Theme Paper and Special Reports
Theme Paper and Special Reports
Theme Paper and Special Reports
I. Introduction
1. The crisis economies in this paper refer to the worst hit countries,
namely, Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand.
2. See Walter (1993) for a discussion of the di¬erent modes of nancial
contracting and a stylized model of the financial intermediation process. Also,
Harkansson (1999) argues that a developed bond market reduces systemic risk
and the probability of crisis.
6 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
The nancial systems of the four crisis economies are very di¬er-
ent. The economies of Indonesia and Thailand are easily characterized
as bank-centered nancial systems where banks are required to exert a
signicant monitoring role arising from both equity as well as debt ex-
posures. Malaysia has a more developed equity market, which suggests
better levels of investor protection and governance. This legal protec-
tion should both facilitate arms length bank nancing while also
encouraging disintermediated nancing. Meanwhile, the Republic of Korea,
with its chaebol structure, displays a web of interconnected corporate
cross-holdings. Added to the corporate control processes within these
nancial systems are the divergent inuences of the state, small groups
of founding families, and also shareholders, who are often poorly orga-
nized and lacking in political inuence. The mitigation of these agency
factors and the di¬erent degrees of development of institutional and
legal infrastructure have a¬ected the structure of the respective bond
and equity markets in the crisis economies.
The size of bond and equity markets and domestic bank lending
in the crisis economies at year-end 1998 is shown in Table 1. All crisis
economies have signicantly large banking sectors and much smaller
bond and equity markets. The table clearly shows how domestic nanc-
ing in these countries has traditionally relied on the banking sector.
Malaysia has the largest market for bank loans and equity market capi-
talization in relation to gross domestic product (GDP), while the Republic
of Korea has the largest corporate bond market in relation to GDP (27.3
percent), followed by Malaysia (5.1 percent), Thailand (2.6 percent), and
Indonesia (1.5 percent).
Expanding Long-term Financing 9
TABLE 1
Bank Loans, Corporate Bonds, and Equities in Asian Crisis Countries
and the US, End-1998
(percent of GDP)
TABLE 2
Outstanding Corporate Bonds in Asian Crisis Countries and the US
(percent of GDP)
TABLE 3
International Bank Lending to Crisis Economies
(in US$ billion)
Note: Asia includes Afghanistan; Bangladesh; Bhutan; British Overseas Territories; Brunei; Cambo-
dia; Peoples Republic of China; Fiji Islands; French Polynesia; India; Indonesia; Kiribati; Democratic
Peoples Republic of Korea; Republic of Korea; Lao Peoples Democratic Republic; Macao; Malaysia;
Maldives; Mongolia; Myanmar; Nauru; Nepal; New Caledonia; Pakistan; Papua New Guinea; Philip-
pines; Solomon Islands; Sri Lanka; Taipei, China; Thailand; Tonga; Tuvalu; US Pacic Islands; Viet
Nam; Wallis-Futuna Islands; Western Samoa. Singapore and Hong Kong, China are treated as o¬shore
banking centers and are not included.
Source: BIS (1999) Consolidated International Banking Statistics for End-June 1999 November and
BIS (1997), The Maturity, Sectoral and Nationality Distribution of International Bank Lending: Second
Half 1996, Basle July.
lending), this picture changed rapidly in the wake of the regional crisis,
with Asia accounting for only 35.4 percent of lending by June 1999. Of
this, the amount directed specically to the crisis economies fell from
37.8 percent in December 1996 to just 19.8 percent in June 1999. In
other words, not only has international lending shifted away from Asia
as a whole, but of the reduced funds lent to the region a greatly limited
sum has been allocated to the crisis economies.
This situation has ensued due to two factors. First, there is evidence
of a structural shift away from bank-intermediated lending by Japan7
owing to that countrys own domestic crisis and an aversion to yen-
denominated loans by regional borrowers. Thailand and the Republic of
Korea have experienced the smallest reduction in loans from Japan, while
Indonesia and Malaysia have been hardest hit.8 However, while the re-
duction in lending from Japan has been partly o¬set by lending from
European banks, the absolute quantity of loans has fallen. Second, the
reduction in lending reects rethinking by developed world lenders about
the creditworthiness of the Asian region as a whole and the crisis economies
in particular. This risk reassessment has been manifest in higher (credit)
spreads on bank intermediated loans and higher yields on bonds trading
in secondary markets. Though the price of debt has risen, the signicant
reduction in lending has increased liquidity concerns for the region.
