Alternative Pathways
of Social Evolution*
Dmitri M. Bondarenko
Center for Civilizational and Regional Studies, Moscow
Leonid E. Grinin
‘Uchitel’ Publishing House, Volgograd
Andrey V. Korotayev
Russian State University for the Humanities, Moscow
It has always been peculiar to evolutionists to compare social
and biological evolution, the latter as visualized by Charles Darwin.1 But it also seems possible and correct to draw an analogy
with another great discovery in the field of evolutionary biology,
with the homologous series of Nikolay Vavilov (1921; 1927;
1967). However, there is no complete identity between cultural parallelism and biological homologous series. Vavilov studied the
morphological homology, whereas our focus within the realm of
social evolution is the functional one. No doubt, the morphological
homomorphism also happens in the process of social evolution
(e.g. in the Hawaii Islands where a type of the sociocultural organization surprisingly similar with the ones of other highly developed parts of Polynesia had independently formed by the end" of
the 18th century [Sahlins 1972/1958; Goldman 1970; Earle 1978]).
But this topic is beyond the present paper’ sproblematique.
What is important for us here is that there are reasons to suppose that an equal level of sociopolitical (and cultural) complexity
(which makes it possible to solve equally difficult problems faced
by societies) can be achieved not only in various forms but on essentially different evolutionary pathways, too. Thus, it is possible
Social Evolution & History, Vol. 1 No. 1, July 2002 54–79
© 2002 ‘Uchitel’ Publishing House
54
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
55
to achieve the same level of system complexity through differing
pathways of evolution which appeared simultaneously (and even
prior to the formation of Homo Sapiens Sapiens [Butovskaya and
Feinberg 1993; Butovskaya 1994; 2000; Butovskaya, Korotayev,
and Kazankov 2000]) and increased in quantity alongside sociocultural advancement (Pavlenko 1996: 229–251; 2000). Diversity could be regarded as one of the most important preconditions
of the evolutionary process. This implies that the transition to any
qualitatively new forms is normally not possible without a sufficient level of variability of sociocultural forms (among both the
given culture’ s predecessors and contemporaries).
Within the first level of analysis, all evolutionary variability can
be reduced to two principally different groups of homologous series (Bondarenko 1997: 12–15; 1998a; 2000; Bondarenko and
Korotayev 1999; 2000b; Korotayev et al. 2000). Earlier these alternatives were distinguished either as ‘hierarchical’ vs. ‘nonhierarchical’ (e.g. Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a), or ‘hierarchical’
vs. ‘heterarchical’ (e.g. Fiirenrdcri, Qurnley, and Levy 1995;
Crumley 2001).
In a recent publication on the problem of heterarchy the latter is defined as ‘... the relation of elements to one another when they are unranked or when they possess the potential for being ranked in a number of different ways’ (Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 3; see
also Crumley 1979: 144). It is clear that the second version of heterarchy is most relevant for the study of the complex societies.
However, when we have a system of elements which ‘possess
the potential for being ranked in a number of different ways’, it
seems impossible to speak about the absence of hierarchy. In this
case we rather deal with a system of heterarchically arranged hierarchies. Hence, it does not appear reasonable to denote the heterarchy alternative as ‘hierarchy’. We would rather suggest to designate it as ‘homoarchy’ which could be defined as ‘...the relation of
elements to one another when they possess the potential for being
ranked in one way only’. Totalitarian regimes of any time give us
plenty of examples of such a sociocultural situation when the ruled
have no chances to get ranked above the rulers in any possible contexts. This stands in a sharp contrast with, say, an archetypal example of a complex heterarchical system – the civil community
(polis) of Athens (the 5Ш–4Ш centuries ВС) where the citizens
ranked lower within one hierarchy (e.g. the military one) could
well be ranked higher in many other possible respects (e.g. eco-
56 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
nomically, or within the subsystem of civil/religious magistrates).
Consequently, it was impossible to say that one citizen was higher
than any other in any absolute sense.
On the other hand, it seems necessary to stress that it appears
impossible to find not only any human cultures totally lacking any
hierarchies (including informal ones), but also any totally homoarchical cultures. Hence, though in order to simplify our analysis in
this paper we speak about heterarchical and homoarchical evolutionary pathways, in fact we are dealing here with heterarchyhomoarchy axis along which one could range all the known human
cultures. Within this range there does not seem to be any distinct
border between homoarchical and heterarchical cultures; hence, in
reality it might be more appropriate to speak not about just two
evolutionary pathways (heterarchical and homoarchical), but about
a potentially infinite number of such pathways, and, thus, finally
not about evolutionary pathways, but rather about evolutionary
probability field (see for detail Korotayev et al. 2000). Yet, as was
mentioned above, in order to simplify our analysis we speak about
just two alternative pathways.
In particular, until recently it was considered self-evident that
just the formation of the state2 marked the end of the ‘Primitive Epoch’ and alternatives to the state did not actually exist. All the stateless
societies were considered pre-state ones, standing on the single evolutionary staircase squarely below the states. Nowadays postulates about
the state as the only possible form of political and sociocultural organization of the post-primitive society, about a-priori higher level of
development of a state society in comparison with any non-state one
do not seem so undeniable as a few years ago. It has become evident
that the non-state societies are not necessarily less complex and less
efficient. The problem of existence of non-state but not primitive (i.e.
principally поп- and not pre-state) societies, alternatives to the state
(as the allegedly inevitable post-primitive form of the sociopolitical
organization) deserves attention.
Of course, in no way do we reject the fact of existence and importance of the states in world history. What we argue, is that the
state is not the only possible post-’ primitive’ evolutionary form.
From our point of view, the state is nothing more than one of many
forms of the post-primitive sociopolitical organization; these forms
are alternative to each other and are able to transform to one another without any loss in the general level of complexity. Hence,
the degree of sociopolitical centralization and ‘homoarchization’ is
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
57
not a perfect criterion for evaluating a society’s evolutionary level,
though it is regarded as such within unilinear concepts of social
evolution.
As Brumfiel wrote several years ago, ‘the coupling of [sociopolitical] differentiation and hierarchy is so firm in our minds that
it takes tremendous intellectual efforts even imagine what differentiation without hierarchy could be’ (Brumfiel 1995: 130).3 Usually, even if the very existence of complex but non-homoarchical
cultures is recognized, they are regarded as a historical fortuity, as
an anomaly. Such cultures are declared as if capable to reach rather
low levels of complexity only, as if incapable to find internal stability (Tuden and Marshall 1972: 454–456).
Thus, on the further level of analysis the dichotomy turns out
not to be rigid at all as far as actual organization of any society
employs both vertical (dominance – subordination) and horizontal
(apprehended as ties among equals) links. Furthermore, in the
course of their history, societies (including archaic cultures) turn
out capable to change models of sociopolitical organization radically, transforming from homoarchical into heterarchical or vice
versa (Crumley 1987: 164–165; 1995: 4; 2001; Bondarenko and
Korotayev 2000c; Dozhdev 2000; Kradin 2000a). Perhaps the most
well known historical example of the latter case is Rome where the
Republic was established and further democratized with the Plebian political victories. Note that in the course of such transformations the organizational background changes, but the overall level
of cultural complexity may not only increase or decrease but may
well stay practically the same (for examples from ancient and medieval history of Europe, the Americas, Asia see, e.g. van der Vliet
1987: Ferguson 1991; Korotayev 1995a; 1996a; Levy 1995; Lynsha 1998; Beliaev 2000; Chamblee 2000: 15–35; Dozhdev 2000;
Kowalewski 2000; Kradin 2000a).
