Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Power law tails in the Italian personal income distribution

Physica A-statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, 2005
...Read more
Power Law Tails in the Italian Personal Income Distribution * F. Clementi a,c , M. Gallegati b,c a Department of Public Economics, University of Rome “La Sapienza”, Via del Castro Laurenziano 9, 00161 Rome, Italy. E-mail address: fabio.clementi@uniroma1.it. b Department of Economics, Universit`a Politecnica delle Marche, Piazzale Martelli 8, 60121 Ancona, Italy. E-mail address: gallegati@dea.unian.it. c S.I.E.C., Universit`a Politecnica delle Marche, Piazzale Martelli 8, 60121 Ancona, Italy. Web address: http://www.dea.unian.it/wehia/. May 11, 2005 Abstract We investigate the shape of the Italian personal income distribution using microdata from the Survey on Household Income and Wealth, made publicly available by the Bank of Italy for the years 1977–2002. We find that the upper tail of the distribution is consistent with a Pareto power-law type distribution, while the rest follows a two-parameter lognormal distribution. The results of our analysis show a shift of the distribution and a change of the indexes specifying it over time. As regards the first issue, we test the hypothesis that the evolution of both gross domestic product and personal income is governed by similar mechanisms, pointing to the existence of correlation between these quantities. The fluctuations of the shape of income distribution are instead quantified by establishing some links with the business cycle phases experienced by the Italian economy over the years covered by our dataset. Keywords: Personal income; Pareto law; Lognormal distribution; Income growth rate; Business cycle JEL Classifications: C16; D31; E32 1 Introduction. In the last decades, extensive lit- erature has shown that the size of a large number of phenomena can be well described by a power-law type distribution. The modeling of income distribution originated more than a century ago with the work of Vilfredo Pareto, who observed in his Cours d’ ´ Economie Poli- tique (1897) that a plot of the logarithm of the num- ber of income-receiving units above a certain thresh- * Paper prepared for the International Conference in Memory of Two Eminent Social Scientists: C. Gini and M.O. Lorenz. Their Impact in the XX th Century De- velopment of Probability, Statistics and Economics, to be held Siena (Italy) on May 23–26, 2005. The authors would like to thank Corrado Di Guilmi and Yoshi Fujiwara for helpful comments and suggestions. old against the logarithm of the income yields points close to a straight line. This power-law behaviour is nowadays known as Pareto law. Recent empirical work seems to confirm the valid- ity of Pareto (power) law. For example, [1] show that the distribution of income and income tax of individ- uals in Japan for the year 1998 is very well fitted by a power-law, even if it gradually deviates as the in- come approaches lower ranges. The applicability of Pareto distribution only to high incomes is actually acknowledged; therefore, other kinds of distributions has been proposed by researchers for the low-middle income region. According to [2], US personal income data for the years 1935–36 suggest a power-law dis- tribution for the high-income range and a lognormal
F. Clementi, M. Gallegati 2 distribution for the rest; a similar shape is found by [3] investigating the Japanese income and income tax data for the high-income range over the 112 years 1887–1998, and for the middle-income range over the 44 years 1955–98. 1 Reference [4] confirms the power- law decay for top taxpayers in the US and Japan from 1960 to 1999, but find that the middle portion of the income distribution has rather an exponential form; the same is proposed by [5] for the UK during the period 1994–99 and for the US in 1998. The aim of this paper is to look at the shape of the personal income distribution in Italy by using cross- sectional data samples from the population of Italian households during the years 1977–2002. We find that the personal income distribution follows the Pareto law in the high-income range, while the lognormal pattern is more appropriate in the central body of the distribution. From this analysis we get the result that the indexes specifying the distribution change in time; therefore, we try to look for some factors which might be the potential reasons for this behaviour. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Sec- tion 2 reports the data utilized in the analysis and describes the shape of the Italian personal income distribution. Section 3 explains the shift of the dis- tribution and the change of the indexes specifying it over the years covered by our dataset. Section 4 con- cludes the paper. 