Keppel Woerz Aug2010
Keppel Woerz Aug2010
Keppel Woerz Aug2010
Catherine Keppel
Wirtschaftuniversitt Wien
Institute for Fiscal and Monetary Policy
Julia Wrz
Oesterreichische Nationalbank
Foreign Research Division
Abstract:
We assess empirically the marginal impact of export orientation for the
severity of the growth downturn in 2009 while controlling for a host of
country characteristics such as structural features, macroeconomic
imbalances, previous growth record, and the like. We employ an iterative
robust regression technique using a sample of 38 mostly European countries
to quantify the direct contribution of trade to the crisis response with a
special focus on Eastern European economies. We find that greater export
orientation is related to a stronger growth downturn in our sample. This
effect is only revealed when we allow for an interaction term between
export orientation and domestic GDP structure. Moreover, we find strong
evidence that the domestic structure of value added (in particular a high
share of industry in GDP) has compounded a countrys vulnerability during
the recent crisis. We further find support for the effects of overheating:
previous high growth rates are systematically linked to a stronger growth
downturn in all specifications. Finally, a negative influence from previously
high debt ratios on the output response during the crisis is confirmed.
JEL-codes: F14, F15, O52
Keywords: trade collapse; industrial structure; Central, Eastern and
Southeastern Europe
Paper prepared for the SUERF/BWG Conference and Special OeNB East Jour Fixe Contagion and Spillovers
New Insights from the Crisis, held on February 12 2010 at the OeNB Vienna. The authors thank Jarko Fidrmuc
for helpful comments and suggestions.
1. Introduction
Since the unfolding of the recent financial crisis, world exports and imports dropped dramatically.
While global GDP is forecast has shrunk by xx% (according to the IMF World Economic Outlook
04/2010), world trade volume has fallen by xx% in 2009. The figures are similar for all major
industrialized regions in the world and some emerging markets. Hence, trade has certainly been one
of the most severely hit economic activities. The question arises to what extent this strong and
immediate trade response has propagated the crisis throughout the globe in 2009 and to what
extent trade openness has reinforced the impact of the crisis for individual countries.
In other words, the remarkably large drop in trade is central in the discussion on how a local financial
crisis could turn into a global economic crisis. The academic discussion seems to agree that only the
combination of a number of distinct shocks could have led to the sudden spread of the crisis and
cause a global recession of this magnitude (see for example Escaith, 2009; McKibbin and Stoeckl,
2009; Rose and Spiegel, 2009, to name just a few). Starting from the bursting of the housing bubble
in the US in mid 2007, households in the US experienced a sharp reduction in wealth which, coupled
with changing perceptions of risk by households and businesses, implied a demand shock in the US.
All else equal, this would have triggered two offsetting effects on the global economy: a shortfall in
external demand for countries which are heavily dependent on the US market on the negative side
and rising investment opportunities in response to low returns on investment in the US on the
positive side (McKibbin and Stoeckel, 2009).
In the recent crisis the latter effect did not materialize, because the reappraisal of risks was just as
global in scope as was the shortfall in demand. In particular, emerging markets which in theory could
have profited from worsening investment conditions in the US (and other highly developed
countries) were negatively affected by changing investor risk perceptions. Hence in the current crisis,
the two effects reinforced instead of offsetting each other. In that way, international trade acted as a
compounding factor not only transmitting but also magnifying the effects of the US crisis. All this has
led to a worsening in investment climate, deteriorating credit conditions and falling domestic
demand in particular for durable and investment goods.
But how important in quantitative terms was trade in the global transmission of the crisis? In this
paper, we try to quantify this effect and argue that the direct contribution of trade to deepening the
economic downturn should not be overstated. Only the combination of structural characteristics and
highly open markets have implied a strong output response in the countries which are most heavily
exposed to the sectors contracting most strongly during the crisis. We start by summarizing the
dramatic developments in world trade in 2009 in Section 2. Section 3 reviews the existing related
literature and discusses the mechanisms of crisis transmission through trade. We identify basically
three factors of theoretical importance in shaping the outcome of the crisis. Two demand-side
explanations are related to the rising importance of global supply chains and structural differences
between the domestic and external sector of the economy. A supply-side explanation relates to
problems in trade financing. Section 4 uses an econometric model to estimate the importance of
trade, structural characteristics and financial uncertainties for the incidence of the crisis in a crosssection of 38 predominantly European countries. Section 5 concludes.
100
1100
100
90
1000
90
80
900
80
800
800
70
70
700
700
60
600
60
600
500
50
500
50
400
40
400
300
40
300
170
170
250
150
130
200
250
150
130
200
110
110
150
150
90
90
70
100
Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug04
05
05
06
06
07
07
08
08
09
09
70
100
Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug- Feb- Aug04
05
05
06
06
07
07
08
08
09
09
CEE (r.s.)
At the sectoral level, mineral fuels, crude materials, manufactured goods and machinery and
transport equipment experienced the most severe drops in trade. Figure 2 displays three-month
moving averages of import growth for different sectors in OECD countries. OECD imports in these
categories recorded dramatic declines between 11% and 15% month-on-month at the height of the
trade collapse (from December 2008 to January 2009). In May 2009, when global trade volumes
reached the trough, these categories were between 49% (mineral fuels) and 34% (machinery and
transport equipment) below their previous levels in annual terms. However, these were also the
categories which showed the strongest signs of recovery in mid-2009.