Information on the average maturity of lending to Asia and to the
crisis economies is also provided in Table 3. At the peak of lending in
1996, most loans to Asia (61.5 percent) and the crisis economies (61.2
percent) had a maturity of less than one year. Though the maturity of
loans has subsequently been extended, the crisis economies still bor-
rowed 50.1 percent of loans as short maturities in June 1999. However,
this gure masks the fact that the increase in average loan maturity is
more a function of the nonrollover of short-term loans.
Though not recorded in Table 3, most international lending over
the period to the Republic of Korea was directed towards the banking
sector (from 65.9 percent in December 1996 to 57.4 percent in June
1999), while lending in the other three crisis economies was aimed at
the private sector (an average of 62.5 percent in December 1996 and
69.2 percent in June 1999). The anomaly in the case of the Republic of
Korea is probably due to the concentration of the banking market and
the nancial arrangements in place between the Korean chaebols. Other
key points relating to international lending to the crisis economies have
been the increase over recent years in levels of lending to the public
sector rather than to other industry sectors, and the fact that capital
inows through banks were not sensitive to movements in interest rate
di¬erentials, resulting in banks increasing their domestic lending once
they had borrowed unhedged from abroad.9
TABLE 4
International Bonds Issued by Asia-Pacic Economies
(US$ billion)
Note: Nepal, Democratic Peoples Republic of Korea, Pakistan, and Viet Nam are excluded from the
table since there were no international bond or note issues recorded. Crisis Economies are Indonesia,
Republic of Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand. Developed Economies are Australia, Japan, New Zealand,
and Singapore.
Source: BIS, International Banking and Financial Market Developments (various issues), Table 13
International Bonds by Nationality.
United Kingdom (UK), and US. Details of these issues are provided in
Table 4. In 1999, total international bond issues by crisis economies
(US$77.7 billion) were signicantly smaller than the intermediated -
nance o¬ered by international banks (US$160.7 billion). However, it
would be expected that these markets compete with one another on
e¹ciency criteria. The larger size of the intermediated nance market is
consistent with a higher entry or cost structure, and may well inhibit the
ability of the Asian crisis economies to tap this market as a debt alternative.
International bond nancing by the crisis economies has increased
from US$30.9 billion in 1995 to US$77.7 billion in 1999 (an increase
of 128 percent over the period). The Republic of Korea has been the
largest issuer, while the level of international bonds issued by Japan has
fallen, a function of the well-documented Japan premium, reecting
the higher yields demanded by investors holding yen bonds in o¬shore
markets. The international issues from the crisis economies have largely
focused on bond issues in the US market (termed yankee bond issues)
by quasi-government or sovereign borrowers. Though these securities
14 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
10. Domestic bond issues in the US must be registered with SEC under
the US Securities Act of 1933.
11. Bond credit rating agencies categorize corporate bond issuers into nine
major classes according to perceived credit quality. These ratings classes include
investment grade issuers: AAA, AA, A, and BBB, and noninvestment grades:
BB, B, CCC, CC, and C. Bonds with ratings below C are bonds in default or of
Expanding Long-term Financing 15
TABLE 5
Credit Ratings of Crisis Economies (as at 10 March 2000)
bankrupts. The two major agencies use slightly di¬erent notation to refer to
equivalent credit risk categories. Standard & Poors use upper-case capitals (e.g.,
AAA), while Moodys Investor Services use an upper case rst character and
have any remaining characters lower case (e.g., Aaa). This paper uses the Stan-
dard & Poors notation.
12. Worldwide, the US dollar is the most frequent currency of Eurobond
issue, with US$1,673.4 billion, followed by the Japanese yen at US$407.1 billion,
the Deutsch mark at US$369.4 billion, the pound at US$308.3 billion, the French
franc at US$191.3 billion, the Swiss franc at US$141.5 billion, the Italian lira at
US$117.9 billion, the Dutch guilder at US$105.3 billion, the ECU at US$99.3 billion,
and nally the Luxembourg franc with US$37.8 billion in outstandings (BIS, 1998
Table 13B).
