Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
This is a repository copy of Value-based tiered pricing for universal health coverage : an idea worth revisiting. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/158749/ Version: Published Version Article: Chalkidou, Kalipso, Claxton, Karl orcid.org/0000-0003-2002-4694, Silverman, Rachel et al. (1 more author) (Accepted: 2020) Value-based tiered pricing for universal health coverage : an idea worth revisiting. Gates open research. p. 16. ISSN 2572-4754 (In Press) 10.12688/gatesopenres.13110.2 Reuse This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) licence. This licence allows you to distribute, remix, tweak, and build upon the work, even commercially, as long as you credit the authors for the original work. More information and the full terms of the licence here: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/ Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing eprints@whiterose.ac.uk including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. eprints@whiterose.ac.uk https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/ Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 OPEN LETTER Value-based tiered pricing for universal health coverage: an idea worth revisiting [version 2; peer review: 3 approved] Kalipso Chalkidou1, Karl Claxton2, Rachel Silverman1, Prashant Yadav1 1Global Health Policy, Center for Global Development, London, UK 2Department of Economics, University of York, UK, York, UK v2 First published: 04 Feb 2020, 4:16 ( https://doi.org/10.12688/gatesopenres.13110.1) Latest published: 21 Feb 2020, 4:16 ( https://doi.org/10.12688/gatesopenres.13110.2) Abstract The pricing of medicines and health products ranks among the most hotly debated topics in health policy, generating controversy in richer and poorer markets alike. Creating the right pricing structure for pharmaceuticals and other healthcare products is particularly important for low- and middle-income countries, where pharmaceuticals account for a significant portion of total health expenditure; high medicine prices therefore threaten the feasibility and sustainability of nascent schemes for universal health coverage (UHC). We argue that a strategic system of value-based tiered pricing (VBTP), wherein each country would pay a price for each health product commensurate with the local value it provides, could improve access, enhance efficiency, and empower countries to negotiate with product manufacturers. This paper attempts to further understanding on the potential value of tiered pricing, barriers to its implementation, and potential strategies to overcome those. Keywords UHC, Universal Health Coverage, Tiered Pricing, Value-based, Open Peer Review Reviewer Status 1 Invited Reviewers 2 3 report report version 2 (revision) 21 Feb 2020 version 1 04 Feb 2020 report 1 Hector E. Castro , Management Sciences for Health (MSH), Arlington, USA 2 Jorge Mestre-Ferrandiz , Universidad Carlos III, Madrid, Spain 3 Lyudmila Nepomnyashchiy , Community Health Acceleration Partnership (CHAP), New York City, USA Any reports and responses or comments on the article can be found at the end of the article. Page 1 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Corresponding author: Kalipso Chalkidou (kchalkidou@cgdev.org) Author roles: Chalkidou K: Writing – Original Draft Preparation, Writing – Review & Editing; Claxton K: Writing – Original Draft Preparation, Writing – Review & Editing; Silverman R: Writing – Original Draft Preparation, Writing – Review & Editing; Yadav P: Writing – Original Draft Preparation, Writing – Review & Editing Competing interests: No competing interests were disclosed. Grant information: This work has been funded by the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation [Investment ID OPP1202541]. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript. Copyright: © 2020 Chalkidou K et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. How to cite this article: Chalkidou K, Claxton K, Silverman R and Yadav P. Value-based tiered pricing for universal health coverage: an idea worth revisiting [version 2; peer review: 3 approved] Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 (https://doi.org/10.12688/gatesopenres.13110.2) First published: 04 Feb 2020, 4:16 (https://doi.org/10.12688/gatesopenres.13110.1) Page 2 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 REVISED Amendments from Version 1 We thank the reviewer for their comments; we have amended the paper including a reference to his review, to address his points. In brief, we have added more references as requested, explained/ qualified various statements and pointed to his review for a list of challenges in making VBTP a reality. Any further responses from the reviewers can be found at the end of the article Background The pricing of medicines and health products has become one of the most hotly debated topics in health policy—in both industrialized/OECD countries and low- and middle-income countries (LMICs). Creating the right pricing structure for pharmaceuticals and health products has become particularly important for LMICs, where pharmaceuticals account for a significant portion of total health expenditure. Under the historical model for global health, most of the world’s poor lived in low-income countries; the global burden of disease was largely communicable, and mostly concentrated in low- and lower-middle-income countries; and development assistance for health financed large portions of health expenditure in low and lower-middle income countries. This model of global health assistance is now passé. The world’s poor (and disease burden) are no longer concentrated in low-income countries (LICs) but now reside primarily in middle-income countries (MICs). And as MICs transition from health assistance, they often face significantly higher prices for health products compared to the prices received by global health mechanisms. This poses a significant risk to sustaining the health gains achieved in immunization, HIV/AIDS, tuberculosis (TB), malaria, family planning, and other disease areas funded though development assistance for health. At the same time, other forces are at work. Epidemiological transition is shifting the disease burden from infectious to noncommunicable diseases (NCDs) across most countries, but many LMICs still face a high communicable disease burden—especially in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia. Economic growth and improved fiscal space have not necessarily translated into commensurate increases in government health spending (Doherty et al., 2018; Tandon et al., 2018). The modest increases in government expenditure for health are insufficient to sustain financing of health programs previously supported by donors, particularly given that countries face higher prices of health products. As donor aid shrinks, and government expenditures do not increase fast enough to keep pace, a majority of the health expenditure in LMICs (especially for medicines/health products) is borne out-of-pocket by individuals and families. For some transitioning countries, high prices for vaccines, antiretroviral therapy (ART) and other products can jeopardize the financial sustainability of health sector budget (Silverman, 2018). When faced with the choice between sustaining donor-financed programs and making other investments in the health system or NCDs, some country governments are inclined to choose the latter—leading to tensions between different global agencies and country governments that further complicate this issue. The lack of a clear architecture for pricing and prioritization of health products continues to be a major impediment to achieving UHC (Schäferhoff et al., 2019; Watkins et al., 2018). National health insurance systems—most of which are still in stages of infancy in most LMICs—are devoting large portions of their limited budgets to health products (e.g. Ghana’s NHIS and Kenya’s NHIF spend between 40–55% of their total budgets on health products); this makes it difficult to expand quality services to cover more of the population. In tandem, new technologies (especially vaccines and diagnostics) are entering LMIC health systems at an unprecedented pace. The pressure to adopt new health technologies creates significant opportunity costs and is likely to crowd out more cost effective interventions (e.g. Kenya and GeneXpert (Callaway, 2017; Muchangi, 2019); Senegal offering free access to trastuzumab, which has in turn been shown not be cost-effective in most African settings1 (Gershon et al., 2019); or the recent listings in the WHO Essential Medicines List of expensive products for cancer and autoimmune diseases, including erlotinib and adalimumab, with incremental cost effectiveness ratios in the order of hundreds of thousands of dollars, in the hope generic versions will materialise (Hill et al., 2016; WHO, 2019—page 222); or dialysis in LMICs absorbing large chunks of small and strained budgets (van der Tol et al., 2019)). This context requires rethinking the current model of pharmaceutical pricing—and, we argue, an important role for value-based tiered pricing (VBTP), a system of pricing where each country pays a price commensurate with local value. In this article we first describe the review the theoretical and empirical literature on the potential benefits and challenges of applying tiered pricing schemes in LMICs. We then present VBTP as an approach to help manage some of the tensions and tradeoffs in the debate around LMIC medicine pricing. While VBTP is no magic bullet for universal LMIC access to medicines, it holds the potential to move countries forward toward UHC. Theory and evidence on pricing models and differential pricing Overview Efficient pricing for on-patent pharmaceuticals is complex and challenging. Under the current IP model, private companies pay upfront for pharmaceutical R&D (though they often benefit from public sector investments in basic scientific research and early stage R&D); they later recoup their upfront investments and earn profits by selling successful pharmaceutical innovations at prices well above marginal cost, protected by term-limited patents (Institute of Medicine (US) Forum on Drug Discovery, Development, and Translation, 2009). If prices are too low, pharmaceutical companies will not invest in innovation (dynamic inefficiency); if prices are too high, the costs of accessing existing therapies will outweigh the benefits (static inefficiency). Pricing policy for innovative pharmaceutical therefore need to achieve a delicate balance between these twin 1 In Brief: Senegal to offer free breast and cervical cancer treatment. Uncensored Opinion. Sept 2019. See here: https://uncensoredopinion.co.za/ in-brief-senegal-to-offer-free-breast-and-cervical-cancer-treatment/ Page 3 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 goals: affordable access to existing treatments on the one hand, and potentially transformative and lifesaving innovation on the other. Zooming out from pricing policy in any individual country, global pricing for on-patent products becomes even more challenging. Pharmaceutical R&D is a global public good; the cost is borne through a one-time upfront investment justified by the potential for future sales, and the benefits are potentially shared across consumers worldwide. Prices are not determined by the costs of R&D; however, the size of investment in R&D is determined by the expectations of the global prices manufacturers are likely to command for the products in development. Since post-hoc sales indirectly fund R&D in this