impression.
Skingsley, C (2016): “Should the Riksbank issue e-krona?”, speech at FinTech Stockholm, 16 November.
Stein, J (2012): “Monetary policy as financial-stability regulation”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127,
February, pp 57–95.
Stevens, A (2017): “Digital currencies: threats and opportunities for monetary policy”, National Bank of
Belgium, Economic Review, June.
Sveriges Riksbank (2017): The Riksbank’s e-krona project – Report 1, September.
Tobin, J (1985): “Financial innovation and deregulation in perspective”, Cowles Foundation Papers, no 635.
Woodford, M (2000): “Monetary policy in a world without money,” International Finance, vol 3, no 2,
pp 229–60.
20
Central bank digital currencies
Annex A: Principles of monetary policy implementation
This Annex provides a short overview of the general principles of monetary policy implementation, namely
the use of the central bank’s balance sheet to achieve its operational target. This target, which can be
controlled by the central bank on a day-to-day basis, is highly relevant to the fulfilment of its mandate
(Bindseil (2014)).
Typically, central banks use an overnight rate as their operational target. The financial institutions that
are directly relevant to this operational target and its transmission to money markets are the central bank’s
monetary counterparties. To achieve their operational target, central banks need to ensure that the value
of attracting or trading away overnight funds from monetary counterparties equals the operational target.
Two operational regimes are typically used for this purpose: a corridor and a floor system.
In a corridor system, central banks apply two interest rates to reserves: (i) up to a limited amount
(depending on reserve requirements), the policy rate is applied; and beyond that (ii) a substantially lower
deposit rate is paid.31 Monetary counterparties may access an overnight lending facility at a higher rate.
Central banks continuously need to ensure via open market operations (OMOs) that the overall amount
of reserves equals the overall limit amount at which the policy rate applies. Central banks can increase
flexibility in fulfilling this requirement by applying: (i) a band at which the policy rate applies instead of a
limit; or (ii) the minimum required amount of reserves averaged over a maintenance period.
Central banks must forecast the demand for liquidity in order to be prepared to inject (or drain) the
right quantity of reserves. This involves projecting day-to-day changes in autonomous factors – that is, all
the balance sheet items outside of the direct control of the central bank’s monetary policy implementation
function that affect the amount of reserves.
The difference between the policy and the deposit rate provides an incentive for monetary
counterparties to trade overnight funds among themselves, on a secured or unsecured basis. Abstracting
from possible balance sheet and collateral costs, such transactions take place close to the policy rate. Thus,
the policy rate becomes the marginal value of attracting or trading away overnight funds from monetary
counterparties, while the overall amount of reserves can be relatively small. This enables central banks to
run a relatively lean balance sheet. This means a balance sheet that is only slightly larger than banknotes
outstanding, limiting the intermediary role of the central bank (Graph A1).
Under a floor system, central banks ensure that the marginal value of attracting or holding overnight
funds from monetary counterparties equals the deposit rate. With substantial excess reserves, the marginal
use for monetary counterparties of holding additional reserves is to earn the deposit rate (Graph A2). The
deposit rate thereby becomes the de facto policy rate. To achieve this, monetary outright holdings must
exceed the original liquidity deficit, ie the liquidity needs caused by net autonomous factors. Liquidity
forecasting is less important because day-to-day fluctuations in the amount of reserves do not change the
marginal value of attracting or holding overnight funds (with monetary counterparties).
In both operational regimes, flows into non-monetary deposits, that is digital central bank money held
by non-monetary counterparties (eg the treasury, foreign central banks or FMIs) and banknotes result in a
drain of reserves. In a corridor system, such flows need to be compensated by liquidity-injecting OMOs. In
a floor system, such flows only need to be compensated if the liquidity surplus becomes insufficient and
rates begin to rise above the deposit rate (monetary outright holdings threaten to fall below the original
liquidity deficit). In practice, flows into banknotes are limited by the carrying cost of cash, making banknotes
relatively inconvenient as a store of value. Flows into non-monetary deposits are typically limited by price
31
Under zero reserve regimes, such as that of the Bank of Canada, the central bank charges a higher policy rate on negative balances (ie
loans) and pays a lower deposit rate on positive balances. Under this system, required reserves are not necessary and the overall limit
amount at which the policy rate applies can be zero.
Central bank digital currencies
21
disincentives beyond certain specified amounts, also making non-monetary deposits relatively unattractive
as a store of value. Such price disincentives are often applied to limit the central bank’s intermediary role.
Different central banks put varying weights on this principle, however, and apply different price
disincentives and access conditions to non-monetary deposits.
A stylised balance sheet of the central bank after the introduction of CBDC is depicted in Graph A3,
reflecting the demand for CBDC and its increased assets holdings.
Corridor system without CBDC
Graph A1
Floor system without CBDC
Graph A2
22
Central bank digital currencies
Central bank balance sheet with CBDC
Central bank digital currencies
Graph A3
23
Annex B: Flow-of-funds representation
A stylised flow-of-funds analysis illustrates qualitatively how sectoral balance sheets and the
implementation and transmission of monetary policy may be affected by the introduction of a general
purpose CBDC. The more CBDC is perceived by economic agents to be an attractive asset, the larger will
be the substitution effects discussed below.
The balance sheets considered are those of:
i.
Households (retail). It is assumed that households hold real assets (RA), retail deposits at commercial
banks (DEP) and banknotes (BAN). Furthermore, they invest in corporate/government and bank bonds
(B + BB) and money market fund shares (FS) if their liquid funds exceed deposit guarantee schemes’
coverage. They finance themselves through retail mortgage loans (RML) provided by commercial
banks and their own funds or equity (E).
ii.