2 Lognormal Pattern with Power Law Tail. We use microdata from the Historical Archive (HA) of the Survey on Household Income and Wealth (SHIW) made publicly available by the Bank of Italy for the period 1977–2002 [7]. 2 All amounts are ex- pressed in thousands of lire. Since we are comparing incomes across years, to get rid of inflation data are 1 Reference [6] suggests that a Pareto law may hold also for lower incomes, yielding a so-called double Pareto-lognormal distribution, that is a distribution with a lognormal body and a double Pareto tail. 2 The data for the years preceding 1977 are no longer avail- able. The survey was carried out yearly until 1987 (except for 1985) and every two years thereafter (the survey for 1997 was shifted to 1998). In 1989 a panel section consisting of units already interviewed in the previous survey was introduced in order to allow for better comparison over time. The basic def- inition of income provided by the SHIW is net of taxation and social security contributions. It is the sum of four main compo- nents: compensation of employees; pensions and net transfers; net income from self-employment; property income (including income from buildings and income from financial assets). In- come from financial assets started to be recorded only in 1987. See [8] for details on source description, data quality, and main changes in the sample design and income definition. -4 -2 0 2 Cumulative probability 1 2 3 4 5 Income (thousand £) Income data Lognormal Power law Fig. 1: The cumulative probability distribution of the Italian personal income in 1998. We take the horizontal axis as the logarithm of the personal in- come in thousands of lire and the vertical axis as the logarithm of the cumulative probability. The green solid line is the lognormal fit with ˆ μ =3.48 (0.004) and ˆ σ =0.34 (0.006). Gibrat index is ˆ β =2.10. reported in 1976 prices using the Consumer Prices Index (CPI) issued by the National Institute of Sta- tistics [9]. The average number of income-earners sur- veyed from the SHIW-HA is about 10,000. Figure 1 shows the profile of the personal income distribution for the year 1998. We take the horizon- tal axis as the logarithm of the income in thousands of lire and the vertical axis as the logarithm of the cumulative probability. The cumulative probability is the probability to find a person with an income greater than or equal to x: P (X x)= x p(t)dt Two facts emerge from this figure. Firstly, the cen- tral body of the distribution (almost all of it below the 99 th percentile) follows a two-parameter lognor- mal distribution (green solid line). The probability density function is: p (x)= 1 2π exp - 1 2 logx - μ σ 2 with 0 <x< , and where μ and σ are the mean and the standard deviation of the normal distribu- tion. The value of the fraction β =1/ ( σ 2 ) returns the so-called Gibrat index; if β has low values (large
Power Law Tails in the Italian Personal Income Distribution∗ F. Clementia,c , M. Gallegatib,c a Department of Public Economics, University of Rome “La Sapienza”, Via del Castro Laurenziano 9, 00161 Rome, Italy. E-mail address: fabio.clementi@uniroma1.it. b Department of Economics, Università Politecnica delle Marche, Piazzale Martelli 8, 60121 Ancona, Italy. E-mail address: gallegati@dea.unian.it. c S.I.E.C., Università Politecnica delle Marche, Piazzale Martelli 8, 60121 Ancona, Italy. Web address: http://www.dea.unian.it/wehia/. May 11, 2005 Abstract We investigate the shape of the Italian personal income distribution using microdata from the Survey on Household Income and Wealth, made publicly available by the Bank of Italy for the years 1977–2002. We find that the upper tail of the distribution is consistent with a Pareto power-law type distribution, while the rest follows a two-parameter lognormal distribution. The results of our analysis show a shift of the distribution and a change of the indexes specifying it over time. As regards the first issue, we test the hypothesis that the evolution of both gross domestic product and personal income is governed by similar mechanisms, pointing to the existence of correlation between these quantities. The fluctuations of the shape of income distribution are instead quantified by establishing some links with the business cycle phases experienced by the Italian economy over the years covered by our dataset. Keywords: Personal income; Pareto law; Lognormal distribution; Income growth rate; Business cycle JEL Classifications: C16; D31; E32 Introduction. In the last decades, extensive lit1 erature has shown that the size of a large number of phenomena can be well described by a power-law type distribution. The modeling of income distribution