JB Case Study 3
JB Case Study 3
JB Case Study 3
Fierce competition
There is a standardized basis but Husky tries to do customization
Low switching costs
Difficult market to enter due to CAPEX requirements, a lot of investment associated with
this
Reputation is also important and specific knowledge is necessary
Substitutes for these machines? Not really, there are other technologies that you can use
for certain applications but no direct substitutes
Buyer power? The is some degree of buyer power. Big clients have higher buyer power,
also because of the bidding process
Not much supplier power because components are mainly standardized. In some areas
there may be some degree because of customization
Not such an interesting market to enter but probably OK if you are already there
Husky has been doing well historically. There is some degree of competitive advantage
Mold Business
Huskys Strategy
Type: Differentiation strategy. They are positioning themselves to offer clients something
with added value for a price premium. They offer faster and lighter products and high
performance machines that are very durable
Scope: They innovate. They specialize in PET bottles (very narrow scope in terms of the
nature of products that they do) and thin wall applications + packaging. Limited
economies of scope. No firm can make everything for everyone, there needs to be a
strategic focus. They also do added services and have a global market approach,
because they are choosing to be more narrow in terms of products and solutions they
need to be more global to have enough clients.
Activities: they need a lot of investment in R&D to sustain their strategy and competitive
advantage. Strong logistics and support structure as they want their clients to be very
reassured that they can provide service if something happens. They have a really skilled
internal sales force, offer complementary products that help clients maximize the value
they get from products they buy, training centers and very firm values in terms of
support and expectation.
If you are a differentiated producer you need to add extra value and that costs more money.
Clients only pay more if they benefit from it they dont pay more, they get more.
The crisis
- Change Strategy
Become general producer
- Do regardless off
Reduce costs, mostly in waste. They used to have a really good margin.
Drop the modd business
Class 2
The S-Curve: A New Forecasting Tool
The beginning of the S-curve represents the introduction of a new technology. Usually, a lot of
research is developed and a lot of try and error is made. The first products that are introduced
in a certain market are not perfect and some problems arise, which are taken care of and new
design concepts appear and other approaches are tried. In early stages of research, one
removes one impediment only to find another. And that is why the S-curve is so flat in the
beginning. Progress is made and we begin to ascend the S-curve of a certain technology. Then
another problem strike and has to be overcome. Progress is slow at first but then accelerates
and, with performance improvements, the curve becomes steeper.
For each new product (or process) the S-curve shows precisely how much performance has
improved and how much effort has been expended to gain that improvement. Usually
it shows us a rather long period of little progress followed by growing success.But the
progress can also work the other way as technological limits are approached. Rather than
showing more and more progress with less and less effort like at the beginning, at the end of
the S-curve each new step makes less and less progress and performance
improvement is rather slow when compared to the steeper part. We start to watch
diminishing returns.
The S-curve traces out the path of development of new products and processes with each
successive point on the curve representing an improvement in performance. The pattern of the
S-curve repeats itself again and again in industry after industry. These curves describe reality.
A forecasting tool if that is true and if the limit for an S-curve can
be predicted, then the S-curve can yield valuable insights. If we can define
important performance parameters, trace the early days of progress of these
parameters versus the effort to make that progress, and develop a point of view
on what the limits of these performance parameters are, then we have a basis for
foreseeing how much further current products can be improved and how much
effort it will take to get them to higher levels of performance. It will give insights
about how products will fare in the future, what new products to try to develop and
how much effort will be required to develop them. What we want to know is the
relationship between effort put and results achieved. You might think you should
be plotting results against the amount of time involved. But that would be an error.
It is not the passage of time that leads to progress, but the application of effort. If
we would plot against time spent we would be making assumptions about the rate
of effort applied. The forecasting error would be a result of bad competitive
analysis, not bad technology analysis. Thus, it such circumstances it might appear
that a technology still has a great potential but in fact what is fueling its advance
is rapidly increasing amounts of investment. At some point it gets more and more
expensive to develop each new generation of a certain product or technology.
The higher the slope, the more productive we are. Thus, a convenient way of
pinpoint where we are on a curve of results versus efforts is to talk about the slope or
productivity of the technical effort. At the start of the curve we need to put in significant
effort before we can expect to see results. Once the learning is done, we begin to make
significant progress for very little expenditure or effort. That usually does not last too
long. At some point we begin to approach the limits of the technology and we start to
run out of steam. Then the question is might there be another way to deliver the desired
performance to customers. Some new technology which, though still undeveloped,
might eventually
improvement?
outperform
the
current
one,
which
is
increasingly
resisting
But too often we dont ask those questions. Behind conventional management wisdom is the
implicit assumption that the more effort we put in, the more progress that results. In fact, this
is only the case in the first half of the S-curve. In the other half it is wrong.
S-curves almost always come in pairs. The gap between the pair of S-curves represents a
discontinuity a point when one technology replaces the other. In fact, rarely does a single
technology meet all customers needs. There are almost always competing technologies, each
with its own S-curve, trying to defeat the others in a market segment. Companies that have
learned how to cross technological discontinuities have escaped this trap. They invest in
research in order to know where they are on relevant S-curves and know what to expect from
the beginning the middle and the end of these curves. These companies have become very
sophisticated at massaging the shape of the curve, making it steeper by developing new
products and processes faster than their competitors.
The cost of being late to the market overwhelms the cost increases for accelerating
development. Some companies have learned how to share the development of technology and
products by making extensive use of external suppliers and managing that in an efficient way.
The better companies collaborate as much as they can. Administrative procedures can also be
eliminated to speed up development. But, perhaps the most important, companies have
learned that in order to be fast to the market, they must invest in understanding the science
that supports the base of the S-curve. Companies that get products to market ahead of their
competitors still dont take shortcuts: they do their research first, then tackle engineering. As a
result their S-curves are steeper than other companies trying to develop the same technology.
However, none of these efforts will save a company from a new technology.
attacker potentially may have to offer to the customer. Defenders and attackers often have a
different perspective when it comes to judging productivity.
Some products fail at first to meet customer standards, but then, almost overnight,
they set new high-quality standards and storm the market. Even if the defender admits
that the attackers product may have an edge, he is likely to say it is too small to matter.
Reallocating resources is thus a painful business. But in order to manage a technological
discontinuity, that is exactly what they must do forsake the past by abandoning a technology
that, more often than not, has just entered the most productive phase of its S-curve.
10
11
S-curve transitions is where a lot of action happens. If you are a new firm, at the
beginning you dont have any liabilities and just want to develop the new technology.