13. See Chart 5, Kamin and von Kleist (1999:17) for graphical evidence of
the decline in spreads (19911997). Lenders favored Asian issues (e.g., spreads on
Latin American issues with the same characteristics as Asian issues were 39 percent
16 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
TABLE 6
Comparison of International Bank Lending and International Debt
Securities of Crisis Economies, 19961999
higher). This may be due to the fact that (i) Latin American and Eastern European
countries exhibited greater volatility than Asian economies (K and VK: 18), and/
or (ii) greater supply, since Latin American countries issue more bonds than
Asian countries (Eichengreen and Mody (1997). But as K and VK note, Asia,
while not issuing bonds, tends to take out more loans. This suggests economic
stability as the key factor for deciding spreads.
Expanding Long-term Financing 17
Implications
14. Capital Data Bondware (Euromoney) generally list the following rms
as the major bookrunners of emerging market bonds: JP Morgan, Merrill Lynch,
CSFB, Union Bank of Switzerland, and Lehman Brothers.
15. It is di¹cult to assess what issue size is necessary to maintain ad-
equate liquidity. One of the worlds largest Eurobond issuers (Federal Home
Loan Mortgage Corporation or Freddie Mac) suggests one bullet maturity issues
of at least US$4 billion every quarter. (Euromoney June 1998: Borrowers, A
Mad Rush for Liquidity).
18 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
TABLE 7
Financial Flows to Emerging Market Economies by Region
(US$ billion)
A. Background
TABLE 8
Domestic Debt Markets in Crisis Economies
Compared with Key Regional Economies
(US$ billion)
Australia 155.40 162.80 174.90 180.30 189.60 173.00 163.00 154.10 170.80
(% Public Sector) (71.36) (70.82) (69.41) (66.44) (63.98) (60.35) (57.98) (52.50) (50.50)
China, Peoples
Republic of 146.50 152.90196.40
(% Public Sector) (67.92) (64.94)
(64.97)
Hong Kong, China 29.00 29.00 30.60
(% Public Sector) (14.78) (14.48)
(18.96)
Indonesia* 0.8 1.1 1.9 1.8 1.3
(% Public Sector) (32.5)
Japan 5,394.30 5,095.20 4,979.80 4,862.00 4,548.70 4,663.70 4,438.10 4,329.90 5,130.80
(% Public Sector) (68.73) (69.66) (69.03) 0 0 (70.93) (70.74) (72.02) (72.05)
(70.12) (69.91)
Korea, Republic of 230.20 238.80 222.70 233.80 164.60 199.00 235.00
(% Public Sector) (18.77) (17.92) (19.08) (19.12) (19.56) (19.80) (21.40)
Malaysia 69.40 74.60 60.40 59.60 55.30 61.30
(% Public Sector) (43.66) (39.41) (37.42) (34.73) (37.25) (37.03
New Zealand 19.50 20.60 20.60 22.20 19.90 18.60 59.70 15.10 16.30
(% Public Sector) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (26.13) (100.0) (100.0)
Singapore 49.00 49.00 53.50 50.6 015.80 15.10 18.60
(% Public Sector) (94.90 )(94.90) (95.51) (95.45) (86.08) (86.09) (89.25)
Thailand* 6.50 10.9 11.3 12.1 10.8
(% Public Sector) (100.0) (30.3) (30.2) (26.8) (56.4)
Total: Crisis
Economies 320.20 307.4 268.2 308.4
Developed
Economies 5,569.2 5,278.6 5,224.3 5,113.5 4,811.7 4,905.9 4,676.6 4,514.2 5,336.5
All Domestic
Debt 5,569.2 5,278.6 5,558.1 5,530.1 5,217.5 5,321.1 5,179.9 5,054.1 5,980.1
Note: (i) The Table records the total (size) of domestic debt markets in US dollars as reported in Table 15 Domestic
Debt Securities, Bank for International Settlements International Banking and Financial Market Developments (vari-
ous issues) for Asia-Pacic and key regional economies. Nepal, Democratic Peoples Republic of Korea, Pakistan,
Philippines and Viet Nam are excluded from the Table since there were no domestic debt issues recorded; (ii) The
Crisis Economies are Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand; (iii) The Major Developed Econo-
mies are Australia, Japan, New Zealand, and Singapore; (iv) The gures in parentheses are the percentage of the
total issued by the public sector. The remainder is the amount of private sector domestic issues; (v) The March 1999
gures for Indonesia and Thailand were not published in the BIS Tables and are estimates based on the Reuters Fixed
Income Database; (vi) The pre-1999 gures for Thailand are year-end gures from the Bank of Thailand; (vii) The
pre-1999 gures for Indonesia are year-end estimates from Asiamoney, May 1999the decomposition by sector is not
available; (viii) The March 1998 gures for Singapore reect the di¬erent treatment of the issues by the Central
Provident Fund (CPF) of Singapore by the BIS. Pre-March 1998 data include these CPF bonds issues.