originated more than a century ago with the work of Vilfredo Pareto, who observed in his Cours d’Économie Politique (1897) that a plot of the logarithm of the number of income-receiving units above a certain thresh∗ Paper prepared for the International Conference in Memory of Two Eminent Social Scientists: C. Gini and M.O. Lorenz. Their Impact in the XXth Century Development of Probability, Statistics and Economics, to be held Siena (Italy) on May 23–26, 2005. The authors would like to thank Corrado Di Guilmi and Yoshi Fujiwara for helpful comments and suggestions. old against the logarithm of the income yields points close to a straight line. This power-law behaviour is nowadays known as Pareto law. Recent empirical work seems to confirm the validity of Pareto (power) law. For example, [1] show that the distribution of income and income tax of individuals in Japan for the year 1998 is very well fitted by a power-law, even if it gradually deviates as the income approaches lower ranges. The applicability of Pareto distribution only to high incomes is actually acknowledged; therefore, other kinds of distributions has been proposed by researchers for the low-middle income region. According to [2], US personal income data for the years 1935–36 suggest a power-law distribution for the high-income range and a lognormal 2 Lognormal Pattern with Power Law Tail. 2 We use microdata from the Historical Archive (HA) of the Survey on Household Income and Wealth (SHIW) made publicly available by the Bank of Italy for the period 1977–2002 [7].2 All amounts are expressed in thousands of lire. Since we are comparing incomes across years, to get rid of inflation data are 1 Reference [6] suggests that a Pareto law may hold also for lower incomes, yielding a so-called double Pareto-lognormal distribution, that is a distribution with a lognormal body and a double Pareto tail. 2 The data for the years preceding 1977 are no longer available. The survey was carried out yearly until 1987 (except for 1985) and every two years thereafter (the survey for 1997 was shifted to 1998). In 1989 a panel section consisting of units already interviewed in the previous survey was introduced in order to allow for better comparison over time. The basic definition of income provided by the SHIW is net of taxation and social security contributions. It is the sum of four main components: compensation of employees; pensions and net transfers; net income from self-employment; property income (including income from buildings and income from financial assets). Income from financial assets started to be recorded only in 1987. See [8] for details on source description, data quality, and main changes in the sample design and income definition. Cumulative probability −2 0 Income data Lognormal Power law −4 distribution for the rest; a similar shape is found by [3] investigating the Japanese income and income tax data for the high-income range over the 112 years 1887–1998, and for the middle-income range over the 44 years 1955–98.1 Reference [4] confirms the powerlaw decay for top taxpayers in the US and Japan from 1960 to 1999, but find that the middle portion of the income distribution has rather an exponential form; the same is proposed by [5] for the UK during the period 1994–99 and for the US in 1998. The aim of this paper is to look at the shape of the personal income distribution in Italy by using crosssectional data samples from the population of Italian households during the years 1977–2002. We find that the personal income distribution follows the Pareto law in the high-income range, while the lognormal pattern is more appropriate in the central body of the distribution. From this analysis we get the result that the indexes specifying the distribution change in time; therefore, we try to look for some factors which might be the potential reasons for this behaviour. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reports the data utilized in the analysis and describes the shape of the Italian personal income distribution. Section 3 explains the shift of the distribution and the change of the indexes specifying it over the years covered by our dataset. Section 4 concludes the paper. 