But the incumbents have a huge liability and a lot of times they cannot sustain their
leadership. Paying attention to this transition is great to spot new opportunities. It is
important to understand how the technology cycle evolves.
Variation is something we can now do that we could not do before, or doing it in a
different way.
Fermentation is when we have a discontinuity. Its a different approach towards a certain
problem. We set trials, we are on to something but not sure what. You have an idea of
how to evolve and how to solve the problem but you dont know for sure what
customers want.
Dominant design is the way of thinking about a certain product, the most efficient way to
deliver a certain innovation.
Incremental change orderly performance
In general, in innovation, first movers have an advantage because there is earlier trial
and error and firms are closer to the customer. The later the less opportunities you
have to learn and to become the dominant design.
12
Middle options:
Projects that focus more on the long run and sustainability
Focus more on performance metrics/outcomes
Partner up with content providers
Iterating more with partners and clients
Resolving gap between vision and implementation. They had a clear vision but were
doing too many things ate the same time. They were very unreasonable regarding what
they thought they could do and what they actually did in terms of time.
13
Yes
No
E-Ink is selling what they believe the dominant design is. But for everyone else the dominant
design can be something else. You have all of these firms convinced of what the dominant
design will be. This is the pre dominant design phase where every firm claims to be the future.
Ultimately, one of these firms will be able to push through the S-curve and actually beat all
others when it comes to actually being the dominant design. In the beginning there is a lot of
trial and error. You put money in the company if you believe there is still a fair chance they will
become the dominant design.
The dominant design is not a physical way of displaying information with electronic ink. It is all
about how customers interact with technology.
In this phase you need to deal with a lot of uncertainties, you need to balance a lot of aspects
such as vision, money, partnerships, teams. In this case they were not a total disaster but they
were not the dominant design.
14
15
Class 3
The Art of Standards Wars
Standards wars are battles for market dominance between incompatible technologies. The
outcome can determine the survival of the companies involved.
Incompatibilities can arise almost by accident, yet persist for many years
Network markets ten to tip towards the leading player, unless the other players
coordinate to act quickly and decisively
Seceding from the standard-process can leave you in a weak market position in the future
A large buyer can have more influence than suppliers in tipping the balance
Those left with the less popular technology will find a way to cut their losses, either by
employing adapters or by writing off existing assets and joining the bandwagon
Consumer expectations can easily become self-fulfilling in standards battles
Technologies can seek well-suited niches if the forces towards standardization are not
overwhelming
Ongoing innovation can lead to victory in standards wars
Adapters can be the salvation of the losing technology and can help to ultimately defuse
a standards war
Adoption of a new technology can be painfully slow if the price/performance ratio is
unattractive and if it requires adoption by a number of different players
First-mover advantages need not be decisive, even in markets strongly subject to tipping
Victory in standards wars often require building an alliance
A dominant position in one generation of technology does not necessarily translate into
dominance in the next generation of technology
Standards wars are especially bitter and especially crucial to business success in
markets with strong network effects that cause consumers to play high value on
compatibility.
What is distinct about standards wars is that there are two firms vying for dominance. In some
cases, one of the combatants may be an incumbent that controls a significant base of
customers who use an older technology. In other instances, both sides may be starting from
scratch. Standards wars can end in a truce, a duopoly or a fight to death. True fight-to-death
standard wars are unique to markets with powerful positive feedback based on strong network
effects.
Before entering a standards battle, would-be combatants are well-advised to consider a
peaceful solution. Declaring an early truce in a standards war can benefit consumers as well as
vendors. Even bitter enemies have repeatedly been able to cooperate to establish standards
when compatibility is crucial for market growth. The more costly a battle is for both sides, the
greater are the pressures to negotiate a truce.
Not all standards wars are alike. They come in three distinct flavors. The starting point for
strategy in a standards battle is to understand which type of war you are fighting. The critical
distinguishing feature of the battle is the magnitude of the switching costs, or more generally
the adoption costs, for each rival technology. The classification depends on how compatible
each players proposed new technology is with the current one:
o Evolution strategy When a company or alliance introduces new technology that is
compatible with the old. This strategy is based on offering a superior performance with
minimal consumer switching or adoption costs.
16
17
The second key tactic in a standards war is the management of expectations. Expectations
are a major factor in consumer decision about whether or not to purchase a new technology.
Just as incumbents will try to knock down the viability of new technologies that emerge, so will
those very entrants strive to establish credibility. Vaporware is a classic tactic aimed at
influencing expectations: announce an upcoming product so as to freeze your rivals sales. The
most direct way to manage expectations is by assembling allies and by making grand claims
about your products current or future popularity.
ONCE YOUVE WON
How best to proceed when you actually won a standards war? There is a great deal of
room for strategy. Technology marches forward so you have to keep looking for the next
generation of technology. You may be especially vulnerable if you were victorious in one
generation of technology through a preemption strategy. Going early usually means
making technical compromises, which gives that much room for others to execute an
incompatible Revolution strategy against you. So you should not go early and then lack
flexibility to adapt. You can choose to harvest your installed base of customers. The
strategic implication is that you need a migration path or roadmap for your
technology. If you cannot improve your technology with time, while offering
substantial compatibility with olderversions, you will be overtaken sooner or later.
Rigidity is death, unless you build a really big installed based and even this will fade
away eventually without improvements.
To fend off challenges from upstarts you need to make it hard for rivals to execute a
Revolution strategy. The key is to anticipate the next generation of technology and
co-opt it. Look in all directions for the next threat and take advantage of the fact that
consumers will not switch to a new technology unless it offers a marked improvement in
performance. Anticipate or imitate improvements and incorporate them into
your products. Avoid being frozen in one place by your own success. If you cater too
closely to your installed base by emphasizing backward compatibility you open the door
for a revolution strategy by an upstart. Your product roadmap has to offer your
customers a smooth migration path to ever-improving technology and it must
also stay close to the cutting edge. Give old members of your installed base free or
inexpensive upgrades to a recent version of your product.
Once youve won you want to keep your network alive and healthy. Retain your franchise
as the market leader, but have a vibrant and competitive market for complements
to your product. Try to maintain a competitive market in complementary products and
avoid the temptation to meddle. Enter into these markets only if integration of your core
product with adjacent products adds value to consumers.
You may need to improve performance just to compete against your installed base,
even without an external threat. Drive innovation even faster. One way to grow even
after you have a large installed base is to start discounting as a means of attracting the
remaining customers that have relatively low willingness to pay for your product. But be
careful.