Corporations/government. It is assumed that corporations and the government fund themselves via
bank loans (L) and bonds (B) as well as money market instruments (MM). This sector holds real assets
(eg public infrastructure, corporate facilities) and liquidity buffers in the form of cash pool
participations (CPP).
iii. Banks (monetary counterparties). Funding takes place by accepting retail deposits, by issuing money
market instruments (eg secured funding via repos or unsecured funding via commercial paper) and
bank bonds and by drawing on central bank credit facilities. These instruments fund purchases of
government and corporate bonds, loans to corporates, retail mortgages to households and holdings
of central bank reserves (RES).
iv. The central bank. The liability side of the central bank’s balance sheet consists of banknotes held by
households and reserve balances held by banks. On the asset side, the central bank has outright
holdings of corporate, government and (covered) bank bonds and provides credit to banks, therewith
implementing monetary policy.
The introduction of CBDC opens up a number of channels that affect patterns of financial
intermediation in the economy (see the bold, red font balance sheet items in Table B1).32 First, households
may substitute banknotes for CBDC (CBDCa), which prompts a change on the central bank’s liability side.
Second, households may substitute retail deposits for CBDC (CBDCb) by making payments from retail
deposits to CBDC accounts. To effect such payments, banks request the central bank to debit reserves held
by them and credit the CBDC accounts. In order to ensure that reserves stay at the required level to
implement monetary policy, the central bank buys bonds or provides additional credit to banks. 33
The main question is how large these flows are likely to be and how financial market participants that
attract or lose funding will adjust their behaviour. What assets will the central bank hold against the CBDC
inflows? Will the financial market participants that lose funding raise funds elsewhere or will they
deleverage?
Table B1 shows qualitatively one of the many possible outcomes. The central bank accommodates
CBDC inflows by increasing its lending to monetary counterparties and outright holdings of bonds. The
banks use the central bank’s funds to compensate for the lost retail deposits (CBDCb). In this highly
restrictive scenario, there is only a shift in intermediation and no impact on the real assets held by
corporates/governments and households (ie no deleveraging and/or leveraging). Instead, the central bank
intermediates between households, on the one hand, and banks and corporates/government, on the
other.
32
Further substitution effects could be induced as money market funds switch holdings of money market instruments (eg reverse,
repos, commercial paper or treasury bills) for CBDC. These effects are omitted from the analysis for ease of exposition.
33
Hence, it is assumed that the central bank either implements monetary policy through a corridor or a floor system with a
minimum amount of excess liquidity, consistent with keeping short-term rates close to the deposit rate.
24
Central bank digital currencies
CBDC and the structure of the financial system: a flow-of-funds analysis1
Table B1
Households (retail)
Real assets
Retail deposits
CBDC
Banknotes
Bonds (for investment)
(Money market) fund shares
RA1
Equity
DEP – CBDCb
Retail mortgage loans
E
RML
CBDCa + CBDCb
BAN – CBDCa
B1 + BB1
FS
Corporations/government
Real assets
RA2
Loans
Cash pool participation
CPP
Corporate/government bonds
MM instruments
L
B1 + B2 + B3
MM1
Banks (monetary counterparties)
Corporate/government bonds
Loans
B2
Retail deposits
L
MM instruments
Retail mortgage loans
RML
Bank bonds
Reserves
RES
CB credit facilities
DEP – CBDCb
MM2
BB1 + BB2
RES + BAN – B3 – BB2
+ CBDCb
Central bank
CB credit facilities
Corporate/government/bank
bonds
1
RES + BAN – B3 – BB2
Reserves
+ CBDCb
Banknotes
B3 + BB2
CBDC
RES
BAN – CBDCa
CBDCa + CBDCb
The analysis is performed under the assumption of a central bank operating through a corridor system.
Explanatory notes: CBDCa – amount of banknotes substituted for by households’ CBDC holdings; CBDCb – amount of retail deposits at
commercial banks substituted for by households’ CBDC holdings; RA1 (RA2) – real assets held by households (corporates/government); MM1
(MM2) – money market instruments issued by corporates/government (banks); B1/B2/B3 – amount of bonds (either issued by corporates or
government) held by households/banks/central bank; BB1 (BB2) – amount of bonds issued by banks and held by household (central bank).
In practice, however, some funding losses and gains and thereby some degree of deleveraging and/or
leveraging are likely to happen as central bank credit leads to bank asset encumbrance. This, in turn, is
costly to banks and may induce them to reduce their loans and bond holdings. To the extent that the shift
in the structure of financial intermediation provokes higher (lower) liquidity, term and credit-risk premia
on the funding for households and corporates/government, their capacity to hold real assets may decrease
(increase).
Central bank digital currencies
25
Annex C: The impact of CBDC on seigniorage
Seigniorage represents income earned by a central bank from issuing (non-interest-bearing) banknotes.
In a two-tier banking system, income from issuing money (banknotes and deposits at commercial banks)
partly accrues to commercial banks, giving way to a broader notion of seigniorage. The design features of
CBDC (described in section 2.2) determine how much of this broad seigniorage value accrues to
commercial banks and to the central bank. If CBDC emerges as an attractive asset, seigniorage may move
from commercial banks to the central bank, as agents substitute commercial bank deposits by CBDC.
There are two channels through which broad seigniorage value may change due to CBDC. First, CBDC
affects the overall value of the money issuing function to the extent that CBDC reduces operational costs
(eg costs related to printing, storage and transportation of banknotes, and settlement costs) and, especially
at the outset, entails significant fixed infrastructure costs (but very low marginal costs). Second, as an
additional and possibly attractive asset, CBDC may serve as a substitute for other non-deposit financial
assets (eg shares in money market mutual funds). This latter effect would increase money in circulation
and thereby broaden the overall seigniorage base.
Seigniorage accruing to the central bank depends on two key variables: the stock of currency in
circulation and the difference in returns between central bank assets and currency liabilities. Introducing
CBDC could change both factors. First, any CBDC-driven expansion of the balance sheet has a positive
effect because most the funding cost equals the policy rate (ie the risk-free rate). Any asset that the central
bank may buy from, lend to, or accept as collateral from its monetary counterparties should have an
expected yield above the expected risk-free rate over the investment horizon. As a CBDC-driven expansion
of the balance sheet entails a corresponding decline of retail deposits and money market instruments,
such increased central bank seigniorage corresponds to decreased seigniorage income at banks and
money market issuers. This effect may, however, be offset to some degree if CBDC were to lead to reduced
demand for banknotes, which are non-interest bearing. And the impact would depend on the
remuneration of CBDC: the higher the remuneration, the greater the reduction in seigniorage income from
banknote circulation.