Nevertheless, vertical and horizontal links play different parts in
different societies at every concrete moment. Already among the
primates with the same level of morphological and cognitive development, and even among primate populations belonging to the
same species, one could observe both more and less hierarchically
organized groups. Hence, the non-linearity of sociopolitical evolution appears to originate already before the Homo Sapiens Sapiens
formation (Butovskaya and Feinberg 1993; Butovskaya 1994;
Butovskaya, Korotayev, and Kazankov 2000).
Let us consider now in more detail one of the most influential
and widespread unilineal evolutionary schemes, the one proposed
by Service (1962/1971; its outline is, however, already contained
58 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
in Sahlins 1960: 37): band – tribe – chiefdom – state. The scheme
implies that the growth of the political complexity (at least up to
the stage of the agrarian state) is inevitably accompanied by the
growth of the inequality, stratification, the social distance between
the rulers and the ruled, the ‘authoritarianism’ and hierarchization
of the political system, decrease of the political participation of the
main mass of population etc. Of course, these two sets of parameters seem to be related rather closely. It is evident that we observe
here a certain correlation, and a rather strong one. But, no doubt,
this is just a correlation, and by no means a functional dependence.
Of course, this correlation implies a perfectly possible line of sociopolitical evolution – from an egalitarian, acephalous band,
through a big-man village community with much more pronounced
inequality and political hierarchy, to an ‘authoritarian’ village
community with a strong power of its chief (found e.g. among
some Indians of the North-West Coast – see e.g. Cameiro 2000),
and than through the true chiefdoms having even more pronounced
stratification and concentration of the political power in the hands
of the chief, to the complex chiefdoms where the political inequality parameters reach a qualitatively higher levels, and finally to the
agrarian state where all such parameters reach their culmination
(though one could move even further, up to the level of the ‘empire’ [e.g. Adams 1975]). However, it is very important to stress
that on each level of the growing political complexity one could
find easily evident alternatives to this evolutionary line.
Let us start with the human societies of the simplest level of sociocultural complexity. Indeed, one can easily observe that acephalous egalitarian bands are found among most of the unspe-cialized
hunter-gatherers. However, as has been shown by Wood-burn
(1972; 1979; 1980; 1982; 1988a; 1988b) and Artemova (1987;
1991; 1993; 2000a; 2000b; Chudinova 1981; see also Whyte 1978:
49–94), some of such hunter-gatherers (the inegalitarian ones, first
of all most of the Australian aborigines) display a significantly different type of sociopolitical organization with much more structured political leadership concentrated in the hands of relatively
hierarchically organized elders, with a pronounced degree of inequality both between the men and women, and among the men
themselves.
On the next level of the political complexity we can also find
communities with both homoarchical and heterarchical political
organization. One can mention e.g. the well-known contrast between the Indians of the Califomian North-West and South-East:
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
59
The Califomian chiefs were in the center of economic life, they
exercised their control over the production, distribution and exchange of the social product, and their power and authority were
based mainly on this. Gradually the power of the chiefs and elders
acquired the hereditary character, it became a typical phenomenon
for California... Only the tribes populating the North-West of California, notwithstanding their respectively developed and complex
material culture, lacked the explicitly expressed social roles of the
chiefs characteristic for the rest of California. At the meantime
they new slavery... The population of this region had an idea of
personal wealth... (Kabo 1986: 20).
One can also immediately recall the communities of Ifugao (e.g.
Barton 1922; Meshkov 1982: 183–197) lacking any pronounced
authoritarian political leadership compared with the one of the
communities of the North-West Coast, but with a comparable level
of overall sociopolitical and sociocultural complexity.
Hence, already on the levels of simple and middle range communities we observe several types of alternative sociopolitical
forms, each of which should be denoted with a separate term. The
possible alternatives to the chiefdom in the prehistoric Southwest
Asia, heterarchical systems of complex acephalous communities
with a pronounced autonomy of single family households have
been analyzed recently by Berezkin who suggests reasonably Ара
Tanis as their ethnographic parallel (1995a; 1995b; 2000). Frantsouzoff finds an even more developed example of such type of
polities in ancient South Arabia in Wadi Hadramawt of the 1st millennium ВС (1995; 1997; 2000).
Another evident alternative to the chiefdom is constituted by
the tribal organization. As is well known, the tribe has found itself
on the brink of being evicted from the evolutionary models (Townsend 1985: 146; Carneiro 1987: 760). However, the political forms
entirely identical with what was described by Service as the tribe
could be actually found in e.g. medieval and modern Middle East
(up to the present): these tribal systems normally comprise several
communities and often have precisely the type of political leadership described by Service as typical for the tribe (Service
1971/1962: 103–104; Dresch 1984: 39, 41).
The point is that we are dealing here with some type of polity
that could not be identified either with bands, or with village communities (because such tribes normally comprise more than one
community), or with chiefdoms (because they have an entirely different type of political leadership), or, naturally, with states. They
60 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
could not be inserted easily either in the scheme somewhere between the village and the chiefdom. Indeed, as has been shown
convincingly by Carneiro (see e.g. 1970; 1981; 1987; 1991; 2000),
chiefdoms normally arose as a result of political centralization of a
few communities without the stage of the tribe preceding this. On
the other hand, a considerable amount of evidence could be produced suggesting that in the Middle East many tribes arose as a
result of political decentralization of chiefdoms which preceded the
tribes in time. It is also important to stress that this could not in any
way be identified with a ‘regression’, ‘decline’, or ‘degeneration’,
as we can observe in many of such cases that political decentralization is accompanied by the increase (rather than decrease)
of overall sociocultural complexity (Korotayev 1995a; 1995c;
1995d; 1996a; 1996b; 1996c; 1997; 1998; 2000a; 2000b). Hence,
in many respects tribal systems of the Middle Eastern type appear
to be chiefdom alternatives (rather than chiefdom predecessors).
We have argued elsewhere (Korotayev 1995b) that in general
there is an evident evolutionary alternative to the development of
the rigid supra-communal political structures (chiefdom – complex
chiefdom – state) constituted by the development of internal communal structures together with soft supra-communal systems not
alienating communal sovereignty (various confederations, amphictyonies etc.). One of the most impressive results of the sociopolitical development along this evolutionary line is the Greek poleis (see [Berent 1994; 1996; 2000a; 2000b] regarding the statelessness of this type of political systems) some of which reached
overall levels of complexity quite comparable not only with the
ones of chiefdoms, but also with the one of states. The same can be
said about its Roman analogue, the civitas (Shtaerman 1989). Note
that polis/civitas as a form of sociopolitical organization was
known far beyond the Classical world, both in geographical and
chronological sense (Korotayev 1995b; Bondarenko 1998b),
though quite a number of scholars still insist on its uniqueness.
The ‘tribal’ and ‘polis’ series seem to constitute separate evolutionary lines, with some distinctive features: the ‘polis’ forms
imply the power of the ‘magistrates’ elected in one or another way
for fixed periods and controlled by the people in the absence (or
near-absence) of any formal bureaucracy. Within the tribal systems
we observe the absence of any offices whose holders would be
obeyed simply because they hold posts of a certain type, and the
order is sustained by elaborate mechanisms of mediation and
search for consensus.