Once you have a strong installed base, basic principles of competitive strategy dictate
that you seek to leverage into adjacent product spaces, exploiting the key assets that
give you a unique ability to create value for consumers in those spaces. However, you
may be better off by encouraging healthy competition in complementary products,
which stimulates demand for your own product, rather than trying to dominate adjacent
spaces. Acquisition of companies selling neighboring products should be driven by true
synergies of bringing both products into the same company.
How can you secure a competitive advantage for yourself short of maintaining direct
control over the technology (for example through copyrights or patents)Even without
direct control of the installed base or ownership of key patents you may be able to make
18
the other factors work for you. You can build a bandwagon using an openness
approach of ceding current control over the technology while keeping control over
the improvements and extensions. If you know better than others how the
technology is likely to evolve, you can use this information to your advantage by
preserving important future rights. Developing proprietary extensions is a valuable
tactic to recapture at least partial control over your own technology. You may gain some
control later if you launch a technology that takes off and you can be the first to market
with valuable extensions and improvements. If you are too successful and demand for
your product grows too fast many of your resources may end up devoted to meeting
with current demand rather than investing in R&D for the future. If this happens you can
use all your profits to identifying and purchase firms that are producing nextgeneration products
19
Before you can craft standards strategy, you first need to understand what type of standards
war you are waging. The single most important factor to track is the compatibility between the
dueling new technologies and established products. Standards wars come in three types: Rival
Evolutions, Rival Revolutions and Revolution vs. Evolution. Strength in the standards game is
determined by ownership of critical assets: control of an installed base, intellectual property
rights, ability to innovate, first-mover advantages, manufacturing capabilities, presence in
complementary products, brand name and reputation. The main lessons for strategy and
tactics are:
-
Before you go to warm assemble allies. Youll need the support of consumers, suppliers of
complements, and even competitors. Not even the strongest companies can afford to go it
alone in a standards war.
Preemption is a critical tactic during a standards war. Rapid design cycles, early deals
with pivotal customers and penetration pricing are the building blocks of a preemption
strategy.
Managing consumer expectations is crucial in network markets. Your goal is to convince
customers and your complementors that you will emerge as the victor. Such
expectations can easily become a sell-fulfilling prophecy when network effects are strong.
To manage expectations you should engage in aggressive marketing, make early
announcements of new products, assemble allies, and make visible commitments to your
technology.
When youve won a war, dont rest easy. Cater to you own installed base and avoid
complacency. Dont let the desire for backward compatibility hobble your ability to improve
your product; doing so will leave you open to an entrant offering less compatibility but
superior performance. Commoditize complementary products to make your systems more
attractive to consumers.
If you fall behind, avoid survival pricing as it just signals weakness. A better tactic is to
establish a compelling performance advantage or to interconnect with the prevailing
standard using converters and adapters.
20
21
or products that are widely used, the industry standard. Unlike the supply-side economies of
scale, demand-side economies of scale dont dissipate when the market gets large enough: if
everybody else is using a certain product that benefits from positive feedback than the more
reasons for someone to use it too. There is a virtuous cycle: the popular product with
many compatible users becomes more and more valuable to each user as it attracts
ever more users. In contrast, the product loses value as it is abandoned by users, a vicious
cycle. If consumers expect your product to become popular, a bandwagon will form, the
virtuous cycle will begin, and consumers expectations will prove correct. But if consumers
expect your product to flop, your product will lack momentum, the vicious cycle will take over,
and again consumers expectations will prove correct. Success and failure are driven as much
by consumer expectations and luck as the underlying value of the product. Marketing
strategy designed to influence consumer expectations is critical in network markets.
Being first to market usually helps but is not decisive. Nor are demand-side economies of scale
so strong that the loser necessarily departs from the field of battle. Both demand and supply
economies of scale have been around for a long time. But the combination of the two that has
arisen in many information technology industries is new. The result is a double whammy in
which growth on the demand side both reduces cost on the supply side and makes the product
more attractive to other users accelerating the growth in demand even more. The result is
specially string positive feedback.
NETWORK EXTERNALITIES
Network externalities means that large networks are more attractive to users than small ones.
The sponsor of a network creates and manages that network, hoping to profit by building its
size. Buyers are picking a network, not simply a product. Companies must design their
strategies accordingly. Building a network involves more than just building a product: finding
partners, building strategic alliances, and knowing how to get the bandwagon rolling can be
every bit as important as engineering design skills. Externalities arise when one market
participant affects other without compensation being paid. Positive network externalities give
rise to positive feedback: when I join a network, the value of the network is enhanced since it is
now bigger.
Collective switching costs Network externalities make it virtually impossible for a small
network to thrive. The challenge to companies seeking to introduce new but incompatible
technology into the market is to build network size by overcoming the collective switching
costs, the combined switching costs of all users. In many information industries, collective
switching costs are the biggest single force working in favor of incumbents. Control
over a large installed base of users can be the greatest asset you can have. The collective
switching costs are far higher than all of our individual switching costs because coordination is
so difficult. However, the internet distribution of new applications and standards is very
convenient and reduces some of the network externalities for software by reducing switching
costs.
Is your industry subject to positive feedback?
Not all information infrastructure markets are dominated by forces of positive feedback. Not
every market tips. If your market is a true winner-take-all market subject to such tipping,
standardization may be critical for the market to take off at all. Whether a market tips or not
depends on the balance between two fundamental forces: economies of scale and variety.
Strong scale economies, on either the demand side or the supply side of the market, will make
a market tippy. But standardization typically entails a loss of variety. If different users have
highly different needs, the market is less likely to tip. The strongest positive feedback in
information industries comes on the demand side, but you should not ignore the supply side in
assessing tipping. Traditional economies of scale that are specific to each technology will
amplify demand-side economies of scale.
22
Building your own base of users for a new technology in the face of an established network can
be daunting. Without a compelling reason to switch, consumers refuse to adopt new
technologies. There are two basic approaches doe dealing with the problem of consumer
inertia: the evolution strategy of compatibility and the revolution strategy of
compelling performance. These strategies reflect an underlying tension when the forces of
innovation meet up with network externalities: is it better to wipe the slate clean and come up
with the best product possible (revolution) or to give up some performance to ensure
compatibility and thus ease consumer adoption (evolution)? You can improve performance at
the cost of increasing customer switching costs, or vice versa. Ideally, you would like to have
an improved product that is also compatible with the installed base, but technology is not
usually so forgiving, and the adapters and emulators are notoriously buggy. You will inevitably
face the performance/compatibility tradeoff.