These effects would produce gains and losses for central and commercial banks, as well as for nonbanks, which, in turn, could influence their financial robustness and hence have systemic financial stability
consequences. For central banks, any significant reduction of seigniorage would constrain their ability to
recapitalise following financial losses, in the absence of other sources of income. The persistence of low
or even negative capital could put monetary policy and financial stability goals at risk.
26
Central bank digital currencies
Annex D: Members of the working groups
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures
Chair
Klaus Löber (European Central Bank)
Reserve Bank of Australia
David Emery
National Bank of Belgium
Filip Caron
Central Bank of Brazil
Daniel Gersten Reiss
Bank of Canada
Ben Fung
European Central Bank
Dirk Bullmann
Bank of France
Marion Chich
Deutsche Bundesbank
Heike Winter and Marcus Härtel
Hong Kong Monetary Authority
Nelson Chow
Reserve Bank of India
Supriyo Bhattacharjee
Bank of Italy
Michela Tocci and Giuseppe Galano
Bank of Japan
Shuji Kobayakawa
Bank of Korea
Dong Sup Kim
Bank of Mexico
Ángel Salazar Sotelo
Netherlands Bank
Kirsten van Driel
Central Bank of the Russian Federation
Maxim Grigoriev
Saudi Arabian Monetary Authority
Mohsen Al Zahrani
Monetary Authority of Singapore
Tze Hon Lau
South African Reserve Bank
Arif Ismail
Sveriges Riksbank
Björn Segendorf
Swiss National Bank
Marco Cecchini and Nino Landerer
Bank of England
Simon Scorer
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
David Mills and Brendan Malone
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Vanessa Lee
Bank for International Settlements
Paul Wong (Secretary)
Morten Bech and Stijn Claessens
Workstreams were led by Dirk Bullmann (European Central Bank), Shuji Kobayakawa (Bank of Japan), David
Emery (Reserve Bank of Australia) and Brendan Malone (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System). Significant contributions were also made by Jiamin Lim (Reserve Bank of Australia); Hanna
Halaburda (Bank of Canada); Thomas Leach (European Central Bank); Dion Reijnders (Netherlands Bank);
Cordelia Kafetz (Bank of England); Jeff Marquardt and Sarah Wright (Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System); Antoine Martin and Ray Fisher (Federal Reserve Bank of New York); and Ayse Sungur,
Rebecca Chmielewski, Henry Holden, Rodney Garratt and Codruta Boar (Secretariat).
Central bank digital currencies
27
Markets Committee
Chair
Aerdt Houben (Netherlands Bank)
National Bank of Belgium
Arnoud Stevens
Bank of Canada
Parnell Chu and Scott Hendry
European Central Bank
Jens Tapking and Christoph Ohlerich
Deutsche Bundesbank
Corinna Dietzen and Dorothee Hellmuth
Hong Kong Monetary Authority
Nelson Chow
Reserve Bank of India
Senthil Kumar
Bank of Italy
Tommaso Perez
Bank of Korea
Dong Sup Kim
Netherlands Bank
Steef Akerboom and Dion Reijnders
Monetary Authority of Singapore
Jeremy Hor
Bank of Spain
Covadonga Martín Alonso
Sveriges Riksbank
Per Åsberg Sommar
Bank of England
Cordelia Kafetz, Ben Dyson and Emily Clayton
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Laura Lipscomb and Heather Wiggins
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Elizabeth Caviness
Bank for International Settlements
Andreas Schrimpf (Secretary)
Stijn Claessens
28
Central bank digital currencies
BIS Papers
No 101
Proceeding with caution –
a survey on central bank
digital currency
By Christian Barontini and Henry Holden
Monetary and Economic Department
January 2019
JEL classification: E42, E58, O33
Keywords: Central bank digital currencies, CBDC, digital
innovation, money flower, cryptocurrencies, cryptoassets, financial inclusion
The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS.
This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org).
©
Bank for International Settlements 2019. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be
reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.
ISSN 1609-0381 (print)
ISBN 978-92-9259-238-7 (print)
ISSN 1682-7651 (online)
ISBN 978-92-9259-239-4 (online)
Contents
Introduction ............................................................................................................................................... 1
Central bank digital currencies........................................................................................................... 1
Motivations for general purpose CBDCs: Sweden and Uruguay .......................................... 3
The survey .................................................................................................................................................. 6
Results .......................................................................................................................................................... 7
Conclusion ................................................................................................................................................12
Cryptocurrencies and other private digital tokens...................................................................14
References ................................................................................................................................................16
Annex 1: Central banks participating in the survey .................................................................17
Annex 2: Survey questions .................................................................................................................18
Previous volumes in this series ........................................................................................................ 20
BIS Papers No 101
i
ii
BIS Papers No 101
Proceeding with caution – a survey on central bank
digital currency 1
A survey of central banks shows that a majority are collaboratively looking at the implications of a central
bank digital currency. Although many have reached the stage of considering practical issues, central banks
appear to be proceeding cautiously and few report plans to issue a digital currency in the short or medium
term.
Introduction
Payments are changing at an accelerating pace. Users expect faster, easier payments
anywhere and at any time, mirroring the digitalisation and convenience of other
aspects of life (Bech et al (2017)). And, although paper-based payments like cheques
and cash still play important roles, new technologies and market entrants are
challenging the traditional bank-based payment systems (Jakobsen (2018)).