As mentioned above, trade started to decline in May 2008 and turned negative first in October 2008
when the collapse of Lehman and the consequent re-assessment of risks has added a second,
decisive shock to the global economy in addition to the US-demand shock. The trough in trade
growth was reached already in January 2009, positive import growth, however, was only reached
again in July 2009.
Much of the nominal trade collapse depicted in Figure 2 is of course due to price effects, which
becomes visible in the steep decline in OECD fuel imports shown in the second panel of figure 2. The
weakness in US demand for mineral fuel may also have a supply-chain component since petroleum
3
and natural gas are major inputs into chemicals and plastics, which are in turn intermediate inputs
for many other industrial sectors (Ferrentino and Larsen 2009).
Figure 2
month-on-month growth in %
10
10
-5
-5
-10
-10
-15
-15
-20
2008M1
2008M4
2008M7
2008M10
2009M1
2009M4
2009M7
-20
2008M1
2008M4
2008M7
2008M10
2009M1
2009M4
2009M7
The casual inspection of the data suggests that trade may have the potential to act as an important
transmission channel in particular for countries heavily exposed to those manufactured exports
experiencing the sharpest declines. For example, the Central, Eastern and Southeast European
countries (CESEE) are strongly specialized in exports of machinery and transport equipment. Recent
trade data for the CESEE EU member states reveal that indeed their exports of automobiles and
related parts declined strongly already in the fourth quarter of 2008 and thus before most of these
countries showed a GDP-reaction to the financial crisis. The initial drop was particularly strong in
exports of automobiles and related parts, followed by a substantial reduction in capital goods
exports in early 2009 (see Figure 3).
Figure 3
2.00
0.00
-2.00
-4.00
-6.00
-8.00
-10.00
2007Q1
2007Q2
2007Q3
2007Q4
2008Q1
2008Q2
2008Q3
Fuels, etc.
Capital Goods
Consumer Goods
Other Goods
2008Q4
2009Q1
2009Q2
2009Q3
Industrial Supplies
Source: Eurostat.
By all standards, the trade developments in 2009 represented a dramatic shock for all export
oriented countries throughout the world. In the next section, we will separate conceptually different
mechanisms through which this external demand shock could be transmitted to domestic output
shocks in individual countries.
which are highly integrated. This is also often considered to be an explanation why most crises
remain regional in scope (Caramazza, Ricci and Salgado, 2000).
Assigning the centre of the current crisis to the housing bubble in the US, all other countries have
been confronted with an external shock during 2007/2008. It is still unclear, to which extent this USbased crisis has then been transmitted by the financial channel as opposed to a real (i.e. trade)
channel. Looking at currency crises, Caramazza et al. (2000) identify weak output growth and to a
lesser extent external imbalances as important factors for the vulnerability of emerging and
developing countries. Trade and financial linkages play a role only when coupled with weak current
account balances. Also for industrial countries they find that fundamentals play an important role,
however, their importance differs with unemployment playing a greater role here. Haile and Pozo
(2008) also confirm these findings and stress the importance of fundamentals and highlight the
possibility of contagion through the trade channel, when fundamentals are weak.
Basically, three rather distinct channels emerge, which could explain the fast propagation of the crisis
across the globe. Two of these offer a demand-side explanation, while the third one works through
supply shortages. All three channels imply also an indirect role for international trade in crisis
transmission:
1. Rising importance of global value-chains
2. Structural differences between domestic and external sector
3. Problems in (trade) financing
The first two channels imply that the demand contraction in the US is transmitted across trading
partners with different intensity depending on structural characteristics of these countries. The third
channel is qualitatively different and describes a supply shock, i.e. production outside the US is
impeded due to deteriorating credit conditions.
3.1. Rising importance of global value-chains
The interconnectedness of modern production chains provides for the first channel. The US demand
shock is transmitted via international trade, often within a firm but nevertheless across countries,
through strongly integrated global supply chains, also referred to as fragmentation of production,
outsourcing or offshoring. The elasticity of trade to changes in GDP has been explored by many
empirical studies. While the literature provides different estimates depending on the model being
used, there is a clear consensus that the elasticity of trade to GDP seems to have increased over
recent years in response to the higher degree of vertical specialisation we see today. Irwin (2002)
estimates the elasticity of real world trade to real world income to have increased from around 2 in
the 1960s and 1970s to 3.4 in 1990. In a rather simple empirical framework, Freund (2009) finds this
elasticity to be around 3.5 today. Yi (2008) and Tanaka (2009) also attribute the significant increase in
the elasticity of trade to income to greater fragmentation of production. The high degree of vertical
integration we see today would however imply that the countries which are similarly integrated in
global value chains are hit to the same extent. However, this is not what we observed in practise.
Escaith (2009) attributes also a prominent role in the spreading of the 2008/09 crisis to trade effects.