way, the choice of pricing policy across countries therefore determines how much each country contributes to the joint cost of pharmaceutical innovation. (For products that are off-patent, market competition has the potential to create the right pricing structure—though in practice, market failures and barriers to entry often help sustain artificially high prices in LMICs even after patent expiration (Silverman, 2018). For products under patent and with limited therapeutic substitutes, price is determined by strategic responses between the manufacturer and purchasers in different markets. The manufacturer’s goal is to maximize total profits across all markets. Each purchaser, in contrast, aims to access the drug at the lowest possible price, so long as the benefits at that price outweigh the cost of the drug. (For simplicity, the below section refers interchangeably to “countries” and “consumers”, imagining that each country is served by a single payer able to negotiate and purchase on behalf of all citizens using pooled funds; in practice, however, most markets are served by a heterogenous mix of public payers, private insurers, and out-of-pocket expenditure from individuals.) One possibility would be for the manufacturer to set a uniform single price for all countries across the entire world; countries could choose to either purchase the drug at the uniform price or walk away without purchasing the drug. At a very high price, the manufacturer knows that only a few countries will be willing to pay for the drug and total revenue will be low. At a very low price, on the other hand, almost every country will be willing to pay for the drug—but total revenue will still be low because revenue per-pill will be miniscule and may even fall below the marginal cost of production. The optimal price, from the perspective of the patent holder, would be somewhere in the middle, where the marginal revenue of serving one additional country—accounting for both increased volume, which increases revenue; but also decreased price across all countries, which decreases revenue—is equal to the marginal cost of producing the pill. That is, the manufacturer will choose the single price for the entire world based on the overall/aggregate demand elasticity. But a single price would create significant social dead-weight loss (inefficiency). Some countries would be unwilling or unable to buy the drug at the single uniform price; that means some markets would not be served at all (Kremer & Snyder, 2018). A uniform price would also be suboptimal from the manufacturer’s perspective, since it leaves potential revenues from unserved markets on the table; therefore, a single price would also be inefficient for recouping R&D costs and incentivizing future innovation (Danzon, 1997). Alternatively, a manufacturer could deploy differential pricing across multiple heterogenous markets—that is, a manufacturer could charge different prices for the same product in different countries. Price differences would reflect differences in the willingness (and ability) of each country to pay for the product. (More specifically the manufacturer would charge lower prices to price-sensitive countries, and higher prices to less price-sensitive countries). In theory, differential pricing across countries can create welfare gains by improving access for patients in developing countries without necessarily harming either the profits of the pharmaceutical companies or access for patients in developed countries. Under certain conditions, differential pricing may also lead to better incentives for pharmaceutical research and development, and thus in the long run could benefit patients in both developing and developed countries (Danzon & Towse, 2003). Literature review Yadav (2010) provides a review of literature on differential pricing. Relevant literature is reviewed below to provide the right theoretical background for the rest of this paper. Price discrimination in a monopoly. Multiple studies (Schmalensee, 1981) have shown that differential pricing by a single profit-maximizing manufacturer leads to improvements in overall welfare (i.e. benefits both the manufacturer and the consumers) if total sales increase as a result of differential pricing. Similar findings are reported in Varian (1985) and Schwartz (1990). Layson (1994) shows that if a monopolistic firm serves two markets—one with higher willingness/ ability to pay and larger profit margin, and a second with lower willingness/ability to pay but a large market size—price discrimination will enhance social welfare. More generally, Malueg & Schwartz (1994) show that price discrimination increases social welfare when there are large differences in demand. Hausman & Mackie-Mason (1988) note that price discrimination is also more likely to increase dynamic welfare by better incentivizing research and development. Price discrimination in an oligopoly. There is very little research that examines the impact of price discrimination in an oligopoly (products with a small number of manufacturers, but more than one). Using a simplified model, Fudenberg & Tirole (2000) predict that price discrimination among firms in an oligopoly would lead to high initial prices followed by a subsequent price reduction; consumers would be better off in aggregate. When one market is a monopoly and other market is oligopoly. In some cases, a firm could serve two independent markets—one in which it enjoys a monopoly, and the other in which it must compete with a rival firm. The effect of price discrimination in this scenario remains understudied, though this Page 4 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 analysis would be important for understanding situations where generic competition exists in some countries, but other countries remain under patent exclusivity. In this environment, Armstrong & Vickers (1993) show that a firm would set a monopoly price in the first market; prices in the second market would be determined by the competitive interaction between the two firms. If the firm cannot successfully set different prices in the two markets due to price regulation or other factors, the firm may end up choosing a reduced price in the captive market and a raised price in the competitive market. Under a system of differential pharmaceutical pricing, Mujumdar & Pal (2005) show that price regulation in one county has no impact on prices charged in a second country. As long as there is no price referencing, pricing decisions are made independently for each market. Ramsey pricing. While in theory differential pricing is based on price elasticity of customer segments, in practice price elasticities of individual customer segments/markets are unobservable. As a result, average per capita income is often used as a proxy for price elasticity and differential pricing is designed around GNI/capita or GDP/capita. While voluntary differential pricing by a manufacturer achieves higher social welfare compared to charging a single uniform price, the absolute price levels charged by a profit-maximizing monopolist may not be socially optimal. Ramsey pricing (Ramsey, 1927) can be utilized to determine differential prices in each market to recoup the variable and joint R&D costs. Ramsey pricing, which was originally explored as a pricing approach for public utilities with large fixed costs, involves choosing prices in each market in inverse relation to the demand elasticities, and subject to assuring a specified target profit level for the manufacturer, e.g. a firm’s target internal hurdle rate of return. Depending on who sets the target rate of return, Ramsey pricing can be more akin to a regulated profit maximizing monopolist. Even though Ramsey pricing can be welfare efficient, it may not be consistent with the goal of improving access to LMICs. Without consensus on what would be the socially acceptable rate of return for the manufacturer, the selected price differentials often transfer a larger portion of surplus to the manufacturer, making it similar to a price discriminating monopolist. Welfare effects in global markets using simulation or empirical data. Several papers use simulation or empirical data to interrogate the welfare effects of price discrimination across global pharmaceutical markets. Dumoulin (2001) uses a simulation model to compare a single global price with differential prices based on country income. The analysis shows that differential pricing maximizes both manufacturer profit and affordability to the population, increasing access by a factor of roughly 4–7. Among countries with the same GDP per capita, the country in which wealth is most concentrated will face a higher price under price discrimination; companies would rationally price for the rich segment of society rather than the more populous but less lucrative lower-income segment. Scherer (2004) considers the welfare effects of allowing poor countries to access generic versions of medicines protected by patents in rich countries. Globally, he finds this would increase welfare because the marginal utility of income (the benefit derived from one extra unit of currency) is greater in poor nations than in rich ones. However, this may lead to negative welfare effect in the rich countries. Danzon (1997) compares the welfare effects of differential pricing for pharmaceuticals in the United States and the European Union (EU). They show that prices in the European Union (EU), are farther from ‘Ramsey Optimal Prices’ due to parallel trade and monopsony buying structure. Danzon & Chao (2000) compared the prices of a limited sample of drugs across countries and conclude that prices for generics are lower in markets without price regulation. Hellerstein et al., (2004) examine differential pricing for ARVs for HIV/AIDS and show that until 2000 there was little variation in the prices of ARVs between the high and low-income countries. Reich & Bery (2005) discuss differential pricing among various options of improve access to AIDS medicines. They list three possible mechanisms for a differential pricing system: internal company polic- based differential pricing, international agency facilitated differential pricing and wider distribution of price information to different actors. Lopert et al. (2002) recommend a mechanism of setting prices in each country based on the incremental cost per life-year gained for each country based on its per capita gross domestic product (GDP) as a proxy for a patient’s ability to pay. Based on an extensive literature search, Lang & Hill (2004) conclude that differential pricing can lead to improved access for low-income countries, increased market share for companies, and no price increases for high-income countries. Summary. Compared to a single price across countries, the literature clearly demonstrates that differential pricing enhances both static and dynamic efficiency. The debate, therefore, is not about the value of differential pricing per se but rather how differential pricing should be structured; how it should distribute surplus between the manufacturer and buyer(s); and, relatedly, how it should trade off between dynamic and static efficiency. Traditional price discrimination allows the manufacturer to capture a larger portion of the economic surplus, therefore privileging R&D investment (dynamic efficiency); Ramsey-style pricing, in contrast, could in theory transfer most of the surplus to consumers and regulate profits, therefore privileging affordable access to existing therapies (static efficiency). Challenges in conventional differential pricing The theoretical benefits of differential pricing