ties to quickly ll the domestic nancing gap. It was therefore not sur-
prising that domestic nancial institutions and industrial corporations
borrowed huge amounts of foreign funds, generally of short maturity (it
was possible to extend or rollover the borrowings). The major factors
that accelerated such borrowings were a substantial di¬erence between
domestic and foreign interest rates and a rigid foreign exchange policy,
causing a signicant appreciation of local currencies.16
Before the crisis, domestic lending rates were much higher in Indonesia
and Thailand than the one-year London interbank o¬ered rate (LIBOR)
rates on US dollar lending, while the gap between domestic and overseas
rates was moderate in the Republic of Korea and Malaysia. The gap between
the two rates in the early 1990s was as high as 1216 percentage points per
annum in Indonesia, and 58 percentage points per annum in Thailand. In
the rst two countries, domestic lending rates were generally roughly 25
times higher than the LIBOR each year. Under these circumstances, together
with the misalignment of exchange rates as discussed below, domestic
banks and corporations, as rational economic entities, must have made
best e¬orts to maximize their borrowing from international nancial markets.
The domestic interest rates in all the economies before the crisis
were much higher than international interest rates. Table 9 shows the
trends of interest rates in the crisis economies as well as in international
nancial markets.
TABLE 9
Comparisons of Domestic and Overseas Interest Ratesa
(percent per annum, period average)
16. An expectation that the local currency will not depreciate more than the
interest rate di¬erential between the two countries encourages unhedged foreign
currency borrowing. International parity relationships predict that over time interest
rate di¬erentials equal the actual depreciation or appreciation of floating-rate currencies.
22 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
TABLE 10
Purchasing Power Parity of Crisis Economies Currencies
(1990 ⫽ 100)
Combining the interest rate gap and the PPP index shows that
foreign borrowing was a protable precrisis nancial method in these
countries. International interest rates were always cheaper than local rates,
encouraging domestic rms and nancial institutions to borrow from
abroad. The borrowing was further protected by the exchange rate re-
gime that has continued to keep the local currencies overvalued, making
foreign loans even cheaper.
Expanding Long-term Financing 23
turnover, albeit very small, does exist. The Republic of Korea and Malaysia
also display very small levels of daily turnover even relative to small,
developed economies such as New Zealand. Another method of zero-
curve construction is through the implied zero rates from long-dated
forward contracts or currency swaps. The daily turnover of these instru-
ments is also very small, with Indonesia, Republic of Korea and Malaysia
having approximately US$1 billion of daily turnover, while Thailand
has US$2.3 billion. This volume in total is less than daily turnover in
New Zealand. It is clear that the use of alternate sources for the con-
struction of benchmark curves will be di¹cult, due to the lack of liquidity
in the underlying instruments.
TABLE 11.1
Foreign Exchange Derivatives Daily Turnover in
Selected Asia-Pacic Countries, April 1998
Local Turnover
Total Share to
Country Turnover Amount Total
(percent)
Australia 28.75 16.50 57.4
China, Peoples Republic of
Hong Kong, China 48.94 13.53 27.6
Indonesia 1.04 0.76 73.08
India 1.29 0.90 69.8
Japan 91.65 77.04 84.06
Malaysia 0.80 0.54 67.5
New Zealand 4.97 3.75 75.5
Philippines 0.40 0.28 70.0
Singapore 85.40 5.23 6.1
Korea, Republic of 1.05 0.32 30.4
Taipei,China 1.52 0.37 24.3
Thailand 2.28 1.93 84.6
UK 468.26 77.07 16.5
US 235.37 220.02 93.50
Note: 94.47 percent of World Average FX Derivatives Turnover is specied against the
US$. Turnover includes OTC forwards, FX swaps, currency swaps, and options.