Evolution: Offer a Migration Path compatibility with the installed base of
equipment is often critical to the launch of a new generation of technology. When compatibility is
critical, consumers must be offered a smooth migration path to a new information technology. The
evolution strategy, which offers consumers an easy migration path, centers on reducing switching
costs so that consumers can gradually try your new technology. In virtual networks, the evolution
strategy of offering consumers a migration path requires an ability to achieve compatibility with
existing products. In real networks, the evolution strategy requires physical interconnection to existing
networks. They key to the evolution strategy is to build a new technology by linking it to the old one.
One of the risks of following the evolution approach is that one of your competitors may try a
revolution strategy for its product. Compromising performance to ensure backward compatibility may
leave an opening for a competitor to come in with a technologically superior product. You need to
develop a technology that is at the same time compatible with, and superior to, existing products. Only
in this way you can keep customers switching costs low, by offering backward compatibility, and still
offer improved performance.
One way to deal with the compatibility/performance tradeoff is to offer one-way compatibility.
Your strategy with respect to selling upgrades should be to give the users a reason to upgrade
and then to make the process of upgrading as simple as possible. In order to smooth user
migration paths to new technology you can use creative designs, think in terms of the system
and consider converters and bridge technologies. Another obstacle has to do with legal and
contractual reasons: you need to have or obtain the legal right to sell products that are
compatible with the established installed base of products. Incumbents with intellectual
property rights over an older generation of technology may have the ability to unilaterally
blockade a migration path.
23
Anyone launching a new technology must also face a second fundamental tradeoff, in addition
to the performance/compatibility tradeoff. Do you choose an open approach by offering to
make the necessary interfaces and specifications available to others, or do you attempt to
maintain control by keeping your system proprietary? Proprietary control will be exceedingly
valuable if your product or system takes off. An installed base is more valuable if you do not
face rivals who can offer products to locked-in customers. Likewise, your network is far more
valuable if you can control the ability of others to interconnect with you. However, failure to
open up a technology can spell its demise, if customers fear lock-in or if you face a strong rival
whose system offers comparable performance but is nonproprietary. Openness will bolster your
chances of success by attracting allies and assuring would-be customers that they will be able
to turn to multiple suppliers down the road. Which route is the best, openness or control? The
answer depends on whether you are strong enough to ignite positive feedback om your
own. Remember that your goal is to maximize the value of your technology, not your control
over it. The total value added to the industry depends first on the inherent value of the
technology what improvement it offers over existing alternatives. But when network effects
are strong, total value also depends on how widely the technology is adopted that is, the
network size. To maximize the value of your new technology you will likely have to share that
value with other players in the industry. Opening up the technology freely can fuel positive
feedback and maximize the total value added of the technology. But the boundary between
openness and control is not sharp.
Openness the openness strategy is critical when no one firm is strong enough to
dictate technology standards by itself. Openness also arises naturally when multiple products
work together. The underlying idea is to forsake control over the technology to get the
bandwagon rolling as the whole is greater than the sum of parts. You can choose a full
openness strategy, where anybody has the right to make products complying with the
standard, whether they contributed to its development or not, or choose an alliance strategy,
where each member of the alliance contributes with something toward the standard and, in
exchange, each is allowed to make products complying with the standard.
Control only those in the strongest position can hope to exert strong control
over newly introduced information technologies. Companies strong enough to unilaterally
control product standards and interfaces have power but they have much to lose by promoting
poorly conceived standards.
Performance Play is the boldest and riskiest of the four generic strategies. It involves
the introduction of a new incompatible technology over which the vendor retains strong proprietary
control. It makes the most sense if your advantage is primarily based on the development of a striking
new technology that offers users substantial advantages over existing technology.
Controlled Migration consumers are offered a new and improved technology that is
compatible with their existing technology, but is proprietary. If you have secure domination in your
market you can introduce the new technology as a premium version of the old technology, selling it
first to those who find the improvements most valuable.
Open Migration is very friendly to consumers as the new product is supplied by many
vendors and requires little by way of switching costs. It makes most sense if your primarily advantage
is based on manufacturing capabilities. In that case, you will benefit from a larger total market and an
agreed-upon set of specifications, which will allow your manufacturing skills and economies of scale to
shine.
24
25
26
27
What now?
How should foursquare monetize? They should attract more customers or more elements to the
network first because they should make sure they do not drive users and venues away. So they
should continue to build the network, work more on usage and have a clear differentiation
strategy because when bigger players start entering this game they need to make sure they
have a clear differentiated value proposition.
What can happen?
Either they launch something and become the dominant design, they get bought or they build
sufficient differentiated space in order to compete with facebook, google and other giants.
28
Class 4
Managing Intellectual Capital
If there are innovators who lose, there must be followers and/or imitator who win. Successful
followers may in turn lose in the next generation to even later followers.
The most fundamental reason why innovators with good marketable ideas fail to enter or open
up markets successfully is that they are operating in an environment where new technology
is difficult to protect and this constrains their ability to appropriate the economic benefits
arising from their ideas. Patents do now work in practice as they do in theory and they are
specially ineffective at protecting process innovations. Often patents provide little protection
because the legal and financial requirements for upholding their validity or for proving their
infringement are high. In some industries, particularly where the innovation is embedded in
processes, trade secrets are a viable alternative to patents. Moreover, the degree to which
knowledge about an innovation in tacit or easily codified also affects the ease of imitation. Tacit
knowledge is, by definition, difficult to articulate and so is hard to pass on unless those who
possess the know-how can demonstrate it to others. It is also hard to protect using intellectual
property. Codified knowledge is easier to transmit and receive and easier to protect using the
instruments of intellectual property law.
The best market entry strategies for innovators with good, marketable ideas depend not only
on the appropriability regime, but also where the industry is in in its development cycle. The
existence of a dominant design is of great importance to the strategic positions of
the innovator and its competitors. Once a dominant design emerges, competition migrates
to price and away from design fundamentals. Competitive success then shifts to a whole new
set of variables. Scale and learning become much more important, and specialized capital is
deployed as incumbents seek to lower unit costs through exploiting economies of scale and
learning. The product/process innovation cycle does not characterize all industries. It seems
more suited to mass markets where customer tastes are relatively homogeneous. It is less
characteristic of small niche markets where the absence of economies of scale and learning
attaches much less of a penalty to multiple designs.
Strong Appropriability None of these threats need unduly worry an innovator who is
preparing to enter a market with relevant technology which is inherently difficult to replicate
and/or has a good intellectual property protection, because the innovator knows that the ideas
possessed must form some part of the eventual dominant design. Even if the innovator comes
to market in this early phase with a sound product concept but the wrong design, good
intellectual property protection may afford the time needed to perform trials needed to get the
design right. If the innovator possesses an impenetrable thicket of patents or has technology
29
which is simply difficult to copy, then the market may well afford the innovator the necessary
time to ascertain the right design without being eclipsed by imitators.