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
61
There is also a considerable number of other complex stateless
polities (like the ones of the Cossacks of Ukraine and Southern
Russia till the end of the 17th century [Chirkin 1955; Rozner 1970;
Nikitin 1987; etc.], the Celts of the 5tn-ist centuries ВС [Kradin
2000c: 149], or the Icelandic polity of the ‘Age of Democracy’ till
the middle of the 13th century [Olgeirsson 1957; Gurevich 1972;
Steblin-Kamenskij 1984]) which could not yet be denoted with any
commonly accepted terms, and whose own self-designations are
often too complex (like Kazach ‘e Vojsko) to have any chance to
get transformed into general terms. Such examples can of course
be further multiplied.
And this is not all. There is another evident problem with
Sendee’s scheme. It is evidently pre- ‘Wallersteinian’, not touched
by any world-system discussions, quite confident about the possibility of the use of a single polity as a unit of social evolution. It
might be not so important if Service were speaking about the typology of polities; yet, he speaks about the ‘levels of cultural integration’, and within such a context the world-system dimension
should be evidently taken into consideration4.
The point is that the same overall level of complexity could be
achieved both through the development of a single polity and
through the development of a politically uncentralized interpolity
network. This alternative was already noticed by Wallerstein
(1974; 1979; 1987) who viewed it as a dichotomy: worldeconomy – world-empire. Note that according to Wallerstein these
are considered precisely as alternatives, and not two stages of social evolution. As one would expect, we agree with Wallerstein
whole-heartedly at this point. However, we also find here a certain
oversimplification. In general, we would like to stress that we are
dealing here with a particular case of a much more general set of
evolutionary alternatives.
The development of a politically uncentralized interpolity network
became an effective alternative to the development of a single polity
long before the rise of the first empires. As an example, we could
mention the interpolity communication network of the Mesopotamian
civil-temple communities of the first half of the 3millennium ВС
which sustained a much higher level of technological development
than that of the politically unified Egyptian state, contemporary to it.
Note that the intercommunal communication networks already constitute an effective evolutionary alternative to the chiefdom. E.g. the sociopolitical system of the Ара Tanis should be better described as an
62 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
intercommunal network of a few communities (incidentally, in turn
acting as a core for another wider network including the neighboring
less developed polities [chiefdoms and sovereign communities] – see
Fiihrer-Haimendorf 1962).
We also do not find it productive to describe this alternative
type of cultural integration as a world-economy. The point is that
such a designation tends to downplay the political and cultural dimension of such systems. Take for example, the Classical Greek
inter-polis system. The level of complexity of many Greek poleis
was rather low even in comparison with a complex chiefdom.
However, they were parts of a much larger and much .more complex entity constituted by numerous economic, political and cultural links and shared political and cultural norms. The economic
links no doubt played some role within this system. But links of
other types were not less important. Take, e.g. the norm according
to which the inter-poleis wars stopped during the Olympic Games,
which guaranteed the secure passage of people, and consequently
the circulation of enormous quantities of energy, matter and information within the territory far exceeding the one of an average
complex chiefdom. The existence of the inter-poleis communication network made it possible, say, for a person born in one polis
to go to get his education in another polis and to establish his
school in a third. The existence of this system reduced the destructiveness of inter-poleis warfare for a long time. It was a basis
on which it was possible to undertake important collective actions
(which turned out to be essential at the age of the Greek-Persian
wars). As a result, the polis with a level of complexity lower than
the one of the complex chiefdom, turned out to be part of a system
whose complexity was quite comparable with that of the state (and
not only the early one).
The same can be said about the intersocietal communication
network of Medieval Europe (comparing its complexity in this case
with an average world-empire). Note that in both cases some parts
of the respective systems could be treated as elements of wider
world-economies. On the other hand, not all the parts of such
communication networks were quite integrated economically. This
shows that the world-economies were not the only possible type of
politically decentralized intersocietal networks. Actually, in both
cases we are dealing with the politically decentralized civilization,
which for most of human history over the last few millennia, constituted the most effective alternative to the world-empire. Of
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
63
course, many of such civilizations could be treated as parts of larger world-economies. Wallerstein suggests that in the age of complex societies only the world-economies and world-empires (‘historical systems’, i.e. the largest units of social evolution) could be
treated as units of social evolution in general. Yet we believe that
both politically centralized and decentralized civilizations should
also be treated as such. One should stress again the importance of
the cultural dimension of such systems. Of course, the exchange of
bulk goods was important. But exchange of information was also
important. Note that the successful development of science both in
Classical Greece and Medieval Europe became only possible
through an intensive intersocietal information exchange, whereas
the development of science in Europe affected, to a significant extent, the evolution of the Modern World-System.
It is important to stress that the intersocietal communication
networks could appear among much less complex societies (Wallerstein has denoted them as ‘mini-systems’ without actually studying them, for a recent review of the research on the archaic intersocietal networks see Chase-Dunn and Grimes 1995; Chase-Dunn
and Hall 1993; 1994; 1995; 1997). Already it seems possible to
speak about a communication network covering most of aboriginal
Australia. Again we come here across a similar phenomenon-a
considerable degree of cultural complexity (complex forms of rituals, mythology, arts, and dance well comparable with the ones of
early agriculturists) observed among populations with an apparently rather simple political organization. This could largely be
explained by the fact that relatively simple Australian local groups
were parts of a much more complex whole: a huge intersocietal
communication network that apparently covered most of Australia
(e.g. Bakhta, Senyuta 1972; Artemova 1987).
Thus, it is possible to contrast societies that followed the pathway of political centralization and ‘authoritarianization’ with cultures that further elaborated and perfected democratic communal
backgrounds and corresponding self-government institutions.
However, such a culture as the Benin Kingdom of the 13tn–19tn
centuries can make the picture of sociopolitical evolution even
more versatile. In particular, it reveals that not only heterarchical
but also homoarchical societies can reach a very high (incomparably higher than that of complex chiefdoms) level of sociocultural
complexity and political centralization still never transforming into
a state during the whole long period of existence. The Benin evi-
64 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
dence also testifies that local community’ s autonomy is not a
guarantee of complex society’ s advancement along the hierarchical pathway. We have suggested elsewhere to define this form of
sociopolitical organization as ‘megacommunity’ (see e.g. Bondarenko 1994; 1995a: 276–284; 1995b; 2001: 232–249). Its structure may be depicted in the shape of four concentric circles forming an upset cone. These ‘circles’ are as follows: the extended family, extended-family community (in which familial ties were supplemented by those of neighbor ones), chiefdom, and finally, the
broadest circle that included all the three narrower ones, that is the
megacommunity as such (the Benin Kingdom as a whole). The
specific characteristic of megacommunity is its ability to organize
a complex, ‘many-tier’ society predominantly on the basis of transformed kinship principle within rather vast territories.
Still, another evident alternative to the state seems to be represented by the supercomplex chiefdoms created by some nomads of
Eurasia – the number of the structural levels within such chiefdoms
appear to be equal, or even to exceed those within the average
state, but they have an entirely different type of political organization and political leadership; such type of political entities do not
appear to have been ever created by the agriculturists (e.g. Kradin
1992: 146–152; 1996; 2000a; 2000b).
