Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

The BRICs and the Washington Consensus: An introduction

Review of International Political Economy, 2013
...Read more
The BRICs and the Washington Consensus: An Introduction Cornel Ban and Mark Blyth, editors Review of International Political Economy (forthcoming) Over the past two decades the spread of ideas and policies associated with the Washington Consensus (WC) has captured the attention of political economists. As a systemic feature of the global economy this process of diffusion has merited such scholarly attention. However, the systemic shock of the Great Recession has called into question the oft-noted convergence of rising economic powers such as Brazil, Russia, India and China (BRICs) along with their supposed relationship to the WC policy paradigm. Indeed, the crisis has brought to the fore the question of whether the BRICs have ‘grown apart’ from both the ideas and the policies prepared for them by Washington-based institutions. To date there has been no systematic scholarly effort aimed at analyzing the spread of WC ideas and policies in relation to the rise of the BRICs. This special issue attempts to fill in this gap through six contributions that bring together scholars interested in the political economy of development and the sociology of ideational and institutional change. Their main finding is that the BRICs attempted to balance their adoption of select parts of the WC template while defending and often reinventing the relevance of state-led development policies under the guise of being compliant with the WC itself. In so doing, they have neither pioneered a post-neoliberal transformation, nor have they proved to be simply forces for the continuation of WC ideas and policies in the global economy. Two questions therefore animate this special issue: What did the Washington Consensus look like in practice? And how have the BRICs appropriated, adopted, adapted, or abandoned specific aspects of this transnational policy paradigm? These are important questions for scholars of international political economy because they cut to the heart of ongoing debates taking place in several social science disciplines concerning the diffusion of liberal economic ideas and the remaking of global economy (Meseguer 2005; Jordana and Levi-Faur 2005; Simmons et al 2008; Orenstein 2010; Gilardi 2010; Hurrell and Narlikar 2006; Waquant 2011; Peck 2011). The BRICs have a special role in this drama. As a group of emerging economies, they started out as a mere Goldman Sachs investment meme a decade ago and yet went on to become one of the few beacons of the global economy during the Great Recession. They even formed an inter-governmental alliance of South-South cooperation 1 with an 1 Interestingly, the BRICS group is a lot less institutionalized and less coherent than IBSA, a platform for intergovernmental cooperation between India, Brazil and South Africa. While the BRICS is a more heterogenous group, the IBSA are all developing economies, with democratic regimes, net debtor positions, current account deficits, floating exchange rates and no permanent seats in the UN Security
ambitious agenda in international economic institutions. 2 What makes them particularly interesting to us however is that although these countries went through their impressive growth spurts in an international context dominated by neoliberal economic ideas and narratives about the dos and don’ts of development, they nevertheless reclaimed the role of the state in development far beyond the limits of the WC framework. The BRICs have a greater degree of policy autonomy from WC core institutions -the World Bank and the IMF – then other states in the so-called ‘Global South’ (Woods 2006; Pop-Eleches 2008). Given this and their systemic importance in the global economy the BRICs stand as critical cases where we can examine the domestic dynamics of WC support and contestation. The added value of this special issue is threefold. First, we examine the relationship between the BRICs and the Washington Consensus over time and attempt to extract the dynamics of this interaction for the BRICs as a group. As such, the contributors examine the ideas and institutions of this transnational policy paradigm while explaining why and how they were reproduced, modified, or contested in the domestic politics of each state. Second, while calls for interdisciplinarity are many, their realization in focused empirical work is harder to come by (e.g. Simmons et al 2008). This special issue contributes to this emerging literature by hosting contributions from political science and sociology. The efforts of four political scientists to illuminate the workings of the individual cases (Cornel Ban, Peter Rutland, Rahul Mukherji and Matthew Ferchen) are framed by the insights of sociologists working on the transnational institutional devices of the WC (Sarah Babb) and its economic ideas respectively (Marion Fourcade). Finally, the case studies approach the topic from varying theoretical perspectives that seek to specify the political conditions under which economic ideas play a critical role in institutional transformations. In the remainder of this introduction we unpack these issues. In the first section we review the relevant literature, briefly discuss the genealogy of the BRICs as a concept, and then showcase how the WC was practiced by the international financial institutions. In the next section we present the main findings of the case studies. In the final section we outline several ways that the special issue contributes to existing scholarship on policy diffusion in the international political economy. From Basic Concepts to the State of the Art In a recent study Leon Wansleben (2013) examined the conceptual genealogy of the term BRICs via the investment discourses and statistical tools used by Goldman Sachs. Wansleben traced the origins of the BRICs concept through the common classificatory regimes of investment banks. He traced the concept’s journey across the boundaries demarcated in these classificatory regimes between low-risk developed economies and Council. Despite this, the IBSA have remained in the shadows of public and scholarly attention while the BRICS have been in a great deal of limelight (Emerson 2012). 2 Since 2011 the BRICS have had several annual summits and even announced they might establish a multilateral bank. So far, beyond a number of aspirational statements, attempts at further institutionalization have been delayed.