Source: BIS Survey
28 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
TABLE 11.2
Interest Rate Derivatives Daily Turnover in
Selected Asia Pacic Countries, April 1998
A. Supply-Side Strategies
24. Note the Institute of International Finance Task Force on Risk Assessment
Report (2000:January) that species best risk management practice for the private
sector.
25. Note the Institute of International Finance report (1999:March): Report
of the Working Group on Emerging Markets Finance also recommended that this
information include the o¬-balance sheet positions of reporting institutions. See
this report for further details on data transparency and disclosure.
Expanding Long-term Financing 33
B. Demand-Side Strategies
TABLE 12
Issuance of Publicly O¬ered and Privately Placed Bonds by Non-Financial
Corporations in the US, 1975 to 1991
(US$ billion, annual rate)
C. Developing Infrastructure
agreement from Standard & Poors (SP). Another new agency, Kasnik,
Du¬ and Phelps, was licensed in 1997 and has recently become opera-
tional. PEFINDO has rated some 200 companies involving about 250
debt securities (including commercial paper-CP). Requirements for rat-
ing of listed bonds and CP have increased the demand for the services.
PEFINDOs relationship with SP has clearly helped it gain international
credibility. In the Republic of Korea three local agencies are in opera-
tion: Korea Management Consulting and Credit Rating Corporation
(KMCRC), Korea Investors Service (KIS), and the National Information
and Credit Evaluation Corporation (NICE). All publicly issued
nonguaranteed bonds must be rated by at least two credit rating agen-
cies and those corporations rated A or higher may issue nonguaranteed
bonds.31 However, postcrisis nonguaranteed bonds now make up the bulk
of the market, illustrating the development of rating services.
In general, however, local rating agencies are not particularly reli-
able, because of poor rating skills and techniques, limited sources of
information, and inadequate accounting practices of corporations. Part-
nership agreements with internationally reliable agencies such as SP or
Moodys, as in the case of Indonesia, will signicantly increase the reli-
ability of local rating agencies. In small countries, it would be advisable
to use these international agencies rather than to set up local agencies
in view of large xed operating costs.
31. The rating categories of these agencies are similar to Standard & Poors.
38 Government Bond Market Development in Asia
would assist the long-term viability of domestic bond markets. The es-
tablishment of uniform procedures would provide a rst step in this
direction. At the specic country level, policy e¬orts are being made
which provide some idea of the challenges ahead. For example, in Thai-
land the real-time delivery versus payment project (DvP) was started in
April 1998 and is due to be completed by the third quarter of 2000. A
real time bond price quotation system to newswire services has also
been established to improve information ows and pricing mechanisms.
Thailand also has a Master Plan to serve as an internal guideline for
policy implementation and coordination between agencies such as the
Thai Bond Dealing Center, Securities and Exchange Commission, and
the Ministry of Finance.
A. Background
Benchmark Yield Curves. One cannot separate concerns over the lack
of corporate and government benchmarks, as corporate pricing is based
on a spread over the government bond of equivalent maturity. Therefore,
governments in crisis economies also need to pursue strategies which
establish benchmark yield curves in o¬shore markets if inadequate infra-
structure and the lack of demand from domestic investors prevents them
from immediately doing so in domestic markets. Examples such as the
Philippines global bond issues in 1998 and 1999 serve as a benchmark
for other sovereign issues.
VII. Conclusions
Appendix
1. Indonesia
TABLE A.1
Summary of International Bank Lending to Indonesia
(19961999)
2. Republic of Korea
TABLE A.2
Summary of International Bank Lending to Republic of Korea
(19961999)
3. Malaysia
TABLE A.3
Summary of International Bank Lending to Malaysia
(19961999)
4. Thailand
TABLE A.4
Summary of International Bank Lending to Thailand
(19961999)
References