Besides the Benin megacommunity and nomadic supercomplex
chiefdoms, the first half of the 19Ш century Zulu power can serve
as an example at this point. Within that vast and mighty militaristic
power one can observe high degree of supracommunal institutions’
hierarchization and high rigidity of this institutional hierarchy (see,
e.g. Gluckman 1940; Ritter 1955). Societies with profoundly
elaborated rigid caste systems may be a homoarchical alternative
to also homoarchical (by the very definition; see Claessen and
Skalnik 1978: 533–596, 637–650) early states, too (Quigley 1999:
114–169; Kobishchanov 2000: 64).
So, alternativity characterizes not only two basic macrogroups
of human associations, i.e. homoarchical and heterarchical societies. Alternativity does exist within each of them, too. In particular,
within the upper range of complexity and integrativity of the sociopolitical organization the state (at least in the pre-industrial
world) ‘competes’ with not only heterarchical systems of institutions (e.g. with polis) but also with some forms of sociopolitical
organization not less homoarchical than the state.
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
65
Among numerous factors capable to influence the nature of this
or that society, the family and community type characteristic of it
seems to deserve notice. The distinction in the correlation of kin
and neighborhood (territorial) lines is in its turn connected with the
dominant type of community (as a universal substratum social institution). A cross-cultural research conducted earlier (Bondarenko
and Korotayev 1999; 2000b) has generally corroborated the initial
hypothesis (Bondarenko 1997: 13–14; 1998b: 198–199) that the
extended-family community in which vertical social ties and nondemocratic value system are usually vividly expressed, being
given the shape of kinship relations (elder – younger), is more
characteristic of homoarchical societies5. Heterarchical societies
appear to be more frequently associated with the territorial communities consisting of nuclear families in which social ties are
horizontal and apprehended as neighborhood ties among those
equal in rights6.
In the course of our cross-cultural research in the community
forms, another factor important for determining societies’ homoarchization vs. heterarchization was revealed. It appeared that probability of a democratic (heterarchical) sociopolitical organization
development is higher in cultures where monogamous rather polygynous families dominate (Korotayev and Bondarenko 2000).
However, besides social factors (including those mentioned
above), a set of phenomena stemming from the fact that political
culture is a reflection of a society’ s general culture type, is also
important for determining its evolutionary pathway. The general
culture type that varies from one civilization to another defines the
trends and limits of sociocultural evolution. Though culture itself
forms under the influence of different factors (sociohistorical,
natural, etc.) the significance of the general culture type for the
sociopolitical organization is not at all reduced to the so-called
‘ideological factor’ (Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000c; Claessen
2000b). It influences crucially the essence of politicaf culture characteristic for a given society, ‘most probably revealing itself as
fully as economic, religious, artistic potential from the very beginning’ (Zubov 1991: 59). In its turn, political culture determines
human vision of the ideal sociopolitical model which correspondingly, may be different in various cultures. This way political culture forms the background for the development of character, types
and forms of complex political organization emergence, including
the enrolling of this process along either the homoarchical or het-
66 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
erarchical evolutionary pathways. But real, ‘non-ideal’ social institutions are results of conscious activities (social creativity) of people to no small degree, though people are frequently not capable to
realize completely global sociopolitical outcomes of their deeds
aimed at realization of personal goals. People create in the social
sphere (as well as in other spheres) in correspondence with the
value systems they adopt within their cultures in the process of socialization. They apprehend these norms as the most natural, the
only true ones.
Hence, it is evident that the general culture type is intrinsically
connected with its respective modal personality type. In their turn,
the fundamental characteristics of modal personality types are
transmitted by means of socialization practices which correspond
to the value system generally accepted in a given society and can
influence significantly its political evolution (see Irons 1979: 9–10,
33–35; Ionov 1992: 112–129; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a:
309–312) though scholars usually tend to stress the opposite influence, i.e. the influence of political systems on socialization processes and personality types.
The ecological factor is also important for determination of the
pathway which this or that society follows (Bondarenko 1998b;
2000). Not only natural environment but the sociohistorical one as
well should be included into the notion of ‘ecology’ in this case.
The environment also contributes a lot to the defining of a society’s evolutionary potential, creating limits to its advancement
along the homoarchical or heterarchical axes. For example, there is
no predestined inevitability of transition from the simple to complex society (Tainter 1990: 38; Lozny 2000) or from the early state
to mature one (Claessen and van de Velde 1987: 20 etc.).
Let us discuss now the implications of the approach discussed
above for the study of the state formation processes and ‘politogenesis’ in general. The tendency to see historical rules always
and everywhere the same results in gross perversion of historical
reality. For example, concurrent political processes are declared
consecutive stages of the formation of the state. Besides, the features of already mature state are illegitimately attributed to its
early forms and in consequence of this it becomes impossible to
find any ‘normal’ early state practically anywhere.
The notion of ‘politogenesis’ was elaborated in the 1970s and
80s by Kubbel (e.g. 1988) who imployed it to define the process of
state formation. But it has become evident by today that processes
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
67
of archaic societies’ political evolution should not be reduced to
the rise of the state exclusively because this is rather just one particular version of those processes. We suggest to use this term in
order to denote the formation of any types of complex political
organization, which also looks more justifiable from the etymological point of view: in ancient Greece the word politeia meant
the political order of any type, and not ‘state’.
We believe that among the students of politogenesis one can
observe a tendency to narrow the analysis to the study of the state
formation process only. This entirely legitimate intention to restrict
and define the study field still leads to the underestimation of the
fact that for long periods of time the state formation process was
inseparably linked with other evolutionary processes (e.g. processes of religious evolution), and this seems to hinder any really
profound explanation of the state formation processes themselves.
We believe that such explanations may be only achieved if the
state formation processes are studied against background of all the
other contemporary evolutionary processes.
It seems impossible to say that such an approach was always ignored (see e.g. Claessen and Skalnik 1978; Claessen 2000a [especially p. 2]). However, notwithstanding substantive achievements
in the analysis of the general cultural context of state formation processes this problem still appears to be far from its real solution.
One of the causes of this situation can be defined as ‘politocentrism’. Volens-nolens the state formation starts to be regarded
as a central process of the evolution of medium complexity cultures not just because of initial definition of the research objective
(which seems to be entirely legitimate); it starts to be regarded as
an objectively central process, whereas this is not always true, because in many cases other processes (e.g. sociostructural or religious) could be more important (for details see Grinin 2001).
On the other hand, sure enough, there were not one but many
models of politogenesis in the time of the transition from more
simple societies to more complex (both socioculturally and technologically) ones. The resultant cultures often differ from the state,
but it is incorrect to consider them prestate structures, because they
could be well compared to the early state as regards their complexity, functions and causes of their formation.
Therefore, the evolutionary pathway within which the features
of the state familiar to us are guessed retrospectively, is only one of
the possible ‘branches’ of the politogenesis. But since later most
68 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
alternative sociopolitical structures were destroyed by states, absorbed into states, or transformed into states7, it might be reasonable to recognize the ‘state’ branch of the politogenesis as ‘general’ and the alternative pathways as ‘lateral’.
This, however, does not deny the fact that the alternative sociopolitical structures mentioned above cannot be adequately described as prestate formations, that they are quite comparable with
early states by range of their functions and level of their structural
complexity. Therefore, it seems possible to designate them as state
analogues. The term ‘state analogue’ underlines both typological
and functional resemblance of such forms to the state and differences in structure. The introduction of this term makes it possible
to describe the process of politogenesis more adequately.