The BRICs and the Washington Consensus: An Introduction Cornel Ban and Mark Blyth, editors Review of International Political Economy (forthcoming) Over the past two decades the spread of ideas and policies associated with the Washington Consensus (WC) has captured the attention of political economists. As a systemic feature of the global economy this process of diffusion has merited such scholarly attention. However, the systemic shock of the Great Recession has called into question the oft-noted convergence of rising economic powers such as Brazil, Russia, India and China (BRICs) along with their supposed relationship to the WC policy paradigm. Indeed, the crisis has brought to the fore the question of whether the BRICs have ‘grown apart’ from both the ideas and the policies prepared for them by Washington-based institutions. To date there has been no systematic scholarly effort aimed at analyzing the spread of WC ideas and policies in relation to the rise of the BRICs. This special issue attempts to fill in this gap through six contributions that bring together scholars interested in the political economy of development and the sociology of ideational and institutional change. Their main finding is that the BRICs attempted to balance their adoption of select parts of the WC template while defending and often reinventing the relevance of state-led development policies under the guise of being compliant with the WC itself. In so doing, they have neither pioneered a post-neoliberal transformation, nor have they proved to be simply forces for the continuation of WC ideas and policies in the global economy. Two questions therefore animate this special issue: What did the Washington Consensus look like in practice? And how have the BRICs appropriated, adopted, adapted, or abandoned specific aspects of this transnational policy paradigm? These are important questions for scholars of international political economy because they cut to the heart of ongoing debates taking place in several social science disciplines concerning the diffusion of liberal economic ideas and the remaking of global economy (Meseguer 2005; Jordana and Levi-Faur 2005; Simmons et al 2008; Orenstein 2010; Gilardi 2010; Hurrell and Narlikar 2006; Waquant 2011; Peck 2011). The BRICs have a special role in this drama. As a group of emerging economies, they started out as a mere Goldman Sachs investment meme a decade ago and yet went on to become one of the few beacons of the global economy during the Great Recession. They even formed an inter-governmental alliance of South-South cooperation 1 with an                                                                                                                 1  Interestingly,  the  BRICS  group  is  a  lot  less  institutionalized  and  less  coherent  than  IBSA,  a  platform   for  intergovernmental  cooperation  between  India,  Brazil  and  South  Africa.  While  the  BRICS  is  a  more   heterogenous  group,  the  IBSA  are  all  developing  economies,  with  democratic  regimes,  net  debtor   positions,  current  account  deficits,  floating  exchange  rates  and  no  permanent  seats  in  the  UN  Security   ambitious agenda in international economic institutions.2 What makes them particularly interesting to us however is that although these countries went through their impressive growth spurts in an international context dominated by neoliberal economic ideas and narratives about the dos and don’ts of development, they nevertheless reclaimed the role of the state in development far beyond the limits of the WC framework. The BRICs have a greater degree of policy autonomy from WC core institutions -the World Bank and the IMF – then other states in the so-called ‘Global South’ (Woods 2006; Pop-Eleches 2008). Given this and their systemic importance in the global economy the BRICs stand as critical cases where we can examine the domestic dynamics of WC support and contestation. The added value of this special issue is threefold. First, we examine the relationship between the BRICs and the Washington Consensus over time and attempt to extract the dynamics of this interaction for the BRICs as a group. As such, the contributors examine the ideas and institutions of this transnational policy paradigm while explaining why and how they were reproduced, modified, or contested in the domestic politics of each state. Second, while calls for interdisciplinarity are many, their realization in focused empirical work is harder to come by (e.g. Simmons et al 2008). This special issue contributes to this emerging literature by hosting contributions from political science and sociology. The efforts of four political scientists to illuminate the workings of the individual cases (Cornel Ban, Peter Rutland, Rahul Mukherji and Matthew Ferchen) are framed by the insights of sociologists working on the transnational institutional devices of the WC (Sarah Babb) and its economic ideas respectively (Marion Fourcade). Finally, the case studies approach the topic from varying theoretical perspectives that seek to specify the political conditions under which economic ideas play a critical role in institutional transformations. In the remainder of this introduction we unpack these issues. In the first section we review the relevant literature, briefly discuss the genealogy of the BRICs as a concept, and then showcase how the WC was practiced by the international financial institutions. In the next section we present the main findings of the case studies. In the final section we outline several ways that the special issue contributes to existing scholarship on policy diffusion in the international political economy. From Basic Concepts to the State of the Art In a recent study Leon Wansleben (2013) examined the conceptual genealogy of the term BRICs via the investment discourses and statistical tools used by Goldman Sachs. Wansleben traced the origins of the BRICs concept through the common classificatory regimes of investment banks. He traced the concept’s journey across the boundaries demarcated in these classificatory regimes between low-risk developed economies and                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                           Council.  