can only be met under specific conditions. Manufacturers must be able to securely separate economic markets based on demand Page 5 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 elasticity—preventing either physical or informational leakage between markets and using the right proxies for demand elasticity in each. See Table 1 below for a description of the three main product characteristics to consider for the applicability of differential pricing. In LMICs, these conditions are rarely met in practice (Yadav, 2010). Many LMICs have highly skewed income distributions, making it more lucrative to cater to richer segments of society than the more voluminous poorer classes (oftentimes including large migrant/undocumented populations from neighbouring countries). This is exacerbated by relatively low levels of pooling; most purchase decisions, in practice, are made by individuals, who are likely to be more price sensitive than a pooled payer. Manufacturers are also wary of physical arbitrage (e.g. reimportation to higher value markets) and informational arbitrage (e.g. lower LMIC prices used to inform pricing in higher value markets via external reference pricing). Drug resistance and supply/manufacturing constraints may also create impediments for serving more price-sensitive consumers (Yadav, 2010). In addition, while overall welfare may be higher, tiered pricing may allow producers to charge a margin which is far higher than the amount needed to recoup R&D investments and production costs (Moon et al., 2011). Differential pricing and procurement architecture Real-world transactions, including manufacturer price-setting, are often more complex than basic economic theory would predict. When a single manufacturer sells to multiple markets, the manufacturer considers not just price elasticity of the market but also the purchaser’s buying power, as well as other factors such as payment timeliness, long-term customer value, and transaction costs. Smaller country purchasers are then at a natural disadvantage; the volume they are purchasing is too small to create negotiating leverage based on market power, and the transaction costs are high relative to a manufacturers’ total potential revenue. To achieve welfare enhancing prices, some argue that the monopoly pricing power of a manufacturer must be constrained by regulatory price controls or through competition (via compulsory licensing). This may achieve static efficiency gains, but the resulting effect on dynamic efficiency could be problematic. One option used to increase small countries’ purchasing power and reduce transaction costs is pooled or joint procurement. Pooled procurement has been deployed, for example, via the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) pooled procurement mechanism, the Pan-American Health Organization (PAHO) Revolving Fund for Vaccines, the Organisation of Eastern Caribbean States (OECS), and the African Island States procurement service, both for single source/on-patent drugs and generics. Such arrangements can only work if participating countries have comparable income levels and/or willingness to pay, since a single price is set across participating countries. Table 1. Product and market characteristics for applicability of differential pricing. Differential pricing can only create welfare gains for certain product and market types. There are three main product characteristics to consider for the applicability of differential pricing: 1. Product life cycle: ° ° ° Established products with dozens of generic manufacturers do not require differential pricing; the forces of market competition are the best lever to achieve optimal prices. New health technologies which are currently being launched in HICs may be a good candidate for differential pricing, allowing simultaneous (versus delayed) market launch in LMICs. On-patent products that have already been launched in LMICs through donor-led procurement—e.g. new ARVs or vaccines—could also be good candidates for differential pricing 2. Production cost and economies of scale: ° ° ° Production of biologics and vaccines requires significant capital investments to set up manufacturing plants; their production cost curves are steep downward sloping. This implies that differential pricing can enhance economies of scale for one (or a few) manufacturers, allowing lower prices at the lowest tier. In the long run, however, differential pricing (and the subsequent higher prices) could create barriers to entry/ competition; new manufacturers may not be able to achieve the economies of scale enjoyed by the one or two large incumbent manufacturers. 3. Complexity in administering the product: ° As discussed earlier, the welfare-enhancing properties of differential pricing only apply when differential pricing leads to higher overall sales for manufacturers—that is, when lower prices lead to a higher sales volume. For products that require more sophisticated health system infrastructure to administer, a lower price may not necessarily lead to a substantial increase in sales volume. Differential pricing may not be the best approach for such products unless health system infrastructure is improved in parallel. Page 6 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Monopsony power of large buyers carries some risks and can lead to unintended consequences. For example, if pooled monopsonist purchasers with high income heterogeneity between participating countries use their buying power to exercise lowest price clauses in their price negotiations, it can lead to decreases in welfare (Privett & Yadav, 2012). A large pooled purchaser which has a combination of low-, middle- and high-income countries in its pool can leverage its buying power to demand low prices for all its members, including middle- and highincome countries. Strategic pricing response from manufacturer to the presence of such a buyer reduced overall welfare in the system. Value-based tiered pricing In economic theory, true differential pricing should reflect each market’s willingness to pay. In contrast, conventional differential (tiered) pricing used in global health (e.g. for vaccines, ARVs, malaria medicines, and contraceptives (Yadav, 2010) has primarily used per capita income as a proxy for willingness to pay. The use of GDP per capita as a crude proxy for willingness to pay is a significant flaw in the design of differential pricing programs, driving contention and debate. The highly skewed income distribution in countries such as Brazil, India, and Thailand leads to discontent with prices offered based on national average GNI/capita (Yadav, 2010). A different approach—value-based (benefit-based) tiered pricing (VBTP)—has the potential to address previously observed challenges with conventional differential pricing (Danzon et al., 2015). Under VBTP, prices in each country should be based on a health system’s willingness to pay, where willingness to pay reflects the actual, assessed value of the product within that market/health system (‘value-based pricing’) accounting for affordability and budgetary constraints (See Figure 1) (Claxton, 2007). The assessed value of a product is based on three factors. First, how much additional health will the product create (compared to the current standard of care or potential comparator products)? Second, what are the net additional costs to the health care system of adoption, including how may decrease or increase health spending elsewhere? (For example, a vaccine would prevent disease, which a health system would otherwise need to pay to treat; but a new medical device would also require implantation or surgical costs in addition to the procurement price of the product.) Finally, how much is the health system willing and able to pay for additional health benefits offered (e.g. per disability- or quality-adjusted life years)? Determining value…locally Use of value assessment to inform pricing decisions is already supported by a substantial research and institutional infrastructure. Many LMICs are already using or exploring value assessment (through health technology assessment) to inform their procurement/price negotiation and reimbursement decisions, including Thailand, China, India, Ghana, South Africa, the Philippines, Indonesia, Brazil Mexico, Colombia, Kenya and Tanzania (Government launches health technology assessment to inform policy decision making Nairobi, (n.d.); Hollingworth et al., 2019; MacQuilkan et al., 2018; Surgey et al., 2019; Tantivess et al., 2017). There is also a large body of literature around how to estimate a health system’s willingness and ability to pay for health gains. Figure 1. Sequence of actions for value-based tiered pricing. Page 7 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 The key question is what improvement in health would be possible if the additional (net) resources required had, instead, been made available for other health care activities. This assessment of health opportunity cost is relevant whether the additional costs of the investment must be found from existing commitments and current levels of health expenditure, or when health expenditure can/will be increased to accommodate the additional resources required. Therefore, the problem of establishing how much a health care system should be willing and able to pay for the benefits of a product is the same as estimating the relationship between changes in health care expenditure and health outcomes. Countries vary in disease burden, demographics, health expenditure and system structure. As a consequence the marginal productivity of health care expenditure, health opportunity costs, and how much health care systems can afford to pay for the health benefits of products are likely to be correlated with income levels; however, GDP per capita, by itself, will not precisely predict optimal pricing. Estimates of the marginal productivity of health expenditure in producing health (quality-adjusted life-years) are becoming available for some high-income countries based on approaches to estimation which exploit within-country data, (Claxton et al., 2015; Edney et al., 2018; Lomas et al., 2018; Martin et al., 2008; Vallejo-Torres et al., 2018). This evidence from high-income settings can be used to give some indication of possible values in lower income countries (Woods et al., 2016) based on a number of assumptions about income elasticity of demand for health and the relative ‘under funding’ of health care systems. The effect of different levels of health care expenditure on mortality outcomes has been investigated in a number of published studies using country level data, many including LMICs (Gallet & Doucouliagos, 2017). The challenge is to control for all the other reasons why mortality might differ between countries in order to isolate the causal effect of differences in health expenditure. A number of studies try and overcome this problem and estimate outcome elasticities for all cause adult and child mortality, by gender, as well as survival, disability and DALYs (Bokhari et al., 2007; Ochalek et al., 2018). These estimated elasticities have been used to provide country specific estimates of health opportunity costs (cost per DALY averted) for 97 LMICs, taking account of measures of a country’s infrastructure, donor funding, population distribution, mortality rates, conditional life expectancies (all by age and gender), estimates of disability burden of disease and total health care expenditure (Haasis et al., 2015). These types of estimates suggest that optimal prices under VBTP will vary across countries and as a general trend