In addition to changes in how payments are made, even the type of money used
could be changing. Across the world, central banks are reportedly thinking about how
new central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) could replace traditional money (CPMIMC (2018)). There is significant public interest in such a fundamental potential
change, and this paper takes stock of central banks’ current work and thinking. It is
based on a recent survey of central banks to which 63 responded 2 (representing
jurisdictions covering close to 80% of the world population). The survey asked central
banks about their current work on CBDCs, what motivates that work, and how likely
their issuance of a CBDC is.
The survey shows that, although a majority of central banks are researching
CBDCs, this work is primarily conceptual and only a few intend to issue a CBDC in the
short to medium term.
Central bank digital currencies
The 2018 report by the Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (CPMI)
and the Markets Committee (MC) defines CBDCs as new variants of central bank
money different from physical cash or central bank reserve/settlement accounts.
Based on four key properties, the CPMI-MC report provides a taxonomy of money
(“The money flower”) which delineates between two broad types of CBDC: general
purpose and wholesale – with the former type coming in two varieties (Graph 1).
The four key properties of money are: issuer (central bank or not); form (digital
or physical); accessibility (widely or restricted); and technology. In terms of technology,
1
We thank Morten Bech and Paul Wong for valuable comments, Codruta Boar for excellent research
assistance, Harish Natarajan and World Bank colleagues for help disseminating the survey, and
Klaus Löber and members of the CPMI Working Group on Digital Innovations for comments on the
questions asked. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect those of the BIS.
2
See complete list in Annex 1.
BIS Papers No 101
1
the report distinguishes between money that is token- or account-based. In payment
economics, a key difference between tokens and accounts is in their verification: a
person receiving a token will verify that the token is genuine, whereas an intermediary
verifies the identity of an account holder (Green (2008) and Kahn and Roberds (2009)).
However, the definition of tokens varies considerable across scientific fields, and other
reports distinguish between value- or account-based forms of CBDC (eg Sveriges
Riksbank (2018) and Norges Bank (2018)). This paper uses the terms value- and
token-based interchangeably.
The money flower: a taxonomy of money
Graph 1
The Venn diagram illustrates the four key properties of money: issuer (central bank or not); form (digital or physical); accessibility (widely or
restricted); and technology (account-based or token-based). CB = central bank. Private digital tokens (general purpose) include
cryptocurrencies, such as Bitcoin. For examples of how other forms of money may fit in the diagram, please refer to the source.
Sources: CPMI-MC (2018); Bech and Garratt (2017).
In sum, this paper discusses the three variants of CBDC highlighted by the greyshaded areas within the “money flower” above. The first is a “general purpose”,
“account-based” variant, ie an account at the central bank for the general public. This
would be widely available and primarily targeted at retail transactions (but also
available for broader use). The second form is a “general purpose”, “token-based”
variant, ie a type of “digital cash” issued by the central bank for the general public.
This second variant would have similar availability and functions to the first, but would
be distributed and transferred differently. The last form is a “wholesale”, “token- or
value-based” variant, ie a restricted-access digital token for wholesale settlements (eg
interbank payments, or securities settlement). Two general purpose CBDC projects,
the e-Peso and e-Krona, and the motivations behind them, are discussed in detail in
Box A.
2
BIS Papers No 101
Box A
Motivations for general purpose CBDCs: Sweden and Uruguay
Although in many parts of the world, the amount of cash in circulation has risen over the last decade, there are some
countries that buck the trend (Bech et al (2018)). In this small club of jurisdictions, a few have considered general
purpose CBDCs that would be a complement to cash. Sweden and Uruguay are notable not just for the advanced
stage of their work but the amount of information their central banks have made publicly available about their
respective projects.
e-Krona
Cash use in Sweden has declined for many years (Graph A). The country’s retailers have good reason to expect that
the decline will continue and the cost of accepting cash will become prohibitive, so that it will no longer be accepted
in the future (Sveriges Riksbank (2018)).
Sveriges Riksbank payment survey
As a percentage of respondents
Who paid for their most recent purchase in cash?
Graph A
How often do you withdraw cash from an ATM or cash
desk at a bank?
Source: Sveriges Riksbank.
In response to this decline, the Riksbank is working on an “e-Krona” project, beginning in early 2017 and
publishing its second report in October 2018. The report noted that the use of cash continues to decline and that the
state needs to have a role in the payment market. A means by which to do this is to have an electronic krona. The ekrona would be a complement to cash, as well as to current electronic payments (especially in a serious crisis where
other electronic payments might not be available).
Electronic payments beyond cards (specifically, a mobile payment system called “Swish”) have recently seen a
significant increase in Sweden, but usage is markedly lower among the elderly (Graph B). The Riksbank notes that
some in society, who may have access only to cash, including the elderly and other more vulnerable groups, may need
a simpler, more user-friendly offering to avoid exclusion.
An e-krona might be “value-based” (ie not an account). However, the current versions of distributed ledger
technology (DLT) are considered to be too immature, although they are not ruled out for the future. The Riksbank
envisages a “platform” where payment service providers (PSPs) of the e-Krona would connect and distribute the
currency. Those PSPs could, the Riksbank thinks, use DLT in providing their services.
A value-based approach would be compatible with the Riksbank’s legal mandate (the Sveriges Riksbank Act), but
an account-based e-Krona would require the mandate to be adapted for clarity. An account-based e-Krona is not
BIS Papers No 101
3
ruled out, but the Riksbank notes that coordination with other agencies would be necessary, and so dialogue should
begin. The next stage will be a pilot programme for a prepaid value, non-interest bearing and traceable e-Krona. This
will investigate a range of possible choices to better inform the decision whether to issue a full-scale e-Krona.
Rapid increase in use of new payment solution in Sweden
Sweden
Means of payment
% of GDP
Graph B
Means of payment for different age
groups
% of GDP
Per cent
Per cent
Sources: Sveriges Riksbank; CPMI Red Book statistics.
e-Peso
The Central Bank of Uruguay has just completed a pilot programme on a general purpose CBDC. The pilot was part
of a wider governmental financial inclusion programme, which began in 2011, aiming for greater access, labour market
formalisation and payment system efficiency. Since these efforts began, the availability of ATMs and other cash
dispensing mechanisms has grown enormously but cash withdrawals have plateaued (Graph C) and cash in circulation
has fallen (Graph D).