Despite  this,  the  IBSA  have  remained  in  the  shadows  of  public  and  scholarly  attention  while   the  BRICS  have  been  in  a  great  deal  of  limelight  (Emerson  2012).     2  Since  2011  the  BRICS  have  had  several  annual  summits  and  even  announced  they  might  establish  a   multilateral  bank.  So  far,  beyond  a  number  of  aspirational  statements,  attempts  at  further   institutionalization  have  been  delayed.     high-risk developing economies, and through the assumptions regarding return expectations and the risks assigned to states by these distinctions. The BRICs concept, as crafted by Goldman Sachs, re-narrated a specific cluster of large emerging economies as safe, long-term financial asset providers using a broad array of financial industry narrative and calculative devices. A decade later, as sovereigns in the European capitalist core were experiencing levels of distress once thought to be specific to developing countries (Gabor and Ban 2013), the BRICs not only increased their share of the world economy. They took the performance of Goldman Sachs’ concepts to an advanced level by organizing BRICS summits, debating a joint intervention in the Eurozone crisis, and even discussing the possibility of a BRICS bank. Indeed, one would be hard pressed to find a better illustration of the relevance of the performativity of a financial product in the global economy (MacKenzie et al 2007). However, perhaps more important for our purposes here, common understandings about world trade as a largely North-North and North-South phenomenon have been definitively challenged by the BRICs boom of outward investment in both developed and developing countries (Gammeltoft 2008; Santiso 2008; Pradhan and Singh 2009; Pradhan 2011; Milelli et al 2010; Gallagher and Porzecanski 2010; 2011; Wójcik and Burge 2010; Sweet 2010; Filippov 2011). The BRICs have shaped developments in the Global North too, not only in investment and trade by putting downward pressure on inflation in developed countries (Baudry 2012), and through the de-linking stock prices in their own financial systems vis-à-vis the US financial markets during the financial crisis (Xu and Hamori 2012; Ono 2011). Old Western niches of high value added privilege like IT and advanced manufacturing are today challenged by the BRICs as never before. Indeed, the most salient question becomes how this extremely disparate group of countries managed such impressive growth rates and sectoral expansions in the first place? The answers given by mainstream economists tend to conform to mainstream growth theories. Some of these authors see revolutions in labor reallocation and, in the case of Brazil, labor formalization as contributors to massive increases in labor productivity and subsequent growth (de Vries et al 2012). Others see the rise of the BRICs in terms of human capital (Ardichvili et al 2012). Such findings are valuable, yet they give short shrift to the BRICs’ engagement with the policies of the WC and the economic ideas that undergird it. In the light of the extensive political science literature on the domestic workings of the WC one may be inclined to expect political scientists to study these dynamics. Yet the few political scientists who have examined the BRICs focus on foreign policy issues (Laidi 2012; Hooijmaaijers and Keukeleire 2012; Glosny 2009; Roberts 2009), the BRICs role in global governance institutions (Larionova 2012; Isachenko 2012), or their role in development aid (Rowlands 2013).3 Similarly, most of the work on BRICs done by political economists has focused on individual countries or, at best, on China-India                                                                                                                 3  For Zaki Laidi (2012), for example, the BRICs do not seem to be willing to converge with the liberal internationalism of the G7 as they remain wedded to a realist view of national sovereignty and international institutions. Zooming into this issue Hooijmaaijers and Keukeleire (2012) have explored the voting cohesion of the BRICs in the UN General Assembly committees.   comparisons (Saad-Filho and Morais 2012; Kröger 2012; Ye 2009; Tsai 2007; Hsueh 2012; D’Costa 2012a; 2012b; Mukherji 2010; Appel 2004; 2008; Appel and Orenstein 2012; Johnson 1994; 2001; 2000; Lane 2008; Rutland 2008; Robinson 2011). This narrowness of focus provides us with a unique opportunity for interdisciplinary scholarship to systematically analyze how the BRICs compare with each other with regard to one very significant and specific issue: their translation of the WC’s ideas and policies and how this impacted their pathways to growth. Policy Paradigm Adoption as a Process of Translation The articles that make up this special issue examine the Washington Consensus as a policy paradigm whose boundaries shifted over time and place. During the past two decades of its existence, the Consensus survived several major crises that appeared to disconfirm the economics on which it was based. This in turn led to what might be described as several rounds of ‘edits’ cut into the original version proposed by John Williamson in 1991 (Rodrik 2006; Peck et al 2010; Birdsall and Fukuyama 2011; Shepperd and Leitner 2012; Blyth 2013; Babb this issue). But the transformations of the ideational and institutional bases of this paradigm in the aftermath of those crises should not be construed as a sign of its weakness. Instead, they should be seen as evidence of its adaptability to countervailing political and economic dynamics (Peck 2010). Sarah Babb frames the special issue through a close empirical analysis of the dynamic interventions through which the Bretton Woods institutions, rather than intellectual framers such as John Williamson or Dani Rodrik, developed and deployed the Washington Consensus in their actual policy interventions. Unlike previous understandings of the Consensus as either purely an intellectual framework or as a simple list of policies, Babb