Weak AppropriabilityIn the early design development of an industry with weak
appropriability, the innovator has to recognize that imitators may enter the fray, modifying the
product in important ways, yet relying on the fundamental designs pioneered by the innovator.
When imitation is possible and occurs in conjunction with design modification before the
emergence of a dominant design, followers have a good chance of having their modified
product anointed as the industry standard, often to the great disadvantage of the innovator. In
this situation the innovator must be careful to let the basic design float until sufficient evidence
has accumulated that a design has been delivered which is likely to become the industry
standard. The reason for letting the design float is that once a heavy capital investment is
committed to a particular design, the innovator will have created irreversibilities that will prove
to be a sever handicap if the initial guesses with respect to what the market wants turn out to
be wrong. In summary, the probability may be low that an innovator in a market with weak
appropriability will enter possessing the dominant design. The probability will be higher the
lower the cost of prototyping and he more tightly linked the firm is to the market.
AFTER THE EMRGENCE OF A DOMINANT DESIGN
If the innovator is still in the game when the dominant design has emerged then the company
has to secure access to complementary assets.The successful commercialization of an
innovation requires that the know-how in question be utilized in conjunction with the services
of other assets such as marketing, competitive manufacturing and after-sales support. On the
other hand, successful commercialization of the innovation may depend critically on a
bottleneck asset which has only one possible supplier. There is the possibility of
cospecialization where the innovation and the assets depend on each other. The main
decision the innovator has to make is what to do with respect to complimentary assets. Two
pure types stand out:
-
At one extreme the innovator could integrate into (build or acquire) all of the necessary
complementary assets. But this is likely to be unnecessary and expensive.
At the other extreme, the innovator could attempt to access these assets through
straightforward contractual relationships, but this exposes the innovator to various hazards
and dependencies that he may well wish to avoid.
Contractual Modes
The vantage of collaborative agreements whereby the innovator contracts with
independent suppliers, manufacturers or distributors are obvious. The innovator will not have
to make the up-front capital expenditures needed to build or buy the assets in question. This
reduces risk as well as cash requirements. Also, they add credibility to the innovator, especially
if he relatively unknown while the contractual partner is already established and viable. Even
for established companies, strategic partnering is essential, enabling companies to learn things
they could not have learned without many years of trial and error. This might lead them to miss
the market window. But they must keep control of their intellectual property. Smaller, less
integrated companies are often eager to sign on with established firms because of the name
recognition and reputation.
However, it is important to note that strategic partnering makes the company exposed to
certain hazards, particularly for the innovator, and especially when he is trying to use
contracts to gain access to special capabilities. It may be difficult to induce suppliers to make
costly, irreversible commitments which depend on the success of the innovation. Making these
alliances is inviting the partners to take risks along with the innovator.There is the added
30
danger that the partner wont perform according to the innovators perception of what the
contract requires and also the risk that the partner may imitate the innovators technology and
attempt to compete with him. This possibility is particularly acute if the provider of the
complimentary asset is uniquely situated with respect to the complimentary assets in question
and has the capacity to absorb and imitate the technology.
Integration Modes
Integration modes, which by definition involve equity participation, are distinguished from pure
contractual modes in that they typically facilitate greater control and access to commercial
information. Owning rather than renting the requisite specialized assets has clear advantages
when the complimentary assets are in fixed supply over the relevant time period. However an
innovator may not have the time to acquire or build the complimentary assets that ideally he
would like to control. This is particularly true when the imitation is easy, so timing becomes
crucial. Or he may not have the financial resources to proceed. Innovators need to rank
complementary, specialized assets as to their importance. If the assets are critical, ownership
is warranted. When imitation is easy, strategic moves to build or buy complementary assets
which are specialized must occur with due reference to the moves of competitors. There is no
point in moving to building a specialized asset of ones imitator can do it faster and cheaper. In
industries experiencing rapid technological change, technologies advance so rapidly that it is
unlikely that a single company has the full range of expertise needed to bring advanced
products to the market in a timely and cost effective fashion. Hence, the integration issue is not
just a small firm issue.
Mixed Modes
The real world rarely provides extreme or pure causes. Decisions to integrate or license involve
trade-offs, compromises and mixed approaches. There are blends of contracting and
integration. Sometimes mixed modes represent transitional phases. In different industries firms
are discovering that they lack capabilities in the others. Since interdependence of some of
them, this requires collaboration, coordination and information flows.
31
competitors/owners of the specialized assets. This does not stem form size itself, but from the
portfolio of specialized assets that big firms are likely to control.
- The best situation is, of course, where appropriability is strong, the innovation is
competency enhancing and the innovator is strongly placed with regard to the relevant
complementary assets.
- Contractual strategies are appropriate whenever imitation is difficult and the innovator is
well placed with regard to the suppliers of complementary assets. However, the
innovators chances of winning diminish as appropriability weakens and imitators are
better positioned with respect to commissioning the complementary assets.
- The most difficult decision for innovators occur when the owners of complementary
assets are strongly placed (because there are few suppliers, the asset in question being
a critical bottleneck in the market entry programme) and the innovation can only be
exploited in conjunction with the asset but not vice versa.
- In the worst case, when imitators are better placed (for example because they own the
relevant assets) and imitation is easy, the innovator cannot afford the risk of committing
substantial resources to integrating. The firm should contract to limit its exposure, but
this will further reduce the already low chances of winning, and if it wins, the asset
owner will be ideally placed in the future to extract maximum benefits from the
contract.
Unfortunately, all too often in the real world of international commerce, legal and technical
protection is weal, complementary assets (like specialized marketing and selling systems) are
more important than the innovation itself, and they are in the hands of potential competitors.
In the end, smart choices may not guarantee success. If an innovator chooses to integrate when
it should have contracted (or not even enter the game), it will certainly commit more resources
than needed for no additional strategic benefit. Conversely, if the innovator contracts when it
should integrate it may never get into the game because an imitator may cut the innovation out.
The asset supplier will always be in a position to extort maximum benefits from the innovator
whenever a contract fails.