He argues that global production networks aggravated the downturn in the real sector because
global supply chains involve a high degree of stock-building and hence financing. The drop in final
demand and the drying up of credit markets consequently resulted in the aggravation of the initial
effect in each link in the chain and thereby exacerbated the economic downturn. By the same logic,
economic recovery should also work its way back the supply chain in a similar way.
However, increased vertical specialization and supply chains might be only part of the explanation for
the strong trade reaction. As several authors point out (Francois and Woerz, 2009; Freund, 2009), a
6
part of the unproportionally strong drop in trade is due to simple accounting reasons. Since GDP is a
value added measure but trade data are measured on a gross value basis, any decline in GDP
necessarily triggers a relatively higher decline in trade. Double counting over countries adds to this.
Hence, the contribution to crisis-transmission by trade potentially remains considerably smaller than
the observed volatility in trade flows. A large decline in trade could reflect a much smaller decline in
global value added if production is done across countries at the margin and - as demand falls international production chains break down. For example, Porsche in April announced that it is
reducing production in Finland, but upholding German production (New York Times, 4 April 2009).
Firms may tend to source relatively more from home country suppliers during times of crisis.2
3.2. Structural differences between domestic and external sector
A second demand-side transmission channel via trade is to be found in structural differences
between the domestic sector and the external sector of an economy. For developed countries, about
80% of trade is manufactures, while they constitute only 20% of domestic GDP. This structural
argument offers an explanation for a different crisis-impact on countries depending on their specific
trade and GDP structure. Thus, not only openness as such matters for a countrys vulnerability to a
severe external demand shock, but it is important whether the country is particularly exposed to
those sectors which suffer the strongest decline in demand.
A casual inspection of available data underlines this argument. Figure 3 contrasts the differences in
GDP versus trade structure for the EU25 (as of 2004). The left panel of figure 3 shows a weighted
average for all EU members which acceded prior to 2004 (EU15), while the right hand side panel
gives the same data for the Central and Eastern European countries which acceded in 2004 (CEE EU
member states). The differences are striking. First of all, we see a clear distinction between the
industrial structure of the external sector (exports and imports) and domestic value added in each
region. The EU15 exhibit a typical structure for highly industrialized countries with 66% of domestic
income generated by the service sector in 2005. The manufacturing sector accounted for 30% in
domestic value added but as much as 80% of trade. The respective figures for the CEE EU member
states manufacturing sector were 43% and 89% respectively in 2005, the share of services in
domestic value added was at 48%. Thus, the importance of manufacturing in trade is much greater
than in domestic GDP for both regions, hence explaining the steep drop in trade during the peak of
the crisis.
As a word of caution, there is the danger that protectionist policies kick in when global GDP drops sharply and
this sharp drop is exacerbated through a decline in trade. However the same protectionist policies, while
arriving too late to shield a country from the downturn may also impede the country to profit from the global
upswing again. The Great Depression of the 1930s illustrated very impressively this policy mistake which has
led to a prolonged period of recession. (see Almunia et al. 2009)
Figure 4
100%
17.5
90%
80%
80%
12.1
60%
50%
50%
40%
40%
20%
66.6
3.2
11.3
72.7
73.7
3.8
63.0
30%
39.4
20%
26.9
10%
0%
15.6
70%
66.2
60%
30%
12.8
48.1
14.0
70%
9.9
90%
22.0
10%
8.7
3.7
1.9
2.9
Value Added
Exports
Imports
primary
other manufacturing
transport equ.
0%
services
Value Added
primary
1.8
2.2
Exports
Imports
other manufacturing
transport equ.
services
These figure further illustrates a second important difference between the two regions: The catchingup economies of Central and Eastern Europe show a higher share of manufacturing not only in trade
but also in domestic value added. A tenth of this is transport equipment, almost 4% of GDP and more
than 15% of exports for the region as a whole. This share is however higher for the three largest
economies in the region. According to recent Eurostat figures, exports of automobiles and related
parts accounted for 22% in the Czech Republic, 21% in Hungary and almost 23% in Poland in 2008.
Countries with high trade shares in industries and sectors that were hit especially hard in the crisis
were strongly affected by the crisis as well. During the 2008/09 downturn, the manufacturing
industries have been among the ones that have been hit the hardest. For Central and Eastern Europe,
the automobile sector along with increased risk perceptions by international investors was
particularly relevant for the deep impact of the crisis in 2009.
3.3. Problems in (trade) financing
Finally, financial crises may affect different sectors not only on the demand side but also through
different financing needs. Iacovona and Zavacka (2009) show that sectors which are highly
dependent on external financing needs suffer more from a banking crisis than other sectors. Auboin
(2009) assigns an important role to problems with financing in general and hence also with trade
finance concerning the trade collapse in the recent crisis. He stresses that credit for trade while
holding up well compared to other forms of credit until autumn 2008 - was subject to a tremendous
reassessment of risk and scarce liquidity in late 2008 as shown by the increase in spreads for credit
for emerging and developing countries. This is in line with Chauffour and Farole (2009) who underline
the role of trade finance in the recent trade collapse and give a number of reasons why trade finance
declines particularly strongly during times of financial crises: First, markets may encounter difficulties
in (re)assessing the associated risks, second, market participants face asymmetric information and
increased risks of default, third, financial intermediaries have to respond to scarce liquidity and
needs of recapitalization and finally, political factors might play a role as well. Furthermore, it might
be more difficult to assert ones claims across borders during times of crisis. Alun (2009) emphasizes
that trade is usually financed via short-term credit lines which are more easily cut back in times of
crises. He shows that the simultaneous halt of capital inflows and banking crises significantly lowers
imports in emerging economies.