defines it as a contested and evolving transnational policy paradigm straddling the political and scholarly fields. Her contribution provides the special issue with a model and a periodization of the WC: its rise, high influence, weakening and crisis. Babb proposes a novel analytical framework for understanding the political mechanisms of this transnational policy paradigm. According to her, attention to the coercive mechanisms wielded by IFIs should be complemented by a close reading of the relationship between the U.S. Congress, on the one hand, and the IMF and the World Bank, on the other. Without a good understanding of domestic American politics one would gain only a partial understanding of the politics of diffusing the WC around the world. Yet for all the discussion of the WC in the context of its actual use by IFIs, during the past decade new industrial and skill revolutions in China and India, and commodity booms in Brazil and Russia, enabled these large emerging markets to evade the policy conditionality used by Washington-based IFIs. The contributions of Cornel Ban, Matthew Ferchen, Rahul Mukherji and Peter Rutland follow Baab’s contribution and take a closer look at how each of these countries dealt with the WC in an international political and economic environment largely deprived of the IFI’s main tool of this transnational policy paradigm: international policy conditionality. How the BRICs tore at the Fabric of the Washington Consensus In each of the case studies examined we find that the adoption of the core liberal economic ideas of the WC dramatically altered the domestic ideational and institutional landscape of each case. But we also find that the policy imperatives demanded by these ideas were only selectively institutionalized. The most important pattern is that in all four countries, the role of the state as a critical actor in development was rediscovered and reestablished in ways that go far beyond the modest institutionalist turn experienced by the WC after the East Asian crisis (Wade 2009; Fine and Jomo 2005). The endurance of heterodox economic traditions at a domestic level, the endogenous dynamics of the political system, and the extent to which corporate interests or mass publics mobilized against pro-WC technocratic elites have all contributed to bringing the state back in once again. The result of which was a proliferation of institutional and ideational hybrids that bore the imprint of distinctive ‘edits’ of the original WC to make them compatible with the domestic context. These findings must however be interpreted with caution. These hybrids do not constitute a qualitatively different type or constitute a new and fundamental challenge to the current capitalist order (Apeldoorn et al 2012). Nor do they serve as solid evidence for some counter-hegemonic “state capitalist” economic model (Bremmer 2009; Aligica and Tarko 2012). Sympathetic with these warnings, Matthew Ferchen notes how a back-to-back comparison of the Washington Consensus (WC) and the so-called ‘Beijing Consensus’ (BC) conceals more than it reveals, arguing instead that the focus should be on the domestic politics in play in each half of this comparison. Peter Rutland’s study of the travails of the WC in Russia, in contrast, shows how the WC can in fact simply be ignored. Meanwhile, Cornel Ban’s tracing of the WC’s imbrication in the Brazilian political economy and Rahul Mukherji’s focus on the causal mechanisms that powered India’s partial, albeit genuine, turn to the WC provide still other examples of editing and hybridization. While Ban and Rutland’s findings hinge on the endurance of the high commodity prices that sustain the Brazilian and Russian economies, Ferchen and Mukherji see mostly political challenges to the status quo in China and India. Ban shows that Brazil’s policy elites engaged quite consciously with the WC policy paradigm. They “edited” it and “grafted” its ideas and institutions onto pre-existing domestic heterodox traditions. The result of this process has been the gradual crafting of a so-far sustainable alternative to the WC that recovers the importance of the state in development. Specifically, continuing commitment to mainstream ideas about macroeconomic discipline have been layered in Brazil with policy positions that emphasize heterodox debt management in good times (reduced reliance on foreign finance) and heterodox countercyclical interventions in times of crisis (off-the-books fiscal stimuli through public development banks, expansionary minimum wage policy, and controls on capital flows). Brazil’s state managers engaged in bold privatization campaigns while consolidating the state’s role as owner and investor in financial institutions able to fund industrial, innovation and credit policies. Deregulation was only selectively pursued in the case of the financial industry and, in defiance of the WC, it left few traces in the labor market. Finally, the conditional cash transfer programs certified as legitimate by the latest incarnation of the WC were followed by heterodox wage and employment policies. Ban captures the hybridity of this policy regime that blends the WC with heterodox economics as a hybrid that pursues growth with redistribution through an inclusionary state activism that avoids the wrath of financial markets. Like Brazil, India also institutionalized a hybrid form of economic governance that lies between the WC policy paradigm and domestic institutional imperatives. Yet unlike Ban’s study of Brazil, Rahul Mukherji’s study of India’s is less concerned with the details of the hybrid. Mukherji instead attempts to unpack the causal generators of India’s paradigm shift of 1991 in order to explain where its hybrid form today came from. He argues that in India this process was neither driven simply by capitalist interests, nor was it the result of the IMF’s coercive interventions. Mukherji also dismisses the established narrative that the turn from import substitution to deregulation and globalization was the inevitable result of the balance of payments crisis of 1991. First Mukherji notes the increasing influence