increase with increasing GDP per capita, but specific pricing in each country would depend on how much health would be produced in that system, the specific cost structure of the health system, and how a country values health gains achieved through a health technology. VBTP therefore offers an opportunity to improve upon conventional tiered pricing and sustainably capture the potential efficiency gains from differential pricing, particularly in countries which are moving towards high coverage in their national insurance programs and are already using value-based pricing and cost-effectiveness thresholds. Value assessment provides a more accurate measure of a country’s willingness to pay than use of GDP per capita, which is likely to be correlated with willingness to pay but offers only a crude, often imprecise proxy. Definitionally, VBTP also ensures that a product would be locally affordable, as the value assessment explicitly considers a country’s willingness to pay for health gain, which is directly linked to its ability to pay for health gain, given resource constraints. “What’s in it for me?” Benefits of VBTP for different actors in the health system Below we describe how a functional VBTP system would benefit different actors within LMIC health systems. As described in the previous section, our definition of “value” is always based on benefits that accrue to the payer and the payer’s willingness to pay for these benefits. Health care systems in low- and middle-income markets. A VBTP system would dramatically increase the accessibility and affordability of health innovation in LMICs. VBTP would ensure that transaction prices are affordable, reflect local opportunity costs, and therefore remove the politically difficult choice between restricting access to effective medicines or allowing access at too high a price, thereby damaging other parts of the health care system and the economy. By using the benefits-based price as the starting point/ceiling price in negotiations with industry, country payers can ease budget pressure, making collective or universal coverage more politically and financially sustainable. In particular, VBTP can help relieve budget pressure within the MICs currently setting up insurance or universal health coverage schemes and payer agencies, especially when existing health technology assessment infrastructure is already driving listing decisions and price negotiations. In the absence of tiered pricing (e.g. at a single global price), most MICs would be priced out of the market for innovative pharmaceuticals, except perhaps among a handful of wealthy individuals willing and able to pay out of pocket. In contrast, prices that reflect the budgetary constraint can help drive appropriate and equitable uptake of branded pharmaceuticals, provided arrangements are in place to adjust the value-based price downwards2 in situations where adoption would lead to significant budget impacts (e.g. introduction of PCV in the Philippines (Ochalek et al., 2018); or HepC drugs in Australia). Appropriate VBTP implies that a country payer can afford to purchase an innovative product for the entire covered population in need—avoiding inequities caused by rationing either on an ad hoc basis or based on individuals’ ability to pay 2 See (Lomas et al., 2018) for a discussion of non-marginal effects, though applying such adjustments in real time may be impractical in many MICs systems. Page 8 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 out-of-pocket. Likewise, differential pricing across countries implies that a greater number of countries could afford health innovation—reducing cross-country inequities of access and health outcomes (though better outcomes for many NCDs such as cancer or diabetes also require significant expenditure and capacity elsewhere in the health system, e.g. cancer outcomes depend on early diagnosis, access to radiotherapy, and surgery etc.). Likewise, a global system of VBTP would help signal LMIC health needs and demand to product developers, creating at least some influence on commercial research and development decisions (to a significant extent compared to single global price3). Private sources invest over $170 billion each year in healthcare R&D; over time, consistent demand signaling from LMICs should direct at least some of these resources toward LMICs’ specific health needs. The strength of this signal will grow smoothly and progressively with economic growth rather than the ‘binary’ effect of a single global price. Further, as MICs invest in their own healthcare product industries, a VBTP system could expand the size of domestic and global pharmaceutical markets. The Chinese government, for example, is already emphasizing R&D (including biosimilars and increasingly “innovative” products) within the Chinese pharmaceutical industry with the government emphasis on R&D including biosimilars. Importantly, such an R&D system is still likely to underserve low-income countries (LICs), which are shrinking in number and population but continue to represent a substantial portion of the global disease burden. LICs are likely to have different innovation needs than MICs (e.g. treatment/prevention for neglected tropical diseases or products that can be delivered without cold chains), extremely limited ability to pay for innovation, and continued reliance on donor funding and procurement support. However, a VBTP could still benefit LICs by improving access to existing products with a shared burden across LICs and MICs/high-income countries (HICs)—so long as the LIC value-based price still exceeds the manufacturers’ marginal cost of production. More broadly, in situations where the value- or benefit-based price an LMIC is less than the manufacturer’s marginal cost of production, the manufacturer will still have no commercial incentive to offer the product for sale, even under a system of perfect global price discrimination. This scenario may be quite common in LICs, where evidence-based, budget-sensitive thresholds are likely to be much lower than those used by global partners (or formerly by WHO) and even small molecules may be too costly at marginal-cost prices (Chalkidou & Keller, 2017). Further, the production costs of new biologics (and biosimilars) remain very high also requiring significant upfront investment costs in manufacturing plants (unlike small 3 See Kremer & Snyder, 2018 in reference list for a modelled assessment if the implications of a price discrimination ban and hence the imposition of single global price on the price (and access) of HIV drugs. molecule generics). In addition, the total cost of serving an additional market also includes the costs associated with regulatory approval, product launch, and safe delivery in the context of care pathways and with associated systems—which may be cost-ineffective, given competing priorities and limited budgets, in many LICs and some MICs. So, while a VBTP system should improve access to some portion of innovative health products in at least some markets, perfect price discrimination alone will not, unfortunately, lead to full access for all branded drugs in all contexts. Industry. VBDP would increase industry’s revenue and profit for a product during patent protection. Pricing (and volumes) in each country would be based on evidence of a product’s value proposition—a rational and therefore accountable assessment for each health system. A VBTP system would be more predictable than current arrangements, where regulatory approval is disconnected from listing decisions and listing decisions themselves offer little information on the likely extent of take by the health system. As such, price discrimination reduces unnecessary risks while maintaining companies’ incentives to develop better products, as more effective drugs will predictably increase revenue while an ineffective or dangerous product would yield no revenue at all. It is theoretically possible that perfect VBTP across systems would lead to lower revenue than the status quo for some products. If this is the case, however, this implies that some countries are presently overpaying for pharmaceuticals relative to the opportunity cost; this means current revenues are likely to be unsustainable in the medium-term regardless as they would be unsustainable for the healthcare system. Indeed, VBTP is by design sustainable, as healthcare payers will be able, definitionally, to afford access at price offered in their setting. This may help reduce the likelihood that national payers adopt more drastic policy responses to address unaffordable pharmaceutical prices, which may include: a. Arbitrary regulatory, evidential, and budgetary barriers to entry which prevent market access and increase development costs b. Competitive tendering or other all-or-nothing aggressive price negotiation tactics by monopsonists. c. Complete abandonment of patents as products unaffordable (e.g. through compulsory licensing). are The clear demand signals from MICs (see previous section) would also create additional commercial opportunities for innovator companies to serve MIC health needs, widening the pipeline of products and disease areas as the healthcare industry gradually shifts focus to fast-growing emerging markets. Global agencies and development partners. • Better targeting of non-commercial R&D investment In the context of the aid transition, there is growing concern that available resources for assistance are being spent on wealthier Page 9 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 countries as opposed to the poorest ones in need (e.g. see latest analysis on EU aid (Morton et al., 2018)). Aid should not be used to purchase products at unnecessarily high prices in situations where price discriminate could enhance access to needed medicines at locally affordable prices. Development partner subsidies should instead be devoted to the poorest countries, who cannot afford basic health products even at marginal cost, and real sources of market failure where global public goods are needed, for example R&D targeting the poorest nations. While continued aid will still be needed to fund R&D when a market’s commercial proposition remains unattractive, VBTP would make some R&D investment commercially viable; commercial viability would also increase so with expectations of economic growth across LMICs. In turn, agencies, donors and foundations could focus their investments where there is insufficient commercial incentive for market forces to be effective. • Pooled purchasing arrangements for specific product types VBTP, with each country paying prices commensurate with local value, can form the basis of multinational, cross-country pooled purchasing agreements for certain types of products suffering from specific market failures, including unpredictable demand or onerous country-by-country launch requirements (e.g. cancer drugs, biosimilars, and insulin products). Such arrangements already work in HIC settings, where countries are forming buyer coalitions for horizon scanning, joint price negotiations, and procurement deals (PMPRB, 2019). Such arrangements could be organized by LMICs themselves or with support from development partners. • More efficient development partner commodity portfolio Similarly, publicly funded conduits, such as the Global Fund to Fight AIDS, Tuberculosis, and Malaria (Global Fund), can use VBTP calculations to guide their own investment portfolios (Grubert, 2019; Isabelle et al., 2017). With more than half of the Global Fund’s $14 billion budget going to commodities (many of which remain on-patent), the lack of a mechanism