In order to find solutions for a certain range of political anthropology problems it is necessary to consider the genesis of early
state in the general context of socioevolutionary processes coeval
with it. This could make it possible to appreciate more exactly the
correlation between general evolution and state formation processes. For example, it seems evident that the early state formation
is finally connected with general changes caused by the transition
from the foraging to food production. This generally resulted in the
growth of sociocultural complexity. This led to the appearance of
the objective needs in new methods of organization of societies and
new forms of contacts between them. But in different societies it
was expressed in different ways. So, over long periods of time, the
growth of sociostructural complexity, the exploitation of
neighbors, development of commerce, property inequality and private ownership, growth of the role of religious cults and corporations etc. could serve as alternatives to purely administrative and
political decisions of above-mentioned problems. And in these
terms, the early state is only one of forms of new organization of
the society and intersociety relations.
As a result we could suggest the following points for the future
study of the socioevolutionary processes in medium complexity
cultures:
1) interrelatedness and inerconnectedness of the political aspects of the politogenesis and the other aspects (religious, sociostructural etc.);
2) causes of underdevelopment and fragmentary character of
the administrative institutions in the early states;
3) causes of relative easiness of the transition from one pattern
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
69
of growing sociocultural complexity to another;
4) determining of sociopolitical evolution models by historicalcultural and geographical conditions.
NOTES
* This study was supported by grants from the Russian Foundation for the
Humanities (RGNF # 01–03–00332a) and from the Russian Foundation for Basic
Research (RFBR/RFFI # 01–06–80142).
1
Note, however, that in fact this was frequently essentially Spencerian vision
which was implied in such cases; that is the evolution was perceived as ‘a change
from an incoherent homogeneity to a coherent heterogeneity’ (Spencer 1972
[1862]: 71).
2
The state is understood throughout as ‘...a sufficiently stable political unit
characterized by the organization of power and administration which is separated
from the population, and claims a supreme right to govern certain territory and
population, i.e. to demand from it certain actions irrespective of its agreement or
disagreement to do this, and possessing resources and forces to achieve these
claims’ (Grinin 1997: 20; see also Grinin 2000: 190).
3
See also its fundamental criticism by Mann (1986), the most radically negative attitude to this scheme expressed in categories of social evolution ‘trajectories
alternativity’ by Yoffee (1993), several collective works of recent years (Patterson
and Gailey 1987; Ehrenreich et al. 1995; Kradin and Lynsha 1995; Kradin et at
2000; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a), proceedings of recent international
conferences (Butovskaya et al. 1998; Bondareko and Sledzevski 2000).
4
There is considerable difference in the general ‘world-system’ and civilizational approaches. While the former tends to develop the globalistic viewpoint
on history, the latter emphasizes regional trends and tendencies of evolution. At
the same moment, our employment of the ‘world-system’ approach in this part of
our paper, in our opinion must not be apprehended as a contradiction within our
overall ‘civilizational’ approach. First, there is an important aspect the respective
approaches share: both of them stress supra-local (of more than one society)
trends of changes in different spheres; and, second, pre-modern ‘world-systems’
as they are represented in the corresponding approach supporters’ works (except
A. Gunder Frank’ s version [e.g. Frank and Gills 1993]) look very similarly with
what is called ‘civilizations’ within another approach [e.g. Abu-Lughod 1989;
Sanderson 1995; Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997]. Furthermore, it looks very much
like that in the United States the general understanding of the necessity to study
evolution and history on the supra-local level came through Wallerstein while in
reality it was the civiuzational approach (especially of the Danilevsky –
Spengler – Toynbee ‘brand’ ) for which this principle became most fundamental
much earlier.
5
This appears to be especially relevant for those societies where extended
families are dominated not by groups of brothers, but by individual ‘fathers’ (see
e.g. Bromley 1981: 202–210).
6
Note that among not only humans but other primates too, the role of kin relations is greater in homoarchically organized associations (Thierry 1990;
Butovskaya and Feinberg 1993: 25–90; Butovskaya 1993; 2000; Butovskaya,
Korotayev, and Kazankov 2000).
70 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
7
However, such transformations could only happen when certain conditions
were present. E.g. this could happen as a result of the influence of neighboring
state systems.
REFERENCES
Abu-Lughod, J. L.
1989. Before European Hegemony: The World System AD 1250–1350.
Oxford - New York: Oxford University Press.
Adams, R. N.
1975. Energy and Structure. Austin – London: University ofTexasPress.
Artemova, O. Yu.
1987. Lichnost’ i sotsial’ nye normy v rannepervobytnoy obshchine
[Personality and Social Norms in the Archaic Community]. Moskva:
Nauka.
1991. Egalitarnye i neegalitarnye pervobytnye obshchestva [Egalitarian and Inegalitarian Primitive Societies]. In Korotayev, A. V. and Chubarov, V. V. (eds.), Arhaicheskoe obshchestvo: uzlovye problemy sotsiologii razvitiya [Archaic Society: Basic Problems of Evolutionary Sociology], (vol. 1, pp. 44–91). Moskva: IRI AN SSSR.
1993. Pervobytnyi egalitarizm i rannie formy sotsial’ noy differentsiatsii [Primitive Egalitarianism and Early Forms of Social Differentiation]. In Popov, V. A. (ed.) Rannie formy sotsial’ noj stratifikatsii:
genezis, is-toricheskaja dinamika, potestarno-politicheskie funktsii [Early
Forms of Social Stratification: Genesis, Historical Dynamics, Potestaland-Political Functions] (pp. 40–70). Moskva: Nauka.
2000a. Initial Phases of Politogenesis. In Bondarenko and Korotayev
2000: 54–72.
2000b. Monopolization of Information and Social Inequality. In Kradin et al. 2000: 132–137.
Bakhta, V. M. and Senyuta, T. V.
1972. Lokal’ naja grappa, sem’ ja i uzy rodstva v obshchestve aborige-nov Avstralii [Band, Family, and Ties of Kinship in the Australian
Aboriginal Society]. In Reshetov, A. M. (ed.), Okhotniki, sobirateli, rybolovy [Hunters, Gatherers, Fishermen] (pp. 68–90). Leningrad: Nauka.
Barton, R. F.
1922. Ifugao Economics. Berkeley: University of California Press:
Beliaev, D. D.
2000. ‘Joint Government’ in Mesoamerican History. In Bondarenko
and Sledzevski 2000: 13–14.
Berent M.
1994. Stateless Polis. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis manuscript. Cam
bridge: Cambridge University.
1996. Hobbes and the ‘Greek Tongues’. History of Political Thought
17: 36–59.
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
71
2000a. Greece (11th–4th Centuries ВС). In Bondarenko and Korotayev
2000: 228–254.
2000b. The Stateless Polis: Towards a New Anthropological Model of
the Ancient Greek Community. In Kradin et al. 2000: 225–241.
Berezkin, Yu. E.
1995a. Alternative Models of Middle Range Society. ‘Individualistic’
Asia vs. ‘Collectivistic’ America? In Kradin and Lynsha 1995: 75–83.
1995b. Vozhdestva i akefal’ nye slozhnye obshchestva: dannye arkheologii i etnograficheskie paralleli [Chiefdoms and Acephalic Complex Societies: Archaeological Data and Ethnographic Parallels]. In Popov, V. A.
(ed.), Rannie formy politicheskoj organizatsii: ot pervobytnosti к gosudarstvennosti [Early Forms of Political Organization: From Primi-tivity to
Statehood] (pp. 62–78). Moskva: Nauka.