Lessons for management:
Even with a terrific product, the innovator is likely to lose unless its intellectual property is
extremely well protected and/or it is strategically well positioned with respect to key
complementary assets. It will never be enough to have the best science and engineering
32
establishment and the most creative engineers and designers. Since the fruits of scientific
effort are increasingly open to imitation, extracting value from a nations scientific and
engineering prowess will require its firms to have good access to competitive capacities in
certain of the key complementary assets, such as manufacturing. Public policies that dont
recognize that translating scientific and technological leadership into commercial leadership in
most cases requires parallel excellence in capacities complementary to the innovation process
will doom a nation to economic decline. It is the complementary capacities and dynamic
capabilities which must be built if a nation with the technological lead is also to lay claim to
commercial lead.
Lessons for governments of innovation nations:
33
34
35
36
with cooperation and competition at each stage of the value chain, with the result that
the optimal strategy may involve intermediate level of integration.
Firms opportunistically take advantage of potential revenue opportunities as they present
themselves, rather than choosing a strategy that focuses resources and attention towards
activities most likely to yield the highest long-term return. The ability to extract value from the
innovation ultimately depends on the customer value proposition, rather than the simple
offering of the technology itself
.
Cooperation Is much more likely to be chosen by firms able to acquire intellectual property
protection or for whom control over complementary assets is not cost-effective. The key to an
effective cooperation strategy is to initiate cooperation at a point where technological
uncertainty is sufficiently low but sunk costs have not yet become substantial. At the heart of a
competition strategy is the ability to delay the timing when established firms recognize the
threat posed by the novel value proposition offered by the technology entrepreneur. If
detection is sufficiently early, established firms can respond and adapt the entrepreneurs
technology in order to take advantage of their competencies and specific positioning.
Strategies such as targeting niche customer segments allow a startup innovator to delay
detection until they are ready to compete head-to-head with incumbents a stealth
commercialization strategy achieves this objective.
Key aspects of the commercialization environment drive entrepreneurs to choose
between cooperation and competition, and these strategies impact the evolution of
market structure. When intellectual property protection is strong and important
specialized complementary assets are held by incumbent firms, startups generate more
innovative rents if they pursue cooperative options with incumbent firms rather than
competing directly in product markets. As a result, changes in technological leadership
need not result in changes in market leadership. In contrast, when weak intellectual
property for innovation exists alongside low barriers to entry, competitive
commercialization strategies are more likely. A clear understanding of this environment
leads startup innovators to exploit the blind spots of incumbent players. As a result, the
failure to recognize threats to market leadership may often be the result of an active
stealth strategy on the part of entrepreneurs.
While intellectual property protection provides a valuable asset, it also serves to enhance
the creation of a market for ideas. Consequently, it allows for cooperation between
startups and incumbents who might otherwise view innovation purely as a competitive
threat. This serves as an opportunity for incumbents to tap the high-powered incentives,
creativity and flexibility traditionally associated with small firms.
If entrepreneurial innovation undermines existing incumbent assets, the returns of
cooperation are reduced in favor of competition. In contrast, the fact that a technology
is disruptive should not be decisive if key complementary assets remain with
established players. In this situation, an incumbents competitive position may often be
enhanced rather than threatened by startup innovation.
Stronger intellectual property protection allows innovators to earn greater rents by
improving their contracting operations and not simply by granting them market power.
That is, such policies alleviate the problems of disclosure allowing startup firms to
consider contracting options without fear of expropriation.
37
owners
often
require
complementary
assets
for
Integrate
of
Contract
38
Diversifies risk
Reduces cash requirements
Increases incentives
Brings credibility
in
39
40
Class 5
Open Innovation
Companies are increasingly rethinking the fundamental ways in which they generate ideas and
bring them to the market harnessing external ideas while leveraging their in-house R&D
outside their current operations.
In the past, internal R&D was a valuable strategic asset, even a formidable barrier to entry by
competitors in many markets. These days, however, the leading industrial enterprises from the
past have been encountering remarkably strong competition from many upstarts. Newcomers
conduct little or no basic research on their own, but instead get new ideas to the market
through a different process. Companies that compete in the same industry can innovate in
different manners. Instead of internal R&D, they can turn to external sources. Whatever
technology companies need, they can acquire it from outside, usually by partnering or
investing in promising startups. In this way, they can keep up with the R&D output all without
conducting much research of their own.
Why is internal R&D no longer the strategic asset it once was? We can now see a fundamental
shift in how companies generate new ideas and bring them to the market. In the old model of
closed innovation, successful innovation required control and companies had to generate
own new ideas that they would then develop, manufacture, market, distribute and service
themselves. It was a vicious cycle as those that invested more heavily in R&D than their
competitors and hired the best and the brightest were able to discover the best and greatest
number of ideas which would allow them to get to the market first, allowing them to reap the
most profits, which they protected by aggressively controlling their Intellectual Property to
prevent competitor from exploiting it. They would then reinvest the profits in more R&D,
creating a virtuous circle of innovation.
A number of factors contributed to erode the underpinnings of closed innovation:
There was a dramatic rise in the number and mobility of knowledge workers, making
it increasingly difficult for companies to control their proprietary ideas and expertise.
Growing availability of private venture capital, which has helped to finance new firms
and their efforts to commercialize ideas that have spilled outside the silos of
corporate research labs.
If a company that funded a discovery doesnt pursue it in a timely fashion, the people involved
could pursue it on their own in a startup financed by venture capital. The successful startup
would generally not reinvest in new fundamental discoveries, but instead look outside for
another technology to commercialize. In this new model of open innovation, firms
commercialize external (as well as internal) ideas by developing outside (as well as in-house)
pathways to the market. Companies can commercialize internal ideas through channels outside
of their current business in order to generate value for the organization. Some vehicles for
accomplishing this include startup companies and licensing agreements. The boundary
between a firm and its surrounding environment is more porous, enabling innovation to move
easily between the two. Open innovation is based on a landscape of abundant knowledge,
which must be used readily if it is to provide value for the company that created it. However,
an organization should not restrict the knowledge it uncovers in its research to its internal
market pathways. No longer should a company lock up its IP, but instead it should find ways to
profit from others use of that technology through licensing agreements, joint ventures and
other arrangements. A company that is focused too internally can miss a lot of opportunities
41
because many will fall outside the organizations current business or will need to be combined
with external technologies to unlock their potential. Like this, companies can reap tremendous
benefits. Many industries are currently transitioning from closed to open innovation. The locus
of innovation in these industries has migrated beyond the confines on the central R&D
laboratories of the largest companies and is now situated among various startups, universities,
research consortia and other outside organizations. Extending companies R&D to the outside
world by moving their own innovations outside allows any idea that originates in their labs to
be offered to outside firms, preventing promising projects from losing momentum and
becoming stuck inside the organization.