Uruguay
Graph C
POS Terminals
ATMs
000s
POS = point of sale.
ATMs = automated teller machines.
Cash withdrawals
Number
Mn
Electronic payments
UYU bn
OEMP = other electronic means of payment.
Source: Central Bank of Uruguay.
4
BIS Papers No 101
mn
To respond to these changes and further its broader financial inclusion goals, the Central Bank of Uruguay began
a pilot programme in November 2017 to issue, circulate and test an e-Peso. Unique digital banknotes in several
denominations were issued for distribution to an “e-note manager platform”. The platform acted as registry of the
ownership of the digital banknotes. DLT was not used. In total, 20 million e-Pesos were issued, of which 7 million were
distributed by a third-party PSP, which held an equivalent value of pesos in a central bank account. Individual users
and businesses, in electronic wallets, could hold a maximum of 30,000 e-Pesos (roughly USD 1,000) and 200,000 ePesos respectively. Transfers took place instantly and peer-to-peer, via mobile phones using either text messages or
the e-Peso app. The Central Bank of Uruguay’s legal mandate was sufficient to issue the electronic e-Peso as a
complement to physical cash.
The pilot was deemed a success and closed in April 2018, after which all e-Pesos were cancelled. The programme
is now in an evaluation phase and a number of questions are being considered, before a decision on further trials and
potential issuance can be made. These include design specific challenges, eg how best to manage the stock of digital
banknotes in different denominations as well as wider questions eg the level of anonymity the e-Peso would have,
whether it would bear interest, the final role of the central bank and what the wider impact on businesses and the
economy would be.
M1 and its components in Uruguay
As a percentage of GDP
Graph D
Source: Central Bank of Uruguay.
Sveriges Riksbank (2018).
Slides presented at the Conference on "Economics of Payments IX", hosted by the Bank for International Settlements and Committee on
Payments and Market Infrastructures in Basel, Switzerland, 15–16 November 2018 (agenda).
BIS Papers No 101
5
The survey
Geographical coverage
Some 63 central banks replied to the survey, of which 41 are located in emerging
market economies (EMEs) and 22 in advanced economies (Graph 2). Together, the
respondents represent close to 80% of the world’s population and over 90% of its
economic output.
Respondents to the survey1
Graph 2
1
The black circles represent the Cayman Islands, the Dominican Republic, the Dutch Caribbean, the euro area, Hong Kong SAR, Samoa,
Singapore, the Solomon Islands and Tonga. “Advanced economies” and “Emerging market economies” as defined by the IMF World
Economic Outlook country classification.
The boundaries and names shown and the designations used in this map do not imply endorsement or acceptance by the BIS.
Questionnaire
The survey was conducted in latter part of 2018. It starts by asking central banks if
they work on CBDCs or not and, if they do, it further inquiries about the type of CBDC
and how advanced the work is. Motivations and current expectations for potentially
issuing a CBDC are also queried, as well as whether central banks have legal authority
to issue. The questions asked are included in Annex 2.
Given the complexities involved, central banks also provided a wealth of
supplementary qualitative explanations to their answers. This survey follows a similar
(but smaller-scale and unpublished) survey conducted by the CPMI in 2017. Results
from the 2017 survey are included where relevant.
In addition to questions about CBDC, the survey also asked about “private digital
tokens” and their use for payments. Private digital tokens encompass the wide variety
of digital tokens not issued by central banks. The survey differentiated between socalled “cryptocurrencies” and other private digital tokens, with cryptocurrencies
defined as decentralised tokens without an issuer or representing an underlying asset
or liability. Central banks’ responses are discussed in Box B.
6
BIS Papers No 101
Results
The survey finds that a wide variety of motivations is driving an increasing number of
central banks to conduct conceptual research on CBDCs. However, only a few central
banks have firm intentions to issue a CBDC within the next decade.
Work underway
Some 70% of respondents are currently (or will soon be) engaged in CBDC work, a
slight increase compared to the 2017 survey (Graph 3, left-hand panel). Central banks
currently not looking at CBDC are typically from smaller jurisdictions and/or face
more pressing priorities. Some central banks indicate that they rely on research
conducted by international organisations (in particular the BIS) or regional networks
(eg CARICOM’s fintech Advisory Work Group). Of those that are engaged in work,
over half cover both general purpose and wholesale CBDCs (Graph 3, right-hand
panel), with about a third focusing only on general purpose and an eighth only on
wholesale.
Central bank CBDC work
Share of respondents
Graph 3
Engagement in CBDC work
1
Focus of work1
Share of respondents conducting work on CBDCs, 2018 survey.
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
All central banks have begun their CBDC work with theoretical and conceptual
research and are generally sharing their studies, with a view to developing a common
understanding of this new field of study. At this point, half have moved on to
experiments or more “hands-on” proof-of-concept activities to test new technologies
(Graph 4, left-hand panel). This represents an increase of 15 percentage points over
2017 (Graph 4, right-hand panel).
Many central banks in both advanced economies and EMEs are attempting to
replicate wholesale payment systems using distributed ledger technology (eg
projects Jasper, Ubin and Khokha (Bank of Canada (2018), Monetary Authority of
Singapore (2018), South African Reserve Bank (2018)).
BIS Papers No 101
7
Only five central banks have progressed to running pilot projects. The e-Peso
project described in Box A is an example of a completed pilot. Importantly, despite
the quantity of work underway, many of these proofs-of-concept or even pilot
projects are only investigative in nature and do not imply plans to issue a CBDC.