2000. Once Again on Horizontal and Vertical Links in Structure of the
Middle Range Societies. In Kradin et al. 2000: 220–224.
Bondarenko, D. M.
1994. Precolonial Benin: Personality, Authority and the Structure of
Society. In Sabloff, J. A. and Lai, M. (eds.), State, City and Society
(pp. 1–10). New Delhi: WAC-3.
1995a. Benin nakanune pervykh kontaktov s evropejtsami: Chelovek.
Obshchestvo. Vlast’ [Benin on the Eve of the First Contacts with Europeans: Man, Society, Authority]. Moskva: IAf RAN.
1995b. Megacommunity as a Variant of Structure and Type of Society: Precolonial Benin. In Kradin and Lynsha 1995: 100–108.
1997. Teorija tsivilizatsij i dinamika istoricheskogo protsessa v dokolonial ‘noj Tropicheskoj Afrike [The Theory of Civilizations and the Dynamics of Historical Process in Pre-colonial Tropical Africa]. Moskva:
IAf RAN.
1998a. ‘Homologous Series’ of Social Evolution. In Butovskaya, Korotayev, and Khristoforova 1998: 98–99.
1998b. Mnogolinejnost’ sotsial’ noj evoljutsii i al’ ternativy gosudarstvu. Vostokl: 195–202.
2000. ‘Homologous Series’ of Social Evolution and Alternatives to the
State in World History (An Introduction). In Kradin etal 2000: 213–219.
2001. Doimperskij Benin: formirovanie i evoljutsija sistemy sot-sial’
no-politicheskikh institutov [Pre-Imperial Benin: Formation and Evolution
of the System of Sociopolitical Institutions]. Moskva: IAfRAN.
Bondarenko, D. M. and Korotayev, A. V.
1999. Politogenez, “gomologicheskie rjady” i nelinejnye modeli sot
sial’ noj evoljutsii (K kross-kul’ turnomu testirovaniju nekotorykh politan-tropologicheskikh gipotez) [Politogenesis, ‘Homologous Series’ and
Nonlinear Models of Social Evolution (A Cross-Cultural Testing of Some
Political Anthropological Hypotheses)]. Obshchestvennye nauki i sovremennost’ 5: 129–140.
2000a (eds.). Civilizational Models of Politogenesis. Moscow: IAf
RAN.
72 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
2000b. Family Size and Community Organization: A Cross-Cultural
Comparison. Cross-Cultural Research 34: 152–189.
2000c. Introduction. In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 5–31.
Bondarenko, D. M. and Sledzevski, I. V. (eds.)
2000. Hierarchy and Power in the History of Civilizations. Moscow:
IAfRAN.
Bromley, Yu. V.
1981. Sovremennye problemy etnografii (ocherki teorii i istorii)
[Modern Problems of Ethnography (Essays in Theory and History)]. Moskva: Nauka.
Bramfiel, E. M.
1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies: Comments.
In Ehrenreih et al. 1995: 125–131.
Butovskaya M. L.
1993. Kinship and Different Dominance Styles in Three Species of
the Genus Macaca. Folia Primatologica 60: 210–224.
1994. Universal’ nye printsipy organizatsii sotsial’ nykh sistem и primatov vkljuchaja cheloveka [Universal Principles of Social Systems’ Organization of Primates Including the Humans]. Dr.Sc. thesis official
summary. Moskva: IEA RAN.
2000. Biosocial Preconditions for Sociopolitical Alternativity. In
Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 35–53.
Butovskaya, M. L., and Feinberg, L. A.
1993. U istokov chelovecheskogo obshchestva. Povedencheskie
aspekty evoljutsii cheloveka [At the Sources of Human Society. Ethological Aspects of Human Evolution]. Moskva: Nauka.
Butovskaya, M. L., Korotayev, A. V., and Kazankov, A. A.
2000. Variabilite des relations sociales chez les primates humains et
non humains: a la recherche d’ un paradigme general. Primatologie 3:
319–363.
Butovskaya, M. L, Korotayev, A. V., and Khristoforova, О. В., (eds.)
1998. Sociobiology of Ritual and Group Identity: A Homology of Animal
and Human Behavior. Concepts of Humans and Behavior Patterns in the
Cultures of the East and the West: Interdisciplinary Approach. Moscow:
RSUH.
Carneiro, R. L.
1970. A Theory of the Origin of the State. Science 169: 733–738.
1981. The Chiefdom: Precursor of the State. In Jones, G. D. and
Kautz, R. R. (eds.), The Transition to Statehood in the New World
(pp. 37–79). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
1987. Cross-Currents in the Theory of State Formation. American
Ethnologist 14: 756–770.
1991. The Nature of the Chiefdom as Revealed by Evidence from the
Cauca Valley of Colombia. In Rambo, A. T. and Gillogly, K. (eds.), Pro-
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
73
files in Cultural Evolution (pp. 167–190). Ann Arbor, MI: University of
Michigan Press.
2000. Process vs. Stages: A False Dichotomy in Tracing the Rise of
the State. In Kradin et al. 2000: 52–58.
Chamblee, J. F.
2000. The Classic-Postclassic Transition in the Central Mixteca Alta,
Oaxaca. Unpublished M.A. thesis manuscript. Tucson, AZ: University of
Arizona.
Chase-Dunn, Ch. and Grimes, P.
1995. World-System Analysis. Annual Review of Sociology 21: 387–417.
Chase-Dunn, Ch, and Hall, T. D.
1993. Comparing World-Systems: Concepts and Working Hypotheses. Social Forces 71: 851–886.
1994. The Historical Evolution of World-Systems. Sociological Inquiry 64: 257–280.
1995. The Historical Evolution of World-Systems. Protosoziologie 7:
23–34, 301–303.
1997. Rise and Demise. Comparing World-Systems. Boulder, CO –
Oxford: Westview Press.
Chirkin, V. E.
1955. Ob izuchenii gosudarstvennykh obrazovanij, voznikavshikh v
khode vosstanij rabov i krest’ jan [On the Study of States which Appeared
in the Course of Slave and Peasant Rebellions]. Voprosy istorii 9: 57–64.
Chudinova, O. Yu.
1981. Muzhchiny i zhenshchiny v obshchestve aborigenov Avstralii
[Men and Women in the Australian Aborigines’ Society]. In Malahovskiy, K. V. (ed.), Puti razvitiya Avstralii i Okeanii. Istoriya, ekonomika,
etnografiya (pp. 220–237). Moskva: Nauka.
Claessen, H. J. M.
2000a. Problems, Paradoxes, and Prospects of Evolutionism. In Kradin et al. 2000: 1–11.
2000b. Structural Change. Evolution and Evolutionism in Cultural
Anthropology. Leiden: Research School CNWS, Leiden University.
Claessen, H. J. M. and Skalnik, P. (eds.)
1978. The Early State. The Hague: Mouton.
Claessen, H. J. M. and van de Velde, P. (eds.) 1987. Early State Dynamics. Leiden: Brill.
Claessen, H. J. M, van de Velde, P, and Smith, M. E. (eds.) 1985. Development and Decline. The Evolution of Sociopolitical Organization.
South Hadley, MA: Bergin and Garvey.
Crumley, С. L.
1979. The Locational Models: An Epistemological Assessment for
Anthropology and Archaeology. In Schiffer, M. (ed.), Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory (vol. 3, pp. 141–173). New York: Academic Press.