for ex ante value assessment risks compromising value-for-money VFM and setting unaffordable pricing precedents price that cannot be sustained following aid transition4. Similarly, other global players such as CHAI and UNITAID can use value-based assessments to negotiate market shaping deals, (i.e. for dolutegravir) and advise on post-transition listing/procurement decisions. Pre-requisites for VBTP For a global VBTP to work in practice, several preconditions must be in place—some of which are not yet fully operational in many LMICs: • Value-informed market shaping Where donors still play a role in market shaping, VBTP can address the current lack of consideration for products’ comparative clinical value or global/national affordability. Initiatives such as MedAccess, which helps manage the risk of new product launches in LMICs, can use VBPT to anchor price negotiations with manufacturers, helping ensure better value for the HIC taxpayers which financially support MedAccess and helping signal appropriate country-by-country price points for co-financing. In addition, VBTP would be most effective when complemented by the following conditions, which would allow for healthy market competition: • Affordable and predictable LMIC government co-financing during aid transition A VBTP system could be used in tandem with aid, especially in the context of aid transition. Development partners are imposing increasing requirements LMICs to take on part or all of the cost for select products. VBTP can help inform decisions about the appropriate price point for country co-financing of donor-funded products; for example, LMICs could be asked to pay up to the locally-affordable value-based price, while donors pay the remainder of the purchase price (Claxton, 2007; Claxton et al., 2011). 4 See here for Kenya’s recently announced commitment to take on the funding of GeneXpert, a POC diagnostic introduced and financed so fat by GFATM. It is not clear what price the government of Kenya will pay for the machine or the cartridges. In summary, VBTP can improve the value-for-money of health aid, benefiting both HIC taxpayers and aid beneficiaries, including LMIC governments. • A functional regulatory system trusted by consumers and professionals; • Purchasing/reimbursement and price negotiation arrangements through a national or subnational payer able signal willingness to pay based on budgetary constraints; and • A functional healthcare system through which the population can consistently access procured health products. • A competitive, quality-assured generics market, resulting in significant price reductions in following patent expiry; • Acceptance of the current patent system for most products (with possible exceptions for antimicrobials, and other specific cases) and with modest modifications to prevent abuses observed under the status quo (e.g. to remove practices such as evergreening). Potential challenges Countries with large out-of-pocket markets. The VBTP approach would work well in countries where a single or handful or purchaser/payers make reimbursement decisions for the entire population. But despite progress, most LMICS still lack insurance coverage for a majority of the population; most still purchase medicines out of pocket. The demand curves for individual patients’ out-of-pocket demand are very from population level willingness to pay, making it harder to implement any form of VBTP, especially as the poorest and sickest individuals tend to be the most price sensitive. External reference pricing. One major obstacle to a global VBTP system is the risk posed by external reference pricing, Page 10 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 where some countries or payers benchmark the prices that they are willing to pay to the prices paid by other countries or payers. Such a system may achieve short-term price reductions for individual payers, but in the long run external reference pricing leads prices to converge towards a single global price—likely close to the current high prices observed in the United States due to the and pull of the American market (see theory section for further discussion of this phenomenon). Although the difficulties are considerable, the potential gains are large. And despite national and EU legislation, pooled procurement and joint price negotiation (with different prices per country) are already taking place through country coalitions such as BeNeLuXa for select products. Further, the current political appetite in the US to reduce prices can make VBTP—which would likely result in lower than current price in the US—a politically viable option. To address this challenge, any individual healthcare system could adopt a value-based pricing and price negotiation mechanism with confidential rebates—some of which are already in use. The United Kingdom’s National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE), for example, negotiates confidential rebates with manufacturers to maintain a distinction between the observed price paid and the true net transaction price for the NHS. However, since confidential discounts are applied to each individual technology NICE assesses, it is still technically possible (though hardly straightforward) to identify the transaction price for each product, and for that price then to be referenced in other systems. Though this is rarely or never done in practice under the current international pricing system, expansion of VBTP to other large markets might create additional incentive to uncover the confidential prices achieved by other payers. What if a global agreement is not possible? Starting with NCDs or products affected by aid transition? An alternative starting point would include LMICs and development partners with a particular focus on one or more specific diseases (e.g. NCDs such as cancer and diabetes, or TB/malaria/HIV), products (e.g. vaccines, family planning commodities), or populations (e.g. displaced populations/refugees). Both countries and development partners have experimented with pooling procurement (e.g. see (Jack, 2019) and references therein for an overview; and (Wilkinson et al., 2016) for the EAC experience). However, neither donors nor national governments in LMICs have seriously considered combining such pooling together with some form of differential pricing. As an alternative to avoid some of these issues, one could envisage a two-way value-based rebate. This system would include a minimum volume/revenue guarantee offered to the manufacturer, and a maximum cost guarantee offered to the payer at the national (or international, in the case of a cross country pooled procurement mechanism) level. This would make it harder to identify transaction prices for specific products. The English NHS has applied this mechanism (where English regions could emulate national or subnational payers participating in an international value-based pooled procurement approach) (Nemzoff et al., 2019); see also Canada and its provinces where VBP has recently become law (Syam, 2014). Free riding and other challenges. As long as some countries remain outside a VBTP system, there remain incentives for some purchasers to free ride by selectively referencing lower prices from other systems. Importantly, this is not just a problem for VBTP, but applies to any pricing model besides a uniform single price. One way of addressing this challenge would be an international commitment to prevent parallel trade and/or external reference pricing, potentially administered and enforced through the WTP. However, arriving at such an agreement would be politically difficult; as just one example, the protection of parallel trade between EU states is enshrined in EU law). Even if this initial barrier could be overcome, further challenges would arise related to monitoring and enforcement; agreeing on and implementing a mechanism to calculate value-based prices in each healthcare system (e.g. capacity and technical constraints or gaming); and ensuring that real transaction prices remain difficult to detect. In the case of development partners, the Global Fund and Gavi have periodically considered price discrimination but abandoned it, in part due to technical and informational challenges and in part due to political pressure from disease and access to medicines advocates who fiercely (and correctly, in our view) oppose a model of value-based pricing dictated by the healthcare products industry5. The Global Fund’s Pooled Procurement Mechanism, StopTB’s Global Drug Facility, and UNICEF’s Supply Division are examples of pooled procurement—but they too tend to secure a single price across the countries on behalf of whom they buy, sometimes as a deliberate policy decision (though in some cases only specific countries, e.g. Gavi-eligible or transitioning countries, may be eligible for specific UNICEF vaccine prices). Market shaping efforts and volume guarantees do not consider incremental benefit-related value (other than price minimization through higher volumes) from the perspective of the purchaser or the end beneficiary. Instead the emphasis has traditionally been on volume guarantees (Lomas et al., 2018) and underwriting the risk of shortfalls or delays in payment. Countries have also tended to join forces for achieving a single price, with PAHO’s revolving fund for vaccines and the more recent strategic fund for NCDs and Hep C being cases in point. There again the fund insists on a single price across all participating countries. A similar approach for NCD products through PAHO’s strategic fund has proven less successful. We posit that insistence on a single price, delinked from payers’ incremental value, is no longer sustainable. Instead, in the context of aid transition, expanding UHC, and growth 5 Indeed advocacy groups such as MSF and Oxfam are keener on pooling patents instead—but the two approaches are not mutually exclusive. Page 11 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 of emerging markets’ purchasing model, pooled procurement coupled with VBTP becomes a viable proposition. In this case, a single product-specific purchaser representing a block of country payers would commit to purchasing the appropriate total volume at the average value-based (benefit-based) price—that is, the weighted average of VBPs across participating payers). For manufacturers, this would be equivalent to a situation of perfect price discrimination across the participating countries (or states/provinces in the case of large and diverse federal countries such as India and China). Each payer would then purchase at their particular value-based price from the single global purchaser. Existing mechanisms of underwriting payment risk, especially for poorer purchasers, could still apply as needed; however, country purchasers would play a major role in product selection and in assessing local value. Further research is required to scope out the viability of a global VBTP mechanism, its welfare impact and its distributional consequences. The future research agenda might include themes such as an analysis and evaluation of possible mechanisms and institutions; or applying game theory to understand the dynamic interactions between different actors in the healthcare system and consequent welfare effects. Important research questions include: •฀฀฀฀What are the benefits and drawbacks of alternative mechanisms/institutional options? •฀฀฀฀What is scale of potential value that different stakeholders could achieve through a functional VBTP mechanism? How large is this value relative to total current revenue or current health? Such an assessment would inform