2 F. Clementi, M. Gallegati 1 2 3 Income (thousand £) 4 5 Fig. 1: The cumulative probability distribution of the Italian personal income in 1998. We take the horizontal axis as the logarithm of the personal income in thousands of lire and the vertical axis as the logarithm of the cumulative probability. The green solid line is the lognormal fit with µ̂ = 3.48 (0.004) and σ̂ = 0.34 (0.006). Gibrat index is β̂ = 2.10. reported in 1976 prices using the Consumer Prices Index (CPI) issued by the National Institute of Statistics [9]. The average number of income-earners surveyed from the SHIW-HA is about 10,000. Figure 1 shows the profile of the personal income distribution for the year 1998. We take the horizontal axis as the logarithm of the income in thousands of lire and the vertical axis as the logarithm of the cumulative probability. The cumulative probability is the probability to find a person with an income greater than or equal to x: P (X ≥ x) = Z∞ p(t)dt x Two facts emerge from this figure. Firstly, the central body of the distribution (almost all of it below the 99th percentile) follows a two-parameter lognormal distribution (green solid line). The probability density function is: "  2 # 1 1 logx − µ √ exp − p (x) = 2 σ xσ 2π with 0 < x < ∞, and where µ and σ are the mean and the standard deviation of the normal √ distribution. The value of the fraction β = 1/ σ 2 returns the so-called Gibrat index; if β has low values (large 3 −2 Cumulative probability −1 0 Cumulative probability −1 0 1 1 2 Power Law Tails in the Italian Personal Income Distribution 3.5 −2 Income data Power law 1977/78/79 1980/81/82/83/84/86/87/89 1991/93/95/98 2000/02 4 4.5 Income (thousand £) 5 Fig. 2: The fit to the power-law distribution for the year 1998. The red solid line is the best-fit function. Pareto index, obtained by least-square-fit, is α̂ = 2.76 (0.002); the estimated minimum income is x̂0 = 17, 141 thousand lire. The goodness of fit of OLS estimate in terms of R2 index is 0.9993. variance of the global distribution), the personal income is unevenly distributed. From our dataset we obtain the following maximum-likelihood estimates:3 µ̂ = 3.48 (0.004) and σ̂ = 0.34 (0.006);4 Gibrat index is β̂ = 2.10. Secondly, about the top 1% of the distribution follows a Pareto (power-law) distribution. This power-law behaviour of the tail of the distribution is more evident from Fig. 2, where the red solid line is the best-fit linear function. We extract the power-law slope (Pareto index) by running a simple OLS regression of the logarithm of the cumulative probability on a constant and the logarithm of personal income, obtaining a point estimate of α̂ = 2.76 (0.002). Given this value for α̂, our estimate of x0 (the income level below which the Pareto distribution would not apply) is 17,141 thousand lire. The fit of linear regression is extremely good, as one can appreciate by noting that the value of R2 index is 0.9993. The distribution pattern of the personal income expressed as the lognormal with power-law tails seems to hold all over our time span, as one can easily recognize from Fig. 3, which shows the shape of income distribution for all the years. The corresponding esti3 We exclude from our estimates about the top 1.4% of the distribution, which behaves as outlier, and about the bottom 0.8%, which corresponds to non positive entries. 4 The number in parentheses following a point estimate represents its standard error. 2.4 3 4 Income (thousand £) 5 Fig. 3: Time development of the Italian personal income distribution over the years 1977–2002. mated parameters for the lognormal and Pareto distributions are given in Table 1. The table also shows the values of Gibrat index and the OLS R2 . However, the power-law slope and the curvature of the lognormal fit differ from each other. This fact means that the indexes specifying the distribution (Pareto and Gibrat indexes) differs from year to year. We therefore try to quantify the fluctuations of the shape of income distribution in the next section. Time Development of the Distribution. We 3 start by considering the change of the distribution over time. As Fig. 3 shows, the distribution shifts over the years covered by our dataset. Macroeconomics argues that the origin of the change consists in the growth of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP). To confirm this hypothesis we study the fluctuations in the growth rates of GDP and Personal Income (PI), and try to show that similar mechanisms may be responsible for the observed growth dynamics of both country and individuals. The distribution of GDP annual growth rates is shown in Fig. 4. We calculate it using the data from the OECD Statistical Compendium [10], and expressing the rates in terms of their logarithm, RGDP ≡ log (GDPt+1 /GDPt ), where GDPt and GDPt+1 are the GDP of the country at the years t and t + 1 respectively. Data are reported in 1976 prices; moreover, to improve comparison of the values over the years we detrend them by applying the Hodrick-Prescott filter. By means of a non-linear algorithm, we find that the probability density function of annual growth rates is well fitted by a Laplace distribution (the red solid line in the 4 F. Clementi, M. Gallegati Table 1: Estimated lognormal and Pareto distribution parameters for all the years (standard errors are in parentheses). Calculations are conducted using data and methods described in the text. For the lognormal distribution and the Pareto distribution also shown are the values of Gibrat index and R2 index respectively. 