Type of CBDC work
Share of respondents conducting work on CBDCs
2018 survey
Graph 4
Experiments/proof-of-concept
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
Central banks are also increasingly collaborating with each other to carry out
proof-of-concept work on eg cross border payment and securities settlement
arrangements. Collaborations include Project Stella by the ECB and the Bank of Japan
(ECB-BoJ (2017)) as well as a joint project by the Bank of Canada (BoC), the Monetary
Authority of Singapore (MAS) and the Bank of England (BoE) (BoC, MAS and BoE
(2018)).
Motivations
The survey asked central banks about their motivations for potentially issuing a
wholesale or a general purpose CBDC. Central banks chose from the same set of
predefined factors for each type of CBDC, concerning payment safety and efficiency
as well as other aspects of central banks’ mandates. The central banks ranked their
relative importance on a four-point scale ranging from “not so important = 1” to “very
important = 4” and supplemented their choice with comments.
Looking across all respondents for both types of CBDC, payments safety and
domestic efficiency are the most important motivating factors to central banks (Graph
5). Least important are, predictably, financial inclusion for wholesale CBDCs and, lesspredictably, cross-border payments efficiency, for general purpose CBDCs. To note,
however, all rankings remain in a rather narrow range which suggest at this
“investigative” stage the main motivation is to learn. However, as central banks
progress, more differentiation in terms of motives might emerge.
Outside the predefined choices, many central banks consider a range of other
factors important as well. For general purpose CBDC, this broadly relates to issues
around cash, either responding to dwindling use or discouraging it through
supporting electronic innovations and payments. For wholesale CBDC, the other
8
BIS Papers No 101
factors are more diverse and overall, considered less important. They include better
monitoring of transactions as well as safety and efficiency benefits for end users.
Motivations for issuing a CBDC, ranked in order of importance
Score1
Graph 5
General-purpose CBDCs
Wholesale CBDCs
1
The score is calculated as an average of the options: “Not so important” (1), “Somewhat important” (2), “Important” (3) and “Very
important” (4).
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
Breaking respondents down by stage of economic development shows that, for
general purpose CBDC, EMEs value domestic payments efficiency and financial
inclusion most (Graph 6). On the other hand, cross-border payments efficiency is the
least important. In contrast, for advanced economies, payments safety and financial
stability are the primary motivators for potential issuance. Financial inclusion is clearly
the least important factor.
In qualitative commentary, EME central banks also note that supporting
digitalisation, incorporating the informal economy and fighting financial crime, are
key motivators for potentially issuing a CBDC. Some advanced economies are
motivated by the prospect of a “less-cash” or even “cash-less” society (see Box A for
a discussion of the e-Krona).
BIS Papers No 101
9
Motivations for issuing general-purpose CBDCs, ranked in order of importance
Score1
Advanced economies
Graph 6
Emerging market economies
1
The score is calculated as an average of the options: “Not so important” (1), “Somewhat important” (2), “Important” (3) and “Very
important” (4).
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
For wholesale CBDCs, both advanced economies and EMEs consider payments
safety and efficiency the most important motivating factors (Graph 7). However, for
EMEs, the cross-border dimension is somewhat less important. All central banks
(including EMEs) consider financial inclusion the least important factor for wholesale
CBDCs.
Motivations for issuing wholesale CBDCs, ranked in order of importance
Score1
Advanced economies
Graph 7
Emerging market economies
1
The score is calculated as an average of the options: “Not so important” (1), “Somewhat important” (2), “Important” (3) and “Very
important” (4).
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
10
BIS Papers No 101
Outlook
The survey asked central banks to describe the likelihood of their issuing each type
of CBDC over the short (up to three years) and medium (up to six years) term. Central
banks could choose from “very likely” to “very unlikely” on a five-point scale.
In the short term, over 85% of central banks see themselves as either somewhat
unlikely or very unlikely to issue any type of CBDC (Graph 8). No central banks are
very likely to issue a wholesale CBDC in the short term, but two EME central banks
are considering issuing a general purpose CBDC over the same horizon.
Beyond the short term, an increased proportion of central banks consider the
issuance of both types of CBDC to be possible. Nevertheless, a majority still consider
this move at least somewhat or very unlikely. In the medium term, only one central
bank reported that they see themselves as very likely to issue a wholesale CBDC.
Overall, the likelihood of issuing both types of CBDC is somewhat similar, despite the
perceived greater operational complexity and larger impact on the financial system
of a general purpose CBDC (CPMI-MC (2018)).
Likelihood of issuing a CBDC in the short and medium term1
Share of respondents
Graph 8
General-purpose CBDC
1
Wholesale CBDC
Short term: 1–3 years and medium term: 1–6 years.
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
The 2017 survey also asked about the likelihood of issuing CBDC. However, the
questionnaire did not differentiate between general purpose and wholesale CBDCs.
Of the central banks that answered, half deemed issuance possible whereas the other
half deemed it unlikely. At that time only one central bank was considering CBDC
issuance to be likely but in the 2018 survey, it indicated that it is no longer pursuing
any research.
Legal authority
A prerequisite for issuing a CBDC is that the central bank has the legal authority to
do so. The survey asked central banks to indicate whether they have, or are in the
process of acquiring, this authority. The same question was asked in the 2017 survey.
BIS Papers No 101
11
Almost a quarter of central banks have, or will soon have, authority to issue a
CBDC while a third do not, and about 40% remain unsure (Graph 9, left-hand panel).
The high level of uncertainty is unsurprising, given that most central bank mandates
predate not only cryptocurrencies but also many forms of electronic money. However,
as central banks are studying all aspects of CBDC, the level of uncertainty has fallen
compared with the 2017 survey (Graph 9, right-hand panel). The uncertainty does not
differ materially by geography or a jurisdiction’s economic development.
Legal authority to issue a CBDC
Share of respondents
2018 survey
1
Graph 9
Over time
There was no “laws are currently being changed to allow for it” option for the survey in 2017.