8
interpreted as an indication of economic weakness (or perceptions thereof) before the full impact of
the crisis stroke. Apart from these prime variables of interest, we also control for a range of
alternative factors. Previous growth is included to control for effects from overheating. We further
control for weak fundamentals by including external debt stocks in relation to GDP. Finally, we also
include regional integration dummies. A detailed description of the variables used is given in
appendix table A1.
In order to minimize the number of missing observations and to even out short-term fluctuations on
some variables, we calculate a three-year average for all explanatory variables over the period 20062008. This approach also avoids endogeneity problems, since all explanatory variables are lagged
compared to the short-term reaction of GDP on changes in the external environment.3 For the
exchange rate and CDS spreads, we use the percentage change over the period 2006-2008 instead of
average levels, since we want to capture strong revaluations and thus already existing vulnerabilities
in these variables prior to the crisis, rather than relative standing of countries as reflecting a potential
initial weaknesses.4
We base our analysis on a sample consisting of 38 OECD and European countries (see appendix table
A2). Our data comes from various sources. We combine data from the IMF International Financial
Statistics and the World Banks World Development Indicators with data from Eurostat, national
sources and Datastream in order to obtain detailed information on trade structure and changes in
risk perception. A first inspection of the data shows an apparent but rather weak positive
relationship between the share of exports in GDP and the output response to the crisis. As
mentioned before, our dependent variable is defined such that a large positive value implies a strong
decline in GDP growth, hence in the figure below a positive correlation is interpreted as a reinforcing
effect of trade openness on the crisis response.
We also run two robustness checks replacing our dependent variable by the decline between 2008 and 2009
as well as 2007-2010. The results are presented in the appendix.
4
It lies outside the framework of our empirical model to capture transmission channels, and in particular the
financial channel, during the unfolding of the crisis, due to the simultaneity of events. The time period between
the large and sudden re-assessments of risks in late 2008, leading to sharp increases in credit costs, and the
outbreak of the crisis in individual countries is too short to be captured by the macro-economic data which we
are using in our model.
10
Figure 5
25
20
15
10
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
T rade O penness
We would like to emphasize that, although our original model might at first sight resemble a neoclassical
growth model, we are not trying to explain long-run determinants of economic growth here. Rather we want to
identify stylized facts of the short-run output reaction to the crisis. Put differently, we identify the
characteristics shared by countries prior to the outbreak of the crisis and which implied a particularly strong
decline in output.
6
This form of estimation is implemented in Stata through the command rreg.
11
12
(1)
-0.003
0.89
0.427 ***
0.00
0.074
0.20
0.511 ***
0.01
0.002 ***
0.00
(2)
0.019
0.47
(3)
(4)
0.354 ***
0.00
0.830 ***
0.00
0.001
0.56
0.487 ***
0.01
0.002 ***
0.01
-0.034
0.62
0.872 ***
0.00
0.001
0.48
xratio*vad_ind
xratio*er
constant
N
2
R
F
Prob > F
-5.721 ***
0.01
38
0.69
14.0 ***
0.00
4.953 ***
0.00
38
0.32
5.4 ***
0.00
-3.644 *
0.08
38
0.60
17.3 ***
0.00
5.510 ***
0.00
38
0.37
6.7 ***
0.00
(5)
0.216
0.03
0.705
0.00
0.107
0.34
0.652
0.00
0.002
0.01
-0.009
0.02
-0.004
0.09
-13.000
0.01
38
0.71
10.7
0.00
**
***
***
***
**
*
***
***
Note: The dependent variable is the percentage point change in real GDP growth between 2007 and
the projected growth rate for 2009; p-values are reported below each coefficient; *(**)[***] indicate
significance at the 10% (5%) [1%] level or below.
Columns 2-4 in table 1 show that our main variables of interest are robust to in- or exclusion of the
remaining two variables. Nevertheless, we further tested for possible multiplicative relationships
between export orientation and the remaining two main variables of interest. Controlling for
interactions between the export ratio and the weight of industry in GDP in column (5) brings out
more clearly the importance of either factor in aggravating the growth downturn, while at the same
time the two factors jointly seemed to have ameliorated the situation. Put differently, greater export
orientation has helped to soften the adverse effects arising from the dominance of the industrial
sector which was hit particularly strongly in during the crisis. However, this dampening effect is very
limited in scope, given the statistically significant (at the 2% level), but economically rather small
coefficient on the first interaction term. The second interaction between the export ratio and
exchange rate developments also shows a similar, economically small and statistically only weakly
significant, dampening impact on the growth downturn.7
Let us now turn to the remaining control variables in our model. There is clear evidence for the
overheating-hypothesis: countries with a previous fast growth performance (avgrowth) showed a
significantly greater contraction in GDP during the crisis. This effect is highly significant and robust
across different specifications. The coefficient of 0.6 implies that countries which on average grew by
1 pp more over the period 2006-2008 experienced a decline in GDP growth of 0.6 pps beyond the
average in the period 2007-2009. Finally, also the debt to GDP ratio (debt) emerges as a robust and
significant determinant of the growth reaction to the crisis in the sense that starting from a higher
debt ratio has clearly added to a countrys vulnerability in 2009.