3.31 3.33 3.34 3.36 3.36 3.38 3.38 3.39 3.40 3.49 3.53 3.52 3.47 3.46 3.48 3.50 3.52 µ̂ (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) 1 Year 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1986 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1998 2000 2002 0.34 0.34 0.34 0.33 0.32 0.31 0.30 0.32 0.29 0.30 0.26 0.27 0.33 0.32 0.34 0.32 0.31 σ̂ (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005) 0 .2 Probability density .4 .6 .8 GDP data (1977−2002) Laplace fit −.04 −.02 0 Growth rate .02 .04 Fig. 4: Probability density function of Italian GDP annual growth rates for the period 1977–2002 together with the Laplace fit (red solid line). The data have been detrended by applying the HodrickPrescott filter. figure), which is expressed as:   1 |x − µ| p (x) = √ exp − σ σ 2 with −∞ < x < +∞, and where µ and σ are the β̂ 2.08 2.09 2.08 2.15 2.23 2.27 2.32 2.24 2.40 2.38 2.70 2.58 2.15 2.19 2.10 2.20 2.25 3.00 3.01 2.91 3.06 3.30 3.08 3.11 3.05 3.04 2.09 2.91 3.45 2.74 2.72 2.76 2.76 2.71 α̂ (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.008) (0.005) (0.006) (0.007) (0.005) (0.002) (0.002) (0.008) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) x̂0 10,876 11,217 11,740 11,453 10,284 11,456 11,147 11,596 11,597 24,120 15,788 14,281 16,625 16,587 17,141 17,470 17,664 R2 0.9921 0.9933 0.9908 0.9915 0.9939 0.9952 0.9945 0.9937 0.9950 0.9993 0.9995 0.9988 0.9997 0.9996 0.9993 0.9994 0.9997 mean value and the standard deviation. This result seems to be in agreement with the growth dynamics of PI, as shown in Fig. 5 for two randomly selected distributions. We calculate them using the panel section of the SHIW-HA, which covers the period 1987– 2002. As one can easily recognize, the same functional form describing the probability distribution of GDP annual growth rates is also valid in the case of PI growth rates. These findings lead us to check the possibility that the growth rates of both GDP and PI are drawn from the same distribution. To this end, we perform a two-sample Kolmogorov-Smirnov test and check the null hypothesis that both GDP and PI growth rate data are samples from the same distribution. Before applying this test, to consider almost the same number of data points relating to units with different sizes we draw a 2% random samples of the data we have for individuals, and normalize them together with the data for GDP annual  growth rate using the transformations RPI − RPI /σPI and  RGDP − RGDP /σGDP . As shown in Table 2, which reports the p-values for all the cases we studied, the null hypothesis of equality of the two distributions can not be rejected at the usual 5% marginal significance level. Therefore, the data are consistent with the assumption that a common empirical law 5 Power Law Tails in the Italian Personal Income Distribution Table 2: Estimated Kolmogorov-Smirnov test p-values for both GDP and PI growth rate data. The null hypothesis that the two distributions are the same at the 5% marginal significance level is not rejected in all the cases. Growth rate RGDP R89/87 R91/89 R93/91 R95/93 R98/95 R00/98 R89/87 0.872 R91/89 0.919 0.998 R93/91 0.998 0.984 0.970 might describe the growth dynamics of both GDP and PI, as shown in Fig. 6, where all the curves for both GDP and PI growth rate normalized data almost collapse onto the red solid line representing the non-linear Laplace fit.5 We next turn on the fluctuations of the indexes specifying the income distribution, i.e. the Pareto and Gibrat indexes, whose yearly estimates are reported in Fig. 7. Figure 7(a) shows the fluctuations of Pareto index over the years 1977–2002. The black connected solid line is the time series obtained by excluding income from financial assets, while the red connected solid line refers to the yearly estimates obtained by the inclusion of the above-stated income, which was regularly recorded only since 1987 (see note 2). The course of the two series is similar, with the more complete definition of income showing a greater inequality because of the strongly concentrated distribution of returns on capital. The same can be said for the time series of Gibrat index (Fig. 7(b)). Although the frequency of data (initially annual and then biennial from 1987) makes it difficult to establish a link with the business cycle, it seems possible to find a (negative) relationship between the above-stated indexes and the fluctuations of economic activity. For example, Italy experienced a period of economic growth until the late 1980s, but with alternating phases