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
Conclusion
Most central banks are conducting research into CBDC. Many are progressing from
conceptual work into experimentation and proofs-of-concept, including in
cooperation with other central banks. Nonetheless, motivations for issuing a CBDC
are largely idiosyncratic (eg falling availability of cash in a jurisdiction). This has meant
that only a limited number of central banks are proceeding to the pilot stage with
CBDCs, and even fewer see issuance of a CBDC as likely in the short or medium term.
At this stage, most central banks appear to have clarified the challenges of
launching a CBDC but they are not yet convinced that the benefits will outweigh the
costs. Those that do see clear benefits are predominantly from EME jurisdictions.
From survey responses, this seems to be because financial inclusion projects create a
clear mandate for central bank action, and a lack of current infrastructure limits the
disruption a CBDC could create while simultaneously encouraging the use of new
technology.
The trends identified in the survey are likely to continue. Different central banks
will continue to move at different speeds. This creates a potential risk for spillover
effects across borders (CPMI-MC (2018)). However, the evidence from this survey is
that central banks are proceeding cautiously, and also that they are collaborating and
12
BIS Papers No 101
sharing the results of their work. Caution and collaboration will reduce the likelihood
of unintended consequences.
To meet the payment needs of the future, physical cash is unlikely to be the main
answer. Yet, most people will have to wait to use a CBDC. However, central banks are
working hard to make sure the wait is worth it.
BIS Papers No 101
13
Box B
Cryptocurrencies and other private digital tokens
As well as questions on CBDC, the survey asked central banks about private digital tokens, encompassing the wide
variety of digital tokens not issued by central banks. Decentralised digital tokens without an issuer that are not
representative of any underlying asset or a liability are referred to as “cryptocurrencies”. The survey included questions
on the use of cryptocurrencies for domestic and cross-border payments, their judgement on whether that use would
rise or fall and the state of experimentation with other digital tokens by the private sector in their jurisdictions.
Cryptocurrencies
No central banks reported any significant or wider public use of cryptocurrencies for either domestic or cross-border
payments in their jurisdictions (Graph E). Usage of cryptocurrencies is assessed to be either minimal (“trivial / no use”)
or concentrated in niche groups for a large majority of the responding central banks. Answers were largely based on
judgment, informed by industry, market and research sources although a few transaction monitoring programmes are
reportedly in place. This is consistent with other research looking at payments made with cryptocurrencies (Graph G,
right-hand panel), (Auer (2019)).
Current use of cryptocurrencies for payments1
Share of respondents
Domestic
1
Graph E
Cross-border
There were no responses for the options “Significant use” and “Wider public use”.
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
Judgments about future usage are, unsurprisingly, difficult to make. Most central banks have not formed a firm
view, especially in the case of cross-border payments (Graph F). Of those that could, the majority think use in payments
will remain minor. Reasons for this judgment include low retail acceptance, compliance issues, better public
understanding by the general public of the risks involved and, for some jurisdictions, outright bans. This is in line with
other research that suggests the values and volumes of cryptocurrencies are influenced by regulators’ actions (Auer
and Claessens (2018)).
Some central banks reported that both the current and prospective use of cryptocurrencies seemed contained
to such assets being used for investment purposes.
14
BIS Papers No 101
Anticipated use of cryptocurrencies for payments
Share of respondents
Graph F
Domestic
Cross-border
Source: Central bank survey on CBDCs.
Other private digital tokens
A great deal of attention has been paid to the distributed ledger technology (DLT) underlying cryptocurrencies, with
almost a quarter of respondents reporting that banks or non-banks are experimenting with or issuing private digital
tokens as part of their payment services (Graph G, left-hand panel). The reported experiments are concentrated in
advanced economies and remittance-receiving EMEs in Asia and are mostly at early stages. Projects reportedly focus
on cross-border payments, consistent with domestic faster payments being available in the relevant jurisdictions.
Some central banks note that initiatives are often akin to more traditional arrangements (eg e-money or
correspondent banking) and may blur boundaries or give rise to definitional issues
Are banks or non-banks experimenting with or issuing private digital tokens as
part of their payment services?
2018 Survey
Graph G
Bitcoin payment transactions
Per cent
USD mn per month
Sources: Auer (2019); Central bank survey on CBDCs.
BIS Papers No 101
15
References
Auer, R (2019): “The mechanics of decentralised trust in Bitcoin and the block chain”,
BIS Working Papers, forthcoming.
Auer, R and S Claessens (2018): “Regulating cryptocurrencies: assessing market
reactions”, BIS Quarterly Review, September, pp 51–65.
Bank of Canada (2018): Jasper phase 3 – securities settlement using distributed ledger
technology, October.
Bank of Canada, Bank of England and Monetary Authority of Singapore (2018): Crossborder interbank payments and settlements – emerging opportunities for digital
transformation, November.
Bech, M, Y Shimizu and P Wong (2017): “The quest for speed in payments”, BIS
Quarterly Review, March, pp 57–68.
Bech, M, and R Garratt (2017): “Central bank cryptocurrencies”, BIS Quarterly Review,
September, pp 55–70.
Bech, M, U Faruqui, F Ougaard and C Picillo (2018): “Payments are a-changin’ – but
cash still rules”, BIS Quarterly Review, March, pp 67–80.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (2015): Digital currencies,
November.
——— (2017): Distributed ledger technology in payment, clearing and settlement: an
analytical framework, February.
——— (2018): Cross-border retail payments, February.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures and Markets Committee (2018):
Central bank digital currencies, March.
European Central Bank and Bank of Japan (2018): Securities settlement systems:
delivery-versus-payment in a distributed ledger environment, March.
Financial Stability Board (2018): Crypto-asset markets, October.
G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors Meetings (2018): Communiqué,
March.
Green, E, (2008): “Some challenges for research in payment systems” in A Haldane, S
Millard and V Saporta (eds), The Future of Payment Systems, Routledge.
Jakobsen, M (2018): “Payments are a-changin' but traditional means are still here”,
Commentary on the CPMI “Red Book” statistics, December.
