Henn
Henn
Henn
avoiding protectionism
Cargo at Maersk Terminal, Long Beach, California.
so far the world has resisted widespread resort to trade measures, but the hardest part may be yet to come
ECESSIONS and their aftermath adjusted gross domestic product (GDP) have been breeding grounds for during the same periodwhich reached protectionist pressures. When eco2 percent among major advanced economies nomic output falls and joblessness (see Chart 1). The severity of the trade colrises, the notion that somehow foreign trade lapse does not appear to be the result of any is at fault is seductive. The temptation grows significant resort to protectionism, however. to export unemployment by blocking imports Instead, it appears to be the result of a globally and subsidizing domestic industrieseven synchronized decline in overall demand that though evidence shows that such policies are had a particularly strong effect on international commerce because of three major charcounterproductive. The Great Depression of the 1930s spawned acteristics of trade flows in recent years. serious protectionist actions that exacerbated First, trade in durable goods and other and extended the economic and social chaos McDonald postponable purchaseswhich comprise around the world. The recent global financial crisis is generally Chart 1 considered the worst economic calamity since Out of line the 1930s. Financial markets froze. Output plummeted, especially in the advanced econoRelative to declines in output and industrial mies. World trade shriveled in the final months production, the drop in world trade in the final months of 2008 was far steeper than in of 2008. World leaders, though, averred that previous recessions. they had learned the lessons of the Great (September 2008 = 100) Depression and vowed to resist protectionist 105 pressures. Have they succeeded? And even if G-3 real GDP 100 the world has so far withstood the pressure, are these concerns behind us? 95
90 85 80 2005
World industrial production World trade volume 2006 2007 2008 2009
Sources: CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, and IMF, World Economic Outlook. Note: Real GDP is a simple average of the GDPs of the United States, the euro area, and Japan, seasonally adjusted.
McDonal
a disproportionately large share of tradecollapsed most sharply. Financial turmoil led credit markets to seize up. The spike in uncertainty in financial markets caused consumers (already shaken by the loss of wealth in the housing and stock market downturns) to delay purchases of durable items, such as electronic products and cars, on an unprecedented scale. Firms shelved investment plans in response to lower consumer demand and higher capital costs, reducing demand for capital goods. Capital goods and consumer durables make up most of global merchandise trade (see Chart 2)but a much smaller share of world GDP, which is composed largely of services and nondurables. This asymmetry may explain half or more of the collapse in trade (Levchenko, Lewis, and Tesar, 2009; Baldwin, 2009). Second, because of extensive global supply chains, components are traded a number of times before the final good is produced. Downturns magnify these supply chain effects: postponable goods have more extensive supply chains, and in a downturn firms curtail their intermediate input orders both to reduce output and to cut inventories (Freund, 2009). Justin-time production techniques have allowed firms to maintain lower inventories, but they propagate demand shocks more rapidly. This inventory-adjustment role can shed light on the abruptness of the trade collapse in late 2008 and early 2009after which trade leveled off quickly. Countries most integrated in global supply chains experienced the most abrupt decline in trade. Japans exports, for example, contracted by a third over this period. Third, increased reliance on trade finance may have contributed to trade contraction. Global supply chains mean that firms need longer-term financing for their working capital, given that products take more time to reach the end consumer. And because of these longer supply chains, bankintermediated trade financing, which creates assurances between importers and exporters, has become more important. At least in the early stages of the crisis, the higher costs and declining availability of trade finance had a negative impact, especially in emerging market economies (Dorsey, 2009). Trade has begun to recover, but the durability of that recovery is not yet assured. World export volumes increased by about 10 percent between May and November 2009 (see Chart 3). Global supply chains seem to be playing a key role in the rebound: the regions most integrated in these chains, such as east Asia, have experienced the strongest recovery in trade. However, advanced economy imports have slowed down since September (see Chart 4). Sustaining open markets will be especially important to underpin trade and to support a broad-based recovery.
Chart 2
Postponable purchases
Consumer durable items and capital goods make up a large portion of world trade.
Iron and steel Chemicals Fuels and minerals Agricultural products Electronics Autos Textiles/clothing Other manufactures
Manufactures
Source: World Trade Organization, International Trade Statistics. Note: Data are for 2007.
McDonal
Chart 3
Hit hardest
Countries most integrated in the global supply chain have experienced the fastest recovery.
(export volume, September 2008 = 100) 105 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65
Jan. Dec. Oct. Sep. Feb. Mar. Nov. Apr.
Japan
Jun. Jul. Sep. Aug. Oct. Nov. May
McDonal 60
2008
2009
Chart 4
Sluggish again
After rebounding in early 2009, import growth in advanced economies began to slow in September.
(import levels, September 2008 = 100) 105 100 95 90 85 80 75 Japan Euro area United States
Jan.
Dec.
Jun.
Sep.
Sep.
Aug.
Mar.
Nov.
Feb.
Oct.
Oct.
Apr.
Jul.
2008
2009
Nov.