of the internal business cycle: of slowdown of production up to the 1983 stagnation; of recovery in 1984; again of slowdown in 1986. As one can recognize from the figure, the values of Pareto and Gibrat indexes, inferred from the numerical fitting, tend to decrease in the periods of economic expansion (concentration goes up) and increase during the 5 See [11] for similar findings about GDP and company growth rates. R95/93 0.696 0.431 0.979 0.839 R98/95 0.337 0.689 0.995 0.459 0.172 R00/98 0.480 0.860 0.994 0.750 0.459 0.703 R02/00 0.955 0.840 0.997 1.000 0.560 0.378 0.658 recessions (income is more evenly distributed). The time pattern of inequality is shown in Fig. 8, which reports the temporal change of Gini coefficient for the considered years.6 In Italy the level of inequality decreased significantly during the 1980s and rised in the early 1990s; it was substantially stable in the following years. In particular, a sharp rise of Gini coefficient (i.e., of inequality) is encountered in 1987 and 1993, corresponding to a sharp decline of Pareto index in the former case and of both Pareto and Gibrat indexes in the latter case. We consider that the decline of Pareto exponent in 1987 corresponds with the peak of the speculative “bubble” begun in the early 1980s, and the rebounce of the index follows its burst on October 19, when the Dow Jones index lost more than 20% of its value dragging into disaster the other world markets. This assumption seems confirmed by the movement of asset price in the Italian Stock Exchange (see Fig. 9(a)).7 As regards the sharp decline of both indexes in 1993, the level and growth of personal income (especially in the middle-upper income range) were notably influenced by the bad results of the real economy in that year, following the September 1992 lira exchange rate crisis. The effects of recession (visible in Fig. 9(b)) produced a leftwards shift of the distribution and widened its range; this, combined with a concentration of individuals towards middle income range, induced an increase in inequality.8 It 6 Unlike the Pareto and Gibrat indexes, which provide two different measures corresponding to the tail and the rest, the Gini coefficient is a measure of (in)equality of the income for the overall distribution taking values from zero (completely equal) to one (completely inequal). 7 See [3] for a study of the correlation between Pareto index and asset price in Japan. 8 In particular, in this year there was a significant reduction of the number of self-employees, whose incomes are much more dependent from the business cycle. See [12] for further details 6 1 1 F. Clementi, M. Gallegati GDP (1977−2002) PI (1989/1987) PI (1991/1989) PI (1993/1991) PI (1995/1993) PI (1998/1995) PI (2000/1998) PI (2002/2000) Laplace fit 0 0 .2 .2 Probability density .4 .6 Probability density .4 .6 .8 .8 PI data (1989/1987) Laplace fit −4 0 Growth rate 1 2 −2 0 Growth rate 2 4 .8 −1 Fig. 6: Probability distribution of Italian GDP and PI growth rates. All data collapse onto a single curve representing the fit to the Laplace distribution (red solid line), showing that the distributions are well described by the same functional form. Probability density .4 .6 −2 Concluding Remarks. In this paper we find 4 that the Italian personal income microdata are consistent with a Pareto (power-law) behaviour in the 1 (a) 0 .2 PI data (1993/1991) Laplace fit −2 −1 0 Growth rate 1 2 (b) Fig. 5: Probability distribution of Italian PI growth rates RPI ≡ log (P It+i /P It ) for the years 1989/1987 (a) and 1993/1991 (b). The red solid line is the fit to the Laplace distribution. The data are taken from the panel section of the SHIW-HA, which covers the years 1987–2002. would be expected that these facts cause the invalidity of Pareto law for high incomes. This was well the case of Italian economy during the mentioned years. Fig. 10 shows the power-law region in 1987 and 1993. Compared to other years, one can observe that the data can not be fitted by the Pareto law in the entire range of high-income. on this issue. high-income range, and with a two-parameter lognormal pattern in the low-middle income region. The numerical fitting over the time span covered by our dataset show a shift of the distribution, which is claimed to be a consequence of the growth of the country. This assumption is confirmed by testing the hypothesis that the growth dynamics of both gross domestic product of the country and personal income of individuals is the same; the two-sample Kolmogorov-Smirnov test we perform on this subject lead us to accept the null hypothesis that the growth rates of both the quantities are samples from the same probability distribution in all the cases we studied, pointing to the existence of correlation