The results are more or less robust to using an alternative timing for the calculation of the growth
downturn (see appendix table A3). In particular our results are not sensitive to measuring the growth
downturn by the change in GDP growth rates between 2008-2009 rather than 2007-2009. The same
7
We also included in a different specification the interaction term between the exchange rate and the industry
share in GDP, which turned out to be insignificant and without impact on the results.
13
factors emerge as being relevant, apart from the debt to GDP ratio, which looses its significance in
the very short term. On the other hand, strong currency depreciation just prior to the outbreak of
the crisis seemed to have intensified the growth downturn in the short run. The coefficient of roughly
0.2 in the appendix table implies that a 1% greater depreciation over the 2006-2008 period translates
into a 0.2 pp further decrease in real GDP on average in the very short-run (2008-2009). This may
reflect less investor confidence in countries with rather volatile exchange rate developments already
before the crisis as well as the fact that strong devaluations before the crisis may have limited the
scope for further devaluation during the crisis, which have improved nominal competitiveness in the
short run.
In this context, it is interesting to see some qualitative differences arising when looking at the
medium-term growth response. The last column of appendix table A3 uses the change in real GDP
growth between 2007 and the forecast for 2010 as the dependent variable. Neither the export ratio,
nor the share of industry in GDP or any of the interaction terms between the two show a significant
effect here. In contrast, now strong currency devaluation seems to have smoothed the GDP
contraction. This implies that in the medium term, depreciation and hence improvements in nominal
competitiveness have helped to bolster the impact of the crisis on GDP. However, one should bear in
mind that the dependent variable in this last specification in the appendix is subject to considerable
uncertainty, since the 2010 forecasts rely on information up until September 2009 plus on certain
external assumptions. Therefore, we decided to focus on the more short term output response using
forecasts for 2009 only which are already based on data for the first three quarters of 2009.
Table 2: Controlling for Different Regions
Variable
xratio
EU-27
0.198
0.05
vad_ind
0.680
0.00
er
0.123
0.28
avgrowth
0.674
0.00
debt
0.002
0.01
xratio*vad_ind
-0.008
0.03
xratio*er
-0.004
0.11
EU
0.591
0.51
EU10
**
***
***
***
**
EU-10
0.204
0.04
0.690
0.00
0.083
0.45
0.723
0.00
0.006
0.05
-0.009
0.02
-0.004
0.15
BAL
**
***
***
**
**
CEE
0.218
0.02
0.727
0.00
0.099
0.32
0.744
0.00
0.006
0.03
-0.009
0.01
-0.005
0.05
**
***
***
**
***
**
***
***
**
**
*
14.441 ***
0.00
CEE
N
2
R
F
Prob > F
**
0.845
0.39
BAL
constant
0.206
0.04
0.691
0.00
0.104
0.34
0.600
0.01
0.006
0.04
-0.009
0.02
-0.004
0.09
-13.000 ***
0.01
38
0.72
9.1 ***
0.00
-13.000 ***
0.00
37
0.74
9.9 ***
0.00
-14.000 ***
0.00
37
0.90
30.6 ***
0.00
1.188
0.27
-13.000 ***
0.00
37
0.74
9.9 ***
0.00
Note: The dependent variable is the percentage point change in real GDP growth between 2007 and
the projected growth rate for 2009; p-values are reported below each coefficient; *(**)[***] indicate
significance at the 10% (5%) [1%] level or below; see appendix table A1 for explanation of regional
dummies.
14
Controlling for regional integration clubs (table 2) does not alter the results of our baseline model
(last column in table 1). Controlling for membership in the EU or the effect of being located in
Eastern Europe, brings out the effect of most factors more clearly: the coefficients on domestic
economic structure, previous growth and debt ratios all increase marginally. This is particularly true
when we include a dummy for the three Baltic states, which showed by far the worst growth
performance, or in the framework of our model: the largest crisis response.
4.4. Robustness of the Results
Finally, we performed a series of robustness checks, using alternative measures to capture the effect
of financial weakness and trade. We continue to include the dummy for the Baltic states given their
extremely bad growth performance in 2009, which seems to be largely unrelated to the explanatory
variables in our model.8 In the first column in table 3 we use the growth in CDS spreads (in percent)
to control for early indication of financial trouble instead of changes in the exchange rate. The results
suggest that the reappraisal of risks has had a decisive influence for the impact of the crisis,
amounting to half a pp of additional loss in GDP growth following a one percent stronger rise in CDS
spreads. In columns 2 and 3 we alternatively use a dummy variable for Euro area members and fixed
exchange rate regimes instead of exchange rate movements. The results are again robust, however
the exchange rate dummies themselves are not statistically significant. Thus, we cannot identify any
effect (neither negative nor positive) from being a member of the euro zone or having a fixed
exchange rate regime.