of neoclassical ideas about development in the late 70s and 1980s that reached a tipping point in elite policy circles during the balance of payments crisis of 1991. To strengthen this thesis Mukherji shows that similar reforms had been tried earlier, but without the preparatory ideational work, and as a result they failed. Second, Mukherji argues that the actual institutionalization of these ideas by India’s state was negotiated with a coalition of industrialists, professionals and farmers, whose political power filtered out some of the key elements of the WC (labor deregulation, the removal of farm subsidies, the liberalization of the retail sector and of sectors considered strategic). As such, ideas and interests together explain the trajectory of the Indian case. Ferchen’s study of contemporary China focuses primarily on illuminating how Chinese elites try to make sense of the WC and come up with alternatives to it. He shows that a checklist comparison points to a general correspondence between the WC and Chinese policy goals and instruments. Yet as it is the case with the other BRICs, this correspondence registers several important local deviations in such areas as exchange rate policy, capital controls, selective privatization, and an industrial policy centered on stateowned industrial champions. Ferchen’s analysis of China pushes the diagnoses offered by the contributions to this special issue in a new direction. That is, while China exhibits several forms of state intervention in the economy that give Chinese capitalism a distinctly non-WC flavor, these local adaptations do not necessarily amount to the antithesis of, or an alternative to, the WC. Western observers of China often juxtapose a “Beijing Consensus” (BC) model of development to the WC and assume that that the BC is a coherent model shared by a wide spectrum of Chinese policy stakeholders. Ferchen disagrees and shows that what matters about the BC, to the extent that it actually exists, is not its content per se, but how policymakers on both shores of the Pacific understand it. His in-depth analysis of the economic ideas of Chinese elites finds that any attempt to compare the policy implications of the WC with the institutional dynamics of China’s political economy is problematic because such a comparative exercise is inherently political among domestic actors themselves. Thus, Communist Party, New Left and neoliberal intellectual leaders use the WC as a weapon in their ideational struggles. In short, Ferchen shows us how the politics of the WC in China is a politics of authority and legitimacy among domestic elites as much as it is a dispute over appropriate modes of economic policy. As such, any analysis of the political economy of China would be incomplete without understanding the politics of ideas in this “clash of consensuses.” Turning to Russia, Peter Rutland does not find a “Moscow Consensus” (MC) standing in sharp contrast with the Washington Consensus either. Instead, Rutland argues that two sets of factors converged to bring Russia where it is today. First, he shows that the interests of managerial elites and would-be oligarchs that preyed on state resources and converted their political capital into economic capital checked the enthusiastic embrace of WC by the governing Russian technocratic elite during the 1990s. Despite this checkmating, Russian governments of this period did in fact implement the core prescriptions of the WC. Yet despite these massive policy interventions policy Potemkin villages dotted the policy landscape everywhere in postcommunist Russia. The reasons for these policy failures constitute Rutland’s second set of actors. This has more to do with the ideational environment of Russia in the 1990s than simply the material environment in which they operated. Specifically, he argues that although reformists inspired by the WC tried to forge a pro-reform coalition by bridging nationalist and economically liberal discourses, this attempt failed because in the Russian context it was hard to package market liberalization as a re-assertion of Russian national identity. As such, a new form of checkmate, and ideational one, was placed on top of the political one. Putin’s governments of the 2000s attempted to break this state of affairs in two ways. On the one hand, they reasserted state power and curbed the political power of the oligarchs by integrating security and military elites in the government apparatus. This raised the state’s share of the economy by reasserting state control over strategic sectors such as energy and banking. But on the other hand, and relative to Brazil and even China, Russia’s rediscovery of the economic role of the state did not translate into significant efforts to curb rising inequalities, with the country’s super-class even experiencing a renewed boom under Putin. In this latter period, Russia’s commodity boom and its subsequent decoupling from IFI conditionality enabled Russian governments to treat the WC less like a policy straitjacket and more like a malleable set of policy constraints within which radical policy experimentation become possible. Cases, Comparisons and Theoretical Extensions All four case studies share a theoretical perspective that seeks to specify the political conditions under which ideas play a critical role in institutional change. Ban introduces to political economy a perspective on institutional change rooted in the sociology of translation that enables back-to-back comparisons between institutional originators and domestic localizations via distinctive sets of institutional complementarities. By putting hybridity on a par with paradigms, this approach contributes to emerging debates in political economy that challenge paradigm-centric analyses (see also Carstensen 2011). Ferchen and Mukherji put ideas at the core of their analysis, but approach them from different perspectives. Mukherji employs a brand of bridge-building constructivism that parses out points of difference and overlap between idea-based and interest-based account of institutional change. This approach is now common in research