74 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
1987. A Dialectical Critique of Hierarchy. In Patterson, Т. С and
Gailey, С W. (eds.), Power Relations and State Formation (pp. 155–
169). Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Association.
1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies. In Ehrenreih
etal. 1995: 1–15.
2001. Communication, Holism, and the Evolution of Sociopolitical
Complexity. In Haas J. (ed.), From Leaders to Rulers (pp. 19–33). New
York etc.: Kluwer Academic/ Plenum Publishers.
Dozhdev, D. V.
2000. Rome (8th–2nd Centuries ВС). In Bondarenko and Korotayev
2000: 255–286.
Dresch, P.
1984. The Position of Shaykhs among the Northern Tribes of Yemen.
Man 19: 31–49.
Earle, T.
1978. Economic and Social Organization of a Complex Chiefdom:
The Halelea District, Kiua ‘i, Hawaii. Ann Arbor, MI: University of
Michigan Press.
Ehrenreih, R. M., Crumley, С L., and Levy, J. E. (eds.) 1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies. Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Association.
Ferguson, Y.
1991. From Chiefdoms to City-States: The Greek Experience. In
Earle, T. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy, and Ideology (pp. 169–192).
Cambridge – New York: Cambridge University Press.
Frank, A. G. and Gills, В. К. (eds.)
1993. The World System: Five Hundred Years or Five Thousand?
London – New York: Routledge.
Frantsouzoff, S. A.
1995. The Inscriptions from the Temples of Dhat Himyam at Raybun.
Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 25: 15–27, tables I–II.
1997. Regulation of Conjugal Relations in Ancient Raybun. Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 27: 47–62.
2000. The Society of Raybun. In Kradin et al. 2000: 258–265.
Fiihrer-Haimendorf, C.
1962. The Ара Tanis and Their Neighbours. London-New York:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Gluckman, M.
1940. The Kingdom of the Zulu of South Africa. In Fortes, M. and
Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (eds.), African Political Systems (pp. 25–55). London: Oxford University Press.
Goldman, I.
1970. Ancient Polynesian Society. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
75
Grinin, L. E.
1997. Formatsii i tsivilizatsii. Gl. 4. Sotsial’ no-politicheskie, etniches-kie i dukhovnye aspekty sotsiologii istorii [Formations and Civilizations. Ch. 4. Sociopolitical, Ethnic, and Spiritual Aspects of the Sociology of History]. Filosofija i obshchestvo 5: 5–64.
2000. Proizvoditel’ nye sily i istoricheskij protsess [Productive Forces
and Historical Process]. Moskva: Teis.
2001. Genesis gosudarstva как sostavnaja chast’ protsessa perehoda ot
pervobytnosti к tsivilizatsii (obshchij kontekst sotsial’ noj evoljutsii pri
obrazovanii rannego gosudarstva) [State Formation as a Component of
the Civilization Formation Process (General Socioevolutionary Context of
the Early State Formation)]. Filosofija i obshchestvo 4: 5–60.
Gurevich, A. Ya.
1972. Istorija i saga [History and the Saga]. Moskva: Nauka.
Ionov, I. N.
1992. Istoricheskij subjekt i al’ ternativy sotsial’ noj dejatePnosti. In
Shemjakin, Ya.G. and Korotayev, A. V. (eds.), Al’ ternativnost’ istorii
(pp. 109–131). Donetsk: DO SAMI.
Irons, W.
1979. Natural Selection, Adaptation, and Human Social Behavior. In
Chagnon, N. A. and Irons, W. (eds.), Evolutionary Biology and Human
Social Behavior. An Anthropological Perspective (pp. 4–39). North Scituate, MA: Duxbury Press.
Kabo, V. R.
1986. Pervobytnaja dozemledel’ cheskaja obshchina [Primitive Preagricultural Community]. Moscow: Nauka.
Kobishchanov, Yu. M.
2000. The Community-Caste Systems. In Bondarenko and Sledzevski
2000: 63–64.
Korotayev, A. V.
1995a. Ancient Yemen. Some General Trends of Evolution of the Sabaic Language and the Sabaean Culture. Oxford – New York: Oxford
University Press.
1995b. Mountains and Democracy: An Introduction. In Kradin and
Lynsha: 60–74.
1995c. Nekotorye problemy sotsial’ noy evolyutsii arhaicheskih (i ne
tol’ ko arhaicheskih) obshchestv [Some Problems of Social Evolution of
Archaic (and not only Archaic) Societies]. Vostok 5: 211–220.
1995d. ‘Apologiya traybalizma’: Plemya как forma sotsial’ nopoliticheskoy organizatsii slozhnyh nepervobytnyh obshchestv [‘Apologia
for Tribalism’: Tribe as a Form of Socio-Political Organization of Complex Non-Primitive Societies]. Sotsiologicheskij zhurnal 4: 68–86.
1996a. Pre-Islamic Yemen. Sociopolitical Organization of the Sabaean Cultural Area in the 2nd and 3r Centuries AD. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz Verlag.
76 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
1996b. Dva sotsial’ no-ekologicheskih krizisa i genezis plemennoy
organizatsii na Severo-Vostoke Yemena [Two Socio-Ecological Crises
and Genesis of Tribal Organization in the Yemeni North-East]. Vostok
6: 18–28.
1996c. Ot vozhdestva к plemeni? Nekotorye tendentsii evolyutsii politicheskih sistem Severo-Vostochnogo Yemena za poslednie dve tysy-achi
let [From Chiefdom to Tribe? Some Trends of Political Evolution of
North-East Yemen in the Last Two Millennia]. Etnograficheskoe obozrenie 2: 81–91.
1997. Sabeyskie etyudy. Nekotorye obshchie tendentsii i faktory
evolyutsii sabeyskoy tsivilizatsii [Sabaean Studies: Some General Trends
and Factors of Evolution of the Sabaean Civilization]. Moskva: Vostochnaja literatura.
1998. Vozhdestva i plemena strany Hashid i BakJl [Chiefdoms and
Tribes of the Land of Hashid and Bakll]. Moskva: IV RAN.
2000a. The Chiefdom: Precursor of the Tribe? (Some Trends of the
Evolution of the Political Systems of the North-East Yemen in the 1st And
2nd Millennia A.D.) In Kradin et al. 2000: 242–257.
2000b. North-East Yemen (1st and 2nd millennia AD). In Bondarenko
and Korotayev 2000: 191–227.
Korotayev, A. V. and Bondarenko, D. M.
2000. Polygyny and Democracy: A Cross-Cultural Comparison.
Cross-Cultural Research 34: 190–208.
Korotayev, A. V., Kradin, N. N., Lynsha, V. A., and de Munck, V.
2000. Alternatives of Social Evolution: An Introduction. In Kradin et al.
2000: 27–89.
Kowalewski, S. A.
2000. Cyclical Transformations in North American Prehistory. In
Kradin et al. 2000: 177–187.
Kradin, N. N.
1992. Kochevye obshchestva (problemy formatsionnoj kharakteristiki)
[Nomad Societies (Problems of Evolutionary Attribution)]. Vladivostok:
Dal’nauka.
1996. Imperija hunnu [The Hsiung-nu Empire]. Vladivostok:
Dal’nauka.
2000a. The Hsiung-Nu (200 ВС – AD 48). In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000: 287–304.
2000b. Nomads, World-Empires, and Social Evolution. In Kradin et
al. 2000: 274–288.
2000c. Politicheskaja antropologija [Political Anthropology]. Moskva: Ladomir.