In the last three columns of table 3, we add different measures of trade structure to our model. In
column 4 we include the share of consumer goods in total exports, while columns 5 and 6 use the
share of intermediate goods and goods shipped to the EU instead. The results are again highly robust
when controlling for sectoral and regional trade structure in addition openness to trade as in our
baseline specification. One new result emerges with respect to the commodity structure of trade: A
large share of consumption goods in total exports seemed to have had a cushioning effect during the
crisis. Contrary to our expectations, there is no evidence for a significantly negative influence arising
from global production chains given that the coefficient on the intermediate goods share fails to be
significant. Finally, export orientation to the EU also had no systematic effect for the growth
downturn.
To summarize, the sensitivity checks show that our results are rather robust to alternative
specifications concerning the financial channel and to refining the trade channel. Domestic output
structure appears as one of the strongest and quantitatively speaking most important determinant of
a countrys vulnerability in the recent crisis. Further, we find string evidence for an aggravating
impact (in terms of subsequent output loss) from previous high growth rates (i.e. overheating).
Finally, the negative influence from previously high debt ratios on the output response during the
crisis is confirmed.
The three Baltic countries show average values of export orientation, export structure and the share of
industry in GDP. They all have a fixed exchange rate regime. Their previous growth performance was mixed,
only Latvia showed very strong growth, coinciding with rather low debt ratio. The other two countries had
elevated debt ratios. All three countries clearly stand out with respect to the increase in CDS spreads between
2006 and 2008.
15
0.229 ***
0.01
0.462 ***
0.00
er
avgrowth
debt
exports*vad_ind
exports*financial 1)
BAL
cds
0.712
0.00
-0.008
0.13
-0.009
0.00
-0.015
0.01
16.55
0.00
0.505
0.00
***
***
***
***
EURO
FIX-ER
Exp_int
0.059
0.032
0.163
0.47
0.64
0.08
0.476 ***
0.403 ***
0.646
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.113
0.27
0.797 ***
0.871 ***
0.676
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.005 *
0.006 **
0.005
0.06
0.02
0.04
-0.003
-0.002
-0.007
0.36
0.50
0.04
-0.044
-0.077
-0.004
0.55
0.18
0.08
13.48 ***
14.25 ***
14.367
0.00
0.00
0.00
*
***
***
***
**
*
***
Exp_cons
0.188
0.02
0.626
0.00
0.033
0.72
0.816
0.00
0.007
0.00
-0.008
0.01
-0.004
0.04
15.136
0.00
**
***
***
***
***
*
***
***
***
***
***
*
***
1.017
0.67
FIX-ER
1.683
0.36
exp-int
0.054
0.17
exp-cons
-0.066 *
0.07
exp-eu27
N
R2
F
Prob > F
**
***
EURO
constant
Exp_EU27
0.216
0.02
0.697
0.00
0.062
0.58
0.774
0.00
0.006
0.02
-0.009
0.01
-0.004
0.07
14.410
0.00
-5.378
0.12
36
0.93
42.6 ***
0.00
-7.333 **
0.05
37
0.90
30.5 ***
0.00
-5.372 *
0.10
37
0.92
40.1 ***
0.00
-14.000 ***
0.00
37
0.90
26.6 ***
0.00
-9.448 ***
0.02
37
0.92
36.1 ***
0.00
-0.019
0.50
-12.000 ***
0.01
37
0.90
27.3 ***
0.00
Note: The dependent variable is the percentage point change in real GDP growth between 2007 and
the projected growth rate for 2009; p-values are reported below each coefficient; *(**)[***] indicate
significance at the 10% (5%) [1%] level or below.
1)
The interactions terms are built with the respective variables for financial factors used in each
specification and thus vary across columns.
16
5. Conclusions
World trade has reacted strongly to the global recession. Several reasons explain the particularly
strong response of trade to the decline in GDP. Besides accounting and price effects, increased
vertical specialisation and global supply chains boosted the drop of trade figures in the aftermath of
the financial crisis. While on the one side the decline in GDP had an impact on imports and exports
worldwide, the collapse of trade on the other side may also have aggravated the decline in growth
and helped to spread the crisis quickly and profoundly across regions. Due to sudden and severe
financing constraints demand dropped steeply in particular for durable consumption and investment
goods, thus causing a recession which fell hard on manufacturing and within the manufacturing
sector on intermediate goods. This in turn affected the functioning of global supply chains, making a
role for international trade as a transmission channel of the crisis. As a consequence, regions with
high trade and output share in these sectors are expected to be hit particularly hard during the crisis.
In this paper we present some empirical evidence to verify the above line of argument and to
quantitatively assess the importance of different factors for the impact of the crisis within a
predominantly European context. We focus on a sample of 38 countries, consisting of EU members,
advanced OECD members and a number of Eastern and South-Eastern European countries. We
employ robust regression techniques in the cross-section (owing to the uniqueness of the event) to
quantify the effect of trade openness on the reversal of GDP growth, thereby controlling for a range
of additional determinants such as structural features of the economies, exchange rate
developments, previous growth performance and external debt ratios to account for macroeconomic
imbalances at large. Thus, we do not attempt to determine the timing or causes of the crisis. Our
econometric model rather identifies how the vulnerability of individual countries to the common
shock occurring in late 2008 is determined by national characteristics of each country.