on economic ideas, but Mukherji makes an important analytical innovation by emphasizing the understudied gradualism of ideational change and the role of tipping points rather than critical junctures. While constructivists tend to look at new economic ideas as playing a central role in moments of crisis (punctuated equilibrium), this author shows that in order for them to move the building blocks of policy in such moments they should have already reached a tipping point in their lengthy journey through the corridors of power. Absent this kind of process, institutional change is unlikely. While Mukherji tries to refine our understanding of the causal role of ideas in the timing of new policy paradigms, Ferchen invites us to focus instead on the politics of ideas as weapons in domestic struggles over who has authority and legitimacy. He proposes a framework that gives pride of place to domestic contention over WC ideas. Ferchen sees this as part of an critical elite-level competition to shape the political economy of China, thus opening up a new avenue of research for political economists who study ideas: the politics of legitimacy via model comparison and adoption. Marion Fourcade’s essay concludes the special issue by examining both the material and the symbolic constitution of the BRICs. Summing up the findings from the empirical studies of the special issue, she stresses that in the BRICs, a territory where the IMF has not intervened of late, the Consensus has become “more invisible than irrelevant,” in the sense that its contents have been adapted to local conditions by policy elites. She complements this analysis of the material construction of the BRICs with a more symbolic reading. Fourcade suggests that the term BRICs became a financial and policy asset in and of itself thanks to the outsider status of Brazil-Russia-India-China relative to the dominant discursive and political fields. In addition to the positive markers assigned to them by the financial industry, the media and the BRICs' leaders themselves, what united these countries was their exclusion from the dominant ideologies and institutional infrastructures of the world economy. This is important, Fourcade also notes, because the simultaneous moral and economic upgrade of the BRICs following Goldman Sachs’s sustained marketing campaign coincided with the stigmatization of Southern Europe (PIGS). This symbolic flip, Fourcade suggests, highlights the role of morality plays in the economy, the centrality of markets’ symbolic power and the financial markets’ insatiable appetite for new sources of profit. Conclusions and implications for future research The BRICs reassertion of the role of the state in development is one of the most consequential events of the global economy. This special issue is an early attempt to understand some of its internal dynamics by connecting the BRICs models of capitalism to specific ideational debates. To do so, the contributors show how ideas shape policy outcomes after having been filtered by political and economic processes situated at both the domestic and the international levels of analysis. In the unfolding drama domestic interest groups, policy intellectuals, and other interested agents compete over different societal projects using international ideas that complicate the simple core-periphery model of the diffusion of economic ideas and institutions. The result is not the simple reproduction of what Western policy innovators say or certify. Instead, one encounters hybrids and even mistranslations that follow from domestic political struggles facilitated by the ever-widening policy space created by the growing weight of the BRICs in the global economy. Yet this reassertion and resuscitation of the state that we find in the BRICs was neither predetermined nor widely shared. Indeed, it may constitute the (partial) exception rather than the rule). Some countries reduced the economic role of the state to the supply of institutional and material resources demanded by foreign direct investment. In Eastern Europe for example, the result was the transformation of autonomous local economies into dependent internationalized economies that constitute little more than assembly platforms for the semi-standardized goods of multinational corporations (Nölke and Vliegenthart 2009; Ban 2013). Others went further even. For example the Baltic countries joined the global economy by eviscerating most of the state’s economic functions (Bohle and Greskovits 2012). In other contexts the state was rediscovered in a different way. Brazil’s liberal brand of neo-developmentalism is arguably much closer to the reformist versions of the WC than are the economic models of Venezuela or Argentina (Wylde 2011; 2012; Riggirozzi 2010; Bresser-Preira 2012; Balestro 2013), while being much further from it than Mexico’s (Theret and Bizberg 2012; Gallagher and Shaffedin 2010). In other words, the BRICs could have been different than the difference that they already exhibit. This special issue is an attempt to tell us why these political economies look the way they do. Further research is needed to explain on a more systematic basis the diffusion of the Washington Consensus in the BRICs. Crucially, more work is needed to explain how the dynamic of their autonomy relative to the coercive apparatus of the IFI has enabled more state-led development interventions than it would have been the case otherwise. This means more research on how the BRICs were exposed to the IFIs acting not as coercive political forces, but in their capacity as platforms for normative debate (Hurrell 2003; Park and Vetterlein 2010; Weaver 2010 ), agents of elite socialization (Finnemore and Barnett 2004; Momani 2006; Chwieroth 2009) or norm innovators (Acharya 2012). Looking at the relationship between BRICs and the IFI using this constructivist conceptual apparatus may open up a new research agenda on how BRICs elites negotiated their understandings of the Consensus with the very managers of this policy paradigm. In this regard, the space for experimenting with more heterodox ideas about development was perhaps