the appropriate effort (in time, resources, and political capital) that could be spent to achieve a workable VBTP process. Where do we start? No such single purchaser exists, but the Global Fund already purchases on behalf of most low- and middle-income countries for specific products. An endorsement of Health Technology Assessment by the routinely carried out by HICs and successful MIC health systems such Thailand and China, would allow it to assess value for each product across participating countries, ideally using accepted standards such as the iDSI Reference case, to inform country-specific prices (Lomas et al., 2018). Gavi could also play a similar role. This approach would benefit transitioning countries while also improving donors’ value for money and rationalizing co-financing requirements for beneficiary countries. Additional empirical research will be needed to address questions central to making a VBTP mechanism work, such as: •฀฀฀฀Shortlist of appropriate products for applying the VBTP mechanism and appropriate payers to join. Of course, the Global Fund, Gavi, and other specific donor institutions only cover limited disease areas. One might envision a similar approach for cancer drugs (e.g. biosimilars or biologics), autoimmune conditions, or diabetes products. Such pooling and VBTP would only work for products that are not commoditized (generics); in the latter case, different arrangements to increase the competitiveness of generics markets would be needed and VBTP would add little value. •฀฀฀฀Designing/agreeing/establishing an accountable process for coming to scientific value judgments about what the evidence and analysis suggests (drawing on the work of iDSI, DCP and others as well as national payers such as NICE, NIPH and HITAP). A research and action agenda What we propose is not an easy solution but a necessary step to progress the discussions regarding innovation and access to products in emerging economies. One of our reviewers highlights a series of challenges in making VBTP a reality. •฀฀฀฀How motivated would different players be to participate in this system? What could be done to better motivate players who would have less to gain? •฀฀฀฀Assessment of evidence-informed prices and volumes. •฀฀฀฀Assessment of health effects and system costs across the range of population subgroups that could benefit from a selected product (drawing on the iDSI Reference Case). •฀฀฀฀An estimate of thresholds relevant to each healthcare system, ideally distinguishing the effects of changes in public and private spend (plus their interaction with GDP per capita, drawing on previous work). Data availability No data are associated with this article. References Armstrong M, Vickers J: Price Discrimination, Competition and Regulation. J Ind Econ. 1993; 41(4): 335–359. Publisher Full Text of Automated Test Highlights Need for Better Health-Care Infrastructure in Many Countries. Nature. Nature Publishing Group. 2017; 551(7681): 424–425. Reference Source Bokhari FA, Gai Y, Gottret P: Government health expenditures and health outcomes. Health Econ. 2007; 16(3): 257–73. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Castro HE: Peer Review Report For: Value-based tiered pricing for universal health coverage: an idea worth revisiting [version 1; peer review: 1 approved]. Gates Open Res. 2020; 4: 16. Publisher Full Text Callaway E: TB Diagnostic Test Fails to Curb Cases: Poor Response to Roll-out Page 12 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Chalkidou K, Keller JM: Six Reasons Why the Global Fund Should Adopt Health Technology Assessment | Center For Global Development. 2017. Reference Source Jack A: Innovative Finance Schemes Increase Access to Medicine | Financial Times. 2019. Reference Source Claxton K: OFT, VBP: QED? Health Econ. 2007; 16(6): 545–58. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Kremer M, Snyder C: Preventives Versus Treatments Redux: Tighter Bounds on Distortions in Innovation Incentives with an Application to the Global Demand for HIV Pharmaceuticals. Cambridge, MA. 2018. Publisher Full Text Claxton K, Martin S, Soares M, et al.: Methods for the estimation of the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence cost-effectiveness threshold. Health Technol Assess. 2015; 19(14): 1–503. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Claxton K, Sculpher M, Carroll S: Value-based pricing for pharmaceuticals: Its role, specification and prospects in a newly devolved NHS. 2011. Reference Source Danzon PM: Price Discrimination for Pharmaceuticals: Welfare Effects in the Us and the Eu. Int J Econ Bus. 1997; 4(3): 301–22. Publisher Full Text Danzon PM, Chao LW: Cross-national price differences for pharmaceuticals: how large, and why? J Health Econ. 2000; 19(2): 159–95. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Danzon PM, Towse A: Differential pricing for pharmaceuticals: reconciling access, R&D and patents. Int J Health Care Finance Econ. 2003; 3(3): 183–205. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Danzon P, Towse A, Mestre-Ferrandiz J: Value-based differential pricing: efficient prices for drugs in a global context. Health Econ. 2015; 24(3): 294–301. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Doherty J, Kirigia D, Okoli C, et al.: Does expanding fiscal space lead to improved funding of the health sector in developing countries?: lessons from Kenya, Lagos State (Nigeria) and South Africa. Glob Health Action. 2018; 11(1): 1461338. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Lang D, Hill S: Differential Pricing of Pharmaceuticals: What About the Rest of the World? 2004. Reference Source Layson S: Market Opening under Third-Degree Price Discrimination. J Ind Econ. 1994; 42(3): 335–40. Publisher Full Text Lomas J, Claxton K, Martin S, et al.: Resolving the “Cost-Effective but Unaffordable” Paradox: Estimating the Health Opportunity Costs of Nonmarginal Budget Impacts. Value Health. 2018; 21(3): 266–75. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Lopert R, Lang DL, Hill SR, et al.: Differential pricing of drugs: a role for costeffectiveness analysis? Lancet. 2002; 359(9323): 2105–7. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text MacQuilkan K, Baker P, Downey L, et al.: Strengthening health technology assessment systems in the global south: a comparative analysis of the HTA journeys of China, India and South Africa. Glob Health Action. 2018; 11(1): 1527556. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Malueg DA, Schwartz M: Parallel imports, demand dispersion, and international price discrimination. J Int Econ. 1994; 37(3–4): 167–95. Publisher Full Text Dumoulin J: Global Pricing Strategies for Innovative Essential Drugs. Int J Biotechnol. 2001; 3(3–4): 338–49. Publisher Full Text Martin S, Rice N, Smith PC: Does health care spending improve health outcomes? Evidence from English programme budgeting data. J Health Econ. 2008; 27(4): 826–42. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Edney LC, Haji Ali Afzali H, Cheng TC, et al.: Estimating the Reference Incremental Cost-Effectiveness Ratio for the Australian Health System. Pharmacoeconomics. 2018; 36(2): 239–52. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Moon S, Jambert E, Childs M, et al.: A win-win solution?: A critical analysis of tiered pricing to improve access to medicines in developing countries. Global Health. 2011; 7(1): 39. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Fudenberg D, Tirole J: Customer Poaching and Brand Switching. Rand J Econ. 2000; 31(4): 634. Reference Source Morton A, Arulselvan A, Thomas R: Allocation rules for global donors. J Health Econ. 2018; 58: 67–75. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Gallet CA, Doucouliagos H: The impact of healthcare spending on health outcomes: A meta-regression analysis. Soc Sci Med. 2017; 179: 9–17. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Muchangi J: Government to Take over Costs of TB Drugs for Sh1 Billion. 2019. Reference Source Gershon N, Berchenko Y, Hall PS, et al.: Cost effectiveness and affordability of trastuzumab in sub-Saharan Africa for early stage HER2-positive breast cancer. Cost Eff Resour Alloc. 2019; 17(1): 5. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Government launches health technology assessment to inform policy decision making Nairobi, KENYA, 18 March 2018. MINISTRY OF HEALTH. (n.d.). Retrieved February 19, 2020. Reference Source Grubert N: Cross-Border Collaboration on Drug Pricing and Procurement Takes Another Step Forwards | LinkedIn. 2019. Reference Source Haasis MA, Ceria JA, Kulpeng W, et al.: Do Pneumococcal Conjugate Vaccines Represent Good Value for Money in a Lower-Middle Income Country? A CostUtility Analysis in the Philippines. Edited by Bernard Beall. PLoS One. 2015; 10(7): e0131156. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Mujumdar S, Pal D: Do Price Ceilings Abroad Increase U.S. Drug Prices? Econ Lett. 2005; 87(1): 9–13. Publisher Full Text Nemzoff C, Chalkidou K, Over M: Aggregating Demand for Pharmaceuticals Is Appealing, but Pooling Is Not a Panacea | Center For Global Development. 2019. Reference Source Ochalek J, Lomas J, Claxton K: Estimating health opportunity costs in lowincome and middle-income countries: a novel approach and evidence from cross-country data. BMJ Glob Health. 2018; 3(6): e000964. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text PMPRB: Working Group to Inform the Patented Medicine Prices Review Board (PMPRB) Steering Committee on Modernization of Price Review Process Guidelines Final Report. 2019. Reference Source Privett N, Yadav P: Analysis of the Procurement and Pricing Architecture for New Vaccines. Working Paper. New York, NY. 2012. Hausman JA, Mackie-Mason JK: Price Discrimination and Patent Policy. Rand J Econ. 1988; 19(2): 253–265. Reference Source Ramsey F: A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation. Econ J. 1927; 37(145): 47–61. Publisher Full Text Hellerstein R, Akerlof G, Pranab B, et al.: Do Pharmaceutical Firms Price Discriminate Across Rich and Poor Countries? Evidence from Antiretroviral Drug Prices | Request PDF. 2004. Reference Source Reich MR, Bery P: Expanding Global Access to ARVs: The Challenges of Prices and Patents. Academic Press. 2005; 324–350. Publisher Full Text Hill A, Gotham D, Fortunak J, et al.: Target prices for mass production of tyrosine kinase inhibitors for global cancer treatment. BMJ Open. 2016; 6(1): e009586. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Hollingworth S, Gyansa-Lutterodt M, Dsane-Selby L, et al.: Implementing health technology assessment in Ghana to support universal health coverage: building relationships that focus on people, policy, and process. Int J Technol Assess Health Care. 2019; 1–4. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Institute of Medicine (US) Forum on Drug Discovery, Development, and Translation: 2. Current Model for Financing Drug Development: From Concept Through Approval. Breakthrough Business Models: Drug Development for Rare and Neglected Diseases and Individualized Therapies: Workshop Summary. Washington (DC): National Academies Press (US); 2009. Reference Source Isabelle LN, Karla D, Gertjan M, et al.: Horizon Scanning for Pharmaceuticals: Proposal for the Beneluxa Collaboration. 2017. Reference Source Schäferhoff M, Martinez S, Ogbuoji O, et al.: Trends in global health financing. BMJ. BMJ Publishing Group. 2019; 365: l2185. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Scherer FM: A Note on Global Welfare in Pharmaceutical Patenting. World Econ. 2004; 27(7): 1127–42. Publisher Full Text Schmalensee R: Output and Welfare Implications of Monopolistic Third-Degree Price Discrimination. Am Econ Rev. 1981; 71(1): 242–47. Reference Source Schwartz M: Third-Degree Price Discrimination and Output: Generalizing a Welfare Result. Am Econ Rev. American Economic Association. 1990. Reference Source Silverman R: Projected Health Financing Transitions: Timeline and Magnitude - Working Paper 488 | Center For Global Development. 2018. Reference Source Surgey G, Chalkidou K, Reuben W, et al.: Introducing health technology assessment in Tanzania. Int J Technol Assess Health Care. 2019; 1–7. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Page 13 of 22 Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Syam N: Regional Pooled Procurement of Medicines in the East African Community. 2014. Reference Source Tandon A, Cain J, Kurowski C, et al.: Intertemporal Dynamics of Public Financing for Universal Health Coverage: Accounting for Fiscal Space Across Countries. DISCUSSION PAPER December 2018. 2018. Reference Source Tantivess S, Chalkidou K, Tritasavit N, et al.: Health Technology Assessment capacity development in low- and middle-income countries: Experiences from the international units of HITAP and NICE [version 1; peer review: 2 approved]. F1000Res. 2017; 6: 2119. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text van der Tol A, Lameire N, Morton RL, et al.: An International Analysis of Dialysis Services Reimbursement. Clin J Am Soc Nephrol. 2019; 14(1): 84–93. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Vallejo-Torres L, García-Lorenzo B, Serrano-Aguilar P: Estimating a costeffectiveness threshold for the Spanish NHS. Health Econ. 2018; 27(4): 746–61. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Varian HR: Price Discrimination and Social Welfare. Am Econ Rev. 1985; 75(4): 870–75. Reference Source Watkins DA, Yamey G, Schäferhoff M, et al.: Alma-Ata at 40 years: reflections from the Lancet Commission on Investing in Health. Lancet. Lancet Publishing Group. 2018; 392(10156): 1434–1460. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text WHO: The Selection and Use of Essential Medicines Report of the WHO Expert Committee on Selection and Use of Essential Medicines, 2019 (Including the 21st WHO Model List of Essential Medicines and the 7th WHO Model List of Essential Medicines for Children). 2019. Reference Source Wilkinson T, Sculpher MJ, Claxton K, et al.: The International Decision Support Initiative Reference Case for Economic Evaluation: An Aid to Thought. Value Health. 2016; 19(8): 921–28. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text Woods B, Revill P, Sculpher M, et al.: Country-Level Cost-Effectiveness Thresholds: Initial Estimates and the Need for Further Research. Value Health. 2016; 19(8): 929–35. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Yadav P: Differential Pricing for Pharmaceuticals Review of Current Knowledge, New Findings and Ideas for Action. 2010. Reference Source Page 14 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Open Peer Review Current Peer Review Status: Version 2 Reviewer Report 05 March 2020 https://doi.org/10.21956/gatesopenres.14289.r28584 © 2020 Nepomnyashchiy L. This is an open access peer review report distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Lyudmila Nepomnyashchiy Community Health Acceleration Partnership (CHAP), New York City, NY, USA Summary of the article: This article provides a case for why the global health community should embrace value-based tiered pricing as an approach to incentivizing innovation sustainably while optimizing access to life-saving, cost-effective products. The article provides a literature review on the value of differential pricing and focuses significantly on what could be done specific to LMICs, including the roles that donors, partners and countries could play. The article also reviews specific challenges and potential solutions that could be explored. Specific suggestions: In Background, paragraph 2: It might be good to more explicitly call out how MICs will have reduced eligibility for development assistance for health. It would be good to prove that this is true (we know that 36/73 GAVI countries will transition away from GAVI assistance by 2030, not sure what the plan is for GF). Background, paragraph 4: It's not clear why 40-55% of budgets spent on health products doesn't cover the population sufficiently. If you were able to contrast that with the percentage of the population that can access NHIS, then it would demonstrate what I think you want to say which is that they spend too much money on commodities while covering a limited percentage of the population. The example of vaccines entering LMICs isn't that applicable yet because Kenya & Ghana are GAVI countries for some time. In the same paragraph, the explanation on how new technologies put pressure on decision-making and raise the stakes to assess opportunity cost is really helpful. However, it's not clear what is cost-effective that is being crowded out. The rest are examples of new technologies that are requiring a lot more money from countries but the opportunity cost isn't clear (perhaps a few examples of those would be helpful much like the stream of examples of the pricey commodities). Theory and evidence on pricing models & differential pricing - Overview: Paragraphs 4 & 5 might benefit from a graph that shows various scenarios & implications (in Page 15 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Paragraphs 4 & 5 might benefit from a graph that shows various scenarios & implications (in particular the deadweight loss from a single price) - readers who don't have an economic background might get confused otherwise. Challenges in conventional differential pricing: Another point that may be relevant to highlight in this section might be related to a few other factors that drive up high prices in LMICs, namely: volatile demand (a supplier can't start and stop production, there are fixed costs and lots of inefficiencies without visibility on capacity needs; prices may be high to compensate for uncertainty with demand). Suppliers' limited visibility on demand in LMICs limits their ability to schedule production, procurement and deliveries. The solution to this becomes standardized, centralized and longer-term procurement (mentioned later in the procurement architecture section). Additionally, any special regulatory approvals or packaging also adds to cost (common with LMICs). In research and action agenda - I think it would be helpful to dig a bit into what it would take to get to the pre-requisites mentioned previously (e.g., many LICs are way off from functional regulatory systems!) and to have some idea of how those pre-requisites compare in terms of impact (high/medium low) and feasibility within LMIC settings where these pre-requisites are weak. An argument could be made that VTBP would strengthen all of that - and starting with 1-2 products could sow the seeds for this on a wider scale (e.g., like HITAP?). The reason why I said 'partly' for different views & opinions is because this is mentioned in the end as a suggestion for further research (alternative mechanisms/institutional options). Why should LMICs embrace VBTP vs. other pricing policies? How should pharmaceutical policy evolve in these challenging circumstances? I suspect that is enough for another paper and this one should focus but just wanted to call this out. Perhaps it is possible to reference alternatives earlier on (besides just one global price which is described well theoretically but not practical). Is the rationale for the Open Letter provided in sufficient detail? Yes Does the article adequately reference differing views and opinions? Partly Are all factual statements correct, and are statements and arguments made adequately supported by citations? Yes Is the Open Letter written in accessible language? Yes Where applicable, are recommendations and next steps explained clearly for others to follow? Yes Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed. Reviewer Expertise: pricing policies in LMICs, optimizing medicine access in LMICs from market shaping and delivery perspectives. I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of Page 16 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard. Reviewer Report 02 March 2020 https://doi.org/10.21956/gatesopenres.14289.r28582 © 2020 Mestre-Ferrandiz J. This is an open access peer review report distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Jorge Mestre-Ferrandiz Department of Economics, Universidad Carlos III, Madrid, Spain This paper by Chalkidou and colleagues is very timely and relevant, providing a nice summary of the different theories underpinning the various forms and types of ‘differential pricing’ to improve access to medicines globally, but in particular in low and middle-income countries (LMICs). The authors also provide a roadmap for next steps, which policy makers should certainly reflect and act upon, in my view. I have advocated before for value-based differential pricing (VBDP) – and while value based tiered pricing (VBTP) as considered by Chalkidou et al. has some important nuances on the factors affecting (relative) price levels relative to VBDP (i.e. prices should not be based solely on average income per capita), the same overarching principles apply. Thus, I would support the recommendations offered by this timely paper that “While VBTP is no magic bullet for universal LMIC access to medicines, it holds the potential to move countries forward toward universal health coverage (UHC)”. I have three main comments related to three broad issues which the authors could provide further thoughts and insights, given their relation with VBTP: 1. First, authors could discuss in greater detail the use of differential pricing within countries, especially in middle income countries where income inequality is high. I assume the same rationale applies to global VBTP, and where benefits of VBTP could be maximised? I believe there is already some examples of differential pricing across countries (see for instance the work published by Access to Medicine Foundation here and here). 2. The authors discuss nicely some of the pre-requisites and challenges of implementing VBTP, but I miss a discussion of the implications of the WHA Resolution on “transparency of prices”, and in particular whether these moves hinder or favour VBTP. I feel that the implications of this resolution are wider than “just” affecting the feasibility of VBTP; specifically on VBTP, it could potentially hinder its application as it could leave little room for different prices globally. 