Kradin, N. N., Korotayev, A. V., Bondarenko, D. M., de Munck, V.,
and Wason, P. K. (eds.)
2000. Alternatives, of Social Evolution. Vladivostok: FEB RAS.
Kradin, N. N. and Lynsha, V. A. (eds.)
1995. Alternative Pathways to Early State. Vladivostok: Dal’nauka.
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
77
Kubbel’, L. E.
1988. Ocherki potestarno-politicheskoj etnografii [Essays of Potestal
and Political Ethnography]. Moskva: Nauka.
Levy, J. E.
1995. Heterarchy in Bronze Age Denmark: Settlement Pattern, Gender, and Ritual. In Ehrenreih et al. 1995: 41–53.
Lozny, L.
2000. Social Complexity: Necessity or Chance? In Bondarenko and
Sledzevski 2000: 79–80.
Lynsha, V.
1998. From Chiefdom to Tribe: Svealand in AD. 400–1100. In Butovskaya, Korotayev, and Khristoforova 1998: 99–100.
Mann, M.
1986. The Sources of Social Power. Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Meshkov, K. Yu.
1982. Filippiny [The Philippines]. In Cheboksarov, N. N. and Kuznetsov, A. I. (eds.), Malye narody Indonezii, Malajzii i Filippin [Scanty Peoples of Indonesia, Malaysia and the Philippines] (pp. 175–226). Moskva:
Nauka.
Nikitin, N. I.
1987. О formatsionnoj prirode rannikh kazachjikh soobshchestv
(k postanovke voprosa) [On the Formational Nature of Early Cossack
Communities (An Introduction)]. In Janin, V. L. (ed.), Feodalizm v Rossii
[Feudalism in Russia] (pp. 236–245). Moskva: Nauka.
Olgeirsson, E.
1957. Iz proshlogo islandskogo naroda [The Past of the Icelandic
People]. Moskva: Nauka.
Patterson, Th. С and Gailey, С W. (eds.)
1987. Power Relations and State Formation. Washington, D.C.:
American Anthropological Association.
Pavlenko, Yu.
1996. Istorija svitovoj tsivilizatsii. Sotsiokul’ turnij rozvitok ljudstva
[History of World Civilization. Sociocultural Development of the Humankind]. Kiiv: Lybed’.
2000. Proiskhozhdenie tsivilizatsii: al’ ternativnye puti [The Origins
of Civilization: Alternative Pathways]. In Kradin et al. 2000: 115–128.
Quigley, D.
1999. The Interpretation of Caste. New Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Ritter, E. A.
1955. Shaka Zulu: The Rise of the Zulu Empire. London: Longmans,
Green.
78 Social Evolution & History / July 2002
Rozner, I. G.
1970. Antifeodal’ nye gosudarstvennye obrazovanija v Rossii i na
Ukraine v XVI–XVIII vv. [Antifeudal States in Russia and Ukraine in the
16th–18th Centuries]. Voprosy istorii 8: 42–56.
Sahlins, M. D.
1960. Evolution: Specific and General. In Sahlins, M. D. and Service,
E. R. (eds.), Evolution and Culture (pp. 12-th). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
1972/1958. Social Stratification in Polynesia. Seattle – London: University of Washington Press.
Sanderson, S. K., (ed.)
1995. Civilizations and World-Systems: Two Approaches to the Study
of World-Historical Change. Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press.
Service, E. R.
1971/1962. Primitive Social Organization. An Evolutionary Perspective. 2nd ed. New York: Random House.
Shtaerman, E. M.
1989. К probleme vuzniknovenija gosudarstva v Rime. Vestnik drevnej istorii 2: 76–94.
Spencer, H.
1972/1862. On Social Evolution. Chicago: Aldine.
Steblin-Kamenskij, M. I.
1984. Mirsagi [The World of the Saga]. Leningrad: LGU.
Tainter, J. A.
1990. The Collapse of Complex Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge
Universtiy Press.
Thierry, B.
1990. Feedback Loop between Kinship and Dominance: The Macaque
Model. Journal of Theoretical Biology 145: 511–521.
Townsend, J. B.
1985. The Autonomous Village and the Development of Chiefdoms.
In Claessen et al. 1985: 141–155.
Tuden, A. and Marshall, С
1972. Political Organization: Cross-Cultural Codes 4. Ethnology 11:
436–464.
Vavilov, N. I.
1921. Zakon gomologicheskikh rjadov v nasledstvennoj izmenchivosti [The Law of Homologous Series in Hereditary Variability]. Sel
‘shoe i lesnoe khozjajstvo 1: 27–39.
1927. Geograficheskie zakonomernosti v raspredelenii genov kul’ –
turnykh rastenij [Geographical Regularities in the Distribution of Cultured Plants]. Priroda 10: 41–56.
1967. Izbrannye proizvedenija [Selected Works]. Vol. 1–2. Leningrad:
AN SSSR.
Bondarenko, Grinin, and Korotayev / Alternative Pathways
79
van der Vliet, E. Ch. L.
1987. Tyranny and Democracy. The Evolution of Politics in Ancient
Greece. In Claessen, H. J. M. and van de Velde, P. (eds.), Early State Dynamics (pp. 70–90). Leiden: Brill.
Wallerstein, I.
1974. The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New
York: Academic Press.
1979. The Capitalist World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
1987. World-Systems Analysis. In Giddens, A. and Turner, J. H.
(eds.), Social Theory Today (pp. 309–324). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Whyte, M. K.
1978. The Status of Women in Preindustrial Societies. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Woodburn, J. С
1972. The Local Group among Hunters and Gatherers: An East African Example and its Implications. In Ucko, P. J., Tringham, R., and Dimbleby, G. W. (eds.), Man, Settlement and Urbanism (pp. 193–206). London: Duckworth.
1979. Minimal Politics: The Political Organization of the Hadza of
North Tanzania. In Shack, W. A. and Cohen, P. S., (eds.), Politics in
Leadership: A Comparative Perspective (pp. 244–266). Oxford: Clarendon Press.
1980. Hunters and Gatherers Today and Reconstruction of the Past. In
Gellner, E. (ed.), Soviet and Western Anthropology (pp. 95–117). London:
Duckworth.
1982. Egalitarian Societies. Man 17: 431–451.
1988a. African Hunter-Gatherer Social Organization. Is it Best Understood as a Product of Encapsulation. In Ingold, Т., Riches, D., and Woodburn, J. (eds.), Hunters and Gatherers. I. History, Evolution and Social
Change (pp. 31–64). Oxford: Berg Publishers.
1988b. Some Connections between Property, Power and Ideology. In
Ingold, Т., Riches, D., and Woodburn, J. (eds.), Hunters and Gatherers.
II. Property, Power and Ideology (pp. 10–31). Oxford: Berg Publishers.
Yoffee, N.
1993. Too Many Chiefs? (Or, Safe Texts for the ‘90s). In Yoffee, N.
and Sherratt, A. (eds.), Archaeological Theory: Who Sets the Agenda?
(pp. 60–78). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zubov, A. B.
1991. ‘Vestminsterskaja model" i obshchestvennoe bytie Vostoka. In
Zubov, А. В., Salmin, A. M., and Tajvan, L. L. (eds.), Retrospektivnaja i
sravnitel’ naja politologija. Publikatsii i issledovanija, (vol. 1 pp. 50–75).
Moskva: Nauka.