significantly larger. This research agenda becomes even more pressing as BRICs profile in IFIs is increasing following the ongoing process of quota revision or the heightened profile of BRICs representatives at the highest levels of the IFIs. Finally, more research is needed on the role of mass publics in the BRICs engagement with Consensus orthodoxy. This scope of this special issue is constrained by an elite bias that future scholarship needs to temper. This is especially the case for contexts such as the BRICs because they have more domestic autonomy in addressing the Polanyian tension between the push towards the self-regulation of the market mechanism suggested by the underlying ideology of the Consensus and the protective arrangements against its externalities that mass publics can be expected to demand. This may entail more comparative work on a wide range of issues, from the politics mass political movements and the politics of financial market actors to the dynamics of everyday political economy (Hobson and Seabrooke 2007). Bibliography Appel, Hilary. 2004. New Capitalist Order: Privatization and Ideology in Russia and Eastern Europe. University of Pittsburgh Press. Appel, Hilary, and Mitchell A. Orenstein. 2012. “Ideas Versus Resources: Explaining the Flat Tax and Pension Privatization Revolutions in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union.” Comparative Political Studies. Ardichvili, Alexandre, Elena Zavyalova, and Vera Minina. 2012. “Human Capital Development: Comparative Analysis of BRICs.” European Journal of Training and Development 36 (2/3) (April 6): 213–233. Ban, Cornel. 2013. From Cocktail to Dependence: The Great Recession and the Transformation of Romanian Capitalism. SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2215124. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network. Berg, Andrew, and Yanliang Miao. 2010. “The Real Exchange Rate and Growth Revisited: The Washington Consensus Strikes Back?” IMF Working Papers: 1– 24. Birdsall, Nancy, and Francis Fukuyama. 2011. New Ideas on Development After the Financial Crisis. Johns Hopkins University Press. Blyth, Mark. 2012. “Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea.” OUP Bohle, Dorothee, and Béla Greskovits. Capitalist Diversity on Europe's Periphery. Cornell University Press, 2012. Bosworth, B., and S. M. Collins. 2007. Accounting for Growth: Comparing China and India. National Bureau of Economic Research. Bremmer, Ian. 2009. “State Capitalism Comes of Age.” Foreign Affairs 88 (3): 40–55. Carstensen, Martin B. 2011. “Paradigm Man Vs. the Bricoleur: Bricolage as an Alternative Vision of Agency in Ideational Change.” European Political Science Review 3 (1): 147–67. Chaudhary, Latika, Aldo Musacchio, Steven Nafziger, and Se Yan. 2012. Big BRICs, Weak Foundations: The Beginning of Public Elementary Education in Brazil, Russia, India, and China. Working Paper 17852. National Bureau of Economic Research. Chwieroth, Jeffrey M. 2009. Capital Ideas: The IMF and the Rise of Financial Liberalization. Princeton University Press. D’Costa, Anthony P. 2009. “Economic Nationalism in Motion: Steel, Auto, and Software Industries in India.” Review of International Political Economy 16 (4): 620–648. ———. 2012. Globalization and Economic Nationalism in Asia. OUP Oxford.. Desai, M. 2008. India & China: An Essay in Comparative Political Economy. Critical Quest. http://new.palgrave.com/PDFs/1403943516.pdf. Filippov, S. 2011. “Russia’s Emerging Multinational Companies Amidst the Global Economic Crisis.” UNU-MERIT Working Paper (2011-003). http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1856518. Gabor, Daniela, and Cornel Ban. "Fiscal Policy in Financialized Times: Investor Loyalty, Financialization and the Varieties of Capitalism." Financialization and the Varieties of Capitalism (SSRN January 16, 2013) (2013). Gallagher, K., and R. Porzecanski. 2010. The Dragon in the Room: China and the Future of Latin American Industrialization. Stanford University Press. Gammeltoft, Peter. 2008. “Emerging Multinationals: Outward FDI from the BRICS Countries.” International Journal of Technology and Globalisation 4 (1) (January 1): 5–22. Gilardi, Fabrizio. 2010. “Who Learns from What in Policy Diffusion Processes?” American Journal of Political Science 54 (3): 650–666. Grugel, Jean, and Pía Riggirozzi. 2012. “Post-neoliberalism in Latin America: Rebuilding and Reclaiming the State After Crisis.” Development and Change 43 (1): 1–21. Vom Hau, Matthias, James Scott, and David Hulme. 2012a. “Beyond the BRICs: Alternative Strategies of Influence in the Global Politics of Development.” European Journal of Development Research 24 (2): 187–204. Hobson, John M., and Leonard Seabrooke. 2007. Everyday International Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hooijmaaijers, Bas, and Stephan Keukeleire. 2012. “Voting Cohesion of the BRICS Countries in the UN General Assembly: Analysis and Possible Implications for EU Foreign Policy.” May. https://lirias.kuleuven.be/handle/123456789/346895. Hsueh, Roselyn. 2012. “China and India in the Age of Globalization.” Comparative Political Studies 45 (1): 32–61. Johnson, Juliet. 1994. “Should Russia Adopt the Chinese Model of Economic Reform?” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 27 (1): 59–75. ———. 2000. A Fistful of Rubles: The Rise and Fall of the Russian Banking System. Cornell University Press. ———. 2001. “Path Contingency in Postcommunist Transformations.” Comparative Politics: 253–274. Jordana, Jacint, and David Levi-Faur. 2005. “The Diffusion of Regulatory Capitalism in Latin America: Sectoral and National Channels in the Making of a New Order.” The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598 (1): 102–124. Kröger, Markus. 2012. “Neo-mercantilist Capitalism and Post-2008 Cleavages in Economic Decision-making Power in Brazil.” Third World Quarterly 33 (5): 887–901. Laïdi, Zaki. 2012. “BRICS: Sovereignty Power and Weakness.” International Politics 49 (5) (September): 614–632. doi:10.1057/ip.2012.17. Lane, David. 