Our analysis suggests that greater export orientation is related to a stronger growth downturn in our
sample but the effect is only revealed when allowing for interaction terms between the export ratio
and the structure of GDP. In quantitative terms, the marginal effect of export openness is nonnegligible but still considerably lower than the impact of domestic economic structure on the growth
reversal. In contrast to the conditional findings for openness, we find quite convincing evidence that
the domestic structure of value added matters strongly for a countrys vulnerability during the recent
crisis. Those countries with a higher share of domestic value added in the industrial sector as
opposed to more service-based economies were suffering more severe GDP shortfalls. While the
predominance of the industrial sector for a countrys output response in the crisis is independent of
other characteristics of the economy, the trade effect only materializes when interacted with
structural characteristics of the economy. Thus, an important finding relates to the observation that
the trade shock could only result in adverse growth dynamics when coupled with an appropriate
economic structure. Hence, only the combination of different characteristics allow us to explain
regional differences in the impact of the crisis.
Another highly robust result gives support to the overheating hypothesis: previous high growth rates
are systematically linked to a stronger growth downturn in all specifications. Further, a negative
influence from previously high debt ratios on the output response during the crisis is confirmed
reflecting increased vulnerability from the fiscal side. Our results support the view that a higher level
of indebtedness prior to the crisis implied severe limitations to the room for necessary countercyclical measures during the crisis.
Sensitivity checks show that our results for are rather robust and in particular do not depend on the
geographical composition of trading partners and only to a limited extent on the sectoral
composition of trade. Countries which are specialized in consumption goods suffered relatively
weaker declines in output growth, while a specialization on intermediate goods failed to yield a
17
statistically significant result. However, all these robustness checks suggest that the case for a strong
role for trade alone in aggravating the crisis remains limited.
The robust correlation between the importance of industry and manufacturing and the severity of
the crisis response raises of course another, highly policy relevant question: Did the crisis reveal a
fundamental structural change, or in other words: Are the industries which suffered the strongest
declines in the recent crisis going to recover or will they loose importance in the near future? This
would of course call for a completely different set of long-term, structural policy responses, rather
than short-term interventions in the reaction to the crisis.
Finally, since we find only weak evidence that openness to trade has reinforced the impact of the
crisis on the growth performance in the short-run, it remains an open question by how much trade is
able to spur growth in the upswing. In the presence of global supply chains, open borders are of
course an important pre-requisite to guarantee the functioning of economic activity and to assure a
prosperous development in all countries. However, hopes that trade will pull the world out of
recession may be unwarranted as long as credit markets are not fully functioning and global demand
for goods continues to remain below average.
18
References
Aizenman J. (2008), On the hidden links between financial and trade opening, Journal of
International Money and Finance 27 (2008) 372-386.
Almunia M., A. Bntrix, B. Eichengreen, K.ORourke, G. Rua (2009), From Great Depression to Great
Credit Crisis: Similarities, Differences and Lessons, Paper presented at the 50th Economic Policy
Panel Meeting, Tilburg, October, 2009
Alun T. (2009), Financial Crises and Emerging Market Trade, IMF Staff Position Note 09/04
Auboin M. (2009) Boosting the availability of trade finance in the current crisis: Background analysis
for a substantial G20 package, Policy Insight No. 35, June 2009, Centre for Economic Policy Research
Caramazza F., L. Ricci and R. Salgado (2000), Trade and Financial Contagion in Currency Crises, IMF
Working Paper 55/2000.
Cavallo E., J. Frankel (2008), Does openness to trade make countries more vulnerable to sudden
stops, or less? Using gravity to establish causality, Journal of International Money and Finance 27
(2008) 1430-1452.
Chauffour J-P., T. Farole (2009), Trade Finance in Crisis Market Adjustment or Market Failure?,
Policy Research Working Paper 5003, July 2009, The World Bank.
Cook, R. D. (1977), "Detection of Influential Observations in Linear Regression", Technometrics,
American Statistical Association 19 (1) 1518.
Edwards S. (2004), Financial Openness, Sudden Stops and Current Account Reversals NBER Working
Paper 10277
Escaith H. (2009), Trade Collapse, Trade Relapse and Global Production Networks: Supply Chains in
the Great Recession, MPRA Paper No. 18433.
Ferrentino M., A. Larsen, (2009), Transmission of the global recession through US trade, VoxEU,
November 2009.
Fidrmuc J., I. Korhonen (2009), The impact of the global financial crisis on business cycles in Asian
emerging economies, BOFIT Discussion Papers 11/2009.
Francois J., J. Woerz (2009), Follow the Bouncing Ball Trade and the Great Recession Redux
Freund, C. (2009), The Trade Response to Global Downturns. Historical Evidence, World Bank
Working Papers 5015, August 2009.
Haile F., S. Pozo (2001), Currency crisis contagion and the identification of transmission channels,
International Review of Economics and Finance 17 (2008) 572588.
Huber, P. (1981), Robust Statistics, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 153-199.
Iacovona and Zavacka, (2009), Banking Crises and Exports: Lessons from the Past, World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper No. 5016, August 2009
IMF World Economic Outlook 10/2009
19
Irwin, D. (2002) Long-Run Trends in World Trade and Income World Trade Review, 1, pp 89-100.