3. I think one of the most important comments of this paper is: “The debate, therefore, is not about the value of differential pricing per se but rather how differential pricing should be structured; how it should distribute surplus between the manufacturer and buyer(s); and, relatedly, how it should trade off between dynamic and static efficiency.” I am aware of other work from the authors discussing how to distribute the surplus, but I was wondering if the authors could provide their view on how this distribution could be agreed? I have a number of other minor points, which are generally about clarifying some of the comments made by the authors. These are as follows: Page 2: “leading to tensions between different global agencies and country governments that further Page 17 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Page 2: “leading to tensions between different global agencies and country governments that further complicate this issue”: this seems a very important barrier/challenge – any recommendations from authors on how to resolve part of these tensions? Page 3: “they later recoup their upfront investments and earn profits by selling successful pharmaceutical innovations at prices well above marginal cost, protected by term-limited patents”: Agreed with this comment, although it could be possibly argues that companies will recoup their R&D costs IF they earn profits sell from a successful innovation (rather than AND). Page 3: “Prices are not determined by the costs of R&D; however, the size of investment in R&D is determined by the expectations of the global prices manufacturers are likely to command for the products in development”. I agree prices should not be determined by R&D costs, although we still have examples of cost-plus price regulation? Also, I would argue the size of investment in R&D is indeed determined by price expectations, but this factor will not be the only one determining R&D expenditure. Page 3: “Since post-hoc sales indirectly fund R&D in this way,”: directly, rather than indirectly? Page 4: “Even though Ramsey pricing can be welfare efficient, it may not be consistent with the goal of improving access to LMICs”. Why do authors argue Ramsey pricing may not be consistent with this goal? Page 4: “Without consensus on what would be the socially acceptable rate of return for the manufacturer, the selected price differentials often transfer a larger portion of surplus to the manufacturer, making it similar to a price discriminating monopolist”: I have two comments with this sentence. First, is there any evidence supporting the point that manufacturers receive a larger proportion of surplus? Second, I would argue that if we could reach a global consensus on VBTP, agreeing an acceptable rate of return would be much easier to do – albeit still complicated! Page 4: the reference to Scherer (2004) is about an alternative way of having differential pricing, although not for the same product, but by having multiple products. Page 4: ref to Hellerstein et al., (2004): out of curiosity, does this article comment on impact on access to ARVs of not having differential pricing? Page 5: “In addition, while overall welfare may be higher, tiered pricing may allow producers to charge a margin which is far higher than the amount needed to recoup R&D investments and production costs (Moon et al., 2011)”. Is this an opinion by Moon et al, or do they offer empirical evidence about the level of margins? Page 5: “or through competition (via compulsory licensing)”: This phrase could imply that compulsory licensing is the only way to increase competition, but I would argue there could be better ways to promote competition (both therapeutic and generic) other than via compulsory licensing. Table 1: this is a nice summary table – I was wondering if we should consider whether the context where treatment is dispensed (primary care pharmacy or hospital) could affect the feasibility of differential pricing? Page 6: “Many LMICs are already using or exploring value assessment (through health technology assessment) to inform their procurement/price negotiation and reimbursement decisions,…”: although in the Background section you mention that “The lack of a clear architecture for pricing and prioritization of health products continues to be a major impediment to achieving UHC” and that many health products get funded that should not be funded? Page 18 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 funded that should not be funded? Figure 1: this is also a nice Figure – one question I have is whether the two options under “Coordination mechanism and/or pooled procurement” are mutually exclusive or complementary? Page 7, and references to “Estimates of the marginal productivity of health expenditure”: these estimates are certainly very useful, but I would argue the authors need to also flag some of the critiques around these estimates (e.g. here). Moreover, even though authors provide a reference (Woods et al, 2016) to argue that these estimates could be used to give some indication of possible values for lower income countries, it could be seen as an inconsistency with other remarks you make about the important differences across countries. I would welcome the authors own views on this issue. Page 7: Paragraph starting “VBTP therefore offers…”: Could VBTP imply higher prices in some countries vs status quo? Page 7: “By using the benefits-based price as the starting point/ceiling price in negotiations with industry, country payers can ease budget pressure, making collective or universal coverage more politically and financially sustainable”: I agree with this point, but if VBTP is used to set maximum prices, then further negotiations leading to price discounts would imply that the “net” price will not really reflect “value”? Page 9: Section on “Pre-requisites for VBTP”: I miss in this section having separated markets as a pre-requisite; for example, with the current system of international reference pricing, is VBTP feasible? Page 9: “The demand curves for individual patients’ out-of-pocket demand are very from population level willingness to pay,”: missing word “DIFFERENT” between “are” and “very” i.e. out-of-pocket demand are very DIFFERENT from population… Page 10: Refs Nemzoff et al., 2019 and Syam, 2014: Do the authors think these 2 initiatives merit a bit more information? Page 10: “and access to medicines advocates who fiercely (and correctly, in our view) oppose a model of value-based pricing dictated by the healthcare products industry.”: I guess everyone opposes to anything that is dictated by any single agent. We need some kind of overall agreement. Page 11: “Assessment of evidence-informed prices and volumes”: list or net prices? Is the rationale for the Open Letter provided in sufficient detail? Yes Does the article adequately reference differing views and opinions? Partly Are all factual statements correct, and are statements and arguments made adequately supported by citations? Partly Is the Open Letter written in accessible language? Yes Where applicable, are recommendations and next steps explained clearly for others to follow? Page 19 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 Where applicable, are recommendations and next steps explained clearly for others to follow? Yes Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed. Reviewer Expertise: Economics of life sicences industry I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard. Version 1 Reviewer Report 10 February 2020 https://doi.org/10.21956/gatesopenres.14278.r28537 © 2020 Castro H. This is an open access peer review report distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Hector E. Castro Pharmaceutical Economics & Financing, Management Sciences for Health (MSH), Arlington, VA, USA The document is relevant and very interesting, and opens an opportunity for global debate. However, it will require some adjustments: 1. "private companies pay upfront for pharmaceutical R&D (though they often benefit from public sector investments in basic scientific research and early stage R&D)” - add a couple of references here (page 2). 2. Maybe add a graph to contrast high, low and potential optimal price? (page 3). 3. "Manufacturers must be able to securely separate economic markets based on demand elasticity" – perhaps it is worth mentioning the effect on demand due to forced displacement of big chunks of the population from one LMIC to a neighboring country affecting elasticity of demand? (page 4). 4. "Many LMICs have highly skewed income distributions, making it more lucrative to cater to richer segments of society than the more voluminous poorer classes" (page 4) - perhaps mention something about the ability of LMICs to aggregate demand on behalf of the population through UHC? Reducing skimming of those able to pay? “This is exacerbated by relatively low levels of pooling; most purchase decisions, in practice, are made by individuals" - this applies mostly to LIC, but worth discussing the case of MIC (page 5). 5. "Pooled procurement has been deployed, for example...Pan-American Health Organization (PAHO) Revolving Fund for Vaccines" (page 6) – it is worth adding the Strategic Fund from PAHO for Hep C and other costly drugs. 6. "Under VBTP, prices in each country should be based on a health system’s willingness to pay, Page 20 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 6. "Under VBTP, prices in each country should be based on a health system’s willingness to pay, where willingness to pay reflects the actual, assessed value of the product within that market/health system (‘value-based pricing’) (See Figure 1) (Claxton, 2007)" (page 6) - is this a realistic assumption with resources available in LMICs? Should be added as a major challenge. 7. "Many LMICs are already using or exploring value assessment (through health technology assessment) to inform their procurement/price negotiation and reimbursement decisions, including Thailand, China, India, Ghana, South Africa, the Philippines, Indonesia, Brazil Mexico, Colombia, Kenya and Tanzania" (page 6) – this is worth clarification, there are many ad-hoc exercises with different levels of success and political buy-in. 8. "Potential challenges (pages 9-11) - What if a global agreement is not possible?": Competing agendas of donors vs burden of disease and needs of LMICs? Lack of systematic priority setting in many LMICs? Starting with NCDs or products affected by aid transition? Or by local burden of disease? Who should play the role of the agency? A global body, regional clusters or local bodies to decide and inform on VBTP? Limited local capacities to assess value? The issue of using thresholds with limited/low quality data or by-passing mechanisms to grant market access affecting elasticity of demand (i.e. judicial intervention)? Inability to say 'no'? Lack of trust and political will from payers and manufacturers? Two sides of the coin advocates for TRIPS flexibilities vs full access to innovation regardless of cost? Other variables affecting ex-factory prices of medicines (e.g., mark ups, taxes)? Transition from donations to tier pricing (i.e. commodities for NTDs)? The issue of oligopolies under unfair competition/low quality standards (i.e. branded generics)? Lack of ability to mobilize more resources for health of many LMICs affecting cash flows? Even if interventions are worth doing? Is the rationale for the Open Letter provided in sufficient detail? Yes Does the article adequately reference differing views and opinions? Partly Are all factual statements correct, and are statements and arguments made adequately supported by citations? Partly Is the Open Letter written in accessible language? Yes Where applicable, are recommendations and next steps explained clearly for others to follow? Partly Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed. Reviewer Expertise: Health systems, pharmaceutical policies, health technology assessment, health financing, health economics, market dynamics, health reform Page 21 of 22 Gates Open Research Gates Open Research 2020, 4:16 Last updated: 05 MAR 2020 I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard. Author Response 19 Feb 2020 Lydia Regan, Center for Global Development, UK We thank the reviewer for his comments; we have amended the paper including a reference to his review, to address his points. In brief, we have added more references as requested, explained/qualified various statements and pointed to his review for a list of challenges in making VBTP a reality. Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed. Page 22 of 22