2008. “From Chaotic to State-led Capitalism.” New Political Economy 13 (2): 177–184. MacKenzie, Donald A., Fabian Muniesa, and Lucia Siu. 2007. Do Economists Make Markets?: On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton University Press. Meseguer, Covadonga. 2005. “Policy Learning, Policy Diffusion, and the Making of a New Order.” The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598 (1): 67–82. Milelli, C., F. Hay, and Y. Shi. 2010. “Chinese and Indian Firms in Europe: Characteristics, Impacts and Policy Implications.” International Journal of Emerging Markets 5 (3/4): 377–397. Momani, Bessma. 2006a. “Assessing the Utility of, and Measuring Learning from, Canada’s IMF Article IV Consultations.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 39 (2): 249. Mukherji, Rahul. 2010. India’s Economic Transition: The Politics of Reforms. Oxford University Press. http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:oxp:obooks:9780198069676. Nölke, Andreas, and Arjan Vliegenthart. 2009. “Enlarging the Varieties of Capitalism: The Emergence of Dependent Market Economies in East Central Europe.” World Politics 61 (4): 670–702. Orenstein, Mitchell A. 2010. Privatizing Pensions: The Transnational Campaign for Social Security Reform. Princeton University Press. Park, Susan, and Antje Vetterlein. 2010. Owning Development: Creating Policy Norms in the IMF and the World Bank. Cambridge University Press. Peck, Jamie. 2011. “Geographies of Policy From Transfer-diffusion to Mobilitymutation.” Progress in Human Geography 35 (6): 773–797. Peck, Jamie, Nik Theodore, and Neil Brenner. 2010. “Postneoliberalism and Its Malcontents.” Antipode 41 (s1): 94–116. Pop-Eleches, Grigore. 2008. From Economic Crisis to Reform: IMF Programs in Latin America and Eastern Europe. Princeton University Press. Pradhan, J. P. 2011. “Emerging Multinationals: A Comparison of Chinese and Indian Outward Foreign Direct Investment.” International Journal of Institutions and Economies 3 (1): 113–148. Pradhan, J. P., and N. Singh. 2008a. “Outward FDI and Knowledge Flows: a Study of the Indian Automotive Sector.” International Journal of Institutions and Economies 1 (1): 155–186. Robinson, Neil. 2011. “Russian Patrimonial Capitalism and the International Financial Crisis.” Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics 27 (3-4): 434–455. Rodrik, Dani. 2006. “Goodbye Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Confusion? A Review of the World Bank’s Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform.” Journal of Economic Literature 44 (4): 973–987. Rutland, Peter. 2008. “Russia as an Energy Superpower.” New Political Economy 13 (2): 203–210. Saad Filho, Alfredo, and Lecio Morais. 2012. “Neo-Developmentalism and the Challenges of Economic Policy-Making Under Dilma Rousseff.” Critical Sociology. Sandbrook, Richard, Marc Edelman, Patrick Heller, and Judith Teichman. 2007. Social Democracy in the Global Periphery: Origins, Challenges, Prospects. Cambridge University Press. Santiso, J. 2008. “The Emergence of Latin Multinationals.” Cepal Review (95): 7–30. Seabrooke, Leonard. 2007. “The Everyday Social Sources of Economic Crises: From ‘great Frustrations’ to ‘great Revelations’ in Interwar Britain.” International Studies Quarterly 51 (4): 795–810. Sheppard, Eric, and Helga Leitner. 2010. “< I> Quo Vadis</i> Neoliberalism? The Remaking of Global Capitalist Governance After the Washington Consensus.” Geoforum 41 (2): 185–194. Simmons, Beth A., Frank Dobbin, and Geoffrey Garrett. 2008. The Global Diffusion of Markets and Democracy. Cambridge University Press. Simmons, Beth, Frank Dobbin, and Geoffrey Garrett. 2007. “The Global Diffusion of Public Policies: Social Construction, Coercion, Competition or Learning?” Annual Review of Sociology 33: 449–472. Sweet, C. 2010. “Indian Pharmaceuticals in Brazil: Emerging Multinationals in Emerging Markets.” International Journal of Emerging Markets 5 (3/4): 398–422. Tsai, K. S. 2004. “Imperfect Substitutes: The Local Political Economy of Informal Finance and Microfinance in Rural China and India.” World Development 32 (9): 1487–1507. Tsai, Kellee S. 2007. Capitalism Without Democracy: The Private Sector in Contemporary China. Cornell University Press. De Vries, Gaaitzen J., Abdul A. Erumban, Marcel P. Timmer, Ilya Voskoboynikov, and Harry X. Wu. 2012. “Deconstructing the BRICs: Structural Transformation and Aggregate Productivity Growth.” Journal of Comparative Economics 40 (2) (May): 211–227. doi:10.1016/j.jce.2012.02.004. Wacquant, Loïc. 2012a. “Three Steps to a Historical Anthropology of Actually Existing Neoliberalism.” Social Anthropology 20 (1): 66–79. Wade, Robert H. 2011. “Emerging World Order? From Multipolarity to Multilateralism in the G20, the World Bank, and the IMF.” Politics & Society 39 (3): 347–378. Wansleben, Leon. 0. “‘DREAMING WITH BRICs’.” Journal of Cultural Economy 0 (0): 1–19. doi:10.1080/17530350.2012.756826. Weaver, Catherine. 2010. Hypocrisy Trap: The World Bank and the Poverty of Reform. Princeton University Press. Woods, Ngaire. 2006. The Globalizers: The IMF, the World Bank, and Their Borrowers. Cornell University Press.. Wylde, Christopher. 2011. “State, Society and Markets in Argentina: The Political Economy of Neodesarrollismo Under Nestor Kirchner, 2003–2007.” Bulletin of Latin American Research 30 (4): 436–452. ———. 2012. Latin America After Neoliberalism: Developmental Regimes in Post-Crisis States. Palgrave Macmillan.. Xu, Haifeng, and Shigeyuki Hamori. 2012. “Dynamic Linkages of Stock Prices Between the BRICs and the United States: Effects of the 2008–09 Financial Crisis.” Journal of Asian Economics 23 (4) (August): 344–352. doi:10.1016/j.asieco.2012.04.002. Ye, M. 2008. Embedded States| The Economic Transitions of China and India. Princeton University. Ye, Min. 2009. “Policy Learning or Diffusion: How China Opened to Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal of East Asian Studies 9 (3): 399–432.  
Keep reading this paper — and 50 million others — with a free Academia account
Used by leading Academics
Rachel E Smith
University of Aberdeen
Don Ross
University College Cork
Avni Önder Hanedar
Sakarya University
Gilberto Bercovici
Universidade de São Paulo