between them. Moreover, by calculating the yearly estimates of Pareto and Gibrat indexes, we quantify the fluctuations of the shape of the distribution over time by establishing some links with the business cycle phases which Italian economy experienced over the years of our concern. We find that there exists a negative relationship between the above-stated indexes and the fluctuations of economic activity at least until the late 1980s. In particular, we show that in two circumstances (the 1987 burst of the asset-inflation “bubble” begun in the early 1980s and the 1993 recession year) the data can not be fitted by a power-law in the en- 7 .3 2.5 Pareto index 3 Gini coefficient .32 .34 3.5 .36 Power Law Tails in the Italian Personal Income Distribution Excluding financial assets .28 2 Excluding financial assets Including financial assets Including financial assets 1977 1977 1980 1985 1990 Year 1995 2000 2002 2.8 (a) 2.6 Excluding financial assets 1980 1985 1990 Year 1995 2000 2002 Fig. 8: Gini coefficient for Italian personal income during the period 1977–2002. The black connected solid line excludes income from financial assets, while the red connected solid line includes it. Including financial assets 2.2 Gibrat index 2.4 [2] E.W. Montroll, and M.F. Shlesinger (1983), Maximum Entropy Formalism, Fractals, Scaling Phenomena, and 1/f Noise: A Tale of Tails, Journal of Statistical Physics, 32, 2, 209–230. 2 [3] W. Souma (2001), Universal Structure of the Personal Income Distribution, Fractals, 9, 4, 463–470. 1977 1980 1985 1990 Year 1995 2000 2002 (b) Fig. 7: The temporal change of Pareto index (a) and Gibrat index (b) over the years 1977–2002. The black connected solid line is the time series of the two indexes obtained by excluding income from financial assets, while the red connected solid line refers to the yearly estimates obtained by the inclusion of the above-stated income. tire high-income range, causing breakdown of Pareto law. [4] M. Nirei, and W. Souma (2004), Two Factors Model of Income Distribution Dynamics, SFI Working Paper, http://www.santafe.edu/research/publications/ workingpapers/04-10-029.pdf. [5] A.A. Dragulescu, and V.M. Yakovenko (2001), Exponential and Power-Law Probability Distributions of Wealth and Income in the United Kingdom and the United States, Physica A, 299, 1–2, 213–221. [6] W.J. Reed (2003), The Pareto Law of Incomes – An Explanation and an Extension, Physica A, 319, 469–486. [7] Bank of Italy, Survey on Household Income and Wealth, http://www.bancaditalia.it. References [1] H. Aoyama, Y. Nagahara, M.P. Okazaki, W. Souma, H. Takayasu, and M. Takayasu (2000), Pareto’s Law for Income of Individuals and Debt of Bankrupt Companies, Fractals, 8, 3, 293–300. [8] A. Brandolini (1999), The Distribution of Personal Income in Post-War Italy: Source Description, Data Quality, and the Time Pattern of Income Inequality, Temi di discussione n. 350, Bank of Italy, Rome. 8 Income data Power law −2 −1 −.5 MIB 0 Cumulative probability −1 0 1 2 .5 F. Clementi, M. Gallegati 1977 1980 1985 1990 Year 1995 2000 2002 3.5 4 6 Income data Power law 1 Cumulative probability −1 0 −2 5.8 1980 1985 5 (a) Gross Domestic Product 5.85 5.9 5.95 (a) 1977 4.5 Income (thousand £) 1990 Year 1995 2000 2002 (b) 3.5 4 4.5 Income (thousand £) 5 (b) Fig. 9: Temporal change of Italian Stock Exchange MIB Index (a) and Italian GDP (b) during the period 1977–2002. Shown are the logarithmic values of the variables. The GDP is with the unit of million EUR at 1995 prices. The data source is [10]. [9] National Institute of http://www.istat.it. Statistics, Fig. 10: The power-law region in 1987 (a) and 1993 (b). The red solid line is the fit to the power-law distribution. The Pareto index for 1987 data is α̂ = 2.09 (0.002), while for 1993 data we have α̂ = 2.74 (0.002). These estimates were obtained by least-square-fit excluding about top and bottom 1.2% for 1987 data, and about top 1.4% and bottom 1.3% for 1993 data. OLS R2 values are 0.9993 and 0.9997 respectively. ConIstat, As one can note, a large deviation from Pareto law is seen in both the years. [10] Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD Statistical Compendium, [12] Bank of Italy (1993), Italian Household Budgets ed. 02#2003. in 1993, Supplements to the Statistical Bullettin, n. 44, Rome. [11] Y. Lee, L.A.N. Amaral, D. Canning, M. Meyer, and H.E. Stanley (1998), Universal Features in the Growth Dynamics of Complex Organizations, Physical Review Letters, 81, 15, 3275–3278.
Keep reading this paper — and 50 million others — with a free Academia account
Used by leading Academics
zerife yıldırım
Harran University
Anoop Chaturvedi
University of Allahabad
Murat Atan
Ankara Hacı Bayram Veli University
Selliah Sivarajasingham
University of Peradeniya