However, not all industries have been or will be migrating to open innovation. This is true for
those that depend mainly on internal ideas and that have low labor mobility, little venture
capital, few and weak startups and relatively little research being conducted at universities.
Funding Innovation
Two types of organizations innovation investors and benefactors are focused primarily on
supplying fuel for the innovation fire. Innovation investors capital helps move ideas out of
corporations and universities into the market, typically through the creation of startups. They
can also supply valuable advice. Innovation benefactors provide new sources of research
funding, they focus on the early stages of research discovery and by doing this they get a first
look at the ideas and can selectively fund those that seem favorable to their industry.
Generating Innovation
There are four types of organizations that primarily generate innovation: innovation explorers,
merchants, architects and missionaries. Innovation explorers specialize in performing the
discovery research function that previously took place primarily within corporate R&D
laboratories. They innovate for the sake of innovation, seeking new missions for their work and
much of their basic research is finding applications in commercial markets. Innovation
merchants must also explore, but their activities are focused on a narrow set of technologies
that are then codified into IP and aggressively sold to and brought to the market by others.
They will innovate but only with specific commercial goals in mind. Innovation architects create
value for their customers by putting everything together where the DIY approach doesnt work.
They work closely with a lot of companies in complex and fast-moving environments and
provide integrated solutions to their clients while seeking financial profits from their work.
Innovation missionaries consist of people and organizations that create and advance
technologies to serve a cause, the mission is what motivates them.
Commercializing Innovation
Two types of organizations are focused on bringing innovations to the market: innovation
marketers and one-stop centers. Innovation marketers define attributes and this is their keen
ability to profitably market ideas, both their own as well as others. Marketers focus on
developing a deep understanding of the current and potential needs in the market and this
helps them to identify which outside ideas to bring in-house. They interact a lot with their
customers to gain in-depth knowledge about their needs. Innovation one-stop centers provide
comprehensive products and services. They take the best ideas and deliver those offerings to
their customers at competitive prices. They thrive by selling others ideas, but are different in
that they typically from unshakable connections to end-users, increasingly managing a
customers resources to his or her specifications (specially B2B).
42
Some companies do all three. Others are called fully integrated innovators and continue to
espouse the closed innovation credo of Innovation through total control.They need to
manage and coordinate a lot of different internal R&D efforts to stay competitive, for example
products that are 100% produced in-house, where all technology comes from the same
company.
A corporation can deploy different modes of innovation in different markets as competing
modes can exist in the same market. One possible development in the future is the rise of
specialized intermediaries that function as brokers or middlemen to create markets for IP.
The logic that supports an internally oriented, centralized approach to R&D has become
obsolete. Useful knowledge has become widespread and ideas must be used with
readiness. If not, they will be lost. Such factors create a logic of open innovation that
embraces external ideas in conjunction with internal R&D and this change offers novel
ways to create value. However, companies must still perform the difficult and arduous
work necessary to convert promising research results into products and services that
satisfy customers needs. Innovators must integrate their ideas, expertise and skills with
those of others outside the organization to deliver the result to the marketplace. Firms
that can harness outside ideas to advance their own businesses while leveraging their
internal ideas outside their current operations will likely thrive in this new era of open
innovation.
43
LU have a better ability to generate breakthrough ideas new product ideas that form the basis
of an entire new line of products or services. Traditional methods focus on subjects that are
strongly constrained by their real-world experience. Thus, those who use an object or see it
used in a familiar way are blocked from using that object in a novel way. Representative targetmarket customers, users of todays products, seem to be poorly situated to envision novel
needs or solutions. LU are better situated in this regard, they live in the future, experiencing
today what representative users will experience months or years later. Users rather than
manufacturers, to whom the solution creation is awarded in traditional methods, are often the
initial developers of what later becomes commercially significant new products or processes.
LU ideas are significantly more novel than ideas generated by non LU methods, they address
more original/newer customer needs, have significantly higher market share, have greater
potential to develop into an entire product line are strategically more important. Also, projected
annual sales are higher than those generated by non-LU methods. LU methods do generate
ideas with greater commercial potential. Non-LU methods produce mainly funded ideas for
improvements and extensions to existing product lines. Also, LU methods of identifying and
learning from lead users outside of the target market will increase the overall rate at which the
organization generates major product lines. LU ideas involve as high a level of intellectual
property protection as ideas generated by non-LU methods. However, LU idea-generation
methods cost more in time and money. All in all, the LU idea-generation method does appear to
generate better results than traditional methods.
44
45
o
o
o
o
o
Open
Closed
46
Retain solution
Independent
Modular
No need to disclose valuable key
strategic knowledge
Time sensitive
Problems
that
leverage
complementary assets
You really need to manage your R&D staff in a sensitive way in order to augment the capacities
you will gain from external sources but also to limit the downsizes.
Value of IC in particular?
47
Challenge themselves
Money
Gratification to contribute
Part-time job/freelance
Range of opportunities to contribute
Reputation/recognition
Self-esteem
Professional reasons
Fun
Bad
Combine knowledge
Increase the chance of getting to a solution
New knowledge from teams
Get at least a piece of the cake
Social value
48
49
Class 6
Customer Power, Strategic Investment, and the failure of Leading
Firms
It is hard for firms to repeat their success when technology or markets change. The failure of
leading firms can sometimes be ascribed to managerial myopia or organizational lethargy, or to
insufficient resources or expertise. Why and under what circumstances do financially strong,
consumer-sensitive, technologically deep and rationally managed organizations fail to adopt
critical new technologies or enter important markets? Failure to innovate may lead to the
decline of once-great firms. A primary reason why such firms lose their positions of industry
leadership when faced with certain types of technological change has little to do with
technology itself. Rather, they fail because they listen too carefully to their customers and
customers place limits on the strategies firms can and cannot pursue. Patterns of resource
allocation heavily influence the types of innovation at which leading firms will succeed or fail. In
every organization, ideas emerge daily about new ways of doing things. Most proposals to
innovate require human and financial resources. The patterns of innovation evidenced in a
company will therefore mirror to a considerable degree the patterns in how resources are
allocated to, and withheld from, competing proposals to innovate. Because effective resource
allocation is market-driven, the resource allocation procedures in successful organizations
provide impetus for innovations known to be demanded by current customers in existing
markets. Firms possessing the capacity and capability to innovate may fail when the innovation
does not address the foreseeable needs of their current customers. When the initial
price/performance characteristics of emerging technologies render them competitive only in
emerging market segments, and not with current customers, resource allocation mechanisms
typically deny resources to such technologies. The inability of some successful firms to allocate
sufficient resources to technologies that initially cannot find application in mainstream markets,
but later invade them, lies at the root if the failure of many once-successful firms.