Kahn, C and W Roberds (2009): “Why pay? An introduction to payments economics”,
Journal of Financial Intermediation, vol 18, no 3, January, pp 1–23.
Monetary Authority of Singapore (2017): Project Ubin phase 2 – re-imagining
interbank real-time gross settlement system using distributed ledger technologies,
November.
Norges Bank (2018): Central bank digital currencies, Norges Bank Papers, no 1 2018,
May.
South African Reserve Bank (2018): Project Khokha – Exploring the use of distributed
ledger technology for interbank payments settlement in South Africa, June.
Sveriges Riksbank (2018): The Riksbank’s e-krona project – Report 2, October.
16
BIS Papers No 101
Annex 1: Central banks participating in the survey
Some 63 central banks participated in the survey from the following jurisdictions:
-
Argentina
Australia
Azerbaijan
Bangladesh
Belgium
Brazil
Cambodia
Canada
Cape Verde
Cayman Islands
China
Colombia
Curaçao & Sint
Maarten
Cyprus
Dominican
Republic
Ecuador
Egypt
Euro area (ECB)
France
Georgia
Germany
BIS Papers No 101
-
Hong Kong SAR
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iraq
Israel
Italy
Jamaica
Japan
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Korea
Kosovo
Latvia
Malaysia
Montenegro
Morocco
Netherlands
Nigeria
Norway
Pakistan
Papua New
Guinea
-
Philippines
Russia
Samoa
Saudi Arabia
Serbia
Singapore
Slovenia
Solomon
Islands
South Africa
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Thailand
Tonga
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Uruguay
Vietnam
Zambia
17
Annex 2: Survey questions
1. Has your central bank engaged, or will engage, in any kind of research, experiments
or development work related to the development and use of CBDC? [Yes / No]
2. Is your work related to:
-
wholesale CBDC:
general purpose CBDC
both
3. What type of work is being, or will be, conducted? Please check all that apply.
-
research/ study
experiments / proof-of-concept
Development / pilot arrangement
4. How important are the following aspects to your motivations in issuing a:
-
General purpose CBDC
Wholesale CBDC
The following aspects were proposed:
o
o
o
o
o
o
o
financial stability
monetary policy implementation
financial inclusion
payments efficiency (domestic)
payments efficiency (cross-border)
payments safety / robustness
others (please specify below)
For each: very important / important / somewhat important / not so important
5. How likely is it that your central bank will issue a CBDC in the:
-
General purpose CBDC
Wholesale CBDC
For both, two time horizons were proposed:
o short term (within the next three years)
o medium term (four to six years)
For each: very likely / somewhat likely / possible / somewhat unlikely / very unlikely
6. Does your central bank have the legal authority to issue a CBDC?
-
Yes / no / uncertain / laws are currently being changed to allow for it
7. Please provide any other details about CBDC and the thoughts and work in your
jurisdiction, including your key motivations.
8. For your jurisdiction, please tick "True" or "False" for the following statements:
-
18
Domestically:
o There is a real-time-gross-settlement system (RTGS) available
o The RTGS system settles more than one currency
o There is a faster payment system used for domestic retail payments
o There is broad participation by eligible financial institutions in the faster
payments system
o There is a legal framework for e-money
BIS Papers No 101
-
o Non-banks are active in issuing e-money
cross-border:
o Payment mechanisms for cross-border e-commerce are widely available
o There are exchange or capital controls that apply to cross-border retail
payments
9. In your jurisdiction, how significant do you think consumer use of cryptocurrencies
or crypto-assets for payments is?
-
For domestic payments
For cross-border payments
For each, the following options were proposed:
o
o
o
o
o
Significant use
Wider public use
Use by niche groups
Trivial / no use
Do not know
10. In your jurisdiction, do you think consumer use of cryptocurrencies or cryptoassets for payments is increasing or decreasing?
-
For domestic payments
For cross-border payments
For each, the following options were proposed:
o
o
o
o
increasing
staying the same
decreasing
Do not know
11. In your jurisdiction, are banks or non-banks experimenting or issuing private
digital tokens as part of their payment services? [Yes / no / don’t know]
BIS Papers No 101
19
Previous volumes in this series
No
Title
Issue date
BIS Papers No 100
Globalisation and deglobalisation
December 2018
BIS Papers No 99
Central banks and debt: emerging risks
to the effectiveness of monetary policy
in Africa?
October 2018
BIS Papers No 98
Low for long or turning point?
July 2018
BIS Papers No 97
Financial spillovers, spillbacks, and the
scope for international macroprudential
policy coordination
April 2018
BIS Papers No 96
The price, real and financial effects of
exchange rates
March 2018
BIS Papers No 95
Frontiers of macrofinancial linkages
January 2018
BIS Papers No 94
Macroprudential frameworks,
implementation and relationship with
other policies
December 2017
BIS Papers No 93
Building Resilience to Global Risks:
Challenges for African Central Banks
August 2017
BIS Papers No 92
Long-term issues for central banks
August 2017
BIS Papers No 91
Financial systems and the real economy
March 2017
BIS Papers No 90
Foreign exchange liquidity in the
Americas
March 2017
BIS Papers No 89
Inflation mechanisms, expectations and
monetary policy
November 2016
BIS Papers No 88
Expanding the boundaries of monetary
policy in Asia and the Pacific
October 2016
BIS Papers No 87
Challenges of low commodity prices for
Africa
September 2016
BIS Papers No 86
Macroprudential policy
September 2016
BIS Papers No 85
A spare tire for capital markets:
fostering corporate bond markets in
Asia
June 2016
BIS Papers No 84
Towards a “new normal” in financial
markets?
May 2016
BIS Papers No 83
What do new forms of finance mean for
EM central banks?
November 2015
BIS Papers No 82
Cross-border financial linkages:
challenges for monetary policy and
financial stability
October 2015
BIS Papers No 81
Currency carry trades in Latin America
April 2015
All volumes are available on the BIS website (www.bis.org).
20
BIS Papers No 101