Martin P., H. Rey (2006), Globalization and Emerging Markets: With or Without Crash?, NBER
Working Paper 11550.
McKibbin, W.J., A. Stoeckel (2009), Modelling the Global Financial Crisis. Centre for Applied
Macroeconomic Analysis, The Australian National University, Working Paper 25/2009.
Dougherty C. (2009), Porsche Finds Fortune From Unlikely Outsourcing, New York Times,
04.04.2009
Rose A., M. Spiegel (2009), Cross-Country Causes and Consequences of the 2008 Crisis: International
Linkages and American Exposure, NBER Working Paper 15358.
Tanaka, K. (2009) Trade collapse and international supply chains: Evidence from Japan VoxEU.org,
May 2009.
Yaffee, R. (2002) Robust Regression Analysis: Some Popular Statistical Package Options ITS
Statistics, Social Science and Mapping Group, New York State University, downloaded on Dec 23 2009
from: http://www.nyu.edu/its/statistics/Docs/RobustReg2.pdf
Yi, K-M. (2009) The Collapse of Global Trade: The Role of Vertical Specialization in The Collapse of
Global Trade, Murky Protectionism, and the Crisis: Recommendations for the G20, edited by R.
Baldwin and S. Evenett, a VoxEU.org publication.
20
Appendix
Appendix Table A1: List of Variables and Data Sources
Variable name
Description
dependent variable
gdp0709
Absolute difference in real GDP growth 2007 to real GDP growth forecasts for 2009, in pp
gdp0809
gdp0710
Absolute difference in real GDP growth 2008 compared to real GDP growth forecasts for
2009, in pp
Absolute difference in real GDP growth 2007 compared to real GDP growth forecasts for
2010, in pp
Source
Eurostat/ Consensus Economics
trade factors
xratio
exp_cons
exp_eu27
Export share of consumption goods plus motor spirit and passenger motor cars (in % of total Eurostat/ IMF
exports)
Export share to EU-27 (in % of total exports)
Eurostat/ IMF
exp_int
Eurostat/ IMF
Datastream
Eurostat/ IMF
structural factors
vad_ind
financial factors
cds
2
er
Eurostat/ IMF
Eurostat/ IMF
regional dummies
BAL
CEE
Dummy variable for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Belarus, Czech Republic,
Estonia, Croatia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Montenegro, Macedonia, Poland, Romania,
Serbia, Russia, Slovenia, Slovakia, Ukraine
EU
EU10
Dummy variable for Poland, Slovakia, Slovenia, Czech Republic, Hungary, Estonia, Latvia,
Lithuania, Bulgaria, Romania
FIX-ER
Dummy variable for countries with fixed exchange rates (Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Bosnia
and Herzegovina, Cyprus, Germany, Estonia, Spain, Finland, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy,
Luxembourg, Lithuania, Latvia, Macedonia, Malta, Montenegro, The Netherlands, Portugal,
Slovakia, Slovenia)
EURO
Note: All control variables represent averages over the period 2006-2008, except of the exchange
rate and CDS, where the growth rate between 2006 and 2008 was used.
1
Growth of CDS spreads between 2006 and 2008; data on 5y CDS spreads were not available for
Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Belarus, Switzerland, Macedonia, Norway, and the United Stated,
for these countries, CDS spreads were assumed to equal zero.
2
Growth of the nominal exchange rate of national currency vis-a-vis the euro between 2006 and
2008, a positive number indicates a depreciation of the national currency vis-a-vis the euro.
21
Greece
Romania
Austria
Hungary
Russia
Belarus
Ireland
Serbia
Belgium
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Italy
Slovak Republic
Japan
Slovenia
Bulgaria
Latvia
Spain
Croatia
Lithuania
Sweden
Czech Republic
Luxembourg
Switzerland
Denmark
Macedonia
Turkey
Estonia
Netherlands
Ukraine
Finland
Norway
United Kingdom
France
Poland
United States
Germany
Portugal
Appendix Table A3: Sensitivity of results to differences in the timing of measured growth downturn.
Variable
xratio
vad_ind
er
xratio*vad_ind
xratio*er
avgrowth
debt
constant
N
2
R
F
Prob > F
2007-2009
0.216
0.03
0.705
0.00
0.107
0.34
0.65
0.00
0.00
0.01
-0.009
0.02
-0.004
0.09
-13.000
0.01
38
0.71
10.7
0.00
**
***
***
***
**
*
***
***
2008-2009
0.237
0.02
0.524
0.00
0.196
0.09
0.88
0.00
0.00
0.21
-0.008
0.03
-0.002
0.39
-11.000
0.01
37
0.75
12.4
0.00
**
***
*
***
**
***
***
2007-2010
-0.054
0.34
0.073
0.43
-0.114
0.08
0.81
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.002
0.42
0.002
0.19
-1.942
0.44
37
0.83
20.4
0.00
*
***
***
***
Note: The dependent variable is the percentage point change in real GDP growth; p-values are
reported below each coefficient; *(**)[***] indicate significance at the 10% (5%) [1%] level or below.
22