1
May
since the crisis began (WTO, 2009). Although several countries have raised tariffs on some (mostly narrow) product categories, only a few countries have imposed more widespread increases. Many developing countries have eschewed tariff increases despite WTO tariff ceilings that provide ample room for them to raise their applied tariff ratesdemonstrating, perhaps, an awareness of the importance of open markets to their own economic performance as well as to global recovery. Trade measures adopted in response to the crisis may nonetheless have tilted the playing field in some markets. Government bailouts and increased subsidies may have deflected pressure for more damaging measures, but have tended to favor domestic enterprises, particularly in the financial and manufacturing sectors. Expanded government procurement preferences for domestic firms also disadvantaged competitorsand diminished the impact of stimulus measures on global growth. Other subtle responses to the crisis include nontariff barriers such as restrictive import licensing and more cumbersome customs procedures, and the apparent intensification of product standards and regulations. Finally, as trade recovered, industries began to file petitions for antidumping measures at a greater rate in the second half of 2009 (Bown, 2009).
payments (Eichengreen and Irwin, 2009). Major countries undertook substantial currency devaluations, imposed exchange restrictions, or sharply tightened import tariffs and introduced import quotas. Lacking an independent monetary policy, countries that kept their currencies fixed against gold were more likely to restrict trade, particularly once partner countries devalued their own currencies. Global trade volume fell by 25 percent between 1929 and 1933, with nearly half of this decline attributable to higher trade barriers. In the United States, the new tariff raised the average rate on dutiable imports from an already high 40 percent to 47 percent. A larger effect, however, came through the interaction of deflation and the use of specific tariffs. Irwin (1998) concluded that increases in the effective tariff (both from Smoot-Hawley and deflation) accounted for a 12 to 20 percentage point decline in U.S. imports between 1930 and 1932. Although protectionism did not cause the Great Depression, higher trade barriers exacerbated it andmost important worked to choke off recovery. Global output returned to its precrisis levels by 1938, but with a trade-to-GDP ratio some 20 percent below that of 1929. Even though the layers of restrictions were peeled away from 1934 onward, in some cases it took decades to reverse the missteps of 193032.
Because trade has begun to grow more quickly than has overall activity, the return of imports toward their precrisis market share could stir protectionist demands.
Job losses during 200809 occurred at a time of declining imports, when trade was contracting much more than overall economic activity. As the market share of imports was falling, foreign-made goods were not typically blamed for job losses. Nor did targeting imports appeal to those concerned with stemming job losses. But, because trade has begun to grow more quickly than has overall activity, the return of imports toward their precrisis market share could stir protectionist demandsparticularly where unemployment remains high and in sectors that are slow to recover. There are other reasons protectionist sentiment may grow. In the past, multilateral or bilateral current account deficits have commonly been used as an argument to restrict trade. Although the recent trade contraction resulted in a narrowing of external imbalances, the extent to which these may reemerge is not yet clear. When fiscal, monetary, and financial sector stimulus measures are withdrawn, affected firms and industries may begin to call for trade protection. Higher commodity prices bring a risk that some countries will impose taxes or restrictions on their commodity exportsa risk that was demonstrated during the 200708 food price crisis. Finally, in some emerging markets a surge in capital inflows has brought significant currency appreciation. Regardless of the appropriateness of the new exchange rate, this can strain the competitive position of exporters and of the importcompeting domestic sector and generate pressure for import protection and export support.
many restrictions may have been imposed, but their application has been relatively narrow. Still, protectionist pressures may intensify in 2010 because unemployment is likely to remain high and imports will bounce back. In the near future there are three key issues that bear on international trade developments: Enhanced monitoring of trade policy actions has influenced policy for the better. Clearly identifying discriminatory policieswithout overstating their frequency or effectshas been an effective deterrent. There is room for more of this activity. The possibility of backdoor or murky protectionism remains. The risks may materialize not as a customs tariff, but as public procurement policies, product standards, customs procedures, or other actions whose protectionist effects are less transparent. Concluding the WTO Doha Round of multilateral trade negotiations would help ensure that markets remain open, allowing trade to play its role in the economic recovery and to support strong growth for years to come. Securing tariffs at lower levels, reducing the potential for trade-distorting farm subsidies, enhancing trade policy transparency, and tightening multilateral rules in such trade-related areas as food aid and fishery subsidies would reduce the risk of future trade conflicts and strengthen global economic relations. n Christian Henn is an Economist and Brad McDonald a Deputy Division Chief in the IMFs Strategy, Policy, and Review Department.
References: Baldwin, Richard, ed., 2009, The Great Trade Collapse: Causes, Consequences and Prospects. Available at VoxEU.org Bown, Chad, 2009, The Global Resort to Antidumping, Safeguards, and other Trade Remedies amidst the Economic Crisis, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS5051 (Washington). Dorsey, Thomas, 2009, Trade Finance Stumbles, Finance and Development, Vol. 46, No. 1, pp. 1819. Eichengreen, Barry, and Douglas A. Irwin, 2009, The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why? NBER Working Paper 15142 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Freund, Caroline, 2009, The Trade Response to Global Downturns: Historical Evidence, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS5015 (Washington). Irwin, Douglas A., 1998, The Smoot-Hawley Tariff: A Quantitative Assessment, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80, No. 2, pp. 32634. Levchenko, Andrei A., Logan Lewis, and Linda L. Tesar, 2009, The Collapse of International Trade During the 20082009 Crisis: In Search of the Smoking Gun, Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy Research Seminar in International Economics Discussion Paper 592 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan). World Trade Organization (WTO), 2008, World Tariff Profiles 2008 (Geneva). , 2009, Overview of Developments in the International Trading Environment (Geneva, November).
Finance & Development March 2010