Why do firms that lead may fail when faced with technology change? New technologies often
are initially deployed in new markets, and these are usually brought into the industry by
entering firms. Established firms confront new technology often by intensifying their
commitment to conventional technology, while starving efforts to commercialize the new one,
even while it is gaining ground market.
Incumbent firms may stumble when technological change destroys the value of established
technological competences or when new architectural technologies emerge. We need to make
a distinction between the innovations that sustain the industrys rate of improvement in
product performance and those innovations that disrupt or redefine that performance
trajectory.
Sustaining technological changes have an impact on an established trajectory of
performance improvement and they address the improvements that the companys
current customers expect. On the other hand, disruptive technologies disrupt an
established trajectory of performance improvement, or redefine what performance
means. The new architectures do not address the perceived need of current customers
but they do possess attributes that appeal to emerging market segments. In general,
sustaining technological changes appeal to established customers in existing
mainstream markets. They provide existing customers with more of what they expect. In
contrast, disruptive technologies rarely can initially be employed in established markets.
They tend instead to be valued in remote or emerging markets.
50
Leading firms might successfully pioneer in the development and adoption of many new and
difficult technologies, and yet they lose their positions of industry leadership by failing to
implement others. In spite of the wide variety in the magnitudes and types of sustaining
technological changes in the industry, the firms that lead in their development and adoption
are the industrys leading, established firms. The established firms lead in the adoption of
sustaining technology, entrant firms follow. In contrast, the firms that lead the industry in
introducing disruptive innovation tend to be entrant.
The ability of established firms to lead the industry in the sustaining innovations that power
steep technological trajectories are technologically difficult, risky and expensive but there is no
evidence that this makes them gain market share. This leadership enables them to maintain
their competitiveness only within specific technological trajectories. On the other hand,
entrant firms leadership in disruptive innovations enable them not only to capture
new markets as they emerged but, because the trajectories of technological
progress are steeper than the trajectories of performance demanded, to invade and
capture established markets as well.
Why is it that firms which at one point could be esteemed as aggressive, innovative, customersensitive organizations could ignore or attend belatedly to technological innovations with
enormous strategic importance? When confronted with disruptive technological change,
developing the technology per se is not the problem. It is in the process of allocating scarce
resources that disruptive projects get stalled. Programs addressing the needs of the firms most
powerful customers almost always consume the resources from the disruptive technologies,
whose markets tend to be small and where customers needs are poorly defined.
Although entrants are the leaders in commercializing the disruptive technology, the first
engineers to develop it usually are from the leading firms and use bootlegged resources.
While architectural innovative, these designs almost always employ off-the-shelf
components. Prototypes are made and showed to lead customers of the existing product
line so that they can evaluate the new models. But they show little interest in the
disruptive technologies because they do not address their current needs for higher
performance within the established architectural framework. As a consequence,
marketing managers are unwilling to support the disruptive technology and offer
pessimistic sales. Also, because the disruptive technology is targeted at emerging
markets and lower performance is lower, initial forecasts of sales and margins are low,
which makes financial analysts against the disruptive technology as well. In response to
the needs of current customers, the marketing managers throw impetus behind
alternative sustaining projects. These give their customers what they want, can be
targeted at large markets and generate sales and profits required to maintain growth.
Although they generally involver greater development expense, such sustaining
investments appear less risky than investments in the disruptive technology,
because the customers are there. Established firms are more concerned with
competitive wars against each other, rather than to prepare for an attack from entrants
below. New companies were formed to exploit the disruptive product architecture. The
start-ups find new customers and start selling their products without a clear marketing
strategy. Once they find an operating base in new markets, they start adopting
sustaining improvements in the new technology and the performance improvement
evolves at a faster rate than the one requires by their new markets, which allows them
to move into new upscale ones. Customers in these established markets eventually
embrace the new technology they rejected earlier because now their performance
requirements are met. Once this starts to happen, leading firms start to enter the
market with this new technology as well, but at this point the entrants are already fully
performance competitive as they develop advantages in costs and design experience.
51
The new products (with new technology) cannibalize the sales of the older in such a way
that many times former leading firms are forced to leave the market because they
cannot keep up.
Many of the sustaining innovations are extremely expensive and risky form a technological
point of view. Yet, because they addressed well-understood needs of known customers,
perceived market risk was low. Although these sustaining innovations clearly helped the
innovators retain their customers, there is no evidence from the industrys history that any firm
was able to gain market share by virtue of such technology leadership. On the other hand,
disruptive innovations are technologically straightforward: several established firms had
already developed them by the time formal resource allocation decisions were made. But these
were viewed as extremely risky because they could not see the markets for it.
Engineers in established firms that developed disruptive-architecture products were innovative
not just in technology, but in their view of the market as they intuitively perceived
opportunities. But organizational processes allocate resources based on rational assessments
of data about returns and risks. Information provided by innovating engineers was hypothetical
at best: without existing customers, they could only guess the size of the market, the
profitability of products, and required product performance. In contrast, current customers
could articulate features, performance and quantities they would purchase with much less
ambiguity. The popular slogan stay close to your customer may not always be robust advice.
Neglect of disruptive technologies prove damaging to established firms because the trajectory
of performance improvement that the technology provided was steeper than the improvement
trajectory demanded in individual markets. The mismatch in these trajectories provide
pathways for the firms that enter new markets eventually to become performance competitive
in established markets as well. If the trajectories were parallel we would expect disruptive
technologies to be deployed in new markets and stay there; each successive market would
constitute a relatively stable niche market out of which technologies and firms would not
migrate.
A firms scope for strategic change is strongly bounded by the interests of external entities
such as customers and shareholders that provide the resources the firm needs to survive. So
we usually see this resources used to sustaining innovation that addresses current customers
needs. But managers can, in fact, change the strategic course of their firms in directions other
than those in which its resource providers are pulling it. Managers can align efforts to
commercialize disruptive technology which entails a change in strategy with the forces of
resource dependence. Shortly, the reason why strong, capably managed firms stumble when
face with particular types of technological change, is an issue of investment.
When technological competence exists but impetus from customers lacks, firms are unable to
commercialize what they already can do. This is because disruptive technologies initially tend
to be saleable in different markets whose economic and financial characteristics render them
unattractive to established firms. In the end, it appears that although the stumbles of these
established firms are associated with technological change, the key issue appears to be firms
disabilities in changing strategy, not technology.
52
o
o
o
o
o
53
54
55
56